Jürgen Kurtz, 2 - History
Jürgen Kurtz, 2 - History
Jürgen Kurtz, 2 - History
History
2.1 Introduction
The story of the development of international law protections for foreign
trade and investment is complex and multi-faceted. When it comes to the
creation of modern standards, that historiography comprises three distinct
stages. Firstly, one can identify a joint birth as both protections were
developed, superficially at least, as part of a comprehensive effort to
entrench political and economic cooperation in the aftermath of the
Second World War. Section 2.2 traces this story of ‘inception’ (from
1945 to the 1970s) with a focus on the contingent political and economic
causes that led to a splintering between treaty coverage of international
trade (confined to the GATT) versus foreign investment (within a small
but growing number of bilateral treaties) at international law. Section 2.3
then examines the next historical stage of ‘expansion’ covering the 1980s to
late 1990s. Both systems are structurally characterized by growth and,
especially within the transition from the GATT to the World Trade
Organization (WTO), expanded scope of operation. Indeed, the comple-
tion of the Uruguay Round marks the first stage in a formal reunification
between the two fields given the inclusion of foreign investment issues in
select parts of the WTO. This, however, is only part of the phenomenon of
reconnection. Within investment law, the constitutive factors that had led
to the inception of the treaty system had largely eroded by the 1980s. As
a result, states parties begin to use investment treaties for a different
functionality from their original role of mediating entrenched political
and economic conflict. Investment treaties now constitute a means to
signal commitment to select liberal economic policies, including
extension of competitive opportunities to foreign investors, which
parallels a similar foundational promise made to international traders
originally in the GATT. Section 2.4 concludes with an assessment of the
contemporary period, described as one of ‘activation, engagement and
recalibration’. It begins by exploring the disjuncture between the
31
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
32 h ist ory
1
E.g. N. Ferguson, Empire – How Britain Made the Modern World (Penguin Books, 2003).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
inc ep t ion: 1945 to the 1 970s 33
2
K. Vandevelde, Bilateral Investment Treaties: History, Policy and Interpretation (Oxford
University Press, 2010), p. 38. See also H. Walker Jr, ‘Modern Treaties of Friendship,
Commerce and Navigation’ (1957–58) 42 Minnesota Law Review 805.
3
The Oscar Chinn Case (Britain v. Belgium), [1934] PCIJ (Ser. A/B) No. 63.
4
The Oscar Chinn Case, p. 70. 5 The Oscar Chinn Case, p. 75.
6
The Oscar Chinn Case, p. 84.
7
Case Concerning Oil Platforms (Islamic Republic of Iran v. United States of America),
Preliminary Objection, Judgment, ICJ Rep. 1996, p. 803.
8
Case Concerning Oil Platforms, p. 813.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
34 h ist ory
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
inc ep t ion: 1945 to the 1 970s 35
naturally opposed for the ITO the strong investment disciplines of the
sort found in an FCN treaty. Despite that opposition, the US delegation
eventually succeeded in its quest to include some coverage of foreign
investment within the Charter.17 However, the rights granted to foreign
investors were substantially diluted from earlier articles put forward by
the United States and those classically found in FCN treaties of the era.18
Not surprisingly, then, the ITO’s provisions on foreign investment19 are
far less detailed and comprehensive than those directed at cross-border
trade in goods.20
The overall structure of the Charter’s limited provisions on foreign
investment sought to balance the interests of host and home countries.
Investment disciplines were never intended to simply and only protect
foreign property rights. They were a functional vector whereby host
states could use foreign investment to achieve development outcomes,21
a vital imperative not only for newly independent states, but also for the
many European countries where war had devastated political, economic
and social institutions and patterns. Naturally, then, Article 11 specifi-
cally positions capital as one mechanism by which to promote ‘industrial
and general economic development’.22 It also seeks to strike a balance
between capital importers and exporters by (i) requiring members to
cooperate to ensure transfer of capital, while (ii) also providing that ‘no
Member shall take unreasonable or unjustifiable action within its terri-
tory injurious to the rights or interests of nationals of other Members in
the enterprise, skills, capital, arts or technology which they have sup-
plied’.23 This latter commitment is the only hard and operative constraint
on sovereignty of host states in this part of the ITO. The remaining
provisions on foreign investment are largely forward-looking in that
17
C. Wilcox, A Charter for World Trade (Macmillan, 1949), pp. 37–53.
18
For example, the early articles proposed by the US delegation at a meeting in Geneva in
1947 set out extensive rights for investors, including the obligation of host states to accord
national treatment as well as unqualified most-favoured-nation treatment. These exten-
sive rights provoked opposition by a number of countries, including the Czech
Government, which refused to give German investors the same status as investors of
other countries. The resulting compromise is reflected in Art. 12 of the Charter, which
significantly dilutes the liberalization commitments proposed by the US delegation.
Article 12(2) merely requires member states to ‘give due regard to the desirability of
avoiding discrimination as between foreign investments’. T. Brewer and S. Young, The
Multilateral Investment System and Multinational Enterprises (Oxford University Press,
1998), p. 67.
19
Havana Charter, Ch. III (Economic Development and Reconstruction).
20
Havana Charter, Chp. IV (Commercial Policy). 21 Havana Charter, Recitals 2 and 3.
22
Havana Charter, Art. 11. 23 Havana Charter, Art. 11.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
36 h ist ory
24
Havana Charter, Art. 12.2(b). 25 Havana Charter, Art. 12.1(c)(i) and (ii).
26
W. Diebold, ‘The End of the ITO’ in 16 Essays in International Finance (Princeton
University Press, 1952), pp. 1–37.
27
Havana Charter, Ch. IV (Commercial Policy).
28
For analysis of the flexibility in GATT Art. XI to impose short-term export restrictions for
food security reasons, see below Ch. 5, section 5.3.2 (‘Modelling from the law of
the WTO’).
29
GATT Art. XI.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
inc e pt ion: 1945 to the 1 970s 37
30
GATT Art. II.
31
B. Hoekman and M. Kostecki, The Political Economy of the World Trading System: The
WTO and Beyond, 2nd edn (Oxford University Press, 2001), pp. 25–33.
32
R. Hudec, ‘“Like Product”: The Differences in Meaning in GATT Articles 1 and III’ in
T. Cottier, P. Mavroidis and P. Blatter (eds), Regulatory Barriers and the Principle of Non-
Discrimination in World Trade Law (University of Michigan Press, 2000), pp. 108–109.
33
Hoekman and Kostecki, The Political Economy of the World Trade System, pp. 101–102.
34
GATT Art. I.
35
An alternative theoretical proposition would position trade law as restraining terms-of-
trade manipulation. Yet even here, the goal is ultimately one of efficiency (at least in global
allocation of resources). D. Regan, ‘What Are Trade Agreements For? Two Conflicting
Stories Told by Economists, with a Lesson for Lawyers’ (2006) 9(4) Journal of
International Economic Law 951–988.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
38 h ist ory
workers will lose their livelihoods. The manner and extent to which those
who suffer loss from free trade are compensated is an important prism
through which to assess whether free trade maximizes overall social
welfare. Even with those distributional consequences in mind, a wel-
fare-based case has provided an important degree of substantive legiti-
macy to multilateral trade rules that focus on the explicit, price-distorting
effect of tariffs and comparable regulations.36
The strong economic case for MFN treatment was matched by a key
political motivation influential in shaping the perspectives of the
framers of the GATT. The inter-war period was characterized by wide-
spread departure from policies of economic liberalism. Despite its
position as the world’s leading creditor nation in the immediate post-
First World War period, the United States raised tariff levels with
trigger effects on devastated debtor nations in Europe.37 This increase
made it difficult for those countries to earn the dollars in which to make
required interest payments. The result was the so-called ‘beggar-thy-
neighbour’ policies of progressively extreme and ruinous forms of trade
protection. Although there was an attempt to ameliorate this tendency
at the World Economic Conference of 1927, these efforts ended without
result by the onset of the Great Depression in 1929.38 By the time of the
stock market crash in the United States, international considerations
became even more subordinate to national demands on fostering inter-
nal economic recovery. The infamous 1930 American Smoot-Hawley
increase in tariffs as a response to the Depression saw retaliation by
other governments leading to devastating levels of economic balkaniza-
tion.39 From 1931 to 1932, Great Britain – the political champion of
economic liberalism in the nineteenth century – shifted tack and turned
inwards by negotiating the Ottawa agreements to set up a system of
tariff preferences among the Commonwealth countries.40 The impact of
these protectionist policies on the international economy in the inter-
war years was severe; from 1929 to 1934, world trade levels declined by
36
R. Howse, ‘The Legitimacy of the World Trade Organization’ in J.-M. Coicaud and
V. Heiskanen (eds), The Legitimacy of International Organizations (United Nations
University Press, 2001), pp. 355, 365.
37
A. Brown, Reluctant Partners: A History of Multilateral Trade Cooperation 1850–2000
(University of Michigan Press, 2003), p. 69.
38
A. G. Kenwood and A. L. Lougheed, The Growth of the International Economy 1820–1860
(Routledge, 1971), p. 186.
39
Brown, Reluctant Partners, p. 73.
40
G. Winham, The Evolution of International Trade Agreements (University of Toronto
Press, 1992), p. 30.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
i nc e pt i o n : 1 9 45 t o th e 1 9 7 0 s 39
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
40 his tor y
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
inc ep t ion: 1945 to the 1 970s 41
52
J. H. H. Weiler, ‘The Rule of Lawyers and the Ethos of Diplomats: Reflections on the
Internal and External Legitimacy of WTO Dispute Settlement’ (2001) 35(2) Journal of
World Trade 191, 194.
53
M. K. Young, ‘Dispute Resolution in the Uruguay Round: Lawyers Triumph Over
Diplomats’ (1995) 29 International Lawyer 389.
54
J. Jackson, ‘GATT as an Instrument for the Settlement of Trade Disputes’ (1967) 61
American Society of International Law Proceedings 144.
55
UNCTAD, World Investment Report 1996 (United Nations, 1996), pp. 147–148.
56
L. T. Wells and R. Ahmed, Making Foreign Investment Safe: Property Rights and National
Sovereignty (Oxford University Press, 2007), p. 38; A. Chua, World On Fire: How
Exporting Free Market Democracy Breeds Ethnic Hatred and Global Instability (Anchor,
2003), pp. 120–121.
57
GATT Art. XVIII(2).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
42 h ist ory
58
Brewer and Young, The Multilateral Investment System and Multinational Enterprises,
p. 53.
59
S. N. Guha-Roy, ‘Is the Law of Responsibility of States for Injuries to Aliens a Part of
Universal International Law?’ (1961) 55(4) American Journal of International Law 863,
866–886; C. F. Amerasinghe, State Responsibility for Injuries to Aliens (Clarendon Press,
1967), pp. 128–129.
60
Permanent Sovereignty over Natural Resources, GA Res. 1803, 14 December 1962, 2 ILM
223 (1963), para. 4.
61
‘Mexico-United States: Expropriation by Mexico of Agrarian Properties Owned by
American Citizens’, 193.
62
Amerasinghe, State Responsibility, p. 156.
63
Declaration on the Establishment of a New International Economic Order, GA Res. 3201,
1 May 1974, 13 ILM 715 (1974).
64
Charter of Economic Rights and Duties of States, GA Res. 3281, 12 December 1974, 14
ILM 251 (1975), s. 2.2(2)(c).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
i nc e pt i o n : 1 9 45 t o th e 1 9 7 0 s 43
65
Case Concerning Military and Paramilitary Activities In and Against Nicaragua
(Nicaragua v. US), Judgment, ICJ Reports 1986, para. 188.
66
TOPCO v. Libya, Award 17 ILM 3 (1974), 31–37.
67
Government of the State of Kuwait v. American Independent Oil Co. (AMINOIL), Award,
21 ILM 976 (1984), paras 143–144.
68
Shahin Shaine Ebrahimi v. Iran, Iran-US Claims Tribunal Award 560–44/46/47–3 (12
October 1994), para. 88.
69
SEDCO Inc. v. National Iranian Oil Co. & The Islamic Republic of Iran (Interlocutory
Award), 10 CTR 180, 184–189 (1986-I), 25 ILM 629 (1986).
70
CME Czech Republic B.V. v. Czech Republic, Separate Opinion by Ian Brownlie on the
Issues at the Quantum Phase (UNCITRAL, 14 March 2003), paras 23–32.
71
J. Karl, ‘The Promotion and Protection of German Foreign Investments Abroad’ (1996)
11(1) ICSID Review 1.
72
Between 1960 and 1966, Belgium, Denmark, France, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands,
Norway, Sweden and Switzerland all concluded their first BITs. UNCTAD, International
Investment Law Rule-Making: Stocktaking, Challenges and the Way Forward (United
Nations, 2008), p. 11.
73
K. Vandevelde, ‘The Political Economy of a Bilateral Investment Treaty’ (1998) 92
American Journal of International Law 621, 627.
74
Vandevelde, ‘Political Economy’, 627.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
44 h isto ry
accelerated slightly throughout the 1970s, with a further 166 BITs con-
cluded by the end of 1979.75 The United States was a comparative late
starter as it had folded investment commitments into FCN treaties76 and
only launched its own specific BIT program in 1981.77
These early BITs are characterized by striking asymmetry in economic
and power relationships. The vast majority were initiated by European
capital exporters and directed towards developing states with a high
degree of uniformity in many substantive provisions, especially the
rules concerning expropriation. Those rules reflect the long-standing
preference of developed states to the protection of private property by
adopting the older Hull standard of ‘prompt, adequate and effective’
compensation rather than the evolving customary notion of ‘appropriate’
compensation in the event of expropriation of foreign assets.78 In this
respect, the animating ethos of investment treaties is fundamentally
different from that of the GATT. For developed states, the clear goal is
to substitute treaty protections for, and at the margins contest, the down-
ward shift in the customary standard of property protection articulated
by newly independent states.
Indeed, the sovereignty constraints imposed by early BITs have a
remarkably distinct conceptual orientation when compared to the nega-
tive integration bargain of the GATT. Take the manner in which a typical
BIT of this period regulates the contentious practice of state takings of
private (foreign) property. Even if a state is acting for a public purpose
and in a non-discriminatory fashion, compensation must be paid to the
foreign property holder.79 Notably, the guarantee of compensation is
even extended beyond the paradigmatic case of direct expropriation to
encompass domestic regulatory or tax measures that might be considered
‘indirect’ forms of expropriation.80 There is no attempt within early BIT
practice to delineate the level of disruption or impact on a foreign
investor sufficient to trigger the positive obligation to pay compensation
for ‘indirect’ expropriation. A similar hard constraint on regulatory
75
UNCTAD, International Investment Law Rule-Making, p. 13.
76
C. Lipson, Standing Guard: Protecting Foreign Capital in the Nineteenth and Twentieth
Centuries (University of California Press, 1985), p. 97.
77
K. Vandevelde, United States Investment Treaties: Policy and Practice (Kluwer, 1992).
78
UNCTAD, Taking of Property: Series on Issues in International Investment Agreements
(United Nations, 2000), pp. 28–31.
79
1994 US Model BIT, Art. III extracted in C. McLachlan, L. Shore and M. Weiniger,
International Investment Arbitration: Substantive Principles (Oxford University Press,
2007), p. 388.
80
Ibid.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
i nc e pt i o n : 1 9 45 t o th e 1 9 7 0 s 45
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
46 hi sto ry
85
Case Concerning the Barcelona Traction Light and Power Co. Ltd (Belgium v. Spain),
Second Phase, Judgment, ICJ Reports 1970, 44.
86
Interhandel Case (Switzerland v. United States of America), Preliminary Objections, ICJ
Reports 1959, 6.
87
Interhandel Case, Preliminary Objections, 27.
88
Dolzer and Schreuer, Principles of International Investment Law, pp. 122–129.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
i n c e p ti o n : 1 9 4 5 t o t he 1 9 7 0 s 47
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
48 h ist ory
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
e x p a n s i o n : t h e 19 8 0 s t o t he l a te 1 9 9 0s 49
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
50 h ist ory
gains.102 An illustrative list holds open the possibility, for instance, that
a WTO panel might find that technology transfer requirements
(imposed on foreign investors) fall within the potential scope of the
TRIMs Agreement. Indeed, mature investment treaty instruments (such
as NAFTA Chapter 11) will often explicitly prohibit this type of perfor-
mance requirement, evidencing once again the growing entanglement
between the two fields.103
The second key legal outcome of the Uruguay Round directly engaging
foreign investment is the GATS. While the GATS ostensibly pertains only
to ‘trade in services’,104 it contains detailed provisions concerning FDI.
This reflects the strategic fact that FDI tends to be especially important in
service industries that are heavily regulated (such as banking), as it is
often the only legally permissible modality for firms to enter and supply a
foreign market. Indeed, the services sector is typically the largest recipi-
ent of FDI, such that in 2012, for instance, the service sector accounted
for a majority of total inward global FDI stock.105 Reflecting this eco-
nomic reality, FDI through ‘commercial presence’ is included as one of
the four modes of service supply covered by the GATS.106 Yet while the
GATS covers foreign investment in the services sector, its legal structure
and orientation is significantly different from that of a BIT. The GATS is
certainly an instrument of economic liberalization, as it obliges WTO
members to offer market access to their service sectors.107 The invest-
ment treaties of a limited number of states – especially the United States
and Canada – similarly encompass guarantees of market access typically
by extending national treatment and/or MFN to the pre-establishment
phase.108 Yet those investment treaties (such as NAFTA Chapter 11 and
other instruments entered into by the United States and Canada) will
adopt a negative list approach to scheduling commitments to market
access.109 This aggressive top-down structure means that the investment
102
N. Kumar, ‘Performance Requirements as Tools of Development Policy: Lessons from
Developed and Developing Countries’ in K. Gallagher (ed.), Putting Development First
(Zed Books, 2005). For an argument that export performance requirements (that necessa-
rily distort trade flows) may increase host state welfare, see D. Rodrik, ‘The Economics of
Exports Performance Requirements’ (1987) 102 Quarterly Journal of Economics 633.
103
NAFTA Art. 1106(1)(f). 104 GATS Art. I(1).
105
UNCTAD, World Investment Report 2013 (United Nations, 2013), p. 9.
106
GATS Art. I(2)(c). 107 GATS Art. XVI.
108
I. Gómez-Palacio and P. Muchlinski, ‘Admission and Establishment’ in P. Muchlinski,
F. Ortino and C. Schreuer (eds), The Oxford Handbook of International Investment Law
(Oxford University Press, 2008), pp. 239–245.
109
Gómez-Palacio and Muchlinski, ‘Admission and Establishment’, p. 243.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
e x pa ns i o n : th e 1 980 s t o t h e la te 1 9 9 0 s 51
110
NAFTA Art. 1108 (Reservations and Exceptions). 111 GATS Art. XVI.
112
GATS Art. XVII.
113
GATS Art. XX; WTO, Revision of Scheduling Guidelines (SC/CSC/W/19, 5 March 1999).
114
B. Hoekman, ‘Assessing the General Agreement on Trade in Services’ in W. Martin and
L. A. Winters (eds), The Uruguay Round and the Developing Countries (Cambridge
University Press, 1996), pp. 88–124.
115
R. Adlung, P. Morrison, M. Roy et al., ‘FOG in GATS Commitments: Boon or Bane’,
World Trade Organization: Staff Working Paper, ERSD-2011-04 (March 2011),
pp. 10–11.
116
GATS Art. XIV(a).
117
See below Ch. 5, section 5.3.1 (‘Deep integration via ‘incorporation by reference’).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
52 h ist ory
118
A. Deardorff and R. Stern, ‘Enhancing the Benefits for Developing Countries in the Doha
Development Agenda Negotiations’ (Policy Brief No. 1, William Davidson Institute,
University of Michigan Business School, 2003), pp. 5–6.
119
As a targeted example of this base level of harmonization on patents, consider the fact
that TRIPS mandates that ‘[t]he term of protection available shall not end before the
expiration of a period of twenty years counted from the filing date’ (TRIPS Art. 33).
120
M. Trebilcock and R. Howse, ‘Trade Liberalisation and Regulatory Diversity:
Reconciling Competitive Markets with Competitive Politics’ (1998) 6 European
Journal of Law and Economics 5, 18–21.
121
See below section 2.4 (‘Activation, engagement and recalibration: the 2000s’).
122
Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade, Annex 1A, Marrakesh Agreement
Establishing the World Trade Organization, 15 April 1994, Final Act Embodying the
Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations.
123
Agreement on Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures, Annex 1A, Marrakesh Agreement
Establishing the World Trade Organization, 15 April 1994, Final Act Embodying the
Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations.
124
Ibid., Art. 2.2.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
ex pa nsion: the 1 980s to the l at e 1 990 s 53
125
DSU Art. 16(4). 126 DSU Art. 17(6).
127
M. Minor, ‘The Demise of Expropriation as an Instrument of LDC Policy 1980–1992’
(1994) 25 Journal of International Business Studies 177.
128
Trebilcock and Howse, The Regulation of International Trade, pp. 486–487.
129
These countries, however, did not simply adopt policies of unconstrained market
liberalization, but also offered a range of targeted industrial policies, including export
incentives to specific firms (Trebilcock and Howse, The Regulation of International
Trade, p. 488).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
54 h ist ory
The net effect of these trends was the emergence of ‘a consensus in the
developing world about the desirability of attracting foreign investment
through free market policies’.130 This is illustrated firstly and sharply by
the direction of changes in domestic laws. States take unilateral steps to
liberalize domestic restrictions on the entry and operation of foreign
investment throughout the 1990s. Between 1991 and 2006, out of 2,533
national legal and regulatory changes relevant to foreign investment, 91
per cent were in the direction of making the host country more favour-
able for FDI.131 This trend encompassed widespread expansion in prac-
tices of positive discrimination, as both developed and developing states
offered locational incentives to attract foreign capital into their jurisdic-
tions.132 Even for those developing states that remained skeptical of the
market model, the harsh structural adjustment policies imposed on them
by international financial institutions left many with little alternative but
to liberalize their domestic economies.133
The constellation of these various factors drove explosive growth in
investment treaty-making throughout the 1990s. States parties had con-
cluded a relatively modest 385 BITs in the thirty years from 1959 to
1989.134 In comparison, 1,857 BITs were concluded in the next ten
years.135 With this dramatic expansion of the BIT network, José
Alvarez has argued that ‘[t]he 1990s, not the 1980s and certainly not
the 1970s, were the era when the modern investment regime was
born’.136 Interestingly, we find stability in the underlying form and
structure of treaty making as the basic features and content of the classic
BIT model continue to be replicated in this fertile growth period.137
Despite this replication, there are now nuanced shifts when it comes to
130
K. Vandevelde, ‘Sustainable Liberalism and the International Investment Regime’ (1998)
19 Michigan Journal of International Law 373, 390.
131
L. Sachs and K. Sauvant, ‘BITs, DTTs and FDI Flows: An Overview’ in K. Sauvant and
L. Sachs (eds), The Effect of Treaties on Foreign Direct Investment: Bilateral Investment
Treaties, Double Taxation Treaties and Investment Flows (Oxford University Press,
2009), p. xlix.
132
UNCTAD, Incentives and Foreign Direct Investment (United Nations, 1996).
133
R. Gilpin, Global Political Economy: Understanding the International Economic Order
(Princeton University Press, 2001), pp. 313–317; J. Bhagwati, ‘The Capital Myth: The
Difference between Trade in Widgets and Dollars’ (1998) 77 Foreign Affairs 11, 11–12.
134
UNCTAD, Bilateral Investment Treaties 1959–1999 (United Nations, 2000), p. 1.
135
UNCTAD, BITs 1959–1999.
136
J. Alvarez, ‘The Once and Future Foreign Investment Regime’ in M. Arsanjani,
J. K. Cogan, R. D. Sloane et al. (eds), Looking to the Future: Essays on International
Law in Honor of W. Michael Reisman (Brill, 2010), p. 15.
137
Alvarez, ‘The Once and Future Foreign Investment Regime’, p. 20.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
ex pa nsion: the 1 980s to the l at e 1 990 s 55
the justifications for states parties to enter into BITs during this period
which begin to parallel the long-standing economic rationale for the
discipline of key trade barriers in the GATT and later the WTO.
The negotiation of every IIA is not only an international event, but also a
manifestation of the domestic political economy of the signatory coun-
tries. In this regard, it is important to recognize that over the last two
decades, most developing economies have undertaken deep and signifi-
cant economic reform that has generated complex political and social
dynamics within their own borders. The negotiation of IIAs is then, to a
great extent, the result of such domestic dynamics.139
138
UNCTAD, World Investment Report 1999 (United Nations, 1999), p. 21.
139
R. Echandi, ‘What Do Developing Countries Expect from the International Investment
Regime?’ in J. Alvarez, K. P. Sauvant, K. G. Ahmed et al. (eds), The Evolving International
Investment Regime: Expectations, Realities, Options (Oxford University Press, 2011), p. 6.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
56 h ist ory
140
Echandi, ‘What Do Developing Countries Expect?’, p. 13.
141
C. Marichal, A Century of Debt Crises in Latin America (Princeton University Press,
1989).
142
Newcombe and Paradell, Law and Practice of Investment Treaties, pp. 8–14.
143
P. Blustein, And the Money Kept Rolling In (and Out): Wall Street, the IMF and the
Bankrupting of Argentina (Public Affairs, 2005), p. 23.
144
Blustein, And the Money Kept Rolling In, p. 24.
145
Blustein, And the Money Kept Rolling In, p. 24.
146
LG&E Energy Corp. and others v. Argentina, Decision on Liability (ICSID Case No. ARB/
02/1, 3 October 2006), para. 49.
147
Z. Elkins, A. Guzman and B. Simmons, ‘Competing for Capital: The Diffusion of
Bilateral Investment Treaties 1969–2000’ (2006) 60 International Organization 811,
821 (Fig. 5).
148
UNCTAD, BITs 1959–1999, pp. 26–27.
149
Elkins et al., ‘Competing for Capital’, 821 (Fig. 5).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
exp ansion: the 1 980s to the l at e 1 990 s 57
of market building following the end of the Cold War.150 Similar patterns on
BIT signings are evident throughout a range of other Central and Eastern
European states, including Albania,151 Armenia,152 Belarus,153 Latvia,154
Lithuania155 and Slovakia.156 For many Central and Eastern European
states, the signal represented by the BIT was also aimed at select supra-
national institutions and their member states. Most of their BITs were
concluded with members of the European Union, as part of a strategy of
using BITs to signal the depth of their commitment to market structures
and thereby facilitate accession into the European Union.157 For these states,
investment treaties offered an established external and therefore legitimate
normative standard for the transition to a market-based economy.
Outside of Europe and Latin America, there are equivalent stories in
the investment treaty practice of both South Africa and India. South
Africa’s first BIT was signed in late 1994, immediately after the first
universal elections were held in that country.158 A review by the South
African Department of Trade and Industry of the South African BIT
program described the decision to enter into BITs as ‘within the broader
mandate of the [Republic of South Africa] to attract FDI and open up its
economy, post-democracy’.159 For much of the post-Second World War
150
The Czech Republic’s first BIT was signed in 1992 and by the end of 1999, the Czech
Republic had signed a total of fifty-two BITs. The Russian Federation’s first BIT was
signed in 1989 with Finland. By the end of 1999, the Russian Federation had signed fifty-
two BITs. UNCTAD, BITs 1959–1999, pp. 45–46, 96–98.
151
Albania’s first BIT was signed with Greece in 1991. By the end of 1999, it had signed a
total of twenty-nine BITs. UNCTAD, BITs 1959–1999, pp. 25–26.
152
Armenia’s first BIT was signed with China in 1992. By the end of 1999, it had signed a
total of twenty-one BITs. UNCTAD, BITs 1959–1999, pp. 27–28.
153
Belarus’ first BIT was signed with Poland in 1992. By the end of 1999, it had signed a total
of twenty-seven BITs. UNCTAD, BITs 1959–1999, p. 31.
154
Latvia’s first BIT was signed with Finland in 1992. By the end of 1999, it had signed a total
of thirty-five BITs. UNCTAD, BITs 1959–1999, pp. 75–76.
155
Lithuania’s first BIT was signed with Germany in 1992. By the end of 1999, it had signed
a total of thirty-six BITs. UNCTAD, BITs 1959–1999, pp. 77–78.
156
Slovakia’s first BIT was signed in 1992. By the end of 1999, Slovakia had signed a total of
twenty BITs. UNCTAD, BITs 1959–1999, p. 100.
157
The Czech Republic is a case in point. Following the Velvet Revolution in 1989, the
Czech Republic concluded BITs with every member of the European Union by 2002.
Eastern Sugar BV v. The Czech Republic, Partial Award (UNCITRAL Ad Hoc
Arbitration, SCC No. 088/2004, 27 March 2007), paras. 1–2 (statistics on BIT use by
the Czech Republic); 235–247 (detailing the Czech Republic’s implementation of EU
agricultural quotas in the lead up to accession to the Union).
158
UNCTAD, BITs 1959–1999, pp. 101–102.
159
Republic of South Africa (Department of Trade and Industry), Bilateral Investment
Treaty Framework Review: Government Position Paper (2009), p. 15.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
58 h ist ory
160
B. DeLong, ‘India Since Independence: An Analytic Growth Narrative’ in D. Rodrik
(ed.), In Search of Prosperity: Analytic Narratives of Economic Growth (Princeton
University Press, 2003).
161
India’s first BIT was signed with the United Kingdom in 1994. By the end of 1999, it had
signed a total of thirty-five BITs. UNCTAD, BITs 1959–1999, p. 64.
162
Sachs and Sauvant, ‘BITs, DTTs and FDI Flows’, p. xxxv.
163
UNCTAD, International Investment Agreements Navigator (http://investmentpolicy-
hub.unctad.org, accessed 23 December 2014).
164
S. Schill, ‘Tearing Down the Great Wall: The New Generation Investment Treaties of the
People’s Republic of China’ (2007) 15 Cardozo Journal of International and Comparative
Law 73, 78–81.
165
Schill, ‘Tearing Down the Great Wall’, 82.
166
Schill, ‘Tearing Down the Great Wall’, 94–97.
167
Schill, ‘Tearing Down the Great Wall’, 89–91.
168
Agreement on the Mutual Protection of Investment, Sweden–PRC, 29 March 1982, Art. 2(1).
169
Sweden–PRC Agreement, Art. 2(2).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
e x p a n s i o n : t he 1 9 8 0 s t o th e l a t e 1 9 90 s 59
170
Sweden–PRC Agreement, Art. 3. 171 Sweden–PRC Agreement, Art. 6.
172
Agreement between the Government of the People’s Republic of China and the
Government of the Kingdom of Norway on the Mutual Protection of Investments,
Norway–PRC, 21 November 1984.
173
Agreement between the Government of the People’s Republic of China and the Belgian-
Luxembourg Economic Union on the Reciprocal Promotion and Protection of
Investments, Belg.–Lux.–PRC, 4 June 1984.
174
Belg.–Lux.–PRC Agreement, Art. 10(3).
175
Q. Kong, ‘Bilateral Investment Treaties: The Chinese Approach and Practice’ (1998–99)
8 Asian Yearbook of International Law 105, 124; W. Shan, ‘National Treatment for
Foreign Investment Enterprises and the Conditions for Its Implementation’ (1998) 5
Social Sciences in China 128, 132.
176
L. Lau, Y. Qian and G. Roland, ‘Reform without Losers: An Interpretation of China’s Dual-
Track Approach to Transition’ (2000) 108(1) Journal of Political Economy 120, 120–143.
177
J. Zhou, ‘National Treatment in Foreign Investment Law: A Comparative Study from A
Chinese Perspective’ (2000) 10 Touro International Law Review 39, 48–114.
178
Schill, ‘Tearing Down the Great Wall’, 100.
179
Agreement on the Encouragement and Reciprocal Protection of Investments between
the Government of the Republic of Korea and the Government of the People’s Republic
of China, Korea–PRC, 30 September 1992, Art. 4.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
60 his tor y
The BIT program’s basic aims are to: 1) protect U.S. investment abroad
in those countries where U.S. investors’ rights are not protected
through existing agreements; 2) encourage adoption of market-orien-
tated domestic policies that treat private investment fairly; and 3) sup-
port the development of international law standards consistent with
these objectives.183
Lang then went on to outline the ‘six basic guarantees found in U.S. BITs’,
beginning with national and most-favoured-nation treatment:
First, our BITs ensure that host governments treat U.S. companies as
favorably as their competitors. U.S. investors receive the better of national
or most favored national (MFN) treatment both when they seek to initiate
investment and throughout the life of the investment, subject to certain
limited and specifically described exceptions listed in annexes or protocols
to the treaties.184
180
Schill, ‘Tearing Down the Great Wall’, 91–94; 97–100.
181
T. Büthe and H. Milner, ‘Bilateral Investment Treaties and Foreign Direct Investment: A
Political Analysis’ in Sauvant and Sachs (eds), The Effect of Treaties on Foreign Direct
Investment, p. 211.
182
Büthe and Milner, ‘BITs and FDI’, pp. 211–212.
183
J. Lang, ‘Keynote Address’ (1998) 31 Cornell Journal of International Law 455, 457
(emphasis added).
184
Lang, ‘Keynote Address’, 457 (emphasis added).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
exp ansion: the 1 980s to the l at e 1 990 s 61
There is a close and logical connection between Lang’s second basic aim
of US BITs (to encourage adoption of ‘market-orientated domestic poli-
cies’) and his description of the fundamental role of national treatment
(to ensure US companies are treated as favourably as their domestic
‘competitors’). Lang’s outline of the market-supporting goals of the US
BIT program is also formally reflected in the background documents of
US investment treaties.185
We have, then, a distinct evolution in the function of investment
treaties from their beginnings in the post-Second World War period. It
is historically incorrect to describe BITs in this fertile period as instru-
ments designed to only achieve investment protection.186 There is now
an important shared functionality with the law of the GATT and now
WTO. The explosion in numbers of BITs from the late 1980s to the early
1990s reflects a growing consensus on the value of a liberal market model
and developing states are using entry into BITs to communicate their
commitment to the strict economic transitions of the post-Cold War
period. Viewed in this light, the replication without amendment of the
classic BIT model in this period is unsurprising. The stringency of that
model reflects the depth of policy realignment undertaken by, or imposed
on, those states in this period. As we have seen, the use of BITs to support
market structures in developing states is also a key strategy of developed
states in this period. This historical and analytical account is to some
degree predicated on a dyadic treaty structure that couples a developed
state-capital exporter with a developing state-capital importer, with the
latter facing a significant reputational deficit vis-à-vis prospective foreign
investment. Yet the growth period of the late 1980s to early 1990s
also witnessed the inception of a triadic structure with a very different
grouping of states parties.
185
Investment Treaty with Albania, US-Albania, 11 January 1995, S. Treaty Doc. No.
104–19 (1995). (In the Message from the President of the United States Transmitting
the Treaty between the Government of the United States of America and the
Government of the Republic of Albania Concerning the Encouragement and
Reciprocal Protection of Investment with Annex and Protocol Signed at Washington
on 11 January 1995 to the US Senate for ratification, President Clinton stated: ‘The
bilateral investment treaty (BIT) with Albania will protect US investment and assist the
Republic of Albania in its efforts to develop its economy by creating conditions more
favourable for US private investment and thus strengthen the development of its private
sector.’)
186
Cf. N. DiMascio and J. Pauwelyn, ‘Non-Discrimination in Trade and Investment
Treaties: Worlds Apart or Two Sides of the Same Coin?’ ’ (2008) 102(1) American
Journal of International Law 48, 53–56 (distinguishing between the goals of the GATT
(liberalization) and BITs (protection)).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
62 h ist ory
187
On CUSFTA, see M. Kinnear, A. Bjorklund and J. Hannaford, Investment Disputes under
NAFTA: An Annotated guide to NAFTA Chapter 11 (Kluwer, 2006), General Section 30.
188
NAFTA Ch. 20. 189 NAFTA Ch. 11, s. B.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
e x p a n s i o n : t he 1 9 8 0 s t o t he l a t e 1 9 9 0s 63
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
64 hi sto ry
2.3.2.3
The ill-fated draft OECD Multilateral Agreement
on Investment
In 1995, two years after the finalization of the NAFTA, the member states
of the Organisation for Co-operation and Development (OECD) com-
menced negotiations towards a Multilateral Agreement on Investment
presidential nominee, said in 2002, ‘not a single word was uttered in discussing
Chapter 11. Why? Because we didn’t know how this provision would play out. No one
really knew just how high the stakes would get’).
195
S. Ratner, ‘Regulatory Takings in Institutional Context: Beyond the Fear of Fragmented
International Law’ (2008) 102 American Journal of International Law 475, 513.
196
J. Stiglitz, The Roaring Nineties: A New History of the World’s Most Prosperous Decade
(Norton, 2003), p. 91.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
e x p a n s i o n : t he 1 9 8 0 s t o t he l a t e 1 9 9 0s 65
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
66 hi stor y
consideration of all relevant circumstances, including those relating to a
foreign investor and its investments, in deciding to which domestic or
third country investors, and investments they should appropriately be
compared.202
We have, then, the first potent sign of dissatisfaction with the classic
BIT model, as well as an attempt to rebalance its terms. That rebalan-
cing process extends not only to absolute standards of protection
(including those directed against expropriatory behaviour), but also
to the assumed softer and easier norm of national treatment. Notably,
it directly opposes a broad reading of national treatment, that disparate
adverse impact suffered by foreign investor is a sufficient condition of
breach. A disparate impact approach of this sort, which paradoxically
finds hard reflection in later arbitral cases, would prove corrosive to
many instances of legitimate regulatory intervention.203 These belated
attempts to strike a sustainable balance between investment protection
and regulatory autonomy were ultimately insufficient to save the MAI
negotiations. That broader objective, however, eventually begins to find
crystallization – often via the use of new exception provisions directly
modelled on WTO law – in the extensive recalibration of bilateral and
regional investment treaties in the early 2000s.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
a c t i v a t i o n , en g a g e m en t an d r e c a l i b r a ti o n 67
206
See below Ch. 6, section 6.2 (‘Judicial power, politics and legitimization from the GATT
to the WTO’).
207
‘Recommendations and rulings of the [Dispute Settlement Body] cannot add to or
diminish the rights and obligations provided by the covered agreements’ (DSU Art.
3(2)).
208
Japan – Alcohol, Report of the Appellate Body, p. 17.
209
US – Gasoline, Report of the Appellate Body, p. 20.
210
Weiler, ‘The Rule of Lawyers and the Ethos of Diplomats’, 206–207.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
68 h isto ry
branch that formulated the treaty, and thereby shields the Appellate
Body from a charge of expansive judicial activism.
The project of legitimation of WTO dispute settlement is further
evident in the Appellate Body’s sensitive mediation between trade and
other public values. This is visibly on offer in its first decision in US-
Gasoline. While the Appellate Body ultimately struck down the United
States’ gasoline purity regulation, it explicitly acknowledged the legiti-
macy of the American policy objective (being the preservation of clean
air).211 What the Appellate Body faulted was the method by which that
policy was applied, which plainly discriminated against gasoline produ-
cers in Brazil and Venezuela, while putting domestic actors at an advan-
tage.212 The Appellate Body has also sought to mediate between trade and
other values through careful attention to systemic frictions at interna-
tional law. It famously declared in US-Gasoline that the treaty texts of the
WTO are ‘not to be read in clinical isolation from public international
law’.213 And to that end, it has (usually impliedly) engaged the require-
ment under VCLT Article 31(3)(c) that ‘any relevant rules of interna-
tional law applicable in the relations between the parties’ be brought to
bear on interpretation of a WTO treaty text. The US–Shrimp case pre-
sented a charged factual question of whether certain species of sea turtles
constituted an ‘exhaustible’ natural resource for the purpose of an
exemption from treaty obligations in GATT Article XX(g). While the
disputants and third parties conceded this to be the case, the WTO
Appellate Body pointedly went on to rule that this factual position was
confirmed by the very fact that all seven recognized species of sea turtles
were listed as ‘threatened with extinction’ under a dedicated environ-
mental treaty.214 This external dimension has been especially important
in enhancing the legitimacy of adjudication of competing values, by
requiring non-WTO international legal rules to be considered in the
interpretation of WTO treaties.
Looking to the future, the case docket of the WTO also evidences a
growing entanglement of trade and investment issues. Since the early
GATT panel decision in Canada-FIRA, there has been a steady number
of cases assessing the consistency of performance requirements with the
211
United States – Standards for Reformulated and Conventional Gasoline, Report of the
Appellate Body (WT/DS2/AB/R, 29 April 1996), pp. 29–30.
212
US – Gasoline, Report of the Appellate Body, pp. 22–29.
213
US – Gasoline, Report of the Appellate Body, p. 17.
214
United States – Prohibition of Certain Shrimp and Shrimp Products, Report of the
Appellate Body (WT/DS58/AB/R, 12 October 1998), para. 132.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
a c t i v a t i o n , en g a g e m e nt a nd r e c a l i b r a t i o n 69
215
Indonesia – Certain Measures Affecting the Automobile Industry, Panel Report (WT/DS/
54/R, WT/DS554/R, CSD59/R, DS64/R, 23 July 1998); India – Measures Affecting the
Automotive Sector, Report of the Appellate Body (WT/DS146/AB/R, WT/DS175/AB/R,
19 March 2002).
216
Canada – Certain Measures Affecting the Renewable Energy Generation Sector, Canada –
Measures Affecting the Feed-in-Tariff Program (WT/DS412/AB/R, WT/DS426/AB/R, 6
May 2013).
217
Mesa Power Group v. Canada, Notice of Arbitration (UNCITRAL, 4 October 2011).
218
Ministerial Declaration, WTO Doc. WT/MIN(01)/DEC/1 (14 November 2001).
219
On the high cost of medication to treat HIV/AIDS in developing countries, see
S. Hensley, ‘Pfizer Makes Aid Pledge, Breaks Aid Pact’, The Wall Street Journal (12
November 2003), B1.
220
Declaration on the TRIPS Agreement and Public Health, WTO Doc. WT/MIN(01)/DEC/
2 (20 November 2001).
221
Implementation of Paragraph 6 of the Doha Declaration on the TRIPS Agreement and
Public Health – Decision of 30 August 2003, WTO Doc. WT/L/540 (2003); ‘WTO
Countries in Deadlock on TRIPS’ (26 October 2001) 1(43) Inside US Trade 1, 22–23.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
70 h isto ry
222
R. Keohane and J. Nye, ‘Redefining Accountability for Global Governance’ in M. Kahler
and D. Lake (eds), Governance in a Global Economy: Political Authority in Transition
(Princeton University Press, 2003), pp. 409–410.
223
WTO, World Trade Report 2011– The WTO and Preferential Trade Agreements: From
Co-Existence to Coherence (WTO Secretariat, 2011).
224
UNCTAD, Global Value Chains and Development: Investment and Value Added in the
Global Economy (United Nations, 2013); WTO, Trade Patterns and Global Value Chains
in East Asia: From Trade in Goods to Trade in Tasks (WTO Secretariat, 2011).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
activa tion, e ngagement and recalibration 71
Not surprisingly, this new economic reality has profoundly influenced the
content of bilateral and regional FTAs that now encompass key disciplines
on both trade and investment.225 It would seem almost inconceivable to
retain the old institutional division when confronted with this fundamental
shift in political economy. As aptly described by the WTO Director General
Roberto Azevêdo, ‘a more globalised world rewards policy coherence – and
punishes incoherence’.226 Overlapping treaty coverage has significant
implications for the nature of the growing connection between interna-
tional trade and investment law. The co-mingling of ‘trade’ and ‘invest-
ment’ treaty negotiators within the same institutional context begins, as we
will see later, to produce a more diverse and nuanced set of perspectives on
what investment commitments should contain.
In parallel to the WTO, the onset of the twenty-first century has
marked a significant shift in the operation of the investment treaty
regime. For one thing, several emerging economies (Brazil, China,
India, the Russian Federation and South Africa) have become capital
exporters as well as capital importers. Much of their outward investment
finds destination in other developing countries, frequently within the
same region, leading to sizeable growth in South-South BITs.227 At the
same time, the deep economic reforms undertaken in developing states
(throughout the late 1980s to the 1990s) have had a decidedly mixed track
record in contributing to improvements in living standards.228 This in
turn feeds into a more cautious approach to the conclusion of BITs by
many developing states, some of whom have publicly acknowledged that
they did not realize the full import of investment treaties that they were
signing during the expansion period.229
While WTO dispute settlement had reached critical mass by the late
1990s, it is only by the turn of the century that one can discern rapid
225
D. Steger, ‘International Trade and Investment: Towards a Common Regime?’ in
R. Echandi and P. Sauve (eds), Prospects in International Investment Law and Policy
(Cambridge University Press, 2013), pp. 162–163.
226
WTO News: Speech, ‘Linking up to Trade and Investment Networks Can Help Fast-
Track Growth – Azevêdo’ (15 October 2014).
227
UNCTAD, ‘South-South Investment Agreements Proliferating’, IIA Monitor No. 3
(United Nations, 2007), p. 1.
228
D. Rodrik, ‘The Global Governance of Trade as if Development Really Mattered’ (United
Nations Development Programme, 2001).
229
L. S. Poulsen and D. Vis-Dunbar, ‘Reflections on Pakistan’s Investment Treaty Program
after 50 Years, An Interview with the Former Attorney-General of Pakistan, Makhdoom
Ali Khan’, Investment Treaty News (16 March 2009) (www.investmenttreatynews.org,
accessed 10 September 2010); Republic of South Africa, Bilateral Investment Treaty
Framework Review, p. 5.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
72 h ist ory
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
ac tiva tio n, e ngag ement and r ec alib ra tion 73
certainly did not always engage the paradigmatic concern of direct taking
of property motivated by entrenched hostility to foreign capital. Instead,
what was often at issue was general regulation passed by a member state
for ostensibly legitimate objectives that had caused some consequential
loss to a foreign investor. In 2005, for example, a Canadian producer of
methanol challenged a Californian environmental ban on a methanol-
based gasoline oxygenate passed after extensive scientific inquiry.236 The
claimant put forward a range of broad legal readings and speculative
allegations of corruption in the Californian regulatory process.237 Cases
such as this have highlighted problematic absences in the classic invest-
ment treaty model. Older investment treaties (and their successors such
as NAFTA Chapter 11) contain no GATT Article XX-type environmen-
tal exception. Had the NAFTA project been marked by a sense of balance
at its inception measured by the inclusion of such an exception, this sort
of aggressive case may never have arisen.
Aside from the speculative nature of some of these early challenges, the
reasoning adopted by arbitral tribunals often reflected a blunt pro-
investor tendency, crudely in line with the ethos of earlier periods and
mirroring GATT-era hermeneutics. This certainly stands in vivid con-
trast with the careful interpretative practices of the Appellate Body and
has greatly contributed to the slow erosion of state commitment to the
investment treaty regime. Take, for example, the default notion expressed
in the 2004 ICSID Tribunal in the SGS v. Philippines that ‘[t]he BIT is a
treaty for the promotion and reciprocal protection of investments . . . [i]t
is legitimate to resolve uncertainties in its interpretation so as to favour
the protection of covered investments’.238 Pro-investor readings have led
to an understandable concern that host states will be found liable even
when regulating in the public interest and without hostile intent. In the
2004 Occidental v. Ecuador award, an Ecuadorian tax was found to have
breached a BIT obligation of national treatment even though the
Ecuadorian tax authority was characterized as a ‘professional service’
that had acted without the express purpose of discriminating against
the foreign investor.239 Perhaps most significantly, there are the multiple
236
Methanex v. US, Final Award.
237
Methanex v. US, Final Award, Pt II, Ch. I, p. 29 (criticizing the investor’s conduct of the
case as having ‘offended basic principles of justice and fairness required of all parties in
every international arbitration’).
238
SGS Société Générale de Surveillance v. Republic of the Philippines, Decision on
Jurisdiction (ICSID Case No. ARB/01/13, 29 January 2004), para. 116.
239
Occidental v. Ecuador, Final Award, para. 177.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
74 h ist ory
240
See below Ch. 5, section 5.3.3.1 (‘Methodologies of conflation’).
241
J. Salacuse, The Law of Investment Treaties (Oxford University Press, 2010), pp. 110–111.
242
For a comprehensive and recent overview of the principal empirical studies, see
J. Yackee, ‘Do Bilateral Investment Treaties Promote Foreign Direct Investment? Some
Hints from Alternative Evidence’ (2010) 51 Virginia Journal of International Law
405–414. For one of the latest studies in this abundant stream of secondary literature
(which post-dates Yackee’s summary), see T. Allee and C. Peinhardt, ‘Contingent
Credibility: The Impact of Investment Treaty Violations on Foreign Direct
Investment’ (2011) 63 International Organization 401, 401–432.
243
A. Berger, M. Busse, P. Nunnenkamp et al., ‘Do Trade and Investment Agreements Lead
to More FDI? Accounting for Key Provisions Inside the Black Box’ (2013) 10
International Economics and Economic Policy 247, 268.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
ac tiva tio n, e ngag ement and r ec alib ra tion 75
back the expansive protections offered by the classic BIT model. There has
been targeted intervention within older treaties such as the NAFTA, where
the member states have invoked the authority of the inter-governmental
Free Trade Commission (FTC) to make binding interpretations of
Chapter 11.244 During the course of the Pope & Talbot arbitration,245 the
FTC issued a ruling designed to override the broad reading on the fair and
equitable standard adopted in the first part of that award.246 Recalibration
has also manifested itself in a range of prospective changes by states parties
to newer investment treaties. In 2004, the United States revised its Model
BIT to include a new annex on expropriation that has since been replicated
in the investment chapters of various free trade agreements.247 This annex
directly counters parts of the early NAFTA jurisprudence such as
Metalclad v. Mexico that had adopted expansive and flawed readings of
the broad guarantee against indirect expropriation.248 These newer treaty
standards offer greater elaboration on the precise conditions by which
general regulation would be sanctioned as indirect expropriation.249 WTO
law has pride of place in this complex strategy of recalibration of invest-
ment treaties. The post-Doha right of states to issue compulsory licences
over patent rights for public health purposes is now classically shielded
from investment treaty challenge.250 We also now have an especially
striking departure from earlier periods as select newer instruments contain
substantive and binding exceptions for host state conduct modelled on
WTO law. We saw earlier that Canada is a strong proponent of such
flexibilities, with similar exceptions in the treaty practice of Japan,
Australia and the ASEAN states.251 The United States, on the other
244
NAFTA Art. 1131(2).
245
The Pope & Talbot Tribunal issued its award on the merits on 10 April 2001. Pope &
Talbot v. Canada, Award on the Merits of Phase 2 (UNCITRAL, 2 April 2011). The FTC
Interpretation was released on 31 July 2001 before the Pope & Talbot Tribunal had ruled
on the damages component of the dispute.
246
NAFTA FTC, Notes of Interpretation of Certain Chapter 11 Provisions, Pts B(1)–(2).
247
2004 US Model BIT, Annex B(4).
248
Metalclad Corp. v. Mexico, Award (ICSID Case No. ARB(AF)/97/1, 30 August 2000),
para. 111; P. Sands, Lawless World: America and the Making and Breaking of Global Rules
(Allen Lane, 2005), pp. 136–138.
249
Contrary to the blunt approach in Metalclad, the purpose of the governmental action is
now central in delineating expropriatory behaviour from legitimate regulation. The
‘character of the government action’ is a mandatory factor to be considered along with
its ‘economic impact’ and interference with ‘reasonable investment-backed expectations’
in determining whether a regulatory measure could constitute an indirect expropriation.
2004 US Model BIT, Annex B(4).
250
2004 US Model BIT, Art. 6(5).
251
See above Ch. 1, section 1.3 (‘Five convergence factors’).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
76 h ist ory
hand, has resisted broad-scale exemption of this sort. Yet it too includes
specific carve-outs for select obligations such as indirect expropriation.252
Moreover, in the aftermath of the investor-state challenges brought against
Argentina, the United States amended its model BIT to ensure that
invocation of the treaty exception for ‘essential security interests’ becomes
a matter of competence for signatory states alone.253 Even for the United
States, there are clear signs of the influence of the WTO model in its
recalibration strategy. On systemic reform, the United States and other
countries (such as Australia) have publicly signalled a desire to parallel
institutional developments in the WTO by requiring its treaty partners to
begin negotiations on the establishing of an appellate mechanism for
investor-state arbitration.254
The project of recalibration is not entirely a stable one of only effecting
technical amendment to the treaty instruments. It has also manifested
itself in selective forms of exit by states from the investment treaty
system. This again tends to track the episodic experience of particular
states as respondents in investor-state adjudication, highlighting the
critical importance of a jurisprudential system that builds and engenders
state confidence in international law constraints. Part of the challenge
here is to construct an adjudicatory system that carefully and sustainably
mediates between investment protection and other public policy goals. In
2007, Bolivia withdrew entirely from the ICSID255 following an adverse
ruling on jurisdiction in a highly sensitive case concerning the privatiza-
tion of the water system in Bolivia’s third largest city.256 Ecuador, the
respondent state to the Occidental award, originally planned to only
withdraw its consent to ICSID arbitration over specific disputes on
investments in natural resources.257 By 2009, however, Ecuador had
followed Bolivia’s lead and submitted a full denunciation of its ICSID
membership.258 Ecuador has further initiated termination of its BITs,
252
2004 US Model BIT, Annex B(4)(b). 253 2004 US Model BIT, Art. 13.
254
2004 US Model BIT, Annex D.
255
ICSID News Release, ‘Bolivia Submits Notice of Denunciation under Article 71 of the
ICSID Convention’ (16 May 2007) (http://icsid.worldbank.org, accessed 1 March 2009).
256
Aguas del Tunari, SA v. Republic of Bolivia, Decision on Jurisdiction (ICSID Case No.
ARB/02/3, 21 October 2005). On the sensitivities of this case, see G. Palast, ‘New British
Empire of the Damned: Bolivia’s Water Supply is the Latest Acquisition of Thirsty
British Firms in the Service of Uncle Sam’, The Observer (23 April 2000).
257
ICSID News Release, ‘Ecuador’s Notification under Article 25(4) of the ICSID
Convention’ (5 December 2007) (http://icsid.worldbank.org, accessed 1 March 2009).
258
ICSID, ‘List of Contracting States and Other Signatories to the ICSID Convention’
(http://icsid.worldbank.org, accessed 18 December 2010).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
co nc lusion 77
2.5 Conclusion
We have seen that the earliest stages of treaty-based international eco-
nomic law disciplines (throughout the nineteenth century) were char-
acterized by unified coverage of trade and investment issues. This logical
orientation is separated by the ‘inception’ of modern trade and invest-
ment rules by the mid twentieth century. The GATT as an instrument of
trade liberalization became constituted on a multilateral basis with BITs
designed more to protect foreign investors against growing hostility in
transition and newly independent states. The political and development
causes of hostility to foreign investment were always temporally limited
and/or contingent on outcomes. By the late 1980s, most of these factors
had eroded, with both systems rapidly ‘expanding’, driven by growing
commitment (whether voluntarily or imposed) to the benefits of a liberal
economic model. Critically, here, the functionality of investment treaties
259
UNCTAD, ‘Denunciation of the ICSID Convention and BITs: Impact on Investor-State
Claims’, IIA Issues Note 1 (United Nations, 2010).
260
Proclamation No. 8788, 77 Fed. Reg. 18, 899 (29 March 2012); C. Rosenberg, ‘The
Intersection of International Trade and International Arbitration: The Use of Trade
Benefits to Secure Compliance with Arbitral Awards’ (2013) 44 Georgetown Journal of
International Law 504, 510–528.
261
Rosenberg, ‘The Intersection of International Trade and International Arbitration’, 524.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002
78 h ist ory
shifts to reconnect with international trade law. Both regimes are now, at
first instance, mechanisms to embed economic transitions and extend
competitive opportunities to foreign traders, service providers and inves-
tors. Yet by the late 1990s, the ‘activation’ of their respective dispute
settlement systems had revealed starkly different pictures. The careful
juridical methods adopted by the new WTO Appellate Body soon gar-
nered growing state confidence in the new dispute settlement structures
of the WTO. The loose and sometimes pro-investor claims of arbitral
tribunals, reminiscent of GATT-era practices, have begun to trigger
distinct levels of state dissatisfaction. The new institutional shift to
FTAs (with common ‘engagement’) is an obvious first vote of state
unease with the single-issue BIT network, while also reflecting a powerful
contemporary economic logic. More fundamentally, that growing dis-
satisfaction manifests itself in a strategic desire to better ‘recalibrate’
investment law disciplines so that they approximate the balanced trade-
offs in the WTO. Two key strategies are clearly at play to achieve this
important goal. There is now logical desire to match individual treaty
provisions with a compelling conceptual case for inclusion being some
underlying theoretical and instrumental justification. Relatedly and cen-
trally, states parties are exploring strategies to achieve a better and more
sophisticated accommodation between investment protection/liberaliza-
tion and competing public values. Here, too, WTO law is placed, as we
will see throughout the remainder of this book, front and centre in that
strategic goal.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. The Librarian-Seeley Historical Library, on 16 Mar 2017 at 12:04:32, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511842115.002