Respondent Memo Antitrust 2014
Respondent Memo Antitrust 2014
Respondent Memo Antitrust 2014
Special Leave Petition filed under Article 136 of the Constitution of Bohemia & Appeals filed
under Section 53T of the Competition Act,2002
Most Respectfully Submitted to the Hon’ble Judges of the Supreme Court of Bohemia at
Riverdale
TABLE OF CONTENTS
TABLE OF C O N T E N T S ..............................................................................................................i
LIST OF A B B R E V I A T I O N S ....................................................................................................iii
INDEX OF A U T H O R I T I E S ......................................................................................................iv
S T AT E M E N T OF J U R I S D I C T I O N .......................................................................................viii
S T AT E M E N T OF F A C T S ...........................................................................................................x
SUMMARY OF A R G U M E N T S ...............................................................................................xiii
W R I T T E N S U B M I S S I O N S ........................................................................................................1
I. WHETHER THE ORDER OF THE RIVERDALE HIGH COURT DECLARING THE DIRECTOR
GENERAL’S REPORT AND THE ENSUING COMPETITION COMMISSION OF BOHEMIA’S (CCB)
ORDER VOID IS CORRECT IN LAW?.................................................................................................1
II. WHETHER THE AGREEMENT BETWEEN THE MRI MANUFACTURERS AND THE SERVICE
2.1. THAT THE AGREEMENT IN ITSELF IS NECESSARY AND HAS THE ABILITY TO PROMOTE
COMPETITION...............................................................................................................................5
AREA OPERATES TO THE BENEFIT OF THE CONSUMER AND IT IS NOT LIKELY THAT ANTI-
ANTICOMPETITIVE.....................................................................................................................11
2.6. THAT THE COMPAT’S DECISION HOLDING THAT THE AGREEMENT WAS NOT ANTI-
3.1. THAT THE RELEVANT MARKET EXTENDS TO THE SPARE PARTS OF ALL
PROVIDERS.................................................................................................................................17
3.2. THAT THE MANUFACTURERS’ DID NOT EXERCISE A POSITION OF DOMINANCE IN THE
RELEVANT MARKET...................................................................................................................20
3.3. THAT THE MANUFACTURERS’ DID NOT ABUSE THEIR POSITION OF DOMINANCE.......21
CARTELIZATION?..........................................................................................................................25
4.3. THAT THE RESOLUTION TO EXCLUSIVELY AVAIL THE SERVICES OF THE ASP IS
JUSTIFIABLE...............................................................................................................................28
P R AY E R .......................................................................................................................................xv
LIST OF A B B R E V I AT I O N S
Abbreviation Description
DG Director – General
EC European Commission
INDEX OF AUTHORITIES
Cases
Aberdeen Journals Ltd. v. Director General of Fair Trading, (No.1) [2002] CAT 4..............18, 20
Allied Tube & Conduit Corporation v. Indian Head, Inc., 486 U.S. 492......................................29
Barr Labs, Inc. v. Abbott Labs, 978 F.2d 98, 111 (3d Cir.1992)......................................................7
Carbour SA et Nord Distribution Automobile, SA v. Arnor SOCO SARL, [1998] ECR I-2055....11
Chi. Prof’l Sports Ltd. P'ship v. NBA, 961 F.2d 667, 674 (7th Cir. 1992)....................................23
Digital Equip. Corp. v. Uniq Digital Techs.. Inc., 73 F.3d 756, 763 (7th Cir.1996).....................13
District Collector, Chittor & Ors v. Chittoor District Groundnut Traders, 1989 (2) SCC 58........3
Eastman Kodak Company v. Image Technical Services, Inc., 504 U.S. 451 (1992).....................13
FICCI - Multiplex Association of India v. United Producers/ Distributors Forum, Case No. 01 of
2009............................................................................................................................................27
In Re: Suo-moto case against LPG cylinder manufacturers, Case No. 03 of 201, decided on
Lee v. Life Ins. Co. of North America, 130 L.Ed.2d 340 (1994)..............................................13, 25
Manappuram Jewellers Pvt. Ltd. v. Kerala Gold & Silver Dealers Association, Case No. 13 of
2011............................................................................................................................................24
Menasha Corp. v. News America Marketing In-Store, Inc., 354 F.3d 661 (7th Cir.2004)..............6
Paddock Publ'ng, Inc. v. Chicago Tribune Co., 103 F.3d 42 (7th Cir.1996)...................................6
Prevention and Control of Water Pollution v. Andhra Pradesh Rayons Ltd., AIR 1989 SC 611.. .2
Prime’s Brief for Judgment N.O.V., E.D. Mich., Case 89-CV-71762, 29 November 1990, at p.714
Psi Repair Services, Inc., v. Honeywell, Inc., 104 F.3d 811 (6th Cir.1997)...................................14
Race Tires America, Inc. v. Hoosier Racing Tire Corp., 2011 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 48847................8
Roofire Alarm Co. v. Royal Indemnity Co., 373 U.S. 949 (1963).................................................29
Sh. Dhanraj Pillay & Ors. v. M/S Hockey India, Case No. 73 of 2011........................................23
Shailesh Kumar v. M/S Tata Chemicals Limited & Ors , Case 66/2011 decided on April 16,
2013............................................................................................................................................14
Shri Jyoti Swaroop Arora v. M/S Tulip Infratech Ltd. & Ors., Case No. 59 of 2011....................27
Shri Shamsher Kataria v. Honda Siel Cars India Ltd. & Ors., 2014 Comp LR001 (CCI)...........20
Southern Pac. Communications Co. v. AT&T, 740 F.2d 980 (D.C.Cir. 1984).................................8
Surinder Singh Barmi v. Board for Control of Cricket in India, Case No. 61 of 2010.................18
Toys ‘R’ Us, Inc. v. Federal Trade Commission, 221 F.3d 928 (7th Cir. 2000).......................23, 24
United States v. Dentsply International, Inc., 399 F.3d 181 (3rd Cir. 2005).................................23
Other Authorities
C. Edward Fee & Shawn Thomas, Sources of Gains in Horizontal Mergers: Evidence from
Customer, Supplier, and Rival Firms, 74 J. FIN. ECON. 423, 424-27 (2004)...........................22
Competition and Market Authority, Guidance on Trade Associations, professions and self-
regulating bodies........................................................................................................................26
D.P Mittal, Competition Law and Practice 409 (2nd edn., 2007)...................................................7
Joshua D. Wright, The Economics of Resale Price Maintenance & Implications for Competition
Robert Pitofsky, Self Regulation and Antitrust, Prepared Remarks before the 34 Annual
SVS Raghavan Committee, Report of High Level Committee on Competition Law & Policy
(2000) ¶ 2.8...................................................................................................................................3
United Kingdom Office of Fair Trading, Market Definition: Understanding Competition Law, in
Treatises
S TAT E M E N T OF JURISDICTION
THE PETITIONER HAS APPROACHED THIS HON’BLE COURT UNDER ARTICLE 136 OF THE
CONSTITUTION OF BOHEMIA.
(1) Notwithstanding anything in this Chapter, the Supreme Court may, in its discretion, grant special
leave to appeal from any judgment, decree, determination, sentence or order in any cause or
Nothing in clause (1) shall apply to any judgment, determination, sentence or order passed or
made by any court or tribunal constituted by or under any law relating to the Armed Forces.”
THE APPELLANTS HAVE APPROACHED THIS HON’BLE COURT UNDER SECTION 53T OF THE
The Central Government or any State Government or the Commission or any statutory authority
or any local authority or any enterprise or any person aggrieved by any decision or order of the
Appellate Tribunal may file an appeal to the Supreme Court within sixty days from the date of
Provided that the Supreme Court may, if it is satisfied that the applicant was prevented by
sufficient cause from filing the appeal within the said period, allow it to be filed after the expiry
I SS U E S FOR C O N S I D E R AT I O N
I. WHETHER THE ORDER OF THE RIVERDALE HIGH COURT DECLARING THE DIRECTOR
II. WHETHER THE AGREEMENT BETWEEN THE MRI MANUFACTURERS AND THE SERVICE
III. WHETHER THE MANUFACTURERS HAVE ABUSED THEIR DOMINANT POSITION UNDER
S TAT E M E N T OF FACTS
magnetic resonance imaging (MRI) machines. These machines are purchased by hospitals,
high specialty clinics and diagnostic clinics. HCF is a key market player for the manufacture
and supply of MRI machines, with other notable competitors being Takshi Inc. and Parry
Ltd.
2. HCF, Takshi and Parry together account for approximately 50% of the global market share,
and approximately 70% of the Bohemian market share. HCF, as a general rule, required the
MRI machines manufactured by it to be repaired only using genuine parts. Also, such
installation of the spare parts and other components was to be carried out by Authorized
Service Providers (ASP) expressly authorized by HCF. In the event of violation of these
terms, the consumers (i.e., the hospitals and super speciality clinics) would stand in breach
of the warranty provided by HCF (otherwise for a period of three years). A similar practice
3. HCF had entered into agreements with selective suppliers on the basis of their technical
expertise, financial strength and affiliation from standardizing agencies and thus, the
consumers were required to procure the spare parts of the MRI machines through these ASP
only.
4. In December, 2012, Bohemia Medical Association (BMA) passed a resolution that instructed
the hospitals to avail the services on authorised service providers employed by HCF, Takshi
5. Mr. Amandeep Sodhi, the sole proprietor of Fantasy Medicare Service Limited, based in
Riverdale, had been providing hospitals with medical supplies, equipment and spare parts
for close to 45 years. However, since early 2013, Mr. Sodhi had seen a gradual decline in his
business with the emergence of the ASPs which had been steadily garnering the market
6. Mr. Sodhi, contacted HCF to become an ASP but refused as he became aware of the terms
and conditions of the agreement. Alternately, he was allowed by HCF to enter into
agreement for the supply of spare parts at a price 1.5 times higher than the others.
7. Aggrieved, Mr. Sodhi filed an application under Section 19(1) (a) of the Competition Act
before the CCB against HCF, Takshi and Parry alleging that the agreements entered into
between HCF, Takshi and Parry and their respective ASPs amounted to an exclusive supply
8. The CCB ordered the office of the Director-General (DG) to investigate, the alleged
violation. The DG, in his report, found HCF, Takshi and Parry to be in violation of section
3(4) of the Competition Act. In addition to this, he also found them to be in violation of
section 4 due to their dominant position in the market being abused for the supply of spare
parts of their respective MRI Machines. The Competition Commission Board (CCB) upheld
these findings. As a result, Takshi and Parry appealed the order to the Competition Appellate
Tribunal (COMPAT) (Appeal No. 1/2014), while HCF challenged the jurisdiction of the DG
to expand the scope of its investigation to a violation of Section 4 before the Riverdale High
Court.
9. The Riverdale High Court ruling in favour of the petitioner ordered that the DG’s
investigation and the resulting final order of the CCB was void as the DG did not have any
10. Meanwhile, in April 2013, Ms. Debjoy Bhattacharya, a retired Major with the Bohemian
National Navy was at the Athena Specialty Hospital in Riverdale for getting an MRI done.
However, she was informed that her medical insurance, did not include MRI diagnostics,
and hence, as a result, Ms. Bhattacharya was forced to pay for the high cost herself. She also
discovered that other hospitals were charging similarly exorbitant rates for their MRI
11. Aggrieved, she filed an application alleging that the hospitals were involved in price-fixing
arrangement with the BMA. The DG Report found the BMA to be in violation of Section 3
of the Competition Act for entering into anti-competitive practices in the nature of a cartel,
through price-fixing by virtue of agreeing upon negotiated prices among HCF, Takshi and
12. The BMA and the hospitals appealed before the COMPAT (Appeal No. 2/2014). The
COMPAT found that the two sets of appeals to be inter-connected and decided to hear the
13. The CCB filed a Special Leave Petition before the Supreme Court of Bohemia challenging
the order of COMPAT. Meanwhile, Mr. Sodhi and Ms. Bhattacharya also appealed against
S U M M A RY OF ARGUMENTS
CORRECT IN LAW?
It is humbly submitted that as per the Competition Act, 2002, the Competition Commission has
the power to direct the Director General to investigate into any matter where the Commission
finds a prima facie infringement of the sections of this Act. In the instant matter, the Director
General investigated into a violation of Section 4 when he had been given a direction to
investigate into a violation of Section 3(4). It is contended that the statutory provision is
unambiguous and the legislative intent is clear as to the extent of power bestowed on the Director
General. Formation of an opinion that there is a prima facie contravention of the provisions of
the Act is sine qua non for an investigation by the Director General. The scheme of the Act
provides for hearing at multiple stages. The law entitles the parties the opportunity to be heard
before the Director General as well as the Commission. Therefore, allowing the Director General
to expand the scope of investigation results in the violation of the principles of natural justice.
Thus the Riverdale High Court’s order declaring the Director General’s report and the ensuing
It is humbly submitted that the agreement between the MRI manufacturers and the authorised
service providers is not likely to cause an appreciable adverse effect on competition, therefore it
does not contravene Section 3(1) of the Act. It is contended in this regard that the order of the
COMPAT finding no violation should be upheld and the agreement be declared as valid. It is
submitted that the agreement in question has pro-competitive effects in the form of accrual of
benefits to the consumers. Further any anti-competitive effect as enshrined in Section 19(3) of
the Act is not a likely result of the agreements in question. The agreement enhances competition
and efficiency in the primary manufacturing market as well as the aftermarket for spare parts and
services. The exclusive supply clause, the territorial allocation and the minimum recommended
resale price have sound business justifications and ultimately provide enhanced services to the
consumer.
It is submitted that the relevant market in the present matter is the market for all the spare parts
and repair and maintenance services in the market. The manufacturers’ are not the only source of
spare parts in the relevant market and hence, possess limited market share. Therefore, they do not
exercise a position of dominance in the relevant market. Moreover, the manufacturers’ have not
abused their position of dominance as they have not imposed discriminatory pricing, engaged in
exclusionary or exploitative abusive conduct or used their position in the market for spare parts
to leverage their position in the market for repair and maintenance services.
It is submitted that the BMA is a trade association that has acted as a representative of its
members. The BMA exercises buying power and hence, negotiated rates of services with the
ASPs. It is contended that the encouragement to recover the negotiated rate from the consumer
was recommendatory in nature and therefore, not binding. Hence, the price rise in the industry
may only be attributed to the use of the ASP and not the recovery of the negotiated rates.
Moreover, the resolution to exclusively avail of the services of the ASP is justifiable. It is
submitted that the association may engage in self-regulatory conduct to ensure quality standards
in the relevant sector. Hence, the BMA has not acted as a platform for cartelization.
W R I T T E N S U BM I SS I O N S
I. WHETHER THE ORDER OF THE RIVERDALE HIGH COURT DECLARING THE DIRECTOR
It is humbly submitted that as per Section 26(1) of the Competition Act, 2002, 1 the CCB has the
power to direct the Director General2 to investigate any matter where it finds a prima facie
infringement of the sections of the Act. In the instant case, the CCB passed an order under
Section 26(1) of the Act, directing the DG to investigate into a violation of Section 3(4). The DG,
along with a violation of Section 3(4) also reported a violation of Section 4 of the Act. It is
contended that the High Court’s order declaring the investigation and the subsequent CCB order
void3 is correct in law. This contention is sought to be substantiated on the grounds of, a) the
DG’s power to investigate being limited to the directions he receives from the CCB and b) the
violation of principles of natural justice in allowing the DG to expand the scope of his
investigation.
1.1.1. It is submitted that according to Section 26(1) of the Act, the CCB alone is given the
power to decide whether certain information amounts to prima facie infringement of the
2 Hereinafter DG.
3 Proposition ¶ 10.
provisions of the act and may accordingly direct the DG to investigate or may reject such
information. The DG only has the limited power to investigate on the basis of such
interpretation of the provision of the statute itself and b) determination of the intention of
the legislature.
1.1.2. It is humbly submitted that when a statutory provision is unambiguous and if from the
words, the intention of the legislature can be gathered, the Court must use the literal rule
of interpretation. 4 There is a presumption that words are used in an Act of the Parliament
correctly and exactly and not loosely and inexactly.5It is therefore clear that a plain
reading of the Section 26 yields that the direction from the Commission is a prerequisite
for the DG to conduct investigation. Further, the Act has not restricted the kind of
direction that may be given by the Commission. Hence, if the direction is issued in
regards to a violation of one section, only that violation must be investigated and
reported. Moreover, it has been held that since Regulation 20(4) of the CCB (General)
Regulations, 20096 requires the DG to report his findings on each of the allegations made
the instant case, Mr. Sodhi only alleged a violation Section 3(4) of the Act. Therefore, the
4 M/s. Hiralal Ratanlal v. STO, AIR 1973 SC 1034; Institute of Chartered Accountants of India
v. Price Waterhouse, AIR 1998 SC 74.
5 Prevention and Control of Water Pollution v. Andhra Pradesh Rayons Ltd., AIR 1989 SC 611.
1.1.3. It is humbly submitted that when the provisions of a statute requires an act to be done in a
particular manner, such an act can be done only in the prescribed manner and not
contravention of the provisions of the Act, is sine qua non,8 for an investigation by the
circumvented. It is an established legal principle that what cannot be done directly, cannot
be allowed to be done indirectly as that would be an evasion of the statute. 9 When the Act
has made it clear that a prima facie opinion is necessary, allowing the DG to investigate a
Section 4 violation when no prima facie opinion has been formed regarding its violation
1.1.4. It is humbly submitted that the word suo moto is ordinarily defined as ‘on its own
motion.’ In the instant case, it is contended that the act of the DG reporting in excess of
his direction is an act done suo moto and such suo moto exercise of power is not allowed
under the scheme of the Act. The Raghavan Committee report, 2000, provides that the
DG will have no suo moto powers of investigation. He is authorized to only look into the
complaints received from the Competition Commission of India (CCI) and submit his
10
findings to the Commission. It is further submitted that though MRTP Act, 1969
7 Grasim Industries Limited v. CCI, 2014 (206) DLT 42.
8 Id.
9MTNL v. Telecom Regulatory Authority Of Delhi, AIR 2000 Del. 208; District Collector,
Chittor & Ors v. Chittoor District Groundnut Traders, 1989 (2) SCC 58.
10 SVS Raghavan Committee, Report of High Level Committee on Competition Law & Policy
(2000) ¶ 2.8.
empowered the DG to exercise suo moto power of investigation, the said power has been
expressly denied to him under the Competition Act. This shift can be reasonably inferred
to be a deliberate act of the legislature carried out in order to limit the authority of the
DG. If the parliament wished to retain the wide scope of the power that was previously
granted, the pre-existing provision would have been retained. Thus, it is submitted that in
light of the unambiguous provision of law and its legislative intent, the DG has
1.2.1. It is humbly submitted that of Regulation 41(4) of the 2009 Regulations empowers the
DG to call for the parties to lead evidence by way of affidavit or oral evidence. The
quasi-judicial matters.11Where the CCI argued that the DG’s report for the contravention
was held to be in violation of the Act. 12 The Court discussed it in a detailed manner,
stating that “the scheme of the Act provides for hearing at multiple stages. The law
entitles the parties the opportunity to be heard by the before the DG as well as before the
mandatory and Commission can pass his order based under Section 27 on the basis of
11 A.K.Kripak v. Union of India, AIR 1970 SC 150; State of U.P. v. Neeraj Awasthi & Ors.,
(2006) 1 SCC 667.
the DG Report. In such a case if the party is deprived of adequate opportunity to defend
his case at the stage of DG investigations, he will not be able to lead evidence and to
cross-examine the witnesses of the opposite party, even before the Commission”. 13
Hence, in the instant case taking a stance contrary to that of the High Court would result
1.2.2. Therefore, it is contended that the DG acted in excess of his authority by reporting a
violation of Section 4.
II. WHETHER THE AGREEMENT BETWEEN THE MRI MANUFACTURERS AND THE SERVICE
It is humbly submitted that Section 3(1) of the Act provides that any agreement which causes or
is likely to cause appreciable adverse effect on competition 14 shall be void. Section 3(4) of the
Act provides that any agreement amongst persons or enterprises at different levels of the
production chain shall be in contravention of Section 3(1) if it causes or is likely to cause AAEC.
It is humbly submitted that the agreement between the MRI manufacturers and the authorised
service providers15has not and is not likely to cause AAEC. Therefore, it does not contravene
Section 3(1) of the Act. Further, the agreement in question has pro-competitive effects as
provided under Section 19(3) of the Act. Such pro-competitive effects are observed the form of
accrual of benefits to the consumer. This is established through a thorough analysis of the
13 Id.
14 Hereinafter AAEC.
15 Hereinafter ASP.
agreement as a whole and of the seemingly restrictive clauses contained in it. Therefore, it is
contended that the order of the COMPAT finding no violation 16 should be upheld and the
2.1. THAT THE AGREEMENT IN ITSELF IS NECESSARY AND HAS THE ABILITY TO PROMOTE
COMPETITION.
2.1.1. It is submitted that the manufacturers enter into agreements with select service providers
on the basis of certain criteria such as affiliation with quality standard agencies, technical
expertise and knowhow of employees, and financial strength of the entities. 17 In the case
of Menasha Corp. v. News America Marketing In-Store, Inc.,18 it was held that where
organizations in good faith have freely adopted their own equipment rules and then freely
entered into exclusive contracts with the respective suppliers, the resulting exclusive
contract does not violate the antitrust laws, even if the supplier has a high market share
and offers money for the exclusivity. It has been appropriately explained that the
competition to be an exclusive supplier may constitute “a vital form of rivalry, and often
the most powerful one, which the antitrust laws encourage rather than suppress.” 19 Since
the agreement entered into is based on qualitative assessment, the opportunity to become
16 Proposition ¶ 14(i)
17 Proposition ¶ 4.
18 Menasha Corp. v. News America Marketing In-Store, Inc., 354 F.3d 661 (7th Cir.2004).
19Paddock Publ'ng, Inc. v. Chicago Tribune Co., 103 F.3d 42 (7th Cir.1996).
2.1.2. Further, the terms and conditions are formulated in order to cater to the existing customer
base. Most of the hospitals providing MRI services pride themselves in providing the best
medical facilities to their patients.20 In order to retain their customer base, it becomes
imperative for the manufacturers to prioritize quality assurance. Thus, it is contended that
the agreement in question has been formulated based on such market considerations.
2.2. THAT THE CLAUSE STIPULATING PRIOR APPROVAL TO DEAL IN GOODS OF COMPETING
2.2.1. It is humbly submitted that the clause stipulating that the service providers require prior
exclusive supply agreement having pro-competitive effects. Further, it is not likely that
the said clause will have any adverse effect on competition that is not more than
2.2.2. It is humbly contended that the legitimacy of a vertical restraint has to be having due
business justifications for the legality of a contract has been recognized. 23 A balance has
to be drawn between risks of inefficiency and poor quality of service on one hand and the
20Proposition ¶ 6.
21Proposition ¶ 4, clause v.
22 D.P Mittal, Competition Law and Practice 409 (2nd edn., 2007).
23 Barr Labs, Inc. v. Abbott Labs, 978 F.2d 98, 111 (3d Cir.1992).
dealers’ autonomy on the other hand. Since the manufacturing market is oligopolistic,
each manufacturer needs to capitalize on economies of scale available to him. The dealers
carry the weight of protecting the manufacturers’ reputation, goodwill and thereby their
future market performance. The system of approval ensures that the quality of service
provided to the consumer is not compromised while ensuring that the manufacturer’s
2.2.3. Further, it is submitted that the indispensability test has been used to justify vertical
less efficient. If the application of what appears to be a commercially realistic and less
question is treated as indispensable.24 In the instant case, the MRI manufacturers have
entered into agreements with the service providers. Therefore, the manufacturers are
aware of the capacity of the service providers. A less restrictive alternative in the form of
laying out specifications to the ASP dilutes the purpose of the ESA. In such a set-up, the
manufacturers are less equipped to check compliance of the ASPs. Therefore, considering
the sensitive nature of the industry concerned, it is submitted that the customers are better
2.2.4. It is humbly submitted that in United States v. Colgate & Co.25, the Court held, “the
purpose of the Sherman Act is not to restrict the long recognized right of a trader or
freedom to choose customers, the circumstances and conditions to deal with; it also has
the right to refuse to supply its production in its business interest.27In the instant case, it is
contended that natural entry barriers inherent to the industry exist in the form of high
capital investment, R&D and reputation. An enterprise which overcomes these natural
barriers has the potential to compete effectively in the market. In the present case,
varied distribution formats such as Independent Service Providers, 28multi-brand ASPs and
the ISPs who may want to become ASPs ensures that no additional cost is accrued by
2.2.5. It is respectfully submitted that the manufacturers’ condition that an authorized dealer
would maintain a separate area within the showroom for the manufacturer’s parts and
employ separate trained personnel for its products is reasonable. It has further been held
26 Race Tires America, Inc. v. Hoosier Racing Tire Corp., 2011 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 48847.
27 Southern Pac. Communications Co. v. AT&T, 740 F.2d 980 (D.C.Cir. 1984).
28 Hereinafter ISP.
suppliers may require distributors to have suitable premises, adequately trained staff and
other service requirements in respect of complex consumer products and luxury products,
where such requirements are necessary to preserve quality of service around the products
and/or ensure their proper use. In the instant case, servicing an MRI machine requires
expertise. Further, since the parts of each brand of machine are not substitutable, 30
AREA OPERATES TO THE BENEFIT OF THE CONSUMER AND IT IS NOT LIKELY THAT ANTI-
2.3.1. It is submitted that the clause stipulating that the service provider shall be given a
geographical area of responsibility where the designated service provider would be the
2.3.2. It is respectfully submitted that within a given product market each distribution system is
competing with every other distribution system and all products in a given market are
competing for the purchasing dollar of the ultimate consumer. In the present case, the
manufacturers aim to provide the customers the alternative that is best for them.
Therefore, the distribution system should find the optimum balance between competitive
competitive pricing continues to exist due to the presence of the ISPs. In order to retain
customer loyalty post the warranty period, the ASP will not charge monopolistic prices.
They restrain the ASPs from engaging in monopolistic pricing. Further, to ensure quality,
an incentive in the form of geographical allocation has been provided. Such incentives are
system would be to the detriment of the customer and shift the focus away from quality.
The service provider would have to engage in cost savings in order to provide services at
a discounted rate. Such savings may compromise the quality of the services that the
2.3.3. It is submitted the benefits of territorial restrictions are widely recognised. Where dealers
are required to make heavy investments in stocking spare parts and in the maintenance of
after sale service stations, it has been held that territorial restrictions did not hinder
competition but promoted it.33 Various justifications for selective and exclusive
distribution in the supply of new cars have been brought forward. The European Court of
Justice discussed these in the Cabour case.34 The main reason is to allow manufacturers to
continue to influence the quality of their product by offering a high standard of service to
the consumer.35 The Commission itself used consumer protection as a justification for the
restrictions allowed in the block exemption. Citing the nature of the product concerned, it
33 Id.
34 Carbour SA et Nord Distribution Automobile, SA v. Arnor SOCO SARL, [1998] ECR I-2055.
were indispensable in order to allow some rationalization and as a result better vehicle
36
distribution and servicing. It is humbly submitted that such an explanation may be
extended to the present case considering the complex nature of the MRI machine and the
utmost necessity in ensuring its superior quality. Therefore, it is contended that the
ANTICOMPETITIVE.
2.4.1. It is submitted that the clause stipulating that the service provider should comply with the
recommended minimum price of the spare parts, as set and revised by the manufacturer
and while the service provider is free to sell at prices below the recommended minimum
price, doing so would make the service provider ineligible for the discount 37 is necessary
and procompetitive. Further, the clause is not likely to have an adverse effect on
competition.
2.4.2. It is humbly submitted that a practice, which strikes the balance between incentivizing the
dealer and promoting consumer welfare, must be adopted. In the instant case, the standard
of service that is expected from an ASP involves substantial investment on their part. The
service provider must maintain a stock of the manufacturer’s spare parts for the MRI
with the manufacturer.38 Moreover, in case that they are recognised as being capable of
being a multi-brand retail, the ASP would maintain a separate area within the showroom
for the manufacturer’s parts and employ separate trained personnel for its products at its
own cost.39 The manufacturers therefore recommend a minimum resale price providing a
fifteen percent rebate if the said price is conformed to. 40 These is done to ensure that the
dealers make the best possible effort in ensuring quality to their consumers and are
2.4.3. Further, from a consumer welfare perspective, measuring the impact of a minimum resale
price alone tells us little about the competitive effects of the same. 41 In the instant case, it
is observed that the pricing format has been successful, and the consumers are satisfied
with the services being provided by the ASPs. A general perception that the authorized
service providers are more reliable and provide better services than independent service
providers has emerged.42 This is an indicator of consumer satisfaction and the pro-
38 Proposition ¶ 4.
41Joshua D. Wright, The Economics of Resale Price Maintenance & Implications for
Competition Law and Policy (2014) available at
http://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/public_statements/302501/140409rpm.pdf[last
accessed on 2 March 2015].
42 Proposition ¶ 6.
2.4.4. It is humbly asseverated that the minimum price that the manufacturers set and revise is
inherently competitive and therefore does not result in double marginalisation. A "double"
markup results from the fact that each firm takes its pricing decision independently,
without taking into consideration the impact of its decision on its partner in the vertical
structure. As a result, the price is likely to be too high. 43 In the instant case, such an
eventuality would not arise due to two reasons (a) the accounting of lifecycle prices by
2.4.5. It is humbly submitted that courts have interpreted the finding in the Kodak44 case with
the seller's policy was not generally known.45 In Lee v. Life Ins. Co. of North America, 46 it
has been held that the Court did not doubt in Kodak that if spare parts had been bundled
with Kodak's copiers from the outset, or Kodak had informed customers about its policies
before they bought its machines, purchasers could have shopped around for competitive
life-cycle prices. The material dispute that called for a trial was whether the change in
policy enabled Kodak to extract supra-competitive prices from customers who had
already purchased its machines. The timing of the ‘lock in’ at issue in Kodak was central
47
to the Supreme Court's decision. In the instant case the MRI manufacturers have made
44 Eastman Kodak Company v. Image Technical Services, Inc., 504 U.S. 451 (1992).
45 Digital Equip. Corp. v. Uniq Digital Techs.. Inc., 73 F.3d 756, 763 (7th Cir.1996).
46 Lee v. Life Ins. Co. of North America, 130 L.Ed.2d 340 (1994).
their policy regarding service providers clear from the start. 48 Since this information was
previously available to the consumers, it is only reasonable to assume that they would
have made a life cycle cost analysis. Since this is an occurrence in the market, the
following argument must be accepted- “The quality and price of post-sale service are
critical to the competitiveness of each firm’s computer systems. No firm has the power or
incentive to take advantage of its current system users by lowering the quality or raising
the price of such service. Any firm attempting to do so would quickly lose future system
2.4.6. It is humbly contended that the minimum resale price that is set and revised is subject to
market forces. Countervailing power by definition implies the ability to exert influence
on suppliers.50 In the case of Shailesh Kumar v. M/S Tata Chemicals Limited & Ors 51 it
was noted that the suppliers could not engage in exploitative behaviour as there were a
large number of customers having bargaining strength vis-à-vis the sellers due to their
size, commercial importance to the seller and ability to switch to alternative suppliers. In
the instant factual matrix, it is found that 90% of hospitals/clinics that provide MRI
47 Psi Repair Services, Inc., v. Honeywell, Inc., 104 F.3d 811 (6th Cir.1997).
48 Proposition ¶ 3
49 Prime’s Brief for Judgment N.O.V., E.D. Mich., Case 89-CV-71762, 29 November 1990, at
p.7
50In Re: Suo-moto case against LPG cylinder manufacturers, Case No. 03 of 201, decided on
February 24, 2012.
51Shailesh Kumar v. M/S Tata Chemicals Limited & Ors , Case 66/2011 decided on April 16,
2013.
services are a part of the Bohemian Medical Association (BMA). 52 The BMA has
negotiated a rate on behalf of the all the hospitals. Further, it is noticed that individual
53
hospitals may negotiate greater discounts. The ASPs are commercially dependent on
these hospitals. Alternative forms of distribution such as the ISPs and the numerous mom
and pop shops continue to exist in the market. Thus, the ASPs cannot afford to price their
because it may affect changes in the market conditions,54 where the change would be in
mitigation of recognized evils and would not impair, but rather foster fair competitive
opportunities.55 The question is one of intent and effect, not to be determined by arbitrary
assumptions, but by close scrutiny of the particular conditions and purpose of each case. 56
In the instant case, the market being dealt with falls under the umbrella of health sector.
the primary requirement. For such reliability to be acquired, the highest possible quality
standard must be assured. It is contended that the manufacturing market and aftermarket
53 Proposition ¶ 5.
55 Id.
56 Id.
are interlinked. The business strategy of the upstream market is bound to influence the
changes. The introduction of this new system has only intensified existing competition.
The emergence of an additional distribution format has created competition among the
service providers to be a part of that format and those outside the format to ensure that
they remain competitive. The ISPs losing out on buyer loyalty may not be attributed to
the acts of the MRI manufacturers. Therefore, a decline in Mr. Sodhi’s business or an
increase in the market share of the ASPs cannot be taken to be indicative of the anti-
2.6. THAT THE COMPAT’S DECISION HOLDING THAT THE AGREEMENT WAS NOT ANTI-
2.6.1. The COMPAT held that the agreement was not anti- competitive stating that nature of the
terms and conditions resulted in “fewer repairs because of the increased longevity of
57
components and longer intervals between services. It is submitted that assessment of
vertical agreements must be made through a rule of reason analysis. The true test of
legality is whether the restraint imposed is such that it merely regulates or promotes
three factors to be considered in this regard,59 a)facts that is peculiar to the business to
which the restraint is applied, b) what was the condition before and after the restraint is
57 Proposition ¶ 14.
imposed and iii)what is the nature of the restraint and what is its actual and probable
effect.”60
2.6.2. It is humbly contended that this approach has been adhered to while establishing the anti-
competitive nature of the agreement. Therefore, it is seen that the pro-competitive effect
generated by the agreement outweighs any possible anti-competitive effect that it may
create.
In the present matter, it has been alleged that the manufacturers’ exercise a position of dominance
in the relevant market of spare parts and have abused their position of dominance in
In order to inquire into the issues of dominance and abuse under the provisions of the Act, it is
necessary to, (a) determine the relevant market under Section 2(r) of the Act, (b) assess
dominance in the relevant market under Section 4(a) of the Act, and (b) establish abuse of
3.1. THAT THE RELEVANT MARKET EXTENDS TO THE SPARE PARTS OF ALL
PROVIDERS.
61 Proposition ¶ 16.
It is humbly submitted that Section 2(r) of the Act defines “relevant market” as “the
market which may be determined by the Commission with reference to the relevant
product market,” Further Section 2(t) of the Act defines “relevant product market” as “a
market comprising all those products or services which are regarded as interchangeable
3.1.1. It is humbly submitted that the relevant market must be identified according to the
particular facts of the case at hand.62 The relevant market in the present matter is
determined by the choice of spare parts and repair and maintenance service made
available to the (i) potential customers of the manufacturers’ and (ii) existing customers
of the manufacturers’. In the instant case, the manufacturers’ require owners of the MRI
machines to use genuine spare parts when replacing parts of the MRI machine and avail
the services of ASPs during the warranty period.63 In the event these terms and conditions
are not met the owners would stand in breach of a warranty 64 which extends to a period of
three years.65
3.1.2. It is submitted that the CCI has applied the hypothetical monopoly test to determine the
scope of the relevant product market.66 The hypothetical monopoly test is an economic
62 Aberdeen Journals Ltd. v. Director General of Fair Trading, (No.1) [2002] CAT 4.
63 Proposition ¶ 3.
64 Id.
65 Id.
66 Surinder Singh Barmi v. Board for Control of Cricket in India, Case No. 61 of 2010.
number of consumers to switch to another product.67 The important factor is whether the
consumers are likely to switch, the product they switch to comprises the relevant market.
3.1.3. In the present matter, assuming that each manufacturer is a monopolist in the market for
spare parts it needs to be proven that an increase in the price of the spare parts and repair
and service maintenance would (a) reduce demand for the MRI machines, or (b) provoke
customers to switch from the use of genuine spare parts and services provided by the
ASPs, hence, preventing the manufacturers’ from profitably sustaining prices above
competitive levels.
3.1.4. It is humbly contended that in the event that the price for the spare parts and repair and
maintenance services is increased above the competitive level, the demand for the MRI
machines shall be affected. This is because potential owners of the MRI machines shall
engage in whole life costing. Whole life costing means that customers view the purchase
of the primary and secondary product as a unified deal. 69 It is reasonably inferred that
67 United Kingdom Office of Fair Trading, Market Definition: Understanding Competition Law,
(2004),available at
https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/284423/oft403.pdf
(last accessed on 14th March, 2015).
68 Id.
69 Supra note 7.
since the machine is a durable good the potential customers will anticipate the cost of
necessary future purchases when buying the MRI machine. Further, it is contended that a
manufacturer will not wish to facilitate an increase in prices of its spare parts and repair
and maintenance services if doing so would earn it a reputation for exploitation and
3.1.5. It is humbly contended that in the event that the price for the spare parts and repair and
maintenance services is increased above the competitive level, the owners whose
warranty periods have expired are free to purchase non-genuine spare parts and avail the
service of ISPs. They are not constraint by the terms and conditions of the
manufacturers’. Hence, a rise in price would provoke these customers to switch from the
use of genuine spare parts and availing the services of the authorized service providers.
For the owners whose warranty periods have not expired, a rise in price would not only
cause them to purchase genuine spare parts from ISPs70 but impair the ASPs ability to
3.1.6. Moreover, it is submitted that competitive conditions may change over time. Policy
changes may make substitution between products easier and so change the market
definition.71 In the present matter, upon the expiration of the warranty period the MRI
machine owners are under no obligation to avail the services of the ASPs or purchase
genuine spare parts. Hence, it is submitted that in accordance with the hypothetical
70 Proposition ¶ 8.
monopolist test, the relevant market extends to non-genuine spare parts and the services
3.1.7. Therefore, there are two separate relevant markets that have been identified in the present
matter; (a) the ‘primary market’ comprising the manufacturing and sale of MRI
machines; and (b) the ‘aftermarket’ comprising the spare parts and after sale repair and
purchased after another product i.e. the primary product which they relate to.72
3.2. THAT THE MANUFACTURERS’ DID NOT EXERCISE A POSITION OF DOMINANCE IN THE
RELEVANT MARKET.
3.2.1. It is submitted that Section 4 of the Act defines “dominant position” as, “a position of
strength, enjoyed by an enterprise, in the relevant market, in India, which enables it to:
(i) operate independently of competitive forces prevailing in the relevant market; or (ii)
3.2.2. In the present matter, the relevant market for spare parts comprises parts manufactured by
not the only source of spare parts in the aftermarket. Hence, each manufacturer possesses
limited market share and is unable to operate independently in the aftermarket of spare
parts.
72 Shri Shamsher Kataria v. Honda Siel Cars India Ltd. & Ors., 2014 Comp LR001 (CCI).
Moreover, the ASPs’ are unable to operate independently in the relevant aftermarket of
services. This is so because (i) the ISPs’ offer competitive pricing 73, (ii) the ASPs’ are
constrained by their need to retain customers in their post warranty periods and (ii) the
3.2.3. It is humbly contended that each manufacturer would be unable to affect its competitors
in its favor as the ISPs’ offer competitive pricing. Further, they are constrained by the
need to retain customers in their post warranty periods. Therefore, it is submitted that the
manufacturers’ are not the dominant enterprises in the relevant aftermarket for spare
parts.
3.3. THAT THE MANUFACTURERS’ DID NOT ABUSE THEIR POSITION OF DOMINANCE.
It is humbly submitted that without prejudice to the above contentions, Section 4 of the
Act prescribes types of conduct that will be considered abusive if carried out by a
dominant enterprise. In the instant case, it is contended that the manufacturers’ conduct
was not in violation of (i) Section 4(2)(a), (ii) Section 4(2)(c), and, (iii) Section 4(2)(e) of
the Act.
3.3.1. It is submitted that Section 4(2) (a) of the Act prohibits (a) unfair or discriminatory
conditions in sale of goods or service and, (b) unfair or discriminatory price in sale of
goods or service. The explanation for Section 4(2) (a) states that any discriminatory or
unfair pricing or condition imposed “shall not include such discriminatory condition or
73 Proposition ¶ 6.
74 Proposition ¶ 4.
(i) In the present matter, the manufacturers’ entered into agreements with service
entered into on the basis of qualitative criteria such as, technical expertise and
easier and (b) allowing for reduction of transaction costs, because the parties need
(ii) It is contended that prices charged by the manufacturers’ are not discriminatory as
they are imposed to prevent free riding. Free riding takes place “when one
benefits at no cost from what another has paid for.” 78 In the present matter,
genuine spare parts are made available in the relevant market via two separate
distribution channels.79 The ISPs’ may free ride on the goodwill of the
manufacturers’ by offering the spare parts at costs lower than the ASPs’. They
may further free ride on the presale service investments of ASPs’ and then using
75 Proposition ¶ 4.
76 Proposition ¶ 4.
77C. Edward Fee & Shawn Thomas, Sources of Gains in Horizontal Mergers: Evidence from
Customer, Supplier, and Rival Firms, 74 J. FIN. ECON. 423, 424-27 (2004).
78 Chi. Prof’l Sports Ltd. P'ship v. NBA, 961 F.2d 667, 674 (7th Cir. 1992).
savings to lure customers away through lower prices. Since these costs may be
captured in the price,80 spare parts are being offered at alternative prices to protect
the interests of the ASPs’. Further, it is submitted that the Commission has held
that in the absence of cost data “it is neigh impossible to term pricing as being
excessive”81. Therefore, a case of excessive pricing cannot be made out against the
manufacturers’.
3.3.2. It is contended that the manufacturers’ cannot be held liable under Section 4(2)(c), that is
denial of market access, under the Act. Denial of market access is any conduct by which
a dominant enterprise forecloses the market or defers entry of new players in the market
3.3.3. The US case of Dentsply83 has held that there should always be scope for a rival to access
the market on a scale sufficient to be a viable competitor. In the instant case, the
manufacturers’ offered ISPs’ with the opportunity to become ASPs’ 84 and further made
3.3.4. In the case of Snapdeal85 the CCI observed that distributed circulars only clarified that the
warranty services offered by the manufacturer were limited to those products brought
80 Toys ‘R’ Us, Inc. v. Federal Trade Commission, 221 F.3d 928 (7th Cir. 2000).
82 Sh. Dhanraj Pillay & Ors. v. M/S Hockey India, Case No. 73 of 2011.
83 United States v. Dentsply International, Inc., 399 F.3d 181 (3rd Cir. 2005).
84 Proposition ¶ 8.
from its authorised distributors, genuine spare parts and services of the same. The CCI
further stated that “the conduct of SanDisk in issuing such circular can only be
maintenance be carried on by an authorized dealer during the warranty period does not
amount to a tie up as it ensures that that the installation of the after-product does not
3.3.5. It is submitted that the notices issued only informed the member hospitals of the policy
the manufacturers’ followed. In a quality-driven market, brand image and goodwill are
important concerns and it is only prudent business policy that sale of products emanating
from unauthorised sources are not encouraged. Hence, any insistence that hospitals avail
3.3.5.1. It has been held that if a consumer declines to purchase anything from a customer,
it would not affect the market and could not be treated as causing denial of market
access.87 In the present matter, the BMA has resolved to avail the services of the ASPs’ on
its’ own accord. The ISPs’ are required to show that all other non-member hospitals were
discouraged from buying from the ISPs’.88 Therefore, the manufacturers’ cannot be held
86 Id.
87Manappuram Jewellers Pvt. Ltd. v. Kerala Gold & Silver Dealers Association, Case No. 13 of
2011, Decided on, 23.04.2012.
88 Id.
3.3.6. It is submitted that the manufacturers’ did not leverage their market power to protect or
enter into the aftermarket for services. In the case of Lee v. Life Ins. Co. of North
America89 specifies that the timing of the alleged ‘lock in’ was at issue. It was held that if
customers are aware that the manufacturers’ implement allegedly restrictive parts-
servicing policy, the manufacturers’ ‘market power,’ i.e., its leverage to induce customers
to buy spare parts is curtailed. Hence, the manufacturers’ were not in a position to use
their dominant position in the market for spare parts to protect the market for repair and
maintenance services.
Therefore, it is submitted that the manufacturers’ did not exercise a position of dominance
in the relevant market and therefore did not abuse this position of dominance under
CARTELIZATION?
In the present matter, the BMA, an association comprising 90% of the hospitals in Bohemia, has
resolved to avail the services of ASPs. This resolution has been adopted after hospitals were
made aware the manufacturers’ policy requiring them to avail the services of the ASPs’. Further,
the BMA has negotiated rates with the ASPs on which the hospitals may negotiate greater
discounts. It has been alleged that the BMA acted as a platform for cartelization wherein the
4.1.1. It is submitted that trade associations seek to promote, represent and protect the interests
of their members on legislation, regulations, taxation and policy matters likely to affect
them.90 Further, OFT guidelines prescribe that trade associations may provide advice of
commercial nature.91 In the present matter, the BMA (i) negotiated rates with the ASP’s
on which the hospitals could avail further discounts, 92 and (ii) encouraged the hospitals to
4.1.2. It is submitted that the BMA was acting in its capacity as a representative of its members
when it negotiated rates for the repair and maintenance services. In the instant case, the
BMA exercises buying power which enabled it to negotiate discounts on behalf of its
members. This buying power is exercised for reason of the BMA being the largest
medical association in the country.94 Moreover, its individual members exercise buying
power for reason of market allocation of the ASP.95 Hence, the BMA acted within its
91Competition and Market Authority, Guidance on Trade Associations, professions and self-
regulating bodies, available at https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/trade-associations-
and-professionalself-regulating-bodies-and-competition-law,[ last accessed on 7th March, 2015].
92 Proposition ¶ 5.
93 Id.
95 Proposition ¶ 4.
4.1.3. It is submitted that the latter half of the BMA’s resolution makes use of the phrase
in the literal sense of the word.97 Therefore, the latter half of the resolution is not binding
on the member hospitals and can be categorized as being advice of a commercial nature.
Further, it has been held that a cartel is capable of monitoring the behaviour and conduct
of the members of the cartel.98 In the present matter, there is no mechanism in place for
Moreover, it has been held that there is always a punishment mechanism in place for
those members of a cartel who do not follow the cartel mandate. 99 In this case, there is no
punishing mechanism, that is, threat of expulsion in the event that the members do not
4.1.4. Furthermore, it is contended that the negotiated rate was to act as a cap for the hospitals.
A reasonable range has been laid out for the member hospitals by the BMA within which
96 Proposition ¶ 5.
97 Supra note 4.
98 Shri Jyoti Swaroop Arora v. M/S Tulip Infratech Ltd. & Ors., Case No. 59 of 2011.
99 FICCI - Multiplex Association of India v. United Producers/ Distributors Forum, Case No. 01
of 2009.
4.2.1. In the alternative that a price fixing agreement is made out it is contended that a
maximum price fixing agreement cannot be held to be illegal per se. It is asseverated that
4.2.2. It is submitted that in order to determine whether an agreement can raise prices it needs to
be determined whether the agreement enables the seller to charge more than he could
obtain without the agreement. In the present matter, the answer is in the negative. The
BMA sets a cap on the price that the ASP may charge. This cap is in itself a negotiated
rate. It is contended that in the absence of the agreement the starting point for
negotiations of each member would have been higher, inducing them to charge the
consumer a higher rate. Further, any argument that the maximum price becomes the
minimum price does not hold good as the ASPs are constrained by their need to retain
4.2.3. Secondly, it needs to be determined whether the price of participants in the maximum
price arrangement is higher than the price of non-members.100 In the instant case, the
uniform increase in the pricing of the services is a consequence of the increase in input
costs of the hospitals and not the recommended price range. The same is inferable
because the recommended price range does not factor into the pricing consideration of
non-member hospitals. In the Maricopa101 case these inquiries indicated that a maximum
price arrangement did not amount to a cartel in disguise. Hence, it is submitted that the
101 Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Society, 457 U.S. 332 (1982).
resolution is not a price fixing agreement and that the BMA is not acting as a platform for
cartelization.
4.3. THAT THE RESOLUTION TO EXCLUSIVELY AVAIL THE SERVICES OF THE ASP IS
JUSTIFIABLE.
4.3.1. It is contended that in complex markets, such as the healthcare sector, consumers benefit
from the setting of a product or service standards that assure them of at least minimum
safety standards based on the, “merits of objective expert judgment” the private standards
4.3.2. In the present matter, the BMA has resolved to avail of the services of the ASPs as a self-
regulatory measure. This resolution to exclusively avail the services of the ASPs is
justifiable based on three arguments, (i) that there exists an asymmetry of information
between hospitals and their customer; (ii) considerations relating to the quality of care
that have an impact not only on the hospitals but also on the final consumer, and (iii) the
4.3.3. Moreover, with regards to the allegation of cartelization, there is a lack of anticompetitive
purpose, that is, (i) the lack of competition between the ASPs’ and BMA, and (ii) that the
4.3.4. It is submitted that the strongest inference of anti-competitive purpose is when all or
substantially all the consumers are in direct competition with the service provider and
102 Allied Tube & Conduit Corporation v. Indian Head, Inc., 486 U.S. 492.
stand to benefit from the restraint on its output. 103 It has been held that when an
association does not avail of low cost services, despite none of the members having a
financial interest in the production of the service, anticompetitive purpose is absent. 104 In
the instant case, the member hospitals do not have any vested interest in the provision of
services. In fact, the challenged resolution is more likely a praiseworthy effort at self-
regulation than a device for facilitating supra-competitive pricing. 105 Even if the hospitals
seek to maximize profits they realize that a practice likely to bring their service into
disrepute will depress profits in the long run. 106 Hence, there is a lack of anticompetitive
purpose.
4.3.5. It is submitted that further gains may be realized to the consumer when, (i) there is a
standard settings that helps ensure that consumers can compare prices rather than debate
on the quality of a product,107 (ii) deterrence of undesirable conduct that is not otherwise
unlawful in the form of the use of the ISPs and (iii) provision of a more prompt and
efficient means of industry oversight than government regulation. 108 Hence, the
104 Roofire Alarm Co. v. Royal Indemnity Co., 373 U.S. 949 (1963).
106 Id.
107 Eliason Corp. v. Natl. Sanitation Foundation, 449 U.S. 826 (1980).
108Robert Pitofsky, Self Regulation and Antitrust, Prepared Remarks before the 34 Annual
Symposium on Associations and Antitrust (Feb. 18, 1998).
4.3.6. Therefore, it is submitted that the BMA did not act as a platform for a price-fixing cartel
P R AY E R
I. HOLD THAT THE DIRECTOR GENERAL EXCEEDED THE SCOPE OF HIS AUTHORITY
II. HOLD THAT THE AGREEMENT BETWEEN THE MANUFACTURERS AND AUTHORISED
III. HOLD THAT THE MRI MANUFACTURERS HAVE NOT ABUSED THEIR DOMINANT
POSITION.
IV. HOLD THAT THE MANUFACTURERS AND BOHEMIAN MEDICAL ASSOCIATION ARE