From Peasant To Farmer
From Peasant To Farmer
From Peasant To Farmer
F R O M P E A S A N T T O FA R M E R : A S T U D Y O F
A G R A R IA N T R A N S F O R M A T IO N IN A N IR A N IA N
V IL L A G E , 1 9 6 7 – 2 0 0 2
Iranian agriculture and rural society have undergone profound socioeconomic and po-
litical changes over the past four decades. While recognizing the significant impact
of urbanization, economic development, and integration of the rural economy in the
market, this paper contends that the land-reform program of the 1960s and the 1979
revolution represent the primary turning points in the rural transformation. Land re-
form, through intense state intervention, dramatically changed the traditional landlord-
sharecropping system (nizam-i arbab-rayati).1 Peasant uprisings, the forcible occupation
of large estates, and the agrarian policies of the postrevolutionary regime have led to
the demise of the urban agricultural bourgeoisie and the empowerment of the peasants.
There has been a disintegration of large-scale public and private agricultural production
systems, including agribusinesses, farm corporations, and the agricultural production
cooperatives developed under the shah’s regime.2
This paper contextualizes these macrosocietal changes by tracing the patterns of
socioeconomic transformation of one village community over a thirty-five–year period,
providing a longitudinal study within the general conceptual framework of agrarian
transition theory. In its classical model, first outlined by Lenin, this theory postulates
that the penetration of capitalism into the countryside would result in the concentra-
tion of landholdings by rich peasants and absentee urban landlords, while poorer farm-
ers would be dispossessed and converted into a class of landless rural proletarian wage
laborers.3 An alternative model advanced by Y. Hayami and M. Kikuchi focuses on peas-
ant stratification, not inevitable polarization, where there is increasing differentiation in
a continuous spectrum ranging from landless laborers to noncultivating landlords.4 Yet
despite the debate on the agrarian transition theory and its applicability to rural transfor-
mation in developing countries,5 this conceptual framework provides a starting point to
identify the relevant issues, processes, and tendencies in village agrarian transformation.
Using a case study, I show that the structural changes in the pattern of land ownership,
coupled with the integration of the village economy into the market, will propel its
transition to capitalist agriculture and differentiation of its peasantry. Changes in the
system of agricultural production, diversification of occupational structure, and shifts in
Amir Ismail Ajami is Associate Director of International Programs, College of Agriculture and Life Sciences,
University of Arizona, Tucson, Ariz. 85721-0136, USA: e-mail: aajami@ag.arizona.edu.
social stratification are indicators of the village transition. This case study of agrarian
transformation in a local context provides empirical evidence, illuminating some of the
controversial aspects of agrarian transition theory, including the polarization paradigm.
As significant, this in-depth focus on one village is a reflection of the broader socio-
economic trends occurring in rural Iran over the past four decades. Despite the emer-
gence of a considerable body of literature on Iranian land reform and state policies on
agriculture since 1960s, there is little analysis of the impact of these policies on rural
transformation and the changing socioeconomic conditions of the Iranian peasantry.
The focus of this study is one village, Shishdangi (a pseudonym used for this set-
tlement). I first investigated Shishdangi in 19676 and restudied it in field work in 1999
and 2002. The village is located in Fars Province near the town of Marvdasht, about
45 kilometers northwest of Shiraz. At the time of the 1967 study, the village had a
population of 784 individuals who lived in 140 households residing in 118 houses, all
entirely enclosed within a high earthen wall, or qalah. The villagers made their living
mostly through farming and raising livestock; only 13 percent of the heads of households
were employed in nonagricultural activities. Agricultural production depended heavily
on irrigation, the water being supplied by both the Sivand River and twenty-seven
irrigation pumps tapping groundwater. The cropping pattern, mainly wheat, barley, and
sugar beets, had changed little over the previous decades, except that the cultivation of
melons had increased considerably. The village arable lands consisted of approximately
1,215 hectares, more than 40 percent of which was laid fallow annually. All land in
1967 belonged to two absentee landowners who lived in Shiraz, each owning half of the
village.
After more than thirty years, I returned to study Shishdangi to examine how the village
had responded to the changing socioeconomic and political conditions over this period,
particularly since the 1979 revolution. As will be described in this paper, far-reaching
changes indeed have taken place over the past thirty years in the village’s socioeconomic
structure, especially in terms of land ownership, systems of agricultural production, and
stratification of the peasants. The regional setting of the village has also seen dramatic
changes in this period, particularly as a result of rapid urbanization. With the quadrupling
of the population of the regional center, Marvdasht, from 25,498 in 1966 to 103,030 in
1996,7 and the development of better transportation facilities, the village’s population
now has much more contact with that center, influencing economic diversification and
change in the village.
M ETHODOLOGY
TABLE 1 Population, land use, crop density, and outputs of crops: Shishdangi
(1967–2001)
% Change
1967 2001 1967–2001
crops: wheat, 400 kilograms; barley, 400 kilograms; corn, 900 kilograms; sugar beet, 600 kilograms; and
tomato, 1,000 kilograms per hectare.
Source: Field studies, 1967, 2002; 1996 Census: Sarshumari-yi umumi-yi nufus va-maskan shahristan-i
marvdasht, 1375 (Tehran: Markaz-i Amar-i Iran, 1997).
One principal reason for the selection of Shishdangi in 1967 for field research was
its plural agrarian structure. This included the coexistence of four different types of
agricultural-production systems in the village: (1) a peasant production system (nizam-i
dihqani); (2) pump-owner tenant farmers (nizam-i tulumbah kari); (3) a large private
capitalist farm (nizam-i sarmayi dari); and (4) the remnant of the landlord-sharecropping
system (nizam-i arbabi). The 1967 baseline study provides a set of socioeconomic
data on the village population, landownership, its four production systems, and social
stratification. In the initial phase of the restudy in 1999, information was gathered
on the village’s land ownership, irrigation, agricultural and livestock production, and
population characteristics. During summer 2002, a random sample of 39 households
was selected for interviews from a listing of the total 176 landowning households.
In addition, 39 landless households were randomly selected for interviews from a
listing of 143 such households. In total, seventy-eight interviews were conducted by the
author with the heads of the sample households. The information obtained from these
interviews, the key informants, and personal observations constitute the bulk of data
used in the restudy.
Between 1967 and 2001 major changes occurred in the village’s population, per capita
arable land, crop density, and agricultural productivity (Table 1). There was a substantial
decline in per capita arable land (by 47%), resulting from the combination of a high
population-growth rate and a slight decrease in the village’s arable land. Substantial
increases occurred in crop yields (wheat by 200%, barley by 156%, and sugar beet by
330 Amir Ismail Ajami
102%), which correspond to average annual growth rates of 3.2 percent, 2.8 percent,
and 2.1 percent, respectively. The changes in Shishdangi reflect corresponding trends
throughout Iran in the agricultural sector, as overall per capita arable land has declined by
an estimated 24 percent,9 and increased crop yields were reported of roughly 76 percent
for wheat, 63 percent for barley, and 42 percent for sugar beet over the 1961–93 period.10
In light of changes in the pattern of land ownership, three distinct periods can be
discerned in Shishdangi’s transformation: (1) the village under landlord domination;
(2) land reform, the rise of peasant proprietorship, and the development of capitalist
farming; and (3) revolution, the demise of capitalist farming, and the transformation of
the peasants. This paper will explore and analyze the dynamics and consequences of the
socioeconomic changes in the village agrarian transition under each of the three periods,
with a special focus on the postrevolutionary era.
T H E V IL L A G E U N D E R L A N D L O R D D O M IN AT IO N
There is little information on the historical development of Shishdangi for the period
under landlord domination, which roughly ended by the mid-1960s. In 1935, a sugar-
beet refinery was founded in Marvdasht, and as far as the villagers recall, the entire
village (Shish-dang)11 was owned by one large absentee landowner, who lived in Shiraz.
The land was leased out to a mustajir, an intermediary between the landowner and the
peasants in the management of crop production. The village land was divided into a
number of fields, each of which was worked cooperatively by a team (harasah) of some
four to six sharecroppers. These harasah, similar to what elsewhere has been called
a bunah, sahra, or bunku, function as a cooperative organization of farming whereby
peasants are organized in working teams, each cultivating the fields jointly under a
sarbunah on a crop-sharing basis with the landlord.12 The mustajir provided land, water,
and seed to each harasah while the peasants supplied labor and draft animals. The
cultivation of crops was limited to wheat, barley, and rice, the peasants receiving one-
third of the wheat and barley and one-half of the rice harvest as their annual share of the
crops. Shortly after the initiation of sugar-beet cultivation in the village, the landlord sold
the village to two landowners, each of whom bought one-half of the village land, along
with the water rights from the Sivand River. The new landowners, hereafter referred to
by the fictitious names Haj Arbab and Aqa Muhandis, also lived in Shiraz, and they
continued leasing the land to the peasants. They dominated the village’s agriculture and
controlled its administration because they appointed the village headman (kadkhuda).
The peasants were physically tied to the village, as well, since their homes in the qalah
were owned by the landowners. Furthermore, because cultivation rights (nasaq) were
tied to membership in the harasah, if a peasant left his harasah, he would also lose
his cultivation rights to the village farmland. The sharecroppers depended totally on the
landowners for their livelihood.
With the development of pump irrigation by the late 1950s, a new system of agricul-
tural production, locally known as tulumbah kari (pump-owner tenant farmer), emerged
in the village. Tulumbah kari involves the transfer of land-use rights (usufruct) from
the landowner to the peasant, who digs a well, installs water pumps to irrigate the
land, and provides other production inputs for the cultivation of the land. This system of
production spread very quickly in the village, and by 1967 some 340 hectares (28% of the
From Peasant to Farmer 331
total arable land) were cultivated by thirteen pump-owner tenant farmers. Furthermore,
another new agricultural system, capitalist farming, began to develop in the village in
the late 1950s when Aqa Muhandis’s eldest son took over the management of his family
estates from the mustajir. He proceeded to dig four wells and water-pump installations,
introduced tractors, and dismissed the sharecroppers. Consequently, some forty-eight
sharecroppers lost their cultivation rights to the capitalist farm and joined the ranks of
the wage laborers (khwushnishin), a lower socioeconomic status than the sharecropper
in the village’s social hierarchy.
Before these changes, Shishdangi’s social structure was nearly homogenous, largely
dominated by absentee land ownership and sharecropping arrangements. Most house-
holds were sharecroppers at the same level in the village’s social hierarchy and lacking
any appreciable internal socio-economic differentiation. The village exemplifies the
pre–land reform agrarian structure in Iran, characterized by (1) the predominance of
an absentee landlord–sharecropping system; (2) low capital investment in agriculture,
leading to low productivity and poverty of the peasants; and (3) a pattern of landlords’
domination over the social and economic institutions of the countryside.13
L A N D R E F O R M , T H E R IS E O F P E A S A N T P R O P R IE T O R S H IP, A N D
T H E D E V E L O P M E N T O F C A P ITA L IS T FA R M IN G
Iran launched a sweeping land reform in 1962, which was implemented in three phases
over a decade under the shah’s “White Revolution.” While the shah’s regime’s interest
in land reform is believed to have been primarily political14 —dismantling the power base
of the landowning class—the implementation of the reform contributed to a dramatic
decline in absentee land ownership and the sharecropping system, leading to a substantial
increase in peasant proprietorship.15 All together, as a result of land reform, some
6 million to 7 million hectares of agricultural land (between 52% and 62% of the total)
was transferred to the occupant sharecroppers and tenant farmers.16 However, not all rural
households benefited from the land reform. Due mainly to the scarcity of agricultural
land, some 35 percent of the households who did not hold cultivation rights (nasaq)
were mostly employed in agriculture as wage laborers (khwushnishins) and were not
included among the beneficiaries of the land-reform program.
In 1965, the half of the village that belonged to Haj Arbab was cultivated under
sharecropping arrangements, subject to land redistribution under the second phase of
the land-reform program. Consequently, one-third of this half, along with the water rights
from the Sivand River, were transferred to the thirty-four occupying sharecroppers—on
average, about 4.7 hectares each. The other half of the village (Aqa Muhandis’ farm),
which was worked by wage laborers, was exempt from redistribution.17 Implementation
of the land reform gave rise to the development of the peasant production system,18
the decline of absentee land ownership and sharecropping arrangements, and further
consolidation of capitalist farming in the village (Table 2).
The implementation of land reform reinforced the trends toward development of cap-
italist agriculture. Haj Arbab redistributed more than 30 percent of his estates in 1965,
discontinuing sharecropping arrangements and transforming his remaining land into
capitalist farming by investing in water-pump irrigation and farm mechanization, and by
hiring wage laborers and a farm supervisor. Aqa Muhandis further expanded his capitalist
332 Amir Ismail Ajami
TABLE 2 Number and size of holdings by production system: Shishdangi (before and
after land reform)
Before Land Reform: 1962 After Land Reform: 1967
— not applicable
Source: Data extracted from Ajami, Shishdangi, chapter 5, tables 1, 6, 10; chapter 6, tables 2, 4.
R E V O L U T IO N , T H E D E M IS E O F C A P ITA L IS T FA R M IN G , A N D
T R A N S F O R M AT IO N O F T H E P E A S A N T R Y
As the 1977–79 revolutionary upheavals gathered momentum in the urban centers, they
eventually reached the rural areas, leading to peasant radicalization and land seizure
in the countryside. Current scholarship suggests that the peasants’ participation in pre-
revolution antiregime demonstrations and political activities was by and large limited.29
However, villagers who commuted daily to city jobs and those who migrated and became
part of the urban subproletariat were often willing participants in the urban uprisings
as well as active agitators in the village.30 Therefore, what is apparent is that when
the power of the central government was weakened, the peasantry gradually joined the
protest movement, primarily for land takeovers.31 As an illustration of peasants’ delayed
participation, Morio Ono, who was in Kheirabad, a village in the Marvdasht region, in
November 1978, observed: “when I am in Kheirabad, I don’t feel the anti–Shah protest
or the intense anti-government unrest which I witness in the city.”32 However, some three
months later, an eyewitness report by his friend who visited the village in mid-January
1979 informed him that “in Kheirabad the villagers used to support the Shah, but recently
60 percent of them have changed their position to pro–[Ayatollah] Khomeini.”33
In the case of Shishdangi, interviews with the two landlords and the village’s key
informants suggest that peasants were mostly in the “wait-and-see” mode during the
revolutionary upheavals, except for a few activists who began agitating against the
Aqa Muhandis capitalist farm about three months before the collapse of the regime in
February 1979. In fact, peasants’ protests against the village’s two landlords occurred at
different times, depending largely on the nature of their past relations with the landlords.
Those who had been evicted by Aqa Muhandis in the early 1960s when he transformed
his estate into capitalist farming were the ones who began their uprising prior to the
revolution. In contrast, the peasant sharecroppers who were the beneficiaries of land
334 Amir Ismail Ajami
redistribution by Haj Arbab under the 1962 land-reform program did not join the land-
takeover movement until almost a year and a half later.
The earliest uprising was organized by two brothers whose father had been evicted
by Aqa Muhandis when the capitalist farm was developed. They mobilized the former
sharecroppers against the landowner by seizing the farm piece by piece. The peasants
first took over about 14 hectares of land, then they moved to stop the landlord’s delivery
of sugar beets to the Marvdasht processing plant. Their next move was to occupy another
130 hectares of the capitalist farm’s fallow land, which they collectively ploughed and
planted with sugar beets. Finally, immediately after the revolution, the peasants seized
the remaining fields, occupied the landlord’s five water pumps, and expelled his farm’s
supervisor from the village. They then subdivided the farm among themselves and
began working the fields by initially setting up the former harasah system. Despite the
landowner’s protest and frequent appeals to the local authorities, the peasants continued
farming the occupied fields without paying any rent or a share of the crops to the
landowner, except for the 1978–79 grain crops planted by the landowner. Almost a
year and a half after the revolution, the peasants who were the beneficiaries of the land
reform in the other half of the village began to agitate against Haj Arbab, the other
landowner. They began by disrupting his farming operations, including the irrigation
and fertilizing of the fields. Haj Arbab appealed to the Marvdasht governor’s office, local
gendarmes, and the Islamic Guards to prevent the peasants’ aggressions on his estate. He
argued that, since more than 30 percent of his estate had been distributed to the peasant
sharecroppers in 1965 under the land-reform program, the peasants had no legitimate
claim. His complaints were to no avail, however, and the peasants continued to disrupt
his farming activities. Finally, in January 1981 they took over his land, two water pumps,
a tractor, and other farm machinery.34 They subdivided the farm into six units and began
to work the fields under the customary harasah system. The landowner appealed to
the qadi-i shar in Marvdasht, requesting the eviction of the peasants. They refused to
evacuate the land but agreed to the qadi’s ruling, which stipulated the division of the
1980–81 crops between them and the landowner, as well as subsequent payments of
annual rent to the landowner. Yet peasants continued to pay annual rent for the occupied
land only until 1986, after which they refused to make any further rent payments.
The dispute over the occupied lands between different peasant groups and the two
landowners has passed through various phases since the 1979 revolution. First, in ad-
dressing the petition of the landless agricultural workers for a portion of the village farm-
land, the local members of the “Sevener Commission”35 (hayat-i haft nafarah) visited
Shishdangi in 1981. A decision was made by the commission to transfer 120 hectares
of the capitalist farm (Aqa Muhandis) to twenty-three farmworkers (5.2 hectares per
worker) and 30 hectares of the estate of the other landowner, Haj Arbab, to nine workers
(3.3 hectares per worker). Since the legal status of these lands was in dispute, no land
titles were issued; instead, the agricultural workers were granted temporary cultivation
rights.
In the meantime, both the peasants and the two landowners remained unwilling to settle
their disputes. The peasants hoped that the revolutionary government might eventually
transfer the ownership of the occupied lands to them, while the landowners expected to
gain the return of their estates through the courts. This climate of uncertainty drastically
changed in October 1986 when the Islamic Parliament approved a land-reform law
From Peasant to Farmer 335
whose primary purpose was to legalize the transfer of the occupied lands to the peasant
squatters.36 Following the passage of the law, newly emerging political pressures forced
the Sevener Commission, the landowners, and the squatters to seek a quick resolution
to the legal status of the occupied lands. Thus, in 1988 the owners of the capitalist farm,
Aqa Muhandis and his brother, agreed to transfer, free of charge, about 250 hectares
to the fifty-five peasant squatters. The peasants agreed to return the remaining
140 hectares—70 hectares each—to the two brothers. Based on this agreement, land
titles were accordingly issued to the landowners and the peasants. As for the legal status
of some 120 hectares that were temporarily transferred to twenty-three agricultural
workers in 1981, the two brothers also agreed to grant free ownership of the land to
them. It took the other landowner, Haj Arbab, until 1999 to resolve his dispute with the
peasants who had occupied his land, even though an appeals court had issued a verdict
in 1989 for eviction of the squatters from the land. The settlement finally reached
between the two parties involved a no-charge transfer of some 130 hectares out of Haj
Arbab’s total holding of 218 hectares to the forty-four peasant squatters. The remaining
88 hectares were to be returned by the peasants to the landowner, however, as the two
parties failed to agree on the specifics regarding which tract of village land was to be
returned to the landowner, the agreement still had not been implemented by summer
2002. Thus, the insecurity and disputes over landownership rights, coupled with intense
hostility between the landlords and the peasants following the revolution, have continued
to dominate economic life in Shishdangi to the present.37
The revolution’s impact38 is clearly evident in the present pattern of land ownership
in the village as contrasted to 1966-67 (Table 3). As the data indicate, absentee land
ownership has substantially declined, from a total of 59.1 percent of the village farm-
lands (41.2% capitalist farm plus 17.9% arbabi estate) in 1967 to 20.6 percent in 2001.
Parallelling this change is a significant increase in smallholdings, from 13 percent in
1967 to 33.2 percent of the cultivated land in 2001. Moreover, as some former small-
holders occupied additional land during the land-takeover movement, a new category of
landholders (medium farmers), who own 5–10 hectares, has emerged in the village. This
radical redistribution of land has, however, resulted in a 70 percent decline in the average
size of holdings, from 24.8 hectares in 1967 to 7.5 hectares in 2001. Even though it has
led to a notable decrease in the scale of landlessness among village households, from
64.4 percent of the total households in 1967 to 49 percent in 2001, the absolute number
of landless households has increased from 85 to 143 because of population growth. The
substantial rise in the absolute number of landless households reinforces the fact that
even radical land-redistribution measures under a revolutionary regime cannot by itself
resolve the issue of landlessness in the countryside where land scarcity is coupled with
a rapid population growth rate.
T H E D E M IS E O F C A P ITA L IS T FA R M IN G
The impact of revolutionary changes besides the peasants’ land seizures and land redis-
tribution includes the disintegration of capitalist farming in the village. As mentioned,
the two capitalist farms were seized and parceled out among former sharecroppers, farm-
workers, and its two landowners. In 1988, when Aqa Muhandis and his brother regained
a portion of their farm, they contracted their total 140 hectares to three local farmers,
336 Amir Ismail Ajami
Number of
Mean Size
Holdings Area of Holdings
of Holdings
Production System Total % Hectares % (hectares)
— not applicable
a Capitalist estates include the estates of two former owners of the capitalist farm, who currently own
70 hectares each, and a former tulumbah kar who owns and operates a highly capitalized 100 hectare farm.
b The decline in the village agricultural land from 1,215 hectares in 1967 to 1,113 hectares in 2001 is largely
the result of land sales to the city of Marvdasht for urban development and the expansion of the village
boundaries into farmlands.
Source: 1966–67 data from Ajami, Shishdangi, chapter 5, tables 1, 6, 10, 19, 20; 2000–2001 data from 2002
field study.
who were each to work the land for a three-year period. Farming operations during
the period consisted mainly of an annual cultivation of roughly 70 hectares of wheat
and 35 hectares of corn, while the remaining 35 hectares were left fallow. This simple
cropping pattern is in sharp contrast to the pre-revolution period, when this capitalist
farm was characterized as a highly diversified and productive agricultural enterprise. The
other large estate—that is, the remnant of the nizam-i arbabi, which was also developed
into capitalist farming by its owner, Haj Arbab, after the 1965 land redistribution—has
totally disintegrated and ceased to operate as an agricultural enterprise.
In 2002, continued land disputes, economic insecurity, and vacillating state agrarian
policies were cited by the three urban landowners, Haj Arbab, Aqa Muhandis, and
his brother, as primary reasons for their hesitation to commit capital investment and
management to what has remained of their estates since the revolution. This insecurity
of land tenure and government indecisiveness on the role of the private sector also are
often postulated in the literature as the main causes in the deterioration of private capital
formation in agriculture in post-revolutionary Iran.39
It seems clear that these socioeconomic changes have led to a dramatic interruption
in the village agrarian transition to capitalism, as is evident in a quadrupling of the
number of peasant smallholders, reinstatement of the sharecropping system by one of
From Peasant to Farmer 337
the former large landowners, and the fact that there was less investment in agriculture
by urban merchants and former large landowners. The local-level changes were strongly
reinforced by post-revolutionary political instability, social turmoil, and the new regime’s
antagonism toward large capitalist agricultural enterprises. Taken as a whole, the
Shishdangi evidence suggests that agrarian transition to capitalism can follow a number
of different paths, depending on the configuration of local-level conditions and on
external sociopolitical forces. As Benjamin White argues, “[T]here is no universal or
all-purpose ‘agrarian question’ awaiting investigation, nor is there any universal form of
‘agrarian differentiation’ (agrarian transition).”40
T R A N S F O R M AT IO N O F T H E P E A S A N T R Y
The increased access to land and water resources by a larger number of villagers coupled
with the impact of rapid urbanization in the Marvdasht region and further integration
of the village economy into the market (see later) have largely contributed to the ac-
celeration of the socioeconomic transformation of the peasants in Shishdangi. This is
mainly reflected in (1) changes in the agricultural production system; (2) diversification
of occupational structure; and (3) shifts in social stratification. Each transformation will
be discussed in detail.
TABLE 4 Mean size of holdings, output per hectare, crop density, hired labor, and
percent of output sold, by production system:a Shishdangi (pre- and post-revolution)
Output
Output per Hectare
Mean Hired Sold into
Number of Size of Sugar Labor the
Holdings Holdings Wheat Barley Beet Corn Tomato Crop (Man Market
Production System (Total) (hectares) (tons) (tons) (tons) (tons) (tons) Densityb Days) (%)
— not applicable
a Data are based on information gathered from sample households in both the 1967 and 2002 studies.
b Crop density: area under cultivation/arable land.
c Melon cultivation was a second cash crop, next to sugar beet, on pump-owner tenant farmers’ farms and the
market networks in the Marvdasht region, as mentioned earlier, has brought the village
more into the urban economy, which has contributed considerably to this transition.
Peasant agriculture has also changed with regard to animal husbandry. Most villagers
have moved to new housing outside the old confinement of the qalah, and so they have
largely given up the practice of raising a few sheep and goats. In 1967, each household
had an average of twenty head of sheep and goats and one cow, but by 2002, sheep raising
and milk production had been largely taken over by a few relatively specialized farmers.
A further indicator of peasant transformation is reflected in new patterns of household
consumption that have appeared gradually over the past thirty years, including the
adoption of new types of housing, clothes, food items, televisions, refrigerators, and
telephones.44
Considering the fundamental changes that have taken place in peasant production
and consumption patterns since 1967, it can be argued that the concept of a peasant
mode of production is no longer applicable to the village’s small landholders.45 With
this transformation in mind, the village households currently engaged in small-scale
From Peasant to Farmer 339
agriculture are more correctly referred to as farmers, not peasants or peasant farmers.
The emerging production system in Shishdangi is a shift from peasant labor–intensive
agriculture to mechanized commercial agriculture, and from large urban (absentee)
landlord capitalist farming to small and petty capitalist farmers.
A striking feature of the transformation in the mode of production is the emergence
of a small number of petty capitalist farmers in the village. The changes actually began
in the 1960s when a few pump-owner tenant farmers increased the number of fields
under sugar-beet cultivation and introduced melons into their cropping pattern. This
trend has continued, particularly since the early 1990s, when some farmers began to
diversify into milk production and increase tomato cultivation in their fields. The new
developments, which required increased investment and hiring wage labor, have resulted
in sharp distinctions between “ordinary” smallholders and the emerging petty capitalist
farmers.46 Reinhold Loeffler observed a similar development in Sisakht, a village in
the Boir Ahmad region, where the farmers installed drip irrigation in their vineyards
in 2002, drastically increasing their grape production and shipping to markets all over
Iran.47 Also, the farmers in Kheirabad, in the Marvdasht region, abolished their cooper-
ative arrangements for land and water use a year after the revolution and proceeded to
build chicken farms, dig wells, install irrigation pumps, and expand cash crops in their
fields.48
The question of how these patterns of emerging capitalist farmers may be typical
of rural Iran can be answered only in tentative terms because of the limited amount
of comparable field research. We can reasonably argue that conditions conducive to
the development of capitalist farmers are prevailing in most villages, especially those in
proximity to urban centers. This argument can be supported by the fact that the number of
rural entrepreneurs in agriculture—that is, capitalist farmers—increased by 255 percent
between the 1976 census and the 1996 census.49 Furthermore, the size of holdings of
about 50 percent of commercial farms enumerated in the 1993 Agricultural Census was
less than 50 hectares, which can be assumed to be operated mostly by local capitalist
farmers.50
The development of petty capitalist farming in Shishdangi is primarily associated
with two groups. The first consists mainly of a small number of relatively well-off
pump-owner tenant farmers who have extended their farming into the production of
high-value crops, primarily tomatoes. These farmers, whose tomato fields in 2000–2001
covered 2–5 hectares of their holdings, are referred to hereafter as “cultivators.” The
second group is made up of those farmers who have diversified into milk production,
holding some eight to thirty-three dairy cows; hereafter referred to as “cultivator/milk
producers.”51 A total of seventeen farmers (11.6 %) can be identified as petty capitalist
farmers—nine cultivators and eight cultivator/milk producers. The landholding size of
cultivators ranges from 10 to 25 hectares, while among the “cultivator/milk producers”
the landholding size is from 3 to 10 hectares.
Table 5 shows a sample of six petty capitalist farmers (three cultivators and three
cultivator/milk producers). The three cultivators had diversified their cropping pattern
by planting 4 to 4.7 hectares of tomatoes and sugar beets in 2000–2001. They used
Green Revolution technologies, widespread farm mechanization, and wage labor, and
sold nearly all of their output to the market in 2000–2001. The three farmers who have
diversified into dairy come from the ranks of small and medium farmers. Although
340 Amir Ismail Ajami
TABLE5 Size of holdings, area under cultivation of main crops, number of dairy cows,
number of hired laborers, capital costs and revenues in a sample of petty capitalist
farmers: Shishdangi (agricultural year 2000–2001)
Area under
Cultivation of Dairies
Main Crops Revenuesb
Mean Milk Hired Capital
Sample Size of Cash Number production Labor Costsa Total
Farmer Holding Grain Crops of Milk (kilograms/ (man (in millions (in millions Crops Dairyc
Number (hectares) (hectares) (hectares) Cows Cow/day) days) of rials) of rials) (%) (%)
— not applicable
a Capital costs exclude land and include investment in wells; water pumps; farm machinery; dairy herds;
construction of barns, silos, and milk parlors; milking machines; milk storage tanks; and trucks for milk
delivery.
b Revenues are calculated on the basis of average prices paid to farmers: wheat, 1,225 rials; corn, 900 rials;
feed corn, 130 rials; barley, 850 rials; sugar beets, 250 rials; tomatoes, 550 rials; and milk, 1,450 rials per
kilogram.
c Dairy revenues include milk production plus sales of calves and culls.
d The owner does not work on the farm, which is managed by a full-time hired farm supervisor.
corn and barley were used for animal feed, almost all of the wheat crop and milk
were sold to the market. The development of petty capitalist farming in Shishdangi
has been influenced mainly by increased access to landholdings, a growing demand for
commercial crops by agroindustries developed recently in the Marvdasht region, and
state policies of highly subsidized inputs and favorable guaranteed prices, especially for
milk.
This transformation has been reinforced by a rising number of land transactions in
the village. Since the early 1990s, approximately 33 landholders (22% of the total)
have sold all or part of their holdings, amounting to 156 hectares (12.8% of the total
arable land). About two-thirds of the land was sold to the city of Marvdasht to construct
housing, as well as to three small agricultural-processing plants. The remaining one-
third, approximately 55 hectares, has changed hands among the farmers.
This rise of petty capitalist farmers does not mean the agrarian transition to capitalist
agriculture accompanied by rural polarization—as postulated in the classical model—
has taken root in the village. Rather, it should be interpreted as revealing an emerging
tendency toward the development of farmer capitalism, which calls for further studies.
1967 2002
(in total village (in 33% sample of
population) population)
Main Occupational Categories Total % Total %
— not applicable
a Although most farm laborers were seasonally employed and often worked in off-farm jobs, mainly in
engaged in trade, petty entrepreneurial activities, moneylending, smuggling, service work, or other similar
activities.
c Artisan includes carpenters, masons, blacksmiths, tailors, and barbers.
the male population ten years or older engaged in agriculture has dramatically decreased,
from 86.8 percent in 1967 to 45.9 percent by 2002,52 while the share of the nonagri-
cultural occupations, especially in transportation, mechanics, and shughl-i azad (petty
trading, moneylending, and other similar activities) has sharply increased (Table 6). The
decline in agricultural occupation in Shishdangi is similar to the overall trend in rural
Iran, as the percentage of the population age 10 and older engaged in agriculture has
declined from 76.6 percent in 1956 to 49 percent in 1996.53 The reduction in agricultural
employment in Shishdangi has come about particularly as a result of a phenomenal
drop in the percentage of farm laborers, from 66.7 percent in 1967 to 7 percent of the
village labor force by 2002. This can be partly accounted for by the disintegration of
the two large capitalist farms, which together employed some twenty-four permanent
workers and a larger number of seasonally hired laborers before the 1979 revolution.
Moreover, the rise in family-operated small holdings, widespread use of farm machinery,
and increased access to urban jobs has contributed to this change. Similarly, Loeffler
notes that, even for prerevolutionary Iran, “the occupational structure of Sisakht has be-
come totally transformed. Whereas in 1966 virtually all Sisakhti gained their livelihood
exclusively from the land, already ten years later only 44 percent of households did
so any longer. Today the members of young generations are either students or have an
income from salaries, business, craft, or wage labor. . . . Agriculture, which now largely
342 Amir Ismail Ajami
TABLE 7 Mean annual household income, literacy rate, and mean household size by
socioeconomic status: Shishdangi (pre- and post-revolution)
Mean Annual
Household Income
in Constant 2001
Number of
Pricesa Mean
Households
(in thousands Literacy Household
Socioeconomic Status Total % of rials) Rateb % Size
Prerevolution: 1967
Peasant proprietor 34 25.8 6,156 35 6.2
Pump-owner tenant farmer 13 9.8 23,850 61 7.7
Khwashnishin: farm and nonfarm 80 60.6 4,824 27 5.2
laborers
Petty bourgeoisie 5 3.8 n.a. n.a. n.a.
Total 132 100.0 n.a 37 5.6
Postrevolution: 2001
Small farmer 87 29.8 14,800 70.6 5.1
Medium farmer 45 15.4 28,400 74.2 5.1
Petty capitalist farmerc 17 5.8 171,700 80 5.3
Farm and nonfarm laborer 99 33.9 12,000 80.6 4.7
Petty bourgeoisie 44 15.1 n.a. 79.4 4.8
Total 292 100.0 n.a. 73 4.9
Source: The pre-revolution data are from Ajami, Shishdangi, chapter 7, tables 1, 5; the post-revolution data
are based on the 2002 field study, Consumer Price Index, International Monetary Fund, International Financial
Statistics Database.
the sharp differences in literacy rates and mean household sizes that existed in 1967
between various social strata has almost totally disappeared. This trend reflects the
widespread diffusion of education and family planning across all socioeconomic classes
in Shishdangi over the past thirty-five years. However, the widening income-inequality
gap between rich and poor farmers, despite land redistribution and land takeovers by the
latter, cannot readily be explained. One possible reason for this growing disparity might
be that the adoption of Green Revolution technologies and better farm-management
skills are more predominant among the petty capitalist farmers than the small and
medium farmers.
C O N C L U S IO N
This study has examined a village transformation in Iran within the conceptual frame-
work of agrarian transition theory. It is postulated that structural changes in the pattern
of the landownership system, coupled with the integration of the village economy
into the market, would propel its transition to capitalist agriculture and differentiation
of its peasantry. We maintain that changes in the system of agricultural production,
diversification of occupational structure, and shifts in social stratification reflect this
transition. Three distinct periods are discerned in Shishdangi’s transition: (1) the village
under urban domination; (2) land reform and the rise of peasant proprietorship; and (3)
the post-revolutionary transformation. The data on the first two periods illustrate the
dynamics and implications of landlord domination and land redistribution, including the
dual development of the peasant production system and capitalist agriculture. They also
provide the context necessary for understanding the post-revolutionary transformation.
The evidence from this study shows significant differences in peasant responses to the
1978–79 revolutionary upheavals, as well as the persistence of hostility and disputes
over landownership between peasants and landlords.
The most significant changes during the post-revolutionary period have been the
transformation of the peasant, as perceived in its conventional sense, into a farmer,
including the emergence of a small but significant number of petty capitalist farmers.
These two interrelated changes have had far-reaching implications in the village’s so-
cioeconomic structure, which can be expected to contribute to the development of farmer
capitalism in the future. Peasant transformation was further manifested by a sharp decline
in the proportion of Shishdangi’s active population engaged in agriculture and, hence,
the substantial increase in the number of households whose primary source of income
depended on nonagricultural occupations and who worked outside the village. Finally,
changes culminated in relatively large-scale shifts in the village’s social stratification.
The substantial increase of small holders and the rise of medium farmers reflect the extent
of this shift. Also, the declining khwushnishin population, coupled with the increased
diversification in their occupations and higher literacy rates, is an indication of upward
mobility for the khwushnishins.
The disruptions and changes in Shishdangi support the notion that the agrarian transi-
tion to capitalist agriculture does not proceed through a unilinear evolutionary process, as
postulated in the classical model. Contradictory tendencies in the transition, particularly
the 1979–80 revolutionary turmoil, led to disruptions in the development of capitalist
agriculture. A sharp diversion from large-scale capitalist farming to mostly small and
From Peasant to Farmer 345
NOTES
Author’s note: Special thanks are due to Ahmad Behpoor for his valuable assistance in the field survey. I
thank Sohrab Behdad, Michael E. Bonine, Mohsen A Fardi, Roger Fox, Mansoor Moaddel, Vahid Nowshirvani,
Frank W. Young, and four anonymous referees for their constructive comments.
1 The current literature on Iran’s 1960s land reform is highly controversial. For a review of different
perspectives, see A. K. S. Lambton, The Persian Land Reform, 1962–1966 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1969);
Eric J. Hooglund, Land and Revolution in Iran, 1960–68 (Austin: University of Texas Press, 1982); Khosrow
Khosravi, Masalah-i dihqani va-masalah-i arzi dar Iran (The Peasant Question and Land Question in Iran)
(Tehran: Payvand, 1980); Afsaneh Najmabadi, Land Reform and Social Change in Iran (Salt Lake City:
University of Utah Press, 1987); Asghar Schirazi, Islamic Development Policy: The Agrarian Question in Iran
(Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner Publishers, 1993); Fatemeh E. Moghadam, From Land Reform to Revolution:
The Political Economy of Agricultural Development in Iran, 1962–1979 (London: Tauris Academic Studies,
1996); Mohammad G. Majd, Resistance to the Shah: Landowners and Ulama in Iran (Gainesville: University
Press of Florida, 2000); Hosein Azimi, “Tawzi-i zamin va-daramad dar astana-yi islahat-i arzi” (Distribution
346 Amir Ismail Ajami
of Land and Income on the Eve of Land Reform), in Masail-i arzi va-dihqani (The Agrarian and Peasant
Questions), Kitab-i Agah (Tehran: Muassisa-yi Intisharat-i Agah, 1982), 75–94; Ahmad Ashraf, “State and
Agrarian Relations before and after the Iranian Revolution, 1960–1990,” in Peasant and Politics in the
Modern Middle East, ed. Farhad Kazemi and John Waterbury (Miami: Florida International University Press,
1991), 277–311; and Ismail Ajami, “Islahat-i arzi va-tahavvul-i nizam-i zirai-yi Iran” (Land Reform and
Transformation of the Agricultural Production System in Iran), Majallah-i tahqiqat-i iqtisadi 8 (1972): 135–
51.
2 For discussions of some of the revolutionary changes, see, among others, Bank Markazi Iran (hereafter,
BMI), Barrisi-yi tahavvulat-i iqtisadi-yi kishvar bad az inqilab (A Survey of National Economic Changes after
the Revolution) (Tehran, n.d. [ca. 1984]), esp. 28–68; Ahmad Ashraf, “Dihqanan, zamin va inqilab” (Peasants,
Land and Revolution), in The Agrarian and Peasant Questions, 6–49; Adnan Mazarei, Jr., “The Iranian
Economy under the Islamic Republic: Institutional Change and Macroeconomic Performance (1979–1990),”
Cambridge Journal of Economics 20 (1996): 289–314; Schirazi, Islamic Development Policy; Sohrab Behdad,
“Winners and Losers of the Iranian Revolution: A Study in Income Distributions,” International Journal of
Middle East Studies 21 (1989): 327–58; Farhad Kazemi, Poverty and Revolution in Iran (New York: New
York University Press, 1980); Mansoor Moaddel, “Class Struggle in Post-Revolutionary Iran,” International
Journal of Middle East Studies 23 (1991): 317–43; Bahaal-din Najafi, Darbarah-i iqtisad-i kishavarzi-yi
Iran (On the Agricultural Economics of Iran) (Tehran: Shirkat-i Intisharat-i Ilmi va-Farhangi, 1997). For an
annotated bibliography on pre–post-revolutionary rural studies, see Mohamad J. S. Mazanderani, “Mururi
tahlili bar sayr-i tahqiqat-i rustai va-ashayiri dar Iran” (An Analytical Review of Rural and Tribal Studies in
Iran), Iqtisad-i kishavarzi va-tawsiah 6 (1994): 151–79.
3 V. Lenin, The Development of Capitalism in Russia, vol. 3 of Collected Works (London: Lawrence and
Wishart, 1960); idem, The Agrarian Question and the “Critics of Marx” (Moscow: Progress Publishers,
1976).
4 Y. Hayami and M. Kikuchi, Asian Village Economy at the Crossroads (Tokyo: Tokyo University Press,
1981), 60–65.
5 See, among others, Teodore Shanin, “Polarization and Cyclical Mobility: The Russian Debate on the
Differentiation of the Peasantry,” in Rural Development: Theories of Peasant Economy and Agrarian Change,
ed. John Hariss (London: Hutchinson University Library, 1982), 223–45; Robert M. Netting, Smallholders,
Householders: Farm Families and the Ecology of Intensive, Sustainable Agriculture (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford
University Press, 1993): 214–21; and David Goodman and Michael Redclift, From Peasant to Proletarian:
Capitalist Development and Agrarian Transition (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1982).
6 Ismail Ajami, Shishdangi: pazhuhishi dar zaminah-yi jamahshinasi-yi rustai (Shishdangi: A Study in
marvdasht, 1345 (1966 Census) (Tehran: MAI, 1969); idem, Sarshumari-yi Umumi-yi Nufus va maskan—
shahristan-i marvdasht, 1375 (1996 Census) (Tehran: MAI, 1997).
8 For studies that use similar methodologies, see, among others, Reinhold Loeffler, Islam in Practice:
Religious Beliefs in a Persian Village (Albany: State University of New York Press, 1988); Morio Ono,
Kheirabad Namah: bist-panj sal ba rustai yan-i Iran (Kheirabad Namah: Twenty-five Years with Iranian
Villagers), trans. Hashem Rajab-Zadeh (Tehran: Intisharat-i Danishgah-i Tehran, 1998); and Hosein Mahdavi,
“Tahavvulat-i si sala-yi yik dih dar dasht-i qazvin” (Thirty-Year Transformations in One Village in Qazvin),
in The Agrarian and Peasant Questions, 50–74.
9 This is calculated on the basis of the data on the rural population provided in the 1956 and 1996 censuses
and on the arable land area reported in the First National Census of Agriculture, 1961, and 1993 Agricultural
Census.
10 The Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO) provides data on the yield (kilograms
per hectare) of the major crops for 1961–78: 802 of wheat, 800 of barley, 2,914 of rice, 939 of cotton, and
19,202 of sugar beets in 1961–65; 896 of wheat, 891 of barley, 3,355 of rice, 1,198 of cotton, and 21,082
of sugar beets in 1966–70; 884 of wheat, 753 of barley, 3,455 of rice, 1,650 of cotton, and 24,243 of sugar
beets in 1971–75; and 1,011 of wheat, 841 of barley, 3,315 of rice, 1,598 of cotton, and 25,314 for sugar beets
in 1977–78 (Production Yearbook [Geneva: United Nations, 1971–79], Table 7:14); see also the 1961 First
National Census of Agriculture and the 1993 National Census of Agriculture.
11 A dang is one-sixth of a real-estate property or a village. In traditional Iranian agriculture, a village would
be divided into six dangs, and the ownership of an entire village was referred to as a shish-dang (six dangs).
From Peasant to Farmer 347
12 For further discussion, see Javad Safi-Nezhad, Bunah: nizamha-i ziraati sunnati dar Iran (Bunah:
Traditional Farming Systems in Iran) (Tehran: Muassisa-yi Intisharat-i Amir Kabir, 1989); Hushang Elyasian,
“Bunah bandi dar dasht-i qazvin: nimunah-yi az nizam-i kar kishavarzi-yi dastihjami dar Iran” (The Structure
of Bunah in Qazvin: An Example of Agricultural Work Team in Iran), Iqtisad-i Kishavarzi va-Tawsiah 2
(1994): 143–50; and Eckart Ehlers, “The Iranian Village: A Socio-economic Microcosm,” in Agricultural
Development in the Middle East, ed. P. Beaumont and K. McLachlan (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1985),
151–70.
13 For a discussion of urban landlord domination, see, among others, Paul Ward English, City, and Village
in Iran: Settlement and Economy in the Kirman Basin (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1966); Javad
Safi-Nezhad, Talibabad: nimunih-i jami az barrisi-i yik dih (Talibabad: A Comprehensive Example of the
Study of One Village) (Tehran: Muassisa-yi Mutaliat va Tahqiqat-i Ijtimai, 1967); Morio Ono and Mehdi Talib,
Munugrafi-yi Ibrahim Abad (A Monograph of Ibrahim Abad) (Tehran: Muassisa-yi Mutaliat va-Tahqiqat-i
Ijtimai, 1967); and Michael E. Bonine, Yazd and Its Hinterland: A Central Place System of Urban Dominance
in the Central Iranian Plateau (Marburg: Geographischen Instituts der Universität Marburg), Marburger
Geographische Schriften 82 (1980), chap. 3.
14 For a survey of debates on 1960s land-reform politics, see Keith McLachlan, The Neglected Garden: The
Politics and Ecology of Agriculture in Iran (London: I. B. Tauris, 1988), 105–52; Ashraf, “State and Agrarian
Relations”; Majd, Resistance to the Shah, 88–163; and Hooglund, Land and Revolution in Iran, 123–37.
15 See, among others, Azimi, “Distribution of Land and Income,” 88–89; Mohammad Javad Amid, Agricul-
ture, Poverty and Reform in Iran (London: Routledge, 1990), 88–110; Cyrus Salmanzadeh and Gwyn E. Jones,
“An Approach to the Micro Analysis of the Land Reform Program in Southwestern Iran,” Land Economics 55
(1979): 108–27; and Ismail Ajami, “Land Reform and Modernization of Farming Structure in Iran,” Oxford
Agrarian Studies 2 (1973): 120–31.
16 Ashraf, “State and Agrarian Relations,” 305–306.
17 Under the provisions of Article 3, Part 2, of the Land Reform Law, mechanized lands—that is, those
that were at least ploughed by mechanical means and cultivated by wage laborers—were exempt from
redistribution.
18 For a discussion of peasant production system (nizam-i dihqani), see Gholam Reza Heydari, “Yikparchigi
arazi tawsiah-yi kishavarzi dar Iran” (Land Consolidation and Agricultural Development in Iran), Iqtisad-i
Kishavarzi va-Tawsiah 4 (1996): 145–203; and Ismail Ajami, “Naqsh-i nizam-i bahrih bardari-yi dihqani
dar tawsiah-yi kishavarzi” (The Role of Peasant Production System in Agricultural Development], Namah-i
Ulum-i Ijtimai 2 (1976): 189–99.
19 This type of sharecropping, which advanced rapidly in the villages surrounding urban centers during the
1960s–70s, is also referred to as saifi kari, qumi kari, and muqasimah kari in different regions of Iran: see Safi-
Nezhad, Talibabad, 123–24; Najmabadi, Land Reform, 112–14; and Mahdavi, “Thirty-year Transformations,”
55–56.
20 Mahdavi, “Thirty-year Transformations,” 59–64.
21 Safi-Nezhad, Talibabad, 203–206.
22 Abdolali Lahsaeizadeh, Contemporary Rural Iran (Avebury, U.K.: Ashgate Publishing, 1993), 179, 183.
23 For details, see Ajami, Shishdangi, 59–96.
24 For further discussion of dualistic agrarian structure, see Amid, Agriculture, Poverty and Reform, 111–
34. On the disintegration of the Bunah system, see Eric J. Hooglund, “Rural Socioeconomic Organization in
Transition: The Case of Iran’s Bonehs,” in Continuity and Change in Modern Iran, ed. Michael E. Bonine
and Nikki Keddie (Albany: State University of New York Press, 1981); S. Amini, “The Origin, Function
and Disappearance of Collective Production Units (Haraseh) in Rural Areas of Iran,” Der Tropenlandwrit 48
(1983): 47–61; and Amir Ismail Ajami, “Bunah dar sakht-i ijtimai rustai-yi Iran” (The Bunah System in Iran’s
Rural Society), Iran Namah 13 (1995): 503–22.
25 See, among others, Majd, Resistance to the Shah, 344–46; and Hooglund, Land and Revolution, 81–98.
26 Moghadam, From Land Reform to Revolution, 88–92.
27 Massoud Karshenas, Oil, State, and Industrialization in Iran (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
1990), 153.
28 The total area of agricultural land increased from 11.3 million hectares reported in the 1961 Agricultural
composed of two representatives from the Ministry of Agriculture, one from the Ministry of the Interior, one
from Jihad-i Sazandigi, one from the Islamic Court, and one from the village council concerned: see Schirazi,
Islamic Development Policy, 161–63.
36 For details of the 1986 Land Reform Law, see ibid., 186–95.
37 Despite the existing hostility, a few villagers told me in private conversations that the majority of the
farmers are willing to return the 70–80 hectares of land to the landowner, Haj Arbab, and get their document
“sanad.” They believed that, “since the land seizure, as the illicit ‘harām’ land has been mixed with our
legitimate ‘halāl’ property, smoking, drug addiction, and fatal car accidents have been on the rise among our
youth.”
38 For an overall review of the revolution’s impact on the villages, see Mansur Vosooghi, Jamahshinasi-yi
rustai (Rural Sociology) (Tehran: Intisharat-i Kayhan, 1987), 229–89; and Mostafa Azkia, “Rural Society
and Revolution in Iran,” in Twenty Years of Islamic Revolution, ed. Eric Hooglund (Syracuse, N.Y.: Syracuse
University Press, 2002), 96–119.
39 On the decline of domestic capital formation in agriculture, see Kambiz H. Kiyani and Mohamad R.
Alizadeh, “Barrisi-yi avamil muasir bar sarmayi guzari-yi bakhsh-i khususi dar kishavarzi-i Iran” (A Study
on the Factors Affecting Private Sector Investment in Iranian Agriculture), Iqtisad-i Kishavarzi va-Tawsiah
8 (2000): 45–73; and Ahmad Mojtahed and Hadi S. Esfahani, “Agricultural Policy and Performance in Iran:
The Post-Revolutionary Experience,” World Development 17 (1989): 839–60.
40 Benjamin White, “Problems in the Empirical Analysis of Agrarian Differentiation,” in Agrarian Trans-
formation: Local Processes and the State in South East Asia, ed. Gillan Hart, Andrew Turton, and Benjamin
White (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1989), 17.
41 For a discussion of a similar trend in Egyptian agriculture, see Nicholas S. Hopkins and Kirsten
advantage to sell their wheat harvest to the market and buy family bread from urban bakeries.
43 As an illustration, the number of water pumps increased from twenty-seven in 1967 to sixty by 2002,
and the average amount of fertilizer used per irrigated hectare increased from 92 to 550 kilograms over this
period.
44 The 2002 sample household survey shows that all of the small and medium farm households except one
now have a refrigerator, television, and telephone, whereas in 1967, 39 percent of peasant households had just
a radio.
45 For a discussion of a similar trend in peasant transformation, see Caglar Keyder, “Paths of Rural Trans-
Farming: Agrarian Structure and Ideology in Northern Tamil Nadu (Bombay: Oxford University Press,
1982); and Luis Llamli, “Small Modern Farmers: Neither Peasants nor Fully-Fledged Capitalists,” Journal of
Peasant Studies 15 (1988): 350–72.
47 Reinhold Loeffler, “Change and Continuity in Sisakht,” paper presented at the Fifth Biennial Conference
MAI, 1998).
From Peasant to Farmer 349
51 For an empirical study of integrated crop/dairy farming in Fars Province, see Javad Torkamani and
Mahmood A. Borazjani, “Muqayisa-yi ulguha-yi bihinah-i vahidha-yi zirai va-damdari-yi infiradi va-talfiqi”
(A Comparative Study of Crop Farms with Integrated Crop/Dairy Farms), Iqtisad-i Kishavarzi va-Tawsiah 7
(1999): 61–76.
52 It is interesting to note that this trend is much stronger in Shishdangi when compared with the other
rural areas in the Marvdasht region, where the share of male employment in agricultural and nonagricultural
occupations were 55.6 percent and 44.4 percent, respectively, in 1996: see Sarshumari-yi umumi-yi nufus
va-maskan shahristan-i marvdasht, 1375 (National Census of Population and Housing—Marvdasht Region,
1996) (Tehran: MAI, 1997), 29.
53 Sarshumari-yi nufus va-maskan kull-i kishvar, 1335 (National Census of Population and Housing, 1956)
(Tehran: Vizarat-i Kishvar, 1956); Sarshumari-yi umumi-yi nufus va-maskan kull-i kishvar, 1375 (National
Census of Population and Housing, 1996) (Tehran: MAI, 1997).
54 Loeffler, “Change and Continuity,” 7.
55 For a discussion of similar trends in a village northwest of Shiraz, see Eric Hooglund, “Letter from an
Economies and Their Transformations, Monographs in Economic Anthropology, no. 3, ed. Morgan D.
Maclachlan (Lanham, Md.: University Press of America, 1987), 155–72.
57 Azkia, “Rural Society and Revolution in Iran,” 101–103.
58 In the 1967 study, khwushnishins often expressed their overall life conditions as being destitute and
powerless. They did not express such a negative outlook on life during interviews conducted in 2002.
59 Hopkins, “Agrarian Transition,” 157.
60 Netting, Smallholders, Householders, 216.