0765616750
0765616750
0765616750
ECONOMICS
INTRODUCING
ECONOMICS
A Critical Guide for Teaching
Mark H. Maier
and
Julie A. Nelson
M.E.Sharpe
Armonk, New York London, England
Copyright 2007 by M.E. Sharpe, Inc. All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced in any form without written permission from the publisher, M.E. Sharpe, Inc., 80 Business Park Drive, Armonk, New York 10504. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Maier, Mark, 1950 Introducing economics : a critical guide for teaching / Mark H. Maier and Julie A. Nelson. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN: 978-0-7656-1675-3 (cloth : alk. paper) 1. EconomicsStudy and teaching (Secondary) I. Nelson, Julie A., 1956 II. Title. HB74.5.M35 2007 330.0712dc22 Printed in the United States of America The paper used in this publication meets the minimum requirements of American National Standard for Information Sciences Permanence of Paper for Printed Library Materials, ANSI Z 39.48-1984. ~ BM (c) 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 2006032332
CONTENTS
Contents
List of Activities and Resources Acknowledgments Part I: Overview 1. Introduction 2. Why Are We Teaching Economics? The History of Economics in High Schools 3. Where Did This Idea Come From? A Primer on Major Schools of Economics Part II: Teaching Economics, Chapter by Chapter 4. What Is Economics? 5. Economic Systems 6. Supply, Demand, and Markets 7. Competition and Monopoly 8. Consumer Education 9. Business Education 10. Labor and the Distribution of Wealth and Income 11. Gross Domestic Product 12. Roles of Government 13. Unemployment and Ination 14. Money, Banking, and the Federal Reserve 15. Fiscal and Monetary Policy 16. Economic Growth and Development 17. Global Economics and Trade Part III: Resources 18. Resource Materials Index About the Authors vii ix 1 3 7 19 33 35 53 69 87 95 103 113 131 141 153 161 169 181 189 199 201 217 229
v
LIST
OF
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
VII
Topic (Alphabetically) Advertising: The Tricks of the Trade Better Measures of Economic Activity and Well-Being Consumer Choice Consumer Society Consumer Sovereignty Controversies and Practices in Economics Corporate Accountability Corporate Power Development Distribution of Income and Wealth in the U.S. Downsides of Competition Ecological Economics Economic Growth Economic Systems Economic Systems and Goals Employees Rights in the Workplace Employer Power Experimental Economics Federal Reserve Fiscal Policy Getting Familiar with GDP Global Distribution of Well-Being Globalization Government Outlays Government Regulation Ination
Page 99 137 44 100 63 50 107 93 188 128 89 45 184 65 67 124 116 56 166 175 134 38 190 144 151 158
vii
viii
LIST
OF
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
International Finance Labor History Labor Market Discrimination Macroeconomic Models Marginal Versus Discrete Decision Making Markets for Pollution Minimum Wage Monetary Policy Money and Banking Multinational Corporations Opportunity Costs Personal Financial Management Price Ceilings and Floors Problems with Market Allocation and Incentives Pros and Cons of Property Rights Responsible Entrepreneurship Small Businesses and Entrepreneurship Stock Market Games Supply and Demand Sweatshops Taxes Trade and Comparative Advantage Unemployment Variations in Rewards to Labor WorkFamily Issues
196 120 122 178 84 86 118 177 164 197 40 97 81 79 62 46 105 111 74 59 148 195 156 115 126
WHAT
IS
ECONOMICS?
ix
Acknowledgments
e owe thank-yous to many who helped us write this book, including our colleagues at Glendale Community College (Amber Casolari, Caroline Kaba, and Steve White) and the Global Development and Environment Institute. High school teachers who answered our questions and gave us new insight into their profession include Brian Goeselt, Simon Holzapfel, Libby Porter, and John Ruch, and all the Glendale Unied School District economics instructors who generously met with Mark after school hours. Pam Sparr read nearly every chapter, providing sage advice based on her wide-ranging teaching experience. Robin Bartlett, Tami Friedman, Adria Scharf, and Tom Schlesinger offered their expertise on selected topics as did the hardworking staff at several economics education organizations. We wish to thank the following publishers for sending us copies of their textbooks: Amsco School Publications; Glencoe/ McGraw-Hill; Globe Fearon/Pearson Learning; Holt, Rinehart and Winston; Junior Achievement; and National Textbook Company. At M.E. Sharpe, Lynn Taylor, and Nicole Cirino answered our questions promptly and always provided encouraging support. Anne Schiller gave the manuscript her keen eye for straight-forward expression, and gave Mark twenty (and counting) years of joy. Finally, our children, Sam and Julia on the West Coast, and Anne and Patrick on the East, provided wisdom about teaching and learning from the other side of the desk.
ix
PART
I Overview
INTRODUCTION
Introduction
You, we assume, are a high school teacher, assigned to teach classes in economics or to teach the subject of economics as part of some other class. You are committed to good pedagogy and to fostering real learning and critical thinking in your students. But you are also pressed for time, and, if you are like most high school economics teachers, your own educational background is more likely to be in history or another social science than in economics. Because you are (probably) not an economist, you may nd the task of mastering unfamiliar content rather daunting. You may feel less than fully competent to teach the material to your students. On the other hand, not being trained as an economist also has its advantages. You may be more likely than someone who chose to study academic economics to nd some of what you are supposed to teach a bit hard to swallow, intellectually or politically. You may have noticed that your textbook says little or nothing about economics and the environment, the distribution of income and wealth, discrimination, labor unions, globalization and the power of corporations, or other issues that might be close to your heartor that what it does say seems to be nave or one-sided. Most available textbooks are slanted toward free market, small-government solutions, reecting an increasingly conservative bias in economics curriculum materials. If you have investigated some of the online materials developed by prominent councils and foundations, you may be aware that some seem to represent a distinct political perspective (which some might describe as a little to the right of Attila the Hun). What is a dedicated and concernedbut time-constrainedteacher to do?
3
OVERVIEW
We are two economists who share a deep interest in education and somewhat critical views about the way economics is conventionally taught. Mark received his Ph.D. in economics in 1980 from the New School for Social Research in New York City, an institution well known for fostering alternative and progressive intellectual viewpoints. He teaches economics at Glendale Community College, Glendale, California. He has served on many professional panels related to economics education, and authored numerous articles on the teaching of economics. Julie had a more conventional education, receiving her Ph.D. in economics from the University of Wisconsin, Madison, in 1986, but has special concerns about the treatment of women and the natural environment. After teaching for thirteen years at universities including the University of California, Davis, she now works in a position focusing on economics education at the Global Development and Environment Institute at Tufts University. She has published many articles and books about the foundations of economic thought, as well as coauthored a college-level textbook. We have both been made aware of high school issues in our own towns through our own childrens recent experiences as students. Neither of us has, admittedly, taught at the high school level, but we hope to make the expertise we have gained within the economics profession of use to you.
THE PURPOSE
OF
THIS BOOK
This book is intended, rst of all, to help you develop your own critical understanding of some of the major currents and controversies in contemporary economics. We believe you will be able to make better choices about using the materials that are already out there and available if you understand a bit of the intellectual and political history behind what you are expected to teach. In many cases, we expect that this background will primarily serve to give you more condence about what you already know. Most textbooks, for example, teach that minimum wages are a bad idea, and that economic growth can be relied on to solve environmental problems. If you are a little skeptical about these assertions, we are on your side. We will tell you why such particular views ended up being showcased in standard teaching
INTRODUCTION
materials, and describe research that balances out the stories. We will also clarify key terms and concepts that are often poorly explained in standard textbooks. Second, we want to assist you in nding high quality, engaging materials and activities you can use in your classroom. Many textbooks do a pretty decent job of presenting usable material on at least some topics. But when they tend to neglect, distort, or inadequately explain a topic, we will point you toward resources available that can help, with a special emphasis on active-learning ideas such as small group classroom activities and case studies. Some of these resources are not only well designed pedagogically, but are also immediately available over the web at no cost. Others are in print or other media, and may only be available for a fee.
A GUIDE
TO
Part I of this book gives a general overview of high school economics education. We encourage you to read straight through these rst three chapters in order to develop a broad context for thinking about your course. Chapter 2, directly following this introduction, describes the historical development of the high school economics course, including the politics behind how curriculum standards came to be set. Chapter 3 describes the intellectual traditions that have fed into the sometimes bewildering variety of topics covered in the typical contemporary high school textbook. We particularly focus on describing the major strengths and weaknesses of neoclassical economics, the dominant perspective in most books. Part II of this book, on the other hand, should be treated much more like a reference bookyou should look up what you most urgently need and leave the rest for another time. The chapters in Part II are arranged to follow, roughly, the ow of topics in a typical textbook. You may nd that your textbook presents topics in a somewhat different order. Feel free to jump around among chapters, or use the extensive index in the back of the book to zero in on the material you need. In each chapter, we have arranged helpful commentaries, teaching suggestions, and references to resource materials. Each section contains a short commentary about the strengths and weaknesses of
OVERVIEW
the typical textbook treatment of a subject. Where applicable, the related Voluntary National Content Standard of the National Council on Economic Education (NCEE)1 is described and briey discussed. When we have found a concept or technique to be particularly inadequately explained in most high school textbooks, we have included a Hint for Clear Teaching box giving tips. Finally, each section concludes with an Activities and Resources section that lists ideas designed to enliven your classroom and help students truly come to a better understanding of economic life. We realize that between the time we write this book and you use it, web links and even sponsoring organizations may come and go, and materials may go out of print or otherwise become available. But we have tried to give you enough information that, with perhaps a little Google searching, you will be able to nd something exciting you can use. A list of Activities and Resources topics is also included at the front of this book, to help you jump straight to these materials if you so choose. New resources, updates, and changed web addresses are available at our web site, www. introducingeconomics.org. Please contact Mark at mmaier@glendale. edu if you nd a source that you would like us to add to the web site, or if you nd a correction that needs to be made. And, last but not least, Part III, Resources, is a further source of useful information. This is where you will nd a whos who of organizations involved in economics education, along with more detailed instructions on how to obtain some of the materials mentioned in the text. Good luck! And, on behalf of all high school students, present and futureand the society they will buildwe sincerely thank you for your concern and your efforts.
NOTE
1. The Voluntary National Content Standards were developed by the National Council on Economic Education in partnership with the National Association of Economic Educators and the Foundation for Teaching Economics. See Chapter 2.
WHAT IS
THE
ECONOMICS COURSE?
Based on state requirements for high school graduation, high school courses fall into four categories, for which we can estimate approximate enrollments.
7
OVERVIEW
One-semester economics course. (About 50 percent of high school economics enrollment.) Fifteen states, including the large states of California, New York, Texas, and Florida, require a high school economics course for graduation. An additional two states require economics to be offered as an elective, not a required course. Most of these states established economics courses during the early 1990s. Infused economics content. (About 35 percent of high school economics enrollment.) Many states that do not require a stand-alone economics course nonetheless mandate coverage of economics. Usually, this is in the form of integrating economics into another social studies course such as government and economics. Consumer education. (About 10 percent of high school economics enrollment.) Seven states require a course in consumer education or personal nance, an increase of three states between 2002 and 2005. In addition, thirty-eight states include personal nance in their standards for economics or social studies courses. Advanced Placement. (About 5 percent of high school economics enrollment.) Economics is one of the fastest-growing subject areas in the AP tests. In 2006, about 53,000 students took the Macroeconomics portion and 33,000 the Microeconomics portion, a more than tenfold increase from 1989 when the AP economics test was rst offered. Approximately 40 percent of students tested received an extremely qualied (5) or well qualied (4) score.
SHOULD ECONOMICS BE
STAND-ALONE COURSE?
The tension between social studies as a unied curriculum versus individual disciplines as separate courses is the subject of a longrunning dispute. A number of economics educators have advocated a stand-alone economics course on the grounds that social studies
THE HISTORY
OF
ECONOMICS
IN
HIGH SCHOOLS
teachers allegedly tend to distort economic concepts when they are part of a civics or other interdisciplinary course. As evidence they point to economics achievement tests showing that students score higher when they take a stand-alone economics course, not one integrated with social studies.1 However, the debate about a stand-alone course versus infusion of economics into social studies also has political overtones. Many leading economics educators are strong adherents of a dogmatically neoclassical approach to economics (see next chapter), to the exclusion of other ways of thinking. When such economics educators identify errors in interdisciplinary curriculum materials (or in state content standards), what they usually mean is that such materials do not sufciently emphasize the benets of free markets or the (presumed) detrimental effects of government interference. Clearly, a balanced approach would present the debate about whether a problem is best addressed by government or market solutions as an empirical and political issue, open to investigation and discussion. Such an approach would also encourage students to develop their skills in critical thinking. Unfortunately, except for efforts in New York and Massachusetts described below, there has been little attempt to present economics as a subject that calls for active applied research and informed discussion, rich in opportunities for learning and debate.
10
OVERVIEW
In fact, one study showed declining enthusiasm for economics after a high school course.3 It is unclear whether poor training for teachers is to blame, or a curriculum that is inappropriate in pedagogy or uninspiring in content.
THE HISTORY
OF
ECONOMICS
IN
HIGH SCHOOLS
11
Such extensive corporate sponsorship of teacher training and support materials raises issues of undue inuence. For example, the Bank of America underwrites the most commonly used personal nancial curriculum, while the Securities Industry Association paid for the book most often used to teach about the stock market. The JA, FTE, and NCEE materials, while often exemplary in pedagogy, should be used with care because they often present one-sided, usually very conservative, positions on important economic and political issues.
WHAT IS
THE
ROLE
OF
TEXTBOOKS?
As in other disciplines, textbooks often determine the curriculum in economics courses, creating a de facto national curriculum. Education researcher Diane Ravitch points out,
If a visitor from another nation were dropped into an American public school classroom without knowing the state or region, he or she would be likely to see the same lesson taught in the same way to children of the same age. In the most important subjects, with only a few exceptions, the textbooks and tests are indistinguishable from each other. Concentration in the educational publishing industry has meant that a few large companies supply tests and textbooks to most school districts.5
Indeed, in economics only a handful of textbooks are used across the country. The market share of each textbook is a jealously guarded trade secret, but it appears that Glencoe/McGraw-Hill dominates the market with several of the top textbooks. Amsco; Prentice Hall; Globe Fearon; Holt, Reinhart and Winston; Junior Achievement; and Thomson South-Western also participate in the market. The AP market is even more concentrated, with an estimated half of all courses using the McGraw-Hill college text by McConnell and Brue.6 High school economics textbooks differ rather little from one another in their chapter order and content coverage. All adapt a common set of materials from the standard neoclassical college introductory course, interspersed with additional sections in response to the various state requirements. The emphasis on watered-down college material means that the theoretical content of the high school textbooks tends
12
OVERVIEW
to be limited to the single viewpoint represented in neoclassical theory (see the next chapter). The high school materials are often even more navely ideological than college materials, since the theory is usually presented in only its most simplistic form. In such a stripped-down presentation, neither the theorys assumptions and limitations nor the ndings of research that might contradict the theorys predictions receives even minimal attention. Added sections on consumer nance, entrepreneurship, and labor unions, while they may be of more practical help than the neoclassical material to students in their future lives, are also often presented in a narrow or biased way.
WHAT IS
THE
ROLE
OF
STATE STANDARDS?
Textbooks and state standards have a mutually reinforcing relationship. On the one hand, existing textbooks tend to set up a canon of thought that is often absorbed into state standard-making. On the other hand, textbook publishers keep a close eye on state standards, and often market their products by demonstratingitem by itemhow their textbook satises the standards outlined by a particular state. So textbooks also evolve in response to state standards. Currently, forty-nine states and the District of Columbia have statewide ofcial course content standards for economics. Iowa, the only state without formal standards in any subject, nonetheless recognizes economics as a discipline to be covered in required social studies courses. These state standards are quite variable in quality, length, and usefulness to teachers. Standards most commonly take the form of a simple list of content and skill expectations. Illinois standards are typical of those at the minimal end in terms of quantity and quality of guidance for teachers, with only ve overall categories with sixteen outcomes including tersely worded guidelines such as analyze the impact of economic growth. On the other side of the quantity spectrum, Minnesota has fty-seven objectives. While these are too numerous to be covered in a single course, they are also vague in direction. One, for example, states describe and analyze the role of unions in the United States in the past and present. It is one of Californias standards, however, that wins the prize for ambitiousness. It asks students to describe the current economy and labor market,
THE HISTORY
OF
ECONOMICS
IN
HIGH SCHOOLS
13
including types of goods and services produced, the types of skills workers need, the effects of rapid technological change, and the impact of international competition. A professional economist would nd this task quite challenging! And that is only one of the thirty goals for the California economics curriculum. Most overly broad standards were written to satisfy state legislators trying to include all the economics that an ideal citizenry should know, with little regard to what anyone could be reasonably expected to learn (or teach!) in a one-semester course. Similar legislative political interests lead to state-specic standards such as analyze and evaluate the role of Wisconsin and the United States in the world economy, and the Texas requirement that economics courses make students understand the importance of patriotism. More helpful to teachers is the New York States 2002 core curriculum. Beginning with the premise that social study skills are not learned in isolation, but rather in context as students gather, organize, use and present information, students are asked to complete case studies, look at policy questions such as economic justice, and demonstrate an ability to identify and evaluate sources of information. A similar approach is used in the Massachusetts History and Social Science Curriculum Framework. This argues that economics lessons are best taught not as timeless abstractions but as reections on the actual choices made by individuals and communities. However, in actual practice we nd that courses in both New York and Massachusetts nonetheless follow a traditional textbook-led approach that differs little from pedagogy and content in other states.
WHAT IS
THE
ROLE
OF
NATIONAL STANDARDS?
The hodgepodge of state standards may eventually be supplanted by uniform national standards. During the 1990s, efforts were made to create voluntary standards at the national level that would guide individual states. The Goals 2000: Educate America Act of 1994 extended to economics the standards-development projects that were already under way for English, history, and science. The legislation also established a National Education Standards and Improvement Council to certify national standards. The process of drafting and certifying
14
OVERVIEW
standards, however, had by 1994 become a political powder keg. In 1992 the National Endowment for the Humanities had commissioned a project to write standards and accompanying curricular material for the eld of history. The effort was supported by George H.W. Bush administration ofcials, most notably by the NEH chair, Lynne Cheney. However, in October 1994, just as the history standards went to press with 2,600 illustrative classroom activitiesa product never before available in any social scienceCheney wrote a Wall Street Journal op-ed article criticizing the standards for alleged liberal political bias. Soon afterward, the U.S. Senate formally condemned the standards and they were withdrawn from consideration. Ironically, publicity from the Senate condemnation prompted enormous interest in the history standards, which were published by UCLAs National Center for History in the School. Within a few months 30,000 copies were sold, and 100,000 copies were sold within ten years. Despite an effort by Cheney to recall the book, the ideas were disseminated far more widely than anticipated. In 2004, Cheney renewed her battle against the books, prompting the U.S. Department of Education to destroy 300,000 pamphlets because they referred readers to the UCLA source material. Prior to the history standards brouhaha, the National Council on Economic Education (NCEE) had been designated to receive federal funding to develop economics standards. When the U.S. Senate cut off federal support, NCEE turned to private sources, receiving grants from the AT&T Foundation, the Calvin K. Kazanjian Economics Foundation, and the Foundation for Teaching Economics (whose current funders include Citigroup Foundation and HSBG-North America). In 1997, after a review by a committee of well-known economists, NCEE published the Voluntary National Content Standards in Economics. Unlike the history standards, NCEE standards went relatively unnoticed by the university academic economics community. In contrast to history, math, English, and the natural sciences, in which leading researchers and the national professional associations comment frequently on K12 instruction in their discipline, prominent scholars and associations in economics rarely address economics education, probably because of the low status teaching (as opposed to research) has within the profession. The absence of a reaction from professional economists is espe-
THE HISTORY
OF
ECONOMICS
IN
HIGH SCHOOLS
15
cially remarkable because the NCEE standards writers chose a new and potentially controversial format. Instead of an approach based on content, the format for standards in other disciplinesthe committee used the title content standards with reservationthe economics standards include what the committee termed fundamental propositions of economics. These were identied as the most important and enduring ideas and concepts of the discipline. The goal was to help students develop a method to deduce conclusions rather than to learn facts that would vary from one situation to another. In comparison with state standards that often are overly ambitious in content coverage, the focus on enduring contributions is readily justied. However, the NCEE standards committee deliberately limited the key concepts to ones taken from a single viewpoint, the neoclassical theory of economic behavior. To include other paradigms would, in the writing committees view, undermine the entire venture, causing teachers and students to abandon economics entirely out of frustration born of confusion and uncertainty.7 Thus, despite frequent disagreement and lively discussion within the professionas evidenced by the joke that laid end to end, economists still wouldnt reach a conclusionthe national standards present a particular set of concepts with no reference to alternative perspectives. Many mainstream economists, even though they take neoclassical theory as forming the core of the discipline, would say that the national standards give only an overly simplistic caricature of what they believe their eld to be about. In particular, many would be appalled at the one-sided endorsement of conservative policy recommendations prevalent in many of the classroom activities and benchmark measures that accompany the economics content standards. Leading gures in the economics profession including recent Nobel laureates Amartya Sen, George Ackerlof, Vernon Smith, and Joseph Stiglitz emphasize that doing economics requires understanding issues of information, behavior, and institutions in a way that goes beyond the neoclassical approach. Yet other economists reject the neoclassical approach entirely, and suggest that alternative theories and practices help us better understand economic behavior (see the next chapter). Students taught with the national standards will not be able to understand economic debates in the news, nor will they be inspired by the intellectual debates that make economics an exciting eld to study.
16
OVERVIEW
One other set of national standards must be mentioned. Soon after NCEE published the economics content standards, a similar private, nonprot organization, the Jump$tart Coalition, issued standards for personal nance content. Revised and updated in 2001, these standards were endorsed by NCEE as well as Junior Achievement and a number of school administrative associations. Unlike the economics standards, the consumer nance standards are content-oriented, listing twenty-six tasks students should be able to perform. Nonetheless, the personal nance standards have a political bias, in this case because they emphasize individual responsibility for nancial well-being, omitting almost entirely inequality and social factors that may constrain or inuence individual decisions. For example, the role of advertising is treated only in two sidelight classroom activities, not as a major factor in consumer decisions or one that could be subject to public regulation. Similarly, the standards make little reference to the contested origins of consumer protection laws, or to ongoing debate about the need to strengthen or weaken consumer protection.
IN
Beginning in 2006, economics is one of the subject areas tested in the National Assessment of Educational Progress (NAEP), a congressionally mandated program overseen by the U.S. National Center for Education Statistics. Administered to twelfth graders nationwide, the test will give extensive media attention to economics in the Nations Report Card already distributed for reading, writing, math, science, and history. The NAEP economics test will be based on the NCEE Voluntary National Content Standards. The steering committee that determined content for NAEP was dominated by the individuals associated with the current national standards, including representatives of conservativeleaning organizations such as Junior Achievement and the Foundation for Teaching Economics. As in the case of NCEE national standards, the NAEP Steering Committee specically wanted to avoid including historical or institutional content, instead maintaining that students have to understand basic economic principles before they can reason
THE HISTORY
OF
ECONOMICS
IN
HIGH SCHOOLS
17
logically about the economic issues that affect their lives.8 Even though NAEP is low stakes, so that no student or school suffers consequences because of their scores, the test will have an impact on the economics curriculum. Initially, NAEP scores will be reported only at the national level, but advocates of the test expect state-by-state scores as is already done for some other subjects. Once attention is focused on comparative ranking, states likely will change their standards to conform to the NCEE standards in order to improve their scores. State standards increasingly are enforced through highstakes testing of individual schools, teachers, and students. In this way, it is possible that the NCEE standards might ultimately evolve into a national curriculum. Despite the likelihood that NAEP will promote a limited approach to economics based on NCEE standards, there are some benets from national testing. For the rst time there will be extensive data available on student understanding of economics, important for researchers who previously worked with scant information. A Harris poll found that students who took a high school economics course scored signicantly better on a test of economic understanding than students with no economics background. However, levels of understanding were low even for those who had studied economics; most did not know the basic tools of monetary policy and were unable to predict the impact of exchange rates on product prices.9 NAEP data may help clarify these issues. The NAEP test is also innovative in that it deliberately avoids economics jargon and the use of graphs, instead requiring the student to apply concepts to everyday life problems in individual, business, or public contexts. Although 60 percent of the test is made up of multiple choice questions, 30 percent of the test requires short written responses and 10 percent requires an extended written response.
18
OVERVIEW
also at some of the varieties that are notably left out. Then, in Part II of this book, we examine the topics generally taught in a high school course, ordering these in a way that roughly corresponds to a typical textbook table of contents, and giving special attention to each of the NCEE standards. We hope that this material will help you explicitly recognize the debatable propositions embedded in your textbook and in the standards, and help you teach a course that is rich in historical and institutional context and in opportunities for critical thinking.
NOTES
1. William B. Walstad and Ken Rebeck, Assessing the Economic Understanding of U.S. High School Students, AEA Papers and Proceedings 91 (May 2001): 45257. 2. William B. Walstad, Economic Education in U.S. High Schools, Journal of Economic Perspectives 15 (Summer 2001): 195210. 3. J.R. Clark and William L. Davis, Does High School Economics Turn off Too Many Students? Journal of Education for Business 67 (Jan/Feb 1992): 15255. 4. Edward M. Scahill and Claire Melican, The Preparation and Experience of Advanced Placement in Economics Instructors, Journal of Economic Education 36 (Winter 2005): 9398. 5. Diane Ravitch, 50 States, 50 Standards: The Continuing Need for National Voluntary Standards in Education, Brookings Review 14 (Summer 1996): 69. 6. Scahill and Melican, The Preparation and Experience of Advanced Placement in Economics Instructors, 95. 7. John J. Sieged and Bonnie T. Meszaros, Voluntary Economics Content Standards for Americas Schools: Rationale and Development, Journal of Economic Education 29 (Spring 1998): 13949. 8. National Assessment Governing Board, U.S. Department of Education, Economics Framework for the 2006 National Assessment of Educational Progress (2005): 12. 9. Walstad and Rebeck, Assessing the Economic Understanding of U.S. High School Students, 45257.
A PRIMER
ON
MAJOR SCHOOLS
OF
ECONOMICS
19
he curriculum materials designed for high school students generally emphasize simple principles and consensus, as though all economists basically agree on what makes an economy run. This is far from true. Although there are good reasons to not get overly complicated in a basic course, you are likely to nd that at least some parts of your materials contradict each other, y in the face of what you know about the world, or fail to meet the interests of your students. In this chapter we will give a brief overview of some of the major models, schools, and emphases frequently represented in high school curriculum materials, to give you some background concerning some of the variety of views representedand not representedin the materials you use.
20
OVERVIEW
to be the most helpful aspect of their economics education, and the one they remember the longest. When presented as a human-created way of thinking about a topicthat is, as a thought experimentthe model is generally useful. It helps students identify some factors that may help explain why prices are where they are, and why they may change. The simple graphs give the students something they can hold onto as they try to puzzle out real-world economic events. The danger is that the model is sometimes presented as though the simple supply-and-demand construct really describes just how actual, real-world markets work. Often, the model is presented within a strongly neoclassical (see below) framework, as if price and quantity are always determined simply by the intersection of two curves. Such a presentation encourages students to believe that the simple theory portrayed in the graph is somehow more real and basic than theoften messy and contradictoryreal-world markets we see around us. Students may erroneously, then, come to believe that realworld factors such as customs, institutions, discrimination, poverty, power, and uncertainty do not have any effect on market behavior nor any relevance for economics in general.
A PRIMER
ON
MAJOR SCHOOLS
OF
ECONOMICS
21
economy as made up of self-regulating markets. It was popularized in university teaching through Paul Samuelsons (b. 1915) writing of a standard-setting economics textbook in 1948. This school takes a model of smoothly functioning, perfectly competitive markets as representing the centerpiece of economic analysis. In your curriculum materials, you will see this school reected in discussions of scarcity and choice, prot and utility maximization, marginal thinking, and efciency. At the core of this theory is a highly sophisticated mathematical model of general equilibrium. While the general equilibrium model itself is not taught at the high school level (since it uses high-level math), and its underlying assumptionsmany of which are highly questionableare not discussed, its inuence permeates the discussion. Professional economists have used the underlying general equilibrium model to derive a mathematical proof that, in a perfectly competitive economy, markets create the highest welfare when left to run on their own. You will likely see this argument played out in your textbook in terms of supply-anddemand diagrams showing that government interference in the form of regulations such as minimum wages or rent control causes inefciency. The school has attracted many followers because of its apparent rigor and engineering-like manner of coming up with rm conclusions presumably based on economic laws. Students who like analytical subjects, abstract thinking, and mathematics and who are pleased when they can nd unambiguous answers to problems may nd this part of the curriculum attractive and even exciting. Universitylevel microeconomics (and, increasingly, macroeconomics as well) is generally taught entirely from this perspective. The National Voluntary Content Standards for the high school economics curriculum follow a strong, simplistic neoclassical bent. The problem with this school, however, is that its central model and proofs rest on very narrow assumptions about what an economy is and how it functions. Efciency is taken as the only goal of life about which economists have anything to say, resulting in issues of fairness and human needs being much neglected. Issues of race, gender, power differences, poverty, and environmental sustainability are among other areas given short shrift. The economic functions of households and governments are downplayed. Even though more
22
OVERVIEW
attention is given to the activities of businesses, these are only studied in terms of narrow short-term prot maximization, and issues of innovation, creativity, and dynamism in the economy are neglected. Markets are discussed only in the abstract, with the actual, real-world market institutions given short shrift. Neoclassical economics, when taught to the exclusion of other views, tends to severely discourage critical thinking by students about economic life. As noted by one commentator, teaching only the concepts in the National Voluntary Content Standards can tend to make young people believe they have all the answers, thus making them easy prey to shrewd demagogues who offer easy solutions.1
A PRIMER
ON
MAJOR SCHOOLS
OF
ECONOMICS
23
levels these materials would be thought of as part of business school education (a professional career track) rather than economics (a social science program often within the liberal arts). Many high school materials contain basic factual and how-to materials concerning the legal formation of businesses (proprietorships, corporations, etc.), basic accounting practices (balance sheets and income statements), and elementary principles of marketing. Practical-minded students interested in entering business elds may nd this emphasis particularly useful and attractive. But high school instructional materials that draw on the entrepreneurial school also have several drawbacks. One is that they tend to emphasize the optimistic, creative side of creative destruction much more than the darker destruction side. The materials tend to highlight businesses that succeed through innovation and creativity, lending the materials a sort of everyone who works hard can get ahead inspirational tone. Meanwhile, they are silent on how other businesses prosper by, say, lowering wages or moving jobs overseas, or use their size and political inuence to drive out less powerful potential competitors. Because the materials often tend to emphasize small business entrepreneurship, they rarely give a realistic portrayal of how important large corporate businesses are likely to be in the future lives of your students as workers, consumers, and citizens. Sometimes the discussions take a decidedly politically libertarian, anti-government perspective (as did the founders of the theoretical school), although others present a more neutral or positive view of business-government interaction. Discussion of business ethics and responsibilities tends to be minimal. Another weakness to be aware of is that this school, similar to a number of others discussed here, tends to minimize problems of injustice, poverty, discrimination, ecological damage, and the like.
24
OVERVIEW
ian theories argue that there is an important role for active government policies to manage recessions and booms, and so avoid unnecessary unemployment and ination. Keynesian theories are generally contrasted with New Classical theories, which argue that markets can be trusted to work out these problems without government help. Inclusion of this approach in introductory economics generally gives students useful knowledge about real-world institutions (such as the Federal Reserve), some insight about the problems of economic coordination that cannot be solved by markets alone, and some insight into the difculties and dilemmas of macroeconomic policy making. Sometimes, unfortunately, the theory is presented in a thoroughly formulaic way, as if all a policy maker needed to know were the right numbers to plug into an equation or how far to shift a curve. This gives students an overly simplisticand unnecessarily dry and boringidea of what macroeconomics is really about. All Keynesians agree that scal and monetary policies, while useful, are imperfect policy tools. As a result, government intervention can steer the economy better than a hands-off classical approach, but it cannot guarantee a stable, growing economy. Other materials draw on work from a variety of Keynesian thought called New Keynesian macroeconomics. New Keynesians justify Keynesian policies while drawing from a generally neoclassical theoretical framework. Materials that draw on this school tend to portray macroeconomic problems as arising from the existence of imperfections inpresumably, otherwise smoothly workingmarkets. The implication is that government action would be unnecessary if markets worked better. Few available curriculum materials teach another variety of Keynesianism, called Post-Keynesian economics. Post-Keynesians build on John Maynard Keyness original, but often overlooked, claim that capitalist economies are inherently unstable. Keynes believed that because of true uncertainty about what the future holds, erratic swings in investment will continue to create business cycles as long as investment decisions are made in a decentralized manner by private businesses. To place the major macroeconomic views on a spectrum, you might think of New Classical economics (with its assumption of smoothly
A PRIMER
ON
MAJOR SCHOOLS
OF
ECONOMICS
25
functioning markets) as being at one pole and Post-Keynesian economics (with its assumption of inherently unstable markets) at the other. New Keynesian economics (with its assumption of imperfect markets) would be in between.
CONSUMER
Consumer economics grew out of what used to be called home economics or family economics. This focusunlike neoclassical economics, which focuses on markets, or entrepreneurial economics, which focuses on businessestakes economic well-being and decision making within households as its focus. Leaders in home/consumer economics scholarship included Margaret Reid (18961991) and Hazel Kyrk (18861957). While consumer economics is covered in many high school materials, it is only very rarely included within the curriculum of introductory college economics courses, although some universities have separate departments of consumer economics. High school materials often include useful, practical information on how to create a household budget, how to make wise choices in the use of credit, and how to recognize manipulative marketing ploys. Unlike the neoclassical school, which teaches that consumers make rational choices based on preexisting preferences, consumer economics takes seriously human failings in decision making and susceptibility to advertising. Especially as many people have increasingly found their personal spending and debt spiraling out of control, such education at the high school level has the potential to make an important direct and positive contribution to your students future quality of life. The main weakness of the presentation of consumer economics in most materials is that it takes for granted the idea that getting satisfaction from consumer spending is the sole goal of household decision making. Students are often given little chance to challenge this more is better mentality. Few textbooks address the role of advertising in creating an atmosphere of consumerism. Few textbooks seriously address the conict between high and rising consumption levels and ecological sustainability. Few textbooks go beyond analysis at the level of individual households to look at how consumer-based social movementssuch as those that
26
OVERVIEW
brought about regulation of food and drug safety (through political advocacy), or better working conditions for farm workers (through consumer boycotts), or that are trying to bring about more adequate and just incomes for farmers and artisans in poor countries (through purchase of fair trade products)have changed and will continue to change our social terrain.
LABOR HISTORY
AND
LABOR RELATIONS
Your curriculum materials may include a chapter on the history of labor unions and information on topics such as collective bargaining. As has been the case with a number of the other schools mentioned earlier, the increasing focus at the university level on the neoclassical school has forced most mention of these topics out of the university economics department curriculum. (Labor economics as taught within economics departments increasingly includes very little history and treats union organizing only as an impediment to free markets.) Important gures in the development of labor relations research in the United States include Frances Perkins (18801965) and John R. Commons (18621945). The activity of labor organization has a longer history, and remains a more important political and economic issue, in much of Europe, Latin America, and other regions of the world. Labor history and labor relations focus on the issues facing people as workers. Some curriculum materials emphasize the history of unions and of pro-labor legislation as a counterpoint to the emphasis they give to business interests in other chapters. Balanced treatments deal with both the power of large companies and the horric abuses that inspired the labor movement, and problems that have sometimes arisen when unions get too powerful or corrupt or represent entrenched groups. Other curriculum materials deal more with current rules regarding collective bargaining or with practical questions like Should I join a union? Labor relations material will particularly appeal to students from union backgrounds, or with an interest in U.S. history. Students who are especially drawn to this topic should, however, be advised to apply to university programs in labor history or labor stud-
A PRIMER
ON
MAJOR SCHOOLS
OF
ECONOMICS
27
ies or programs in a school of labor and industrial relations, rather than to economics programs per se. Sometimes the coverage of this topic may be very sketchy, or exceedingly biased in an anti-union (or, less often, pro-union) direction. Later chapters of this book will suggest materials that could help to esh out a good discussion of this topic.
OF
A number of alternative schools of economics look at the broad span of economic issues starting from assumptions that are very different from those of the neoclassical and entrepreneurial schools. One of the best known is Marxian or radical economics. Based on the work of Karl Marx (181883) and Frederick Engels (182095), the radical approach emphasizes the power that comes with the ownership and control of capital. Radical theory has traditionally asserted that laborers are exploited within a capitalist system, and that factories and land must be owned by the people as a whole for a more just society to come about. The historical results of putting all productive assets into the hands of government bureaucracies in the Soviet Union and China, however, proved very disappointing. Central planning proved far less efcient than market allocation in many spheres, and the concentration of power among political elites led to abuses. High school texts often imply that the dissolution of the Soviet Union and the increasing importance of markets in China and other Communist countries simply prove that Marx was wrong. Some contemporary radical economists, however, have adapted their theories to recent events, and no longer focus on overthrowing capitalism. Instead, they now ask how ownership of capital within market-using economies could be made to be more democratic, egalitarian, and serving of societys needs. Institutionalist economics was founded a little later than the Marxist school, and at about the same time as the neoclassical school. It emphasizes the evolving nature of economic organizations and practices, and the role of habit and social factors in guiding behavior. Early institutionalist economist Thorstein Veblen (1857
28
OVERVIEW
1929), for example, invented the term conspicuous consumption to describe spending designed to show off ones status. John R. Commons (see above, under Labor History and Labor Relations) was another founder. Institutional economists tend to reject dogmatic pro-market, pro-entrepreneur, or pro-revolution theories in favor of investigating how businesses, governments, and other social institutions can best be adapted to address evolving economic problems. During the early decades of the 1900s, institutionalist views competed strongly with neoclassical views, and were inuential in the establishment of programs such as workers compensation and Social Security. Other alternative schools are of more recent origin. One of the major problems facing contemporary societiesthat of depletion and degradation of the natural environmentis a frequent subject of discussion in classes dealing with science and/or current events. Its absence from, or trivialization within, the standard economics curriculum, then, is all the more striking. Ecological economists, however, ght this mainstream trend and do research explicitly related to our dependence on the natural world and the long-term effects our economic activities are having on the environment. Herman Daly and Robert Costanza are among the leading contemporary spokespersons for ecological economics. Mainstream economics developed during a period in which women were considered suited only for performing noneconomic activities in the home, and it was considered acceptable that women regularly be paid less than men when they took outside jobs. Feminist economists challenge these stereotypes and beliefs, and also question whether the denition and methods of economics are as objective as they are usually made to seem. Contemporary inuential feminist economists include Nancy Folbre, Diane Elson, and one of the authors of this book. Some economists currently identify themselves as social (or socio-) economists. Generally economists in this school emphasize the importance of ethics and community life, and measure an economys success in terms of the health and well-being of its individuals and communities. Nobel laureate economist Amartya Sen, for example, has proposed that economic policies should be judged according to how well they enhance peoples capabilities to lead lives they value.
A PRIMER
ON
MAJOR SCHOOLS
OF
ECONOMICS
29
This view has been adopted by many economists who take a more social or human-centered approach. Other scholars explore the way in which the moral values arising from various faith traditions (including Protestant and Catholic Christianity, Judaism, Islam, Buddhism, and others) can inuence how economies are studied and how public policies related to economic issues are formulated. Unfortunately, due to the dominance of neoclassical (and, to some extent, entrepreneurial) interests in the design of high school curriculum materials, you are unlikely to nd these views represented in a standard textbook. You will need to use the links in this bookor your own effortsif you want to bring these perspectives into your classroom.
ON
Unfortunately, the success of institutionalist, ecological, feminist, and social economists in identifying fascinating and important areas of economic research has caused neoclassical look alike schools to form. Beware of these, as they are likely to be represented in your curriculum materials! While these look alike schools generally make interesting contributions relative to narrower pure neoclassical views, their fundamentally neoclassical assumptions bias their analysis, sometimes in very strange ways. For example, the school of new institutionalist economics (as opposed to institutionalist economics) seeks to explain the formation of economic institutions. But while the old institutionalists (discussed above) emphasized the importance of social institutions and norms as economic forces to be reckoned with in their own right, and searched for ways to improve them, new institutionalists generally seek to explain the existence of such institutions using narrow models of individual, rational, utility-maximizing agents. Environmental or natural resource economics (as opposed to ecological economics) seems to look seriously at environmental issues. But consider, for example, the standard responses of such neoclassically based schools to the issue of global climate
30
OVERVIEW
change. By applying time discounting to future costs and benets, the effects of even extreme environmental damage more than a few generations out can be made to look negligible. When it comes to solutions to environmental problems, such economists tend to share the anti-regulation, small-government biases of their neoclassical colleagues. Hence, they tend to prescribe economic growth, deregulation, privatization, and the creation of new markets as the cure-alls for environmental problems. In contrast to ecological economists, who point out the delicacy of the complex ecosystem in which we live and the necessity for immediate society-wide action to avert irreversible harm, environmental and natural resource economists tend to teach complacency. When neoclassical economists look at issues related to gender or poverty, similar results often occur. While a feminist economist might look at the social and economic beliefs and constraints that tend to push women into low-paid jobs, a neoclassical analyst will ask why women choose such jobs. While a socio- or humanistic economist will look into the social, political, and institutional roots of poverty and examine both market and nonmarket solutions, a thoroughly neoclassical economist will, mantra-like, prescribe economic growth, deregulation, privatization, and the creation of new markets. So, even though your curriculum materials might contain interesting sections with titles like The Economics of Global Climate Change or Capitalism and Poverty, you still need this book. When you take a close look at what is actually in such a section, you may nd it to be narrowly neoclassical and dogmatically free market.
CONCLUSION
Unless you have a very sophisticated set of students, you are probably not going to want to present this intellectual history of the various schools of economics directly to them. But it is important for you, as a teacher and advisor, to have some idea about the sources of the ideas you are teaching. (If you do have a sophisticated group of students, you might want to lecture on this topic and distribute
A PRIMER
ON
MAJOR SCHOOLS
OF
ECONOMICS
31
a handout with the name of each school of thought at the top of a blank column. Then, as the course goes along, the students could identify the chapters or parts of chapters in their textbook that draw on particular schools.)
NOTE
1. Marianne A. Ferber, Guidelines for Pre-College Economic Education: A Critique, Feminist Economics 5(3) (1999): 13542.
PART
II
WHAT IS ECONOMICS?
35
What Is Economics?
ecall that in this and following chapters, we have arranged helpful commentaries, teaching suggestions, and references to resource materials following, roughly, the ow of topics in a typical course. You may nd that your textbook presents topics in a somewhat different order. Feel free to jump around among chapters, or use the extensive index in the back of the book to zero in on the material you need. We have also put some key terms in bold print to help draw your eye to the material you want as you skim along. Each section contains a short commentary about the strengths and weaknesses of the typical textbook treatment of a subject. Where applicable, the related National Council on Economic Educations Voluntary National Content Standards is described and briey discussed. We have found certain concepts to be particularly poorly explained in most high school textbooks, so see A Hint for Clear Teaching boxes for help on these. Finally, each section concludes with a list of possible activities that can enliven your classroom and help students truly come to understand economics. We have tried to give you enough information so that, with perhaps a little Internet searching, you will be able to nd something exciting you can use. (For updates, see our web site www.introducingeconomics.org.)
4.1 WHERE
TO
BEGIN: SCARCITY
AND
CHOICE?
Students and some instructors will be surprised that their textbooks do not begin with a discussion of money, stocks, or prots, topics most often associated with economics. Instead, textbooks dene economics as the study of scarcity based on the fact that all indi35
36
BY
CHAPTER
viduals and all economies face limited resources. It makes sense to introduce key concepts at the start of a course, and the lesson, you cant have everything, may be helpful for teenagers who often face trade-offs for the rst time in their ability to buy goods or services and the decision whether to pursue studies or a job. But many books make scarcity and choice the dening concepts of economics, to the neglect of other issues.1
NCEE Standard #1 Productive resources are limited. Therefore, people cannot have all the goods and services they want; as a result, they must choose some things and give up others. Scarcity and choice are given top billing in the National Council on Economic Educations Voluntary National Content Standards in Economics. This unduly narrows a students idea of what economics is about.
For example, an equally important concept, that of the unequal distribution of resources, is rarely mentioned in high school materials as being important to economics. Consider how different an economics class might be if it started off by pointing out the following: Resources are unequally distributed in most economies. As a result, individuals and households face quite different choices depending on their income and wealth. The fact that some people get to choose between Jaguars and Maseratis, while others have to choose between medicine and rent, is glossed over by the typical treatment and would likely be a more compelling introduction to economics than the simple observation that we all must make choices. The idea that people need basic food, shelter, clothing, and care to survive is much downplayed in most texts. (Notice that NCEE Standard #1 says nothing about needs.) In fact, many neoclassical economists go so far as to dismiss the concept of need as a meaningful economic concept on the grounds that needs are subjective,
WHAT IS ECONOMICS?
37
whereas relative wants for one item compared to another will be revealed in market demands. The mathematics behind the neoclassical theory of revealed preference is elegant. However, it rules off the tableand out of the textbookany discussion of what someone needs for a minimum standard of living. While this level changes over time and will differ from one society to another, it is certainly possible and valid to measure how well needs are being met. Some of the activities suggested below have students explore well-being indicators gathered by the United Nations and World Bank. Rather than focus on scarcity and choice, some economists suggest that economics should be dened around the topic of provisioning, or how societies organize themselves to promote survival and ourishing.
A HINT
FOR
CLEAR TEACHING
Many textbooks do not give a very clear denition of scarcity, so that students easily confuse it with situations of shortage or inadequacy. Economists use scarcity to refer to the situation in which resources are insufcient to meet all possible wants, a situation they assume exists everywhere and at all times. Economists use the term shortage, in contrast, to refer to a particular situation that might occur, in which people are not able to buy as much of some particular good as they would like, given their income and the going price. (The popularity of certain gaming consoles, for example, may contribute to shortages of them during the holiday season.) Students often confuse either or both of these with a situation of inadequacy, in which people do not get enough of something (such as food or health care) to meet their basic needs, usually because their incomes are too low. Economics textbooks rarely talk much about inadequacy.
38
BY
CHAPTER
AND
ACTIVITIES
RESOURCES
WHAT IS ECONOMICS?
39
lesson plans using If the World Were a Village available at www.education-world.com. Some available materials recommend an exercise in which students review their own purchases or reflect on other choices they have made or are likely to make in the future. (For example, Marketplace: Back-to-School Retail available at NCEEs EconEdLink, at www.econedlink.org.) You might turn this into a more expansive exercise by combining it with the above-mentioned research into variations in wealth and income asking students to imagine how their answers would be different if they had been born into a poorer community or country. The book Material World: A Global Family Portrait, by Peter Menzel (Sierra Club Books, 1995), is an excellent visual resource for helping students imagine what consumer choices are like elsewhere. In it, thirty statistically average families from around the world are photographed, accompanied by all their household possessions. A similar project focusing only on food resulted in Hungry Planet: What the World Eats, by Peter Menzel and Faith DAluiso (Ten Speed Press, 2005). The simple simulation game, Shop Till You Drop from Facing the Future (www.facingthefuture.org), may prompt discussion about access to resources and the impact of consumption on the environment. See also The Distribution of Income and Wealth in the U.S., p. 128; Development, p. 188.
AND
TRADE-OFFS
The idea that people must choose some things and give up others in Standard #1 refers, of course, to the idea that everything has a costany use of a resource, including ones time, requires forgoing using the same resource for some other purpose. The usual textbook focus on choice leads into discussion of the concepts of opportunity
40
BY
CHAPTER
AND
ACTIVITIES
RESOURCES
Opportunity Costs
For many students, the decision about college or other post-highschool plans will be a relevant application of opportunity cost with perhaps surprising results. Students could add up the costs of attending college, making certain that they take into account lost wages and promotions that would occur if they went directly to full-time employment. Even with these additional costs, for most people the monetary benets far outweigh the costs, on average by more than one million dollars over a lifetime. (Students with mathematical sophistication might learn how to reduce the value of these future earnings to their present value.) In addition to monetary costs and benets, students could explore the nonmonetary benets of college education, including job and intellectual satisfaction for oneself. The topic of positive (that is, benecial) externalities could be introduced and reinforced by looking at the social benets of an educated populace. People who are better educated tend to be more productive, healthier, and more informed about political and civic issues. Thus not only do benets accrue to the person getting the education, but also to everyone around that person.2 If this is true, people should be encouraged to buy more education than they might if they just compared costs and benets on their own. Can your students think of ways society addresses this issue? (Hint: the positive externalities argument can help to explain why governments provide free K12 education and subsidize college education.) To give a more global emphasis to the discussion of opportunity costs of education, you might look at it in the context of a very poor country. There, one factor keeping even elementary-age children out of school is the opportunity cost of their time in terms of their lost contribution to family production and income. In these societies, children are often put to work in farming, herding, small-scale manufacturing, and petty commerce. Girls, in particular, are often kept out of school if they are needed to cook,
WHAT IS ECONOMICS?
41
clean, or care for younger children. What could be done to help children get schooling in such a situation? (Hint: Besides programs to raise the families income level by other means, some schools schedule their hours around childrens work tasks, offer free meals or school uniforms to entice families to send their children, or offer child care for younger siblings.) More interesting than individual trade-offs are societal decisions about what to haveand what to give up. Your textbook may include a production possibilities curve showing the societal trade-off between guns and buttera graph that might be more understandable to those of us who remember President Johnsons 1960s promise to provide both guns (for the war in Vietnam) and butter (for social programs). Your students likely will be interested in the trade-off between resources a society wants to devote to the military and to other activities. For data on military spending by country, see the Stockholm International Peace Research Institute (www.sipri.org, registration required) and Maps of the World (www.mapsofworld.com). Students could quantify the trade-off; for example, the United Nations Development Programme at one point estimated that if developing countries reallocated just one-quarter of the funds they devoted to military spending, this would be enough to fund provision of primary health care, primary education, immunizations, safe drinking water, and family planning to all their citizens.3 cost and trade-offs. The usual examples concern decisions students may make in their daily lives. This is ne, as far as it goes, but overemphasized can reinforce students idea that its all about me. This individualistic approach neglects two very important larger concerns. The rst is that a persons decisions can have impacts that go far beyond their repercussions on him or her. The second is that we, as a society, make important decisions and trade-offs. Costs and benets that affect some party that is not directly involved in an activity are called externalities. Individuals do not necessarily take into account how their actions (like going to school or driving an SUV)
42
BY
CHAPTER
affect not only themselves, but also possibly their family, community, society as a whole, and the natural environment. As a result, they may make decisions that are not as good as they could be, from a larger and more inclusive perspective. Because dealing with externalities often requires the use of non-market institutions (for example, public policies in the form of government subsidies to education or regulation of pollution), many free market oriented textbooks neglect the topic of externalitiescovering it much more briey later in the book or not at all. In their roles as citizens and voters, students will have input into many trade-offs at the local and national level. Thinking in terms of opportunity costs can be helpful here, too. You might encourage a less individualistic view of economics by bringing consideration of externalities and social decision making into your discussions of opportunity costs.
WHAT IS ECONOMICS?
43
double any other countrys per person expenditure? Posed in this way, students can think critically about choices in a market economy. Clearly advertisers have the potential to inuence which goods or services we buy, how much we value possessions as opposed to other goals in life, and, in the case of issue advertising, what we think. Economists often take pride in showing how situations that we usually think of as not chosen can be reframed as issues of rational choice. Presumably, applying the notion of choice to surprising situations is meant to pique students interest and convince them of the power of neoclassical economic reasoning. One available lesson, for example, argues that obesity is a matter of choice.4 The activity asks why Americans, who admire the trim and slender, tend to exercise too little and eat too much. The activity concludes that Americans have made a personal choice, voluntarily trading thinness and health benets for the benets of increased passive entertainment and jobs in a service economy. The lesson to be drawn is, supposedly, that obesity will be self-regulating so that public intervention or government regulation is unnecessary. Other materials choose other examples, such as variations in birthrates across countries.5 The larger family sizes that prevail in some poor countries, for example, are sometimes presented as resulting purely from rational economic choices made in light of needs for agricultural labor or support in old age. The use of surprising cases to illustrate choice theory, however, can also be turned around and become a tool for critical thinking. Sometimes an argument that sounds shy actually is shyand students can be encouraged to be skeptical and to seek out additional sources of information when presented with questionable arguments. Even a minimal familiarity with public health scholarship on obesity, for example, shows that eating habits tend to be formed in childhood, are hard to break, and are much inuenced by the advertising and availability of high-fat and high-caloric foodsand children hardly t the model of rational individuals. To the extent that women in many poor countries have little economic power, and little access to education, medical care, or contraception, it is likewise misguided to point to family size as something they freely choose.
44
BY
CHAPTER
AND
ACTIVITIES
RESOURCES
Consumer Choice
If your materials use surprising cases like obesity or birth rates to try to show that all behavior is chosen, you can encourage your students to question the extent to which the logic of choice applies. See also Advertising: The Tricks of the Trade, p. 99; and Consumer Society, p. 100.
WHAT IS ECONOMICS?
45
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
Ecological Economics
An expanded circular ow diagram (as suggested above) can create the basis for discussion of what we get from, and put out into, the natural environment. What are some of the resources and services represented by the in arrow? What is represented by the out arrow? What happens to an economy when an inow dries up, or an outow is toxic? Are there money ows that compensate the environment for its products and services? (No.) To further bring out the importance of ecological resources to economic life, you might have your students take the Ecological Footprint Quiz available at www.myfootprint.org. The footprint is a project of Redening Progress, whose web site (www.rprogress.org) also has other useful materials on economics and ecology. The lm Whos Counting? Marilyn Waring on Sex, Lies, and Global Economics (1995) focuses on the life and ideas of a New Zealand economist and member of parliament who gained international prominence for pointing out the neglect of household production and environmental damage in standard national economic accounts. Creative Change Educational Solutions (www.creativechange. net) and the Cloud Institute for Sustainability Education (www. sustainabilityed.org) offer classroom materials and professional development programs on ecological economics. The textbook Ecological Economics: Principles and Applications, (by Joshua Farley and Herman E. Daly (Island Press, 2004), is written for the introductory level and may provide insights you can incorporate into your class. See also Better Measures of Economic Activity and WellBeing, p. 137; Markets for Pollution, p. 86.
46
BY
CHAPTER
At a minimum, whenever the standard circular ow diagram is presented, is should be embedded within a larger gure representing the natural environment, with a big in arrow representing the ow of resources and energy into human economic processes, and a big out arrow representing the ow of wastes and pollutants back into the environment. The idea that only rms (or rms and governments) are productive is also very misleading. Could an economy really function without, for example, the care that children receive in families, as well as the roads and schools provided by governments? Households contribute signicantly to the economy, even though their products may not be sold in markets, another big in arrow missing from the circular ow. Some other omissions may be more subtle. The circular ow diagram totally ignores the existence of the private nonprot sector, which includes many economically important organizations such as unions, industry associations, charitable and religious groups, as well as many schools, colleges, and hospitals. Because the diagram portrays two-way exchange in markets as economic, it misses the large role played in economic distribution by one-way transfers such as inherited wealth, passed down from generation to generation, and transfers of care and education from parents to children.
4.5 ENTREPRENEURS
Some textbooks introduce entrepreneurship as a basic factor of production right alongside the more traditional factors of land (or
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
Responsible Entrepreneurship
If your book includes a lot of stories about celebrity businesspeople, giving the impression that their success is due to their individual cleverness and risk taking, you might also encour-
WHAT IS ECONOMICS?
47
age students to notice all of the complementary resources that are needed to build a successful enterprise. An entrepreneur would get nowhere without natural resources, preexisting human capital (dependent on such things as parental investment in children and public investment in education), preexisting infrastructure (including physical infrastructure such as roads and communications, and a legal infrastructure that regularizes property and contracts), and social capital that promotes cooperation. You might use as a base for discussion the following exchange during a Bill Moyers television interview of Bill Gates, Sr. (father of the Microsoft entrepreneur and the nations wealthiest man). The subject was taxes on inheritances, and the rights and obligations of wealthy businesspeople: Moyers: Why shouldnt you be able to direct your money to where you want it to go in your will or however you want to do it? I mean, you earned it. Gates: You earned it is really a matter of you earned it with the indispensable help of your government. You earned it in this wonderful place. If youd been born in West Africa, you would not have earned it. It would not have occurred. Your wealth is a function of being an American. (Transcript at www.pbs.org/now/transcript/transcript_inheritance.html.) The web site of the organization Responsible Wealth (www. responsiblewealth.org) contains links to related media stories that could also provide good starters for classroom discussion. Not all entrepreneurial education is narrow-minded. If you are in a position to inuence your schools curriculum, you might check out the Business and Entrepreneurship Education for the 21st Century course designed by the Cloud Institute for Sustainability Education (www.sustainabilityed.org). See also Corporate Accountability, p. 107; Small Businesses and Entrepreneurship, p. 105.
48
BY
CHAPTER
natural resources), labor (or human capital), and capital (meaning physical capital, that is, buildings and machinery). It is certainly true that risk taking and innovation have contributed enormously to rapid economic development in many countries. But limiting the discussion of the sources of important innovations to private, individual entrepreneurship can give students a distorted sense of the sources of growth, change, and human well-being. Historians can certainly cite many cases in which important developments came from innovations that did not have their source in private entrepreneurial interests. Explorers who were sponsored by their governments, scientists and tinkerers who have come up with clever inventions, and pioneers in the development of public health and education are among the nonentrepreneurs who have greatly contributed to economic ourishing. In addition to natural, human, and physical capital, and possibly entrepreneurship, some social scientists now like to include social capital as an important factor of production. This term refers to factors such as mutual trust and shared values and knowledge that make people willing and able to cooperate in building a successful economy. If a society lacks social capital, people may need to expend considerable resources protecting themselves against theft (and worse), may keep their inventions and knowledge to themselves instead of letting them be shared, and may be generally uncooperative and selsh. Social capital is not created by the actions of any one individual, but is rather created by the evolution of social norms concerning such things as sharing, the work ethic, honesty, and responsibility.
4.6 ECONOMICS
AS A
SETTLED SCIENCE?
The usual focus of textbooks on the pure neoclassical model (see Chapter 3) encourages a very cut-and-dried, authoritative-seeming approach to teaching economics. Many textbooks adopt a tone that suggests to the student that economics is a set body of knowledge, and that economists are all in consensus about how rms, consumers, and markets function. The role of the student is simply to learn the facts about supply and demand, market clearing, prot maximization, and the like. Economics
WHAT IS ECONOMICS?
49
is presented as though it were a totally value-free, objective body of scientic knowledge. For those students (and instructors!) at a learning stage that allows only clear-cut, black-and-white, right-or-wrong ideas to be absorbed, such an approach may be comforting. We disagree. Presentation of economics as an unsettled science is not only honest, but more likely to grab student interest precisely because it highlights conict over important ideas. And, economics makes more sense when students recognize that the experts disagree and then explore why they disagree. Few headlines about economics can be understood without an appreciation of the logic behind competing points of view. As in the examples above on advertising, the application of economic ideas to students everyday life is enriched when students recognize competing points of view. Economists less loyal to neoclassical economics (such as many in the social, feminist, ecological, or radical schools discussed in Chapter 3) are more likely to point out that not only do many of the assumptions of the pure model not hold, but in addition the whole theoretical structure is laden with hidden normative assumptions. Efciency is held up as a goal while fairness is neglected, for example, and wants are treated as the core of consumer analysis, while needs and poverty are relegated to footnotes. The threat of irreversible harm to fragile ecological systems is shunted aside in order to focus on short-term production and prices. The presentation of economics as though every qualied economist agrees on a single answer has an ideological aspect, as well. Markets and market efciency are held up as ideals, and smallgovernment policies are shown to be best because they cause the least interference in these ideal markets. Such a view has gained strength in policy circles in recent decades, providing a dogmatic foundation for global policies advocated by the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the World Bank, and the World Trade Organization (WTO). Even many economists who were trained in neoclassical economics protest this one-answer approach. Cut-and-dried just the facts, mam pedagogy not only discourages critical thinking and debate, it also misrepresents the sort of work in which many economists engage. At the exciting frontiers of economic research, a wide variety of assumptions of the pure neoclassical model are called into
50
BY
CHAPTER
AND
ACTIVITIES
RESOURCES
WHAT IS ECONOMICS?
51
are about $15 billion per year, a difcult-to-comprehend number unless computed per household, about $135. Then, these numbers could be used to analyze the impact of McDonalds advertising expenditure, about $1.6 billion per year, or $14 per household. question, and the search is always on for new empirical evidence on subjects of dispute. For example, two recent Nobel laureates in economics (Daniel Kahneman and Vernon Dixon) have demonstrated that economic decision making is often far from rational. Even the belief that free trade encourages greater economic growtha belief that underlies IMF and World Bank policieshas been called into question by economists who are neoclassically trained but who also engage in serious empirical investigation.6 Professional economists relative neglect of high school teaching may be largely to blame for this large gap between the dynamic, ever-changing, empirically grounded practice of many economists and the cut-and-dried, out-of-date, anti-empirical approach taken in many textbooks. Many practicing economists wish that students would spend less time on blackboard theoretical models and instead be introduced much sooner to the practices and problems of data gathering and data interpretation. In this book we will provide classroom activities and assignments that fulll this goal.
NOTES
1. This denition dates back to the 1930s, when British economist Lionel Robbins asserted that economics should be about the science which studies human behavior as a relationship between scarce means which have alternative uses. (An Essay on the Nature and Signicance of Economic Science, London: Macmillan, 1935, p. 15.) 2. For information on the costs and benets of college, see The Rising Value of a College Education, The Presidency 7 (Spring 2004): 35; Closing Americas Education Gap, Wall Street Journal, May 30, 2002, p. A20; Learn More, Earn More, Lesson 9 in Focus: High School Economics (New York: National Council on Economic Education, 2001); and Invest in Yourself, Lesson 3 in Learning, Earning and Investing: High School (New York: NCEE, 2005). 3. United Nations Development Programme, Human Development Report 1994, pp. 50, 51.
52
BY
CHAPTER
4. See Unit 1, Lesson 1, of Capstone: Exemplary Lessons for High School Economics (NY: NCEE, 2003). The exercise is based on the work of politically conservative scholars T.J. Philipson and Richard A. Posner. 5. See Chapter 3, Lesson 5, Having Many Children or Few, in The Great Economics Mysteries Book: A Guide to Teaching Economic Reasoning Grades 912 (NewYork: NCEE, 2000). 6. See Dani Rodrik, Has Globalization Gone Too Far? (Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 1997); and Joseph E. Stiglitz, Globalization and Its Discontents (New York: W.W. Norton, 2003).
ECONOMIC SYSTEMS
53
Economic Systems
arly on in most textbooks is a description of the benets of a heavily market-reliant economic systemand sometimes, of the disadvantages as well. Free enterprise is the term of choice in some textbooks. Other books equate market orientation with capitalism, or use both terms. Although common in colloquial use, the term free enterprise is misleading because market systems require extensive infrastructures including laws and the means of their enforcement, social networks of trust, stable currencies and nancial systems, means of communication, and widely followed conventions of contracting and normal business behavior. Many of these can only be provided by society-wide cooperation and governmental action, so that the ideapromoted in some educational materialsthat free enterprise springs up naturally as long as government interference is minimized, is profoundly misleading. Most textbooks admit, somewhere, that no country has a purely free enterprise system; what they often fail to mention is that no country could ever have such a system, since the purely individualized and decentralized nature of idealized free market actions means they cannot, on their own, add up to a rational and functional society-wide system. Could you imagine, for example, an economy without a generally accepted form of money? To examine this issue further, we will look at some of the specifics usually emphasized in the textbook discussion of market-reliant systems: incentives, voluntariness, private property, and consumer sovereignty.
53
54
BY
CHAPTER
5.1 INCENTIVES
NCEE Standard #4 People respond predictably to positive and negative incentives. While it is important to keep incentives in mind, many textbooks overemphasize individual and nancial incentives, or imply that free marketsand free markets onlygive the incentives that lead to social well-being.
One arguable benet of a free market system is that it provides incentives, through the payment of wages and prots, for people to be productive and creative. Competitive market prices are also said to provide a better set of incentives than would government-dictated prices, since they presumably reect what consumers really want and the real resource costs of supplying a good. While market systems certainly offer some advantages regarding incentives in many cases, this story sometimes is used to overemphasize individual and nancial incentives. For example, our decisions at home, in the workplace, and in all social organizations are inuenced by a much wider range of factors than simply individual incentives. In fact, standard economics teaching emphasizing self-interested nancial reward has a self-fullling and rather scary outcome. Researchers have found that students who had studied economics were less cooperative than those who had not. They reached their conclusion by studying real-world behavior as well as behavior in the games discussed in the exercises below.1 Students who had not been exposed to the homo economicus (economic man) model were quite up-front in admitting that concerns such as fairness inuenced their actions. Economics students may be more likely to look for the rational, self-interested thing to do. In fact, as the games listed below point out, sometimes the best thing to do, even from the perspective of ones own interests, is to do the best thing for the group.
ECONOMIC SYSTEMS
55
Individual, self-interested incentives tend to be particularly problematic in the case of public goods. Your textbook probably does dene and discuss public goods at some point, but textbooks often treat them as only a minor issue. Public goods are goods that, because everyone can enjoy them and no one can be excluded from them, cannot be provided by markets. The benet from clean air or from a safe neighborhood are examples. If people act purely from individual self-interest, they will try to free rideto get the benets of the good without helping to share the costs (such as for environmental regulation or a police force). Thus, as economist Robert L. Heilbroner explains, The market has a keen ear for private wants, but a deaf ear for public needs.2 If public goods are to be provided at all, people cannot be left to follow their own individual self-interest, but must join togetherfor their own good, as a groupin a system of mandatory taxation. The question of incentives takes a distinctly ideological turn when students are encouraged to believe that government-inuenced incentives generally steer people in the wrong direction, while free enterprise incentives generally lead to socially valuable outcomes. Both these beliefs should be looked at critically. For example, do prot-making incentives for businesses cause business leaders to make decisions about pay, safety, and the environment that are always in the best interest of citizens? See the relevant discussions later in this book if your textbook uses examples of the minimum wage (p. 117), tax policy (p. 145) or the effect of government spending on interest rates (p. 143) to show that government interference with market incentives is always bad. See the discussion of competition and efciency (p. 88), regulation (p. 149), and corporations (pp. 91, 106) if your book gives the impression that prot making is always good.
5.2 VOLUNTARINESS
The idea that all parties benet from market exchange is often listed as a strong point of a free enterprise system. The ability of workers to choose where to work, of businesses to choose what to produce, and of consumers to choose what they want to buy are contrasted to command systems in which economic actors are far more constrained. Frequently, however, students are left with the
56
BY
CHAPTER
AND
ACTIVITIES
RESOURCES
Experimental Economics
A good exercise to illustrate the gap between the theory of economic man and reality is the Ultimatum Game, an experiment widely used in high-level research,3 but easily adaptable to your classroom. In this game, half the class is designated as proposers and half as responders, and each student is assigned a code number that will allow him or her to collect a reward while remaining anonymous. The proposers are told to come up with a plan for sharing a reward with a responder. In actual experiments, this is often a sum of money ($20 or more), though in the classroom it could be simulated with candy, extracredit points, or some other item of value to the students. The proposer may decide to divide the reward $19 for herself and $1 to the other person, or $10/$10, or any other combination. The proposals may be written on slips of paper along with the students code numbers, which then may be mixed up and distributed to the responders. Each responder, after receiving an offer, will write his or her code number on the paper, and the word ACCEPT or REJECT. If the proposal is rejected, neither person will get anything. The slips are turned in and the results of the experiment in terms of amounts and acceptances are written on the board and discussed. (Actual rewards can be paid out later.) The model of the economically rational self-interested decision maker would predict that the proposer would offer the responder only the minimum amount of $1 (since she is self-interested and would prefer $19 to any lesser amount) and that the responder would accept such an offer (since he is interested only in nancial rewards, and $1 is better than $0). In fact, the proposers in this game generally tend to make offers that are far closer to a 5050 split ($10/$10), and responders often reject offers that are more unbalanced than about 6040 ($12/$8). People are not just interested in monetary incentives. They also want to feel that they have been treated fairly, and are frequently willing to give up a nancial reward, if necessary,
ECONOMIC SYSTEMS
57
to express their displeasure with someone who treats them in a way they perceive as unjust. Some specic hints for how to run the Ultimatum Game in a classroom can be found at www. fte.org/capitalism/activities/ultimatum, though the instructions there are mixed with a considerable dose of narrow pro-market ideology that should be read critically.4 For an online version designed for use by college students, see: http://veconlab.econ. virginia.edu/admin.htm. The Public Good Game is similar to the Ultimatum Game, but with a twist. All participants are treated the same, and given something of value, say $10, or ten pieces of candy. They are told that they can decide how much of their money they want to contribute to a public pool. All contributions to the pool will be multiplied by some factor, and then this amount will be divided equally among all participantswhether they contributed or not. If everyone is generous toward the group, everyone will be better off than they would be if each acted selshly. For example, suppose there are ve people in a group, and they each put their entire $10 in the pool. If the amount in the pool is doubled (to $100), they will each end up with $20 (= $100/5) instead of only $10. But an individual who free rideswho acts selshly, if everyone else acts generouslywill be individually even better off. For example, if four people contribute all their money but one contributes nothing, the one who does not contribute will end up with $26 (the $10 he or she held onto, plus 1/5 of the $80 in the pool). The cooperative people will gain less (ending up with only $16 each). If many people try to free ride, anyone who contributes to the pot will actually lose money. (Again, the decisions are usually made anonymously with slips of paper, with the actual rewards given out later.) This is a good exercise to start discussion of how self-interest can get in the way of social well-being, and can lead into discussion about ways of raising funds for provision of real-world public goods such as parks, roads, education, or clean air. For an online version of voluntary contributions designed for use by college students, see: http://veconlab.econ.virginia.edu/admin.htm.
58
BY
CHAPTER
impression that because market exchange is voluntary, therefore there is something intrinsically and universally good about it. The fact that exchanges are often based on extreme imbalances of power is left out of the picture.
NCEE Standard #5 Voluntary exchange occurs only when all participating parties expect to gain. This is true for trade among individuals or organizations within a nation, and usually among individuals or organizations in different nations. That a trade is voluntary, however, does not necessarily mean that it is fair or socially desirable. Uncritical emphasis on the voluntariness of trade tends to hide issues of inequalities in power and the limited choices that an individual may have in making a trade.
If one party to an exchange has far more power than the other, the terms of the exchange might be extremely slanted. A good example is the subcontracting of apparel and shoe manufacturing in very poor countries. Name-brand corporations often pay only pennies an hour to workers in China, Vietnam, or Honduras for assembly of items that they will sell for considerable prot in the United States and other industrialized countries. Advocates of free markets will argue that this is okay because (assuming an absence of corruption and coercionwhich is not always true) the workers voluntarily take the jobs. And, in fact, the pittances paid are generally higher than what the workers could get from working in more traditional crafts or agriculture, so there is an element of truth to this argument. Critics of such corporate practices, however, point out the difference in power between the large corporations and the very many unorganized and relatively unskilled workers. Corporations have the choice to locate their production in any of a number of countries, but workers who refuse
ECONOMIC SYSTEMS
59
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
Sweatshops
Sweatshopsshops in which people work long hours doing work that has been subcontracted at a very low wagehave recently received considerable media attention. You might ask students to look at their clothing, shoes, and sports equipment to see in what country where they were made, and bring this information to class, to start off discussion. Or you may have them calculate hourly and annual wage rates based on daily wage rates. See Global Sweatshops in Rethinking Globalization: Teaching for Justice in an Unjust World (www.rethinkingschools.org) for writing assignments based on these activities. For a list of resources and teaching recommendations see Teaching About Sweatshops and Globalization, by John A. Miller, Review of Radical Political Economics 36 (2004): 32127. Public and consumer pressure has caused a number of corporations to come up with their own codes of conduct regarding subcontracted labor that students could evaluate. Are these adequate? After a widespread consumer boycott of its athletic shoes and equipment based on sweatshop issues, Nike came up with a Code of Conduct (available at www.nike.com). Organizations such as Business for Social Responsibility, at www.bsr.org, encourage companies to draw upand enforcetheir own ethical codes. Yet other organizations tend to be more critical of these efforts. For further information on the debate about corporate pledges, see Workers Rights Consortium at www.workersrights.org; Fair Labor Association at: www.fairlabor.org; and Resource Center of the Americas at www.americas.org. See also Corporate Accountability, p. 107; Development, p. 188; Employees Rights in the Workplace, p. 124; Globalization, p. 190; Multinational Corporations, p. 197.
60
BY
CHAPTER
to accept a low wage will nd that the contracts go someplace else, and so face extremely limited choices. Because of this difference in power, corporations are able to exploit workers by paying them only a tiny fraction of the value of what they make. This may be so little that the workers and their families remain severely impoverished, badly housed, and badly nourished. If the corporation engages in abusive practices such as failing to pay wages when they come due, or ring anyone who speaks out, there is often very little that impoverished workers can do about it. The critics therefore believe that the humane, fair thing to do is to share the wealth created by the productive activity in a way that gives workers a more decent standard of living. Just because an agreement is voluntary does not mean it is fair or humane. Similar arguments apply to poor countries that voluntarily sell off their natural resources (like minerals and lumber) in order to pay the interest on their foreign debt.
NCEE Standard #10 (latter part) Clearly dened and enforced property rights [are] essential to a market economy. Some of the most interesting controversies of our day, however, are about how important these really are and how extensive they should be.
There are many interesting controversies about what, exactly, people should be allowed to own and keep to themselves. The eld of
ECONOMIC SYSTEMS
61
intellectual property rights (copyrights, trademarks, and patents) is brimming with questions about the social usefulness of protecting private ownership of knowledge or creative works. Should drug companies be allowed to retain exclusive rights to produce (and sell for whatever price they choose) medicines that treat epidemic diseases like AIDS or those that might be caused by bio-terrorism? Should students be allowed to copy their favorite music for their friends without paying a royalty to the artists who recorded it? People who believe strongly in private property rights tend to argue that knowledge and art should, in fact, be marketable commodities and that copyright and patent protections should be enforced to the hilt. They argue that such rights are socially useful because they give companies an incentive to invest in research and artists an incentive to create. Others question whether current systems of patent and copyright law may in fact cause undue costs to society, and whether other systems (such as public grants for drug research, or public purchase for a at fee of the rights to produce an important drug) might better accomplish social goals. There is also considerable debate about what things people should be able to treat as property, and be able to buy and sell on markets. In fact, most societies put limits on what things people are allowed to trade. People are not allowed to sell their bodily organs, babies, or their vote, for example. If allowed, markets could certainly spring up for any of these, since some people want such items enough to pay dearly for them, and others are desperate enough for money to be willing to sell. (Some extremist neoclassical economists have gone on record as arguing that markets in such things should be allowed, and that government interference in issues like organ supply and adoption cause inefciency.) Free markets for sexual services and many recreational drugs are also generally socially frowned upon. Other markets, such as those for child labor, so-called surrogate motherhood arrangements, and prescription painkillers, are allowed but are very highly regulated. Rather than emphasize individual freedom alone, a more balanced introduction to economics will also recognize the validity and importance of societal and governmental constraints on treating certain things as tradable commodities.
62
BY
CHAPTER
AND
ACTIVITIES
RESOURCES
ECONOMIC SYSTEMS
63
The idea of consumer sovereignty also packs an ideological punch. By focusing on the idea that an idealized market system serves the interests of individual consumers, two important types of problems are pushed into the background. One is that people may have roles other than consumersuch as worker, parent, spiritual seekerwhich may not be well served by a system that focuses on consumption. A system focused on providing goods at the lowest cost may make working life miserable for the people who produce the goods, for example, while a continual ow of new video games aimed at kids may make it difcult to be an effective parent. The second problem is that the idea
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
Consumer Sovereignty
At the time of this writing, Wal-Mart is often considered to be good for consumers because of its low prices. On the other hand, unionists will point out that its wage, work-hour, and benet policies are often bad for workers compared to similar jobs elsewhere. What should be the balance between consumer and worker interests? See Employer Power, p. 116, in Chapter 10, for references and activities related to Wal-Mart. Should children enjoy full consumer sovereignty in their food choices? More specically, should soft drinks and candy be offered in school vending machines? With childhood obesity on the rise, this is a subject of considerable controversy in many school districts. The Center for Science in the Public Interest offers a School Foods Toolkit for community organizing around issues of nutrition in the schools (www.cspinet.org/schoolfoodkit) for the purpose of improving health. For a contrasting argument, see the Unit 1, Lesson 1 of Capstone: Exemplary Lessons for High School Economics (NCEE, 2003) which is based on the work of politically conservative scholars T.J. Philipson and Richard A. Posner. They treat obesity as a personal choice. See also Advertising: The Tricks of the Trade, p. 99.
64
BY
CHAPTER
of consumer sovereignty is often used to argue for a purely individualistic approach to evaluating social welfare. That is, any regulation that might arguably interfere with consumer rule, such as putting limits on who can purchase a particular drug or banning junk food from sale in schools, may be dismissed as overbearing and paternalistic. Extreme neoclassical economists sometimes make such arguments, ignoring issues of misinformation and misjudgment, public health, and the existence of social interests that go beyond the individual.
5.5 SYSTEMS
OF
TRADITION
AND
COMMAND
Most textbooks contrast market systems with systems of custom (or tradition) and systems of command (or central administration). Identifying command economies with government directives (communism or fascism), they conclude that the United States as a nation has either a primarily market economy or a mixed economy (a market economy with some role for government). The implication is that the use of tradition and command is old-fashioned and inefcient compared to the use of markets in contemporary industrialized economies.
NCEE Standard #3 Different methods can be used to allocate goods and services. People acting individually or collectively through government must choose which methods to use to allocate different kinds of goods and services. Do people really choose their economic system, or does it evolve through historyor is it thrust upon them? This standard carries a heavily neoclassical bias, implicitly assuming that (rational) people will choose (presumably) efcient market allocation, except for special cases (like provision of public goods) where they might choose to let government play a role. Real economies develop out of systems of custom, command, markets, or democratic cooperation, within a context of real social and political struggles and developments.
ECONOMIC SYSTEMS
65
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
Economic Systems
How did systems of allocation of goods and services arise in different societies? Have your students reect on what they have learned in their history classes about slavery in the United States, the Russian revolution, Castros ascendance in Cuba, the early labor movement in the United States, or the dissolution of the Soviet Union. Ask students to keep a record of their social interactions for a week. How many times do they experience a market, traditional, or a command system? Students could learn about the wide variety of mixed economic systems, many with substantially more social welfare programs than in the United States, yet nonetheless successful in the world economy. For a summary of different economies, see www. cia.gov/cia/publications/factbook and web sites for individual countries. Compare types of economies with the ranking on the United Nations Human Development Index (http://hdr.undp.org).
But such a formulation tends to understate the continuing pervasiveness of tradition and command within economies like that of the United States, and completely neglects another form of economic organization: democratic cooperation (or consent). That is, sometimes people actually get together to talk over and agree on issues of production, distribution, or environmental sustainability. Consider, for example, the internal structure of a business. On the one hand, directives are often handed down through a hierarchy from the top ofcers to the middle managers, and from the middle managers to the workers. This is an internal system of command. Oftentimes, within a business, traditional beliefs about race and gender, or about the value of different kinds of work, inuence who gets what job and how they are paid. This is an internal system of custom or tradition.
66
BY
CHAPTER
Groups of managers or groups of workers within a business may often hold meetings to try to work out issues that have come up, attempting to reach consensus or at least a majority vote about what action to take. So internal small-scale democratic and cooperative decision making also plays a role within many business organizations. Other economic organizationsfor example, households or government agenciesalso rely on a variety of modes of internal decision making. Consider an image suggested by economist Herbert Simon, who has questioned whether the image of a market economy could ever really be an accurate description. Suppose that an alien from Mars took a photo of the Earth using a special camera, Simon suggested. Suppose that with this equipment, organizations that are run along nonmarket lines (that is, by custom, command, or democratic cooperation) would show up on a photo as solid green areas. On the other hand, red lines would indicate connections through markets. Even in a country like the United States, Simon suggested, the photo would be dominated by green areas. Organizations, according to Simon, would be the dominant feature of the landscape.5
ECONOMIC SYSTEMS
67
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
elderly. Economists traditionally tend to think of the world as being divided into individual workers, who earn money, and dependents, who do not work. Neither a goal of full employment nor a goal of nancial security for those who cant work says anything about the support that caregivers need in order to be able to continue to do their crucial tasks (often in addition to holding a paid job). These goals also neglect what might seem to be the fairly obvious goal of human happiness. As discussed in Chapter 8, more consumerism does not necessarily serve this goal. While students studying economic systems are often encouraged to compare the United States to countries like China or Cuba, it can be instructive to make some comparisons between the United States and other industrialized nations, especially with regard to the priority given to broader economic goals. For example, virtually all industrialized nations ratied the Kyoto Protocol to reduce the greenhouse gas emissions causing global warmingexcept the United States. Additionally, the United States stands nearly alone in its extreme stinginess with regard to family policies (such as parental leave for childbirth or adoption, or nancial support for child care), even compared to our neighbor, Canada. While U.S. foreign aid is sizable in its dollar amount, the amount of actual humanitarian aid (as opposed
68
BY
CHAPTER
to aid related to military or strategic purposes) given by the United States, measured as a percentage of GDP, lags far behind many other countries, especially those of Scandinavia. Students may be surprised to realize that much of the rest of the world sees the United States as a swaggering bully, imposing unusually harsh treatment on the natural environment, workers, families, and the poor.
NOTES
1. Robert Frank, Thomas Gilovich, and Dennis Regan, Does Studying Economics Inhibit Cooperation? Journal of Economics Perspectives 17(2) (Spring 1993): 15971. 2. Robert L. Heilbroner, A Tune-Up for the Market, New York Times, Sept. 24, 1989, Section 6, Part 2, p. 76. 3.See Joseph Heinrich, Robert Boyd, Samuel Bowles, Colin Camerer, Ernst Fehr, and Herbert Gintis, Foundations of Human Sociality: Economic Experiments and Ethnographic Evidence from Fifteen Small-Scale Societies (New York: Oxford University Press, 2004); and Hessel Oosterbeek, Randolph Sloof, and Gijs van de Kuilen, Differences in Ultimatum Game Experiments: Evidence from a Meta-Analysis, Experimental Economics 7 (2004): 17188. 4. This web site claims, by presenting a highly selective review of the now extensive empirical evidence on the use of this game, that it shows that free markets encourage people to have a cooperative spirit. Most researchers, in contrast, take the game as showing up the limitations of traditional economic theories. Some, cited in Note 1 above, have found that individualistic free market rhetoric tends to reduce cooperativeness. 5. Herbert A. Simon, Organizations and Markets, Journal of Economic Perspectives 5 (Spring 1991): 2544.
SUPPLY, DEMAND,
AND
MARKETS
69
asic supply-and-demand (S&D) analysis is one of the fundamental parts of a standard economics courseand often the part of the course that students will remember the longest, and perhaps even find application for in real life. Being able to distinguish factors that primarily influence the demand side of the market from factors that influence the supply side, and being able to think about the likely effects on market prices of shifts in supply and demand, are important skills. The idea that prices tend to rise when demand rises or supply falls, and that prices tend to fall when demand falls or supply rises, is the main lesson to be drawn from supply-and-demand analysis. Many books also go on to discuss the more subtle issue of elasticities, or the strength of the response of quantity supplied and demanded to price changes.
TO
TEACHING SUPPLY
AND
DEMAND
Where many high school curriculum materials go overboard, however, is in teaching S&D analysis not as one way of thinking about economic phenomena (that is, as a model or thought experiment), but as if it represents the way the world works (that is, as thedirect and exclusivetruth). Supply and demand are presented as laws, and the curves are presented as if they really exist out there in the real worldas if they were something like radio frequencies, which really exist but are invisible and intangible. The job of economists or business decision makers is portrayed as one of detecting the presence and position of these curves, much like an engineer might design a device to detect and decipher radio waves. But people, societies, and the markets they develop are much more complicated, rich, alive, and
69
70
BY
CHAPTER
evolving than could ever be captured in a simple diagram, and so the analogy of S&D curves to radio waves is false. S&D analysis is a model that may help us understand a dimension of human experience, but which is not literally true.
NCEE Standard #7 Markets exist when buyers and sellers interact. This interaction determines market prices and thereby allocates scarce goods and services. This standard gives the misleading impression that prices are always determined by neutral market forces, as illustrated in simple S&D diagrams. In fact, as is discussed under the topic of monopoly, sometimes it is a supplier, not a neutral market interaction, that sets the prices at which exchanges take place. The simple S&D analysis also ignores issues of bargaining power (such as between employers and workers), discrimination, tradition, information, strategic action (such as when a supplier intentionally sells below cost to drive a competitor out of business), and costs of making transactions in markets.
While giving students some tools they can use to understand markets would be a valid purpose, many curriculum materials veer strongly in the direction of a second, less beneficent purpose: preaching to students that markets are inexorable and sacrosanct. Students are taught to put pure market forces at center stage. In the process, other forcessuch as forces of prejudice and greed; environmental forces of climate change; the quest for long-term human survival or justice; or the actions of democratic governmentsare pushed into the shadows, with the implication being that they are not really part of the core of economics. Combined with the standard economics model of perfect competition (see Chapter 7), the ideological repercussions of standard S&D analysis become even more extreme. Students are taught that
SUPPLY, DEMAND,
AND
MARKETS
71
(1) free markets lead to efficient outcomes, (2) efficiency is good, therefore (3) free markets lead to the best outcomes, and therefore (4) interference with free markets is bad. In the supply-and-demand chapters, this last message is communicated through teaching about price floors and price ceilings in a tone that suggests that they are bad for society. What is lost in this (il)logic, however, is the fact that societies can and do value things other than efficiency. A society may rightly judge that other goals, such as the alleviation of poverty or the achieving of ecological sustainability, are more important than achieving maximum market efficiency. This point is lost in materials written with a strong free market bent.
6.2 FALLACIES
IN
You will do your students a great service if you simply teach supply and demand as a model rather than as the truth, and encourage them to keep in mind goals beyond market efficiency. However, if anyone questions why you do not totally believe in the S&D model, you may want to be able to give explicit examples of why the model is just thata model, that is, a first approximation of the way the world may work that is not intended to be a perfectly truthful or direct representation of reality. Many economists have thought about this issue, and here are a few examples of such arguments.
72
BY
CHAPTER
of the what the consumer gets. Nike is not the same as a store brand. People will pay much more for a single chilled can of soda from a machine than for the identical can bought as part of a 64-pack at a warehouse store. How, in real life, then, could you find prices and quantities of a good that would exactly fit on a S&D graph? The answer isto the distress of many economists who do empirical market researchthat this is usually difficult and involves the use of many assumptions and approximations. Probably the closest realworld markets come to the textbook ideal is in the case of certain raw commodities that are rigidly standardized (for example, a particular grade of winter wheat) and traded in a standardized and centralized way (for example, on the Chicago Board of Trade). For most goods, the S&D diagram is simply a metaphor.
SUPPLY, DEMAND,
AND
MARKETS
73
save on administrative costs (relative to a bureaucratic system) ignores the fact that arranging market trades involves real costs, too. Finding information is often costly, and entering and carrying out enforceable, satisfactory agreements is often costly, too. Think about the realtor fees and legal fees involved in selling a house, for example, or how a company has to advertise for and interview potential employees, or how a contractor has to spend time and effort drawing up bids, or even just the time and effort you might expend, and how far you might have to drive, to find the exact type of shoes (or other consumer good) you want. While the Internet has decreased transaction costs for some kinds of goods, even when web shopping people often face shipping costs and the risk of costly Internet fraud. Many companies still send salespeople on costly business trips, having found that even videoconferencing is no substitute for using face-to-face interactions to market their products. The image of the market seamlessly allocating goods by price alone glosses over all these real-world issues.
Market Power
In addition, as discussed in Chapter 7, the model is usually presented as though the market in question contains many buyers and sellers
74
BY
CHAPTER
AND
ACTIVITIES
RESOURCES
Demand Auction
Bring an item to class that will be valued by all students, but will not cost so much that students will be unable to afford it. Ask students to submit bids representing the highest price they are willing to pay for the item (their reservation price). Sell the item to the highest bidder. (If you are concerned about making a profit off your students, use the proceeds to buy something for the entire class.) Use the submitted bids as data with which students can construct a demand curve.
Supply Auction
Survey students about how many hours they would be willing to work at a realistic job they might hold at various wage rates. Use the survey for data with which students can construct a supply curve.
SUPPLY, DEMAND,
AND
MARKETS
75
Market Simulations
Several sources provide paper-and-pencil market simulations in which students are given reservation demand and supply prices and then asked to negotiate with their classmates (demanders with suppliers) to strike a deal. These transactions are recorded and made public, and then subsequent rounds are held in which the price usually moves toward equilibrium. It can take quite a while for students to learn the rules, so that simulations often require at least a full hour to run. (This is a good place to point out how even the very simplest market involves transactions costs in terms of time and effort!) As a follow-up activity, allow players the opportunity to promote their individual product or combine forces with (that is, collude with) other players to try to influence prices. If some students get unlucky initial instructions that block them from trading, use this to start a discussion of the fairness of market allocation. See Lesson 3 in Focus: High School Economics (NCEE, 2003); Lesson 7 in Economics in Action (NCEE, 2003); Unit 2, Lesson 7, in Capstone: Exemplary Lessons for High School Economics (NCEE, 2003), for three different in-class market experiments. For other examples designed for use in college classrooms, but appropriate for use by high school students, see www.marietta. edu/~delemeeg/games. If you have good Internet access, consider online experiments designed for college classrooms, available without cost at http://veconlab.econ.virginia.edu/ admin.htm, and at the commercial site www.aplia.com If you will ask entrepreneurs to speak to your class, you can also use this as an opportunity to look at markets in a more realistic light. What steps do entrepreneurs actually go through in deciding how to set prices? How do they get information about their competitors? Their customers? How do they get information about their product out to their customers? What sorts of transaction costs, such as costs of information, legal fees, or costs of travel, do they incur? What is their marginal cost structureor do they even think in those terms?
76
BY
CHAPTER
that is, that the market is perfectly competitive. This is very often not the case. The point here is not that supply-and-demand analysis is useless. Your students may find it enlightening in explaining some of the movements in prices they observe in real life. The point is that while such analysis can be helpful, it is not complete. Students should not be misled by the seeming precision of the model into thinking that, because they can shift S&D curves, they know all they really need to know about real-world markets.
BY
Many textbooks discuss the merits of using market prices to allocate goods. They claim that the price mechanism gives consumers what they want, gives producers the correct incentives, reduces administrative costs (compared to a bureaucratic system), and allows economies to respond flexibly to changing conditions. As a result, students are encouraged to think that the point of intersection of S&D curves has some sort of inherent virtue, a conclusion reached in neoclassical theory if (and only if) a set of stringent assumptions are met. Students are left entirely unaware of the possible social disadvantages of relying on allocation by market prices.
NCEE Standard #8 Prices send signals and provide incentives to buyers and sellers. When supply or demand changes, market prices adjust, affecting incentives. Even for markets in which supply and demand forces are relatively strong, institutional factors (such as lack of information or long-term contracts) may mean that prices do not adjust nearly as quickly as the simple model assumes. Nor is it the case that incentives always move in ways that are socially or environmentally desirable.
SUPPLY, DEMAND,
AND
MARKETS
77
Market prices reflect what people need or want and are able to pay for. Much current pharmaceutical and medical research in the United States is market driven, for example, and concentrates on products that can be sold to people who are relatively well-off and have health insurance (including products for baldness, impotence, heartburn, and obesity). Research efforts on illnesses that disproportionately, around the globe, affect people who are poor (such as AIDS and malaria), on the other hand, are disproportionately supported by nonprofit charities and public organizations, since there is far less expectation that a company could profit from such research. This is true even though AIDS and malaria kill an enormously large number of people. Market prices reflect what consumers want only if those consumers have sufficient ability to pay. There are clear issues of distributional justice involved in using market prices to create incentives and allocate goods. Market prices also do not give individual producers the proper incentives to produce public goods. Recall from Chapter 5 that public goods are goods that, because everyone can enjoy them and no one can be excluded from them, cannot be provided by markets. Because you can only charge a price for something if you can exclude people who do not pay from enjoying it, left to its own devices the market will produce too few public goods. There is also the question of externalities (as was mentioned in Chapter 4). Not all costs and benefits of an activity are reflected in market prices. When a person drives an SUV, for example, he or she is forced by markets to pay attention to the price of gasoline, but not to the contribution the vehicles emission will make to the problem of global climate change. Likewise, producers have an incentive to manufacture SUVs if enough affluent consumers want to buy them, also ignoring the costs to the environment. People may also pollute lakes, destroy wildlife habitats, deplete important water supplies, and cause other harm when they only pay attention to market prices in making their decisions. Market flexibility has both its good sides and its bad sides. There are certainly some advantages in encouraging producers to respond to changing demands, as your textbook may outline. There are plenty of historical horror stories, for example, about producers in the Soviet Union making things that no one actually wanted,
78
BY
CHAPTER
while real needs went unmet. But people also generally want some stability, as well as flexibility. This is especially true in regard to jobs. If, instead of retraining workers to be productive in a new line of work when faced with a change in demand, a producer simply lays them off and hires elsewhere, this can be very disruptive to the lives of workers, their families, and their communities. In Europe and elsewhere the topic of labor market flexibilization (involving policies that make it easier for firms to fire workers, hire them parttime or with fewer benefits, and so on) is often viewed negatively, as infringing on peoples right to be able to make a reliable living from their labor. In financial markets, the problems caused by overly flexible prices can be even more pronounced. Speculation can cause the prices of many assets (such as stocks or foreign currencies) to fluctuate wildly, creating social and economic upheaval on a national and international scale. In product markets, people may find it very difficult to deal with the sudden price swings in necessities like food, fuel, or housing. Many times, people will enter into long-term contracts for jobs, loans, or goods and services to try to insure themselves against wild swings in prices. The problems caused by instability need to be discussed, along with the advantage of flexibility, in evaluating whether allocation by markets is a good thing. When one considers issues of distribution, public goods, externalities, transaction costs, and instability (discussed above) along with market power (an issue discussed in the next chapter), it is easy to see that there are many reasons why market allocation may not serve the social good. Many textbooks briefly consider some or all of these, calling them cases of market failure. But materials based in a free market ideology tend to slide rather quickly over this point, and follow it with a more detailed and sometimes vociferous exposition of what they call government failure, or the reasons why government action might not serve the social good either (see Chapter 12). The agenda of many textbook discussions of markets is often to promote a politically conservative agenda, rather than to provide a balanced discussion about economic issues. You can give your students a better education by presenting both sides of the story.
SUPPLY, DEMAND,
AND
MARKETS
79
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
80
BY
CHAPTER
inefficiency, seriously reduce economic well-being. The efficiency losses in these cases look dramatic (and spuriously precise) when presented in a (hypothetical) S&D diagram. For example, in the case of a price ceiling it appears that, due to movements along the (upward sloping) supply curve, the quantity supplied of the good in question will be significantly reduced. Textbooks often emphasize that interference with markets gives producers and consumers the wrong incentives. The bottom line is that price controls have a place in the curriculum out of proportion to their importance in the economy; they are neither as common as a student might think given the time spent on the issue, nor is the choice simply between inefficient price controls and a free market. While economists generally recognize that regulations on prices may have some of these undesired effects, good economists also recognize that, as a matter of policy, one has to consider (1) whether these negative effects are large enough to be worrisome, (2) whether the social good achieved by use of price ceilings or price floors makes them worthwhile, in spite of these (possible) negative effects, and (3) whether the alternative to price controls may be something other than a free market: perhaps better results could be obtained by alternative nonmarket solutions such as transferring more resources to those in need or publicly providing the good or service. Sometimes it does turn out that a price policy is misguided; in other cases, a price policy may be a reasonable way to achieve a valuable social goal. Taking the examples of rent control or limits on fuel prices, the story on these can also be turned around. You might encourage your students to consider these problems from the perspective of policy makers whose constituents include poor and elderly apartment dwellers in a northern city. Suppose a developer wants to gentrify a neighborhood and immediately triple the rents, or an oil crisis threatens to double the cost of heating fuel. In an ideal free market world, people would all be flexible enough to immediately move to a cheaper neighborhoodor a warmer climatein response to such price changes. In the real world, where moving is costlyand especially difficult for elderly peoplethe result of relying on flexibility in the face of dramatic rent and fuel price swings may be a rise in homelessness and deaths from pneumonia and exposure. Programs
SUPPLY, DEMAND,
AND
MARKETS
81
such as increased income support or aid in relocation might help such people in the long run (if it is politically feasible to get them enacted), but in the short run the bills come due every month and people may be evicted or freeze to death before such social programs can be put into practice. In such a case, limiting the level ofor the rate of increase ofrent and fuel costs, at least for a period of time, may be an eminently sensible and humane thing to do. If supply is relatively inelastic (that is, if the supply curve can be pictured as close to vertical, as is usually the case for urban housing), negative effects on the quantity supplied will be minimal. If price ceilings are accompanied by rationing, such as is the case in wartime coupon rationing or government allocations of heating oil toward colder regions, people will often understand why it might be necessary in a crisis and accept it as reasonable, as long as the method of rationing is perceived as fair. The example of the minimum wage is discussed in Chapter 10. Giving your students a more balanced view does not mean arguing that government control of prices is always better than market control of pricesit very often would not be. But better teaching does mean helping your students keep an open mind about policies and practices intended to achieve a variety of goals, of which efficiency is only one.
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
82
BY
CHAPTER
Instructional materials vary in the degree to which they discuss marginal thinking, or the idea that optimal consumer and producer decisions must be based on comparing a little bit more of this to a little bit more of that. The more neoclassical and collegepreparation-oriented a textbook is, the more likely it is to stress the concepts of marginal utility, marginal benefit, marginal cost, and marginal revenue. But the usefulness of this way of thinking is very limitedas even many mainstream economists have come to recognize.
NCEE Standard #2 Effective decision making requires comparing the additional costs of alternatives with the additional benefits. Most choices involve doing a little more or a little less of something: few choices are all or nothing decisions. But very many choices are about distinctly different options, rather than just about quantities. This standard tries to make neoclassical marginal thinking appear more important than it is.
Your student decides whether to study to be a mechanic or a vocalist. A manufacturer decides whether to open a new plant in Illinois or in Mexico. Even at the grocery store you need to choose one brand or another. These are all decisions about what activity to do, not simply decisions about how much of particular, preselected activities to do. Such decisions between qualitatively different options are sometimes referred to as discrete decisions. Why, then, do many textbooks emphasize marginal thinking and marginal decisions? The simple answer is that the mathematical technique that underlies the neoclassical model can shed light only on incremental decisions, and is not helpful for yes/no decisions even if they are of major importance.1 One is reminded of the story
SUPPLY, DEMAND,
AND
MARKETS
83
of the drunk who looked for his keys under the lamppost because that is where the light was, even though he had dropped them in the alley. Because neoclassical theory has little to say about nonmarginal decisions, students are told that such decisions are few and not important. While it would not hurt your students to master the concept of making decisions at the margin, neither will your students be particularly handicapped if you choose to cover this topic quickly or even skip it. The one exception is if you are teaching an Advanced Placement course modeled on the standard collegevery neoclassicalcurriculum, since the AP exam is heavily weighted toward this topic. If you choose to teach marginal thinking, you will need to be careful not to endorse the idea that marginal thinking is the crucial key to understanding real-world economic behavior. You can have students practice with cases in which such decision making is appropriate (such as whether to study an extra hour before a test), but also raise their awareness about discrete cases where it is not appropriate (such as deciding which class to take). For example, it is plausible that marginal thinking might be applied to the quantity of French fries a student eats for lunch. In this case, we do make decisions at the margin: eating one more fry will not make a difference although the cumulative effect of many such decisions could be harmful to our health. We face many similar situationshow long to exercise, whether to study the extra hour, or how much to give to a favorite charityin which it is important to pay attention to decisions at the margin. However, by focusing only on the margin, we miss what could be more important decisions such as the discrete choice to eat French fries at all, a behavior influenced by habit, advertising, and the availability of alternatives. Students might differentiate between these bigger questions and those that take place at the margin. Sometimes economics students imagine that businesspeople spend their time graphing marginal cost and revenue curves and solving for optimal quantitieswhen nothing could be further from the truth. Standard instruction tends to make students confused about how abstract theory (such as S&D diagrams and marginal thinking) relates to the real world.
84
BY
CHAPTER
AND
ACTIVITIES
RESOURCES
FOR
POLLUTION
AND
Teaching materials usually neglect the issue of environmental externalities when showcasing the merits of markets, although the issue is usually raised somewhere in the bookoften as a minor issue or in a very late chapter. Then, when the issue of environmental externalities is raised, the textbooks often suggest that environmental (and many other) problems, rather than being the result of too much reliance on free markets, are caused by a lack of markets. They propose market solutions to environmental problems. For example, instead of the government directly regulating the number of gallons of a pollutant that are dumped into a lake (for example, by declaring a maximum
SUPPLY, DEMAND,
AND
MARKETS
85
limit for each industrial plant, monitoring emissions, and imposing fines for illegal dumping), the lake might be privatized. People would then have to pay on a market to use the lake as a place to dump waste. Presumably, now that dumping is costly rather than free, people will dump less. Or a market may be created for pollution permits, as now exist for certain kinds of industrial emissions in the United States. While such a solution seems elegantly in line with pro-market ideology, and in some cases can work effectively, it ignores the very real question of transaction costs (discussed above). In the case of pollution permits, for example, to get the desired results a mechanism for issuing and trading the permits has to be set up and the correct number of permits to issue has to be determined. The more difficult these tasks are, the more costly the process may be and the longer it may be before pollution is actually reduced. Just the economic studies required could take years. Arguments for using a market approach may simply be a smokescreen for creating deliberate delays, to the advantage of the polluting industries. While there are advantages to using prices, taking both advantages and disadvantages of a marketfor-pollution approach into account, it is not hard to see that in some cases immediate, direct regulation of pollution levels may be a more effective and socially useful approach. Many educational materials also try to make environmental regulations look bad by insisting that government policies prove themselves in rigorous cost-benefit terms before any action can be taken. Some NCEE and corporate-sponsored materials related to the concept of marginal benefits and costs refer to environmental policy and the optimal level of pollution. The starting point of each of these lessons is to ridicule what they portray as a commonly held citizen insistence on zero pollution. Marginal cost-benefit analysis suggests that such a goal would be inordinately costly, so that some pollution is to be preferred up to the point at which the marginal cost of reducing pollution falls below the marginal benefit. Such materials use this not-all-pollution-is-bad argument to conclude that we should be skeptical about clean air and water and recycling programs. However, this analysis is irrelevant for many environmental problems for which benefits of environmental protection programs would far outweigh the costs of implementing policies. In such cases, what is often needed is decisive and immediate action. Arguing that
86
BY
CHAPTER
policies should be fine-tuned into just the right balance of marginal benefit and marginal cost before they are implemented can sometimes be simply a stalling tactic employed by powerful polluting industries and their political allies, allowing them to continue their damaging practices. While in an ideal world comparisons of benefits and costs would be instantaneously made and perfectly accurate, in the real world such studies take time and are often rife with controversy. Too great an emphasis on economic rationality can lead to social and environmental irrationality. The best (the ideal of the perfect costbenefit analysis) can sometimes be the enemy of the good (actually getting something done about a critical problem).
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
NOTE
1. Even though the model is not taught using calculus in classes at this level, the concept of comparing marginal this and that follows directly from the mathematical concept of the derivative. For marginal thinking to validly apply to even the narrow case of decision making about the quantity of an activity to engage in, many other assumptions concerning preferences or technology also have to hold.
COMPETITION
AND
MONOPOLY
87
ost textbooks include some discussion of market competition versus monopoly, overemphasizing the case of perfect competition (in which there are many small sellers and buyers, easy entry and exit, all units of the product are identical, and everyone has good information). By presenting competitive markets first and extolling their virtues of efficiency and lower prices, textbooks give the false impression that all or most markets are highly competitive. Some texts include a taxonomy of the gradation from perfect competition to monopoly (one seller) and include the case of oligopoly (a few firms dominate a market), but the books offer no model to describe this last casewhen in fact oligopolies dominate modern capitalism. Consider starting off this section of the course by explaining that varying market structures exist side by side in the global economy. Highly competitive markets, such as for many agricultural products and financial products (stocks, bonds, foreign exchange), approximate the competitive market model. At the other extreme, most utilities are government-regulated monopolies and a few firms such as Microsoft maintain a near monopoly in individual markets. However, the stylized models of competition and monopoly have little to say about the conglomerate, mega-sized, transnational corporations that now dominate many industries. Technically, most are not monopolies because no single firm has the entire market in, say, soft drinks, automobiles, or oil. You will do your students a great service if you can give them an accurate picture of contemporary global markets, in which pockets of intensely competitive small firms exist alongside an economic structure dominated by large, oligopolistic firms that have great powernot only in terms of being able to set the prices of their products, but also politically and culturallyeven if they are not monopolies.
87
88
BY
CHAPTER
NCEE Standard #9 Competition among sellers lowers costs and prices, and encourages producers to produce more of what consumers are willing and able to buy. Competition among buyers increases prices and allocates goods and services to those people who are willing and able to pay the most for them. Amazingly, except for a brief mention of collusion in one accompanying benchmark, issues of market power are mentioned nowhere in the NCEE standards. If one learned about economics from the standards alone, one would think that all markets are highly competitive! This reinforces the romanticization of the small entrepreneur that lies behind many high school curriculum materials. A historical or institutionally based standard might state, in contrast, that concentration of power, most notably in large transnational corporations, can restrict competition and lead to attempts to control consumer demand through advertising. In addition, the standards do not mention the possible social costs of unregulated competition.
COMPETITION
AND
MONOPOLY
89
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
Competition is not always a good thing. If it is especially excessive, overheated, and concentrated on putting financial concerns above all other goals, it can, in fact, cause serious problems. This is especially true when competition among producers results in what is called a race to the bottom. Yes, competition can lead to cost-cutting, but is this always a good thing? Going for the lowest costs may, in unregulated competition, mean hiring eight-year-old children in Pakistan or Vietnam as assembly line workers, for ten-hour days. Production costs can also be lowered if you can dump your mercury-laced waste products into a nearby river for free, instead of paying for cleaner disposal. Countries around the world may race to the bottom in setting lower taxes, looser environmental standards, and weaker workers rights in order to compete with each other in attracting businesses and the jobs they can bring. Cities and states within the United States compete with each other in awarding tax breaks and subsidies to companies (and sports teams) that threaten to relocate elsewhere if their demands are not met. Food and drug manufacturers may compete by cutting the quality of
90
BY
CHAPTER
A HINT FOR CLEAR TEACHING Textbooks do not usually deal with students preconceptions about competitionand much confusion may result. If your students take a business view, for example, they may come to class thinking that competition refers to how rms plot and create strategies to try to beat out other rms and rise to a dominant position in their industry. On the other hand, many concerned citizens have a very negative view about competition, identifying it as the force that makes many businesses fail, cut wages, or move overseas. Your textbooks treatment of competition probably reects neither of these views. Neoclassical economic theory talks only about passive, neutral market forcesnot active business strategiesand presents a positive view of competition. What is a student to think? An analogy to sports may help sort out these problems of language. Businesses are like the individual teamstheir interest is in trying to become the winner. The concerned citizen is like a fan who is disgusted if an excessive desire for the trophy causes the teams to cheat and act unethically. The traditional economist, in contrast, takes a view more analogous to that of a sports leagues administrating board or commissioner. The leagues administrators want to make sure that the teams are of equal enough strength that the season will be interesting and the teams will be motivated to play well. Likewise, neoclassical economists believe that if rms are many, small, and have to work hard to stay even with each other, good things will result. Institutional and social economists are likely to further emphasize the importance of having socially benecial rules of the game, while social and feminist economists urge us to take into account people who, due to different levels of resources, abilities, or caring responsibilities, nd it more difcult to play.
COMPETITION
AND
MONOPOLY
91
their goods in ways that cannot be easily detected by consumers. Many governmental regulations and international negotiations are designed to put a limit on just how low such a competitive race can goin order to preserve (rather than interfere with, as your text may say) the socially beneficial potential of responsible market activities. Competition among buyers is not always beneficial, either. As noted in the NCEE standard, competition among buyers can raise prices by awarding the goods to those with the greatest ability to pay. When the goods in question are basic goods required for survival, however, this is not necessarily a good thing. In a time of shortage, competition among buyers may cause prices of basic foodstuffs and fuel to be bid up beyond what poorer people can payas has often happened in countries of the global South. As a result, rich people may be able to feed grain to their livestock, for example, at the same time that poor children starve. Buyers who can get some market powerperhaps by forming consumer cooperatives or advocating for government-backed commodity boardsmay be better able to survive in such circumstances. Or government action to raise the ability to pay of poorer consumers may be needed. This is not to say that competition is always harmful or that governments do not have to pay attention to market incentives when designing programs, but only that competitive markets are not always the ideal way to address basic human needs.
AND
CORPORATE POWER
Market power exists whenever firms are not at the complete mercy of competitive market forces. Firms with market power do not simply have to take the prices set by the market as givens, but instead exert some degree of control over the markets in which they trade. By starting with the assumption that the economy consists of small entrepreneurial firms interacting on perfectly competitive markets, many textbooks end up downplaying the extent and negative consequences of market power. Since, in fact, the presence of market power destroys (or strongly modifies) the claims that free markets bring us low prices, efficiency, innovation, and what the consumer wants, writers of very conservative educational materials have good reason
92
BY
CHAPTER
to try to keep the issue under wraps. Sometimes when market power is addressed, it is blamed on government intervention. For example, some texts emphasize the cases where monopolies are caused by the government issuing licenses or permits, as for taxi cabs, or rights to local markets, as with cable TV. This bolsters the conservative argument that things only go wrong when the government interferes. Textbooks usually describe a list of cases of market imperfection: monopolistic competition, oligopoly, and monopoly. Often these theoretical descriptions are so brief and dry that students may have trouble understanding them. While the existence of market power means that markets do not have all the socially beneficial properties often attributed to them, the student often loses this crucially important forest point in the trees of various assumptions and models. Rarely is it emphasized that oligopolistic enterpriseslarge companies that each control significant shares of the markets in which they participateare now a very significant feature of the economic landscape. Most companies that your students could list by nameNike, FedEx, Wal-Mart, Coca-Cola, and the likeoperate in oligopoly markets. Moreover, since many large corporations are conglomerates that buy and sell in many markets, the neoclassical focus on price-setting in individual markets does not really begin to touch on all the ways that powerful corporations affect our lives. The huge absolute size of many corporations is rarely discussed or put in perspective, in standard teaching materials. You will give your students a more accurate picture of how firms and markets behaveand also probably better capture their interestif you include some debates about the social, political, and economic roles of large corporations in your course. Textbook materials rarely spend much space discussing the role of advertising and corporate sponsorship on consumer aspirations. The global reach of transnational corporations often barely merits a mention. The political power wielded by large corporations through lobbying and political contributions, and the ability of large companies to strong-arm communities and even national governments into making concessions on taxes and regulations, or to pressure their suppliers (often smaller, more competitive firms) into concessions on prices (see race to the bottom, p. 89), are not usually discussed at length.
COMPETITION
AND
MONOPOLY
93
Most textbooks give an obligatory nod toward antitrust policy, usually with an extensive list of U.S. legislation, including detail that only an antitrust lawyer needs to know. Instead, students will be helped by an understanding of the historical context in which antitrust laws were first enacted to counter railroad, steel, oil, and bank monopoly power, but then not necessarily enforced because of these industries political clout. Similarly, today antitrust depends on the political context in which statutes are sometimes enforced, or as in recent years, set aside in favor of a laissez-faire attitude toward corporate power. Textbooks often define horizontal, vertical, and conglomerate mergers, a taxonomy missing from college-level courses, but in fact quite useful for understanding corporate power. Horizontal mergers between firms in the same line of business are the most frequent today, and the merger type that most commonly receives antitrust attention (that is, if government policy tilts toward enforcement). However, vertical mergers (such as media content providers and media outlets) and conglomerate mergers (such as banking and insurance companies) create the potential for ever-greater political power, an issue absent from textbooks but clearly relevant if students are to make informed decisions as citizens in a modern economy.
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
Corporate Power
Corporate web sites now yield an abundance of material about corporate size, product lines, organization, geographic spread, history, and (stated) policies. Have your students research a single large company that is of interest to them. Does it sell one product or many products? Is it really a company on its own, or is it part of a large corporate family? How many employees does it have? What countries does it operate in? Business magazines such as Fortune or BusinessWeek compile information about many companies, both in their print issues
94
BY
CHAPTER
and on their web sites. Have students use such sources to research questions such as Which are the five largest companies in the United States? In the world? Organizations such as CorpWatch (www.corpwatch.org) and Public Citizen (www.citizen.org) and online magazines such as Multinational Monitor (http://multinationalmonitor.org) take a critical view of corporations, and seek to document cases of corporate abuse. Have your students research and discuss one such case. TeachableMoment (www.teachablemoment.org/high/walmart. html) offers curriculum materials that have students look at Wal-Mart, and its relations with consumers, workers, and suppliers. Ask students to find recent examples of mergers or acquisitions either reported in the media or known from their own community. Students could identify mergers by type and explore the impact of the new, larger firm on consumers, workers, and competing firms. See also Corporate Accountability, p. 107; Employer Power, p. 116; Multinational Corporations, p. 197; Responsible Entrepreneurship, p. 46.
CONSUMER EDUCATION
95
Consumer Education
onsumer education is not part of the traditional college economics course, nor is it a sub-discipline with much recognition or prestige within the economics profession. However, it is a topic covered in detail in many high school textbooks and required as part of many state standards (see Chapter 2). Consumer education can be justied as service to students because of its great practical use.
96
BY
CHAPTER
A HINT
FOR
CLEAR TEACHING
Descriptions of consumer interest rates often are confusing in textbooks because the loan rates are complex and lenders often prefer it that way. Federal and state disclosure notwithstanding, lenders would rather not let consumers fully understand their loans, for example, recently lobbying against a rule that would require disclosure about how long it will take a borrower to pay off a loan at the minimum payment level. Particularly bewildering to students and consumers is the APR (annual percentage rate), an effort to standardize reporting of interest rates but in practice varyingly applied. If your students are up to the challenge, you might consider teaching the mathematics behind the APR. Otherwise it is only necessary for consumers to know that the APR takes into account the fact that a loan may have up-front fees in addition to interest payments. More important for students than the math behind the APR is the potentially explosive cost of compound interest. Almost always it is a good idea to pay off credit cards before interest accrues, while large home and education loans may require professional advice in order to understand their interest rates. Students should be aware of interest rate traps facing an individual consumer, and at the same time learn about collective activism through consumer groups, political parties, or labor unions that is needed to improve disclosure rules, cut back on overly aggressive credit card campaigns, and enact regulations to help consumers make wise decisions.
of intense lobbying by nancial institutions. Students could research the political context of that legislation, or other issues related to consumer rights, to get a broader sense of how economic issues are often the focus of intense political pressure and lobbying. Such research might also encourage students to take a less passive approach
CONSUMER EDUCATION
97
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
98
BY
CHAPTER
for consumers, who are generally better off avoiding paying high credit card interest rates entirely, if possible. To put consumer issues in a larger political context, have students research a current abuse or legislative issue of concern to consumer information and advocacy groups, such as the National Consumers League (www.nclnet.org) or Consumers Union (www.consumerreports.org). Have students research the Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention and Consumer Protection Act of 2005. Who lobbied for it? What do consumer advocacy groups say about it? Did it really result in increased consumer protection, or was that name put on it as a political ploy? For resources and activities regarding Social Security, see Government Outlays, p. 144. to consumer issues, and consider the importance of organizing in a collective manner to improve situations when needed. In college-oriented materials, consumer education is generally omitted, with the only mention of consumer-relevant issues coming in chapters about government (regulations for consumer protection) or nancial markets (descriptions of stocks and bonds). If your materials are weak on this issue, you may supplement them with some of the resources listed below.
8.2 ADVERTISING
Some textbooks give considerable attention to the psychological techniques, such as appeals to identication with celebrities, that marketers use to sell products. Such discussion can be a very important consciousness raising exercise for students, helping enable them to notice how they are being manipulated, and perhaps empowering them to make more thoughtful choices. If your materials are weak on this issue, you may supplement them with some of the resources listed below.
CONSUMER EDUCATION
99
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
100
BY
CHAPTER
AND
ACTIVITIES
RESOURCES
Consumer Society
Are there trade-offs in happiness or environmental degradation from increased consumption? You might show the television special Afuenza (1997). An accompanying web site (www. pbs.org/kcts/afuenza) provides related course activities. You might make use of passages from the books Luxury Fever by Robert Frank (Princeton University Press, 2000) or The Overspent American: Why We Want What We Dont Need by Juliet Schor (Harper Perennial, 1998). The video The Overspent American (2004), based on the book by Juliet Schor, is available from the Media Education Foundation (www. mediaed.org). For additional readings and statistics on Kids and Commercialism, see New American Dream at www.newdream. org/kids. On commercialism and the environment, see the lm Advertising and the End of the World (1998), also available from the Media Education Foundation. A teaching module entitled Consumption and the Consumer Society is available from the Global Development and Environment Institute (www.gdae.org, in the Educational Materials section). Including a reading and discussion questions, the module addresses the historical development of consumer society, the relationship between consumption and well-being, and the ecological impact of consumption. While designed for a college course, it is nontechnical and could be adapted for high school use. Does afuence give us happiness? Have your students read and discuss the article Consumerism and Its Discontents,
CONSUMER EDUCATION
101
available on the web site of the American Psychological Association (www.apa.org). There is now a whole social science research area on the question of what, really, makes us happy. See the World Database of Happiness (http://worlddatabaseofhappiness.eur.nl) for more information. See also Global Distribution of Well-Being, p. 38; Ecological Economics, p. 45.
8.3 CONSUMERISM
The topic of consumerist values is very rarely raised in economics curricula, even though is of primary importance for human happiness and the survival of life on the planet! Does consuming more really make us happy? Survey research casts doubt on that proposition. For example, 35 percent of respondents to a U.S. survey taken in 1957 responded that they were very happy. While the purchasing power commanded by the average U.S. citizen roughly doubled between 1957 and 1998, the proportion very happy in 1998 fell slightly, to 32 percent. Cross-national comparisons of peoples expressed satisfaction also show relatively little relation to income or wealth. Having good relationships with friends and family, being able to help others, and having interesting work often rank much higher than wealth in peoples ideas of what is most necessary to have a good life. And what does striving for a consumerist lifestyle mean for global inequalities and environmental sustainability? The average U.S. resident, in a year, consumes 269 pounds of meat, uses 605 pounds of paper, and uses energy equivalent to 8 metric tons of oil. In the United States, there is about one passenger car for every two people. In contrast, developing countries have, on average, about one passenger car for every sixty-eight people.* Analysts suggest that get *Statistics are from the World Resource Institute database, 2001.
102
BY
CHAPTER
ting everyone in the world to the average U.S. level of consumption would require an extra two to four planets to supply resources and absorb waste. Teens are currently the target of aggressive advertising campaigns promoting consumerism, but at the same time are often very concerned about what the world will be like in their future. Your class could be a great opportunity to raise these issues.
BUSINESS EDUCATION
103
Business Education
extbooks vary by the degree to which they explore business topics such as the legal forms of business ownership, basic accounting, business-related regulations, or how the stock market works. Some of this material may be useful to your students, in a practical sense if they work in the business world, or as citizens who need to understand how businesses operate and how they are regulated. But oftentimes chapters on business are also loaded with conservative ideology, giving your students a distorted view of the world.
OF
SMALL BUSINESSES
AND
ENTREPRENEURS
The significance of small-business entrepreneurship is often overplayed in high school textbooks. Students are frequently given the impression that small businesses are the major players in the contemporary U.S. economy, and they are encouraged to engage in projects that simulate the creation of a small business. But this impression is not based in fact. For example, the Junior Achievement (JA) curriculum claims that small businesses employ more people than all other businesses combined and an accompanying chart claims that 54.6 percent of employees work for companies with fewer than 100 workers.1 But the definition of company used in JAs chart is what is called an establishment, which is a single location at which business is performed, even if this particular location is owned by a much larger firm. For example, each local branch of the Bank of America is counted as a separate establishment even though the Bank of America overall employs in excess of 150,000
103
104
BY
CHAPTER
NCEE Standard #14 Entrepreneurs are people who take the risks of organizing productive resources to make goods and services. Prot is an important incentive that leads entrepreneurs to accept the risks of business failure. This standard emphasizes the role of individually owned small businesses in the U.S. economy. Although many students will be familiar with such businesses in their own communities, most U.S. output comes from large corporations, as does most innovation and investment. A standard more accurately describing the U.S. economy would state: Businesses organize productive resources, and obtain profits by providing goods and services. Many small-business owners nd that prots are the incentive for their hard work, innovation, and the risk they take on. Large corporations have more options about how prots are distributedto shareholders; to keep as retained earnings to reinvest in research and development, new equipment, etc.; to pay as bonuses to executives; or to use to acquire other rms.
workers. When you or your students picture a small entrepreneurial business, a huge company that just happens to have multiple locations is probably not what you have in mind! A better way to characterize employment is to use another table in the Statistical Abstract of the United States that lists employment by firms of various sizes, where a firm includes all establishments owned by the company. (For example, all of the Bank of America is one firm.) By this definition, only about 38 percent of business employees work for companies with less than 100 employees.2 About half of employees of businesses work for firms with 500 or more employees. Many on both the political right and the political left envision the ideal economy as one primarily made up of small, local enterprises. And small, local enterprises do play a role in the U.S. economy. But the current reality is that if your students go on to work in business,
BUSINESS EDUCATION
105
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
106
BY
CHAPTER
they are unlikely to end up working in a company that is small, entrepreneurial, and innovative. They are much more likely to end up as a member of a very large organization. One more word on innovation: while many textbooks stress smallbusiness innovations, much research and design goes on in larger businesses, nonprofit organizations, and the government. Federal and state spending on university research, for example, has been the original source of many technological breakthroughs, which have later been patented and become the basis of commercial products. The Internet, while it has now become the base for massive flows of commerce, originated at the (government) National Science Foundation and initially included only related universities. Innovation may indeed be very important for business success, but it is not the case that businesses are the only source of innovation.
AND
THEIR RESPONSIBILITIES
Many textbooks paint a rosy picture of corporations, claiming that they generate productivity and growth, and that the profit incentive causes their leaders to engage in activities that serve the social good. Regulation of corporations is often presented in a negative light, as something that is nearly always excessive and gets in the way of the good things corporations can bring us. In the real world, many on both the political right and the political left are leery of corporate power. Some worry that large corporations strangle small businesses, discourage real innovation (to protect their own product lines), and, perhapsin league with big governmentfind ways to suppress free trade and individual liberty. Others worry that the predominance of large corporations takes control away from local communities and workers, and that mindless profiteering leads to manipulation of consumers and the overexploitation of the natural environment. Many people including both workers and shareholdersare appalled at the size of many CEO salaries, the pace of corporate mergers, and the lack of ethics too often demonstrated by corporate leaders. People from all political perspectives worry that corporate lobbying may subvert the democratic political process.
BUSINESS EDUCATION
107
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
Corporate Accountability
For critical perspectives on corporations, see the web sites of the AFL-CIO at www.acio.org/corporatewatch, and Public Citizen at www.citizen.org. The feature-length lm The Corporation (Zeitgeist Films, 2004) also gives a critical view. For movements to increase corporate social responsibility, see the Interfaith Center on Corporate Responsibility at www.iccr. org, Ceres at www.ceres.org, and the Social Venture Network at www.svn.org. Since Enron and similar scandals, there has been an increased push for education on business ethics at business schools. Some materials, such as articles at www.caseplace.org (sponsored by the Aspen Institute), may be adaptable for high school use. See also Corporate Power, p. 93; Responsible Entrepreneurship, p. 46. Many proposals have been made to try to steer corporate activities to better serve social goals. Some of these involve, yes, regulations. After accounting scandals at Enron, Global Crossing, and many other companies, there was, for example, a great outcry from many for greater securities regulation and standardization of corporate financial reporting. Even the business community does not want a free-for-all when it comes to the provision of information on which investment decisions are made. Some proposals go further, suggesting that corporations adopt accounting practices that track environmental and social, as well as financial, goals. Some business schools are changing their curricula to give more attention to corporate responsibility and business ethics.
108
BY
CHAPTER
Of course, some people believe that large corporations are themselves a problem, and should be dissolved into smaller entities or replaced with systems of worker ownership. Whatever views you decide to present to your students, you should be aware that there is much more discussion going on about the social value of corporations than you will find in the pages of a standard high school textbook.
BUSINESS EDUCATION
109
Before introducing a stock market game, we recommend that you think carefully about what it will teach your students. Clearly they are enticing, because students experience the feel of real-world finance, tallying their gains as they buy and sell stock at prices relayed electronically from the real-life stock exchanges. And, the games are attractive for teachers because corporate-sponsored simulations come with complete lesson plans, worksheets, professional advice from real stockbrokers, and even cash prizes. But stock market games and their accompanying curriculum guides present a one-sided picture of Wall Street, in which everyone starts out rich and all that matters is short-term profits. Omitting the less attractive side of the stock market fits conveniently with the corporate underwriters viewpoint, but it is poor training for future citizens and investors. Nearly all games follow a common script. Students begin with a tidy sum, usually $100,000, with no reference to the source of this initial endowment. The game perpetuates the idea that individual effort is the way to get ahead because everyone starts with the same amount of money. Unequal distribution of stocks goes unmentioned in teaching guides such as the New York Stock Exchanges The Stock Market Wants You, or the National Council on Economic Educations Learning from the Market. Instead, these manuals emphasize the recent broadening of stock ownership, so that 50 percent of households now own stock. A true-to-life stock market simulation would show that, while more U.S. households do own some stock, ownership remains very unequal with the wealthiest 10 percent owning more than 75 percent of stock and mutual funds, including assets in retirement funds. Even for the small number of students who one day will own a substantial amount of stock, the games are poor practice for realworld investing. The short time period during which students buy and sell stockstypically eight to twelve weeks, to fit comfortably in a school termmeans that students focus on short-term gains. Professional advisors recommend a much longer-term perspective, holding stock for a decade or more in order to avoid periodic downturns in stock prices. In addition, stock market games reward students who take excessive risks. Analysis of game winners shows that the best strategy is for students to ignore diversificationown-
110
BY
CHAPTER
ing stock in a variety of corporationswhich is the starting point for all prudent investment. By focusing on a few stocks known to swing wildly in price, some students, either through blind luck or an ill-advised risky portfolio, will end the game with big winnings, beating students who took the safer, diversified route. When it became apparent that students with such careless investments consistently won stock market competitions, some games forced students to invest in at least four stocks and to make a minimum number of trades. But the winning strategy remains to gamble as much as possible. Most students will take a nave approach, choosing portfolios based on brand names they knowMcDonalds, ColgatePalmolive, or Disney. The training manuals accompanying the best-selling games tell students that they will win if they carefully study these corporations. Several games use McDonalds as an example, suggesting that if students saw the burger chain introduce a popular new menu item, then this would be a good time to buy McDonalds stock. No expert would agree. If McDonalds profitability improves because of a new menu item, then other stock investors would have already purchased McDonalds stock, pushing up the price to a point where further gains are unlikely. Economists debate the full impact of this effect. It may be possible for a few experts, or those with privileged access to new information, to buy and sell stock with above-average success. Alternatively, the stock market may behave irrationally, not following the wisdom of any investor. But it is well proved that the strategy recommended for studentsbuying and selling stocks based on readily available informationis no better than a random choice of stocks and, on average, will cause students to lose because profits are reduced by brokers fees. In a typical classroom, the stock markets random fluctuations will ensure that a handful of students will do well, tallying high profits and winning prizes put up at commercial web sites. Pride in such gains is misplaced. Students with losing stocks may feel an undeserved sense of personal failure. And, when they are adults, students may expect the same returns earned by the lucky few, a lesson no more valid than if students practiced betting on horses.
BUSINESS EDUCATION
111
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
112
BY
CHAPTER
NOTE
1. JA Economics, Colorado Springs: Junior Achievement, 2000, p. 65. 2. This is from data published in 1999, the same year used in the JA materials. By 2002, the figure for employment at firms with less than 100 workers had dropped to 36 percent.
LABOR
AND THE
DISTRIBUTION
OF
WEALTH
AND INCOME
113
10
ost high school textbooks first describe labor markets in terms of neoclassical theory based on supply and demand, and then go on to interesting and real-world topics including discrimination, unions, and negotiations. Unfortunately, the treatment of each is usually brief and out of context, so students will have difficulty seeing the connection to their own lives or controversies they see in the news. In addition, few textbooks have much to say about the distribution of wealth and incomean unfortunate gap, since this, too, is highly relevant to students everyday experience. Nor do textbooks cover unpaid labor such as care for children or other family members, even though it is a large portion of many peoples work day and of increasing interest to economists. This chapter provides resources for filling these gaps. Because the issues are critical to understanding the economy and likely of relevance to your students, you might consider spending more time on these topics than is allocated in your textbook.
114
BY
CHAPTER
If students study only the narrow theory presented in many books, they will be ill equipped to understand why individuals have such widely differing incomes, and why some productive efforts are not well rewardedor not paid at all.
NCEE Standard #13 Income for most people is determined by the market value of the productive resources they sell. What workers earn depends, primarily, on the market value of what they produce and how productive they are. This standard attributes variations in peoples wage incomes to variations in their productivity, following the theoretical model of neoclassical economics. Many labor economists, however, would say that looking at wage outcomes as though they represent only productivity and competitive market value is much too simplistic.
10.2 POWER
IN
LABOR MARKETS
In the competitive market assumed by most supply-and-demand explanations, neither the workers nor the employers have any market power. But most labor markets are not well described by the economic model of perfect competition. Your textbook probably discusses the case of monopolyor one sellerin one of its chapters, but is less likely to discuss the case of monopsony, or one buyer. This theory is particularly relevant to labor markets. A case of pure monopsony occurs when one company is the only big employer in a geographic area (such as a mining company in a company town) or is the only employer of workers with a certain type of skill (for example, steel working or high school teaching). In such a case, potential workers are left with the choice of working for that company, not working at all, or facing potentially large expenses and substantial disruption to their family and social networks should they consider moving or retraining in another field.
LABOR
AND THE
DISTRIBUTION
OF
WEALTH
AND INCOME
115
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
116
BY
CHAPTER
AND
ACTIVITIES
RESOURCES
Employer Power
Consider a case study of employer market power, perhaps examining a local employer using the local newspaper web site or interviews with friends and relatives. In many localities, Wal-Mart is now a major local employer. Much has been written about Wal-Marts labor policies and anti-union activities that could be used to discuss the issue of employer power. Wal-Mart and Its Critics at www.teachablemoment.org contains high school classroom activities drawing on both positive and negative views of the corporation. The AFL-CIO (www.acio.org) web sites Corporate Watch section posts current labor news regarding Wal-Mart, including a campaign regarding back-to-school supplies. The National Education Association (www.nea.org) also includes this campaign among its Issues in Education. Show and discuss the movie Wal-Mart: The High Cost of Low Price (www.walmartmovie.com). Barbara Ehrenreichs Nickel and Dimed: On (Not) Getting By in America offers lively accounts of what is like to work at low-wage jobs. See also the interview of Ehrenreich by Bill Moyers at www.pbs.org. See also Corporate Power, p. 93. employer has all the power. The monopsonist, having the upper hand, can use its power to keep wages low (and working conditions harsh and unsafe). Consideration of employer power puts a different slant on many issues. Textbooks often assert that union (or any other) attempts to raise wages will necessarily reduce the number of jobs available. This assertion is based on an underlying assumption that the labor market is perfectly competitive. When employers have
LABOR
AND THE
DISTRIBUTION
OF
WEALTH
AND INCOME
117
market power, markets are not perfectly competitive, and the job losses allegedly caused by unions do not necessarily follow. The reason is that low wages paid by monopsonists are not the result of market forces, but rather are the result of the company using its power over workers to keep their wages low (and, in the case of private business, to keep profits or managers perks high). Unions give workers more power in negotiating with a powerful employer, because they can, for example, threaten to go on strike. The result of union-management negotiations in such a case can be a redistribution of the surplus created by productionfrom excess profits or executive perks back into fair workers wages. So, higher wages do not necessarily imply a loss of jobs. While cases of pure monopsony are difficult to find in practice, any case in which the power of an employer (or colluding group of employers) exceeds the power of disorganized workers can approximate this case.
118
BY
CHAPTER
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
Minimum Wage
The Economic Policy Institute (EPI, www.epi.org) maintains issue guides on the minimum wage and living wage that can offer quick facts to balance out a biased presentation in your textbook. Do all economists think that minimum wages are bad? In 2006, over 650 economists, including 5 Nobel laureates, signed a statement supporting increases in the minimum wage. See www.epi.org for details. Have your students calculate a basic family budget, individualized for your community, using EPIs online calculator (available, at the time of this writing, at www.epi.org/content. cfm/datazone_fambud_budget). Have them compare this with what a one- or two-earner family can earn, working full time at the minimum wage. For your own background, you might want to look at Alan B. Krueger, Teaching the Minimum Wage in Econ 101 in Light of the New Economics of the Minimum Wage, Journal of Economic Education 32 (Summer 2001): 24359. While the article goes into too much detail for use as a student reading, it gives a good overview of economic research on the topic and how it relates to economics teaching. Krueger writes, The use of the minimum wage is indicative of a more general tendency in introductory economics classes to teach economics as a settled science, as a set of established and universally accepted principles that govern how the economy works. Yet this is not the way most economic research is done in practice, and it does not characterize the way economists approach their field.
LABOR
AND THE
DISTRIBUTION
OF
WEALTH
AND INCOME
119
are quite able to pay a moderately higher wage without cutting back employment. Other labor economists have suggested that the minimum wage has some characteristics of what they call an efficiency wage. That is, somewhat higher wages pay off (to the employer) by making workers more productive, perhaps due to factors such as better health and reduced poverty-related stress, or due to factors of morale and loyalty to the employer. While the minimum-wageleads-to-job-loss story looks good on a graph, its relation to the real world is highly suspect. Another problem in many textbook discussions of the minimum wage is that the focus is placed entirely on efficiency, with little consideration for human needs. Often the minimum wage is portrayed as if it only affects teenagers who want spending money, not people who support their families. Studies by the Economic Policy Institute indicate that a large majority of those who would benefit from an increase in the minimum wage are workers over age twenty; several million are parents with children under eighteen; and close to half work full time. Many states and communities have living wage campaigns that seek to raise local wages to levels that allow a decent standard of living.
AND
LABOR UNIONS
Many high school textbooks give a rather dry summary of labor relations law, practices, and recent history while downplaying the crucial questionwhy did unions arise? Because of the increasing influence of free market thinking on economics education, texts may leave the impression that unions are simply organizations that interfere with free market, competitive, individualist processes in order to serve the selfish desires of a special interest groupthe union members. The vast differences in power that characterize the relations between large, deep-pocket employers and individual, unorganized workers is not noted, and the oppressive conditions and abuses historically suffered by many workers before the rise of unionization are not mentioned. Instructors who also teach U.S. history should, of course, be able to make up this lack by adding coverage of events such as the Pullman strike and the Triangle Shirtwaist fire.
120
BY
CHAPTER
NCEE Standard #10 (first part) Institutions evolve in market economies to help individuals and groups accomplish their goals. Banks, labor unions, corporations, legal systems, and not-for-profit organizations are examples of important institutions. This is the only place in the NCEE standards that labor unions (and not-for-profit organizations) are mentioned. While the phrasing of the NCEE standard implies that these institutions just peacefully organized themselves in response to peoples idiosyncratic interests, the actual history of the labor unions was one of conflict (often violent) about major issues concerning the organization of social and economic life.
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
Labor History
LABOR
AND THE
DISTRIBUTION
OF
WEALTH
AND INCOME
121
Based on primary source materials at Cornell University, students can learn about the Triangle Shirtwaist fire at www. ilr.cornell.edu/trianglefire/texts. A lesson plan developed by the National Park Service on the 1913 Paterson, New Jersey, silk worker strike is at www.cr.nps.gov/nr/twhp/wwwlps/lessons/102paterson/ 102paterson.htm. Based on Smithsonian Institution documents, students can compare conditions for U.S. slaves and wage workers in the 1850s at http://historymatters.gmu.edu/d/6821. On the civil rights and labor movement, see activities at the George Meany Memorial archives at http://www.nlc. edu/archives/students.html. Labor history resources for your state may provide historical materials relevant to your geographic area (see list of sources in www.geocities.com/m_lause.geo/AmLabHist/VL.html, for example www.wisconsinlaborhistory.org). Show the movie Norma Rae (1979) about unionization of a mill, based on a true story. For a personal connection and possible antidote to a textbooks simplistic or antagonistic view toward unions, ask students to interview a union member. Or, bring a union leader to talk in class, especially if business representatives speak in class as in the case of many Junior Achievement courses.
10.5 DISCRIMINATION
Textbooks often touch on the issue of labor market discrimination by race, sex, ethnicity, or other characteristics. But, if they follow the markets-solve-all ideology that is now so prominent in high school
122
BY
CHAPTER
economics materials, they may bring out the old line about how market competition should drive discriminating employers out of business. Discriminating employers, they say, will have higher costs and lower productivity than nondiscriminating employers, make lower profits, and therefore fail. This story tends to leave some students with a very complacent view about labor market injustices, while others just get more alienated from economics because they see it as so far removed from real life. The markets-solve-all story is, of course, incredibly nave in the light of the real history of the civil rights movement and womens rights movement, and in light of the struggles that still go on concerning discrimination, glass ceilings, sexual harassment, racial disparities in education, and the like.
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
LABOR
AND THE
DISTRIBUTION
OF
WEALTH
AND INCOME
123
nesota mining town, based on the true story of the first major successful class action sexual harassment suit. The U.S. Equal Employment Opportunity Commission hosts a web site especially for teen workers (http://youth.eeoc.gov) and offers outreach events. The National Committee on Pay Equity (www.pay-equity.org) provides numerous fact sheets regarding sex discrimination that could be incorporated into class discussion. Education Worlds lesson plan on Closing the Salary Gap (www.education-world.com/a_lesson/02/lp25602.shtml) has students work with data on mens and womens salaries from the National Center on Education Statistics web site. Although very much set within a neoclassical framework, A Fair Wage at NCEEs EconEdLink (www.econedlink.org) may have some ideas of interest. Content of the debate and recommended readings are difficult. For activities on historical changes in median pay by race and gender, see Lesson 6, Viewing Income Through Gender and Race Lenses, in Teaching Economics as if People Mattered, by Tamara Sober Giecek with United for a Fair Economy. The book can be ordered from United for a Fair Economy (www. faireconomy.org). Current data on income by gender and race are available at the U.S. Census Bureau (www.census.gov) and the Economic Policy Institute (www.epinet.org).
124
BY
CHAPTER
AND
ACTIVITIES
RESOURCES
LABOR
AND THE
DISTRIBUTION
OF
WEALTH
AND INCOME
125
one of many possible issues in labor law that could be discussed. The name itself is misleadingunions rephrase it as the Right to Work for Less. The policy debate is about whether unions can require workers to pay for union services after an election in which a majority of workers support the union. No one loses the right to work, nor in most cases are required to join the union, although individuals can be required to pay dues. Many textbooks provide detailed definitions of union versus agency shops and then misrepresent the right to work laws as preventing forced union membership.
OF
INCOME
AND
WEALTH
Most textbooks give little attention to income and wealth distribution. Some imply that all students need to do to enter the ranks of
126
BY
CHAPTER
AND
ACTIVITIES
RESOURCES
Work-Family Issues
The American Time Use Survey, begun in 2003, collects data on the hours people spend in paid work, unpaid work, and other activities such as leisure. You might have students examine the news releases or even the data from this survey (www.bls.gov/ tus) to fill out their picture about how much people work. The Families and Work Institute (www.familiesandwork.org) and the Alliance for Work-Life Progress (www.awlp.org) offer free materials on work/life issues, though not in lesson-plan format. What happens if you need to work for money and see that your children are cared for at the same time? Have your students research going rates for care for infants and young children in your community, in formal child care centers and in family day care homes, and compare this to what a person can earn in a low-wage job. They will find that paying market rates for more than one child often completely uses up low-wage earnings. Have your students research the differences between the United States and Canada, or the United States and most countries of Northern Europe, in public support for parental leave and early childhood care and education. Most industrialized countries guarantee substantial paid leave upon the birth or adoption of a child, and many offer substantial child care subsidies. In the United States, only a very limited unpaid leave is guaranteed for some workers by the Family and Medical Leave Act (FMLA), and support for child care is more limited. See also Better Measures of Economic Activity and WellBeing, p. 137.
LABOR
AND THE
DISTRIBUTION
OF
WEALTH
AND INCOME
127
A HINT
FOR
CLEAR TEACHING
Many students get confused about the difference between income and wealth. Income is what economists call a flow variable, and is always measured over a period of time. Income, then, is the amount someone receives from wages (and other sources of income, such as bonuses, interest, dividends, or rent) over the course of a week, month, or year. National data on the distribution of income is fairly easy to get. Wealth is what economists call a stock variable, and is always measured at a point in time. It refers to the value of what someone owns. Ones wealth includes the value of ones checking and savings accounts, car, equity in a house, stocks and bonds (if any), and other things one owns, less the value of ones outstanding debts. Data on wealth is harder to come by, since U.S. government agencies rarely collect it and some parts of it are intrinsically hard to measure. (For example, the value of a piece of real estate may rise over time, raising the owners wealth, but until the real estate is actually offered on the market and sold its value cannot be directly observed.) The two concepts are quite distinct when comparing how well-off or powerful a person or family is. Your students are probably aware of the very high salaries paid to entertainment and sports superstars. Such people have high annual incomes. On the other hand, many of the wealthiest people inherited their wealth, or are wealthy because they own large shares of prosperous companies. Their income on a year-to-year basis may come only from interest and dividends, and not at all from salaries. But the power they can wield, by controlling millions or billions of dollars, may be immense. You might emphasize the point by estimating the income for a wealthy family. For example, the Mars family, with estimated wealth of $30 billion, can expect annual income in the billions, dwarfing the earnings of entertainers or athletes whose incomes are more often in the news.
128
BY
CHAPTER
the wealthy is save a bit from their paycheck every month. While it is not a bad idea to encourage your students to save, unless their paychecks are extremely large they are highly unlikely to end up rich by following this advice! What is neglected or downplayed in many textbooks is the fact that the U.S. income distribution is very uneven, and has been getting more uneven in the past few decades. The distribution of wealth is even more skewed, with just a very small percentage of individuals and families owning the bulk of the national stocks and bonds and other financial and real (that is, tangible, like real estate or jewelry) assets. Chances are your textbook has no data on U.S. income or wealth distribution, a necessary starting point for discussion of important current issues. If so, consider using the resources listed below.
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
LABOR
AND THE
DISTRIBUTION
OF
WEALTH
AND INCOME
129
could analyze the sources of this wealth: inherited; gained by starting a business; or gained by building a business based on inheritance. See related activity, Born on Third Base, in Teaching Economics as if People Mattered. The pay levels of corporate executives can be analyzed using the AFL-CIO executive pay watch (www.aflcio.org). Students can explore average earnings for different occupations at the U.S. Department of Labors Bureau of Labor Statistics (www.bls.gov). For an activity using these data, see Wages and Me at NCEEs EconEdLink (www.econedlink. org). Students can explore poverty levels and changes in the distribution of income using U.S. census data (www.census.gov). For activities using these data, see Lesson 30, Poverty and Income Inequality, in Capstone: Exemplary Lessons for High School Economics (New York: NCEE, 2003). The web site www.teachablemoment.org contains free classroom activities created by Educators for Social Responsibility, many of which are appropriate for use in a high school economics course. The items Whats Happening to the American Dream? Examining the Tax Cuts, and The Class & Race Divide in New Orleans and in America all involve discussion of issues of economic distribution in the United States. Students could create budgets for individuals and households at different income levels (based on realistic expectations for different people). Use the Economic Policy Institute web site at www.epi.org/content.cfm/datazone_fambud_budget. Or, students could learn budget techniques available from the Jump$tart Coalition for Personal Financial Literacy Clearinghouse at www.jumpstartclearinghouse.org. See also Global Distribution of Well-Being, p. 38.
131
11
easuring the economys overall output is a useful concept, helpful if we want to know how fast the economy is growingor if it is growing at alland to make comparisons between different economies. Even so, many textbooks GDP chapters are extraordinarily tedious, asking students to memorize the mechanics of GDP accounting instead of teaching how to use the accounts. Similarly, students often are presented with a list of GDP measurement problems, but are left wondering what can be done to correct them. Thus, we recommend a pragmatic approach to the typical GDP chapter, using the topics in it as a starting point for learning about what makes a country better or worse off.
132
BY
CHAPTER
a well-defined science, when in fact it is a controversy-ridden and often very approximate art. The common claim that GDP measures market activity, for example, is misleading. Government production of goods such as roads and bridges, and services such as defense and education, is included in GDPyet these products are never sold on markets. The value of government production that is included in GDP is an imputation (that is, a reasonable guess) based on data concerning the costs of inputs used. Government economists and statisticians also impute many other components of GDP when they find it difficult to get actual data, and are continually revising past estimates when better data are obtained. Controversies rage about what should be included and how, and as a result the accounting methods both evolve over time and vary across countries. It would probably be more accurate to say that the government estimates GDP rather than measures it.
A HINT
FOR
CLEAR TEACHING
GDP accounting requires a number of decisions about which economic transactions to include and how best to measure them. Because your students are unlikely to take jobs compiling GDP for the Commerce Department, these accounting conventions described in overwhelming detail in many textbooks are not particularly interesting to students. Instead, consider the following accounting principles that will be used later in life, perhaps focusing on a few in depth.
Circular Flow
Many textbooks show GDP measurement as a circular flow recalling the diagram from an introductory chapter. The diagram shows GDP as a flow variable, measured over one year, different from a stock variable that measures assets already produced. Economists distinguish between flow variables and stock variables just as an individual should keep track of income (flow) and wealth (stock).
133
Intermediate Goods
Most textbooks point out that GDP includes only final goods, not intermediate production. Either the final value of the loaf of bread sold at the grocery is counted, or the total value of the wheat and other intermediate goods used to produce the bread are counted, but not both. If you choose to teach this concept, students will be interested to learn that the U.S. Department of Commerce counts the value-added in production, that is, the extra value added by each step moving from the farmer to the mill to the bakery to the store. This concept of value-added is used to collect a value-added tax, or VAT, in many countries, a new tax proposed by some for the United States.
134
BY
CHAPTER
AND
ACTIVITIES
RESOURCES
135
Students could consider which of their expenditures qualify as consumption and which are investments in the sense of providing a future return. As a follow-up, ask which expenditures should be encouraged by government policy. Most public policy decisions require the use of real values, corrected for inflation. However, politicians often use nominal values, the actual dollar amounts, not corrected for inflation, to exaggerate the size of new spending programs. Use a recent policy decision relevant to students lives, perhaps expenditures on schools, to compare the real and nominal changes in expenditure. Students can practice data reading and graphing skills by finding current data on the U.S. economy. Go to the Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Department of Commerce: www. bea.gov. Students can learn that quarterly GDP reports are erratic, so longer-term trends are needed and that data need to be corrected for inflation. National Council on Economic Education materials provide worksheets for using current GDP data. See EconEdLink at www.econedlink.org. For international data students can consult the CIA Factbook www.cia.gov/cia/publications/factbook. For historical data, see the International Monetary Fund World Economic Outlook Database at www.imf.org. Ask students to compare economic growth in two or more countries and then use other sources to explain the differences.
136
BY
CHAPTER
Nonmarket Production
Textbooks usually mention that production at home is not counted in GDP without noting how much is omitted. By the most conservative estimates, the value of nonmarket production is at least 2535 percent of measured GDP;1 other estimates put its value at over 100 percent of GDP. Textbooks also fail to explain why it makes a difference to omit household production. One problem is that GDP levels and growth rates may be biased. Economic growth has been overstated, for example, to the extent that womens increasing entry into paid labor (an addition measured in GDP) came at the cost of reduced home production (a subtraction not measured in GDP). The neglect of household production also spills over into other policy decisions. For example, government programs such the U.S. Social Security retirement system pay benefits based only on market wages, not the value of time spent raising children. In allocating development funds, international agencies have sometimes failed to fund projects that primarily have nonmarket benefits. For example, new water wells, reducing the time spent by women walking to retrieve water, were not funded because the benefit was not measured by the market.
Environmental Issues
While textbooks acknowledge that rising GDP does not mean we are better off if there is more pollution, students are not made aware of important research on the cost of environmental problems and the sustainability of economic growth. The United States, through the Commerce Department, has lagged behind other countries in integrating environmental accounting into official statistics. Nonetheless, researchers estimate the cost of long-range environmental damage and depletion of nonrenewable U.S. resources runs in the trillions of dollars per year (see the Genuine Progress Indicator, below).
Well-Being Issues
GDP per capita (the value of GDP divided by the size of a countrys population) is often used as a measure of well-being. It is, however,
137
only a very crude measure. GDP per capita in a country might be high, for example, but incomes may be very unevenly distributed, so that a small elite enjoys most of the benefits while the majority lives in poverty. GDP may also overstate how well off we are if we work longer hours or spend our incomes on goods and services that do not serve us well. Are U.S. households better off with higher GDP/capita but longer workweeks than those in Western Europe? How much of our GDP is wasted when two products are advertised heavily simply to maintain their sales relative to one another? If we buy goods or services to keep up appearances relative to others, are we really better off? Other than briefly mentioning that GDP does not really measure well-being, most textbooks ignore these questions even though they will be of interest to students and are at the forefront of current economic research.
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
138
BY
CHAPTER
United States has a higher GDP per capita than Norway, Sweden, Canada, Belgium, and Australia, for example, but life expectancies here are over a year lower than in those five countries, and the United States ranks worse when measured by HDI. Countries with good social infrastructure and a lack of extreme gaps between rich and poor tend to score relatively well on HDI, compared to their achievements measured by GDP alone. Students could use the HDI to compare countries and then find other sources to explain the divergence between the HDI and GDP per capita. A group of researchers at Yale University has created an Environmental Sustainability Index (ESI) that compares countries on the basis of their performance on various measures including air and water quality, biodiversity, and greenhouse gas emissions. While much of the material at their web site (www.yale.edu/esi) is too technical to use for teaching, using their summary of country scores and/or a country profile as a handout may help students understand how such alternative measures are created. The Global Development and Environment Institutes (free) teaching module Macroeconomic Measurement: Environmental and Social Dimensions, available at www.gdae.org, gives a useful summary of methods and controversies in GDP accounting, including summaries of the Genuine Progress Indicator, Human Development Index, and United Nations accounting projects. While designed for first-year college use, it could be used as background reading or for an AP course. Economist Marilyn Waring, the best-known advocate for counting nonmarket production, is featured in a fascinating, although long, film about her life, Whos Counting? Marilyn Waring on Sex, Lies, and Global Economics. See also several interviews available online and her book If Women Counted: A New Feminist Economics (Harper Collins, Reprint edition, New York, November 1990).
139
Livin the Good Life, downloadable without cost from Facing the Future (http://facingthefuture.org), is a lesson plan on quality of indicators, including a survey for students to carry out and analyze. The United Nations Statistics division has developed a set of standards for integrating national environmental accounting into a system of national accounts, and a number of countries have adopted its recommendations. (The United States has not.) More information can be found at http://unstats. un.org. For interesting and little-known data on household production, see the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics Time Use Survey at www.bls.gov/news.release/atus.toc.htm. Ask students to give some examples of ways that much production takes place outside of GDP accounts, and examine who is doing the work. See also: Consumer Society, p. 100; Distribution of Income and Wealth in the U.S., p. 128; Global Distribution of WellBeing, p. 38; Ecological Economics, p. 45.
NOTE
1. Robert Eisner, Extended Accounts for National Income and Product, Journal of Economic Literature 26 (1988): 161184.
ROLES
OF
GOVERNMENT
141
12
Roles of Government
ost textbooks begin this chapter with a list of reasons why government should have a role in the economy, usually leading with the importance of enforcing property rights or safeguarding the market system. By first describing a market economy in ideal terms and then adding government as a possible corrective, textbooks imply that the private sector exists independently, operating quite well without government intervention. Many textbooks have a section on the growth of big government further suggesting that there once was a time when the U.S. economy was relatively government-free, a clear misrepresentation of U.S. history in which the role of state and national banks and economic planning dates back to the nations founding. In reality, there was no mythical laissez-faire past, but rather capitalist economies have always had a combination of household, government, and private production, all constrained by publicly established rules and historical context. These constraints tend to give some people and institutions more power and resources than others. Take, for example, government regulations to protect consumers and workers. Usually described as a role of government, one might assume these regulations will be enforced and will adequately protect consumers and workers. However, as is obvious from current controversies about consumer and workplace safety, such is often not the case. Students would be unable to take part in policy debates without understanding the contested background for nearly all regulations, which were put in place over much objection by those to be regulated. Moreover, without ongoing political pressure, government agencies are ineffective, or even controlled by the same corporate interests intended to be regulated.
141
142
BY
CHAPTER
NCEE Standard #16 There is an economic role for government in a market economy whenever the benets of a government policy outweigh its costs. Governments often provide for national defense, address environmental concerns, dene and protect property rights, and attempt to make markets more competitive. Most government policies also redistribute income. This catchall standard lists possible roles for government, but only when benets exceed costs. Such a stipulation that benets exceed costs is not, however, added when other standards extol the virtues of entrepreneurial incentives, specialization, or market-based incomes. A balanced approach would more clearly identify the costs (such as those related to the generation of negative externalities, the insufcient provision of public goods, or the possibility of extreme inequality) as well as the benets of organizing economic life by way of markets. In addition, the standard completely neglects the macroeconomic role of governments in using scal and monetary policy to even out economic uctuations (discussed in Chapter 15). In this way this standard obliquely reinforces the Classical theory presumption that no such role is necessary.
ROLES
OF
GOVERNMENT
143
the way in which their school is funded. Most of the postWorld War II increase in total government purchases is by state and local governments. Growth in federal government budgets over this period was disproportionately due to increases in the size of transfer programs, primarily Social Security and medical programs. Thus, big government is largely a matter of more services provided at the local level and national programs for the elderly. Short-term changes in government purchases are mostly related to military spending, rising during the 1980s, then again in the 2000s. Textbooks give scant attention to military spending, sidestepping this unquestionably important if contentious issue. Students will be unable to analyze federal government spending without careful attention to this largest single item. There is potential misinterpretation of the level of military spending because the most commonly cited number, about $400 billion in 2006, excludes additional appropriations for the Iraq and Afghanistan wars as well as military pensions and health care, and science research for the military, expenditures that add as much as 50 percent more to the reported level. Another ideological slant on government spending is evident when it is treated as though it is largely for short-run purposes, in contrast to business investment spending, which is treated as more responsible and future-enhancing. Teaching the basic macroeconomic equation Y = C + I + G + Net Exports (i.e., GDP is the sum of consumption, investment, government spending, and net exports) may tend to reinforce the notion that only businesses, not governments (or households), invest. Theoretical discussions about government spending crowding out private investment (by absorbing funds that could have passed into private hands) also serve the ideological purpose of portraying government spending as damaging. Yet, in fact, much of government spending is for investment purposes. Governments build roads, bridges, school buildings, and other important parts of the economic infrastructure, and also spend on other structures and equipment. These sorts of spending would be counted as investment if accomplished by private businesses. Recognizing this fact, in recent years the Bureau of Economic Analysis (creator of the GDP statistics) has begun to break down government spending into government consumption and government investment (estimated at more than $400 billion in 2006).
144
BY
CHAPTER
While the BEA defines investment very traditionally, it should also be recognized that investing for the future is really much more than a matter of bricks and machines. Government-funded research has laid the base for many important technological breakthroughs later capitalized on by businesses (such as rocket technology and the Internet). Government services directed at improving health and education, especially when directed at young people, increase the future human capital of a society. Government spending on environmental protection similarly increases the resource base left to future generations. A fuller accounting of investment would count investment in human, social, and natural capitaland show that the government plays a major role in these important areas.
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
Government Outlays
Use a number line (see Getting Familiar with GDP) to help students understand orders of magnitude in government budgets. In the federal budget, identify the major spending areas in the hundred-billion-dollar rangemilitary spending, Social Security, medical programs, and interest on the debt. It is important to distinguish these big-ticket items from small items such as foreign aid or federal education assistance that may be in the news but have relatively little impact on overall spending. There are several online budget simulations in which students are asked to make decisions about government spending and taxes, and then are shown the impact on the federal budget, often with compelling graphics. As of this writing, three simulations were available: The National Budget Simulation, at www.budgetsim.org/ nbs, encourages decisions about current policy issues. The Budget Explorer comes with historical background at www.kowaldesign.com/budget.
ROLES
OF
GOVERNMENT
145
The NCEE National Budget Simulation, available from EconEdLink at www.econedlink.org, comes with handouts for instructors. Any of these simulation activities could be used to encourage students to record their initial positions on the budget and then initiate a class discussion about appropriate changes in current federal spending. The two largest components of the federal budget, military spending and Social Security, are important current policy questions. On military spending, students may have strong opinions for reasons not directly related to economics. Begin by making it clear how much is at stake in this part of the budget. Ask students to calculate average military spending per year per person and per household (several thousand dollars per year). Compare this amount to spending on other items. What is potentially given up because of military spending? For current data on U.S. military spending, see the Center for Defense Information at www.cdi.org. On Social Security, students likely are misinformed on how it works now and its likely benefits when they retire. For background information showing that Social Security can continue to provide benefits for all retirees, see the Center for Economic and Policy Research (go to www.cepr.net and search the term social security). For a class activity using a Document Based Question technique, see TeachableMoment, at www.teachablemoment.org/high/socialsecurity.html.
146
BY
CHAPTER
tive impact of different taxes. Such instruction is useful not only for young people who have yet to encounter the tax world, but also for citizens in general who frequently support odd or contradictory tax policies because they misunderstand how taxes work.
A HINT
FOR
CLEAR TEACHING
A precise vocabulary is necessary for analyzing taxes, differentiating between types of taxes including income, property, payroll, sales, excise, and inheritance taxes. These definitions will be less tedious if they are tied to actual tax computations students will encounter. Many textbooks provide such activities, including filling out an actual federal income tax form or looking at an actual pay stub. Both the marginal tax rate (the percentage of the last dollar of income that goes to taxes) and the average tax rate (the percentage of total income going to taxes) are necessary for understanding ones own tax situation and for evaluating tax policy.
Often political commentators, and textbook presentations wanting to argue against high taxes, point to marginal tax rates that are higher than average tax rates, giving the false impression that the well-to-do pay 35 percent (the highest marginal income tax rate in 2006) or 45 percent (the highest marginal inheritance tax rate in 2007). In fact, the average tax rate is much less because only a portion of income or inheritance is taxed at the higher marginal rate, and because exemptions and generous deductions reduce the taxable income or taxable wealth for well-to-do households. Textbooks also introduce policy debates about taxes, usually focusing on progressive (tax rates that are higher on higher incomes) versus regressive tax rates (tax rates that are lower on higher incomes). Real-life examples of U.S. taxes nicely illustrate the difference. Most
ROLES
OF
GOVERNMENT
147
textbooks emphasize the progressive nature of the income tax, often calling it the progressive income tax. The regressive nature of other taxes may be overlooked by students because there is little direct explanation for the regressive nature of the payroll tax, sales tax, or most excise taxes. This disparity in presentation carries into political discussion in which reducing taxes is equated with the income tax or the similarly progressive inheritance tax, whereas recent increases in the regressive payroll and sales taxes go unnoticed. Lotteries, which are now used by many states to raise additional revenues, also tend to be highly regressive in their impact. The impact of taxes, called the tax incidence, is complex for indirect taxes such as property or excise taxes that may be passed along to consumers in higher prices or absorbed by the property owner or producer who actually pays the tax to the government. Some textbooks attempt to show that the tax burden is related to price elasticities (see Chapter 6), a difficult concept to teach at the high school level using supply-anddemand diagrams. Nonetheless, the underlying idea is relatively simple: the person or business that directly pays the tax may pass along the tax if buyers will still purchase the good or service at a higher price. The sales tax often is misunderstood as a proportional tax because the rate paid on taxable items appears not to depend on ones income. However, as incomes rise, households spend less of their income on sales-taxable items, instead saving more or buying non-sales-taxed services. As a result, the sales tax is quite regressive and the overall U.S. tax system has become more regressive as the federal income tax has been reduced, in particular for high incomes, while state and local sales taxes have been increased. In addition to ability to pay, textbooks usually list other criteria that make a tax fair, including simplicity, benefits received, and efficiency. These are indeed factors traditionally examined in economics research, although in political debate they more often are used as hasty arguments against progressive taxes. Simplicity, for example, is a laudable goal, one likely to be embraced by students when they see the complicated federal tax forms. However, recent calls for a flat tax, setting a single marginal income tax rate, would not only eliminate its progressive structure, but would make the tax quite regressive if deductions such as the home mortgage interest deduction were maintained. In addition, flat taxers
148
BY
CHAPTER
AND
ACTIVITIES
RESOURCES
Taxes
A number of web sites dedicated to education about consumer finances, such as www.moneyinstructor.com, contain curriculum plans for teaching about the basics of income, sales, and payroll taxes. The lesson plan Examining the Tax Cuts, available from www.teachablemoment.org, leads students through an analysis of the distributional impact of some of the tax cuts instituted by President George W. Bush. The National Budget Simulation at www.budgetsim.org/nbs includes decisions on federal taxes. When making decisions about these taxes, require students to explain their choices in terms of a progressive or regressive impact. Tax policy can be a nicely focused and interesting case study in which students examine a recent controversy using the tools learned in this chapter. For examples of federal and state and local tax proposals, see Citizens for Tax Justice at www.ctj.org.
limit their reform to the progressive income tax, and do not call for changes in the payroll or other regressive taxes. The argument for basing taxes on benefits received makes sense in some cases, but not so much in others. Governments regularly charge user fees in return for things like granting professional licenses, allowing people to enter major parks, or allowing airlines to land their planes at public airports. In these cases, the usage can be directly linked to the tax. However, the evidence is tricky for major government programs such as police and fire protection services or public education, for which the benefits received are widespread. Should the well-to-do pay more for fire and police services because they have more to protect? Who should pay for schooling when
ROLES
OF
GOVERNMENT
149
everyone benefits from an educated population? Students may be attracted by the pay for what you get tax model, but in general it is a poor guide for social policy. The link between efficiency and taxes is the factor most debated in the economic literature. Do taxes reduce productivity by thwarting work effort, entrepreneurship, and innovation? At a theoretical level, people and corporations certainly respond to financial incentives and thus will adjust their efforts in response to taxes. The question is by how much and do the benefits of programs funded by taxes more than offset any efficiency loss? Because it is common to exaggerate this effect in arguments for lower marginal rates on high incomes, students could do thought experiments on the impact of proposed changes in tax rates on the behavior of an actual high-income individual. Would a multimillion-dollar-income corporate executive reduce his or her work effort if the marginal income tax rate was raised from 35 percent to its pre-2001 level of 39.6 percent?
150
BY
CHAPTER
NCEE Standard #17 Costs of government policies sometimes exceed benefits. This may occur because of incentives facing voters, government officials, and government employees, because of actions by special interest groups that can impose costs on the general public, or because social goals other than economic efficiency are being pursued. The standard derives from public choice theory, an important branch of neoclassical theory, but one dominated by conservative policy makers who argue for less government regulation. Public choice theory assumes that peopleincluding advocates, politicians, and government workerstry to manipulate government power to serve their own self-interested ends, rather than to try to work toward the common good. While no one would argue that governments always do a perfect job of serving the common good, this standard portrays governments (in most democratic societies) in an unnecessarily unfavorable light. This negative way of thinking plays an important political role in ideological arguments for reducing government support for consumer and worker rights and poverty relief. Such programs are generally the ones dismissed by advocates of this position as serving special interests and being too costly!
Some textbooks oversimplify the history of U.S. government regulation as a period of growth during from 1930 until the 1970s, then a period of deregulation after 1980, ostensibly to correct productivitylimiting overregulation. Indeed there was substantial deregulation of communications and transportation industries in recent years prompted primarily by new technologies. However, attempts to roll back environmental, labor relations, and antitrust regulations were quite different. There is little evidence that these regulations had reduced efficiency; instead they have important benefits that would be lost if they were abandoned.
ROLES
OF
GOVERNMENT
151
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
Government Regulation
For a provocative discussion of how government programs may become the tool of those seeking to increase their own wealth, see Dean Bakers The Conservative Nanny State: How the Wealthy Use the Government to Stay Rich and Get Richer (Center for Economic and Policy Research, 2006), available at www.conservativenannystate.org. See Corporate Accountability, p. 107; Corporate Power, p. 93; Employees Rights in the Workplace, p. 124; Minimum Wage, p. 118; Personal Financial Management, p. 97; Price Ceilings and Floors, p. 81.
UNEMPLOYMENT
AND INFLATION
153
13
long with the real GDP growth rate (see Chapter 11), the unemployment rate and the inflation rate are key macroeconomic indicators used by economists, and are closely tracked by investors, politicians, and commentators. Thus, students are well served by careful explanations of unemployment and inflation rates, including how they are measured and the goals that economists and policy makers set for them. NCEE Standard #19 Unemployment imposes costs on individuals and nations. Unexpected inflation imposes costs on many people and benefits some others because it arbitrarily redistributes purchasing power. Inflation can reduce the rate of growth of national living standards because individuals and organizations use resources to protect themselves against the uncertainty of future prices. This cautiously worded standard is vague about why we should worry about unemployment, while it goes on at greater length about problems caused by inflation. It does not point out that critical political debates hinge around what, if anything, can be done to prevent unemployment, and about whether any inflationnot just unexpected inflationis harmful. Conservative policy makers and Classical economists tend to argue that it is more important to keep inflation very low, even if this causes a recession. Liberal policy makers and Keynesian economists, on the other hand, argue that low or moderate steady inflation imposes relatively little damage, and express more concern about unemployment.
153
154
BY
CHAPTER
A HINT
FOR
CLEAR TEACHING
Show students the difference between looking at an issue from an individual point of view and a social point of view. Factors that help an individual obtain a job, such as better interview skills or more training, will not apply at the aggregate level because too few jobs would be available if all individuals improved their interview skills or obtained training. Known as the fallacy of composition, this concept is illustrated at a sport event in which one individual can stand up to for a better view, but no one benefits if everyone stands up. Similarly, in inflation, higher prices make things more expensive for an individual, but a rise in overall prices, including peoples earnings, causes no one to be worse off on average (although, as described below, there may be unequal distribution between the losers and winners).
UNEMPLOYMENT
AND INFLATION
155
the unemployment types will appear yet another meaningless set of definitions for students to memorize. The goal for unemployment depends on the types of unemployment because full employment assumes that there will still be structural and frictional unemployment and only cyclical unemployment causes the economy to deviate from full employment. (Seasonal unemployment balances out over the year.) While cyclical unemployment guides macroeconomic fiscal and monetary policies (see Chapter 15), other government programs aim at structural and frictional unemployment. For example, retraining can reduce structural unemployment and job banks can reduce frictional unemployment, in both cases assuming there are jobs available. What is the appropriate goal for full employment, remembering that it is not zero unemployment? According to neoclassical theory, too low unemployment causes inflation to accelerate. Most textbooks call the nonaccelerating inflationary level of full employment the natural rate of unemployment, an unfortunate term because it implies a far too scientific definition. Textbooks usually define a range for the natural rate, sometimes 4 to 5 percent, sometimes 5 to 6 percent. New editions after 2000 typically added a note that U.S. unemployment reached 3.9 percent that year without significant inflation, no doubt confusing to students as it was to many macroeconomic theorists. In other words, the natural rate of unemployment is ill defined, and at best a moving target. Instead of focusing on one level of unemployment as the natural rate, emphasize that there is a political controversy about how much unemployment is acceptable. Anticipate upcoming chapters on fiscal and monetary policy with examples from the news in which some policy makers, such as the Federal Reserve, worry that unemployment is too low, while others, more likely liberal Democrats, worry that it is too high. Because the official unemployment rate leaves out individuals who have given up looking for work (discouraged workers) as well as those who work part-time but would like full-time employment (the underemployed), the policy debate looks at other statistics, such as total employment and the number of job vacancies, in addition to the unemployment rate. Sometimes considering the information from these various data sources can be puzzling. For example, total employment can rise, while at the same time the unemployment rate goes up. (This can happen if employment growth is not fast enough to employ a more quickly rising number of workers. See resources, below.)
156
BY
CHAPTER
AND
ACTIVITIES
RESOURCES
Unemployment
Princeton economist Alan Krueger set up a web site for high school students at the Survey Research Center (www. princeton.edu/~psrc/HSwebSurvey.html), including questions about unemployment similar to those on the U.S. Current Population Survey. The answers are collected condentially, but instructors can download aggregate class data. To bring the types of unemployment to life, ask students to write short skits illustrating each unemployment type and then to provide an appropriate government policy that would address it. NCEEs EconEdLink (www.econedlink.org) lesson Unemployment in My Hometown asks students to nd the unemployment rate for their locality from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics and use other Internet resources to explain why this rate is higher or lower than the national unemployment rate. Rethinking Schools Reading the World with Math in Rethinking Mathematics asks students to critically evaluate the ofcial unemployment rate using alternative data available from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. NCEE lesson Solving the Labor Market Mystery, available in several NCEE print sources, asks students to discover why the unemployment rate has increased at the same time that more people are getting jobs. In nding the answer, students learn how the ofcial unemployment is measured. Instructors should point out that the unemployment rate also frequently goes down even as fewer jobs are available.
Students may wonder why all the fuss about 4, 5, or even 6 percent unemployment. Textbooks usually neglect to point out that such low
UNEMPLOYMENT
AND INFLATION
157
numbers affect everyone. Unemployment means that the country as a whole is not producing as much as it might, lost GDP that causes everyone to lose access to the goods and services the unemployed could have produced. Also, high unemployment is a signal that the labor market is loose, causing those with jobs to be more wary of asking for higher wages. There are high social costs for unemployment, including more crime, social problems, disease, and even higher death rates among the unemployed. Finally, government data show much higher unemployment rates for blacks, Hispanics, and young people, differences not mentioned in many textbooks.
A HINT
FOR
CLEAR TEACHING
Even though inflation is part of students everyday experience, there are several easy-to-make mistakes regarding the concept. First, the inflation rate is the percentage rise in the price level calculated over a period of time; it does not refer to a high price level. So, for example, some cities have a high cost of living, but not necessarily high inflation. Second, inflation means a rise in the overall price level, not necessarily an increase in every individual price, so that some prices go down even when there is inflation. Recent increases in oil prices and college tuition did not translate into similarly high inflation because the prices of other goods and services did not rise as fast or even fell.
158
BY
CHAPTER
AND
ACTIVITIES
RESOURCES
Ination
Students can learn to calculate real (corrected for ination) values, a skill they may require in their future lives as workers, consumers, and businesspeople. Students could use online calculators available at several web sites (see, for example, www.bls.gov) or could learn the underlying arithmetic, a formula not included in most textbooks but worthwhile as an important skill. Calculating the real interest rate (the nominal interest rate minus the anticipated ination rate) is simpler and is similarly a useful concept to know. Ask students to provide data from their life experience such the price of candy bars or gas, the minimum wage, or the interest received on a savings account, and then convert these numbers into real values. Or, ask students to interview their parents or another older person to nd prices for comparison over a longer time. EconEdLink (www.econedlink.org) has frequently updated lessons, A Case Study: The Ination Rate, in which students analyze the most recent ination trends using the monthly release of the Bureau of Labor Statistics Consumer Price Index. See also the activity on economic forecasting called Economic Forecasting: An Internet WebQuest, in which students make predictions about GDP growth, the unemployment rate, and the ination rate and then track the accuracy of those predictions over the course of a school term. Illustrate demand-pull ination by conducting an auction in class using pretend money but real objects for sale. After an initial round, increase the money supply (more demand) and show the impact on the overall price level when students bid on the same objects with more money. For a more complex version involving monetary policy, see the NCEE activity Money, Interest and Monetary Policy (www.ncee.net).
UNEMPLOYMENT
AND INFLATION
159
Textbook explanations for inflation are clearer than they are for unemployment, usually identifying inflation causes as demand pull or cost push. These are useful distinctions, but sometimes are couched in language that makes it sound as if price-gouging corporations or greedy workers needlessly cause prices to rise. It is true that inflation is the norm for modern economies in which firms have considerable market power and some workers are able to bargain collectively to protect their wages and benefits. However, the situation is preferable to sudden rises and falls in the price level as occurred frequently before 1900. The important question is what level of inflation is acceptable without dire consequences that might require government action. At first, students might argue for stable prices, and indeed there are economists of a particularly conservative bent who advocate a zero inflation goal. After all, who wants higher prices? The answer is that zero inflation may come at a very high cost in terms of more unemployment. Also, there is a well-accepted argument that moderate inflation benefits businesses because it gives them flexibility in setting wages. This is because, instead of having to explicitly cut the pay of less productive workers, they can wait for inflation to erode the purchasing power of a constant wage. In this way, they can reduce the real wage they pay some of their workers over time, while not having to deal with the resentment that nominal wage cuts would provoke. Textbooks usually list those who are hurt by inflation, most important being creditors and those on fixed incomes, versus those who come out even or actually may benefit from moderate inflation, including some borrowers and those with pay protected by cost-ofliving agreements. These lists do not indicate the important political disputes over inflation that will interest students and will affect their future economic well-being. Among the losers from inflation are those on fixed incomes, who are usually identified as pensioners who retired on a set income. In reality, Social Security payments are adjusted for inflation, while the groups left behind are those paid the minimum wage (which as of 2006 is at its lowest level in decades, when adjusted for inflation) and recipients of government assistance (which has been allowed to fall far behind inflation). The group most concerned about inflation is creditors, especially banks, which saw the value of loan repayments greatly reduced by
160
BY
CHAPTER
the 1970s inflation. As a result, many loans are now adjusted for inflation, but still borrowers may benefit from inflation, including students with fixed-rate school or car loans. Textbooks often feature stories about hyperinflation, which are indeed intriguing examples of economies gone wrong in which currency is valued in the billions and the economy collapses because of spiraling prices. While it is worthwhile to understand important examples of hyperinflation such as postWorld War I Germany and war-torn 1990s former Yugoslavia, students may confuse present-day concern about inflation with these examples of destructive hyperinflation. Since the Confederacy during the Civil War, the United States has never experienced hyperinflation, so debate about inflation should focus on the advisability of moderate inflation, not hyperinflation.
MONEY, BANKING,
AND THE
FEDERAL RESERVE
161
14
oney is a topic likely to appeal to students. In particular, the questions What is money? and How is it created? may spark interest because the answers are unexpected. Also, high school courses generally include discussion of the Federal Reserve, a part of government about which students likely have heard about, but whose extraordinary power has likely not been explained to them.
NCEE Standard #11 Money makes it easier to trade, borrow, save, invest, and compare the value of goods and services. This simplistic standard highlights only the market-oriented uses of money, and gives the impression that money always makes the world run more smoothly. In fact, historically and in contemporary cultures, money also plays important economic roles in facilitating tax collection, the transfer of assets (such as inheritances), gift giving, and many other nonmarket activities. Problems related to money can also disrupt economic activity, as when high inflation or rapid currency depreciation destabilizes an economy. A more complete economic analysis would include these nonmarket uses of money and point out the real issues involved in creating institutions and policies that make money work to peoples benefit instead of detriment.
161
162
BY
CHAPTER
HOW IS IT CREATED?
After many chapters presenting economics as a theoretical construct in which market analysis is applied without regard to context, textbooks suddenly become far more anthropological and historical on the concept of money. Illustrative examples compare money across cultures, usually focusing on oddities such as Yaps giant stone disks. However, students may gain the false impression that market economies existed every time money was used. In fact, historically speaking, money was in many places originally invented to facilitate the paying of tribute, tax collection, or gift giving, rather than for market exchange. If earlier textbook chapters had included as many historical and cross-cultural comparisons as in this section, students would have learned about nonmarket relationships that can coexist with money and remain part of modern capitalism in the home and the workplace. The history of money often is described in detail, from nineteenthcentury U.S. bimetallism through the end of the gold standard in 1933. It may be important to disabuse students of the notion that gold still plays a role in the money supply. Except for a few gold standard advocates on the far right, few economists endorse its return because it would impose unnecessary restrictions on the money supply and thus on economic growth. Most textbooks provide unnecessary detail about the bank types, including discussion of the difference between commercial banks, savings banks, and savings and loansa holdover from older editions written when differences between these banks affected consumers. More important than these obsolete bank types is an understanding of the critical services provided by banksand how this has at sometimes broken down, such as during the bank runs (when all depositors want their funds at once) and bank closures that occurred during the early years of the Great Depression. Special rules have been imposed on banks since then, including far closer financial scrutiny than is required of other corporations, as well as limits on the services a bank is allowed to provide. These rules have created relative stability in banking since the Great Depression by insuring banks or bailing them out at the governments expense. Today, an important issue is the boundary between banks and
MONEY, BANKING,
AND THE
FEDERAL RESERVE
163
A HINT
FOR
CLEAR TEACHING
It is good pedagogy to begin literally with what is in students pockets. However, the textbook emphasis on numismatic details such as the new state quarters and lesseasily counterfeited $20 bills distracts from the important concept that money is primarily not coins and currency. Instead, most money today has a less tangible form as checks or electronic funds transfers. Help students learn the counterintuitive lesson that money is not the currency they carry around by asking where their household keeps most of its money. The answer will be in bank checking and savings accounts; most adults do not keep their money as currency. Consequently, the money supply does not depend on printing paper currency as your students and most citizens believe, but rather on bank lending. Surprisingly, textbooks provide little information about electronic funds transfers. Students should be reminded that digital transactions still involve money, but that electronic forms of money will require new forms of consumer protection and will require that monetary policy take into account money that changes hands much faster.
other types of businesses. Should other corporations be allowed to act as a bank as envisioned by Sears, Wal-Mart, and other retailers? Should banks sell stocks or other relatively risky investments? Crucial public policy is at stake. Although these debates are generally poorly explained in textbooks, they should be of interest to students both because of their impact on students dayto-day consumer lives and because of their implications for the future economic and political power of such combined bank and nonbank corporations.
164
BY
CHAPTER
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
MONEY, BANKING,
AND THE
FEDERAL RESERVE
165
166
BY
CHAPTER
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
Federal Reserve in order to understand why the Fed makes the sorts of policies that will be described in the next chapter. The most important Federal Reserve policy maker is the FOMC, which includes the Board of Governors whose seven members are appointed to fourteen-year terms by the president and confirmed by the Senate, with none of the attention given to Supreme Court nominees. Because the members of the Board of Governors are ignored by the media, students can be excused for not knowing about them and their political perspectives. Other members of the FOMC are presidents of the Federal Reserve District banks, appointed by banks themselves. This peculiar arrangement in which policy makers are appointed by private banks with little public accountability could be another topic for classroom debate. Federal Reserve decision making usually is described in terms of central bank independence contrasted with political influence and thus easily confused with payoffs that occur in Congress and other political offices. Instead, economists mean independence as the ability
MONEY, BANKING,
AND THE
FEDERAL RESERVE
167
to focus on an economic goal without fear of public retribution. In practice, this allows the Federal Reserve to pursue inflation-lowering policies at the expense of employment and equality with little oversight or public discussion. Similarly, textbooks celebrate Federal Reserve transparency, which increased somewhat during the 1990s. Instead of keeping monetary policy secret, the Federal Reserve now announces its decisions promptly after each meeting. However, Federal Reserve meetings still take place behind closed doors and there is no support from current governors to expand the discussion to include public representatives or to increase Federal Reserve accountability, which is now limited to semi-annual reports to Congress. Textbooks are not alone in their uncritical approach to the Federal Reserve. Much of the media describe Federal Reserve policies as in the public interest without investigating who will benefit and who will lose based on its decisions. Similarly, there are few commentaries on the ways in which the Federal Reserve structure is at odds with the democratic and open decision making expected elsewhere in government. Your classroom would be a good place to start a more critical discussion of the Federal Reserve and its policies.
FISCAL
AND
MONETARY POLICY
169
15
n the sections on scal and monetary policies, textbooks combine a number of historical and theoretical topics that vary greatly in their difculty, thus presenting a challenge to the instructor. The coverage of the impact of government spending and taxes on GDP is usually relatively straightforward and is necessary for students NCEE Standard #20 Federal government budgetary policy and the Federal Reserve Systems monetary policy inuence the overall levels of employment, output, and prices. As with other macroeconomic standards, the statement is deliberately vague, collapsing all scal and monetary policy into a single statement. This is because Classical economic theory (and conservative political rhetoric) teaches that market economies, if left to themselves, would settle into states of full employment, growth, and price stability, without any need for government action. Thus the valid reasons foras well as the theories ofmore Keynesian-oriented active government stabilization policies are given short shrift in curriculum materials inspired by this view. Some materials even imply that government action can only make things worsefor example, they claim that government spending will only have the effect of causing interest rates to rise, crowding out private investment. But this pessimistic view of government is not a consensus view even within the neoclassical perspective, nor is it supported by empirical evidence.
169
170
BY
CHAPTER
to understand newspaper headlines. Similarly, coverage of the history of scal policy is accessible and appropriate for a high school course. The actions of the Federal Reserve in regard to interest rates are frequently in the news, and so also deserve explanation in the classroom. But on other concepts, you will need to make choices depending on the sophistication of your students and the time you have to teach more complicated material. In particular, we recommend a careful decision about the Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply diagram, an often misunderstood and therefore incorrectly taught model. As alternatives, you might select from other key concepts, each important for understanding policy (including: the multiplier, the circular ow with leakages and injections, automatic stabilizers, demand side versus supply side policies, and the debt and decit).
FISCAL
AND
MONETARY POLICY
171
NCEE Standard #18 A nations overall levels of income, employment, and prices are determined by the interaction of spending and production decisions made by all households, rms, government agencies, and others in the economy. Macroeconomic issues are almost entirely ignored until this standard, and it contains no conceptual content, merely noting that actors interact to determine outcomes. There is no explicit recognition of the business cycle, that is, the irregular ups and downs in all market economies, nor an analysis of the social costs of these swings. An alternative standard might point out that: The U.S. economy, like most other market economies, has experienced prolonged periods of slow or negative economic growth with high levels of unemployment.
decisions, different for consumers and businesses, can lead to a stable equilibrium below full employment. Waves of optimism and pessimism, he believed, caused business cycles by creating booms and busts in business spendingand then, through multiplier effects, further changes in the same direction in consumption spending and total output. The relatively straightforward observation that rational individual decisions can add up to an outcome that no one wants is lost in most textbooks. It should actually be emphasized because of its usefulness for making sense of the economy. It is easy for students to slip into the view that bad businesses, lazy workers, or spendthrift consumers are responsible for the economys woes. Textbooks do not differentiate carefully between this individualistic view of the world and a social perspective that attempts, as did Keynes, to understand why less-than-ideal society-wide outcomes occur even when people make decisions that are rational from their own individual points of view. Keynes himself never promoted the idea that expansionary scal policyincreased government spending or decreased taxeswas the cure-all for economic sluggishness. In fact, he thought that
172
BY
CHAPTER
A HINT
FOR
CLEAR TEACHING
Media headlines about the federal budget focus on the pros and cons of individual line items, such as Should we raise aid to education? or Should we lower the estate tax? However, macroeconomists recognize that whatever the merits of a particular spending or tax program, any changes in the federal budget will have an expansionary or contractionary impact. To help students remember the effects, you might refer to this as a gas or brake on the economy. As a rst approximation, more government spending speeds up the economy as do cuts in taxes (provided they affect consumption spending), whereas reductions in government spending and hikes in taxes do the reverse. The effect can be immediate, as in construction of a highway that itself adds a new good to GDP, or indirect, as in tax changes that cause more consumer spending or business investment. Each of these changes has a multiplier effect in which spending by government, consumers, or businesses increases the income of those providing the good or service, thereby prompting more spending, and so on. In order to explain equilibrium GDP, many textbooks refer back to the circular ow model that emphasized GDP as a ow that will be larger or smaller depending on injections or leakages. Because of the circular ow diagrams visual complexity, some students may prefer the simple formula used in some textbooks: GDP = C + I + G + Exports Imports, showing the importance of four independent sectors: households, businesses, government, and the foreign sector. The total of spending determined by this equation may or may not equal the amount of production being generated by the economy. If spending falls short of production, recession can result. If spending increases, full employment may be restored.
FISCAL
AND
MONETARY POLICY
173
economies would be inherently unstable as long as the determination of investment spending lay in private hands. He argued rst of all for a greater role for government in national investment planning, and only secondarily for changes in government spending or taxation. Early in the 1970s, some of those economists who called themselves Keynesians optimistically thought policy makers could ne-tune the economy and tame the business cycle by manipulating the levels of government spending and taxation. They were soon surprised by tenacious simultaneous ination and recession known as stagation. However, the Reagan policy response was not supply side economics as textbooks describe it, but actually a combination of straightforward Keynesian tax cuts and spending increases (mostly on the military) that had just the effect of stimulating demand that Keynesians would predict. The term supply side policies is used by textbooks in contradictory ways, both describing policies that were not exclusive to the Reagan era, such as programs to enhance productivity through research and development, and characterizing a conservative agenda to reduce government spending and regulation. This latter program rests on the dubious theory that a shrunken government spurs private investmenteven though important recent productivity-enhancing developments such as the jet engine, fast computers, and the Internet began with public not private initiatives. Many textbooks include lengthy sections on the Laffer Curve, a discredited economic theory proposed during the 1980s as a rationale for Reagan tax cuts. According to the Laffer Curve theory, reduced tax rates could increase government revenues, a result not supported by evidence at that time or since. Modern supply-siders still maintain that tax cuts spur work effort and new investments, but few economists argue for the extreme Laffer Curve outcome of greater tax revenue. Another way to understand scal policy is to examine its practical successes and failures. All textbooks present a list of reasons why scal policy does not work well, likely leaving students wondering what can be done to improve its effectiveness. Because it is difcult to use discretionary scal policy in a timely manner, economists recommend policies that can speed up or slow down the economy automatically, such as unemployment insurance and the progres-
174
BY
CHAPTER
sive income tax. Students may be helped by an analogy to a car, airplane, or other machine that requires some decisions to be made by the operator but does other actions automatically. Even though automatic stabilizers are covered in great detail, textbooks usually do not provide an explanation for why they are so crucial and miss the opportunity to engage students in current policy controversies about proposals to cut back unemployment insurance, the progressive income tax, and other automatic stabilizers. Many economists fear that such cutbacks would make the U.S. economy more prone to serious economic downturns.
A HINT
FOR
CLEAR TEACHING
Most textbooks end the scal policy section with a discussion of the federal debt and decit. It is important for students to differentiate between the debt and the decit, to learn when historically the debt has increased or decreased, and to understand the consequences of a national debt. On the last issue, textbook discussion is far more accurate than media reports that compare the debt to a bankrupt individual, and the decit to an irresponsible spender. While textbooks do a good job of pointing out the possible benets and problems of national debt, their discussion is unlikely to dissuade students who believe that debt is fundamentally wrong or that it necessarily imposes a burden on the future. You might begin by pointing out that individuals and corporations incur debt for investment purposes, sometimes increasing debt over time rather than paying it off just as governments need to nance public investment. However, the analogy stops there because federal government debt also permits constant injections of government spending that modern capitalism may require to prevent economic stagnation.
FISCAL
AND
MONETARY POLICY
175
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
Fiscal Policy
The Buck Institutes Presidents Dilemma at www.bie.org is a two- to three-week-long simulation problem in which students act as a Presidents Economic Consultant Team to develop policies in response to an economy in stagation. The Global Economics Game, available for sale from www. worldgameofeconomics.com, is a computer software simulation in which students control scal, monetary, and trade policies for a ctional country. Controlling the Economy in Economics Live! Learning Economics the Collaborative Way (McGraw-Hill, or contact the coauthor, Mark Maier, mmaier@glendale.edu) is a card game to give students practice in identifying the impact of scal and monetary policies. Fiscal Policy: A Two-Act Play in Capstone: Exemplary Lessons for High School Economics (NCEE, 2003) asks students to write the script for a play that illustrates expansionary and contractionary scal policy. Ask students to explore the ideas and writings of John Maynard Keynes in addition to the oversimplied legacy of Keynesianism. See the New Schools History of Economic Thought at http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/home.htm. The NCEE EconEdLinks (www.econedlink.org) Economics of the New Deal provides a set of questions for students to answer about the Great Depression and the U.S. governments response based on a variety of web resources. For materials to prompt class debate on the federal debt, ask students to compare sophisticated analysis from a conservative perspective (see, for example, www.heritagefoundation.org) and a liberal perspective (see, for example, www.epinet.org)
176
BY
CHAPTER
with relatively ill-informed but widely disseminated sources such as www.federalbudget.com. Students may understand scal policy better if they create their own analogies for scal policy concepts such as the multiplier, automatic stabilizers, leakages, and injections.
NCEE Standard #12 Interest rates, adjusted for ination, rise and fall to balance the amount saved with the amount borrowed, which affects the allocation of scarce resources between present and future uses. This standard presents a purely Classical view of the role of interest rates, investment, and savings. However, the macroeconomic balance implied by the standard is not a consensus viewpoint, even within neoclassical economics. On the aggregate level, many economists argue that the economy is not self-regulating in the way implied by this standard. Rather than a fall-off in borrowing for investment leading smoothly to a corresponding fall in savings due to interest-rate adjustments (as this standard implies will
FISCAL
AND
MONETARY POLICY
177
happen), such a cutback in borrowing can often lead to a fall-off in aggregate demand, a contraction in production, and rising unemployment. An alternative standard might point out that in a complex and interdependent economy, a rational decision at the microeconomic level, such as an individuals decision to forgo or delay investment spending, may not lead to a desirable outcome at the macroeconomic level. Such contradictory outcomes often occur between the individual and aggregate levels of analysis and are the basis for the Keynesian perspectives explanation of the business cycle.
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
Monetary Policy
The NCEE EconEdLink (www.econedlink.org) provides an every-six-week Case Study: The Federal Reserve System and Monetary Policy in which students analyze the latest FOMC announcement. Students will need assistance to appraise it critically. Consider using material from the Financial Markets Center (www.fmcenter.org) to provide political balance. NCEE Econnections, Where Did All the Money Go? The Great Depression Mystery at www.e-connections.org, provides handouts in which students explore possible causes for the Great Depression, including mishandled monetary policy.
178
BY
CHAPTER
AND
ACTIVITIES
RESOURCES
Macroeconomic Models
For a technical discussion of the AD/AS model, see David Colander, The Stories We Tell: A Reconsideration of the AS/AD Analysis, in The Stories Economists Tell: Essays on the Art of Teaching Economics (McGraw-Hill Irwin, 2006). If you have the leeway in your course to teach an alternative model to AD/AS, the basic Keynesian insight that insufcient aggregate demand can cause recession can be presented using the Keynesian Cross model. Unfortunately, while this used to be the bread-and-butter of introductory macroeconomics, it now less often used in college courses, and rarely taught in high school courses. Many expositions of the Keynesian diagram can be found online by simply doing an Internet search for Keynesian Cross. Also, the Global Development and Environment Institute (www.gdae.org) offers a free online macroeconomics textbook that covers this model in its chapter on Aggregate Demand. While written at a college level, it may be useful for background reading or an AP course.
Professional macroeconomists disagree about whether the foundations of the AD/AS model are valid. They abandon it entirely in some college textbooks, or include it only with serious reservations. But alternative approaches have not yet ltered down to high school textbooks. In addition, some textbooks entirely misinterpret the AD/AS diagram as simply the microeconomic demand and supply expanded to a larger scale. This is a serious error. In fact, AD/AS is a quite different model in which the reasoning behind the each lines slope is not the same as the microeconomic demand/supply diagram. Another problem with it is that students may ask why the model predicts deation (falling prices), an uncommon occurrence in modern economies. In its defense, the AD/AS model illustrates the important point that
FISCAL
AND
MONETARY POLICY
179
increases in aggregate demand are more likely to cause ination as the economy moves closer to full employment. However, at the introductory level, this concept could be explained descriptively without reference to an AD/AS diagram. Should you teach this formal macroeconomic model? If your students struggle with abstract concepts and mathematics, a verbal explanation that gets across the main points will be sufcient. You might be cautious about introducing formal modeling even with more-prepared students, since there is a tendency for learners to lose the forest for the trees once they are immersed in curve-shifting exercises. Overall, we do not recommend teaching the AD/AS model, although Advanced Placement instructors will need to cover the topic because it is included in the AP exam.
ECONOMIC GROWTH
AND
DEVELOPMENT
181
16
opics of economic growth and development may be spread out across many chapters of a high school textbook, or treated together in a chapter, usually toward the end of the book. The simplistic rightwing message is that economic growth is always good, is created by free market entrepreneurship, and will lead (if governments get out of the way) to an eventual closing of the income gap between rich and poor in the United States and other countries. The real picture is much more complicated.
NCEE Standard #15 Investment in factories, machinery, new technology, and in the health, education, and training of people can raise future standards of living. This standard is correct up to a point, but leaves out many important aspects of growth and development. For example, the standard completely fails to mention the importance of investing in the maintenance of societys ecological base and neglects to mention that governments and households play crucial roles in providing health and education. The standard may also seem to imply that developing countries need only follow such an investment path to close the global income gap.
181
182
BY
CHAPTER
ECONOMIC GROWTH
AND
DEVELOPMENT
183
or increase child poverty, they can have a very negative effect on economic growth.
AND THE
ENVIRONMENT
While most textbooks briey acknowledge that the average level of GDP per person is a very imperfect indicator of well-being, they still go on to treat GDP growth as unquestionably a good thing. While certainly in very poor countries some increase in production and consumption among the poorest groups is necessary to improve well-being, many economists and others have raised serious questions about whether GDP growth is always a good thing, especially in countries that are already wealthy and especially when long-run implications are taken into account. Does more production always result in more health and more satisfaction? What if more consumption is fueled by aggressive marketing campaigns that simply feed a desire for ever-increasing material goods and entertainment? What if new factories increase the release of toxic chemicals, or new fossil-fuel-based machinery adds to global climate change? Such investments may actually lower future standards of living. Many people question whether ever-higher through-put of materials and energy is good for humansor the planet. Economics textbooks simply ignored this issue for years. These days, with so many students becoming environmentally conscious, conservative curriculum writers have attempted to address this interest by promoting what economists call the environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis (although this technical term will not appear in the textbook). This hypothesis suggests that as income levels rise, countries tend to buy more environmental protection. Increasing afuence, they say, turns peoples attention from basic industrial production to more luxury items, such as a more pleasant environment, with cleaner air and water. Therefore, it is hypothesized, higher growth will (eventually) lead to more environmental protection. Unfortunately, empirical support for this hypothesis is weak, andeven if it were trueconsiderable damage (perhaps much of it irreversible, and severely detrimental to life and health) can occur if we simply wait for people to get rich enough to want to spend on the environment.
184
BY
CHAPTER
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
Economic Growth
Have your students read an article that is critical of the idea that growth leads to greater environmental protection, such as Is NAFTA Working for Mexico? (2006) or Have Faith in Free TradeThe Greatest Story Over Sold (2001), both by Kevin Gallagher and available from www.gdae.org, While the PBS (www.pbs.org) educational web site Commanding Heights: The Battle for the World Economy takes something of an overall pro-growth, free trade slant, some of its component units (such as video clips and lesson plans) give a more rich and nuanced picture. Its unit on economic growthwhich includes discussion of distributional issues is visually rich and comes with a guide for educators. At this point in the course, students may be able to use their economic knowledge to analyze a local or national environmental issue. Help students to sort out the political debate about solutions to environmental problems. Beware of one-sided curricular materials (for example, materials from the Foundation for Teaching Economics) that suggest an economic approach argues against government intervention. In the lesson plan Oil and the Bell-Shaped Curve (www. teachablemoment.org/high/oilbellcurve.html), from Educators for Social Responsibility Metro Area, students critically analyze U.S. energy policy. See also Better Measures of Economic Activity and WellBeing, p. 137; Consumer Society, p. 100; Ecological Economics, p. 45; Globalization, p. 190; Trade and Comparative Advantage, p. 195.
ECONOMIC GROWTH
AND
DEVELOPMENT
185
186
BY
CHAPTER
example, simply create industrial enclaves that do little to promote investment or innovation elsewhere in the economy. Multinational corporations have sometimes engaged in damaging practices, such as colluding with local leaders to violently suppress worker unrest. Some very poor countries have become so deeply mired in foreign debt that they now send more funds abroad as interest payments on their debt than they spend on health care for their own populations, and pay more in interest than they get in new grants and loans. The resulting international debt crisis has drawn the attention of many religious groups and ethical thinkersis it fair to ask desperately poor countries to repay loans, some of which may have been forced upon them by dictatorial regimes? In the 1980s and 1990s the International Monetary Fund and other lenders imposed Structural Adjustment Policies (SAPs) on many countries, including poor ones, when they believed that excessive government spending was behind a countrys failure to make good on its international nancial obligations. In a number of cases, SAPs forced governments to cut spending on health and education. In response to widespread criticism, the IMF has since replaced SAPs with other programs that are ostensibly more directed toward poverty alleviation. But many critics questions whether these reforms go far enough. Militarization also plays a role in diverting resources from development purposes. Sometimes aid given by rich countries to poor countries has been in the form of armamentswhich may even be used to suppress domestic populations. A history of colonialism can also create problems. Many poor countries have a short-run comparative advantage (see Chapter 17) in producing raw agricultural commodities because their economies were shaped by colonizing nations that wanted them to supply such goods. Plantation systems and railroad infrastructure, for example, were set up to get cotton (or some other commodity) to the nearest port, not to get people involved in industry or get children to school. And, of course, the epidemic of AIDS in Africa has caused the rosy forecast of development theorists to become even more remote from reality. In many countries, low levels of both education and opportunities for women contribute to low productivity and high birthrates. While free marketoriented textbooks tend to emphasize the experience of small, export-oriented countries like Singapore and South
ECONOMIC GROWTH
AND
DEVELOPMENT
187
Korea, the real story about development is being told in India and Chinatwo countries that together account for 38 percent of the worlds population. Both countries have made some headway in alleviating poverty, but through the use of a wide variety of policies and institutions. While foreign subcontracting to India has gotten a lot of media attention recently, and markets have played an increasing role in China in the last decades, both countries are far from being poster children for free market entrepreneurship. What serious students of development know is that there is no one size ts all prescription for raising living standards that can be applied to any country. A more serious question concerns the goals of development themselves. Many now dispute the idea that poor countries are developing along a path that will eventually lead them to a standard of living similar to that enjoyed in the United States or Europe. Rather than refer to poorer countries as developing countries, such analysts prefer to divide counties into the classications of Global South (poorer and less industrialized countries) and Global North (industrialized countries in Europe and North America, along with Japan, Australia, and similar nations). Rather than counting on economic growth (alone) to alleviate poverty, issues are raised about global justice. They question the current pattern of global distribution and use of resourcesespecially food, technology, and energyon grounds of fairness and humanity. The relation of development goals to ecological concerns is also a subject of lively debate. The impossibility of the catch-up hypothesis is most clearly illustrated by analysts estimate that, as mentioned in Chapter 8, getting everyone in the world to a U.S. lifestyle would require an extra two to four planets to provide materials and absorb wastes. Serious environmental problems arising from rapid and unregulated industrial growth in China are increasingly coming to light, and discussions of global warming are becoming more urgent. Yet, from a global justice perspective, is it clearly unfair to ask poorer countries, in which many people are still poorly nourished, housed, and educated, to simply halt their economic growth. Many are now calling for ecologically sustainable growth in poorer countries as a way of trying to raise living standards while not causing additional environmental damage. The tricky part is how to get such growth under waysuch a project is much harder than simply dropping trade barriers and welcoming foreign investments.
188
BY
CHAPTER
AND
ACTIVITIES
RESOURCES
Development
The Public Broadcasting Service (www.pbs.org) offers a high school lesson plan, Global Women and Poverty, based on video proles of women in Thailand and Senegal, that includes class activities and references to related resources. Jubilee USA Network, part of an international movement lobbying for cancellation of the debt of poor countries, maintains a list of resources, including print educational materials and lms (www.jubileeusa.org). Be aware that some (but not all) of these materials are designed for use with church groups. The readable essay Kicking Away the Ladder: How the Economic and Intellectual Histories of Capitalism Have Been Re-Written to Justify Neo-Liberal Capitalism, by Ha-Joon Chang, documents how import-protection tariffs and subsidies that are now forbidden to developing countries played key roles in the development of Britain and the United States. It is available from www.paecon.net. MexicoUnited States: The Environmental Costs of Trade-led Growth, by Kevin P. Gallagher, and The WTOs Development Crumbs (2006), by Timothy A. Wise, present evidence against the theory that free trade is of great advantage to developing countries. Both are available from www.gdae.org. Students may be interested in learning about the fair trade movement, which seeks to make international trade more benecial for producers in countries of the South, and often to make it more ecologically sustainable as well. Transfair USA is one organization involved in this movement, and its web site (www.transfairusa.org) offers resources (including factsheets and links) that could be useful in teaching. See also Consumer Society, p. 100; Ecological Economics, p. 45; Global Distribution of Well-Being, p. 38; Globalization, p. 190; International Finance, p. 196; Multinational Corporations, p. 197; Sweatshops, p. 59.
GLOBAL ECONOMICS
AND
TRADE
189
17
nternational economics is a complicated topic, and its treatment is often left to the end of a textbook. Materials created from a politically conservative perspective tend to emphasize the benets of specialization and trade, arguing that a lack of barriers to international ows of goods, services, and nancial capital is the key to economic growth and prosperity. A more balanced approach, while recognizing the potential benets of increased international connectedness, also points out the problems that can be created by unrestrained globalization, in particular if it takes place with rules that favor large corporations or others with access to great power and resources.
17.1 DEBATES
ON
GLOBALIZATION
Debates on globalization have become very heated and often very polarized, especially since the 1999 demonstrations at the Seattle meetings of the World Trade Organization. Many textbooks staunchly defend the most rigid, free market end of the spectrum, and a number of educational web sites continue this theme. On the other hand, you may also nd that materials from some of the critics of globalization oversimplify international economics as purely a domain of evil, predatory, giant corporations bent on grinding the poor and achieving total world domination. Even the denition of globalization is disputed, though most discussions include some aspects of international trade, international nance, or the reach of multinational or transnational corporations. We have tried to highlight some relatively balanced materials in our recommendations for activities and resources, but have also included some that take a decidedly anti-globalization stance since these
189
190
BY
CHAPTER
might be useful in balancing out a very pro-globalization textbook as well as profree trade materials available from the National Council on Economic Education, the U.S. Federal Reserve, and the International Monetary Fund (see Resources chapter). People who study globalization issues seriously and in detail rarely take either extreme position: questions of what is being globalized and how are of primarily importanceand the devil is often in the details.
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
Globalization
Consider getting the book Rethinking Globalization, edited by Bill Bigelow and Bob Peterson (Rethinking Schools, 2002). This volume contains readings and teaching ideas on topics including sweatshops, colonialism, child labor, poverty, and the environment. See www.rethinkingschools.org for a description and a number of links to resources (that can be useful whether you get the book or not). Facing the Future (www.facingthefuture.org) offers a number of helpful lesson plans on global issues, including environmental degradation, poverty, and consumption. A number of lesson plans on globalization issues, including development, women, and the environment, are available from the Center for Strategic and International Studies at www.globalization101.org. While generally informative and less heavily ideological than the most right-wing textbooks, these materials still tend to emphasize optimistic and pro-market arguments. For example, the benets of comparative advantage, positive aspects of the World Bank, and U.S. arguments against the Kyoto Protocol are emphasized, while opposing views are given less attention. See also Ecological Economics, p. 45; Economic Growth, p. 184; Economic Systems; p. 65; Economic Systems and Goals, p. 67; Development, p. 188; Trade and Comparative Advantage, p. 195; International Finance, p. 196; Multinational Corporations, p. 197; Sweatshops, p. 59.
GLOBAL ECONOMICS
AND
TRADE
191
17.2 TRADE
AND THE
THEORY
OF
COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE
The story of comparative advantage and gains from trade may be presented in an international context, or may be found much earlier in the book as part of an argument for free enterprise economic systems. While the exact examples given vary, they usually involve some simple numerical calculations showing that two countries (or people, or rms) will be better off if they each specialize in the production of one good, and then trade to get the amount they desire of the good produced by the other.
NCEE Standard #6 When individuals, regions, and nations specialize in what they can produce at the lowest cost and then trade with others, both production and consumption increase. It is true that the process of specialization and trade may lead to gains in material well-being, especially in the short run. But it may also lead to losses over the long run, interfere with other important goals, or be structured in a way that is unfair or perpetuates poverty among some groups. A more complete view of economic life takes into account the drawbacks as well as the advantages of free trade.
In any context, howeverand particularly the international oneit is important to also consider the drawbacks of specialization according to comparative advantage. These include:
Vulnerability
An obvious problem is that each party becomes more vulnerable to the actions of its trading partners. Countries that are heavily dependent on foreign suppliers for oil, minerals, or food face serious shortages if conicts break out or world prices for these goods rise. Countries that specialize in producing and exporting a narrow range of goods risk disaster if the world price of what they sell falls. Many
192
BY
CHAPTER
poor countries are highly dependent on export earnings from coffee, sugar, and other agricultural commoditiesand see their economies rise and fall steeply with world prices, as well as conditions such as crop-specic diseases or drought. In addition to thinking about the benets of trade, one also has to think about the costs of depending on specialization and trade in terms of lost self-sufciency and diversication.
Job Losses
When a country stops producing something and imports it instead, the people who used to be employed in that industry are put out of work. While conservative textbooks emphasize the short-run benets of excessive specialization, they very much de-emphasize the problem of job losses, claiming that this is merely a short-run problem. They imply that the social costs of job losses are strictly temporary, as workers will move to other jobs. They claim that the loss to some workers will rapidly be balancedand
GLOBAL ECONOMICS
AND
TRADE
193
moreby benets to consumers and workers in other industries. There are problems with each of these arguments. First, structural unemployment caused by changes in industrial patterns can be very persistent, as it may be almost impossible for people to take the skills developed in one line of work and apply them somewhere else. Job losses may be particularly hard on older workers, who have invested deeply in job-specic skills and have little time left to make retraining pay off. Second, the idea that a country is in general better off with free trade ignores the distributional issues involved. If a certain class of workersor a particular community or regionis harmed by the lowering of trade barriers, it does not help them that someone somewhere else is made better off. This is not to say that trade barriers should never be lowered, but rather that arguments for free trade should take issues surrounding job losses seriously, not just gloss them over with rhetoric about their being temporary or limited to one group.
194
BY
CHAPTER
tal standards and taxes. Countries may nd themselves drawn into a race to the bottom, in which they compete to attract businesses based on their lack of attention to social and environmental concerns. Many conservative teaching materials portray labor and environmental standards (such as certication that imports not be produced by slave or child labor, or that they not contain certain toxins) as nothing more than smokescreens for efforts by powerful domestic companies and labor unions to protect domestic jobs. While use of labor and environmental standards as a guise for promotion of narrow interests is not unheard of, certainly some standards serve a valid social purpose andif widely adoptedwould lead to greater human well-being and ecological sustainability. A greater danger than too high standards is often too low standards, as the international bodies that set standards tend to be much more strongly inuenced by powerful corporations than by ecological, consumer, or worker organizations. Typically, textbooks will discuss these drawbacks to free trade, but then refute them with the argument that the increased efciency arising from free trade will create sufcient prosperity to make everyoneand the environmentbetter off. This is, however, merely a statement of ideology rather than a claim based on the workings of real-world economies.
GLOBAL ECONOMICS
AND
TRADE
195
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
196
BY
CHAPTER
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
International Finance
Marketplace: Lets Go Euro! available at www.econedlink. org, provides a classroom activity on the history of the euro and issues arising from its use. Currency rates are available online. Ask students to explain the impact of a recent change on consumers, workers, and producers in different countries. Students can examine current debates about the effect of a higher or lower U.S. dollar exchange rate on different groups in the United States. Or, students could study the impact of sudden changes in currency values, as in the case of the Thai baht in 1997. The PBS video Life and Debt looks at issues of globalization from the viewpoint of Jamaican workers (available from www.pbs.org). The related PBS web site also offers bibliographic materials, including pro and con essays on globalization. The part of the PBS (www.pbs.org) educational web site, Commanding Heights: The Battle for the World Economy, on the nancial contagion that hit Asia in the late 1990s, gives a graphic introduction to the problems of rapid and unregulated international capital ows. Have your students learn about the international Tobin Tax Initiative. (The web site for the U.S. group is currently www. ceedweb.org/iirp.) See also Development, p. 188; Ecological Economics, p. 45; Economic Systems and Goals, p. 67.
GLOBAL ECONOMICS
AND
TRADE
197
ACTIVITIES
AND
RESOURCES
Multinational Corporations
Fortune magazine has an annual listing of the largest international corporations. Ask students to nd out where companies are headquartered, what lines of business they engage in, and whether these companies directly or indirectly touch their lives. To balance an overly rosy globalization curriculum, consider showing the video Global Village or Global Pillage? How People Around the World Are Challenging Corporate Globalization (1999, http://stonesou.xeran.com/gvgp). Many critics from the left believe that corporate responsibility is an oxymoron (that is, self-contradictory), and that corporations are predestined to act irresponsibly. They believe they must be disbanded or brought under strict state control. See the book Economics for Humans, by Julie A. Nelson (University of Chicago Press, 2006), for an alternative view, arguing that businesses can and should be responsible actors.
198
BY
CHAPTER
Now that the students are nearing the end of the course and have had exposure to standardand perhaps some alternative economics, a thought-provoking exercise might be to ask students to think about what the most relevant aspects of an economy would be, judged from various perspectives, such as U.S. citizen versus citizen of Somalia, a corporate CEO versus a worker, rich versus poor, male versus female, businessperson versus social scientist, a U.S. worker versus a worker in Bangladesh. For example, is a very poor person likely to think of economics in terms of rational choice? Will a person who cooks for her or his family accept that only meals produced in restaurants have economic value? Will a person involved in social work, or a government employee, agree that only products sold in markets make an economic contribution? Is marginal thinking really part of the daily practice of business managers, in the students experience? What might a person two or three generations from now think about our present-day economic priorities (particularly concerning the environment and debt)? You might think of other interesting perspectives to add to this list. See also Development, p. 188; Ecological Economics, p. 45; Economic Systems and Goals, p. 67; Corporate Accountability, p. 107; Corporate Power, p. 93; Responsible Entrepreneurship, p. 46.
PART
III Resources
RESOURCE MATERIALS
201
18
Resource Materials
ew resources, updates, and changed web addresses are available at the books web site, www.introducingeconomics.org. Please contact Mark Maier at mmaier@glendale.edu if you nd a new resource that you would like us to add to the web site, or if you nd a correction that needs to be made. American Labor Studies Center www.labor-studies.org
Organized by U.S. labor unions to collect, analyze, evaluate, create and disseminate labor history and labor studies curricula and related materials, the site provides annotated links to dozens of lesson plans on labor, child labor, and labor history, and a twenty-page Labor Education for the K12 Curriculum. This is a good starting point to nd lessons from a variety of sources. American Social History Project / Center for Media and Learning www.ashp.cuny.edu Based at the Graduate Center, City University of New York, the project produces print, visual and multimedia materials about the working men and women whose actions and beliefs shaped U.S. history. The project offers highly engaging lessons based on original books and CD-ROMs and is especially useful for courses integrating economic history and for labor history. Buck Institute, Problem Based Economics www.bie.org/pbe This nonprot research and development organization working to make schools and classrooms more effective through the use of problem
201
202
RESOURCES
and project based learning was created in 1987 with funding from the Buck Trust. In economics, the institute offers eight complete lessons, plus one introductory unit, in which students confront a realistic economic problem and role play to learn economic concepts tied explicitly to NCEE standards. Each unit requires considerable class time (one day to three weeks). Center for Environmental Education Online www.ceeonline.org A nonprot environmental organization funded by a private foundation, this center hosts a Curriculum Library linking to many K12 lesson plans created by other organizations. Some, listed under the headings of Economics or Globalization, contain economic content, but the quality is variable. Center for Popular Economics www.populareconomics.org The Center for Popular Economics is best known for its book, The Ultimate Field Guide to the U.S. Economy (updated at www.fguide. org), and summer workshops for educators and political activists interested in a left perspective. High school teachers will nd most useful the Econ-Atrocity bulletins, interspersed with occasional Econ-Utopia bulletins. These breezily written essays, offering a left-wing view on economic issues such as farm subsidies, soft drink prices, and the legacy of Alan Greenspan, could be a provocative counterpart to articles from the business press. Globalization Briefs published in collaboration with Political Economy Research Institute at the University of MassachusettsAmherst and supported by the Ford Foundation are higher-level readings that may be difcult for high school students even with their convenient online glossary. Consumer Jungle www.consumerjungle.org Established as the result of a lawsuit against Sears Corporation, Consumer Jungle offers teaching units with interactive games on credit, budgeting, and buying cars, computers, and phones. The Consumer Awareness side of the web site provides updated information on corporate practices harmful to consumers.
RESOURCE MATERIALS
203
Creative Change: Educational Solutions www.creativechange.net This nonprot group based in Michigan is committed to promoting economic, environmental, and community well-being. It is a clearinghouse for lesson plans, some of which are downloadable (registration required), on environmental, land use, food, ecological, and cultural responsiveness. Dollars and Sense www.dollarsandsense.org Dollars & Sense is a non-prot group that publishes a bimonthly magazine of economic justice (Dollars & Sense) and Real World readers on microeconomics, macroeconomics, the environment, and globalization. Although most of the articles will be appropriate only for sophisticated high school readers, the magazines up-to-date coverage offers new material that you could use in class. Also helpful for class preparation are the previews and discussion questions in each section of Real World Macro and Real World Micro. EcEdWeb http://ecedweb.unomaha.edu Online since 1995, EcEdWeb is a frequently updated site designed especially for Nebraska teachers, but nonetheless is useful for high school and college teachers nationwide. The Economic Data and Information page includes annotated commentary and links to many online sources. The directory of lesson plans is noteworthy for integrating geography and history in addition to more standard economics lessons from the NCEE (see below), although many of the lessons still reect a strong neoclassical and entrepreneurial bent. Web Teach provides helpful advice on using the Internet in teaching economics, and practical guidance for studying controversial issues and using experiments and simulations in class. Facing the Future www.facingthefuture.org This group, funded by progressive foundations and some corporations, takes as its goal developing young peoples capacity and commitment to create thriving, sustainable, and peaceful local and
204
RESOURCES
global communities. It provides both free downloadable activities (registration required) and materials for sale on global issues, including the environment, poverty, and consumption, designed for use in middle school and high school classrooms. The Federal Reserve www.federalreserve.gov (and see sites for the twelve district Federal Reserve banks) The U.S. Federal Reserve is unique in economic education because it is both a powerful policy-making organization (see Chapters 14 and 15) as well as a prolic source of education publications, online simulation activities, and on-site museum exhibits. The Board of Governors web site is the entry point for information on the U.S. money supply, background of appointees to the Federal Reserve, and minutes of policy-making meetings, as well as helpful links to information about monetary data and central banks in other countries. This site is especially useful for activities that require students to collect up-to-date and reliable information on banking and monetary policy. Although actual policy making is centralized in the Washington, DCbased Board of Governors, economic education efforts are dispersed between the Board and the twelve district banks. Most educational programs are cross-listed, so the Board of Governors is a good place to start, but likely you will be sent to a district banks education site. The Federal Reserve has useful interactive online programs describing its organization and policy-making tools. Since Federal Reserve actions tend to be poorly understood by the public, these may be helpful. Most noteworthy are Fed 101 (from the Board of Governors, cosponsored with USA Today), About the Fed and Fedville (San Francisco), FOMC Simulation (New York), and In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve (St. Louis). Several of the regional bank sites emphasize the role of currency, such as its design and anti-counterfeiting efforts. Although interesting to students, currency is of declining importance in the U.S. economy, and has little to do with the central banks more important monetary policy function. Just as the Federal Reserve policy making straddles the public and private worlds, its economic education role attempts both to educate
RESOURCE MATERIALS
205
the public about how the Federal Reserve operates as well as promote its ideological positions. (See Chapter 14 on the Federal Reserves authority resting both with presidential and private bank appointees.) The Federal Reserves curriculum on central bank independence, concluding that central banks should not be very politically accountable, is just one example of bias in Federal Reserve educational efforts. A study by the independent watchdog Financial Markets Center concluded: in many cases the Fed appears to be lending its unparalleled prestige and authority to instructional programs that collapse the many varieties of economic thought into a simple doctrinaire message: markets rule, business is sovereign, workers are an interest groupand economic education exists to uncritically promote free enterprise. (See below on Financial Markets Center monitoring of Federal Reserve programs.) Teachers should take care in adopting Federal Reserve materials on controversial issues. In some cases, Federal Reserve bias is obvious, as in a Minneapolis Fed essay contest that awarded prizes to essays that argued, for example, that governments should do nothing about income inequality, or that poverty is primarily caused by a lack of private property rights and free markets. Similarly, widely distributed (and free to the user) videos, comic books, and other publications take an unabashedly extreme free market view of economics. For example, the Dallas Fed features Free Enterprise: The Economics of Cooperation, by Dwight R. Lee, a well-known conservative economist. Federal Reserve banks have signed on with one-sided ideological groups such as the E. Angus Powell Endowment for American Enterprise (partnered with the Richmond Fed for workshops and the Econ-Exchange for K12 teachers) and the Foundation for Teaching Economics (partner with several Fed banks). Such collaboration is troublesome for a governmental institution created by the U.S. Congress to act in the public interest. The conservative bias should be noted by teachers who use the Federal Reserve for curricular ideas and materials. Federal Resources for Educational Excellence (FREE) www.ed.gov/free Organized by subject area, the Social Studies/Economics area of this web site contains a short but useful annotated list of online classroom
206
RESOURCES
resources that might otherwise be overlooked. All have been created by federal agencies, including the Library of Congress, the Securities and Exchange Commission, and the Department of the Treasury. For resources from the Federal Reserve, go directly to its site because few are listed here (and see the cautionary note above). Financial Markets Center (FMC) www.fmcenter.org Underwritten mainly by grants from charitable foundations, the FMC works with policy makers, scholars, journalists, and educators to enhance the accountability of monetary authorities and build the capacity of central banks and regulatory systems to promote economic outcomes that broadly benet all members of society. Timely reports by the FMC can help you understand Federal Reserve policy-making and evaluate appointments to the Federal Reserves Board of Governors. Beginning in 2007, FMC will offer reports on its web site evaluating the strengths and weaknesses of Federal Reserve economic education programs, many of which are designed for high school classrooms. Foundation for Economic Education www.fee.org The Foundation for Economic Education is dedicated to the sanctity of private property, individual liberty, the rule of law, the free market, and the moral superiority of individual choice and responsibility over coercion. The foundation offers highly subsidized summer programs for high school students called Freedom 101: Liberty, Morality, and the Free Market. The foundation is best known for its publication The Freeman (archived on line), with short articles that typically push individualistic and anti-government arguments to an extreme. Users beware. Foundation for Teaching Economics www.fte.org The Foundation for Teaching Economics (FTE) provides curriculum materials and training workshops for teachers. Most programs are free or highly subsidized thanks to foundation and corporate funding, including support from large donors to right-wing causes, such as the Sarah Scaife and Castle Rock Foundation. Thus, participants should be
RESOURCE MATERIALS
207
aware of political bias in these programs. For example, FTE interns, who receive substantial stipends, are placed at conservative think tanks such as the Cato Institute and the National Taxpayers Union. As bets the FTEs generous funding, its workshop staff are highly professional and the curricular materials are, from a pedagogical point of view, sophisticated and well tested. However, each of the projects we examined promoted extreme right-wing political positions. The teacher training on environmental issues features a curriculum written with a grant from Coca-Cola through the Political Economy Research Center (PERC), a Montana research organization committed to free market environmentalism and a leader in opposing the Superfund and the Endangered Species Act. Similarly, FTEs Is Capitalism Good for the Poor?available online and on CD realizes the goal of its major funding organization, the John Templeton Foundation, to support programs that encourage free-market principles. FTE measures success of the curriculum based on a 26 percent increase in the number of teachers who agreed with the statement Capitalism is good for the poor after participating in a training program. However, when used with care, sections of the curriculum could encourage critical thinking by students, for example, Lesson 1, Part 1 on What Is Poverty and Who Are the Poor? and Lesson 5 on the Ultimatum Game (see Chapter 5). Somewhat less ideological and of potential interest to instructors are Prize Winning Lessons written by high school instructors and posted at the FTE web site. Games Economists Play: Non-computerized Classroom Games for College Economics www.marietta.edu/~delemeeg/games Although designed for use by college teachers, many of the games are easily adaptable for use in high school classrooms. Includes more than 130 games, most of which can be played within one class meeting. Organized by topic in micro- and macroeconomics. Global Development and Environmental Institute (GDAE) www.gdae.org
208
RESOURCES
Although the educational materials developed by GDAE are primarily geared for a university audience, some of them may be also be useful in a high school course. GDAEs Teaching Modules on Social and Environmental Issues in Economics offer student readings and instructor support materials (downloadable free of charge) on a variety of issues. Funded largely by private and progressive foundations, the institute is dedicated to promoting a better understanding of how societies can pursue their economic and community goals in an environmentally and socially sustainable manner. Globalization 101: A Project of the Carnegie Endowment www.globalization101.org A number of lessons plans on globalization issues, including development, women, and environment, are available from the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. While generally informative and less heavily ideological than most textbooks, be aware that these materials still tend to emphasize optimistic and pro-market arguments. International Monetary Fund Center: A Public Center for Economics Education www.imf.org/external/np/exr/center The International Monetary Fund (IMF), founded in 1944 with 184 member countries, states as its goal: Ensuring the stability of the international monetary and nancial system. The IMF project EconEd Online offers links to lesson plans, many produced by or in partnership with the National Council on Economic Education (NCEE). These follow the National Voluntary Content Standards and are full of self-serving promotion for the IMF. The section Common Criticisms of the IMF simply refutes these criticisms and does not promote critical thinking by students. See Chapter 17 for sources that provide a more balanced view. Jump$tart Coalition for Personal Financial Literacy www.jumpstart.org Jump$tart Coalition is an umbrella group of professional organizations, private corporations, and government agencies created in 1995 to promote the teaching of personal nance. Of greatest interest to teachers is the Jump$tart Clearinghouse, a web-based listing of more
RESOURCE MATERIALS
209
than 500 teaching resources on consumer issues (such as how to buy a car, obtain a credit card, etc.). The database can be searched by grade level and type of resource (e.g., print, web, audiovisual), and provides information on how to contact each items publisher. References to consumer advocacy groups and policy debates, however, are limited. Since the database relies heavily on materials from the U.S. Federal Trade Commission for its high schoollevel resources, you may nd the FTC site to be an easier place to begin a search. In some states, active Jump$tart chapters sponsor workshops and advocate increased attention to personal nance courses. Jump$tart takes partial credit for recent interest in adding personal nance to the high school curriculum either as part of a traditional economics requirement, or a stand-alone course. Jump$tart developed the National Standards in Personal Finance. Jump$tart clearly identies its own funding from modest corporate grants, supplemented in recent years by major support from McGrawHill, Bank of America, and the U.S. Department of Education. Junior Achievement www.ja.org Founded in 1919 as an after-school program in which students set up small businesses, Junior Achievement rst entered the classroom in 1975. Since then, it has broadened its scope to include a kindergarten through twelfth grade economics curriculum with a textbook for use in traditional high school economics courses, as well as courses taught by business executives and a program in which students organize and operate an actual small business selling items such as business cards or coffee beans. Junior Achievement claims to reach 7 million students every year and has expanded to programs in 112 countries. Headquarters staff in Colorado Springs produce curricular material, while regional ofces support classroom volunteers, drawn mostly from local private businesses. Promoting its free enterprise message of hope and opportunity, Junior Achievement is primarily corporate-sponsored, with Kraft Foods, Citigroup, Deloitte, and HBSC as primary donors. Junior Achievements greatest high school market penetration (their term) is JA Economics, a textbook we refer to frequently in this guide. Its brevity and low cost are attractive to schools even if they do
210
RESOURCES
not use Junior Achievement volunteers in the classroom. Many teachers are rightly concerned about being required to use a textbook from a group with such a clear ideological intent. The textbook combines traditional neoclassical and entrepreneurial approaches. Its neoclassical bent is very clear in its strong implicit assumptions about the advantages of markets, and it gives even less attention than other bestselling texts to income distribution and environmental problems. Junior Achievement sponsors frequent surveys on young peoples attitudes toward economics and nance. Although sometimes couched in booster terms, describing youth as an entrepreneurial group of bold and independent risk-takers, the reporting on the polls is presented straightforwardly, including overwhelming support by teens for labor unions, and unrealistic expectations for their own incomes (15 percent believing they will have incomes over $1 million per year by the age of forty). Surveys on boy versus girl expectations about expected earnings and career choices could also be an interesting starting point for a class activity, in particular if student expectations revealed in the poll were compared with current actual economic conditions. The Junior Achievement web site also offers online simulations on personal nance and starting a business. National Association of Economic Educators (NAEE) http://ecedweb.unomaha.edu/naee.htm The professional association afliated with the National Council on Economic Education (see below) serves as a support and communication network for economic educators, primarily on the high school level. It cosponsors a biannual conference with NCEE and offers small grants for professional development activities. National Council on Economic Education www.ncee.net Founded in 1949, the National Council on Economic Education (NCEE) is the largest and most inuential source of materials for the high school economics curriculum. The national organization distributes more than eighty print and CD-ROM publications, and web-based resources for traditional economics courses as well as personal nance, history, and mathematics. NCEE was primarily
RESOURCE MATERIALS
211
responsible for developing the Voluntary National Content Standards discussed throughout this guide. In recent years NCEE has distributed funds under the Federal Excellence in Economic Education program, sponsored an annual National Summit on Economic Literacy, and conducted polls on student and adult economic understanding. NCEE created a network of state councils and over two hundred universitybased centers that offer workshops and other training programs for teachers. These local groups rely largely on NCEE publications, but operate independently and thus vary in the level of support provided to teachers. In terms of expenditure, the largest NCEE program is Economics International, funded by the U.S. Department of Education to introduce economics education in Eastern Europe and the new independent states of the former Soviet Union. The project also generated publications intended for U.S. high schools on transitional economies and international economics. Otherwise, most support for NCEE and its state councils comes from corporate and foundation sources, such as State Farm Insurance, International Paper, and McGraw-Hill Companies, which are also represented on the NCEE Board of Directors. NCEE takes a less overt political position than Junior Achievement and FTE (see above), although NCEE refers teachers to both organizations at its web site. On occasion, the conict of interest between the subject matter and the funding source is obvious, as in the NCEEs Learning from the Market (see Chapter 9). These lessons are based on a stock market game that was sponsored until 2003 by the Securities Industry Association, a trade group representing banks, brokers, and mutual fund companies. Since 2003, it has been sponsored by the associations afliate, the Foundation for Investor Education. More often, corporate inuence is in what is left out of the curriculum, for example in the Bank of Americafunded Financial Fitness for Life, which does not include current debates about advertising, consumerism, or the role of banks in consumer credit card problems. Most NCEE teaching materials underscore the benets of markets and take a negative view of government intervention. When a debate is presented, typically it features a topic about which students and noneconomist teachers are likely to favor government action, such as pollution abatement or wage discrimination. In these activities, students read an eloquent argument in favor of market outcomes that
212
RESOURCES
is likely to challenge their pro-interventionist predilections. Equally strong arguments critical of market outcomes are absent from NCEE materials as are debates about income and wealth distribution and corporate inuence on politics and culture. With these concerns about ideological bias and corporate inuence in mind, teachers nonetheless may nd NCEE materials helpful in preparing class lessons. For an overview, consult Virtual Economics, a CD-ROM available for purchase with 1,200 lessons, and Thinking Economics, an entire economics course taught with CD-ROMs and interactive lessons. A most useful and free NCEE resource for teachers is www. econedlink.org, a partner in www.marcopolo-education.org, a multidisciplinary Internet-based content site, sponsored by MCI. The key feature at EconEdLink is a pull-down list of over four hundred lessons written for this site and organized by topic, grade level, and NCEE content standard. Some of the lessons are dated, and some are onesided in their political presentation. Nonetheless, all are well designed from a pedagogical standpoint, with easily printable handouts, and require reasonable amounts of class time; although they are called Economics Minutes, most take half an hour to an entire class period. The Datalink section describes Internet sources on economic data, mostly macroeconomic, including numbers themselves and separate links to summaries of how they are measured. The Current Events section includes text of news articles updated weekly with links to particular NCEE lesson plans. Powell Center for Economic Literacy www.powellcenter.org Originally underwritten by E. Angus Powell, former chair of the board of the Richmond Federal Reserve Bank, the center provides online lesson plans and a semi-annual publication with teaching ideas, and subsidizes workshops for teachers and courses for students. Most products are highly ideological, reecting Mr. Powells unwavering commitment to the free enterprise system. Rethinking Schools www.rethinkingschools.org
RESOURCE MATERIALS
213
Rethinking Schools publishes educational materials committed to the vision that public education is central to the creation of a humane, caring, multiracial democracy. The quarterly journal Rethinking Schools is an important channel for current debate about U.S. educational practice. Several books published or sold by Rethinking Schools are referenced in this guide: Rethinking Mathematics: Teaching Social Justice by the Numbers; Rethinking Globalization: Teaching for Justice in an Unjust World; and The Power in Our Hands: A Curriculum on the History of Work and Workers in the United States. Rethinking Schools curricular materials, including simulation exercises and activities in which students assess their role in social change, are often quite creative. The lessons often take strong anti-inequality, progressive political stands, and do not include opposing viewpoints. Nonetheless, the large number of articles, poems, cartoons, and moving personal accounts on race, class, and gender issues offer a balance to corporate-sponsored and conservative viewpoints. The Stock Market Game http://smgww.org The most widely used stock market simulation, formerly funded by the Securities Industry Association, now supported by the Foundation for Investor Education. Before using this, or any other stock market simulation, see the discussion of their limitations in Chapter 9. Survey Research Center (Woodrow Wilson School of Public and International Affairs, Princeton University), Explorations in EconomicsA Survey for High School Students www.princeton.edu/~psrc/HSwebSurvey.htm The site offers an online survey in which composite data for your class can be sent back (maintaining student condentiality) along with comparisons to responses from a national sample of high school students. Topics covered include computer usage, parental education, work experience, transportation usage, and knowledge about average earnings in the United States. The site is especially useful for teaching about unemployment because the unemployment question uses language similar to that in the U.S. Current Population Survey.
214
RESOURCES
TeachableMoment www.teachablemoment.org TeachableMoment is project of Morningside Center for Teaching Social Responsibility, a New York Citybased group created to integrate conict resolution and intercultural understanding into the daily life of schools. Several times a month the web site posts activities for use in high school classrooms on war, peace, social justice, and environmental issues. Nearly all activities ask students to evaluate a current controversy, and include ready-to-use student readings, often presenting different sides on an issue. Follow-up questions are carefully organized to promote discussion, writing, and further inquiry. In many activities, TeachableMoment offers document-based questions based on original source material for which students are asked to evaluate the logic behind both sides of an issue. Archived activities relevant to economics include: Problems at the Pump on gas prices, with document-based questions on readings from the free market Cato Institute and Heritage Foundation and the more environmentally minded Public Interest Research Group and National Resources Defense Council. A similar approach is used in The Social Security Controversy and Wal-Mart and Its Critics. The site also includes articles on teaching controversial issues and dealing with problems such as plagiarism from web-based sources. Teaching Economics As If People Mattered www.teachingeconomics.org Under the auspices of Reach and Teach (www.reachandteach.com) and United for a Fair Economy (see below), the site offers high school appropriate, ready-to-go lesson plans from a print book entitled Teaching Economics As If People Mattered, now being converted to a multimedia web format. Many of the lesson plans, including The Ten Chairs, Savings Accounts and Stocks, Born on Third Base, and Signs of the Times are currently available. Teaching for Change www.teachingforchange.org This group focuses on multicultural education with a goal of social justice. While its scope is much broader than high school econom-
RESOURCE MATERIALS
215
ics, searching its catalog for economics or globalization results in information on a number of books and videos produced from a left-of-center perspective. The organization is funded by a number of private foundations and state humanities councils. United for a Fair Economy www.faireconomy.org United for a Fair Economy (UFE) offers research, education programs, and publications on the distribution of wealth and power in the United States. Most inuential has been its Responsible Wealth project, a network of afuent citizens concerned about the issue of the growing inequality of wealth and income. Statements by this group favoring higher taxes and support for government programs could prompt thoughtful class discussion. (See Chapter 4.) The Economics Education section of their web site lists a number of reports (which can be downloaded for free) as well as books and workshop packages, and an extensive reading list. U.S. Federal Trade Commission www.ftc.gov The U.S. Federal Trade Commission offers plentiful free, up-to-date educational materials on consumer issues such as credit, marketing scams, and identity theft. Brochure-length readings can be viewed online, printed, or ordered (individually or in bulk) for delivery by mail. (All the consumer resources are free, but you may need to wait a while for delivery by mail.) The FTC is the authoritative source for information on consumers rights under the law. Some free FTC materials may also be useful in business education and in the study of government regulation. U.S. Library of Congress, The Learning Page www.memory.loc.gov/ammem/ndlpedu/start/index.html This site offers over one hundred complete lesson plans, often including primary materials from the Library of Congress that may be especially useful for economic history, labor history, and civil rights.
INDEX
217
Index
Ability to pay, 77 Ackerlof, George, 15 Ackerman, Frank, 86, 195 Ad and the Ego, 99 AD/AS. See Aggregate demand/aggregate supply Adam Smith, 2021 Adbusters, 99 Advanced Placement, 8, 10, 83, 138, 179 Advertising Age, 42 Advertising and the End of the World, 100 Advertising, 4243, 88, 92, 9899 in schools, 99 Afuenza, 100 Afghanistan war, 143 AFL-CIO, 107, 116, 124, 125, 128 African-American Migration, 122 Agency shop, 125 Aggregate demand/aggregate supply, 170, 17779 Agricultural price supports, 79 AIDS, 61, 77, 182, 186 Alliance for Work-Life Progress, 126 Allocation. See Markets Altria, 111 American Labor Studies Center, 120, 201 American Psychological Association Task Force on Advertising and Children, 99 American Social History Project/Center for Media and Learning, 120, 201
Amsco, 11 Analogy, 90, 91, 174, 176 Annual percentage rate, 96 Antitrust, 93, 150 Asian-Pacic students, 9 Aspen Institute, 107 AT&T Foundation, 14 Auctions, 74 Austrian economics 2223 Automatic stabilizers, 170, 174 Average tax rate, 146 Baker, Dean, 62, 150 Bangladesh, 198 Bank of America, 11, 103, 209, 211 Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention and Consumer Protection Act, 98 Bankruptcy, 9596 Banks, 16267, 208 economics education by, 92 Baseball, 115 Basic goods, 91 Belgium, 138 Benet-cost analysis. See Cost-benet analysis Bigelow, Bill, 190 Birthrates, 43, 44 Blacks, 9, 157 Board of Governors, 16567, 204, 206. See also Federal Reserve Buck Institute, 175, 2012 Budget Explorer, 144
217
218
INDEX
Center for Science in the Public Interest, 63 Center for Strategic and International Studies, 190 Central banks, 166 CEO salaries, 106107 Chang, Ha-Joon, 188 Cheney, Lynn, 14 Child labor, 61, 124, 190 Childcare, 67, 125, 126 China, 27, 67, 187 Choice, 36, 44 CIA Factbook, 135 Cipro, 62 Circular ow diagram, 4446, 132, 170 Citigroup, 14, 209 Citizens for Tax Justice, 148 Civics, 8 Civil rights, 121, 215 Civil War (U.S.), 160 Classical economics, 2021, 153, 169, 176 Climate change, 4446 Closing the Salary Gap, 123 Cloud Institute for Sustainability Education, 47 Coca-Cola, 92, 207 Code of Conduct, 59 Colander, David, 178 Colgate Palmolive, 110 College cost of, 40, 157 economics, 910, 75, 93, 95, 98, 118, 203, 207 Collusion, 88 Colonialism, 186, 190 Command, 6466 Commanding Heights, 184, 196 Commerce Department (U.S.), 131, 136 Commons, John R., 26, 28 Communism, 27, 65 Comparative advantage, 19194, 195 Competition, 7071, 76, 108, 114, 117 downsides of, 89, perfect, 8791 Congress (U.S.), 9596, 205
Budget, family 129 Bureau of Economic Analysis (U.S.), 14344 Bureau of Labor Statistics (U.S.), 115, 139, 156, 158 Bush, George H. W., 14 Bush, George W., 148 Business cycle, 171 Business for Social Responsibility, 59 Business Week, 9394 Business, 20910 education 103112 ethics, 23, 1068 Calculus, 86 California, 8, 9, 12, 13 University of, 4 Calvin K. Kazanjian Economics Foundation 14 Can Openers and Comparative Advantage, 195 Canada, 67, 126, 138 Capital controls, 195 Capitalism, 53, 141 Capital One, 97 Capra, Frank, 164 Capstone (NCEE), 63, 75, 129, 175 Caring labor, 6667 Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, 208 Case Study: The Federal Reserve System and Monetary Policy, 177 Castle Rock Foundation, 206 Castro, Fidel, 65 Cato Institute, 207, 214 Census (U.S.), 123, 129 Center for Commercial-Free Public Education, 99 Center for Defense Information, 145 Center for Economic and Policy Research, 148 Center for Environmental Education Online, 202 Center for Media Literacy, 99 Center for Popular Economics, 202
INDEX
Conservative Nanny State, 151 Conservatives, 15, 17, 63, 101, 153, 175, 189, 205, 207 Consumers, 62, 63 bankruptcy, 9596 choice, 44 education, 8, 95102 loans, 157, 160, protection, 95, 98, 14950 rights, 215 safety, 141 spending, 133, 172 sovereignty, 6263 Consumer Jungle, 202 Consumer Price Index, 158 Consumerism and its Discontents, 100 Consumerism, 2526, 100102 Consumers Union, 98 Consumption and the Consumer Society, 100 Consumption. See Consumer spending Copyright, 61, 62 Cornell University, 121 Corporation, The, 107 Corporations, 5860 accountability of, 107 banking and, 163 CEOs in, 1067, 198 ownership of, 111 power of, 9194, 104, 106108, 211 responsibility of, 104 CorpWatch, 94 Cost-benet analysis, 8486, 142 Costanza, Robert, 28 Counterfeiting, 205 Creative Change Educational Solutions, 45, 203 Creative destruction, 23 Credit cards, 95, 209 Credit, 209 Crowding out, 143 Cuba, 65 Currency rates, 196 Current Population Survey (CPS), 154, 156, 213
219
DAluiso, Faith, 39 Daly, Herman. 28, 45 Data, 5051 Debt, 170, 174, 196 crisis 186 Deloitte, 209 Demand/supply. See Supply/demand Department of Education (U.S.), 14, 209, 211 Department of the Treasury (U.S.), 206 Depression, 131, 162, 177 Deregulation, 150 Developing countries, 182, 185188 Development. See Economic development Discount rate, 165 Discouraged workers, 155 Discrete decisions, 82, 84 Discrimination, 121123 Disney, 110 Distribution. See Income, distribution of, and Wealth, distribution of District of Columbia, 12 Diversication, 192 Dixon, Vernon, 51 Document-based questions, 214 Dollars and Sense, 203 Dow Jones, 108 E. Angus Powell Endowment for American Enterprise, 205, 212 Eastern Europe, 211 EcEdWeb. 203. See also National Council on Economic Education Ecological base, 181 Ecological Economics, 45 Ecological Footprint Quiz, 45 Ecological sustainability, 187 Ecology, 27, 28 EconEdLink, 39, 123, 129, 135, 156. 158, 175, 177, 212. See also National Council on Economic Education Economic development, 18188, 190, growth, 171, 18188 history, 201, 215
220
INDEX
Exchange, 5860 Excise tax. See Taxes Experimental economics, 5657 Explorations in Economics, 213 Externalities, 4142, 77, 79, 142 Facing the Future, 39, 139, 190, 203 Fair Labor Association, 59 Fair trade, 188 Fair Wage, 123 Faith traditions, 29 Fallacy of composition, 154 Family, 126. See also Household Family and Work Institute, 126 Family Medical Leave Act, 126 Famine, 89 Farley, Joshua, 45 Fed 101, 204 Federal budget, 17173. See also Government spending and Taxes Federal funds rate, 165 Federal government, 14244, 17173 Federal Open Market Committee, 165, 204. See also Federal Reserve Federal Reserve (U.S.), 24, 155, 161, 16567, 169, 177, 190, 2045 economics education by, 97, 164, 2045, 206 independence of, 166 transparency and, 167 Federal Resources for Educational Excellence, 2056 Federal Trade Commission (U.S.), 97, 164, 209, 215 FedEx, 92 Fedville, 204 Feminist economics, 2728 Ferber, Marianne A, 23 Finance. See Personal nance Financial crisis, 79 Financial Fitness for Life, 211 Financial Markets Center, 166, 205, 206 Fine tuning, 173 Fiscal policy, 142, 16976 Fiscal Policy: A Two-Act Play, 175
Economic (continued) laws, 6971 man, 54 schools, 1931 systems, 5368, 65 well-being, 13637 Economic Policy Institute, 118, 119, 123, 129 Economics for Humans, 197 Economics in Action, 75 Economics Live, 175 Economics Minute, 212 Economics of the New Deal, 175 EconomicsInternational (NCEE), 211 Education World, 123 Educators for Social Responsibility, 129, 184 Efciency wage, 119 Efciency, 71, 147, 150 Ehrenreich, Barbara, 116 Elasticity, 69 Electronic funds transfer, 163, 164 Elson, Diane, 28 Employee rights, 124. See also Workers rights Employer power, 116, 117. See also Corporate power Endangered Species Act, 207 Engels, Frederick, 27 Enron, 107 Entrepreneurs, 2223. 46, 105, 20910 Environment, 66, 8486, 142, 150, 190, 19394, 203, 214 protection of, 134, 136 Environmental economics, 2930, 8486 Environmental Kuznets curve, 183 Environmental Protection Agency (U.S.), 134 Environmental Sustainability, 101102 index, 138 Equal Employment Opportunity Commission (U.S.), 123 Ethics. See Business ethics Europe, 78, 126, 137, 182 Examining the Tax Cuts, 148
INDEX
Flat tax, 147 Flexibilization, 78 Florida, 8, 9 Flow variable, 132 Focus (NCEE), 75, 164 Folbre, Nancy, 28 FOMC Simulation, 204 Forbes, 128 Foreign direct investment, 184 Fortune, 9394, 197 Foundation for Economic Education, 206 Foundation for Investor Education, 211, 213 Foundation for Teaching Economics, 6, 1011, 184, 2067, 211 Frank, Robert, 100 Free enterprise, 53, 209, 212 Free Enterprise: The Economics of Cooperation, 205 Free market, 10, 53, 119, 182, 18687. See also Market Free riders, 55 Free trade, 19194 Freeman, The, 206 Freedom 101: Liberty, Morality, and the Free Market, 206 Fuel prices, 8081, 157 Gaining with trade?, 62 Gallagher, Kevin, 184, 188 Gallup survey, 10 Games Economists Play: Noncomputerized Classroom Games for College Classroom, 207 Gas prices. See fuel prices Gates, Bill, 47 Gazillionaire, 105 GE Foundation, 14 Gender, 27. 28, 30, 65, 12223, 12526, 138, 182, 190 Genuine Progress Indicator, 137 George Meany Memorial Archives, 121 Germany, 160 Giecek, Tamara Sober, 128 Glass ceiling, 122
221
Glencoe McGraw Hill, 11 Glendale Community College, 4 Global Crossing, 107 Global Development and Environment Institute, 4, 100, 138, 178, 2078 Global Development Resource Center, 38 Global economics, 18998 Global South, 187 Global Village or Global Pillage?, 197 Global Women and Poverty, 188 Globalization 101, 208 Globalization, 18990, 202, 203, 2078, 213, 215 Globe Fearon, 11 Goals 200: Educate America Act, 13 Gold standard, 162 Government 9, 55, 6466, 14151 budget (U.S.), 134 failure, 78 growth of, 14243 investment, 14344 outlays, 14244 regulation, 89,141, 14951, 215 revenue. See Taxes role of, 182 services, 143, spending, 151, 169, 172 Great Britain, 182, 188 Great depression. See Depression Greenhouse gas emissions, 67 Gross Domestic Product, 13139, 143, 157, 169, 172, 183 development and, 38 growth rate, 153, 158 measurement of, 13135 per capita, 38 problems in measuring, 13539 Hall of Fame, 115 Hamilton, Alexander, 170 Happiness, 101 Harris poll, 17 Have Faith in Free Trade, 184 HBSC, 209 Health care, 79
222
INDEX
Ination (continued) demand pull, 159 unexpected, 153 Information, 72, 75 Infrastructure, 186 Infused economics content, 7, 89 Inheritance tax. See Taxes Innovation, 88, 106 Institutional economics 2728 Intellectual property rights, 61 Interdisciplinary courses, 8 Interest rates, 165, 170, 176 Interfaith Center for Corporate Responsibility, 107 Intermediate goods, 133 International nance, 19496 International Monetary Fund, 49, 135, 185, 190, 194, 208 International Paper, 211 Internet, 106, 144, 203 Investment, 133, 174, 176, 181 Iowa, 12 Iraq war, 143 Is Capitalism Good for the Poor?, 207 Is NAFTA Working for Mexico?, 184 Its a Wonderful Life, 164 JA Economics, 20910 Japan, 182, 192 Jefferson, Thomas, 170 Jevons, Stanley, 20 Job loss, 19293. See also Unemployment John Templeton Foundation, 207 Jubilee USA Network, 188 Jump$tart, 16, 97, 129, 2089 personal nance survey, 95 clearinghouse, 95, 129, 209 Junior Achievement, 1011, 103, 105, 20911 Justice, 2729 Kahneman, Daniel, 51 Keynes, John Maynard, 23, 170, 17173 Keynesian cross, 178
Heilbroner, Robert L., 55 Heinzerling, Lisa, 86 Heritage Foundation, 214 Hierarchy, 65 High school economics enrollment in, 710 interest in, 910 curriculum of, 8 history of, 718 teacher preparation for, 3, 10 Hispanics, 157 History, 65, 120, 141, 182, 210 Holt Reinhart and Winston, 11 Home economics. See Consumer economics Homogeneous goods, 7172, 108 Household, 2526, 46, 118 budget, 9598, 118 production, 4041, 136, 139 unpaid labor, 124 Human capital, 144, 182 Human Development Index, 38, 13738 Human Development Report (UN), 38 Hungry Planet: What the World Eats, 39 Hyperination, 160 If the World Were a Village, 38 If Women Counted, 138 Illinois, 12 Imputation, 132 In Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve, 204 Incentives, 5455, 79 Income, 210 distribution of, 113119, 125129 Income tax. See Taxes India, 187 Indirect taxes, 147 Individualistic perspective, 171 Industrialization, 182 Inequality Matters, 128 Inequality, 101, 106, 113119, 12529, 213 Infant industries, 192 Ination, 153, 154, 15760, 161 cost push, 159
INDEX
Keynesian economics 2325, 153, 169, 173, 176 Kicking Away the Ladder, 188 Kids and Commercialism, 100 Killing Us Softly, 99 Kraft Foods, 111, 209 Krueger, Alan, 118, 156 Kyoto Protocol, 67, 190 Kyrk, Hazel, 25 Labor civil rights movement, and, 121 history, 2627, 119121, 201, 213, 215 markets, 2627, 113129 unions 12, 2627, 119123, 210 variations in rewards, 115 Laffer curve, 173 Laissez Faire, 142 Lardner, James, 128 Learning from the Market, 109, 211 Lee, Dwight R, 205 Liberal policymakers, 153, 155, 175 Library of Congress (U.S.), 120, 206, 215 Life and Debt, 196 Livin the Good Life, 139 Living wage, 119 Loan Disclosure, 9598 Luxury Fever, 100 Macroeconomics, 8, 24, 142, 172 indicators, 153 theorists, 155 Maier, Mark, 4, 175, 201 Malaria, 182 Maps of the World, 41 Marginal cost, 73, 75, 8284 Marginal tax rate, 146, 149 Marginal utility, 8284 Marginalist thinking, 84, 198 Marketplace Back to School Retail, 39 Marketplace: Lets Go Euro, 196 Market, 9, 2122, 6986, 91, 198 economy, 6466, 141, 149, 16162, 169, failure, 78 for pollution, 86
223
Market (continued) power, 7475, 88 problems with allocation and incentives, 79, 9194 structure, 8794 Mars family, 127 Marx, Karl. 27 Marxian economics, 27 Massachusetts, 9, 13 Material World: A Global Family Portrait, 39 Mathematics, 38, 86, 156, 210, 213 McDonalds, 5051, 110 McGraw-Hill Companies, 209, 211 MCI, 212 Measures of economic activity, 137 Media Education Foundation, 100 Medicine, 62 Menzel, Peter, 39 Merchants of Cool, 99 Mergers, types of, 93 Metaphors, 72 Mexico-United States: The Environmental Costs of Trade-led Growth, 188 Michigan, 203 Microeconomics, 8, 178 models, 178 Microsoft, 87 Military spending, 41, 134, 143, 145, 186 Minimum wage, 21, 81, 11719, 15859 Minnesota, 12, 12223 Mixed economies, 6465 Models, 1920, 6971, 7376, 17779 Monetary policy, 142, 158, 165, 169, 17679, 208 Money, 161164 management of, 9598 Monopolistic competition, 92 Monopoly, 70, 87 Monopsony, 114, 117 Morningside Center for Teaching Social Responsibility, 214 Moyers, Bill, 47, 116 Multinational corporations, 186, 19798. See also Transnational corporations
224
INDEX
NCEE Standard #1, 36 NCEE Standard #2, 82 NCEE Standard #3, 64 NCEE Standard #4, 5455 NCEE Standard #5, 58 NCEE Standard #6, 191 NCEE Standard #7, 70 NCEE Standard #8, 76 NCEE Standard #9, 88 NCEE Standard #10, 60, 120 NCEE Standard #11, 161 NCEE Standard #12, 17677 NCEE Standard #13, 114 NCEE Standard #14, 104 NCEE Standard #15, 181 NCEE Standard # 16, 142 NCEE Standard #17, 150 NCEE Standard #18, 171 NCEE Standard #19, 153 NCEE Standard # 20, 169 Nebraska, 203 Nelson, Julie A., 28, 197 Neoclassical economics, 5, 9, 15, 2022, 4851, 11314, 169, 176, 210 New American Dream, 100 New classical economics, 2425 New institutionalist economics, 2930 New Keynesian economics, 2325 New School for Social Research, 4 New School History of Economic Thought, 175 New York State, 8, 9, 13 New York Stock Exchange, 109 Nickel and Dimed, 116 Nike, 59, 92 Nominal value. See real value Nonmarket production, 135, 161 Nonprot sector, 46 Norma Rae, 121 North Country, 122123 Norway, 138 NOVA (PBS), 164 Number line, 144
Multinational Monitor, 94 Multiplier, 17072 Music, 62 Nabisco, 111 NAFTA, 184, 195 National Assessment of Educational Progress, 1617 National Association of Economic Educators, 6, 210 National Budget Simulation (NCEE), 145, 144, 148 National Center for Education Statistics (U.S.), 16 National Center for History in the Schools, 14 National Committee for Pay Equity, 123 National Consumers League, 97 National Council on Economic Education (NCEE), 6, 1011, 14, 15, 21, 22, 36, 63, 75, 88, 108, 129, 135, 145, 158, 175, 190, 202, 203, 21012. See also Capstone, EconEdLink, Focus, Standards, Voluntary National Content Standards National Education Association, 116 National Education Standards and Improvement Council, 13 National Endowment for the Humanities, 14 National Foundation for Teaching Entrepreneurship, 105 National Institute for Occupational Safety and Health (U.S.), 124 National Park Service (U.S.), 121 National Resources Defense Council, 214 National Science Foundation, 106 National Standards in Personal Finance, 16, 42 National Summit on Economic Literacy, 211 National Taxpayers Union, 207 Nations Report Card, 16 Natural resource economics, 29
INDEX
Obesity, 4344, 63 Occupational Outlook Handbook (Bureau of Labor Statistics), 115 Oil prices. See fuel prices Oligopoly, 77 Open market transactions, 165 Opportunity cost, 3942 Organs, sale of, 62 Overspent American, 100 Parade, 115 Parental leave, 126 Parents, 63 Pareto, Vilfredo, 20 Payroll tax. See Taxes Peace, 214 Perfect competition. See Competition Perkins, Frances, 26 Personal nance, 8, 12, 16, 9798, 2089, 210 Personal nance survey, 95 Peterson, Bob, 190 Philip Morris, 111 Philipson, T.J., 63 Pizza Tycoon, 105 Plain English: Making Sense of the Federal Reserve, 164 Political Economy Research Center, 207 Political Economy Research Institute, 202 Political power, 92 Pollution, 8486 Posner, Richard, 63 Post Keynesian economics, 2325 Poverty, 190. See also Income, distribution of Powell Center for Economic Literacy, 212 Power in Our Hands: A Curriculum on the History of Work and Workers in the United States, 124, 213 Practical Money Skills for Life, 97 Prentice Hall, 11 Presidents Dilemma, 175 Price ceiling, 7981 Price oor, 7981, 117 Price level, 157
225
Priceless: On Knowing the Price of Everything and the Value of Nothing, 86 Prices, 171 as signals, 76 Private property rights, 6062 Private schools, 9 Problem-based learning, 2012 Problems at the Pump, 214 Prot, 104 Progressive taxes, 146 Property rights, 62, 142 Property tax. See Taxes Proportional tax, 147 Provisioning, 37, 88 Pubic good game, 57 Public Broadcasting Service, 184, 188, 196 Public choice theory, 150 Public Citizen, 94, 107 Public goods, 55, 77, 142 Public Interest Research Group, 214 Public schools, 9 Pullman Strike, 119 Race to the bottom, 89, 19394 Race, 65 Radical economics 27 Rational choice, 42 Rationing, 81 Ravitch, Diane 11 Reach and Teach, 214 Reagan-tax cuts,173 Real value, 135, 158 Real World Macro, 203 Real World Micro, 203 Rebeck, Ken, 18 Redening Progress, 137 Regressive taxes, 146 Reid, Margaret 25 Rent control, 21, 8081 Research and development, 106. See also Federal Reserve Reserve requirement, 165 Resource Center of the Americas, 59 Resource depletion, 4446
226
INDEX
Social justice, 21315 Social perspective, 171 Social responsibility, 107108 Social Security Controversy, The, 214 Social security, 136, 143, 145, 159, 214 Social studies, 8, 10, 13 Social Venture Network, 107 Somalia, 198 South Korea, 185 Soviet Union, 27, 65, 211 Specialization, 191 Speculation, 78, 111, 194 Stability, 78 Stagation, 173 Stand alone courses, 89 Standards state, 1213, 92 national, 1318, 42. See also Voluntary National Content Standards and NCEE, standards in high school curriculum 2223 State and local government, 14243 State Farm Insurance, 211 State requirements, 7, 8, 9 Statistical Abstract of the United States, 105 Statistical discrepancy, 133 Stiglitz, Joseph 15 Stock Market, 211 bubbles, 111 crash, 79 initial public offering, 108 secondary market, 118 simulation games, 108109, 111 strategies, 108111 Stock Market Game, The, 213 Stock Market Wants You, The, 109 Stock variable, 132 Stockholm International Peace Research Institute, 41 Stories Economists Tell, 178 Structural adjustment policies, 186 Student preconceptions, 90 Subcontracting, 58 Superfund, 207 Supply side economics, 173
Responsible Wealth, 215 Rethinking Globalization, 59, 190, 213 Rethinking Mathematics, 156, 213 Rethinking Schools, 99, 156, 190, 21213 Revealed preference, 37 Richmond Federal Reserve Bank, 212 Right to work for less laws, 125 Right to work laws, 124125 Risk, 104, 108110 Robbins, Lionel, 51 Roger & Me, 195 Sales tax. See Taxes Samuelson, Paul, 21 Scaife Foundation, 206 Scandinavia, 68 Scarcity, 35 Schools, spending on, 135 School Foods Toolkit, 63 Schools, junk food in, 63 Schor, Juliet, 100 Schumpeterian economics 2223 Sears, 163, 202 Seattle, 189 Securities and Exchange Commission (U.S.), 206 Securities Industry Association, 211, 213 Self-interest, 54 Self-sufciency, 192 Sen, Amartya, 15, 28, 89 Sexual harassment, 122 Shop Till You Drop, 39 Shortage, 37 Sim Business, 105 Simon, Herbert, 66 Simulations, 5657, 75, 105, 14445 Singapore, 185 Slavery, 121 Small Business Administration (U.S.), 105 Small business, 103106 Smith, David A., 128 Smith, Vernon 15 Smithsonian Institution, 121 Social capital, 4748, 182 Social economics, 28
INDEX
Supply/demand model, 1920, 21, 6986, 117, 119 Survey Research Center, 156, 213 Sweatshops, 5860, 67, 190 Sweden, 67, 138 Tariffs, 62 Tax incidence, 147 Taxes, 145149, 169, 172, 194 excise, 14647 income, 14649 inheritance, 14647 payroll, 146148 property, 14647 sales, 14648 Teachable Moment, 94, 129, 145, 148, 214 Teacher training, 3, 10, 21011 Teaching Economics as if People Mattered, 123, 128, 129, 214 Teaching for Change, 21415 Teaching Modules on Social and Environmental Issues in Economics, 208 Teaching Students about Media, 99 Teaching Tolerance, 122 Texas, 8, 9, 13 Textbooks college, 95, 178 high school, 4, 5, 1112, 19, 20, 25, 37, 53, 64, 87, 95, 103, 110, 114, 125, 141, 14546, 155, 157, 159, 165, 170, 177, 18183, 189, 194 Thailand, 196 Thinking Economics, 212 Time use surveys, 126, 139 Tobin tax, 79, 195, 196 Trade, 18998 gains from, 191 Tradeoff, 36, 3941 Tradition, 6466 Transaction costs, 7273, 75 Transfer programs, 143 Transnational corporations, 87, 88, 92. See also Multinational corporations Triangle shirtwaist re, 119, 121 Tufts University, 4
227
Ultimate Field Guide to the U.S. Economy, 202 Ultimatum game, 5657, 207 Underemployed, 155 Unemployment, 15357, 19293 full, 154 natural rate, 154 types, 15357. See also Job loss Unequal distribution of income. See Inequality Union shop, 125 Unions. See Labor unions United for a Fair Economy, 123, 128, 21415 United National Human Development Index, 65 United Nations Development Program, 137 Statistical Division, 139 United Nations, 37, 41 USA Today, 204 User fees, 148 Value added tax (VAT), 133 Value added, 133 Virtual Economics, 212 Visa, 97 Voluntariness, 5557 Voluntary National Content Standards, 6, 1318, 2123, 42, 36,. 5455, 58, 60, 64, 70, 76, 82, 88, 104, 108, 114, 120, 142, 150, 153, 161, 169, 171, 17677, 181, 191, 202, 208, 21012 See also NCEE Standards von Hayek, Freidrich, 22 von Mises, Ludwig, 22 Wages and Me, 129 Wages, 113114 Wall Street Journal, 14 Wal-Mart and Its Critics, 214
228
INDEX
Workers rights, 123125 Workers Rights Consortium, 59 Work-family issues, 126 Workplace safety, 141 Workshops, 202 World Bank, 185, 190 World Database of Happiness, 101 World Economic Outlook Database, 135 World Health Organization, 66 World Trade Organization, 49, 189 World War II, 143 Yale University, 138 Youth, 157, 193 Yugoslavia, 160 Zapitalism, 105
Wal-Mart, 63, 92, 116, 122, 163 Wal-Mart: The High Cost of Low Price, 116 Walras, Leon 20 Walstad, William, 18 War, 214 Waring, Marilyn, 45, 138 Wealth, distribution of, 113, 12729 Well-being, 137, 183 global distribution of, 38 What People Earn, 115 Whos Counting, 45, 138 Wisconsin, 13 University of, 4 Wise, Timothy, 195 Women, 27. 28, 30, 65, 12223, 12526, 138, 182, 190. See also Gender
A PRIMER
ON
MAJOR SCHOOLS
OF
ECONOMICS
229
Mark H. Maier, Ph.D., teaches economics at Glendale Community College, Glendale, California. He is author of The Data Game: Controversies in Social Science Statistics (3rd edition, 1999), City Unions: Managing Discontent in New York City (1987), and articles on teaching economics published in the Journal of Economic Education, Economic Inquiry, and Papers and Proceedings of the American Economic Association. Julie A. Nelson, Ph.D., is a Senior Research Associate with the Global Development and Environment Institute at Tufts University. She is author of Economics for Humans (2006), Feminism, Objectivity, and Economics (1996), and many articles, and is coauthor of Microeconomics in Context (2005). She has taught at institutions including the University of CaliforniaDavis, Brandeis University, and Harvard University, and her writings on economics education have appeared in the Journal of Economic Perspectives and the PostAutistic Economics Review.
229