Ch2 Budget
Ch2 Budget
Ch2 Budget
Budget Constraint
Consumption Theory
m /p1 x1
Budget Set and Constraint for
x
Two Commodities
2
Budget constraint is
m /p2
p1x1 + p2x2 = m.
m /p1 x1
Budget Set and Constraint for
x
Two Commodities
2
Budget constraint is
m /p2
p1x1 + p2x2 = m.
Just affordable
m /p1 x1
Budget Set and Constraint for
x
Two Commodities
2
Budget constraint is
m /p2
p1x1 + p2x2 = m.
Not affordable
Just affordable
m /p1 x1
Budget Set and Constraint for
x
Two Commodities
2
Budget constraint is
m /p2
p1x1 + p2x2 = m.
Not affordable
Just affordable
Affordable
m /p1 x1
Budget Set and Constraint for
x
Two Commodities
2
Budget constraint is
m /p2
p1x1 + p2x2 = m.
the collection
of all affordable bundles.
Budget
Set
m /p1 x1
Budget Set and Constraint for
x
Two Commodities
2
p1x1 + p2x2 = m is
m /p2
x2 = -(p1/p2)x1 + m/p2
so slope is -p1/p2.
Budget
Set
m /p1 x1
Budget Constraints
Forn = 2 and x1 on the horizontal
axis, the constraint’s slope is -p1/p2.
What does it mean?
p1 m
x2 = x1
p2 p2
Budget Constraints
Forn = 2 and x1 on the horizontal
axis, the constraint’s slope is -p1/p2.
What does it mean?
p1 m
x2 = x1
p2 p2
Increasing x1 by 1 must reduce x2 by
p1/p2.
Budget Constraints
x2
Slope is -p1/p2
p1/p2
-1
x1
Budget Constraints
x2
Give up one unit of good 1. Buy
extra p1/p2 units of good 2.
p1/p2
-1
x1
Budget Constraints - Example
Suppose prices and income are
measured in dollars. Say p1=$3,
p2=$2, m = $12. Then the constraint
is
3x1 + 2x2 = 12.
Example
x
2
Budget constraint is
12/2
3x1 + 2x2 = 12.
=6
Slope = -3/2
12/3 x1
=4
Budget Sets & Constraints;
Income and Price Changes
The budget constraint and budget
set depend upon prices and income.
What happens as prices or income
change?
How do the budget set and budget
constraint change as income m
x2 increases?
Original
budget set
x1
Higher income gives more choice
x2 New affordable consumption
choices
Original and
new budget
constraints are
parallel (same
Original slope).
budget set
x1
How do the budget set and budget
constraint change as income m
x2 decreases?
Original
budget set
x1
How do the budget set and budget
constraint change as income m
x2 decreases?
Consumption bundles
that are no longer
affordable.
Old and new
New, smaller constraints
budget set are parallel.
x1
Budget Constraints - Income
Changes
Increasesin income m shift the
constraint outward in a parallel
manner, thereby enlarging the
budget set and improving choice.
Budget Constraints - Income
Changes
Increases in income m shift the
constraint outward in a parallel
manner, thereby enlarging the
budget set and improving choice.
Decreases in income m shift the
constraint inward in a parallel
manner, thereby shrinking the
budget set and reducing choice.
Budget Constraints - Income
Changes
No original choice is lost and new
choices are added when income
increases, so higher income cannot
make a consumer worse off.
An income decrease may (typically
will) make the consumer worse off.
Budget Constraints - Price
Changes
What happens if just one price
decreases?
Suppose p1 decreases.
How do the budget set and budget
constraint change as p1 decreases
x2 from p1’ to p1”?
m/p2
-p1’/p2
Original
budget set
m/p1’ m/p1 x1
”
How do the budget set and budget
constraint change as p1 decreases
x2 from p1’ to p1”?
m/p2
New affordable choices
-p1’/p2
Original
budget set
m/p1’ m/p1 x1
”
How do the budget set and budget
constraint change as p1 decreases
x2 from p1’ to p1”?
m/p2
New affordable choices
Budget constraint
-p1’/p2 pivots; slope flattens
from -p1’/p2 to
Original
-p ”/p -p1”/p2
1 2
budget set
m/p1’ m/p1 x1
”
Budget Constraints - Price
Changes
Reducing the price of one
commodity pivots the constraint
outward. No old choice is lost and
new choices are added, so reducing
one price cannot make the consumer
worse off.
Budget Constraints - Price
Changes
Similarly,
increasing one price pivots
the constraint inwards, reduces
choice and may (typically will) make
the consumer worse off.
Shapes of Budget Constraints
Q: What makes a budget constraint a
straight line?
A: A straight line has a constant
slope and the constraint is
p1x1 + … + pnxn = m
so if prices are constants then a
constraint is a straight line.
Shapes of Budget Constraints
But what if prices are not constants?
E.g. bulk buying discounts, or price
penalties for buying “too much”.
Then constraints will be curved.
Shapes of Budget Constraints -
Quantity Discounts
Suppose p2 is constant at $1 but that
p1=$2 for 0 x1 20 and p1=$1 for
x1>20.
Shapes of Budget Constraints -
Quantity Discounts
Suppose p2 is constant at $1 but that
p1=$2 for 0 x1 20 and p1=$1 for
x1>20. Then the constraint’s slope is
- 2, for 0 x1 20
{
-p1/p2 =
- 1, for x1 > 20
and the constraint is
Shapes of Budget Constraints
with a Quantity Discount
x2 m = $100
100 Slope = - 2 / 1 = - 2
(p1=2, p2=1)
Slope = - 1/ 1 = - 1
(p1=1, p2=1)
20 50 80 x1
Shapes of Budget Constraints
with a Quantity Discount
x2 m = $100
100 Slope = - 2 / 1 = - 2
(p1=2, p2=1)
Slope = - 1/ 1 = - 1
(p1=1, p2=1)
20 50 80 x1
Shapes of Budget Constraints
with a Quantity Discount
x2 m = $100
100
Budget Constraint
Budget Set
20 50 80 x1
Shapes of Budget Constraints
with a Quantity Penalty
x2
Budget
Constraint
Budget Set
x1