Brealey - Principles of Corporate Finance - 13e - Chap18 - SM
Brealey - Principles of Corporate Finance - 13e - Chap18 - SM
Brealey - Principles of Corporate Finance - 13e - Chap18 - SM
CHAPTER 18
How Much Should a Corporation Borrow?
The values shown in the solutions may be rounded for display purposes. However, the answers were
derived using a spreadsheet without any intermediate rounding.
1. The calculation assumes that the tax rate is fixed, that debt is fixed and
perpetual, and that investors’ personal tax rates on interest and equity income
are the same.
Est. Time: 01 – 05
c. PV tax shield = TC D
PV tax shield = .30 × $1,000
PV tax shield = $300
Est. Time: 01 – 05
Est. Time: 01 – 05
Copyright © 2019 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written consent of
McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 18 - How Much Should a Corporation Borrow?
Shareholders are paid out $14,325 in exchange for their stock, but then gain an
additional $3,008 in tax shields.
Est. Time: 06 – 10
a.
Capital gains:
b.
Cash dividends:
Relative advantage of debt = .63 / (.80 × .79)
Relative advantage of debt = 0.9968
Est. Time: 01 – 05
6. A firm with no taxable income saves no taxes by borrowing and paying interest.
The interest payments would simply add to its tax-loss carry-forwards. Such a
firm would have little tax incentive to borrow.
Est. Time: 01 – 05
Copyright © 2019 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written consent of
McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 18 - How Much Should a Corporation Borrow?
Total tax = (.21 × $1) + {.5 × .35[$1 – (.21 × $1)]} + {.5 × .15[$1– (.21 × $1)]}
Total tax = $.4075
Difference between the total taxes on debt and the total taxes on equity income
= .4075 – 0.35 = $.0575 higher on equity
Est. Time: 06 – 10
8. Consider a firm that is levered, has perpetual expected cash flow X, and has an
interest rate for debt of rD. The personal and corporate tax rates are Tp and Tc,
respectively. The cash flow to stockholders each year is:
(X - rDD)(1 - Tc)(1 - Tp)
Therefore, the value of the stockholders’ position is:
( X ) (1 − T c ) (1 − T p ) (r D ) ( D ) (1 − T c ) (1 − T p )
VL = −
(r ) (1 − T p ) (r D ) (1 − T p )
( X ) (1 − T c ) (1 − T p )
VL = − [( D) (1 − T c )]
(r ) (1 − T p )
The difference in stockholder wealth, for investment in the same assets, is:
VL – VU = DTc
This is the change in stockholder wealth predicted by MM.
If individuals could not deduct interest for personal tax purposes, then:
( X) (1 − T c ) (1 − T p ) (r D )( D)
VU = −
(r ) (1 − T p ) (r D ) (1 − T p )
Then:
(r D ) ( D ) −[ ( r D )( D) (1 − T c ) (1 − T p )]
V L − VU =
(r D ) (1 − T p )
( )
Tp
V L − V U = ( D T c) + D
(1 − T p )
So the value of the shareholders’ position in the levered firm is relatively greater
when no personal interest deduction is allowed.
Est. Time: 11 – 15
Est. Time: 01 – 05
10. Answers here will vary according to the companies chosen; however, the
important considerations are given in Section 18-3 of the text. Costs of financial
distress include bankruptcy costs (direct and indirect), lost customers, and
reduced business risk taking.
Est. Time: 06 – 1
11. a. Direct costs of financial distress are the legal and administrative costs of
bankruptcy. Indirect costs include possible delays in liquidation (Eastern
Airlines) or poor investment or operating decisions while bankruptcy is being
resolved. Also the threat of bankruptcy can lead to costs.
c. See the answer to (b) above. Examples are the “games” described in
Copyright © 2019 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written consent of
McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 18 - How Much Should a Corporation Borrow?
Section 18-3.
Est. Time: 01 – 05
12. a. True.
b. True.
Est. Time: 01 – 05
Market Values
Net working capital $30 $29 Bonds outstanding
Fixed assets 8 9 Common stock
Total assets $38 $38 Total value
Here the shareholder is better off, but has obviously diminished the firm’s
competitive ability.
Copyright © 2019 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written consent of
McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 18 - How Much Should a Corporation Borrow?
Here the value of common stock should have fallen to zero, but the
bondholders bear part of the burden.
Est. Time: 06 – 10
14. a. Stockholders win. Bond value falls since the value of assets securing
the bond has fallen.
c. The bondholders lose. The firm adds assets worth $10 and debt
worth $10. This would increase Circular’s debt ratio, leaving the old
bondholders more exposed. The old bondholders’ loss is the
stockholders’ gain.
d. Both bondholders and stockholders win. They share the (net) increase
in firm value. The bondholders’ position is not eroded by the issue of a
junior security. (We assume that the preferred does not lead to still
more game playing and that the new investment does not make the
firm’s assets safer or riskier.)
Est. Time: 06 – 10
15. a. SOS stockholders could lose if they invest in the positive NPV project and
then SOS becomes bankrupt. Under these conditions, the benefits of the
project accrue to the bondholders.
b. If the new project is sufficiently risky, then, even though it has a negative
NPV, it might increase stockholder wealth by more than the money
invested. This is a result of the fact that, for a very risky investment,
undertaken by a firm with a significant risk of default, stockholders benefit
if a more favorable outcome is actually realized, while the cost of
unfavorable outcomes is borne by bondholders.
Copyright © 2019 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written consent of
McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 18 - How Much Should a Corporation Borrow?
c. Again, think of the extreme case: Suppose SOS pays out all of its assets
as one lump-sum dividend. Stockholders get all of the assets, and the
bondholders are left with nothing. (Note: fraudulent conveyance laws may
prevent this outcome.)
Est. Time: 11 – 15
16. a.
Expected Payoff to Bank Expected Payoff to Ms. Ketchup
Project 1 +10.0 +5
Project 2 (0.4 10) + (0.6 0) = +4.0 (0.4 14) + (0.6 0) = +5.6
Ms. Ketchup would undertake Project 2.
b. Breakeven will occur when Ms. Ketchup’s expected payoff from Project 2
is equal to her expected payoff from Project 1. If X is Ms. Ketchup’s
payment on the loan, then her payoff from Project 2 is:
0.4 (24 – X)
Setting this expression equal to 5 (Ms. Ketchup’s payoff from Project 1),
and solving, we find that: X = 11.5.
Therefore, Ms. Ketchup will borrow less than the present value of this
payment.
Est. Time: 06 – 10
17. a. The bondholders may benefit; the fine print limits actions that transfer
wealth from the bondholders to the stockholders.
Est. Time: 06 – 10
18. More profitable firms have more taxable income to shield and are less likely to
incur the costs of distress. Therefore the trade-off theory predicts high
(book) debt ratios. In practice the more profitable companies borrow the least.
Est. Time: 01 – 05
19. a.
Other things equal, the announcement of a new stock issue to fund an
investment project with an NPV of $40 million should increase equity value by
Copyright © 2019 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written consent of
McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 18 - How Much Should a Corporation Borrow?
$40 million (less issue costs). But, based on past evidence, management
expects equity value to fall by $30 million. There may be several reasons for
the discrepancy:
(i) Investors may have already discounted the proposed investment. (However,
this alone would not explain a fall in equity value.)
(ii) Investors may not be aware of the project at all, but they may believe instead
that cash is required because of, say, low levels of operating cash flow.
(iii) Investors may believe that the firm’s decision to issue equity rather than debt
signals management’s belief that the stock is overvalued.
b.
The fall in value is not an issue cost in the same sense as the underwriter’s
spread. If the stock is indeed overvalued, the stock issue merely brings forward
a stock price decline that will occur eventually anyway. If the stock is not
overvalued, management needs to consider whether it could release some
information to convince investors that its stock is correctly valued, or whether it
could finance the project by an issue of debt.
Est. Time: 11 – 15
20. When a company issues securities, outside investors worry that management
may have unfavorable information. If so the securities can be overpriced. This
worry is much less with debt than equity. Debt securities are safer than equity,
and their price is less affected if unfavorable news comes out later.
Est. Time: 01 – 05
21. a. The firm’s debt ratio is determined by the cumulative requirement for
external financing.
b. Debt ratios depend on past profitability because more profitable firms can
rely more on internal cash flow and need less external financing.
Est. Time: 01 – 05
22. Financial slack is most valuable to growth companies with good but uncertain
investment opportunities. Slack means that financing can be raised quickly for
positive-NPV investments. But too much financial slack can tempt mature
companies to overinvest. Increased borrowing can force such firms to pay out
cash to investors.
Est. Time: 01 – 05
Copyright © 2019 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written consent of
McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 18 - How Much Should a Corporation Borrow?
23. a. True.
c. True.
Est. Time: 01 – 05
24. The four variables are size, tangible assets, profitability, and market-to-book
ratios. Debt ratios tend to be higher for larger firms and those with more tangible
assets. Conversely, more profitable firms and firms with higher market-to-book
values have lower debt ratios.
Est. Time: 01 – 05
25. One advantage of setting debt-equity targets based on bond ratings is that firms
may minimize borrowing costs. This is especially true of bond covenants that
establish lower ratings as a condition of default. One disadvantage is that firms
may not take full advantage of tax benefits from debt financing if they refuse to
borrow amounts they could finance with relative safety.
Est. Time: 06 – 10
26. The right measure in principle is the ratio derived from market-value balance
sheets. Book balance sheets represent historical values for debt and equity,
which can be significantly different from market values. Any changes in capital
structure are made at current market values.
The tradeoff theory proposes to explain market leverage. Increases or
decreases in debt levels take place at market values. For example, a decision to
reduce the likelihood of financial distress by retirement of debt means that
existing debt is acquired at market value and that the resulting decrease in
interest tax shields is based on the market value of the retired debt. Similarly, a
decision to increase interest tax shields by increasing debt requires that new debt
be issued at current market prices.
Similarly, the pecking-order theory is based on market values of debt and equity.
Internal financing from reinvested earnings is equity financing based on current
market values; the alternative to increased internal financing is a distribution of
earnings to shareholders. Debt capacity is measured by the current market
value of debt because the financial markets view the amount of existing debt as
the payment required to pay off that debt.
Est. Time: 11 – 15
Copyright © 2019 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written consent of
McGraw-Hill Education.
Chapter 18 - How Much Should a Corporation Borrow?
27. If it were always possible to issue stock quickly and use the additional proceeds
to repurchase debt, then firms may indeed avoid financial distress. But potential
equity investors may be reluctant to buy stock in a firm if adverse market events
are likely to place the bonds in default: they would effectively be putting money
into a sinking ship and those proceeds would go to repay the senior bond claims
in bankruptcy. This is especially true if the bonds quickly move into default (or if
there are cross-default provisions where one bond series default triggers other
defaults).
In some cases, bondholders may recognize that the firm has greater value as a
going concern and agree to take a haircut on interest payments in exchange for
an equity infusion. Under these circumstances, a firm may indeed be able to
raise additional equity—but the negotiations and gamesmanship of these
workout situations can get tricky.
Est. Time: 06 – 10
Copyright © 2019 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written consent of
McGraw-Hill Education.