Agrarian Questions Old and New
Agrarian Questions Old and New
Agrarian Questions Old and New
Agrarian Questions:
Old and New
Awanish Kumar*
The volume under review sets out to answer five questions. The first relates to the
nature of changes in India’s agrarian economy under neoliberal globalisation. The
second asks whether changes under global capitalism reflect a transition from a
rural and semi-feudal economy to an urban and industrial capitalist economy. The
third relates to the nature of agrarian transition and whether this transition
conforms to the classical model. The fourth highlights regional diversity in terms of
agrarian changes and development, and documents the experiences and responses
to the transition from different regions and states. The final question relates to the
responses of various agrarian classes and interest groups to the transition.
* Tata Institute of Social Sciences, awanishkumar86@gmail.com
The first section in the volume under review is titled “Agrarian Transition: Theoretical
Discourse.” It is followed by a section titled “Global Capitalism, Neoliberalism
and Changing Agriculture.” The final section is “Agrarian Transition: Regional
Responses.” In their opening chapter A. Haroon Akram-Lodhi and Cristobal Kay
dissociate themselves from Bernstein’s idea of redundancy of the agrarian question
under globalisation. Taking their lead from the “historical puzzles” put forward by
Byres (1996, 2003), they contest the widely held linear view of agrarian transition
and development, often attributed to Marx and argue that diverse experiences of
agrarian transition, both successful and unsuccessful, are consistent with Marxist
political economy.
This perspective – that Marx viewed the small-scale pre-capitalist peasantry as a
structural impediment to the full fruition of the capitalist mode of production – is very
widely held. It is also, in our view, false. (p. 55, volume under review).
In the chapter on the peasant question in contemporary Asia, with special reference to
India, D. Narasimha Reddy counters Bernstein’s argument that the peasant question
that formed the core classical agrarian question has been superseded in the wake of
globalisation. He identifies two concerns related to the land-to-the-tiller agenda
expressed by the Left on the land question. First, redistributive land reforms would
allot small parcels of land to peasants but not lead to any gain in productivity. The
second concern relates to the availability of land for redistribution in India, a
problem that some observers have raised. Regarding the first, while the agrarian
question of capital may not be as significant as in the past, the argument can be
countered from a social justice perspective. Reddy points out that ceiling-surplus
land is only one type of land available, and that it can be clubbed with “cultivable”
government land and “Bhoodan” land, with government support. Bernstein’s
argument on the irrelevance of the agrarian question of capital may not be
applicable to India as the rural population continues to face a livelihood crisis owing
to a combination of factors, both historical and current. The other argument, which
examines the contradiction between the “peasantry” and global corporate chains, is
doubtful in the case of India.
D. N. Dhanagare, in a chapter on the neoliberal state and agrarian crisis in India, begins
by pointing out that while the contribution of the agricultural sector to national GDP
has fallen, a substantial section of the population continues to rely on the sector for
employment. He discusses contract farming and bonded labour, and concludes that
neoliberal state policy is responsible for the agrarian crisis.
The last section of the volume has four articles that focus on individual states:
Judith Heyer writes on Tamil Nadu, Daniel Munster on Kerala, Santanu Rakshit on
West Bengal, and Sukhpal Singh and Shruti Bhogal on Punjab. Heyer’s article
discusses the loosening ties of patriarchy among the Gounders in Coimbatore. The
article is based on the author’s long-term academic engagement with the society
and economy of a region where industrialisation has taken place and drawn people
away from villages. With the expansion of the non-agricultural sector, fertility rates
have gone down, and wages for female labour have increased, though they continue
to be lower than wages for male labour. Education for women has made significant
differences to their lives and work.
Munster’s article on Kerala discusses the Zero Budget Natural Farming (ZBNF) method
as a response to the persistent agrarian crisis and farmer suicides in Wayanad district.
Munster endorses the Marxist view on ecology, though he believes that a more
“farmer-focused” alternative is required. He presents the ZBNF as an alternative to
dominant production and exchange paradigms with its new techniques of
cultivation and limited dependence on external markets. The ethnographic study in
Wayanad is situated in a context of despair and pronouncements of “ellam poyi”
(“Everything is gone,” or “We have lost everything”). ZBNF occupies a unique space,
distinct from the state and NGOs to the extent that even standard organic farming is
deemed exploitative and “demonic.” Many farmers under ZBNF in Wayanad district
formerly practised organic farming with little control over their farming practices,
while agencies for certification made organic farming unaffordable. ZBNF is
different from organic farming in at least two aspects. First, the method of natural
farming respects the autonomy of farmers. Secondly, the method has a strong
focus on soil fertility and uses “jivamrita” prepared from cow urine and dung.
According to Munster, though ZBNF farmers do not share an explicit anti-capitalist
agenda – on the contrary, they may appear to be closer to Hindu right-wing
approaches to the ecological question – they still present an alternative for the future.
Santanu Rakshit’s article on West Bengal is located within the framework developed by
Kalyan Sanyal. Based on empirical studies of villages, the article traces the emergence
The article on Punjab by Sukhpal Singh and Shruti Bhogal focuses on the condition
of small and marginal farmers in the State. In recent years the number of small
and marginal holdings in Punjab has declined, opposite to the national trend. This
adds to the increased burden of debt that has led to farmer suicides in the State. A
process of depeasantisation is under way, because of which 14.4 per cent of the
farmers in the State have moved out of agriculture since 1991. About 45 per cent of
these farmers were from the small and marginal landholding categories. The core
issue continues to be the unviability of small-scale farming, a problem that has to be
addressed through policy measures.
Shah and Harriss-White (2011) acknowledge “the structure of agrarian property has
clearly been transformed” (p. 14) with a lack of concentration of land and the
persistence of small-scale peasant holdings. They note that much of the dynamism
of contemporary agriculture is due to the presence of middle caste groups. Further,
workers have not left agricultural work to join industry. Working households
require multiple livelihood strategies. Caste identities have strengthened but caste as
a system has collapsed and “rurality” as an empirical reality might belong to the
past (Gupta 2005; see also Gupta 2015).
A number of changes have taken place in the post-liberalisation period in the 1990s.
First, corporate classes have assumed a position of dominance over the landed elite.
Secondly, with the emergence of competitive federalism, regional party leaders have
moved closer to international and national capital. Thirdly, the urban middle class
has conceded to corporate morality in the wake of globalisation. Within this larger
context, Chatterjee proposes a duality of civil society versus political society. While
the urban middle classes employ managerial-technological ways to influence the
state and support the capitalist class in accumulation, political society is dominated
by the informal sector, the peasantry, or “non-corporate capital,” which is not run
on the logic of corporate capital or the morality of the bourgeoisie.
In sum, the relevance of the land and agrarian question is a matter of intense debate
for politics and policy.
Put simply, the agrarian question in its classical form has three components. These
include the nature, degree, and extent of development of capitalism in agriculture
(i.e. capitalist development), the nature of classes that rise out of the development of
capitalism (class formation), and the possibilities of class alliances and class struggle
(Ramachandran 2011, p. 52). The agrarian sectors of underdeveloped societies are
characterised by semi-feudal and pre-capitalist relations of production in agriculture
and land. These include landlordism, various forms of petty tenancy, servitude and
bondage of labour, and usury (Patnaik 2007, p. 11).
The forces of differentiation of the peasantry and the progressive dissolution of feudal
relations may undergo differing degrees of mutation in different contexts. Further, the
process of transition from a pre-capitalist agrarian structure to capitalist agriculture
has varied significantly across developing economies. As Ramachandran (2011) argues,
The principle “seek truth from facts” has been a hallmark of the agrarian studies of
classical Marxism and beyond: while we study economic trends and trends in
agriculture for society as a whole, our understanding must be moulded also by local
conditions and forms of agriculture. Such sensitivity to local conditions – to
The structural change model of economic development dictates that the size of the
labour force employed in the primary sector, i.e., agriculture and allied activities,
decline as the economy develops. The movement of the workforce towards the
secondary and tertiary sectors signifies economic growth to the extent it usefully
employs the surplus labour in a backward economy characterised by the perfectly
elastic supply of labour in traditional sectors (Lewis 1954). The proportion of
people dependent on agriculture in India has shown little change whereas the
share of agriculture in GDP has fallen (Kuznets 1957; Sen 2002). The agrarian
structure provides a limiting basis for the expansion of agriculture-industry
linkages, development of a home market, and modernisation of the economy. A
backward social and economic system rooted in landlordism and caste has
meant the development of agriculture in India has remained stunted. On the
other hand, the employment elasticity of organised manufacturing and industrial
growth has historically been low and the proportion of agricultural labourers
within the workforce employed in agriculture has shown an increasing trend
(Patnaik 1983).
The nature and relevance of the agrarian question under globalisation, especially in
India, continues to be an important concern. A recent study by Yadu and Satheesha
(2016) shows that the rate of landlessness among rural households has gone down
over the period between 2002–3 and 2012–13 (see Table 1).
According to data from the National Sample Survey Organisation, any household
owning less than 0.002 hectares is classified as landless, but this is an
underestimation. The study defines effective landlessness as any household that
owns less than 1 acre (0.04 hectares) of land. By this definition, landlessness has
increased from 60.1 per cent in 2002–3 to 66.1 per cent in 2014. This is in addition to
marginal holdings, which now constitute over 75 per cent of total holdings.
The volume successfully captures the nuances of the Byres-Bernstein debate, including
its elaboration of the classical agrarian question, its contemporary relevance, and its
diversity across societies. The larger lesson from the volume concerns the nature of
agrarian change and the question of mobilisation for progressive agrarian transition.
The volume establishes the need to take the agrarian question seriously and poses
important questions on the relevance of the agenda for agrarian reform. The
Communist Party of India (Marxist) (CPIM) has recently observed,
The fact that land is no longer the sole, or even dominant, source of income and economic
activity for the class of landlords and big capitalist farmers has important implications for
our movements, particularly the struggle for the seizure and distribution of landlords’
land. The report suggests that we need fresh thinking on how to fight a class enemy of
this type. In a situation where the hegemony and dominance of landlords and big
capitalist farmers derives from their overall control of a wide range of economic
activities and institutions in villages and their surroundings (and not solely or mainly
from village-based exploitation), we cannot fight this class on the issue of land alone.
While recognising the centrality of the land question, and the importance of the
demand for comprehensive land reform, we also recognise that even the demand to
identify, occupy, and redistribute ceiling-surplus land has become a demand that is not
immediately realisable — for a variety of subjective and objective reasons — in many
areas at the present moment (CPIM 2016).
This is a clear assessment of agrarian changes in India over the last few decades. While
the classical categories remain relevant, fresh thinking on the issue of popular
mobilisation for the resolution of the agrarian question is needed. Understanding
agrarian transition in India requires that two specific issues be taken into account.
First, the current agrarian scene is a differentiated one, comprising the older
landlord class and its allies (consolidated into the capitalist farmer and rich peasant
class) and the majority of the peasantry, including landless agricultural workers.
Landlessness has not declined and land redistribution continues to be a focal
point for public mobilisation and policy advocacy. The articles by D. N. Reddy and
D. N. Dhanagare testify to this observation. The village studies in different States of
the country by the Foundation for Agrarian Studies (FAS) have made similar
observations. The importance of agricultural work for landless and marginal
The second aspect of agrarian transition in India relates to the specific experiences
of Dalits, Scheduled Tribes, and women in agrarian social relations. As Habib
writes, “the existence of ‘untouchables’ was thus a pillar of Indian peasant
agriculture from very early times, ever since, that is, the food-gatherers and the
forest folk were humbled and subjugated by settled agricultural communities”
(Habib 1963/2014, pp. 143–4; see also Kosambi 1975). In India, the landless class of
wage labourers was, and continues to be tied to a specific social position in the caste
hierarchy. A distinct class of landless agricultural labourers existed before the
advent of colonial rule and the development of capitalist relations in agricultural
production. This is a uniquely Indian problem and the land question for Dalits and
Scheduled Tribes continues to pose a challenge to Indian society and polity. In the
last few years, a number of socio-political movements for land or against land
alienation have seen active and leading participation from Dalits and Scheduled
Tribes. Issues related to land, livelihoods, and social dignity have been consolidated
into newer demands. The democratisation of social and economic life is dependent
upon the resolution of the agrarian question. With the growth of democratic
consciousness, issues of land and caste have to be addressed in a unified way.
REFERENCES
Bernstein, H. (1996), “Agrarian Questions Then and Now,” Journal of Peasant Studies, vol. 24,
nos. 1–2, pp. 22–59.
Bernstein, H. (2006),“Is There an Agrarian Question in the 21st Century?” Canadian Journal of
Development Studies, vol. 27, no. 4, pp. 449–60.
Borras Jr., S. M., Kay, Cristobal, and Akram-Lodhi, A. Haroon (2007), Agrarian Reform and
Rural Development: Historical Overview and Current Issues, ISS/UNDP Land, Poverty and
Public Action Policy Paper No. 1, Institute of Social Studies, The Hague.
Byres, T. J. (1986), “The Agrarian Question, Forms of Capitalist Agrarian Transition and the
State: An Essay with Reference to Asia,” Social Scientist, vol. 14, no. 11/12, pp. 3–67.