Financing Social Innovation: International Evidence
Financing Social Innovation: International Evidence
Financing Social Innovation: International Evidence
Financing Social
Innovation
International evidence
01. January 2022
Krlev, G., Sauer, S., Scharpe, K., Mildenberger, G., Elsemann, K. & Sauerhammer, M. 2021. Financing Social
Innovation – International Evidence. Centre for Social Investment (CSI), University of Heidelberg & Social
Entrepreneurship Network Deutschland e.V. (SEND).
Consulted experts
About SEND
The Social Entrepreneurship Netzwerk Deutschland (SEND) is connecting social enterprises across Germany, to
strengthen them and give them a common voice. SEND is building important bridg-es of the sector to politics, civil
society, the welfare economy and commercial economy to drive positive change and to improve the framework for
social innovations. With a (constantly) grow-ing network of currently over 800 members, SEND is working towards a
society in which all peo-ple benefit from progress.
We do so through what we call: #GemeinsamWirken! (Working and having impact together)
7. Opening up existing programmes Social impact bonds or outcome funds can stimu-
late innovations in established fields. They promote
[to make instruments of established innovation
effective problem solving and prevention instead of
support available to social innovators]
standard service provision.
8. Vouchers for capacity building and networks Community bonds can help to anchor social innova-
tions locally and to increase citizen‘s identification
[to create an ecosystem that is essential
with social innovations.
for the scaling of social innovations]
Blended market finance helps create an investment
case for commercial investors who do not invest in
social innovations due to high levels of risk or the
lack of an exit option. In order to enable an exit, this
financing vehicle may have to be combined with the
creation of quasi-markets that can generate income
streams for social innovators.
Our study not only develops the concrete recommendations just summarized,
but it also clearly shows how similar political instruments and financing ve-
hicles have been used successfully in other countries.
I. — p. 10 II. — p. 12
III. — p. 14 IV. — p. 16
V. — p. 22
Financing
vehicles
VI. — p. 30 VII. — p. 34
VIII. — p. 35 IX. — p. 35
Why do we need to
think about financing
social innovation?
Instead, we need sustainable and socially oriented solutions, that is innovations with and
for society. Such social innovations need adequate financial support. Promoting social
innovations would not only enhance Germany’s development towards a socio-ecological
market economy, but also help renew the German welfare state and contribute to a di-
verse, lively and pro-active society.
In May 2020, the German Bundestag adopted a motion to promote social innovations for
the very first time. Another important step towards establishing social innovations as a
policy priority was the Social Innovation Strategy (› t1p.de/ttsd [bmbf.de]) developed and
published by nine federal ministries in August 2021. The strategy lays out some central
goals and options for promoting social innovations. Beyond that, however, there is no ho-
listic approach to financing and supporting social innovations.
Recent data show that 90 percent of social enterprises see at least one substantial fi-
nancial barrier for their organization, for example: lack of patient capital (long duration),
lack of adequate start-up finance, lack of adequate growth finance, or difficulties in
using public grant finance or subsidies (see DSEM 2020/21 › t1p.de/7ogr [send-ev.de]).
Many countries across the globe already have public structures and processes for
financing social innovation in place, which can serve as examples for Germany. In our
explorative research project, we analysed a wide range of international evidence from
10 countries and 3 international organizations. In particular we conducted in-depth
interviews with 23 leading national experts to develop propositions on how to best
finance social innovations. [1]
We would like to remark that the countries considered represent a wide range of dif-
ferent economic and welfare systems and that our recommendations are always based
on impulses that came from various countries which shared similar challenges or had
developed similar solutions. The caveat that experiences from other countries cannot
be transferred to Germany, which is often voiced in political discussions about this
subject, is therefore effectively addressed in this report.
While our analysis of challenges and recommendations of how to solve them focus
explicitly on Germany, many prompts can be applied to the situation in other countries
as well, including those for which we gathered evidence. We therefore hope to provide
guidance for policy makers and ecosystem shapers globally through this report.
[1] We are mostly referring to finance or financing instead of investments, because we draw on the full
range of potential financial support for social innovators, including equity, debt, mezzanine, or grant funding.
II.
12
Challenges in
financing social innovation
In this chapter it is becoming evident that approaching the topic from a commercial
venture capital lens, which thinks in terms of “investment per venture”, is hardly
useful. The support of social innovation is more akin to the public research and
development (R&D) support for commercial innovation—and yet it differs in
important ways from the latter as we explain here.
2a
3a
3c
2c 3b
1c
2b Non-market types
Hybrid types
Market-oriented types
1b
Life-cycle Availability
Social innovators need a substantially longer time on First, there is a lack of social mission driven inves-
average to break-even or build a self-sufficient busi- tors, and if providers of finance have a philanthropic
ness model than commercial innovators. Financing orientation, the provided funding is not aligned along
needs are likely to shift as organizations evolve (from the development phases on the innovation funnel. The
pre-seed to growth), whereby only ventures with a seed phase is critical, especially for the non-market
commercial legal form and market orientation (3b.) and hybrid types of social innovators, which often slip
currently draw on the full spectrum of finance (based into the so called “valley of death” due to a lack of
on DSEM 2020/21 [› t1p.de/7ogr] data about the use tailored finance (2. phase in Figure 1). Second, social
of finance by social enterprises). Non-market organ- innovators often do not represent an attractive risk-re-
izations are only able to draw on a small fraction of turn-impact profile for investors. While the may offer a
available finance (1a.-3a.). high impact potential, the associated risk is often also
high or the expected financial return too low. This is
Income and financing models why we need tailored measures to enable more target-
Selling socially innovative products and services is a ed growth funding (3. phase in Figure 1).
source of revenue to for example social enterprises. In
contrast to commercial firms, however, social enter- Long-term orientation
prises typically internalize external effects on socie- The financing landscape mostly focuses on relatively
ty, which makes equal market access more difficult. short-term financial support rather than a long-term
Therefore, many social innovators always depend on orientation at developing social innovators and social
hybrid income or financing sources, which may for ex- innovations throughout their life-cycle. This hampers
ample include public subsidies, donations, or revenues the unleashing of the innovations’ full impact potential
generated on public quasi-markets (1a-c). (goal direction of Figure 1).
Strategies for
designing solutions
1
Process orientation instead
of individual measures
3
Non-financial support
and networks
Financial architecture
and policy tools
In this chapter we aim to explain the tools that are essential within the fi-
nancial architecture and their functions in reference to social innovations.
Eight different policy tools are highlighted and will be explained in more
detail below. How these are connected to specific financing vehicles is
discussed in Chapter 5. Here we only allude to these financing vehicles
by numbering and naming them, and by illustrating and locating them via
graphic schemes.
Social
innovators Pre-Seed Growth
Seed
8. Vouchers
Capacity building & networks
Equity, late or no exit (e.g., silent partnership), exit via transition perspective
I. II.
Accelerator loans/ Blended non-market
Financing V.
vehicles 3. Guarantees Blended market
finance
5. Community Investments
Policy tools
Incubators/accelerators → Venture Philanthropists → CSR → Investment funds → Pensions funds → Venture capital funds →
Private Foundations → Impact Investments → Family Offices →
investors
Retail banks →
6. Social procurement
5. Local community investments: & building public quasi-market:
There is hardly any possibility for citizens to invest in Some social innovations will be able to establish them-
social innovators other than crowd-funding, where the selves as a market product or service that is fully com-
investment often remains limited to the very early phase mercially viable. However, many will require a long-term
of a venture. Ways of institutionalizing and extending the perspective that can only emerge via active state in-
ideas underlying crowd-based funding (pooling of re- volvement. For example, even debt with low or variable
sources, risk diversification etc.) are important, not only interest and a very long duration will need to be repaid
to extend the available amount of finance but also to at some point. Equity investments are altogether unlike-
strengthen the link between citizens and social innova- ly, if investors do not have an exit option at all.
tors, or in fact make citizens co-innovators.
The state could engage in two ways to address these
Locally oriented community bonds, for example to challenges. First, market building by the public sec-
support social innovators in a local urban neigh- tor for the mid- to long-term, for instance through
bourhood or rural region, would provide a vehicle for implementing an innovation as part of the standard
place-based innovation. Municipalities could seek to system of social service provision, can help social
structure such investment opportunities and poten- innovators establish a sustainable and market-ori-
tially co-invest. [4] ented income model. This is needed to be able to
use debt, equity or mezzanine finance. Second,
social procurement is a more universal mechanism
the state could apply, which would establish impact
and social and ecological criteria as core criteria in
public buying decisions. It would not only provide
social innovators with new ways of establishing mar-
ket-based streams of income, but also increase the
impact orientation of organizations across societal
sectors.
In addition to the specific types of public funding already mentioned, there are
several alternative sources of public finance, which could be used finance social
innovations: (1) existing ESF funds of European funds for regional development,
(2) dedicated social welfare budgets to promote innovation in (social) service
provision, (3) dormant assets, which have been used for public social invest-
ments in a number of countries internationally (see a recent policy proposal on
using them in Germany › t1p.de/veeww [send-ev.de], a legal scoping assessment
on its feasibility has recently been completed on behalf of the German govern-
ment). These funds allow for different sector or geographic focuses, and align
with priority areas defined by the sustainable development goals (SDGs).
Financing Social Innovation — International evidence 21
Financing
vehicles
INVESTMENT
› ESF › Family Offices
Vinnova Power-Up Portugal Social Sitra Brabant Community Bonds des Big Society Capital
Scotland Innovation Outcomes Fund Centre for Social Innovation
I. Accelerator
loans/ grants
Purpose
Life-cycle phases
Especially pre-seed, also seed
Logic
The larger share of finance would come from private sources, such as foundations, venture
philanthropists or corporates seeking to provide support to social innovators as part of
the corporate social responsibility (CSR) initiatives. This could be combined with a sub-
stantially smaller share of public funding to form a pool of finance. State foundations such
as KfW Stiftung or the state banks, which exist in every German federal state, in analogy
to their provision of subsidies for commercial innovation could contribute to the public
funding.
International examples
Vinnova Sweden, Power Up Scotland, Portugal Social Innovation
Purpose
Life-cycle phases
Especially seed
Logic
The key principle is to leverage private investment by means of substantial public co-in-
vestment, or other incentives such as tax cuts or premiums. Sources for such public in-
vest-ment could be ESF funds, a re-channeling of social welfare budgets for stimulating
innovation in social service provision, or regional and municipal budgets to support local
innovation.
The types of involved private finance providers would largely mirror that of the accelerator
loans/grants. However, in the seed stage of social innovators public investments need to
be more substantial. This is especially since the mobilized support should have a long-
term orientation and the risk of financial loss would be higher so that risk-return-impact
profiles would need to be smoothed out by the public sector. The main types of finance
are repayable loans, ideally with flexible interest and long-term option of converting these
into equity. In addition, social innovators should be provided with working capital.
International examples
Portugal Social Innovation
Purpose
Life-cycle phases
Seed and growth
Logic
The basic idea of social impact bonds is to mobilize private finance for promoting innovation, and to
outsource public risk. At the same time, SIBs represent a shift in the provision logic from compensating
providers and/or investors based on (a) services provided to (b) results achieved. Only when pre-defi-
ned impact criteria are met, do investors receive a repayment of their investment, plus a premium. The
mobilized investments typically do not go to single organizations but to partnerships of provider, who
based on a combination of expertise hope to contribute to more effective problem solving.
Individual local social impact bonds have been criticized for having very high setup and administrative
costs, which is why outcomes funds that provide an umbrella to finance several initiatives are becoming
the preferred alternative. The range of potential private investors is wide and spans from foundations to
retail banks, who will typically have very different individual risk-return-impact profiles and could thus
meet the financial requirements of different types of social innovators. A pooling of resources across
different risk-return-impact tranches may help lever the overall amount of capital further.
International examples
Brabant Outcomes Fund Netherlands, Portugal Social Innovation,
Sitra Finland, local SIB initiatives in many other countries
IV. Community
bonds
Purpose
Life-cycle phases
Seed and growth
Logic
Investment opportunities for citizens in social innovation are limited to non-existent.
One vehicle for opening such opportunities is the setup of local community bonds
that foster place-based investing into social innovations that are located in one’s
neighbourhood or region. Citizens could for example acquire a share in a building to
be acquired by a social enterprise to establish a new cultural hub. A structured fund
could also provide loans to several local social innovators. Citizen investments might
be leveraged by municipal investments, or by co-investments from local philanthro-
pists or local businesses.
International examples
Centre for Social Innovation bonds, Canada
V. Blended
market finance
Purpose
Life-cycle phases
Growth
Logic
Some social innovators succeed in building models where impact and profits are fully
in line. Finding private investors for such models is typically not a major challenge.
However, many social innovators, even if ready for growth, offer below market or no
financial returns, or contain a high amount of risk both, of financial failure and im-
pact not materializing. Blended finance that taps a variety of financing sources can
be effective in making such investments attractive to the widest possible range of in-
vestors, spanning as far as pension funds or venture capital funds. Even participation
of retail banks and a subsequent offer of individual investments to customers are a
viable option.
However, this requires a pooling of finance with different risk-return-impact profiles to
get to a balance, which individual investors would not be able to achieve when invest-
ing on their own. Guarantee-type or first loss functions could be performed by public
investments of state banks or by private philanthropic capital. Such vehicles would en-
able the provision of long-term debt with flexible interest, mezzanine finance, patient
equity or profit-sharing options. Social procurement or public quasi-market building
may provide effective exit options for private investors if social innovators are unable
to sustain the model through standard market mechanisms.
International examples
Big Society Capital UK, Canada Fund-of-funds
Purpose
― Ecosystem building
Life-cycle phase
Life-cycle phase
Logic
Ecosystem building requires political ownership of the issues and a national leader, ideally
an independent institution that can broker between all involved actors, increase transpar-
ency and collaboration in the field, and identify priority areas for action. The EU-Programme
for Employment and Social Innovation (EaSI) was built around some of these principles.
The foundation of a separate innovation foundation for social innovations, which fosters
non-market as well as market-oriented models would be a good opportunity to provide
targeted support.
International examples
Le French Impact, EaSI programme of the European Commission, Sitra Finland
Le French Impact is the most prototypical institution performing all these functions,
including the early involvement of policy makers in investments to enable legal or in-
stitutional changes, if and as they become necessary over time.
International
evidence
All our recommendations are based on our analysis of 23 expert interviews that we
conducted in the summer of 2021. We talked to representatives of international organ-
izations, more specifically to the OECD, the European Venture Philanthropy Association
(EVPA), the Global Steering Group on Impact Investing (GSG) as well as experts in some
countries that are only in a state of emergence of a wider financial support system for
social innovation (Italy and Spain). These interviews yielded general recommendations,
which were not related to a specific funding programme.
The other interviews focussed on the specific experiences of further countries with
their established funding programmes. [7] Here we intend to provide a brief portray of
each programme and compare them across a number of dimensions, which we high-
lighted as essential for arriving at the financial architecture and individual financing
vehicles we proposed. Table 1 provides an overview of the comparison. The relevant
dimensions include: target groups, life-cycle stages, types of finance provided, risk
management, and impact orientation in the existing programmes. The table and sec-
tions are arranged by complexity and multi-facettedness of the instruments applied
(in ascending order from left to right).
The overview shows that the principles on which the individual programmes act are
very different, but that they also exhibit a significant number of shared traits. Our
financial architecture and its corresponding policy tools and financing vehicles are
based on a composition of the most promising components we were able to identify.
[7] For Canada we focus on the planned Fund-of-funds, since the community bonds, while a valuable
local initiative are not an established scheme. Le French Impact while a major initiative is not a dedi-
cated funding scheme, which is why it is it is not listed separately in the table.
Sweden UK / Scotland Netherlands Finland UK Portugal Canada
Brabant
Programme Vinnova Power Up Scotland Sitra Big Society Capital Portugal Social Innovation Social Finance Fund
Outcomes Fund
From base funding to Local social enter- Bottom-up impact Reform of the wel- Building an impact
Principle Designing an ecosystem SDG-oriented investing
innovation funding prise support evolution fare state investment market
Initiator National government Local initiative Regional government National government National government National government National government
(1. round/planned,
volume (2017-2019, public) (2020, public+private) (2020, public) (2020, public) (2014, public) (planned, public + private)
public + private)
Civil society Civil society Social service Market-oriented From civil society From civil society
Target groups Social enterprises
organizations organizations providers social enterprises organizations to SMEs organizations to SMEs
Rechanneling of civil
Public funding Regional ESF, national and Dedicated national
society funding into State guarantees Welfare budget Mainly dormant assets
sources government budget municipal funds funding
innovation funding
Government
Risk allocation Government Private investors Private investors Shared risk Depending on financing vehicle Shared risk
(first-loss)
Vinnova, Sweden
“From base funding to innovation funding”
The programme of the Swedish innovation agency Vinnova represents a shift from a large
amount of unconditional base funding to civil society organizations in the context of the
Nordic welfare state to a dedicated fund promoting innovative action. Financial support
typically comes in the form of grants. There were several initiatives at capacity building to
promote innovation and impact orientation in social innovators through dedicated training
and other non-financial support, but these element are not as integrated as in the pro-
grammes in many other countries.
Sitra, Finland
“Reform of the welfare state”
The programme is based on the impetus of reforming welfare provision in Finland. Instead
of addressing challenges after they occur, Sitra seeks to promote preventative action. The
innovation aspect mainly stems from brining actors together, who would usually not work
together, for example private commercial fund managers and coalitions of social service
providers. Rather than following the logic of locally embedded impact bonds, Sitra tends to
launch tenders with a cross-regional or national remit. Because these are typically sizeable
investments and the state is ready to pay a substantial premium when pre-defined impact
criteria are met, so as to prevent public welfare expenses in the future, the programme
mainly attracts commercial investors who seek near or at market rates of financial return.
Financing Social Innovation — International evidence 33
Fund-of-Funds, Canada
“SDG-oriented investing”
The programme in Canada is only in the process of being set up. The Canadian state seeks
to make a substantial investment, by which it hopes to leverage even more private capital.
Estimates of exact shares and overall magnitude differ, but the projected overall amount
is at least CAD 750 Mio. of combined public and private investment. A blended fund-of-
funds fed from these sources is then meant to channel finance into more specialized and
individual SDG-oriented funds. Some share of the available finance shall also be dedicated
to capacity building, networks and advancing investment readiness. While the programme
seems to aim to employ a variety of financing vehicles and could thereby provide social
innovators with different types of finance, the programme is strongly market-oriented. Im-
pact criteria are likely to be SDG-grounded, but there is no specific information yet.
VII.
34
Call to action
References and
Glossary more inormation