SSRN Id2695101
SSRN Id2695101
SSRN Id2695101
Jamil Baza , Nick Grangerb , Campbell R. Harveyc , Nicolas Le Rouxd and Sandy
Rattraye
Abstract
We contrast the time-series and cross-sectional performance of three popular investment
strategies: carry, momentum and value. While considerable research has examined the perfor-
mance of these strategies in either a directional or cross-asset settings, we offer some insights
on the market conditions that favor the application of a particular setting.
a JamilBaz is chief investment strategist at Man Group, b Nick Granger is portfolio manager
of Dimension at Man AHL, c Campbell R. Harvey is professor of finance at Duke University,
and investment strategy adviser at Man Group, d Nicolas Le Roux is senior researcher at Man
Group and e Sandy Rattray is CEO at Man AHL.
Electronic copy
Electronic copy available
available at:
at:https://ssrn.com/abstract=2695101
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2695101
2
1 Introduction
In quantitative cash equity strategies, momentum is almost always traded across assets (relative
value) whereas in futures trading, momentum is typically applied directionally. Why? Our goal is
to better understand the performance of three popular strategies, carry, momentum and value in
different implementations: time-series vs. cross-sectional.
Although there is considerable research on each of these popular strategies, there is little work
that compares cross-asset and directional strategies for a wide variety of asset classes. For example,
Moskowitz et al. (2012) focus on time-series momentum. Asness et al. (2013) look at cross-sectional
performance of value and momentum. We fill this gap by providing an analysis of both the time-
series and cross-section using a broad number of asset classes: equity, fixed income, currencies and
commodities. We measure the relative performance of directional vs. cross-asset strategies as well
as strategies that combine the information in each dimension.
We show that these strategies are largely profitable over our sample - and the best performance
is when these strategies are combined. However, we are very aware of the critique in Harvey et al.
(2015) with respect to factor proliferation. Indeed, we are testing three strategies that are select -
they are popular because they have worked. Importantly, our focus is not to document the most
profitable trading strategy; our goal is to explore the conditions where any particular strategy has the
best shot of working. Indeed, there are many conditions that drive the difference between directional
and cross-asset performance. Important drivers are the correlation of asset returns, the correlation
of the information that drives markets (some of which is unobservable), as well as the correlation of
the trading signals. These drivers will be explored in a future paper.
Our paper is organized as follows. In the second section, we present the theoretical underpin-
nings of each of the three strategies. Our data are described in the third section. The empirical
comparison of the different strategies in directional and cross-asset implementations is presented in
the next section. In the fifth section, we offer some thoughts on the underlying drivers of the differ-
ential performances. Finally, we offer some caveats about the average return performance of these
strategies.
Electronic copy
Electronic copy available
available at:
at:https://ssrn.com/abstract=2695101
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2695101
3
Before implementing any strategy, it is important to understand the theoretical basis. That is,
why would carry, momentum and value perform on a priori grounds? The economic foundation may
also be useful in determining why certain strategies work better in the time-series, while others are
best applied in the cross-section and vice versa.
2.1 Carry
We define carry as the difference between the spot and the forward price of an asset – in other
words the profit on a long forward position if prices do not change. A simple version of the carry
trade consists in buying the asset forward if the carry is positive or selling it forward if the carry is
negative.
Carry trades exploit the difference between the expected spot price at expiry and the for-
ward price.1 Why would a forward price be different from an expected spot price? It is actually
straightforward to show why.
Suppose that the forward prices were unbiased estimators of future spot prices (both forward
and spot prices expressed as units of asset A per unit of asset B):
Ft,T = Et (ST ) (1)
where Ft,T is the forward price at time t for expiry at time T and ST is the asset price at time T.
It is then said that the forward bias, the difference between the expected spot price and the forward
price, is zero. Then, if this is a general principle, this should apply to all relative prices, including
units of asset B expressed per unit of asset A:
1 1
= Et ( ) (2)
Ft,T ST
And it should follow that:
1 1
= Et ( ) (3)
Et (ST ) ST
which cannot happen by Jensen’s inequality. This means that forward prices cannot be unbiased
predictors of future spot prices. This should be true for all asset classes, although it is most intuitive
for foreign exchange. In currency markets, the above means that uncovered interest rate parity
cannot hold.
Can we say something about the magnitude of the forward bias and about the carry trade using
basic finance theory?
Consider a dividend paying financial asset. By standard arbitrage, the forward price is equal
to the spot price compounded at the risk-free rate minus the dividend yield:
Ft,T = St e(r−d)(T −t) (4)
1
For practical purposes, readers can think of forwards and futures as equivalent in this section.
where d is the continuously compounded dividend yield and r is the continuously compounded risk-
free rate. Note that the carry is positive (negative) if the interest rate is greater (smaller) than the
dividend yield.
To calculate the expected return on a long forward position, we need to use an asset pricing
theory. With the standard Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), then the expected spot price is:
If the asset beta is positive as is generally the case, the forward price is lower than the expected
spot price:
Et (ST )
= eβπ(T −t) > 1 (6)
Ft,T
Then, the expected P&L on a forward trade is:
• There is a systematic forward bias. Forward prices are lower than expected spot prices for
positive beta assets, that is most assets.
• The sign of the forward bias is independent of carry: the ratio of expected spot to forward
depends on βπ, not on r − d.
To link carry and forward bias requires richer asset pricing models. Suppose, for example, that
expected returns are determined not just by the market factor but also by the dividend factor:
Here, γ is the dividend factor loading and d is the market dividend yield. It follows that:
Et (ST )
= St e(βπ+γ[d−d])(T −t) (9)
Ft,T
With the dividend factor - a proxy for the value factor as we shall see below - the forward bias is
now correlated with carry. The higher the dividend yield, the higher the carry, the lower the forward
compared to the expected spot price, the more profitable the carry trade.
The CAPM and its derivative models apply in principle to all assets. For example, in Lustig
and Verdelhan (2007), high-yielding currencies tend to depreciate whereas low-yielding currencies
hold their own in low domestic consumption states. This hedging property of low-yielding currencies
translates in lower expected returns relative to high yielders. Breeden (1986) derives equilibrium
relationships between interest rates, growth and other parameters from optimal consumption and
production models (more on this in the value sub-section).
Koijen et al. (2013) study the carry strategy across asset classes and find the strategy is rela-
tively uncorrelated with factors such as value and momentum but is partially explained by recession
and volatility risk. Other researchers have made conjectures about the carry strategy that are of a
more ad hoc nature and tend to reflect idiosyncrasies in specific asset classes.
In currencies, the carry trade, also known as the bird-in-the-hand trade, consists in buying high-
yielding currencies against low-yielding currencies. This trade can be profitable because high-yields
are associated with non-diversifiable risk factors such as political turmoil or wavering property rights
or persistently high inflation. In the extreme, the yield differential can remunerate a so-called peso
effect, meaning that jump risk can be very real even though it has not materialized. Alternatively,
a high yield on a currency can reflect a central bank just about to gain or regain anti-inflation
credentials that will make its currency more desirable.
In commodities, the positive difference between spot and futures prices - also known as back-
wardation - was interpreted by Keynes as the result of producers selling futures to insure themselves
against price falls. If this is the case, there is a structural excess supply of futures contracts relative to
spot transactions: curves will tend to be backwardated; and futures prices will tend to roll up toward
spot prices until they converge at expiry date. This is the so-called theory of insurance or theory
of normal backwardation. But as observed empirically, backwardation is not the norm, particularly
today. Indeed, hedging transactions can go both ways: hedgers can sell futures as Keynes asserted;
alternatively, they can be naturally long futures if they are short the underlying commodity (e.g.,
airline companies are short fuel and need to buy futures for hedging purposes). In this case, the curve
is contangoed and speculators are paid to be short futures. In other words, speculators are incented
by hedgers to sell contangoed futures and buy backwardated futures. In a competing explanation,
the theory of storage links backwardation to tight inventories. A low level of inventories may result in
a high convenience yield, hence a backwardation (Working, 1933; Kaldor, 1939 and Schwartz 1997).
Because inventories take time to rebuild, profits from the carry trade can be persistent.
In fixed income, the term structure is, more often than not, upward sloping. Conventional
explanations range from the liquidity theory of rates - investors should be compensated for the
higher risk of holding long bonds, hence the upward sloping yield curve - to the theory of preferred
habitats - investors prefer short bonds to long bonds. Rates tend to roll down the curve: this
translates into excess returns for fixed income investors.
2.2 Momentum
Momentum refers to persistence in asset returns: winners tend to continue to do well and
losers continue to do badly. The conventional trade (at least for academic purposes) is to buy assets
that outperformed and sell assets that underperformed over the previous year. Asset returns appear
to exhibit negative autocorrelation over very short periods (less than one month) and longer time
periods (more than three years) while the sweet spot for momentum, or positively auto-correlated,
strategies is around 6-12 months.
Theories of momentum range from the risk-based to the behavioral. On the risk end of the
spectrum, momentum performs because high-momentum assets are more sensitive to macroeconomic
factors such as, for example, the growth rate of industrial production (Liu and Zhang, 2008); it
can also perform because, to the extent realized and expected returns are highly correlated, then
a cross-section of past winners with high realized returns has higher expected returns and ends
up outperforming a cross-section of past losers (Conrad and Kaul, 1988). On the behavioral end,
investors underreact to news either because they display conservatism bias and are slow updating their
beliefs (Barberis, Shleifer and Vishny, 1998) or because they do not receive and update information at
the same time (Hong and Stein, 1999). Alternatively, it is claimed that prices can overreact to news
and feed upon themselves with noise traders deepening the mis-pricing. Furthermore, behavioral
biases can generate momentum when fund flows exhibit inertia and the market under-reacts to
expected future flows. Price returns will then show persistence until large deviation from price
fundamentals result in a market reversal (Vayanos and Woolley, 2013). The so-called disposition
effect can also help explain momentum returns. Investors tend to sell their winning stocks too early
while holding on to their losers. Grinblatt and Han (2002) present a model where the disposition
effect drives the market clearing price. Let there be a population of rational investors (fraction µ)
and a population of disposition investors (fraction 1-µ) with the following demand curves:
(
Dtr = 1 + β(Ft − Pt )
(10)
Dtd = 1 + β(Ft − Pt ) + α(Pt−1 − Pt )
Dtr and Dtd are the demand functions of rational and disposition investors. Ft is the fundamental
price at t and Pt is the market clearing price. A positive α describes the disposition effect: the lower
today's price relative to yesterday’s, the more disposition investors hold on to their assets, the higher
the excess demand for that asset. A positive β indicates that rational investors demand for an asset
decreases with the difference between its market price and its fundamental price. The asset supply
is equal to one unit. Then aggregating both demand functions, we obtain:
µDtr + (1 − µ)Dtd = 1 (11)
Therefore,
1
Pt = wFt + (1 − w)Pt−1 , where w ≡ (12)
1 + µα
At equilibrium, today’s price is positively correlated to yesterday’s price and only partially reflects
the fundamental asset value.
Some market participants have been trying to evaluate the merit of these competing expla-
nations in the current environment (AHL/MSS Academic Advisory Board, 2014). Is momentum
behavioral? Do today’s markets foster behavioral biases? The answer to both questions is a qualified
yes. Because recent policy moves (negative nominal rates, open-ended quantitative easing, implicit
policy focus on wealth effects) are unprecedented and unfamiliar, people rely more on heuristics:
instinctive thinking may dominate investors’ more deliberative mode of thinking. This can result in
significant trends from anchoring and other behavioral biases. Behavioral biases, combined with more
liquid markets and more efficient information diffusion, tend to favor persistence of slow momentum.
2.3 Value
Value can be defined as the difference between a fundamental asset price and its prevailing
market price. This begs two questions: is there such a thing as the fundamental price of an asset?
What mechanisms cause market prices to deviate from and revert to fundamental prices? We answer
these questions by looking in turn at interest rates, stocks, currencies and commodities.
A simple two-period consumption model yields the following inter-temporal equilibrium condi-
tion: 0
(r−ρ) U (Ct+1 )
Et e =1 (13)
U 0 (Ct )
0
where r is the real interest rate, ρ is the rate of preference for the future and UU(C t+1 )
0 (C )
t
is the ratio of
the marginal utility of
0
consuming a real dollar at t+1 to the marginal utility of consuming it today.
−ρ U (Ct+1 )
The expression e U 0 (Ct ) is commonly called a stochastic discount factor. With logarithmic utility
functions and a log-normally distributed consumption, we can solve for the equilibrium real interest
rate 2 :
r = g + ρ − σ2 (14)
where g is the instantaneous real consumption growth and σ is the volatility of consumption growth.
In a deterministic model where people are indifferent between spending today or tomorrow:
r=g (15)
Another value metric for interest rates is the differential between domestic and foreign real rates.
When capital is free to move across countries, there is evidently a tendency for real rates of return
to converge. Higher domestic real rates will result - all else equal - in an excess demand for domestic
fixed income assets.
How about equity? A stock price can be viewed as the present value of its dividends:
Z ∞
D
P = Degd t e−Rt dt = (16)
0 R − gd
where D is the dividend today, gd the long term real continuous dividend growth rate (we assume
for convenience that the dividend growth rate is equal to the consumption growth rate g) and R the
long term real continuous equity yield. From this equation, one may infer the implied equity yield:
D
R=g+ (17)
P
meaning that the equity yield is the sum of the dividend growth and the dividend yield. The implied
equity risk premium is:
D
ERP = R − r = g − r + (18)
P
By further assuming that r = g, then the implied equity risk premium is simply the dividend yield:
D
ERP = (19)
P
σ2 σ2
2
As mentioned, U (Ct ) = ln(Ct ) and Ct+1 = Ct e(g− 2 +σε)
, and noting that Et (e−σε ) = e 2 , the result follows.
C 1−γ −1
For a broader class of so called constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) utility functions of form : U (Ct ) = t1−γ ,
the real interest rate at equilibrium is r = γg + ρ − γ 2 σ 2 . Note that CRRA utility functions become logarithmic for
γ = 1.
Dividend yields can therefore be used as a measure of value for broad equity markets. High dividend
yields may indicate that stocks are cheap against bonds 3 . Another measure of value is the price-
to-book ratio. The price-to-book is a close cousin of Tobin's Q, another statistic used by investors
to gauge value in stocks. Tobin's Q is defined as the ratio of the market cap to the replacement
cost of assets. A Q that is greater than 1 means that an investor is better off replicating the assets
of a company rather than buying it. It indicates that a company is expensive. Similarly, high
price-to-book ratios are a presumption of expensiveness.
We now turn to commodities. Commodity prices exhibit mean reversion for a number of reasons:
first, high (low) commodity prices incentivise producers to boost (reduce) supply which in turn results
in downward (upward) pressure on prices. Second, in competitive commodity markets, prices will be
pulled toward production costs. This would all suggest that value investing in commodity space is
tantamount to positioning for long mean-reversion cycles.
Currencies also have their garden-variety value indicators. Among these, purchasing power
parity (PPP) has the most intuitive appeal. Absolute PPP theory states that all products must
sell at the same price in a frictionless world. It follows that an exchange rate e (units of domestic
currency per foreign currency unit) is the ratio of the domestic price index p to the foreign price
index p∗. In the same vein, absolute PPP states that the percentage change in e is approximately
equal to the difference between domestic and foreign inflation, all measured over the same period.
One can see how PPP is more a tautology than a theory - the only issue being how much frictions
- such as transportation costs, tariffs, sticky prices, capital flows and economic policies - cause real
exchange rates to deviate from PPP in practice.
We still need to answer the question: what explains the value premium? Much like theories of
momentum, theories of value can be based on rational or behavioral stories.
Dornbusch's overshooting model (1976) is an example of a rational story that explains large
deviations from PPP. The model is quasi-deterministic, assumes rational expectations, sticky prices
in goods and services, fully flexible asset prices, a Keynesian money demand function, a PPP long-
term equilibrium and uncovered interest rate parity (UIP). Here are two key equations of the model
- UIP and money demand: (
E[ln(e)] − ln(e) = r − r∗
(20)
ln(m) − ln(p) = f (r, Y )
UIP states that the expected currency appreciation is equal to the differential between domestic and
foreign interest rates. And demand for real money balances is a decreasing function of the interest rate
(which acts as an opportunity cost) and an increasing function of income Y . How does the exchange
rate react to an unanticipated increase in money supply? Because prices and income are sticky,
the only way for money demand to match the increased money supply is through an instantaneous
decrease in the domestic interest rate. But then people rationally expect two apparently conflicting
outcomes: first, the currency should appreciate in response to the lower domestic interest rate as UIP
would predict; and second, as domestic prices gradually rise to reflect the money supply shock, the
currency needs to depreciate (e increases) in the long run to reach its PPP level. The solution that will
3
Of course the dividend yield can be time-varying and thus not necessarily a measure of value. Also, when interest
rates are lower than growth as is currently the case, dividend yields tend to underestimate the equity risk premium.
But other factors, such as leverage, may indicate that the equity risk premium is less than meets the eye.
reconcile both expectations is an instantaneous depreciation of the exchange rate over and above that
dictated by PPP. This explains the overshooting of exchange rates. This mechanism is reminiscent
of the euro sudden depreciation in response to the unanticipated loosening of monetary policy in
Europe recently. While this model is arbitrage free - the value premium is perfectly neutralized by
the carry, it is easy to see how exchange rate overshooting can create value opportunities in asset
markets that are slow to adjust: for example, real estate prices expressed in euros have been much
stickier than currencies in response to the European monetary policy surprise.
In equities, risk-based value stories are plenty: for example, Hansen Heaton and Li (1998)
attribute the out-performance of value portfolios (relative to growth portfolios) to a higher long term
exposure to consumption risk.
Behavioral stories of the value premium are also plentiful: Lakonishok, Shleifer and Vishny
(1994) argue that value strategies outperform glamour strategies because investors put excessive
weight on past history and just equate well-run firms with good investments. Benartzi and Thaler
(1995) explain how investors with prospect-theory type of utility end up buying large amounts of T-
bills despite a large equity risk premium. Similarly, Maenhout (1999) shows that ambiguity aversion
- in this case the probability distribution of stock returns is viewed as ambiguous - accounts partially
for the large equity risk premium.
The data sources are Bloomberg, Global Financial Data and the Man-AHL proprietary database.
The sample period starts in January 1990 and ends in April 2015. The data we use are detailed in
the Appendix. We study 26 equity futures markets, 14 interest rate swap contracts, 31 currency
pairs, and 16 commodity futures. All prices are in U.S. dollars. We used mid-market prices and do
not therefore account for trading costs (which we discuss later).
Equity:
We used the first two futures of each index and computed a raw carry signal as follows:
1 F utt,T1 − F utt,T2
Raw Carryt = × (22)
(T2 − T1 ) F utt,T2
For every month m, we compute a seasonality adjustment which is the average difference
between the raw carry and its 1Y moving average at time t for all the m-month business days
in the sample:
Adjt = [Raw Carryt − 1Y M A(Raw Carryt )]n (23)
where n is the number of m-month business days in the sample until time t.
We then corrected the raw carry signal by subtracting the seasonality adjustment:
Commodities:
Some commodities display significant seasonal effects (like agricultural and energies markets).
Then, to remove this seasonal effect in the carry computation, we used the first future and the
contract exactly expiring one year later.
F utt,T1 +1 − F utt,T1
Carryt = (25)
F utt,T1 +1
Swap Rates:
Carry is meant as ”carry + roll down”. We used the following formula:
S10Y,t − F ixingt S10Y,t − S7Y,t
Carryt = + (26)
Durationt 3
| {z } | {z }
”Carry” ”Roll”
2. Momentum
For all asset classes, we used a CTA-momentum signal, based on the cross over of exponentially
weighted moving averages. The algorithm building that signal is the following:
(a) Select 3 sets of time-scale with each set consisting of a short and a long exponentially
weighted moving average (EWMA)
(b) Here, we have chosen Sk =(8,16,32) and Lk =(24,48,96).
Those numbers are not look-back days or half-life numbers. In fact, each number (let’s call
it n) translates to a lambda decay factor (λ) of n−1
n
to plug into the standard definition
of an EWMA. The half-life (HL) is then given by:
log(0.5) log(0.5)
HL = = (28)
log(λ) log(1 − n1 )
(d) We normalize with a moving standard deviation as a measure of the realized 3-months
normal volatility (PW=63)
xk
yk = (30)
Run.StDev[P |P W ]
(e) We normalize this series with its realized standard deviation over the short window
(SW=252)
yk
zk = (31)
Run.StDev[yk |SW ]
(f) We calculate an intermediate signal for each k=1,2,3 via a response function R
(
uk = R(zk )
xexp( −x
2
)
(32)
R(x) = 0.89
4
(g) The final CTA momentum signal is the weighted sum of the intermediate signals (here we
have chosen equal weights wk = 13 )
3
X
SCT A = wk uk (33)
k=1
3. Value
FX:
We used relative PPP (purchasing power parity) as value indicator:
(
V aluet = P P Pt = log(SpotReal,t ) − log(SpotReal,t )
CP I (34)
SpotReal,CCY 1/CCY 2,t = SpotCCY 1/CCY 2,t × CP ICCY 1,t
CCY 2,t
Equities:
We used dividend yield as value indicator:
Commodities:
Value is defined as today’s deflated price divided by the deflated historical average price, where
history is the expanding window of all prices available:
Adj.P ricet P ricet
V aluet = , with Adj.P ricet = (36)
Adj.P ricet U S CP It
Swap Rates:
We defined value, in the rate space, as the difference between the 10Y swap rate and the most
recent nominal GDP growth rate (release quarterly):4
An alternative definition of value could have been the difference between the 10Y swap rate
and the most recent yoy CPI inflation (consumer price index).
We tested both definitions and the results were quite similar. All the results presented in the
remainder of the paper will use the GDP definition.
4
We used a three month lag for the GDP growth rate.
5
We used the six most extreme assets. Afterwards, we tested for other configurations and the results were compa-
rable
3. Complications
We mentioned that every portfolio was fully rebalanced every trading day. {“FX”, “carry”}
and {“FX”, “value”} are two exceptions here because mean reversion in FX is slower than in
equity and commodities.
We decided to rebalance 1/252 of the portfolio every trading day, in other words, the positions
taken in January 2005 were closed in January 2006, those taken in February 2005 were closed
in February 2006...This gives one year for value and carry to take effect.
4 Empirical Results
The first step consists in running 12 strategies by crossing the value/carry/momentum styles
with FX/equity/commodity/interest rates asset classes. Results are summarized in table Table 1
Panel A which shows the Sharpe ratio estimates for these trading strategies. We show the Sharpe
ratios for specific combinations of styles and asset classes. We also show average Sharpe ratios
for each style and each asset class. Lastly, the “All Asset” numbers refer to the Sharpe of each
investment style when implemented across all asset classes, meaning that we then benefit from the
diversification. With one exception, all the Sharpe ratios are positive with an average of 0.40 per
asset class. As far as styles go, Sharpe ratios across all assets vary between 0.42 to 1.27, with carry
emerging as the most profitable standalone style. As shown in panel B, maximum drawdowns per
style are of order 1.8 to 3.1 times the volatility. The skew is positive for value and momentum and
negative for carry.
Looking at broad correlations, value is negatively correlated with both carry and momentum.
As expected, value and momentum covary negatively in line with the proverbial battle between
fundamental and technical traders (Table 2 Panel A). It is particularly interesting to investigate
correlations among the various pairs of styles and asset classes. Here, three remarks are in order.
First, correlations vary between roughly -50% and +50%, with most clustered between -10% and
+10%. The average correlation, as evidenced from Table 2 Panel B, is close to zero, indicating
great scope for diversification within a broad portfolio. Second, carry and momentum tend to be
positively correlated. This is mostly due to the high correlation between commodity carry and
commodity momentum as both a high carry and a strong momentum are caused by low inventory
levels (Erb and Harvey, 2006). Also of notice is the very negative correlation between value and
carry in commodity space: a low spot price (revealing deep value) goes hand in hand with a lower
convenience yield (or higher carry6 ) as both are caused by a high level of inventories.
It is also interesting to see that most strategy pairs - each scaled for 15% volatility (in line with
the S&P historical volatility) - are showing low S&P beta estimates, indicating a low correlation with
the market, maybe with the exception of FX carry which, as most currency traders have experienced,
displays a significant pro-cyclical behavior. Note that the carry strategy in both equity and interest
Ft,T
6
Carry measure is St = e(r+s−c)(T −t) , where s and c are the storage cost and convenience yield respectively
rates is countercyclical.
The effect of low correlations between {”asset class”,”style”} pairs is displayed vividly in Table
Table 4, Panel A, B and C. In panel A, the Sharpe ratios of all three styles are greatly enhanced
when styles are aggregated across styles. The Sharpe ratio for each asset class is almost doubled as
a result of this aggregation.
As we explore Sharpe ratios and correlations, the central question is: how consistent are they
over time? Figure 1 presents Sharpe ratio three year moving averages over time per asset class and
investment style. Remarkably, performance is consistently positive for value. It is also uniformly
positive for carry except for a brief episode in the middle of the 90s. The contrast, cross sectional
momentum has suffered over the last few years.
Figure 1. Cross Sectional: 3Y Rolling Sharpe per Asset Class (left) and per In-
vestment Style (right)
In figure 2, it can be seen that correlations across styles are highly unstable, with value showing
at times strong negative correlation with both carry and momentum.
Last but not least, figures 3 and 4 show the cumulative P&L, the 3Y rolling Sharpe ratio and
its distribution when all strategy pairs are aggregated in a single portfolio. The overall Sharpe ratio
is 1.40, with corresponding return and volatility of 6.88% and 4.92% respectively. The reader should
be reminded however that the trading did not account for transaction costs. Figure 4 shows that the
portfolio was never in the red on a 3yr rolling basis with a Sharpe ratio moving between 0 and 2.30
and hovering around 1.35 recently.
Figure 4. Cross Sectional: 3Y Rolling Sharpe (left) and its Distribution (right)
for Value+Carry+Momentum
We now look at the time series approach: unlike the cross sectional portfolio, the time series
portfolio is comprised of positions equivalent to N1 in a universe of N assets, with positions being
long (short) if the signal is positive (negative). Therefore, if the signal is uniformly positive across
an asset class, the portfolio position will be directionally positive in all assets.
As in the cross sectional portfolio, all styles exhibit overall positive Sharpe ratios in the time
series. However, one major difference emerges: momentum more than doubles its Sharpe ratio
from 0.42 to 0.96. The momentum drawdown to volatility ratio is lowest across styles in time
series. As in the cross section, both value and momentum styles, unlike carry, are positively skewed.
Overall, momentum exhibits substantially better risk return characteristics in time series than in
cross section. One can surmise that momentum in a time series portfolio will capture more clearly
market directionality, including reversals than in a cross sectional portfolio. Conversely, risk-adjusted
performance is vastly worse for value in time series than in cross section. From Table 5 Panel A, it
is readily apparent that equity is the prime culprit. Indeed, with stocks trending higher over the last
25 years, the value factor, which relies largely on mean reversion, was bound to underperform. In
the same spirit, the Table 5 Panel B shows the deterioration in the drawdowns associated with value
compared to Table 1 Panel B. It is also worth noting that both value and momentum display a high
positive skewness (Table 5 Panel C).
Of note are the S&P betas and t-stats of {”asset class”,”style”} pairs in the time series (Table
7 Panel A): betas are more, yet weakly, negative and more significant in time series than in cross
section. Specifically, carry strategies are well diversified across asset classes. FX carry is pro-cyclical
as expected whereas equity carry, like equity value, boils down to buying market dips and selling
market tops and will hence show a negative beta. From Table 6 Panel B, equity value and equity
carry correlation is 51%, confirming that both strategies are similar in nature. Trading momentum
and carry on a given asset class also shows a good degree of correlation. This is explained by the fact
that momentum signals are computed on what amounts to a total return series. If a market exhibits
a persistent carry premium this will accumulate though the total return and produce a momentum
effect. The longer the lookback of the momentum signal, the more carry will accumulate and the
higher the correlation between the signals. As in the cross sectional case, the average correlation
in time series is close to zero, indicating substantial scope for diversification across styles and asset
classes.
Combining signals, Sharpe ratios for time series are broadly in line with those for the cross sec-
tion, with the proviso that individual style performances, as noted before, are significantly different.
As in the cross section, the time series Sharpe is high at 1.37, while the 3Y rolling Sharpe ratio for a
combined carry, momentum and value portfolio was always positive and varied between 0.1 and 2.7
over the past 21 years.
Figure 5. Time Series: 3Y Rolling Sharpe per Asset Class (left) and per Invest-
ment Style (right)
Figure 8. Time Series: 3Y Rolling Sharpe (left) and its Distribution (right) for
Value+Carry+Momentum
Readers should be made aware of the fact that, in addition to the daily rebalancing with binary
signals discussed so far, we also tested all of the above strategies using monthly rebalancing and linear
signals. The monthly results are broadly consistent with the daily results.
Contrasting Table 1 Panel A and Table 5 Panel A, we have quite different results for the three
styles: value works well in the cross section, poorly in time series; carry works about equally well in
both cross section and time series and momentum works well in time series, but poorly in the cross
section.
At a basic level, assuming linear signals, cross sectional portfolio weights are equal to time
series weights minus the cross sectional average. This average can be thought of as a global factor.
Therefore, we can think of a cross sectional portfolio as a time series portfolio hedged for the global
factor. Pursuing this line of reasoning, time series momentum will outperform cross sectional mo-
mentum to the extent that the global factor is trending. Alternatively, to the extent that the value
indicator trades reversion to the mean, time series value investing will do better than cross sectional
value investing when the global factor returns are negatively autocorrelated.
So how do we interpret the results from our data exploration? As stated above, momentum
outperformance seems to go hand in hand with value underperformance in the time series versus the
cross section. Although this result is difficult to interpret, we can offer three possible explanations.
The first is that momentum, unlike value, takes the price movements themselves as being
informative and, as in such, may be better placed to assimilate any truly novel information about
the global factor which may not be captured by the valuation model. In other words, the momentum
model may account unwittingly for the factors omitted by the valuation model. This distinction
between value and momentum is most prominent in the more correlated asset classes of equities and
bonds.
In FX and commodities where a global factor is much less apparent the performance differences
between the cross section and time series is much less. This makes sense, because in moving from
time series to cross sectional portfolios we are essentially hedging out a single global factor. If this
factor explains less, there will be less to hedge out and less difference between the portfolios (in either
direction). This is exactly what we observe. Although this explanation may have merits, it does not
help us understand why value performs better than momentum in the cross section.
Another explanation is that major global factors have exhibited very strong trends which have
by definition hurt reversion based value predictors. It may even be claimed that the central purpose
of stimulative public policies recently was to boost wealth effects by supporting a sustained rally in
stocks and bonds, that in turn favored momentum over value in both asset classes.
A third explanation for time series versus cross sectional performance is the correlations of the
signals, and how they compare to the correlations of the underlying markets. All else being equal,
a cross sectional approach has more to gain when asset correlations are very high, as the above-
mentioned global factor will dominate, and hedging this out will increase diversification by boosting
exposure to a wider range of other factors. However, if signals are also highly correlated, a cross
sectional approach will hedge out most of the (presumably informative) signals as well, potentially
canceling out any gain from the diversification. Conversely if asset correlations are high, but signal
correlations low, we will likely lose very little of the information in the signals by forcing them to
be cross-sectional as their information already mostly relates to the non-global factors. This could
potentially explain the outperformance of time series momentum against time series value in bonds
and equities. Although both asset classes are internally highly correlated, the momentum signals
on them are even more correlated, so moving to a cross-sectional framework will potentially hedge
out more of the alpha from the signals than noise from the market. Correlations of value signals are
notably smaller.
While all of the above explanations have appeal, the readers should note that value is tradi-
tionally traded in the cross section while momentum is traded in time series. So it would seem that
traders have generally come to the “correct conclusions”.
We now try our hand at combining cross sectional and time series portfolios for all styles
and asset classes. The overall correlation between the two portfolios is 43%. This translates into
substantial diversification benefits. Also note that each style exhibits positive correlation (39%, 49%
and 51% for value, carry and momentum respectively) between its cross sectional and time series
incarnation (Table 11 Panel A). The Sharpe ratio of the combined portfolios is 1.61 (figure 11), while
the 3Y rolling Sharpe ratio (figure 12) varied from 0.5 to 2.7 since 1994. One should note, however,
overemphasize the diversification achieved by combining cross sectional and time series portfolios:
indeed, it can be shown in a simple set-up that the combined portfolio is just the time series portfolio
with half of the cross sectional mean hedged out.
Table 10: Combining the Cross Sectional and Time Series Signals
Panel A: Sharpe Ratios
Asset Class V C M Avg V+C V+M C+M Avg V+C+M
FX 0.41 0.68 0.81 0.63 0.92 0.87 1.05 0.95 1.21
EQ 0.27 0.35 0.21 0.28 0.43 0.34 0.39 0.39 0.47
Commo 0.12 0.82 0.50 0.48 0.92 0.54 0.76 0.74 0.92
IR 0.60 0.88 0.04 0.51 0.98 0.42 0.65 0.68 0.80
Avg 0.35 0.68 0.39 0.81 0.54 0.71
All Asset 0.71 1.41 0.73 1.59 1.06 1.33 1.61
Table 12: Assessing the Market Risk of Cross Sectional Combined with Time Series
Panel A: Beta Coefficients and T-Statistics in Parenthesis
Asset Class Value Carry Mom. Avg
FX -10%(-9.2) 39%(34.1) -10%(-9.2) 6%
EQ -25%(-21.0) -25%(-23.0) -9%(-8.3) -20%
Commo 0%(-0.1) -7%(-6.4) -6%(-4.9) -4%
IR 5%(4.3) -12%(10.1) -7%(-5.9) -5%
Avg -8% -1% -8%
All Asset -7%(-13.2) -1%(-2.0) -8%(-12.4)
Figure 9. CS+TS: 3Y Rolling Sharpe per Asset Class (left) and per Investment
Style (right)
Figure 12. CS+TS: 3Y Rolling Sharpe (left) and Monthly Return Distribution
(right) for Value+Carry+Momentum
By combining simple signals in carry, momentum and value across less than 100 liquid futures,
forwards and swap markets we are able to achieve a remarkably stable strategy over 25 years with
a Sharpe ratio of close to 2, returning an approximately eight-fold increase on a hypothetical 15%
volatility investment. This can be considered a genuine return, as the strategy has very low funding
costs. Is this too good to be true? Why is not every investor trading these styles in combination?
We tried our hand at six possible explanations.
Selection bias is a partial answer. Why did we choose these styles and not others? Because, by
and large, they have worked consistently over time and across asset classes. However, in defense of
our results, not many styles make sense across such diverse asset classes; so the selection pool is not
large.
What about potential over-fitting? There was no fitting in this exercise, although some po-
tentially creeps in from experience. Why do our value predictors look back much further than the
momentum predictor? Because momentum has worked better at medium frequencies, whereas value
is clearly a long-term game. How obvious would this have been 25 years ago?
Survivorship and selection bias of assets is also a problem. Toxic emerging markets may be
excluded. This study excluded Argentina but included the likes of Russia, Greece, Indonesia. This
kind of bias will likely favor value and carry through the removal of markets where turmoil has caused
major assets to exit.
Momentum suffers from another potential bias. Back in 1990, many markets we would include
now were much smaller. The ones that make it into our study have likely grown over this time, often
via a strong long-term up-trend. By adding data for markets which are now big, but were once small,
we likely give a positive bias to momentum predictors.
Another, perhaps more appealing explanation for the performance is simply that few firms have
the appetite and patience to trade something so simple. It is easy to forget the arguments in 1999
that value had been replaced by growth, in 2008 that carry was toxic, and in 2011-13 that momentum
was finished. These are long-term signals whose performance oscillates over time (figures 1, 5 and
9), with each style experiencing negative performances for at least three years. It is difficult to stick
with underperforming strategies this long.
6 Conclusion
There are many studies that examine carry, value and momentum strategies, either individually
or in combination. However, some of these studies look at the directional or time-series versions of
these strategies while others look across assets usually with long-short portfolios. Our paper explores
the differences in the performance of any strategy depending on the implementation: directional vs.
cross-asset.
Our empirical work examines a large number of assets: equity, fixed income, foreign currency
as well as commodities. While the average performance of the strategies is impressive - and is
particularly striking if the strategies are combined - we argue that caution should be exercised.
There is a reason that carry, value and momentum are popular. They have worked well in the past.
Hence, it is no surprise that average returns for these strategies are positive. However, the focus of
our paper is not to find the most profitable strategy. Our research provides information about the
conditions whereby a particular strategy is best implemented in the cross-section or in the time-series.
Our results are suggestive of a framework that may help identify, ex ante, the likelihood that a
directional will outperform a cross-asset implementation of any particular strategy. The underlying
ingredients are linked to the correlation of the asset returns as well as the correlation of the trading
signals. Such a framework is the subject of on-going research.
7 References
1. AHL/MSS Academic Advisory Board https://www.ahl.com/research/momentum-behavioural
2. Asness, C., Moskowitz, T., and Pedersen, L.H. (2013). “Value and Momentum Everywhere.”
The Journal of Finance, 929-985
3. Barberis, N., Shleifer, A., and Viskny, R. (1998). “A model of investor sentiment.” Journal of
Financial Economics, 307-343
4. Benartzi, S., and Thaler, R.H. (1995). “Myopic Loss Aversion and the Equity Premium Puz-
zle.” Quarter 4 Journal of Economics, 73-92
5. Breeden, D.T. (1986). “Consumption, Production and Interest Rates: A Synthesis.” Journal
of Financial Economics, 3-39
6. Conrad, J. and Kaul, G. (1988). “Time-variation in expected returns.” The Journal of Business,
409- 425
7. Dornbusch, R. (1976) “Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics.” Journal of Political Econ-
omy, 1161-1176
8. Erb, C.B., and Harvey, C.R. (2006). “The Tactical and Strategic Value of Commodity Futures.”
Financial Analysts Journal, 47-68
9. Grinblatt, M., and Han, B. (2002). “The Disposition Effect and Momentum.” NBER Working
Paper, Working Paper No. 8734
10. Hansen, L.P., Heaton J.P., and Li, N. (2008). “Consumption strikes back?: Measuring long
run risk.” Journal of Political Economy, 298-345
11. Harvey, C.R., Liu, Y., and Zhu, H. (forthcoming). “. . . and the Cross-section of Expected
Returns.” Review of Financial Studies
12. Hong, H., and Stein, J.C. (1999). ‘A unified theory of underreaction, momentum trading, and
overreaction in asset markets.” Journal of Finance, 2143-2184
13. Kaldor, N. (1939). “Speculation and Economic Stability.” Review of Economic Studies, 1-27
14. Koijen, R.S.J, and Moskowitz, T., and Pedersen, L.H., and Vrugt, E.N. (2013). “Carry.” NBER
Working Paper, Working Paper No. 19325
15. Lakonishok, J., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. (1994). “Contrarian investment, extrapolation,
and risk.” Journal of Finance, 1541-1578
16. Liu, X., and Zhang, L. (2008). “Momentum profits, factor pricing, and macroeconomic risk.”
Review of Financial Studies, 2417-2448
17. Lustig, H., and Verdelhan, A. (2007). “The Cross-section of Foreign Currency Risk Premia
and US Consumption Growth Risk.” American Economic Review, 89-117
18. Maenhout, P. (1999). “Robust portfolio rules and asset pricing.” Working paper, Harvard
University
19. Moskowitz, T., Hua Ooi, Y., and Pedersen, L.H. (2012). “Time Series Momentum.” Journal of
Financial Economics, 228-250
20. Schwartz, E.S. (1997). “The stochastic behavior of commodity prices: Implications for valua-
tion and hedging.” Journal of Finance, 923-973
21. Vayanos, D., and Woolley, P. (2013). “An Institutional Theory of Momentum and Reversal.”
The Review of Financial Studies, 1087-1145
22. Working, H. (1933). “Price Relations between July and September Wheat Futures at Chicago
since 1885.” Wheat Studies of the Food Research Institute, 187-240
8 Appendix
• G10: AUD, CAD, CHF, EUR, GBP, JPY, NOK, NZD, SEK, USD
• EM Asia: HKD, INR, IDR, KRW, MYR, PHP, SGD, TWD, THB
• EM Latam: BRL, CLP, COP, PEN, MXN
• CEEMEA: CZK, HUF, ILS, PLN, RUB, TRY
• Africa: ZAR
FX: Signal and Total Return Time Series Start Dates
Currency Value TS Carry TS Momentum TS P&L TS
Pair
AUDUSD 05-Nov-74 13-Dec-83 27-Oct-87 27-Jun-86
BRLUSD 16-Nov-95 03-Feb-99 02-May-00 01-Jan-99
CADUSD 05-Nov-74 29-Dec-88 02-May-90 02-Jan-89
CHFUSD 05-Nov-74 29-Dec-88 02-May-90 02-Jan-89
CLPUSD 04-Dec-12 22-Oct-97 02-May-00 01-Jan-99
COPUSD 02-Dec-97 03-Feb-99 02-May-00 01-Jan-99
CZKUSD 10-Apr-97 11-Dec-96 02-May-00 01-Jan-99
EURUSD 03-Nov-78 14-Dec-98 02-May-90 02-Jan-89
GBPUSD 04-Dec-78 02-Jan-87 09-May-88 08-Jan-87
HKDUSD 03-Sep-84 29-Dec-88 02-May-90 02-Jan-89
HUFUSD 18-Apr-97 22-Jul-98 02-May-00 01-Jan-99
IDRUSD 06-Sep-95 04-Feb-04 02-May-00 01-Jan-99
ILSUSD 12-Feb-85 20-Jul-98 11-Aug-82 21-Jul-98
INRUSD 04-May-92 11-Dec-98 02-May-00 01-Jan-99
JPYUSD 05-Nov-74 29-Dec-88 02-May-90 02-Jan-89
KRWUSD 12-Feb-85 11-Dec-98 02-May-00 01-Jan-99
MXNUSD 02-Dec-76 03-Nov-97 02-May-00 01-Jan-99
MYRUSD 02-Dec-08 20-Apr-05 03-May-72 22-Jul-05
NOKUSD 05-Nov-74 29-Dec-88 02-May-90 02-Jan-89
NZDUSD 05-Nov-74 29-Dec-88 02-May-90 02-Jan-89
PENUSD 02-Dec-97 21-Jul-00 02-May-00 01-Jan-99
PHPUSD 06-Sep-95 09-Dec-98 02-May-00 01-Jan-99
PLNUSD 21-Apr-97 21-Jul-98 02-May-00 01-Jan-99
RUBUSD 12-May-97 09-Aug-01 08-Nov-94 02-Jan-01
SEKUSD 05-Nov-74 29-Dec-88 02-May-90 02-Jan-89
SGDUSD 06-Nov-84 29-Dec-88 02-May-00 01-Jan-99
THBUSD 02-Dec-97 20-Sep-95 02-May-00 01-Jan-99
TRYUSD 31-Dec-87 11-Dec-96 02-May-00 01-Jan-99
TWDUSD 06-Aug-87 11-Dec-98 02-May-00 01-Jan-99
ZARUSD 02-Dec-83 29-Dec-88 02-May-90 02-Jan-89
USD 04-Nov-74 01-Jan-71 02-May-72 01-Jan-71
2. Equity
The equity sample covers 26 indices across several geographic regions. Here is the complete
list:
3. Commodities
We used a mix of commodity futures (16 in total). Here is the complete list:
4. Rates
We used swap data (14 in total). Here is the complete list:
• G10: Europe, UK, Japan, US, New-Zealand, Australia, Switzerland, Canada, Norway,
Sweden
• EM: Hungary, Poland, South Africa, Philippines
Rates: Signal and Total Return Time Series Start Dates
Currency Ticker Bloomberg Value TS Carry TS Momentum TS P&L TS
EUR EUSA10 Comdty 01-Jan-99 04-Jan-99 08-May-00 29-Jan-99
GBP BPSW10 Comdty 16-Nov-90 16-Nov-90 20-Mar-92 30-Nov-90
JPY JYSWAP10 Comdty 30-Jun-94 01-Nov-88 19-Mar-90 30-Nov-88
USD USSWAP10 Comdty 01-Nov-88 01-Nov-88 24-Apr-90 30-Nov-88
NZD NDSWAP10 Comdty 25-Mar-96 25-Mar-96 12-Aug-97 29-Mar-96
AUD ADSWAP10 Comdty 01-Jun-88 03-May-89 24-Jan-91 31-May-89
CHF SFSW10 Comdty 16-Nov-90 16-Nov-90 20-Mar-92 30-Nov-90
CAD CDSW10 Comdty 02-Feb-98 09-Dec-91 29-Aug-90 31-Dec-91
NOK NKSW10 Comdty 29-Oct-93 29-Oct-93 03-Nov-95 29-Oct-93
SEK SKSW10 Comdty 31-Mar-94 08-Feb-91 29-Jun-92 28-Feb-91
HUF HFSW10 Comdty 27-Nov-01 27-Nov-01 22-Apr-03 30-Nov-01
PLN PZSW10 Comdty 12-Jun-00 12-Jun-00 07-Feb-02 30-Jun-00
ZAR SASW10 Comdty 03-Oct-95 01-Feb-99 25-Feb-97 26-Feb-99
PHP PPSWN10 Comdty 31-Mar-99 04-Apr-01 14-Aug-00 30-Apr-01