Revenue Mobilization in Developing Countries
Revenue Mobilization in Developing Countries
Revenue Mobilization in Developing Countries
March 8, 2011
Contents Page
I. Introduction ............................................................................................................................6
Table
1.VAT Features by Income Group...........................................................................................25
Figures
1. Revenue-Related and Other Structural Benchmarks, 2002–10 ...........................................11
2. Trends in Total and Tax Revenue 1980–2009 .....................................................................12
2
Boxes
1. Common Elements of Strategies for Reform .......................................................................10
2. The Regional Perspective ....................................................................................................15
3. Aid, Resource Wealth, and Revenue Mobilization ..............................................................16
4. Key Challenges for Tax Reform ..........................................................................................18
5. The Distributional Impact of Exemptions and Reduced Rates ............................................26
Appendices
I. Technical Assistance on Tax Matters ...................................................................................46
II. Tax Reform in Post-Conflict and Successor States .............................................................48
III. Data ....................................................................................................................................50
IV. Understanding Tax Performance and Effort ......................................................................56
V. Estimating Tax Effort..........................................................................................................59
VI. Strong Performers—Three Examples ................................................................................63
VII. Taxing Natural Resources—Issues and Principles ...........................................................66
VIII. Estimated Revenue Gains from Increasing VAT Efficiency ..........................................68
IX. Zambia: Building and Maintaining a VAT ........................................................................70
X. Dangers of Tax Holidays ....................................................................................................71
XI. Regional Agreement on Corporate Taxation—Possible Principles...................................72
XII. Experience with Unilateral Removal of Tax Incentives ..................................................74
Appendix Tables
2. Summary Statistics...............................................................................................................53
3. Fixed Country Grouping ......................................................................................................55
4. Estimated Tax Effort ............................................................................................................60
5. VAT Efficiency by Income Group ......................................................................................68
Appendix Figure
14. Revenue Administration and Tax Policy Mission Intensity, FY2008–10 .........................46
References ................................................................................................................................75
3
IT Information Technology
HR Human Resources
RA Revenue Authority
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
The Fund has long played a lead role in supporting developing countries’ efforts to
improve their revenue mobilization. This paper draws on that experience to review issues and
good practice, and to assess prospects in this key area.1
The need for additional revenue is substantial in many developing countries, but improving
revenue mobilization has importance beyond that. Requirements for relieving poverty and
improving infrastructure are substantial: achieving the Millennium Development Goals, for
instance, may require low-income countries to raise their tax-GDP ratios by around 4 percentage
points (United Nations, 2005). But the quality of measures also matters: increasing revenue by
further taxing readily compliant taxpayers can worsen distortions and perceived inequities;
conversely, reducing reliance on trade taxes can bring real structural gains that outweigh
short-term revenue difficulties. More fundamentally still, the centrality of taxation in the exercise
of state power means that more efficient, fairer, and less corrupt tax systems can spearhead
improvement in wider governance relations.
Experience shows that progress can be made—given strong political will. There have been
disappointments: in some areas of advice (such as early espousal of the global income tax) and in
country practice (the use made of improved IT systems, for instance). But several countries have
significantly improved their tax performance over relatively short periods, and econometric
analysis (comparing performance in differing countries) suggests that many lower-income
countries could increase their tax ratios by 2–4 percent of GDP. A common element of success
stories is sustained political commitment at the highest levels: even administrative reforms can
prompt strong opposition. Reforms must be entrenched, however, to avoid subsequent slippage.
Eliminating exemptions that forego revenue to little useful end—these are often still
substantial and can amount to several points of GDP;
Implementing a broad-based VAT with a fairly high threshold (the turnover level at
which registration for the tax becomes compulsory)—in lower-income countries where
VAT performance is weakest, base-broadening and improved compliance might raise
something in the order of an additional 2 percent of GDP;
Establishing a broad-based corporate income tax, at rates competitive by international
standards—more has been done on the latter than on the former, leaving signs of
significant scope for base-broadening in many lower-income countries;
Extending the PIT base, and ensuring a coherent treatment of alternative forms of capital
income—still a major challenge;
Levying excises on a few key items that are adequate to revenue needs and wider social
concerns—these too have further potential in some countries;
Implementing simple but coherent regimes for taxing smaller businesses—now receiving
increased attention;
Strengthening real estate taxes—minimal in many countries, but with potential to
transform local government finance in the longer-term; and
Developing capacity for tax expenditure and wider policy analysis—impressive advances
in some countries, but much still to do in others.
There are emerging concerns and issues requiring greater attention. Challenges in
international taxation and from regional integration are intensifying, and call for closer
cooperation on tax matters—including with advanced economies—in both policy and
administration, as well as further support for capacity building. Continued trade liberalization
will put pressure on revenue in many lower-income countries. Scope to meet these and other
revenue needs by simply raising standard VAT rates is becoming limited, so the potential lies
largely in better improving compliance and scaling back preferential treatments. Not least, and
important too for the wider legitimacy of tax systems, greater efforts can be made—requiring
political will as much as technical capacity—in taxing elites and high-income/wealth individuals.
6
I. INTRODUCTION
2
Other signs of strong donor interest include the creation of two trust funds to support the Fund’s tax TA, the
emphasis on the issue by the European Commission (2010), the creation by the Development Assistance Committee
of a Task Force on Tax and Development, and of the DfID/NORAD-sponsored International Centre for Tax and
Development.
3
Meaning, broadly speaking, low- and lower middle-income countries (in the World Bank classification, per capita
income below $995 and between $996–3,945); for perspective, indicators for upper middle-income ($3,946–12,195)
and advanced countries are also sometimes reported below.
4
Several recent surveys bear on these issues: African Development Bank and OECD (2010), Bird (2008), ECORYS
(2010; prepared for the Dutch Ministry of Finance), Gordon (2010), Keen and Simone (2004), and Chambas (2005),
and Keen and Mansour (2010a, b) on sub-Saharan Africa.
5
This paper will inform the Fund’s contribution to the work requested by the G-20.
7
for reform strategies), recent trends, and the scope to raise more.
5. Raising revenue is the core objective of any tax system, but revenue is not the sole
concern. The spending needs of developing countries are substantial, and both greater and,
ultimately, more sustained than can be met from foreign assistance.6 In low-income countries
(LICs) the revenue imperative is stark: over 20 still have tax ratios (tax revenue relative to GDP)
under 15 percent.7 But there are other considerations:
The effects which theory suggests the level and composition of taxes can have on
efficiency and long-run growth—via investment, human capital acquisition, and
innovation—have proved hard to identify robustly. For OECD countries, Arnold (2008)
concludes that property taxes are least damaging for growth, followed by consumption
taxes, the personal income tax (PIT), and the corporate income tax (CIT): this is as theory
suggests, with taxation of capital income having a potentially strong impact on
investment. But there has been much less work for developing countries, and what there
is tends to find no significant effect from either the overall level of taxation or the
direct-indirect tax mix (Adams and Bevan, 2005; and Martinez-Vasquez, Vulovic, and
Liu, 2009). Lee and Gordon (2005) find lower CIT rates are associated with faster
growth, including in non-OECD countries, though other tax variables are insignificant.
Evidence that trade liberalization fosters growth (Wacziarg and Welch, 2008) suggests a
potential impact from reduced reliance on trade tax revenue. Other effects likely operate
through the considerable volatility of tax revenue in many developing countries (there
being some evidence that this depresses public investment: Ebeke and Ehrhart, 2010),
stressing the value of diversifying revenue sources;
where the real incidence of taxation falls is difficult in advanced economies, and no
easier in the different context of lower-income economies; and
Taxation is a defining feature of state power, making its improvement a key aspect of
state-building. This consideration, which stresses the view of tax reform as an investment
central to wider institutional development, has been prominent in recent policy
initiatives.8 What remains unclear is what its increased recognition means for tax advice
and policy.
6. Developing countries face many common tax challenges. Most are qualitatively the
same as in advanced economies—but much larger.9 They include:
Dealing with sectors that are ‘hard-to-tax’ everywhere (small businesses, including small
farmers, professionals, and—in some cases—state-owned enterprises), but especially
where administrative capacity and compliance habits are weak. ‘Informality’ is extensive
in developing countries—perhaps 40 percent of GDP on average, up to 60 percent in
many.10 But this is arguably not in itself the problem:11 micro traders may be ‘informal,’
for instance, but are also likely to have income and sales well below any reasonable tax
threshold; and much of the most egregious evasion is by qualified professionals. The
issue is best framed as one of non-compliance. Estimates of non-compliance are scarce,
but Value-Added Tax (VAT) ‘gaps’12 have been put at 50–60 percent in Indonesia and
Mozambique, for instance, compared to 13 percent in the United Kingdom;
8
See for instance OECD (2008) and Everest-Philips (2008).
9
Gordon and Li (2009), Heady (2002), and Keen and Simone (2004) discuss the distinct tax-relevant features of
developing countries.
10
See Schneider, Buehn, and Montenegro (2010).
11
The term is used loosely here, and indeed—one reason to prefer the focus on non-compliance suggested here—is
rarely well-defined (Kanbur, 2009); Keen (2011) elaborates.
12
VAT revenue with full compliance less actual VAT revenue, relative to the former; the figures are from Silvani et
al. (2008) and Castro et al. (2009).
9
Pressures on revenue from trade liberalization, including regional integration, and from
intensifying international tax competition; and
7. But there are also significant differences among developing countries. Probably the
most important is in natural resource wealth. Geography also matters. Small islands are better
able to impose taxes at the border than are landlocked countries; this may explain both why they
have been less inclined to adopt a VAT13 and why, when adopted, it tends to perform well.14
Post-conflict countries, with shattered administrations and tax bases, face particular difficulties,
as do successor states eager to establish investor-friendly reputations (Appendix II provides case
studies). History also has a role: constitutional restrictions dating to the 1935 Government of
India Act still powerfully constrain VAT design in both India and Pakistan, for instance, and
there is evidence that differing legal traditions, reflecting colonial pasts, are associated with
different revenue performance.
8. Fund advice reflects both these similarities and the differences. A common criticism is
that Fund tax advice is ‘one size fits all.’15 Some tax practices are indeed close to universally
appropriate: establishing firm control of the largest taxpayers, for instance. Beyond that there are
certainly commonalities in broad strategies for reform (Box 1), reflecting the generality of
underlying economic and organizational principles. But the timing, relative importance, and
precise design of appropriate tax reform measures varies substantially. Advice has repeatedly
stressed, for instance, the need for substantial administrative reform in advance of VAT
adoption. Sometimes addressing severe non-compliance is an overwhelming priority, leading to
a focus on strengthening enforcement actions before moving to medium-term reforms. And
countries’ idiosyncrasies affect the substance of advice. Substantial re-exporting in The Gambia,
for instance, gave pause before recommending a VAT (given the difficulties of exporter
13
Keen and Lockwood (2010).
14
Chapter 4 of Ebrill et al. (2001), and Aizenman and Jinjarak (2008).
15
As for instance in Stewart and Jogarajan (2004) and Marshall (2009).
10
refunding, discussed below); and constitutional constraints have affected the design and
implementation of effective VATs. Political and social views on the proper degree of
progressivity vary widely, the traditional role of the external advisor then being to describe and
assess alternatives.
16
The term encompasses both domestic tax and customs administration.
11
200
150
100
50
0
2002-03 2007-08 2009-10
10. Revenues in lower-income countries (especially LICs) showed resilience through the
crisis. Figure 218 shows developments since 1980 in three measures of government revenue:
total, excluding grants from abroad, and—the focus in the bulk of this paper—tax revenue
(including social security contributions). The narratives naturally differ, but the buoyancy of
revenues in LICs in particular is apparent.
Government Revenue
45.0
40.0
35.0
30.0
25.0
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
0.0
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
17
The analysis in this paper draws on a mix of GFS, WEO and other data, from 1980 on—an eclecticism that
reflects limitations of available revenue data for developing countries. Appendix III provides detail.
18
Figures show medians (rather than means) to limit the impact of outliers and data gaps. ‘Dynamic’ income groups
are constructed by ranking countries by income per capita at each date, and dividing them into four equal-sized
groups: this avoids biases from classifying countries by income at any single date (using final income per capita, for
instance, could exclude strong revenue performers that migrate to the LMIC group, giving an unduly pessimistic
view of LICs as a group). Averages and/or categorizing groups by their final incomes, however, gives broadly the
same conclusions as follow.
13
Tax Revenue
40.0
35.0
30.0
25.0
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
0.0
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
Low in come Lo wer mid dle income Up per middle in come High income
11. Revenues from natural resources played an important role in the relatively strong
performance of recent years, but were not the only factor. Data on resource-related receipts
are poor, but they loom very large in the fiscal situations of many countries (Figure 3). Keen and
Mansour (2010) find that, within sub-Saharan Africa, revenue has performed more strongly in
resource-rich countries. Figure 4, however—comparing experiences in resource-rich and other
countries more widely—shows not only the massively greater volatility of receipts in the former
but also that tax ratios have increased over recent years in non-resource countries too.
Petroleum Minerals
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
United Arab…
Syrian Arab…
Kazakhstan
Indonesia
Oman
Vietnam
Angola
Algeria
Iraq
Nigeria
Bahrain
Equatorial Guinea
Saudi Arabia
Qatar
Iran
Azerbaijan
Sudan
Venezuela
Turkmenistan
Chile
Botswana
Ecuador
Russia
Papua New Guinea
Guinea
Gabon
Mongolia
Liberia
Namibia
Peru
South Africa
Sierra Leone
Jordan
Kuwait
Congo, Republic of
Norway
Libya
Yemen
Chad
Mexico
Cameroon
Bolivia
Colombia
Mauritania
20.0
20.0
15.0
15.0
10.0
10.0
5.0 5.0
0.0 0.0
12. There has been some increase in lower-income countries’ tax revenues since the
mid-1990s. Regional experiences differ (Box 2) but, following stagnation or even decline,
Figure 2 shows an increase in median performance. Comparing (LICs and LMICs) in 1990–95
and 2003–08, Figure 6 shows, more broadly, a marked increase in tax ratios. Over this period,
five or so countries raised their tax ratios to above 15 percent.
13. These developments in tax performance reflect increased revenue from the VAT,
strong performance of the CIT and declining trade tax revenues (Figure 7)—trends apparent
since the early 1980s.
15
While the focus in this paper is on lower-income countries as a group, experiences have
differed across regions. While sample size becomes more of a concern at finer disaggregation,
Figure 5 suggests, for instance, that tax revenue performance has strengthened in sub-Saharan
Africa since the mid-1990’s but weakened in developing Asia.
30
Proportion of countries (percent)
20
10
0
0 10 20 30 40 50
Tax revenue in percent of GDP
VAT revenues have increased... ...and CIT receipts have been robust.
8 3.5
7
3.0
6
Percent GDP
Percent GDP
2.5
5
4 2.0
1980-1989 1980-1989
3 1.5
1990-1999 1990-1999
2 1.0
2000-2009 2000-2009
1 0.5
0 0.0
Low Lower Upper High Low Lower Upper High
income middle middle income income middle middle income
income income income income
The PIT is modest and flat... ... and trade tax receipts are in decline.
12 6
10 5
Percent GDP
Percent GDP
8 4
6 1980-1989 3 1980-1989
4 1990-1999 2 1990-1999
2 2000-2009 1 2000-2009
0 0
Low Lower Upper High Low Lower Upper High
income middle middle income income middle middle income
income income income income
14. Econometric work has linked revenue performance—the ratio of actual revenues to
GDP—with a range of structural, developmental and institutional features (Appendix IV).
Many (such as the agricultural share, past political instability) are largely exogenous to tax
decisions, especially in the very short-term. The impact of resource wealth and aid on revenue
performance in this context has attracted particular attention (Box 3).
The empirical evidence on whether some kinds of aid might displace own revenues is
mixed. Over 2001–06, aid in recipient countries averaged around 4.4 percent of GDP; in 25
countries it exceeded half of all tax revenue. Such receipts could displace domestic revenue-
raising by reducing immediate needs and creating a disincentive to strengthen performance for
fear of offsetting reductions in future assistance. In practice, empirical findings vary. Gupta et al.
(2004), for instance, find that grants displace domestic revenue (almost fully where corruption is
high) while loans are associated with stronger domestic revenues. Reviewing the evidence more
widely, however, Moss, Petterson, and van de Walle (2006) stress the diversity of country
experiences and empirical results. Better understanding of these links between foreign assistance
and domestic revenues would help ensure that aid is provided in forms most supportive of
developing countries’ own tax reform efforts.
17
There are strong signs that oil revenues displace own taxation, and some that non-oil
resource revenues do too. Bornhorst et al. (2009) find that an increase in hydrocarbon revenues
of $1 displaces about 20 cents of non-hydrocarbon tax revenue. Results for sub-Saharan Africa19
suggest a similar effect for all forms of resource wealth.
16. Several countries have shown the feasibility of substantially increasing domestic
revenue mobilization. While some (such as Egypt, Pakistan) show little movement in tax ratios
over extended periods, others have made impressive progress. Peru, for instance, increased its
tax ratio from 6 to 13 percent over the 1990s and to around 17 percent now. Some have achieved
sustained revenue increases of 4–5 percent of GDP over just a few years. Appendix VI details
three cases of substantial progress: El Salvador, Tanzania, and Vietnam.
17. This section considers central issues of principle and lessons of experience in non-
resource taxation. Taxing natural resources raises more distinct and complex challenges than
can adequately be addressed here: Appendix VII provides an overview.22
19
Not reported here; using the dataset of Keen and Mansour (2010).
20
The terms ‘performance’ and ‘effort’ are often used synonymously, but the distinction made here, due to Lotz and
Morss (1967), proves useful.
21
Gupta (2007) reaches a similar conclusion.
22
A fuller treatment is in Daniel, Keen and McPherson (2010).
18
Priorities vary with country circumstances, but several lessons emerge. Relative to key
elements of the reform strategies set out in Box 1, in many cases:
Progress has been made in administrative reforms, but more on basic organizational
structures than in developing and applying risk-management, and governance problems
remain extensive;
The VAT still has more obvious revenue potential than most other instruments, but
realizing this requires expanding the base—by both policy change and improving
compliance—rather than increasing standard rates;
More systematic attention needs to be given to replacing revenue lost from trade
liberalization;
Incentives, including in free trade zones, continue to undermine revenue from CIT, which
is any event likely to come under continued pressure from globalization in coming years;
Profit-shifting by multinationals is an increasing concern; strengthening capacity and
legislative frameworks is important, but, absent fundamental changes in international tax
policies, there are no easy solutions;
The PIT will likely remain poorly developed for some time, but movement to explicitly,
and coherent, schedular structures can improve effectiveness and fairness;
High-income individuals can be taxed more effectively by removing opportunities for
avoidance and strengthening detection and enforcement;
Establishing streamlined tax regimes for small businesses, and extending to them the
methods of taxpayer segmentation, is unlikely to yield significant short-term revenue
gains but is important for the longer-term development and perceived legitimacy of the
tax system;
Much remains to be done to make tax expenditure analysis routine;
Capacity in tax policy analysis is often very weak, and a significant hindrance to better
design and ownership;
19
19. Improving revenue administration is essential for enhanced and fairer revenue
mobilization and for wider governance improvement; though success is hard to evaluate. It
may be too much to assert that “in developing countries, tax administration is tax policy”
(Casanegra de Jantscher, 1990): tax policy sets the framework within which the revenue
administration must operate. In practice, the distinction between administration and policy is
often hard (and pointless) to make. But there is no doubt that weak and often corrupt revenue
administration remains a fundamental barrier to effective and fair taxation, and to building wider
trust between government and citizens. Key indicators—tax gaps, audit recovery rates and the
level and pattern of arrears—can say much about the performance of tax administrations:
developing the capacity to monitor and analyzing these, indeed, is a central reform aim.
Evaluating the impact of administrative reforms on revenue itself, however, can be especially
difficult, since they take time, are complex, and rarely lend themselves to experiment-type
evaluation. In this respect, assessments are to some degree judgmental.
21. Many major organizational changes have proved constructive, though there have
also been mistakes. Key improvements include moving away from duplicative and narrowly
focused tax-by-tax approaches by implementing function-based organizational structures,
establishing headquarters organizations to guide them, and integrating domestic direct and
indirect tax management. Less successful—because less appropriate given their different tasks—
23
Detailed regional assessments are in Crandall and Bodin (2005), Kloeden (forthcoming), and Zake (forthcoming).
20
have been attempts to merge operational (as opposed to managerial) tax and customs
administration processes (Zimbabwe).
22. Revenue authorities (RAs) have not always lived up to the high expectations held by
some, but, with political will, can provide a framework for sustained progress. The creation
of RAs has been a widely-noted innovation over the last 10–15 years (they are now almost
ubiquitous, for instance, in Anglophone Africa), and the Fund has supported countries that have
chosen this path. RAs differ greatly, the essential being a semi-autonomous status intended to
protect against political interference, give independence in operations and HR management, and
enable flexibility in budgeting and operations. The high hopes sometimes expressed have not,
however, been fully realized (Kidd and Crandall, 2006; Kloeden, forthcoming). The (mostly
anecdotal) evidence is that managerial and staff capacity and practice often have improved
(many examples in Latin America, Eastern and Southern Africa, Ghana, and The Gambia). But
the disruption of instituting an RA often delayed reforming core tax administration functions: the
integration of direct and indirect tax administration is only now getting underway in Anglophone
Africa, for instance. And even substantial increases leave salaries dwarfed by the potential gain
from corruption. As RAs now spread further, including with heightened interest in Francophone
Africa, it is important to recognize that the aim of reform is to improve core administration
functions, not just the vehicle for their delivery.
24. Improved business processes, built on effective IT systems, are critical, but failures
have been too common. Better processes can reduce compliance costs and facilitate self-
21
25. Simplifying tax laws and adopting tax procedure codes (TPCs) can ease both
administration and compliance. Harmonizing across taxes and simplifying key administrative
provisions facilitates administration and compliance. TPCs are not always effective, whether
because of an absence of accompanying measures (Paraguay) or hesitation to impose the strictest
penalties. Where they are, however, they have strengthened administrative powers of
investigation and arrears collection, while protecting taxpayer rights.
Challenges ahead
26. Compliance costs remain high in many developing countries. For the typical firm of
the Doing Business exercise, time spent preparing and paying taxes exceeds 300 hours in
developing countries, compared to under 210 for high-income countries. In the East African
corridor Mombasa-Kigali, customs’ handling costs per import container by road are $0.13 per
km, compared to $0.05 per km along the Danang-Tak corridor in Asia (CPCS Transcom, 2010).
28. Coordination between domestic tax and customs administrations is generally poor.
Tax and customs administrations—and reforms to each—need to be closely coordinated.
Economic activity straddles both domains, and customs has a critical role in managing VAT on
22
international trade: half or more of gross VAT revenue in developing countries is collected by
customs.24 Coordination, which can enable a more complete view of each taxpayer, is often
weak: information on VAT collected on imports and zero-rated exports needs to flow from
customs to tax administration for automatic cross-checking against VAT returns to identify
anomalies and high-risk cases for audit consideration. Transactional customs and tax data
provides opportunities for trend analysis by customs and tax managers to collaboratively and
jointly (particularly within the framework of RA) develop compliance models and response
strategies. All too often these opportunities remain underexploited.
29. Addressing these concerns, and strengthening the legitimacy of the tax system,
requires improving compliance management—dealing with the “hard-to-tax”—in parallel
with consolidating good tax administration fundamentals. Beyond the fundamentals—
functionally structured organizations, taxpayer focus, self-assessment, simple IT-supported
processes, ethical and competent managers and staff—is the need for clear strategies to address
the most non-compliant businesses and individuals. Key elements include: understanding the
nature of the taxpayer/trader population; identifying key compliance risks and how they arise
(from weak laws and regulations, for instance, or administrative incapacity?); clarity on
accountability for, and adequate resourcing of, compliance activities; and specifying
performance indicators and potential corrective actions.
24
Table 4.3 of Ebrill et al. (2001).
23
31. Progress can be made in addressing corruption. It requires strong leadership (political
and managerial), institutional measures—strong and proactive internal audit and staff
investigation functions, visible implementation of a code of ethics (including prosecutions)—and
processes that limit rent-seeking opportunities (minimizing contact between taxpayers and tax
officials). The Uganda Revenue Authority is an example of how (by, for instance, forceful
measures to purge staff and re-hire, with zero tolerance for corruption) a once poorly-perceived
institution is now cited as a model.
33. Most developing countries have now developed a VAT. Since the early 1990s, the
VAT has spread rapidly beyond advanced economies (Figure 8). Though not ubiquitous, it has
become the norm and continues to spread (The Gambia and Syria, for instance, plan
introduction, and it is also under consideration in the Gulf Cooperation Council). The Fund has
been active in its promotion,25 and VAT adoption and implementation continue to be a
significant part of its TA.
25
The probability of adoption is significantly related to participation in a Fund-supported program (Keen and
Lockwood, 2010).
24
140
120
100
Number of countries
80
60
40
20
0
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2009
High Income Other Countries
34. Fund advice—largely followed—favors a broad base, single rate and fairly high
threshold.26 These prescriptions (widely shared by others advising in this area)27 aim to realize
the core potential merits of the VAT: raising significant amounts of revenue in a way that does
less damage to economic activity than alternatives, supports equity objectives, and is relatively
simple to administer and comply with. They do not mean no exemptions:28 some (for financial
services charged for as a margin, government agencies, basic health and education) are common
to most VATs, often on technical (though increasingly challenged) grounds. Others (for staple
foodstuffs) are driven by political and distributional sensitivities. A relatively high threshold
excludes traders with little revenue potential relative to the administration and compliance costs
involved. IMF (2000) found these prescriptions have been widely followed, except perhaps in
relation to the threshold: a single rate is much more common in LICs, for instance, than in higher
income countries (Table 1),29 though there are signs of pressure: the WAEMU VAT directive, for
example, has been amended to allow a second rate.
26
Ebrill et al. (2001).
27
Such as Bird and Gendron (2007). Theory [a recent review is by Crawford, Keen, and Smith (2010)], suggests that
rate differentiation can play a useful role in easing distortions to market participation and (especially where better
targeted instruments are weak) pursuing distributional objectives. In practice, however, it is hard to identify
desirable forms of differentiation (beyond those handled by excises), while differentiation is costly to administer and
comply with, and opens the door to special pleading.
28
‘Exemption’ means sales are not taxed, but (unlike ‘zero-rating’) tax on inputs is not refunded. Fund advice
generally resists zero-rating other than for exports because of the difficulty of controlling refunds.
29
This partly reflects the greater age of VATs in higher income countries: most new VATs have been single rate.
25
Number of
Average VAT C-efficiency
Income Class strictly positive
Rate
VAT rates
35. The VAT has established itself as a robust source of revenue, with signs that it has
proved a relatively efficient instrument. It typically accounts for around one-quarter of all tax
revenue; and no country has ever removed a VAT without subsequently reintroducing it. Keen
and Lockwood (2010) find that countries with a VAT generally raise more revenue than those
without, all else equal, though the likely gain varies with countries’ openness and income levels
(being less, for instance, in smaller countries, presumably because tariffs are then an easy
revenue source, and perhaps lower in sub-Saharan Africa than elsewhere).
36. Close analyses commonly reach fairly benign conclusions on the distributional
impact of the VAT, but more can be done to identify specific spending measures to allay
concerns. A proportional tax on all consumption is regressive relative to annual income, but this
effect is mitigated by the common exemption of sensitive food and other items and (less noted)
by the operation of the threshold: the latter either confers a competitive advantage on smaller and
presumably less well-off retailers and service providers or enables their customers, likely
amongst the poorer, a de facto exemption (Jenkins, Jenkins, and Kuo, 2006). The reach of the tax
is also less in poorer rural regions than in urban centers. Reviewing the evidence, Bird and
Gendron (2007) find the VAT to be generally mildly progressive or mildly regressive. Assessing
the distributional impact of any tax requires, however, comparing it with some alternative. One
possibility is that it replaces other revenue sources: Zolt and Bird (2005) conclude “the evidence
is...that the VAT is likely on the whole to be less regressive than the trade and excise taxes it has
replaced. Furthermore, in at least some developing countries, the VAT may be about as
progressive as the income tax.” Alternatively, if the VAT finances increased expenditure then the
final distributional outcome can be progressive even with a broad-based, single rate VAT: the
benefit of preferential rates/exemptions goes mainly to the better off (since they spend more on
all items), so that the poor can benefit from their elimination and use of the additional tax
revenue to finance targeted spending measures (Box 5). The effectiveness of the targeting
instruments available is critical, but even the relatively blunt instruments available to developing
countries can achieve much: Munoz and Cho (2004), for instance, using microdata to look at the
combined tax-spending of a VAT in Ethiopia, find basic health spending to have a particularly
strong effect. It remains the case, nonetheless, that precise measures to address any equity
26
concerns from proposed tax reforms—alleviating poverty is of course in itself a primary reason
to impose these taxes—are often left unspecified.
Reduced rates on (or exemption of) items particularly important to the poor are inherently
limited as distributional devices: even if the poor spend a larger proportion of their income
on some item, the better off may spend absolutely more (Sah, 1983; and Ebrill et al., 2001).
The practical importance of this recurs in TA and other work: Figure 9 shows how the bulk
of the subsidy implicit in domestic zero-rating in Mexico accrues to the better-off.
The question then is whether spending instruments can do a better job of protecting the poor.
The Ethiopia case study suggests that even where spending instruments are quite weak, rate
differentiation can be an inferior policy, and similar results have been found, for instance, for
the Philippines (Newhouse and Zakharova, 2007). It remains the case, however, that the
equity case for rate differentiation is generally stronger in developing countries than in
advanced economies. Whether rate differentiation is desirable in any specific context
depends on the government’s equity objectives and the precise instruments available to it for
protecting the poor.
20
15
10
0
I II III IV V VI VII VIII IX X
37. Any tax encourages informality, but a VAT may be less harmful than alternatives.
A higher rate of VAT tends to increase informality, so the rate should be lower where
informality is a greater concern. But other tax instruments, such as an income tax, also spur
informality, and the VAT offers some advantages: if a trader’s customers are registered for VAT,
27
it is advantageous for them to register too.30 But ‘bad’ VAT chains can also form: if a trader’s
customer are not registered, better for them not to register either (de Paula and Scheinkman,
2006). It has also been argued that the VAT may deal with informality less effectively than
tariffs, because unregistered traders will at least pay tariffs on their imports (Emran and Stiglitz,
2005). This though can be overstated: unregistered operators will incur unrecovered input VAT
on imports just as they incur customs duty31 and, unlike tariffs, the VAT also reaches informal
operators on their purchases from compliant domestic firms.32
38. VAT introduction can catalyze improvements in tax administration, by using the
VAT threshold for taxpayer segmentation (see Section G), introducing self-assessment and
spurring implementation of functionally-organized tax administrations and IT reform.
39. Flawed design and implementation undermines the effectiveness of the VAT in
many developing countries—with refunds a particular problem. Common difficulties
include: low (sometimes, as in Nigeria, zero) thresholds (pressurizing tax administrations and
diverting attention from higher value and riskier taxpayers); extensive exemptions and zero-
rating (creating classification disputes and increasing compliance costs); inadequate preparations
and public sensitization (making resistance more likely); and piecemeal implementation (as
previously in Yemen, for instance). Refunding exporters requires balancing the risk of fraud
against that of turning the VAT into a de facto export tax. This challenges all tax administrations,
but significant and sometimes corrupt delays in refunding legitimate claims are commonplace in
developing countries, and a major business complaint. Developing effective refunding
procedures is time-consuming and difficult, but crucial: ITD (2005) and Harrison (2008)
elaborate on how it can be done.
40. These difficulties are reflected in relatively low revenue productivity of the VAT in
developing countries—pointing to potentially significant revenue gains from base-
broadening. Standard rates of VAT rates are already quite high in many developing countries
(Table 1),33 and further increases may pose a particularly heavy risk of worsening compliance.
But that is not the only option for increasing revenue, as emerges from considering one common
measure of the effectiveness of a VAT: its ‘C-efficiency,’ the ratio of revenue to the product of
the standard rate and consumption. This would take the value of 100 under a single rate VAT on
a broad base, but will be lower to the extent that reduced rates apply and compliance is
30
This is because by registering for VAT a trader can recover tax on their own inputs while their customer receives
a credit for the tax they are then charged.
31
Import VAT is not subject to any threshold.
32
Keen (2009) reviews the tariffs vs. VAT controversy; Stiglitz (2010) sets out other criticisms of the VAT.
33
In some cases, however, there is risk of introducing a VAT at so low a rate—under 5 percent, say—that it is
questionable whether the effort is worthwhile.
28
imperfect.34 In LICs, for instance, median C-efficiency is only about 36 percent (Table 1 above).
In countries where it is less, raising it to that level—without changing the standard rate, but by
some combination of base-broadening and improving compliance—could raise, on average,
nearly 2 percent of GDP (Appendix VIII). Indeed a long-term objective, given sufficient base-
broadening and improved compliance, could even be lower standard VAT rates.
41. The VAT is work in progress. Adoption is a natural focus of attention, and revenue
commonly performs well in its immediate aftermath. But much—more than often realized—
remains to be done thereafter to develop the audit and other capacities an effective VAT
requires: Appendix IX recounts the experience of Zambia, illustrating the need for continued
nurturing of the VAT.
42. Trade tax revenues, still important to many developing countries, are set to continue
to decline. Relative to both GDP and total revenue, trade taxes have been in trend decline for
thirty years, tracking a decline in collected tariff rates (revenues relative to imports): Figure 10.
Further liberalization (including through regional agreements and bilateral agreements with the
EU and others), some already programmed into agreements in force, mean that the trend will
continue. While the efficiency and growth implications of this are welcome, the fiscal challenges
can be significant: in sub-Saharan Africa, for instance, trade taxes still account for one-quarter of
all tax revenue.
Figure 10. Developments in Trade Tax Revenue and Collected Tariff Rates,
1980–2009
Low-Income Countries
45 5
40 4.5
35 4
30 3.5
25 3
2.5
20 2
15 1.5
10 1
5 0.5
0 0
1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004 2008
34
Care is needed, however, since some poor VAT practices—such as a failure to refund exporters, or exemption of
intermediate products—lead to high C-efficiency; Ebrill et al. (2001): discuss these and other limitations of the
concept.
29
43. Replacing trade tax revenues from domestic sources has proved problematic in
some LICs. Most middle-income countries have readily recovered revenue from domestic
sources (Figure 11; and Baunsgaard and Keen, 2010). The same has not been true of LICs
throughout the sample period [though sub-Saharan Africa may in this respect have performed
better than other regions (Keen and Mansour, 2010)]. The marked decline in trade tax revenues
means that slow progress in overall tax ratios may mask a constructive rebalancing.
Figure 11. Developments in Tax Revenue and Trade Tax Revenue, 1980–2009
Low-Income Countries
16
14
12
Percent GDP
10
8
6
4
2
0
1980-1984 1985-1989 1990-1994 1994-1999 2000-2004 2005-2009
30
20
Percent GDP
15
10
0
1980-1984 1985-1989 1990-1994 1994-1999 2000-2004 2005-2009
15
10
5
0
1980-1984 1985-1989 1990-1994 1994-1999 2000-2004 2005-2009
44. Revenue challenges from trade liberalization will continue. There are signs in Figure
10 that revenue replacement has been more complete since the mid-1990s, but there are also
intensified challenges ahead. The standard policy prescription for recovery is to combine tariff
reduction with increased consumption taxes (exactly matching tariff reductions on excisable
products, for instance, with higher excises),35 and the analysis above suggests further room for
this without an increase in standard VAT rates—already high in many developing countries
(Table 1)—that may pose a particularly heavy risk of worsening compliance. Countries with a
VAT, however, have not been systematically more successful in replacing lost trade tax revenue
(Baunsgaard and Keen, 2010), and the case studies in IMF (2005) suggest that successful
replacement has been associated with using a range of instruments, including the income tax.
While there is thus no simple recipe for success, failure to quantify and prepare for the revenue
impact of trade reforms has in some cases amplified the difficulties. In Lebanon and
Mozambique, in contrast, introduction of an effective VAT was carefully coordinated with trade
reform.
35
This preserves the efficiency gain from the reform, widens the tax base (by including domestic production along
with imports) and can leave consumer prices lower (Keen and Ligthart, 2002). Emran and Stiglitz (2005) stress that
informality can invalidate the argument (because not all domestic consumption can then be taxed), though the result
continues to apply if an appropriate withholding tax is applied to imports (Keen, 2008).
31
46. Many customs administrations still struggle to control rent-seeking, and regional
integration can raise further challenges. Progress in implementing integrity-enhancing
measures (such as adequate salaries and working conditions, management control systems,
computer systems to streamline procedures and minimize face-to-face contacts, and accreditation
of customs brokers and importers) remains patchy. Regional integration also poses distinct
problems. Shifting fiscal control from national to regional borders requires new ways to collect
import VAT and certify export-related refund claims, and potentially new policy frameworks to
deal with intra-regional transactions—issues with which the EU is still struggling, and which can
pose even greater challenges for developing countries.
47. Receipts from the PIT are low and stagnant in developing countries, and come
almost entirely from wage withholding on large enterprises and public sector employees.
Since the early 1980s, the PIT has raised 1–3 percent of GDP in developing countries, compared
to 9–11 percent in developed (Peter, Buttrick and Duncan 2010). Up to 95 percent comes from
wage withholding by the public sector and large firms, compared to about 80 percent in
developed countries. Less than 5 percent of the population pay PIT (compared to nearly 50
percent in developed), and only about 15 percent of income is reached (compared to 57 percent):
Modi et al. (1987).
36
Described in detail in Keen (2003).
37
See http://www.wcoomd.org/home_pfoverviewboxes_tools_and_instruments_pfrevisedkyotoconv.htm
38
http://www.wcoomd.org/home_cboverviewboxes_valelearningoncustomsvaluation_epsafeframework.htm
32
48. Top statutory rates of PIT have been cut, and rate structures simplified, but with no
discernible behavioral impact. These cuts are likely to have been driven, to some degree, by
reductions in CIT rates: absent matching cuts in top PIT rates, these can invite avoidance by
incorporation. They affect even fewer taxpayers in developing countries than in advanced.39
Thresholds vary widely; raising them could enable a better focus on high-income individuals,
though the revenue loss can be non-trivial.
49. An emerging concern is the mandating of universal filing for all PIT taxpayers to
inculcate greater appreciation of the tax system and in the expectation that additional income will
be declared. In Kenya, for instance, processing the additional returns has significantly increased
workloads but collection and compliance outcomes have disappointed. The impact on taxpayer
awareness may have actually been harmful as taxpayers see that non-filing and under-declaration
goes undetected.
50. Evasion and avoidance by high-income individuals, ranging from legal use of tax
preferences to illegal use of low tax jurisdictions, could be addressed more forcefully. These
activities take a variety of forms, some purely domestic (concealing income, exploiting
preferential treatments), some international (not declaring income from abroad). They are
inevitably hard to quantify: for the latter, one estimate is that about $50 billion of tax revenue is
foregone annually in developing countries (Tax Justice Network, 2005). Whatever the precise
amount, there is little doubt that the sums are large—and, moreover, that failure of elites to pay a
fair share of taxes undermines support for the wider tax system. Raising substantially more from
such groups, often influential and intimidating, is hard. At a minimum, appropriate legal
provisions are needed: exemptions for agricultural income, for instance, can pander to the
powerful, and in some countries personal income from abroad is simply exempt. Real estate
taxes can be a powerful tool for reaching the better off. Dedicating units within the tax
administration to high-income/wealth individuals can provide a focus for enforcement efforts,
with high profile prison terms sending a salutary lesson. Strong audit power, including the
possibility to use indirect methods to assess tax liabilities, is an effective tool for increasing the
effectiveness of audit operations: these enable revenue agencies to use third party information,
particularly related to assets and flow of investments, to estimate the taxpayer’s income (Biber,
2010). Collective action on abuse through tax havens, as with the work of the Global Forum on
Transparency and Exchange of Information for Tax Purposes, can benefit developing countries.
51. ‘Global’ PITs have proved especially hard to implement in lower income
countries—explicitly schedular systems, with coherent treatment of capital income, can
offer improvement. On paper, most developing countries have a ‘global’ income tax—a
39
The top PIT bracket starts at about 18 times per capita income in upper middle-income countries, and 83 times in
LICs (Peter, Buttrick, and Duncan, 2010). Lee and Gordon (2005) find no growth impact from the top PIT rate.
33
progressive charge on the sum of income from all sources40—and building such income taxes
was a focus of much advice through the 1970s.41 The low yield, narrow base, and accumulated
structural incoherencies of these taxes mean, however, that this approach has failed: “....in most
developing countries, the global progressive personal income tax long advocated by experts
is…neither global or progressive, nor personal, not often even on income” (Zolt and Bird, 2005).
In practice, many lower income countries have schedular systems—taxing different types of
income separately. The theoretical merit of the global approach has itself been more widely
challenged in recent years (it may, for instance, simply be unrealistic, given their differing
international mobility, to apply the same top marginal rate to capital as to labor income). Several
advanced countries have moved towards a particular form of schedular taxation, the ‘dual
income tax’ (DIT): applying a progressive tax to labor income but a lower (and, critically,
uniform) rate to capital income. Whatever view is taken of this as a long-term objective in
personal income taxation, movement towards explicit and more coherent schedular taxation—
with limited discrimination between different types of capital income—can be a practical option
towards greater effectiveness.42 It can limit avoidance opportunities that arise through relabeling
capital income,43 and ease both administration and compliance, especially where capital income
is taxed at a flat rate (tax then being implementable largely by final withholding). Importantly,
the ‘Achilles heel’ of the DIT in advanced economies—the ability of smaller companies to
reclassify labor as capital income (or vice versa)—is less troubling in developing countries given
the difficulty of subjecting them to any reasonable tax at all.
E. Taxing Corporations
40
Or, in some Francophone countries, a ‘complementary’ income tax: a progressive tax on the sum of net incomes
from sources to which distinct schedular taxes apply.
41
See for instance Goode (1993).
42
Others have reached a similar conclusion: Alm and Wallace (2002), Zolt and Bird (2005).
43
As tax-preferred capital gains, for instance.
44
This may in some cases reflect the use of the CIT to extract resource rents, absent better targeted instruments.
45
This does not imply any causality in the relationship.
34
50
2.00
Percent points
40
In percent
1.50
30
1.00
20
0.50
10
0.00 0
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
30
2.50
In percent
25
2.00
20
1.50
15
1.00 10
0.50 5
0.00 0
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
30
2.50
In percent
25
2.00
20
1.50
15
1.00 10
0.50 5
0.00 0
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
High-Income Countries
4.00 50
3.50 45
40
3.00
35
Percent Points
In percent
2.50 30
2.00 25
1.50 20
15
1.00
10
0.50 5
0.00 0
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
54. Reduced tax rates and incentives can attract foreign investment, but only where
other business conditions are good. Business surveys repeatedly find that while taxation
matters for foreign investors, other considerations—infrastructure, rule of law, labor—matter
more (for instance, McKinsey, 2003), as emerging econometric evidence confirms (van Parys
and James, 2009 and Dharmapala and Hines, 2009).
55. Incentives pose concerns of effectiveness, leakage, governance and spillovers. Some
types of incentive are more likely to attract investment generating wider social benefits than are
others: an investment tax credit, for instance, may for this reason be preferable to simply
exempting profits. Incentives can be hard to control: free zones, for instance, are not always
well-controlled sealed areas,47 and profits can be transfer priced from non-holiday to holiday
companies. Signaling a willingness to provide special tax treatment invites special pleading and
corruption; and the demand for incentives, particularly tax holidays—generally agreed to be the
worst form of incentive (Appendix X)—may in part be a response to, and so entrench, corruption
in the tax administration. The scope to raise more revenue by limiting such incentives is hard to
assess— and even harder where holiday companies are not even required to file tax returns—but
seems likely in many cases to be substantial. Cubeddu et al. (2008) put the revenue cost of CIT
incentives in 15 Caribbean countries at an average of around 5½ percent of GDP. Less dramatic
but sizable, available estimates for Latin America put the cost of preferential treatments under
the income tax at 0.5–6 percent of GDP (Villela, Lemgruber, and Jorratt, 2010).48 And, as an
indicator to be treated with very great caution, for those LICs with ‘CIT-productivity’49 below
the median for their income group, raising it to that median, whether by base-broadening or
improved compliance, would in 2002 have increased revenue by about 0.7 percent of GDP.
46
The convergence of statutory CIT rates over the sample period may also have reduced losses through transfer
pricing.
47
They also raise WTO-consistency issues.
48
The figures need to be interpreted with care: methodologies differ, and, moreover, the need to honor existing
commitments can mean that the revenue gains take some time to materialize.
49
CIT revenue in percent of GDP divided by the CIT rate. One reason for caution is that (unlike VAT C-efficiency)
this is not evaluating revenue performance relative to a coherent benchmark base.
36
56. Regional cooperation can help combat excessive incentives—but unilateral actions
have also succeeded. In competing to attract investment, countries can make themselves
collectively worse off. Regional agreements to limit incentives (a model is in Appendix XI) can
block downward tax competition. This can be especially helpful where the formation of customs
unions increases firms’ mobility and can prompt pressure for alternative protective measures;
indeed one lesson of the continuing difficulties many trading blocs have in reaching such
agreements is that they are best put in place in tandem with other integration measures, before
the intensified pressures come into play. While participants in such agreements remain
vulnerable to competition from third countries, the net gains—including in scaling back
governance problems associated with preferential treatments—could be substantial. The
difficulties in reaching such agreements are more political than technical, as seen in Central
America and the East African Community (EAC), for example. Unilateral actions, however,
have also proved beneficial: Appendix XII.
50
Baker (2005), widely-cited, puts such flows at $700–1,000 billion per year, with $320-520 from developing
countries (with a total of a further $350-500 billion of criminal and corrupt flows); the underlying sources, however,
are not available. While there is indeed substantial evidence that profit-shifting is extensive, Fuest and Reidl (2010)
argue that the methodologies underlying available estimates of its extent and revenue cost are problematic.
51
Torvik (2009) argues that their impact on governance can make tax havens especially damaging for developing
countries.
52
Under the alternative ‘residence-based’ approach, tax paid abroad is creditable against that due at home, so that
those foreign taxes impose no additional liability on the investor; Mullins (2006) elaborates.
37
58. SOEs pose significant compliance problems in some countries. The transition to
taxing them by the same rules and methods as applied to private enterprises has not always been
easy, and in some cases remains incomplete—most evidently so in relation to some natural
resource companies,53 but also sometimes too in such sectors as energy generation and
transmission, telecommunications, and transportation. While the taxation of SOEs profits raises
no net revenue for government broadly interpreted, revenue from the VAT and wage withholding
can suffer, non-compliance undermines good commercial practice and wider taxpayer morale,
and large accumulations of tax arrears can result in administrations diverting scarce resources
away from more productive activities. Solutions rarely lie within the capacity of the tax
administration alone, though efforts can be made to identify and quarantine arrears, following up
by enforcement.
F. Excises
Low income Lower middle income Upper middle income High income
60. Levied on a few key items, excises can serve both revenue and, in some cases, wider
social ends. Special taxes are sometimes levied on luxury goods such as jewelry or perfume, but
53
The particular challenges in dealing with these are discussed by McPherson (2010).
54
Tobacco alone raises around 8 percent of central government revenue in China P.R. and Indonesia: Barber et al.
(2008) and Hu et al. (2008).
38
typically bring little revenue and so have only a token impact on equity. Almost all excise
revenue comes from fuels, tobacco, alcohol and other drinks, cars and, increasingly, mobile
phones,55 the rationale for these charges being not only to tap the revenue potential of a relatively
inelastic and readily identified base but, to varying degrees, to change behavior:
Petroleum products. Fuel taxes are often part of wider frameworks to stabilize and
moderate domestic retail prices. Direct subsidies in developing countries amounted to
around $54 billion in mid-2009, and net revenue foregone relative to a tax of $0.3 per
liter to around $110 billion (Arze del Granado et al., 2010). More effective fuel pricing
would serve distributional ends—empirical work repeatedly finds better ways to help the
poor (del Granado et al., 2010)—and help address environmental concerns (not only, or
even mainly, climate change, but also local pollution and congestion);
Cigarettes: Externality and self-control considerations point to higher taxes than would
otherwise be the case (there being substantial evidence that they can deter new smokers;
Ross and Chaloupka, 2000), with several studies suggesting scope for gains in both
revenue and health from increases in many developing countries: 56 in the order of
0.3–0.4 percent of GDP in India and Vietnam, for instance;57
Alcoholic and other drinks: Local custom, social preferences and drinking patterns mean
that revenue potential can differ widely. Increasing attention is being paid to the case for
taxing non-alcoholic bottled drinks in low-income countries;
Telecoms. Auctioning licenses is in principle the best way to tax the potentially
substantial rents in this increasingly important sector. Failing that, excises can raise
substantial revenue without unduly discouraging use (the positive externalities from
which appear to be sizeable: Jensen, 2007). Liberia, for instance, raises about 6 percent of
its revenue from this source. The amounts are much less elsewhere, but the scope for
increase is clear.
61. Excises can be among the simplest taxes to implement, but there are challenges—
some of which can be eased by regional cooperation. Concentrated production and high
55
In 2009, excises on tobacco and drink accounted for around 80 percent of non-fuel excise revenue in the Central
African Republic and Senegal, and 90 percent in Egypt and the Philippines.
56
See for example: WHO (2010), Sunley (2010), and Petit (forthcoming).
57
International Union against tuberculosis and lung disease, country studies are available at:
http://www.tobaccofreeunion.org (January 4, 2011).
39
import shares make administration (nowadays generally located in the LTO) relatively easy. One
long-standing issue is the choice between specific and ad valorem forms of excise (specified as
monetary amounts and as proportion of the price, respectively): the former are better-suited to
addressing externalities (which generally depend on quantities, not prices), and have often been
regarded as simpler to administer, though any advantages of specific taxation in this respect are
becoming less marked as implementation moves away from physical control).58 But other
concerns are coming more to the fore. Telecoms, for instance, raise less familiar implementation
issues, including the taxation of prepaid airtime and auditing operators without the necessary
software and technical expertise. Still more of a concern in many countries are potential
difficulties—or, for some, a source of revenue gain—from smuggling. Illicit and small scale
production can also undercut excise revenue (and in some cases raise public health issues). Fear
of inducing revenue losses from these sources is one reason many countries have hesitated to
increase rates. Administrative measures, including close control of bonded warehouses and
transit shipments are important, especially within customs unions; however, some degree of
policy cooperation may be needed—perhaps including, in CEMAC and WAEMU, agreement to
raise regionally-agreed maximum rates.
62. There is scope in many countries to raise significant additional revenue from excises
without adverse distributional effects. The declining share of excises in tax revenue suggests
considerable scope for increase (beyond offsetting any tariff reductions on excisables), perhaps
supported by some degree of policy and administrative cooperation. Prescriptions clearly need to
be country-specific (an exception being the universal importance of automatic indexation of
specific taxes), but, for example, sub-Saharan Africa and the Middle East and Central Asia could
increase excise revenue by an average of 0.5 percent of GDP and 1.3 percent of GDP
respectively by increasing the share of excises in total revenue to the world average.
63. Small businesses are extremely difficult to manage, and have limited revenue
potential. This is a highly heterogeneous group, from ‘micro’ businesses—street traders,
subsistence farmers—with limited ability to pay (in both fairness and practical terms), through
professionals and businesses with many employees. The highly skewed size distribution of
firms—in all countries, but perhaps especially so in developing—means that such businesses are
numerous, but have little revenue potential. In Egypt, the largest 4,000 companies account for
about 90 percent of total turnover; even a massive proportional increase in receipts from the 5
million small enterprises would have relatively little impact on total receipts. It is not uncommon
for developing country tax administrations to devote large resources to this segment in the hope
of flushing out medium or large taxpayers by blanket enforcement operations; but results have
been poor and costs of implementation high.
58
Other considerations in making the choice include the stability of revenues (tending to favor specific where the
demand elasticity is low) and maintaining the availability of low-price product variants (favoring ad valorem).
40
64. The tax treatment of small business has importance, however, beyond revenue. They
are often viewed as especially important in generating employment and productivity-enhancing
innovations, although the evidence on this is mixed.59 What is clear is that they are often
politically influential. Such considerations, combined with their limited revenue potential and the
risk of distracting the tax administration from more critical tasks, might suggest subjecting them
to no more than some token tax—as has been common. But there are powerful reasons for
careful attention to the treatment of small businesses, which can:
Contribute to state-building. Bringing small businesses into the tax net can help secure
their participation in the political process and improve government accountability; and
65. Small businesses tax regimes vary widely,61 but a coherent structure can be built
around a relatively high VAT threshold. All too often, a low VAT threshold and overly-
59
Biggs and Shah (1998) find large firms to be the dominant creators of manufacturing jobs in sub-Saharan Africa.
60
Gauthier and Gersovitz (1997) on Cameroon; and Gauthier and Reinikka (2006) on Uganda. This may also partly
explain the ‘missing middle’ in the distribution of firm size in developing countries.
61
Bodin (2010) and Bodin and Koukpaizan (2008) review recent developments and options in taxing small
businesses in lower income countries, including withholding and advance collection schemes discussed below.
41
complex PIT provide incentives to remain outside the tax system. A reasonably high VAT
threshold—the Fund commonly advises around US$50–100,000 in developing countries—
provides a natural reference point for taxpayer segmentation, as firms above it can be assumed to
have basic record- keeping capacity. Two groups can then be distinguished below it: (1) micro
businesses, which can be subject to a simple ‘patente,’ akin to a license fee (likely best
implemented at local level)—the aim being to secure their participation in the political process
and gather information useful for an eventual graduation to the standard tax system; (2) an
intermediate group of taxpayers that can be taxed on their cash flow (i.e. with immediate
expensing of investment and disallowance of financing costs) or turnover, to broadly replicate
the regular PIT (so that progressive rates, including standard exemptions, would apply to
unincorporated businesses).62 The difficulty is not that small traders cannot keep simple
accounts—it is persuading them to share them.63
66. Withholding taxes and advance collection schemes can help improve small business
compliance, but need to be used sparingly. Small taxpayers transact with medium and large
ones, and they import: withholding at these points can improve compliance. Advance collection
on imports is common in Africa and found elsewhere too, sometimes at higher rates for
unregistered enterprises. In most cases the advance payment is creditable only against income
tax, though some apply forms of VAT withholding. Some countries (Burkina Faso, Mali) have
also introduced advanced collection on domestic transactions. Although having some appeal in
principle, and often raising considerable revenue,64 such schemes generally cause significant
difficulty when widely applied: the very ease with which they raise revenue can reduce the
incentive to undertake hard reforms, amplify crediting and refund problems, invite corruption,
and become so pervasive as to undermine the coherence of the wider tax system.65
67. Real estate taxes can be efficient and equitable, and particularly suitable for local
governments. Their efficiency appeal is that location-specific attributes provide a relatively
immobile tax base, less vulnerable to tax competition than others; and since rates are currently
low, the inefficiencies from marginal increases are likely to be modest. Their progressivity arises
62
Where countries are reluctant to raise a VAT threshold set too low, this treatment might appropriately be applied
to some above it.
63
Social contributions can pose particular difficulties in managing smaller enterprises. Where retirement and
healthcare benefits are linked to individual contributions, simple presumptive schemes will not capture all the
information required: so there is no obvious alternative to withholding. This issue will come increasingly to the fore
as countries expand their social systems, making it harder to justify special regimes for smaller taxpayers.
64
Araujo-Bonjean and Chanbai (2003) report that withholding on car imports accounted for 18 percent of direct tax
revenue in Benin (2001), but this is an extreme case.
65
There are also potential issues of WTO-consistency, if refund and crediting does not eliminate any additional
burden on imports by the tax-compliant.
42
from the positive correlations between property ownership, income, and wealth. Since property
values largely reflect the provision of local services, they are well-suited as instruments of local
taxation (Plimmer and McCluskey, 2010).66
68. Their revenue potential is modest in absolute terms, but significant for local
governments. Real estate taxes in developing countries often yield under 0.1 percent of GDP,
and rarely more than 0.5 percent (Bolivia, Cape Verde, Honduras, and Kazakhstan). But they can
be more than 50 percent of local government revenues (Armenia, Lesotho, and Peru). While the
potential of real estate taxes to strengthen national revenues is limited, the potential to finance
improved local government services—local and government accountability and governance—is
considerable. Many developing countries (including Egypt, Namibia, and Vietnam) have
consequently embarked on real estate tax reforms.
69. Low revenues reflect weaknesses of design and implementation—but, for the longer-
term, there are ways ahead. The base is often corroded by multiple exemptions; rates are low;
property rights are not always clearly defined, and coverage in the cadastre is poor; property
values are not updated (relative price changes being large in fast growing urban centers of
developing countries), often reflecting an incentive for undervaluation exacerbated by transfer
and capital gains taxes; and enforcement is weak. There are, however, many ways to value and
tax property (Mikesell and Zorn, 2008). Valuation techniques, for instance, range from simple
unit land taxes (Vietnam, Nigeria), to market-based systems. Computer-assisted mass appraisal
systems can be used to value property by hedonic pricing67 (Eckert, 2008), with satellite
technology minimizing the need for on-site inspections. Progress can though take many years.
Local capacity has to develop; the alternative of having national agencies take over the
administration of property taxes (as in Tanzania) undermines local accountability and diverts
attention from more pivotal reforms. Building cadastres is time-consuming. But this is one area
in which additional revenues can be found in a way that is efficient, fair, and holds the prospect
of improved state responsiveness.
70. Political commitment is essential to progress, and ‘champions’ are key—but lasting
reform requires deep institutional change. Almost all the successful reforms cited here are
associated with two or three particular politicians or officials. All too often, however, progress
stops, or reverses, on their departure. Sustaining change, including in the face of cyclical
shocks—both bad ones that can amplify resistance to base-broadening, and good ones that
reduce the pressure to change—requires entrenching gains made at each stage.
66
Chambas (2010) stresses the potential to improve local government finance in sub-Saharan Africa.
67
Using data on observed transactions to predict properties’ market values on the basis of their characteristics.
43
71. Effective and fair revenue mobilization requires informed and careful analysis, and
transparent institutions and practices. Fact-based policy debate can be critical to developing
the political and social consensus needed for lasting improvement. Key elements include:
Simple and transparent tax laws. In this respect many developing countries score higher
than advanced economies, having enacted high quality laws in recent years.
Implementation can though be problematic, for instance, with slow and cumbersome
appeals processes;
Capable tax policy units. Policy analysis is often left as an adjunct and reactive function
of the tax administration, often lacking the specialist skills and wider view required.
Weaknesses in quantifying and understanding tax gaps, in analyzing the revenue and
distributional effects of tax changes, and in identifying emerging trends and crafting
responses to them are often considerable. Without allocating expertise and authority to
tax policy analysis experience suggests a dedicated unit within the ministry of finance,
working closely with the revenue administration and empowered to collect information
from a range of government agencies—the design of tax changes will be hampered and
their ownership inherently limited; and
Involvement of the wider community. Timely interaction between the tax authorities and
taxpayers educates both sides fosters trust, and can lead to measures that are both better-
designed and more widely accepted. Interactions with CSOs and local academics, and
well-informed media coverage, can communicate and guide reform priorities.
72. Initiatives to further foster transparency in tax relations merit close examination.
One widely discussed instance is ‘country-by-country reporting,’ now under study by both the
European Commission and the OECD/DAC Task Force on Taxation and Development. The aims
of these initiatives, seeking to generalize to some degree the Extractive Industries Transparency
Initiative, are typically dual: to promote accountability of governments for the revenues they
raise; and to promote public transparency in the taxes paid by enterprises, permitting, it is hoped,
the policing of transfer pricing abuses. Broadly speaking, the goal is to make clear the match—
not necessarily required under current tax rules—between the location of corporate financial
profit and/or activity and the location and amount of corporate income taxes paid. Progress likely
requires clarifying both the objectives and the value-added of such exercises. Publicly-owned
44
companies, for instance, already have tax reporting obligation in many countries. This highly
technical issue bears further study and international discussion. At a minimum, this can spur
greater needed thinking regarding the best ways to promote greater transparency within the
existing international tax architecture.
73. There is increasing recognition of the importance of revenue mobilization within the
historical sweep of state development. One strand of literature stresses that the capacity to
collect tax revenue reflects prior investment decisions, and explores how these are shaped by
such considerations as political stability, the extent of common interests—external threats being
a leading instance—and the degree of political consensus (Acemoglu, 2005; and Besley and
Persson, 2009 and 2010). More evident in recent policy documents is the ‘new fiscal sociology,’
which argues that taxation can foster state-building both by providing a focal point for
bargaining between the state and citizenry and through the development of high quality
institutions for tax collection (Bräutigam, 2008).
74. It remains unclear, however, how these concerns might temper standard tax advice.
Some dimensions of state-building are beyond its scope. Constitutional structures are known to
impact tax performance, for instance, and political instability is associated with low VAT
C-efficiency (Aizenman and Jinjarak, 2008): but these are matters beyond fiscal advice. And
standard recommendations on exemptions, management of resource wealth, and decentralization
are already largely driven by concerns beyond the narrowly fiscal. Recent contributions have
stressed the importance of strengthening perceived links between paying tax and enjoying the
benefits of public spending, and increasing awareness of this can clearly be constructive (in
advanced economies too). Here there is a critical role for improving public financial
management—and public confidence in it—together with the transparency of public spending
decisions. Whether more extensive earmarking of taxes can help, as some have argued, is
debatable: even apart from the corruption with which it has sometimes been associated, if
earmarking truly constrains spending on particular items it can lead to harmful inflexibility while
if it does not, then it runs counter to transparency. Many of the ‘nuisance taxes’ in developing
countries that reform often aims to remove, moreover, originated precisely in some form of
earmarking. The implications of state-building concerns for small business taxation—
strengthening the case for efforts to include them in the tax system, to increase the accountability
they require of government—are fairly clear; the question is how they weigh relative to other
considerations discussed above.
75. Donors have a role too. They need to honor their aid commitments, and consider how
aid can be best structured, including through the use of monitorable benchmarks, to encourage
revenue mobilization. Coordination in the substance and processes of tax-related TA can be
improved. There is also a case for easing (as some are now doing) the requirement of tax
exemptions for donor-financed projects. These create administrative complexities and legitimize
exemptions as a routine policy tool, while their rationale (given an increased willingness to
provide direct budget assistance to countries with adequate governance arrangements in place) is
increasingly unclear (International Tax Dialogue, 2006).
45
Do the Directors agree that there is scope to raise significant additional revenue to meet
high priority spending needs in many low-income countries?
Do the Directors believe that the principles for administration and policy reforms set out
in this paper provide a firm basis for further progress in revenue mobilization in
lower-income countries?
Do the Directors agree that efforts should continue to strengthen VAT design and
implementation so as to realize its full potential?
Do the Directors agree that exemptions and preferential tax treatments seriously impede
revenue mobilization in many developing countries, and that more needs to be done to
remove them?
Do the Directors agree that addressing compliance and governance problems in taxation
can make an important contribution to wider state-building?
Do the Directors agree that greater international tax cooperation, including between
advanced and developing countries, can significantly help to strengthen revenue
mobilization?
46
The TA that the Fiscal Affairs Department (FAD) provides to Fund members, at their request, is
extensive, and takes a variety of forms. In FY11, there will be around 35 HQ-led missions on tax
policy issues, and around 61 in revenue administration. Some of these are to advanced
economies, and related to crisis response, but the great bulk continues to be to developing
countries (Appendix Figure 14). Specialist staff also join area department missions (again
including also to advanced countries) to address specific topics. Short-term support is provided
through the seven68 regional technical assistance centers, all of which include a specialist advisor
on revenue administration. FAD offers occasional workshops on specialist topics (such as the
taxation of small businesses and revenue forecasting), as well as periodic high profile
conferences (most recently on the taxation of natural resources). This TA work will benefit from
two recently established Topical Trust Funds: on tax policy and administration, and on managing
natural resource wealth (IMF, 2010b, c).
Appendix Figure 14. Revenue Administration and Tax Policy Mission Intensity,
FY2008–10
68
A new center will soon be opened in Southern Africa, and another is planned for Central Asia.
47
Lessons from FAD TA work are gathered in several books (in recent years, on the VAT, customs
administration, and the taxation of natural resources),69 demand for which has proved strong, and
a series of technical notes on revenue administration.
The Legal Department provides extensive assistance in drafting tax laws, closely coordinated
with FAD’s work. A typical year might see about 25 short-term LEG missions for drafting; over
the past two decades LEG has assisted in drafting about 200 tax laws or regulations enacted in
about 60 countries.
The World Bank, regional development banks and donors also, to varying degrees, provide tax-
related TA: International Tax Compact (2010) and Michielse and Thuronyi (2010) provide initial
overviews, and a fuller mapping is among the requests of the G-20. While the concordat is silent
on the respective roles of the Fund and Bank, in practice the Fund has for several years been
more prominent on tax policy issues and strategic revenue administration advice, and the Bank in
financing and managing large administrative reform projects.
The Fund maintains close links with associations of tax administrations, such as the new African
Tax Administrators Forum and the Inter American Association of Tax Administrations (CIAT).
It was also a founding member, along with the OECD and World Bank, of the International Tax
Dialogue (the ITD). The ITD seeks to be an information source for officials on technical issues,
through its website (www.itdweb.org), which also provides a platform for the exchange of
information on TA and other activities, encourages experience-sharing through a large biannual
conference (the next to be on “Tax and Inequality”) and, with DfID support, has also undertaken
work gathering comparative information on tax administration in Africa.
69
Respectively Ebrill et al. (2001), Keen (2003), and Daniel, Keen and McPherson (2010).
48
Strategies for establishing effective taxation in post-conflict states, set out in Gupta et al. (2005),
are illustrated by the experiences of Liberia and Mozambique; FYR Macedonia is an example of
reform in an upper middle-income successor state focused on establishing a business-friendly
environment.
Liberia: Prolonged civil conflict decimated the tax and customs administrations. With extensive
TA in policy and administration, in which FAD was prominent, revenue recovered from 6.2
percent of GDP in 2003 to almost 20 percent by 2009. Initial efforts focused on the major
revenue handles of customs and a small number of larger businesses managed from a small
special office. Attention then turned to multipronged administrative reform covering
organizational arrangements, forms and procedures, systems and governance arrangements, and
to a range of policy issues, including a fiscal framework for natural resources (petroleum,
mining, forestry, and logging). Next steps include transition to a common external tariff and the
replacement of the sales tax by a VAT, as agreed within ECOWAS. The medium-term revenue
effort for natural resources, however, has recently been put at risk by a number of special
concessions in the mining sector, and by problems in enforcing the land rentals under forestry
contracts.
Mozambique.70 A cornerstone of the extensive reform efforts since the end of the devastating
civil war in 1992 has been a far-reaching reform, with extensive technical support from FAD and
others, of tax policy and administration. Initial efforts focused on simplifying the tariff and
overhauling customs administration. Attention then turned to reforming domestic indirect taxes,
replacing cascading taxes with a VAT and selective excises, and strengthening the domestic tax
administration. In the final phase, direct taxes were transformed (establishing a unified CIT and
moving from a schedular to a global PIT) and a revenue authority created. Revenue collection
(excluding receipts from natural resources), which stood at about 8.5 percent of GDP in 1992/93,
is now around 15 percent.
FYR Macedonia. Administrative effort—with FAD assistance, partly funded by the Dutch
government—focused on integrating the collection of social insurance contributions (SICs) with
that of the PIT. This required a host of legal, organizational and policy reforms (harmonizing the
bases of the PIT and SICs, for instance, and aligning administrative procedures and IT systems).
The minimum SICs were also reduced, with potentially beneficial employment and compliance
effects. Integrated collection began in January 2009, and is reported to have yielded substantial
benefits for (a) the government, through increased SIC collections (despite the economic
downturn, the number of declared workers increased by around 16 percent and the sum of PIT
and SIC receipts by about 8 percent), (b) employees, through a reduction in wage payment
delays (because mechanisms for strong enforcement of SIC payment also ensured prompt wage
70
This account draws on Castro et al. (2009).
49
payment), and (c) employers, through significant simplification. In parallel, with the aim of
attracting FDI and stimulating employment, a flat tax was introduced, the main feature of which
(given that the vast majority of workers already paid at a single marginal rate) is the very low
rate of 10 percent (both PIT and CIT). FAD advice in this area—aimed at safeguarding revenue
by eliminating a multiplicity of tax concessions and allowances—has had much less impact.
50
The analysis in this paper draws on a mix of GFS, WEO and other data, from 1980 on. This
eclecticism reflects limitations of available revenue data for developing countries. While the
Government Financial Statistics is widely used, there are significant gaps and figures can differ
markedly from those prepared by desks and assembled for the World Economic Outlook.
Important compositional detail is often missing, including between the VAT and other indirect
taxes and (increasingly important) of receipts related to natural resources.
Creating a comprehensive set of revenue variables poses several challenges. First, reporting
standards in the GFS, initially following the 1986 manual, underwent a major overhaul with the
introduction of the new GFS framework in 2001. This makes it difficult to construct consistent,
comparable government statistics before 1999. There are breaks in the data across time, with
differences in the terminology and composition of the specific series, and some scaling
problems. Second, reporting may be either on a cash or on an accrual basis. To maximize the
sample of lower income countries, this paper uses revenue data reported on a cash basis. Third,
alternative government data sources suffer from similar problems. WEO collects data directly
from the countries’ fiscal files, but much of the historical data is unavailable as the system is
transitioning to a new environment and only recent data has been formatted for this system.
OECD revenue data has better time coverage, but limited country coverage.
Total government revenue as a share of GDP. As a first step, WEO general government
revenue data are used. Some of the gaps this leaves prior to 2001 are filled with data from an
older WEO dataset compiled by FAD. For the rest, GFS general government revenue is used
and, when this is not available, we use GFS consolidated central government.71 Since most cases
of missing general government data occur for lower income developing economies, this seems a
reasonable proxy as most of the revenue collection in such countries tends to be at central
government level. GFS2001 and GFS1986 differ in that the latter excludes social contributions
by government as employer in the consolidation of government data, meaning that the data might
be skewed downwards in the early years of the sample which rely on GFS1986.
Non-grant government revenue as a share of GDP is calculated by using the same approach as
described above, but by extracting WEO and GFS grants from total government revenue.
Tax revenue as a share of GDP is total tax revenue, inclusive of social security contributions,
collected by the general government relative to GDP at market prices. The main components are
(i) taxes on income, profits, and capital gains; (ii) taxes on payroll and workforce; (iii) taxes on
property; (iv) taxes on goods and services; and (v) taxes on international trade and transactions.
This variable is constructed by first using total tax revenue for the general government from
OECD, which has comprehensive time coverage except for the last year of the sample as data
71
The specific series are “total revenue” from GFS2001 and “total revenue and grants” from GFS1986.
51
available at the time of this work ran only to 2009. OECD reports social security contributions as
a sub-component of total tax, but WEO/GFS reports them as a separate non-tax category. In
compiling the complete data series over 1980-2010, we start with the tax measure from OECD,
and then fill in the gaps with the sum of tax and social contributions from WEO and GFS2010.
Income taxes as share of GDP are taxes on income, profits, and capital gains generally levied on
(i) compensation for labor services; (ii) interest, dividends, rent, and royalty incomes; (iii) capital
gains and losses; (iv) profits of corporations and partnerships; (v) taxable portions of social
security, retirement account distributions, and life insurance; and (vi) miscellaneous other
income items. Data are collected on total income tax, and corporate and individual income tax.
As for total tax revenue, OECD and WEO are used as primary sources, and remaining gaps filled
with GFS data.
Taxes on goods and services as share of GDP are taxes levied on the production, extraction,
sale, transfer, leasing, or delivery of goods and rendering of services, as well as on the use of
such goods. The main components are (i) general taxes on goods and services (value-added
taxes, sales taxes, and turnover and other general taxes on goods and services); (ii) excises; (iii)
other taxes on profits of fiscal monopolies, specific services, and the use of goods to perform
activities. Data is constructed, in order, from OECD, WEO and GFS.
Value-added tax revenue as share of GDP is constructed from OECD and GFS sources only, as
WEO does not report at this level of disaggregation. When data from GFS are not available, for
Sub-Saharan African countries the Keen and Mansour (2010) dataset, compiled from country
documents and IMF fiscal files is used. In some cases, if a country has a value-added tax in place
and no other source is available, we proxy VAT revenue with revenue from general taxes on
goods and services.
Trade tax revenues as a share of GDP includes customs and other import duties, taxes on
exports, profits of export or import monopolies, exchange profits, and exchange taxes. Sources
used are the OECD series (as the sum of import duties and export taxes) and WEO, with
remaining gaps filled from Baunsgaard and Keen (2010) and GFS.
Statutory CIT rates are taken from KPMG’s Corporate and Indirect Tax Survey 2010 from 2001
onward, and from FAD’s database of rates for the years before 2001. The latter source draws on
the World Tax Database compiled by the University of Michigan.
Resource wealth. This dummy is calculated using resource rents from the World Bank’s Net
Adjusted Saving framework which derives hydrocarbon and mineral rents as the difference
between world prices and the average unit cost of extraction, multiplied by total volume of
production in any given year. To construct a country-wide resource endowment measure, rents
are aggregated to include oil, natural gas, bauxite, copper, lead, nickel, phosphate, tin, zinc, gold,
silver, and iron. Resource rich countries at each date are those with estimated rents of more than
10 percent of GDP.
52
Income groups
Fixed. Countries are grouped following the World Bank methodology which divides countries
according to the 2009 gross national income (GNI per capita), calculated using the World Bank
Atlas Method.72 The groups are: low-income, $995 or less; lower middle-income, $996–3,945;
upper middle-income, $3,946–12,195; and high-income, $12,196 or more. See Appendix
Table 3.
Dynamic. Groups are defined using the GNI per capita in each year, similarly calculated using
the World Bank Atlas Method. Low-income countries are those in the bottom 25th percentile of
the GNI distribution in any given year. Lower middle-income countries are those in the next 25th
percentile, followed by upper middle-income. High-income countries are economies in the top
25th percentile.
72
To reduce the impact of transitory exchange rate fluctuations in the cross-country comparison of national income,
the World Bank converts the GNI in national currency into US dollars using the Atlas conversion factor. The
conversion factor is calculated as a three-year average of exchange rates adjusted for the difference between the rate
of inflation in the country (using the country's GDP deflator) and that in a selected group of advanced economies
(using a weighted average of the countries’ GDP deflators in SDR terms).
53
Highlighted countries are those that are ‘resource-rich’ in at least one sample period.
Low-income
Bangladesh, Benin, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cambodia, Central African Rep., Chad, Comoros,
Congo, Dem. Rep. of, Eritrea, Ethiopia, Gambia, The, Ghana, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Haiti,
Kenya, Kyrgyz Republic, Lao People's Dem. Rep, Liberia, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali,
Mauritania, Mozambique, Myanmar, Nepal, Niger, Rwanda, Sierra Leone, Solomon Islands,
Tajikistan, Tanzania, Togo, Uganda, Zambia, Zimbabwe.
Lower middle-income
Angola, Armenia, Belize, Bhutan, Bolivia, Cameroon, Cape Verde, China, P.R.: Mainland,
Congo, Republic of, Côte d'Ivoire, Djibouti, Ecuador, Egypt, El Salvador, Georgia, Guatemala,
Guyana, Honduras, India, Indonesia, Jordan, Kiribati, Lesotho, Maldives, Moldova, Mongolia,
Morocco, Nicaragua, Nigeria, Pakistan, Papua New Guinea, Paraguay, Philippines, Samoa,
Senegal, Sri Lanka, Sudan, Swaziland, Syrian Arab Republic, São Tomé & Príncipe, Thailand,
Tonga, Tunisia, Ukraine, Uzbekistan, Vanuatu, Vietnam, Yemen, Republic of.
Upper middle-income
Albania, Algeria, Antigua and Barbuda, Argentina, Azerbaijan, Rep. of, Belarus, Bosnia and
Herzegovina, Botswana, Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Dominica, Dominican
Republic, Fiji, Gabon, Grenada, Iran, I.R. of, Jamaica, Kazakhstan, Lebanon, Libya, Lithuania,
Macedonia, FYR, Malaysia, Mauritius, Mexico, Namibia, Panama, Peru, Russian Federation,
Seychelles, South Africa, St. Kitts and Nevis, St. Lucia, St. Vincent & the Grenadines.,
Suriname, Turkey, Uruguay, Venezuela, Rep. Bol. de
High-income: OECD
Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany,
Greece, Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, Korea, Republic of, Luxembourg,
Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Spain,
Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom, United States.
High-income: nonOECD
Bahamas, The, Bahrain, Kingdom of, Barbados, Brunei Darussalam, China, P.R., Hong Kong
SAR, Croatia, Cyprus, Equatorial Guinea, Estonia, Kuwait, Latvia, Malta, Oman, Qatar, Saudi
Arabia, Singapore, Trinidad & Tobago, United Arab Emirates.
56
A higher share of agriculture in GDP is associated with lower revenue, whether because
the sector is hard-to-tax and/or granted preferential tax treatment or because public
service provision yields especially high social returns in urban centers;
Increased openness tends to be associated with higher revenue. This is most naturally
interpreted as reflecting the ease of taxing trade, though Rodrik (1998) argues rather that
it reflects a stronger demand for social insurance associated with the greater riskiness
implied by increased exposure to external developments. Landlocked countries,
conversely, tend to raise less;
Income per capita is positively associated with revenue performance, whether as a proxy
for administrative and compliance capacity or through its impact on the demand for
public services. Controlling for other variables, however, many studies find—contrary to
‘Wagner’s Law’ (that the share of government tends to increase with income levels)—an
income elasticity below unity (or even negative). One possibility is that the distortionary
costs of taxation mean the revenue share optimally decreases at higher incomes (Keen
and Lockwood, 2010);
Demographics can also play a role. Larger populations are associated with lower tax
ratios, reflecting economies of scale in providing public goods (Alesina and Wacziarg,
1998), a negative correlation with openness; and, perhaps, an advantage in international
tax games (attracting base from abroad by setting lower tax rates being less costly in
terms of revenues from the domestic base foregone). Faster population growth is
associated with lower revenue, perhaps because of the difficulty of tracking and
administering a rapidly changing tax-payer population and, in more developed countries
at least, aging population is associated with a higher tax effort, presumably to finance
higher social spending;
Higher inflation is associated with lower tax revenue: it is an easy tax to collect,
bypassing classic channels of legislation and administration—indeed optimal seignorage
73
Recent examples include Gupta (2007), Le, Moreno-Dodson, and Rojchaichaninthorn (2008), Bird, Martinez-
Vazquez and Torgler (2008), Brun, Chambas, and Guerineau (2008) and Pessino and Fenochietto (2010).
57
is likely higher where administration is weak;74 it erodes tax revenues when collection
lags are significant (Tanzi, 1978):75 and failure to index specific taxes together with
opportunities to expand deductions (of nominal interest against the CIT, for instance) can
dominate the positive revenue impact of failing to index PIT and other thresholds and
brackets;
A deep financial sector is associated with higher tax ratios. Gordon and Li (2009)
emphasize the monitoring role of financial institution, reducing cash transactions and the
size of the informal sector. Moreover, banks often collect some forms of tax on capital
income;
Recent work has stressed the potential importance of indicators of the quality of
governance and of political and legal institutions. Corrupt revenue administrations
would be expected to collect less official revenue; and a poor quality of the public sector
can increase resistance to taxation that expresses itself in avoidance or evasion. There is
evidence too that political instability is associated with low tax ratios, and that legal
origins also have an impact, with civil law countries generally raising more (see, for
instance, Keen, 2010). Bird, Martinez-Vazquez and Torgler (2008) find that greater
political ‘voice’ and accountability is associated with higher revenue, while Persson and
Tabellini (2003) report evidence that parliamentary systems are associated with stronger
revenue mobilization than presidential ones. Many of these variables tend to be strongly
correlated, so disentangling the effects remains works in progress;
The impact of decentralization on tax effort has not been clearly established. Assessment
of tax performance often focuses on central government tax revenue; this may be justified
in developing countries where local tax revenues remain at very low (less than 1 percent
of GDP); and
The links between own-revenue mobilization and aid and receipts from natural
resources are discussed in Box 3 in the text.
74
Developing countries differ in their access to and use of this tool, for instance, in the two monetary unions in
Africa: the West African CFA Franc and the Central African CFA Franc. Aisen and Veiga (2008) find that
inefficient tax systems induce countries to rely more heavily on seignorage revenue.
75
Dixit (1991), however, shows that charging interest on tax debts makes the optimal inflation tax independent of
the length of the collection lag.
58
Great caution needs to be used, however, in drawing conclusions on the scope for specific
countries to raise more. To the extent that regressors are exogenous—legal and constitutional
structures, for instance—they will, by definition, be difficult to change. Attention then shifts to
the residuals from such estimated equations. Further difficulties then arise. If the regressors are
exogenous (or at least statistically predetermined), the coefficients will reflect not only feasibility
constraints—conceivably the same for all countries—on what can be raised (depending on
whether a country is landlocked, for instance, or has a particular political structure)—but also the
unobserved and (potentially idiosyncratic) policy choices (tax rate and bases) that countries then
make in the light of those constraints. Estimates are thus of a reduced form whose coefficients
(as in the case of the agriculture share, for instance) conflate constraints and policy functions.
This makes it problematic, for instance, to infer scope for the additional revenue that any country
might raise simply by examining the residuals of such regressions. For that one would need to
identify the feasibility constraint alone.
59
Appendix Table 4 sets out results based on the application of this methodology (see Greene,
2008) in Pessino and Fenochietto (2010). Further details of estimation strategy, data sources and
sample—an unbalanced panel over 1991–2006, excluding countries with receipts from
hydrocarbons of more than 30 percent of total tax revenue—are given there. Variables treated as
entering r are income per capita, the degree of openness of an economy, the value added of the
agriculture sector as percent of GDP, public spending on education, and income inequality;
corruption and inflation are treated as entering I. The two columns show actual tax revenue and
estimated effort for the most recent year available. While the technique currently clearly has
limitations—in dealing with endogeneity issues, for instance, and in extension to deal with
resource wealth—the results are suggestive, and in most cases would conform to widely held
presumptions.
60
Low-income
Bangladesh 8.1 41.0
Burkina Faso 11.3 62.0
Ethiopia 13.2 81.0
Gambia,The 17.1 85.7
Ghana 22.4 86.4
Kenya 18.3 80.6
Madagascar 10.7 52.2
Mali 15.5 74.9
Sierra Leone 11.0 64.8
Togo 14.6 80.3
Uganda 12.9 67.6
Zambia 17.0 92.4
Lower middle-income
Armenia 17.1 55.4
Bolivia 26.6 67.6
Cameroon 12.4 57.6
China, People's Republic of 14.9 42.6
Côte d'Ivoire 16.6 96.1
Egypt 14.1 61.8
El Salvador 15.3 53.8
Guatemala 10.7 38.1
Honduras 17.9 64.6
India 16.4 52.2
Indonesia 12.8 59.8
Jordan 26.4 66.3
Moldova 34.7 88.4
Mongolia 27.2 67.2
Nicaragua 21.5 65.2
Pakistan 9.5 46.9
Papua New Guinea 24.7 94.0
Paraguay 15.3 64.5
Philippines 14.3 60.2
Senegal 16.1 71.6
Sri Lanka 14.8 62.0
Syrian Arab Republic 17.5 74.8
Thailand 19.5 49.0
Ukraine 36.6 87.1
Upper middle-income
Albania 21.6 79.3
Argentina 27.4 63.6
Belarus 45.7 98.4
Botswana 22.5 64.7
Brazil 34.2 98.0
Bulgaria 33.8 82.5
Colombia 19.6 71.6
Costa Rica 22.2 66.7
Dominican Republic 14.2 48.3
Jamaica 32.4 95.0
Lithuania 30.2 70.7
Malaysia 18.8 50.4
Namibia 26.1 93.8
Panama 14.3 48.3
Peru 15.3 55.3
Romania 27.9 75.1
Russia 32.3 88.0
South Africa 31.2 81.0
Turkey 32.5 89.6
Uruguay 25.0 87.5
High-income
Australia 30.9 67.2
Austria 41.9 89.1
Belgium 45.4 92.3
Canada 28.5 65.8
China, Hong Kong SAR 16.6 28.3
Croatia 40.2 75.3
Czech Republic 36.7 81.2
Denmark 49.1 94.7
Estonia 30.8 71.7
Finland 43.5 95.1
France 44.7 96.0
Germany 35.7 78.2
Greece 27.4 64.3
Hungary 37.1 92.5
Iceland 41.4 71.0
Ireland 30.6 69.1
Italy 42.7 96.6
Japan 27.4 59.0
Korea, the Republic of 26.8 52.8
Latvia 29.3 68.7
Luxembourg 36.3 72.0
Netherlands 39.5 85.3
New Zealand 34.3 80.1
Norway 43.6 80.3
Poland 34.3 86.2
Portugal 35.4 78.6
Singapore 12.7 22.3
Slovak Republic 29.6 75.1
Slovenia 39.4 85.2
Spain 37.2 79.5
Sweden 50.1 98.1
Switzerland 30.1 60.3
United Kingdom 37.4 79.9
United States 27.3 62.4
Source: FAD, based on Pessimo and Fenochietto (2010), Table 3, truncated normal.
63
El Salvador
Significant and well-designed base-broadening measures have been adopted over the last
six years, improving both efficiency and fairness. These reforms included: (1) restricting VAT
zero-rating to exports; (2) eliminating exemptions on interest earned in banks licensed abroad
and on income from interest and capital gains of individuals; (3) establishing a tax on registration
of new vehicles; (4) broadening the income tax withholding base for non-residents; (5)
introducing a mixed (ad valorem and specific) system of excises on tobacco and alcoholic and
non-alcoholic beverages, replacing the previous system of ad valorem rates to ensure that
reasonable tax is paid even on the cheapest products; (6) introducing provisions to deal with
transfer pricing, previously absent, and rules addressing thin capitalization; (7) eliminating
subsidies on exports; and (8) increasing the tax on lottery prizes from 5 to 15 percent, partly to
counter money laundering.
Reflecting these reforms, tax revenue increased from 10.9 percent of GDP in 2004 to
13.4 percent in 2010. Beyond the revenue increase, these policy changes have taken El Salvador
significantly further towards a tax system centered on low customs duties, a broad-based VAT
and sensitivity to equity concerns. Progress on administrative reform, however, has been less
marked.
Tanzania
Major reforms of policy and administration have been undertaken over the past decade to
address low revenue collection, with implementation guided by five-year plans of the
semi-autonomous Tanzania Revenue Authority (TRA) and supported by development partners.
The authorities sought to raise revenue without increasing tax rates by strengthening the
TRA’s capacity, through: integrating its operations, introducing taxpayer segmentation, and
making better use of IT. Key reforms included: the introduction of a common taxpayer
identification number (TIN) for all taxes, creation of a Large Taxpayers Department and
consolidation of VAT and income tax administration into a single, functionally-structured
Domestic Revenue Department. Registration compliance was improved by such measures as
allocating geographical groups of taxpayers to a specific team with clear performance targets,
and improving assistance to small taxpayers in understanding and complying with their
obligations. A new income tax law (2004) introduced self-assessment and rationalized small
taxpayer administration, and an increase in the VAT threshold focused the TRA’s operations on
64
Policy reforms brought significant simplification. The number of brackets of the PIT was
reduced and the top marginal rate was cut (from 35 to 30 percent) and aligned with the CIT rate.
The exempt amount under the PIT was increased, and indefinite carry forward of losses allowed.
Presumptive income tax rates were adjusted to reduce inconveniences to small-scale businesses,
capital gains taxation was reinstated, and an alternative minimum tax was introduced for
companies reporting losses for 3 consecutive years. Special VAT reliefs to nonprofits were
scaled down, and excise duty rates inflation-indexed.
Tax revenue increased steadily, from 9 percent of GDP in 2000 to 15.3 percent in 2009 (a
retreat to 14.6 percent in 2010 being partly due to a two point cut in the VAT rate in response to
the financial crisis). There remains scope to do more—including by scaling back exemptions
(amounting to 3½ percent of GDP in 2007/08), enforcing property taxes, moving to a single
domestic tax department and reviewing the mining tax regime—but the achievements are
considerable.
Vietnam
The last five years have seen sweeping reforms in both policy and administration. These
have been guided by a five-year Tax Reform Plan (2005–10) intended to create a tax system
appropriate to Vietnam’s changing economic conditions. Their implementation has benefited
from substantial IMF TA.
The tax policy regime has been considerably rationalized. The CIT has been strengthened by:
unifying the rate structure (at 25 percent, rather than 28 and 15); removing some incentives;
permitting deductions for reasonable expenses; and transferring unincorporated businesses to the
PIT. The VAT has been improved by restricting zero-rating to exports, eliminating the
discrimination between domestic and imported products and reducing exemptions. The PIT has
also undergone comprehensive change: capital income has been brought into tax; the 30 percent
surcharge was eliminated; the tax brackets were significantly broadened; the top marginal rate
has been lowered (from 40 percent to 35 percent); and tax allowances for dependents have been
introduced.
set of tax administration procedures has been introduced. All tax offices are now connected via a
computer network and a broad range of IT applications has been developed to support core tax
administration functions. Steps have also been taken to upgrade staff skills, which has been
supported by the creation of a tax college within the GDT.
Reflecting these reforms, tax revenue has increased significantly and other important
benefits have been realized. As a share of GDP, tax revenues increased from an average of 19.6
percent over 2001–04 to an average of 23.7 over 2005–08. Beyond the revenue increase, the tax
policy reforms have been positive steps towards building a tax system conducive to economic
development and dealing with increased exposure to the global economy. Similarly, the tax
administration reforms have better-positioned the GDT to administer an increasingly market-
oriented economy.
66
The features of the natural resource sector pose particular challenges for tax design—and
mistakes can be very costly. Investments commonly involve high sunk costs, perhaps billions
of dollars for a project that can last decades; rents are potentially substantial; output prices are
highly variable; revenue is often the major benefit for the home country; investors are commonly
multinationals capable of sophisticated tax planning; and—for hydrocarbons and minerals—the
resource itself is exhaustible. Issues of credibility, the sharing of risk and return between
investors and home government, and effective administration are thus paramount. While similar
issues arise in other sectors, they loom especially large in natural resources. They also make
errors especially damaging. Granting exemptions or preferences not available under general
legislation, for instance, is costly and hard to undo without damaging the government’s
credibility. Examples of this abound, especially in sub-Saharan Africa, among which recent
mining agreements in Sierra Leone and Liberia are prominent.
Efficient natural resource fiscal regimes complement other initiatives towards sound
management of natural resource revenues. The IMF has published a Guide on Resource
Revenue Transparency, extending the principles of the Extractive Industries Transparency
Initiative across not only tax policy but also public financial management. The Kimberley
Process Certification Scheme for diamonds began as an effort to eliminate conflict diamonds, but
also supports revenue assessment and collection. The Natural Resource Charter is an
76
The analysis here is spelled out in the various contributions to Daniel, Keen and McPherson (2010). On the
challenges that natural resource wealth poses for macroeconomic management more widely, including the
allocation between productive investment, current consumption and the accumulation of financial assets, see Davis,
Ossowski, and Fedelino (2003) and Venables (2010).
67
independent initiative to set out principles of good practice in natural resource revenue
management, to which FAD staff has also contributed. Transparent and well-designed fiscal
regimes for natural resources are now widely recognized as essential for effective governance in
resource-rich countries.
68
Δ Δ
VAT revenue
Standard (in percent of C- efficiency
Country VAT rate GDP) (%) 100% median 80% median 120% median
Australia 10 3.9 52.8 0.09 -- 0.89
Austria 20 8.0 54.3 -- -- 1.54
Belgium 21 7.1 45.6 1.31 -- 2.99
Canada 7 3.3 64.4 -- -- 0.02
Czech Republic 19 7.2 53.3 0.09 -- 1.55
Denmark 25 10.0 54.0 -- -- 2.00
Finland 22 8.7 53.3 0.11 -- 1.87
France 19.6 7.3 46.1 1.25 -- 2.95
Germany 16 6.2 50.2 0.47 -- 1.82
Greece 19 6.9 40.6 2.26 0.44 4.08
Hungary 20 8.4 54.2 -- -- 1.65
Iceland 24.5 11.1 53.9 0.01 -- 2.23
Ireland 21 7.5 57.8 -- -- 0.90
Israel 16.5 8.0 59.4 -- -- 0.72
Italy 20 6.0 37.8 2.56 0.85 4.27
Japan 5 2.6 69.6 -- -- --
Korea, Republic of 10 4.2 61.7 -- -- 0.21
Luxembourg 15 6.0 77.2 -- -- --
Netherlands 19 7.5 54.6 -- -- 1.41
New Zealand 12.5 8.7 90.6 -- -- --
Norway 25 7.9 50.5 0.54 -- 2.23
Portugal 21 8.5 46.9 1.27 -- 3.21
Singapore 5 1.8 72.2 -- -- --
Slovak Republic 19 7.9 54.7 -- -- 1.44
Slovenia 20 8.6 59.1 -- -- 0.84
Spain 16 6.2 51.3 0.33 -- 1.63
Sweden 25 9.0 48.2 1.08 -- 3.09
Switzerland 7.6 3.9 71.7 -- -- --
Trinidad & Tobago 15 3.0 36.9 1.37 0.50 2.23
United Kingdom 17.5 6.7 44.0 1.50 -- 3.13
Average high income 17.1 6.7 55.6 0.95 0.60 1.96
69
Rate and base. When introduced in 1995, the VAT had a single rate of 20 percent, and a broad
base with zero-rating only for exports. But more preferences were added over time (for some
agricultural products, foods, medical supplies and drugs) including, since 2002, increasing
numbers of tourist activities. From 2008, the standard rate was reduced from 17.5 percent to 16
percent.
Revenue and efficiency. Revenues peaked at 6.1 percent of GDP in 2001, but since 2004 have
been declining steadily to around 3.8 percent of GDP in 2009. This was not simply a
consequence of the rate cut: the efficiency ratio (relative to GDP) has fallen from about 29
percent in 2002 to around 24 percent in 2009. Options to increase the yield include bringing fee-
based banking and property and casualty insurance into tax, removing the exemption of
passenger transportation services (raising about 0.1 percent of GDP) and fully taxing tourism
(0.2 percent).
Threshold and small businesses. The original VAT threshold was K 30 million (then US$
30,000), but by 2001 it was equivalent to only US$ 8,000. Half of the then 10,000 registered
taxpayers were below the threshold and had registered voluntarily, but exhibited very poor
compliance. The threshold was increased in 2002 to K 200 million (then around US$75,000, now
US$45,000) and voluntary registration removed. Given the difficulties that small businesses then
faced in transacting with registered VAT taxpayers, voluntary registration was reintroduced in
2007. As commonly found elsewhere in Anglophone Africa, all VAT taxpayers were required to
file and pay monthly until 2007, when quarterly arrangements were introduced for voluntary
VAT registrants.
Mineral exports. Zambia’s dependence on mineral exports made effective VAT refunding
especially important. After an initial attempt to avoid the difficulty by deferring VAT on imports
resulted in revenue leakage and noncompliance, a robust refund mechanism was introduced in
2005. Since 2005, financing of refunds has been ring-fenced, based on returns submitted by the
end of one month, and is made from gross VAT (domestic and import) collections in the
following month, before the net balance is transferred to the Treasury. Refund processing times
have since averaged a few weeks, and between 2004 and 2006 Zambia refunded approximately
38 percent of gross VAT collections, a much higher ratio than many African countries, and
consistent with more developed exporting economies. Given the revenue importance of the
sector and of managing its refunds appropriately, the LTO now includes a specialized mining
audit unit.
71
Tax holidays are time-limited exemptions from the CIT, which may or may not be
renewable. They are widely regarded as a particularly ill-designed form of investment
incentive, and one that poses considerable dangers to the wider tax system:
Unless offered for periods so long that investors are likely to doubt their credibility, they
are most attractive to the most footloose firms, which are those likely to bring the least
benefit to the wider economy (such as textiles and assembly of light manufacturing
goods).
They are open to abuse, undermining tax revenue by providing entrepreneurs with a
strong incentive to use transfer pricing and financial arrangements to shift taxable profits
into holiday enterprises: by arranging, for example, for taxpaying companies (able to
deduct the interest payments) to borrow from holiday companies (not taxable on interest
received). Such devices can operate across national borders, and also between domestic
firms. However clever the legal provisions crafted to address this risk, experience
suggests that companies will prove adept in finding ways to avoid them. Even the most
developed tax administrations have great difficulty dealing with such abuse.
For foreign investors resident in countries operating a foreign tax credit system, the
benefits of the holiday will be undone when profits are repatriated. All the holiday then
achieves (unless a double tax agreement with the residence country provides for ‘tax
sparing’—meaning that they do not offset the holiday by reducing the foreign tax credit
available—which is now rarely the case) is a transfer of tax revenues to the residence
country. It may well be, however, that multinationals have enough ways of deferring
repatriation for this not to be a primary consideration in practice.
Unless depreciation allowances can be carried forward out of the holiday period, the
incentive to invest towards the end of a holiday may actually be lower than it would be
under the regular corporate tax system, as investors defer investment in order to take full
advantage of such allowances (Mintz, 1990).
By offering tax holidays, a government is in effect, to some degree, signaling its own
untrustworthiness in tax matters: otherwise a firm that intends to stay beyond the holiday
period (which is presumably the type that it is the object of policy to attract) would find
even more attractive the promise of a low, constant rate of tax implying a present value of
payments below that implied by the holiday.
Many companies apparently find holidays attractive because they spare them the
necessity of dealing with corrupt or inefficient tax administrations. Thus offering a
holiday can itself signal a corrupt or inefficient tax administration, and distract from the
need to address such underlying problems.
72
Freedom to Invest: All investors, domestic and foreign, can invest in all sectors, subject to
investment registration, and with the following exceptions: [A short negative list, different for
each country, could be inserted here].
National Treatment: Domestic and foreign investors shall be entitled to make investments in
participating countries on the same terms.
Repatriation: Each country will permit prompt transfer of funds related to foreign investment—
such as profits, dividends, royalties, loan payments and from liquidations—in freely convertible
currency.
Expropriation: Investments will not be expropriated except for a public purpose and on a non-
discriminatory basis. If property is expropriated, there will be prompt payment of adequate
compensation.
Transparency: The investment incentive system of each country, including its laws, regulations,
guidelines, and administrative procedures, shall be transparent and readily available.
Investment Incentives:
Any incentives must be in the law and available to all investors on the same terms and
not subject to administrative discretion.
Countries agree not to compete by offering tax holidays or profit-tax rates below the
standard rate in each country.
Any investment tax incentives that are provided must be directly related to the amount of
investment (such as accelerated depreciation, investment allowances, or tax credits) and
cannot favor particular sectors or activities.
Standard Tax Rate: Each country commits not to reduce the standard corporate tax rate below
[insert rate].
New Investment Tax Incentives: Countries agree not to introduce new investment tax incentives
or extend the scope of or increase existing ones that are inconsistent with the guidelines above.
Rollback of Existing Investment Tax Incentives: Countries commit to amend their existing laws
and established practices to eliminate investment tax incentives inconsistent with these principles
by [insert date]. Companies that, prior to [date] have been awarded incentives counter to these
principles should be ‘grandfathered,’ that is, continue to enjoy the incentives during the period
the incentives were promised, assuming they continue to meet the conditions for them.
73
Tax Expenditures: Each country will develop and publish tax expenditures that will cover, at a
minimum, all tax incentives inconsistent with these principles.
China removed in 2008 a five-year break for foreign investors (two years at zero percent, then
three at half the standard rate of 33 percent), in favor of a single rate of 25 percent. Reduced CIT
rates (of 15 percent and 24 percent) were also eliminated in favor of the single 25 percent rate.
Egypt passed a new income tax law in mid-2005 that reduced the top marginal tax rates on
income and profits from 32 to 20 percent for individuals and from 40 to 20 percent for
corporations and partnerships (rates for petroleum, the Suez Canal authority, and the central bank
were left at 40 percent). This reform also increased the personal exemption threshold, liberalized
normal depreciation (equipment and machinery are now eligible for a 30 percent deduction in the
first year of use with normal depreciation rates applying therefore to the remaining balance), and
provided for the phasing out of tax holidays while grandfathering current beneficiaries.
Importantly, these reforms have been accompanied by extensive and continuing reforms of tax
administration, including the successful introduction of self-assessment and a reform of the tax
treatment of small- and medium-size enterprises. Between 2005 and 2006, FDI into Egypt
doubled.
Mauritius removed most existing tax incentives (tax holidays, exemptions and investment tax
credits) for companies with the exception of those already granted. The only notable remaining
investment incentive is a four-year tax holiday for income derived by a small enterprise or
handicraft enterprise under the Small Enterprises and Handicraft Development Authority Act of
2005, designed to encourage regularization of informal businesses. In addition, the standard
corporate tax rate was reduced from 25 to 15 percent from July 2007, thereby harmonizing it
with the prevailing rate on tax-incentive companies. (The PIT rate structure was also changed to
a flat rate of 15 percent). Foreign direct investment was strong following these changes, with net
inflows as a percent of GDP doubling in 2006 over 2005, to about 1 2/3 percent, and almost
tripling in 2007, to 4½ percent of GDP. The share of net inflows was similar for 2008 and 2010,
although there was a slight dip in 2009. Most of the increase in FDI was in the tourism, real
estate (including purchase of property by nonresidents), and, especially, the financial services
and insurance sectors (where there were a number of regulatory changes). During this period,
CIT revenue also increased significantly, from about 2½ percent of GDP in 2006/07 and 2007/08
to 3.8 percent in 2008/09, and 3.6 percent of GDP for the six-month period July–December
2009.
75
References
Acemoglu, Daron, 2005, “Politics and Economics in Weak and Strong States,” Journal of
Monetary Economics, Vol. 52, pp. 1199–226.
Adams, Christopher S., and David L. Bevan, 2005, “Fiscal Deficits and Growth in Developing
Countries,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 89, pp. 571–97.
African Development Bank, and Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development,
2010, “Public Resource Mobilization and Aid in Africa,” in African Economic Outlook,
pp. 79–122 (Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development).
Aisen, Ari, and Francisco Veiga, 2008, “The Political Economy of Seignorage,” Journal of
Development Economics, Vol. 87, pp. 29–50.
Aizenman, Joshua, and Yothin Jinjarak, 2008, “The Collection Efficiency of the Value-Added
Tax: Theory and International Evidence,” Journal of International Trade and Economic
Development, Vol. 17, pp. 391–410.
Alesina, Alberto, and Romain Wacziarg, 1998, “Openness, Country Size and Government,”
Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 69, pp. 305–21.
Alm, James, and Sally Wallace, 2004, “Can Developing Countries Impose an Individual Income
Tax?” mimeo (Atlanta: Georgia State University).
Araujo-Bonjean, Catherine, and Gerard Chambas, 2003, in Taxing the Hard to Tax: Lessons
from Theory and Practice, ed. by James Alm, Jorge Martinez-Vasquez, and Sally
Wallace, pp. 313–29 (Amsterdam: Elsevier).
Arnold, Jens, 2008, “Do Tax Structures Affect Aggregate Economic Growth? Empirical
Evidence from a Panel of OECD Countries,” OECD Economics Department Working
Paper No. 643 (Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
Publishing).
Arze del Granado, J., David Coady, and Robert Gillingham, 2010, “The Unequal Benefits of
Fuel Subsidies: A Review of Evidence for Developing Countries,” IMF Working Paper
10/2020 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Attali, Joseph Gpewopo, Gérard Chambsa and Jean Louis Combes, 2008, “Corruption et
Mobilization des recetes Publiques: Une Analyse Économétrique,” Recherche
Economique de Louvain.
Auriol, Emmanuelle, and Michael Warlters, 2005, “Taxation Base in Developing Countries,”
Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 89, pp. 625–46.
76
Baer, Katherine, and others, 2002, Improving Large Taxpayers’ Compliance, Occasional Paper
215 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
——— and Eric Le Borgne, 2008, Tax Amnesties: Theory, Trends, and Some Alternatives,
(Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Bahl, Roy, 2009, “Property Tax Reform in Developing and Transition Countries,” Andrew
Young School of Policy Studies (for USAID ; Atlanta : Georgia State University).
Baker, Raymond, 2005, Capitalism’s Achilles Heel: Dirty Money and How to Renew the Free-
Market System (John Wiley & Sons).
Baunsgaard, Thomas, and Michel Keen, 2010, “Tax Revenue and (or?) Trade Liberalization,”
Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 94, pp. 563–77.
Besley, Timothy, and Torsten Persson, 2009, “The Origins of State Capacity: Property Rights,
Taxation, and Politics,” American Economic Review, Vol. 99, pp. 1218–244.
———, ———, 2010, Pillars of Prosperity: Peace, Easy Taxes and the Rule of Law, Manuscript
(London: London School of Economics).
Biggs, Tyler, and Manju Shah, 1998, “The Determinants of Enterprise Growth in sub-Saharan
Africa: Evidence from the Regional Program on Enterprise Development,” Regional
Program on Enterprise Development Discussion Paper (Washington: World Bank).
Bird, Richard, 2008, “Tax Challenges Facing Developing Countries,” (New Delhi: National
Institute of Public Finance and Policy).
———, and Pierre-Pascal Gendron, 2007, The VAT in Developing and Transitional and
Countries (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
———, Jorge Martinez-Vazquez, and Benno Torgler, 2008, “Tax Effort in Developing
Countries and High-Income Countries: The Impact of Corruption, Voice and
Accountability,” Economic Analysis and Policy, Vol. 38, pp. 55–71.
Bodin, Jean-Paul, 2010, “Revenue Administration: Developing a Simplified Tax Regime for
Small Businesses,” FAD Technical Notes and Manuals (forthcoming; Washington:
International Monetary Fund).
77
———, and Vincent Koukpaizan, 2008, “Taxation of Small Enterprises: Recent Developments,”
International VAT Monitor, March/April, pp. 121–31.
Bornhorst, Fabian, Sanjeev Gupta, and John Thornton, 2009, “Natural Resource Endowments
and the Domestic Revenue Effort,” European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 25,
pp. 439–46.
Brun, Jean-François, Gerard Chambas, and Samuel Guerineau, 2008, “Aide et Mobilisation
Fiscale dans les Pays en Voie de Développement,” CERDI, Etudes et Documents.
———, and Bertrand Laporte, 2010, “IMF Programs and Tax Effort: What Role for Institutions
in Africa?” CERDI, Etudes et Documents (forthcoming).
Castro, Patricio, Raúl Junquera-Varela, Osvaldo Schenone, and Antonio Teixeira, 2009,
“Mozambique: Evaluation of Reforms in Tax Policy and Administration 1994—2007”
available online at http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2009/090109b.pdf
Chambas, Gérard, 2005, Afrique au sud du Sahara: Mobiliser des Ressources Fiscales pour le
Développement (Paris: Economica).
———, 2010, Mobiliser des Ressources Locales en Afrique Subsaharienne (Paris: Economica).
Coady, David, Robert Gillingham, Rolando Ossowski, John Piotrowski, Shamsuddin Tareq, and
Justin Tyson, 2010, “Petroleum Product Subsidies: Costly, Inequitable, and Rising,” IMF
Staff Position Note 10/05 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Crandall, William, and Jean-Paul Bodin, 2005, “Revenue Administration Reforms in Selected
Middle Eastern Countries, 1994–2004,” IMF Working Paper 05/203 (Washington:
International Monetary Fund).
Crawford, Ian, Michael Keen, and Stephen Smith, 2010, “VAT and Excises,” in Dimensions of
Tax Design: The Mirrlees Review James Mirrlees, ed. by Stuart Adam, Timothy Besley,
Richard Blundell, Stephen Bond, Robert. Chote, Malcolm Gammie, Paul Johnson, Gareth
Myles, and Jim Poterba, pp. 275–362 (Oxford: Oxford University Press for Institute for
Fiscal Studies).
78
Cubeddu, Luis, Andreas Bauer, Pelin Berkman, Magda Kandil, Koffie Nassar, and Peter
Mullins, 2008, “Tax Incentives and Foreign Direct Investment: Policy Implications for
the Caribbean,” in The Caribbean: Enlarging Economic Integration, ed. by Andreas
Bauer, Paul Lashin, and Sanjaya Panth, pp. 44–84 (Washington: International Monetary
Fund).
Daniel, Philip, Michael Keen, and Charles McPherson, 2010, The Taxation of Petroleum and
Minerals: Principles, Practices and Problems (Routledge: Abingdon).
Davis, Jeffrey, Rolando Ossowski and Annalisa Fedelino, 2003, Fiscal Policy Formulation and
Implementation in Oil-Producing Countries (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
de Paula, Aureo, and José Scheinkman, 2006, “The Informal Sector,” mimeo (Princeton
University).
Dharmapala, Dhammika, and James R. Hines Jr., 2009, “Which Countries Become Tax
Havens?” Journal of Public Economics, Vol.93, pp. 1058–068.
Dixit, Avinash, 1991, “The Optimal Mix of Inflationary Finance and Commodity Taxation with
Collection Lags,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 38, pp. 643–54.
Ebe, Christian, and Helene Ehrhart, 2010, “Tax Revenue Instability in sub-Saharan Africa:
Consequences and Remedies,” mimeo, CERDI (Auvergne University).
Ebrill, Liam, Michael Keen, Jean-Paul Bodin, and Victoria Summers, 2001, The Modern VAT
(Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Eckert, Joseph, 2008, “Computer-assisted Mass Appraisal Options for Transitional and
Developing Countries,” in Making the Property Tax Work: Experiences in Developing
and Transitional Countries, ed. by Roy Bahl , Jorge Martinez-Vasquez, and Joan
Youngman (Cambridge MA, Lincoln Institute of Land Policy).
Emran, Shahe, and Joseph Stiglitz, 2005, “On Selective Indirect Tax Reform in Developing
Countries,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 89, pp. 599–623.
FIAS, 2007, “South Africa: Tax Compliance Burden for Small Businesses: A Survey of Tax
Practitioners,” available online at
http://www.fias.net/ifcext/fias.nsf/Content/Pubs_BusinessTaxation
Fuest, Clemens, and Nadine Riedel, 2010, “Tax Evasion and Avoidance in Developing
Countries: The Role of International Profit Shifting,” Oxford University Centre for
Business Taxation, Working Paper No. 10/12.
Gauthier, Bernard, and Mark Gersovitz, 1997, “Revenue Erosion and Evasion in Cameroon,
1993,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 64, pp. 407–24.
———, and Ritva Reinikka, 2006, “Shifting Tax Burdens through Exemptions and Evasion: An
Empirical Investigation of Uganda,” Journal of African Economies, Vol. 15, pp. 373–98.
Ghura, D., 2006, “Tax Revenue in sub-Saharan Africa: Effects of Economic Policies and
Corruption,” IMF Working Paper 98/135 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Goode, Richard, 1993, “Tax Advice to Developing Countries: An Historical Survey,” World
Development, Vol. 21, pp. 37–53.
Gordon, Roger, 2010, Taxation in Developing Countries: Six Case Studies and Policy
Implications (New York: Columbia University Press).
———, and Wei Li, 2009, “Tax Structures in Developing Countries: Many Puzzles and a
Possible Explanation,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 93, pp. 855–66.
Gupta, Abhijit Sen, 2007, “Determinants of Tax Revenue Efforts in Developing Countries,” IMF
Working Paper 07/184 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Gupta, Sanjeev, Benedict Clements, Alexander Pivovarsky, and Erwin R. Tingson, 2004,
“Foreign Aid and Revenue Response: Does the Composition of Aid Matter?” in Helping
Countries Develop: The Role of Fiscal Policy, ed. by Sanjeev Gupta, Benedict Clements,
and Gabrieilla Inchauste, pp. 385–406 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
80
———, Shamsuddin Tareq, Benedict Clements, Alex Sequra-Ubiergo, Rina Bhattacharya, and
Todd Matina, 2005, Rebuilding Fiscal Institutions in Post-Conflict Countries, IMF
Occasional Paper No. 27 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Harrison, Graham, 2008, “VAT Refunds,” in VAT in Africa, ed. by Richard Krever (Pretoria:
Pretoria University Law Press).
Heady, Christopher, 2002, “Tax Policy in Developing Countries: What can be Learned from
OECD Experience?” mimeo (Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development).
Hu, T.-W., Z. Mao, J. Shi, and W. Chen, 2008, “Tobacco Taxation and its Potential Impact in
China” (Paris: International Union against Tuberculosis and Lung Disease).
IFC, 2007, “Designing a Tax System for Micro and Small Businesses: Guide for Practitioners.”
International Monetary Fund, 2000, “Recent Experience with the Value-Added Tax—An
Overview” (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
———, 2005, “Dealing with the Revenue Consequences of Trade Reform,” IMF Policy Paper,
Supplement 2 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
———, 2010a, “Reaching the MDGs: Macroeconomic Prospects and Challenges in Low-
Income Countries,” Background Note for the United Nations MDG Summit.
———, 2010b, “A Multi-Donor Trust Fund for IMF Capacity Building Technical Assistance
in Managing Natural Resource Wealth: Draft Program Document” available at
www.imf.org
———, 2010c, “A Multi-Donor Trust Fund for IMF Capacity Building Technical Assistance in
Tax Policy and Administration—Securing Revenue for Development: Draft Program
Document” available at www.imf.org
International Tax Compact, 2010, Mapping Survey: Taxation and Development, available online
at http://taxcompact.net/documents.html
International Tax Dialogue, 2005, “The Value-Added Tax—Experiences and Issues,” available
online at www.idweb.org.
———, 2007, “Taxing Small and Medium Enterprises,” available online at www.itdweb.org.
Jenkins, Glenn P., Jenkins Hatice P., and Chun-Yan Kuo, 2006, “Is the VAT Naturally
Progressive?” mimeo (Queens University).
81
Jensen, Robert, 2007, “The Digital Provide: Information (Technology), Market Performance and
Welfare in the South Indian Fisheries Sector,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 122,
pp. 879–924.
Kaldor, Nicholas, 1963, “Will Underdeveloped Countries Learn to Tax?” Foreign Affairs, Vol.
41, pp. 410–19.
Keen, Michael (ed.), 2003, Changing Customs: Challenges and Strategies for the Reform of
Customs Administration (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
———, 2008, “VAT, Tariffs, and Withholding: Border Taxes and Informality in Developing
Countries,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 92, pp. 1892–906.
———, 2009, “What Do (and Don’t) We Know about the Value-Added Tax? A Review of
Richard Bird and Pierre-Pascal Gendron, The VAT in Developing and Transitional
Countries,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 47, pp. 155–66.
———, and Jenny Ligthart, 2002, “Coordinating Tariff Reduction and Domestic Tax Reform,”
Journal of International Economics, Vol. 56, pp., 489–507.
———, and Ben Lockwood, 2010, “The Value-Added Tax: Its Causes and Consequences,”
Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 92, pp. 138–51.
———, and Mario Mansour, 2010a, “Revenue Mobilization in sub-Saharan Africa: Challenges
from Globalization I—Trade Reform,” Development Policy Review¸ Vol. 28, pp. 552–71.
———, and Alejandro Simone, 2004, “Tax Policy in Developing Countries: Some Lessons from
the 1990s, and Some Challenges Ahead,” pp. 302–52 in Helping Countries Develop: The
Role of Fiscal Policy ed. by Sanjeev Gupta, Ben Clements, and Gabriela Inchauste
(Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Kidd, Maureen, and William Crandall, 2006, “Revenue Authorities: Issues and Problems in
Evaluating their Success,” IMF Working Paper 06/240 (Washington: International
Monetary Fund).
Klemm, Alex, and Stefan van Parys, 2009, “Empirical Evidence on the Effects of Tax
Incentives,” IMF Working Paper 09/136 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
82
Le, Tuan Minh, Blanca Moreno-Dodson, and Jeep Rojchaichaninthorn, 2008, “Expanding
Taxable Capacity and Reaching Revenue Potential: Cross-Country Analysis,” World
Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4559.
Lee, Young, and Roger H. Gordon, 2005, “Tax Structure and Economic Growth,” Journal of
Public Economics, Vol. 89, pp. 1027–043.
Lotz, Jorgen, and Elliot Morss, 1967, “Measuring Tax Effort in Developing Countries,” IMF
Staff Papers, Vol. 14, pp. 478–99.
Marshall, John, 2009, “One Size Fits All? IMF Tax Policy in sub-Saharan Africa,” Occasional
Paper No. 2 (London: Christian Aid).
Martinez-Vasquez, Vulovic, and Yongzheng Liu, 2009, “Direct versus Indirect Taxation:
Trends, Theory and Economic Significance,” International Studies Program, Working
Paper 09–11, updated (Atlanta: Georgia State University).
McPherson, Charles, 2010, “State Participation in the Natural Resource Sectors: Evolution,
Issues and Outlook,’ in The Taxation of Petroleum and Minerals: Principles, Practices
and Problems, ed. by Philip Daniel, Michael Keen, and Charles McPherson, pp. 263–88
(Abingdon: Routledge).
Michielse, Geerten, and Victor Thuronyi, 2010, “Overview of Cooperation on Capacity Building
in Taxation,” mimeo (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Mikesell, John L., and C. Kurt Zorn, 2008, “Data Challenges in Implementing a Market Value
Property Tax: Market and Market-Informed Valuation in Russia, Ukraine, and the Baltic
States,” ed. by Bahl et al.
Mintz, Jack, 1990, “Tax Holidays and Investment,” World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 4,
pp. 81–102.
Modi, Jitendra, 1987, “Statistical Appendix,” in Supply-Side Tax Policy: Its Relevance to
Developing Countries, ed. by Ved P. Gandhi (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Moss, Todd, Gunilla Pettersson, and Nicolas van de Walle, 2006, “An Aid-Institutions Paradox?
A Review Essay on Aid Dependency and State Building in sub-Saharan Africa,” Center
for Global Development Working Paper 74.
Mullins, Peter, 2006, “Moving to Territoriality? Implications for the U.S. and the Rest of the
World,” Tax Notes International, Vol. 43, September 4, pp. 839–53.
83
Muñoz, Sonia, and Stanley Sang-Wook Cho, 2004, “Social Impact of a Tax Reform: The Case of
Ethiopia,” in Helping Countries Develop: The Role of Fiscal Policy, ed. by Sanjeev
Gupta, Benedict Clements, and Gabriella Inchauste, pp. 353–84 (Washington:
International Monetary Fund).
Newhouse, David, and Daria Zakharova, 2007, “Distributional Implications of the VAT Reform
in the Philippines,” IMF Working Paper 07/153 (Washington: International Monetary
Fund).
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development, 2007, “Putting Public Finances on a
Firmer Footing,” in OECD Economic Survey: Mexico 2007, Chapter 2 (Paris:
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development).
———, 2008, Governance, Taxation and Accountability: Issues and Practice, Development
Assistance Committee Guidelines and Reference Series.
———, DAC GOVNET, 2009, Taxation, State Building and Aid: Factsheet—Update December
2009, available online at www.oecd.org/dac/govenance
Persson, Torsten, and Guido Tabellini, 2003, The Economic Effect of Constitutions (Cambridge:
MIT Press).
Pessino, Carola, and Ricardo Fenochietto, 2010, “Determining Countries’ Tax Efforts,”
Hacienda Pública Española/Revista de Economía Pública, Vol. 195, pp. 61–83.
Peter, Klara Sabirianova, Steve Buttrick, and Denvil Duncan, 2010, “Global Reform of Personal
Income Taxation, 1981-2005: Evidence from 189 countries”, National Tax Journal,
Vol. 63, pp. 447–78.
Petit, Patrick, forthcoming, “Tobacco Excise Taxes,” IMF Staff Position Note (forthcoming;
Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Plimmer, Francis, and William J. McCluskey, 2010, “The Basis and the Administration of the
Property Tax: What Can Be Learned from International Practice?” Presentation to the
XXIV International Federation of Surveyors Congress 2010 (Sydney, Australia).
Rodrik, Dani, 1998, “Why Do More Open Countries Have Bigger Governments?” Journal of
Political Economy, Vol. 106, pp. 997–1032.
Ross, Hana, and Frank J. Chaloupka, 2000, “The Effect of Cigarette Prices on Youth Smoking,”
Health Economics, Vol. 12, pp. 217–230.
84
Schneider, Friedrich, Andreas Buehn, and Claudio Montenegro, 2010, “Shadow Economies All
over the World: New Estimates for 162 Countries,” Policy Research Working Paper
5356, World Bank.
Sah, Raaj K., 1983, “How Much Redistribution is Possible through Commodity Taxes?” Journal
of Public Economics, Vol. 20, 89–101.
Silvani, Carlos, John Brondolo, Eric LeBorgne, and Frank Bosch, 2008, “Tax Administration
Reform and Fiscal Adjustment: The Case of Indonesia (2001–07)”, IMF Working Paper
08/129 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Stewart, Miranda, and Sunita Jogarajan, 2004, “The International Monetary Fund and Tax
Reform,” British Tax Review, pp. 146–75.
Sunley, Emil, 2010, “Taxation of Cigarettes in the Bloomberg Initiative Countries,” Tax Notes
International, April 12, Vol. 58, pp. 161–18.
Tanzi, Vito, 1978, “Inflation, Real Tax Revenue, and the Case for Inflationary Finance: Theory
with an Application to Argentina,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 23, pp. 417–51.
Thuronyi, Victor, 2001, “International Tax Cooperation and a Multilateral Treaty,” Brooklyn
Journal of International Law, Vol. XXVI, pp. 1641–681.
Torvik, Ragnar, 2009, “Why are Tax Havens More Harmful to Developing Countries than to
other Countries?” in Tax Havens and Development, Appendix 1, Report on the
Government Commission on Capital Flight from Poor Countries, Official Norwegian
Reports 2009:19.
Van Parys, Stefan, and Sebastian James, 2009, “Why Tax Incentives May Be an Inefficient Tool
to Encouraging Investment? The Role of the Investment Climate,” mimeo (Washington:
World Bank).
Venables, Anthony J., 2010, “Resource Rents; When to Spend and How to Save,” in
International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 17, pp. 340–56.
85
Villela, Luiz, Andrea Lemgruber, and Michael Jorratt, 2010, “Tax Expenditure Budgets:
Concepts and Challenges for Implementation,” Inter-American Development Bank
Working Paper No. IDB-WP-179.
Wacziarg, Romain, and Karen Horn Welch, 2008, “Trade Liberalization and Growth: New
Evidence,” World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 22, pp. 187–231.
World Health Organization, 2010, Technical Manual on Tobacco Tax Administration (Geneva:
World Health Organization).
Zolt, Eric M., and Richard M. Bird, 2005, “Redistribution via Taxation: The Limited Role of the
Personal Income Tax in Developing Countries,” UCLA Law Review, Vol. 52,
pp. 1627–95.