Business Relations Between The Low Cost
Business Relations Between The Low Cost
Business Relations Between The Low Cost
aiming at publishing high quality research related to air transport. JATS is interested in
publishing papers primarily focusing on economics, geography, policymaking, management,
marketing, operations, technology, logistics/ supply chain management and modelling.
The Journal is published electronically twice a year, i.e. in January and July by the Hellenic
Aviation Society (www.aviationsociety.gr). The January issue usually contains papers
(subject to changes) originally presented at the Air Transport Research Society
(www.atrsworld.org) Conference of the previous year(s) whereas the July issue may be
occasionally dedicated to a special theme. The Journal is accessible online free-of-charge.
ii
Notes for Contributors
JATS publishes the following categories of papers written in scholarly English: a) Full
Research Papers, b) Conference Reports, c) Book Reviews, d) I ndustry Perspectives.
Papers should be submitted electronically to a.papatheodorou@aegean.gr in MS-Word
format ONLY using British spelling, single-column, 1.5 line spacing, Tahoma letters, font size
11. Section headings (and sub-headings) should be numbered and written in capital letters.
Upon acceptance of a paper and before its publication, the corresponding author will be
asked to sign the Transfer of Copyright form on behalf of all identified authors.
Full Research Papers should contain original research not previously published elsewhere.
They should normally be between 4,000 and 7,000 words although shorter or lengthier
articles could be considered for publication if they are of merit. The first page of the papers
should contain the title and the authors’ affiliations, contact details and brief vitae (of about
50 words). Regarding the following pages, papers should generally have the following
structure: a) title, abstract (of about 150 words) and six keywords, b) introduction, c)
literature review, d) theoretical and/or empirical contribution, e) summary and conclusions, f)
acknowledgements, g) references and h) appendices. Tables, figures and illustrations
should be included within the text (not at the end), bear a title and be numbered
consecutively. Regarding the referencing style, standard academic format should be
consistently followed. Examples are given below:
iii
Conference Reports should be between 1,000 and 1,500 words. They should provide
factual information (e.g. conference venue, details of the conference organizers), present
the various programme sessions and summarize the key research findings.
Book Reviews should be between 1,000 and 1,500 words. They should provide factual
information (e.g. book publisher, number of pages and ISBN, price on the publisher’s
website) and critically discuss the contents of a book mainly in terms of its strengths and
weaknesses.
Industry Perspectives should be up to 1,000 words and provide a practitioner’s point of view
on contemporary developments in the air transport industry. Contributors should explicitly
specify whether their views are espoused by their organization or not.
iv
Table of Contents
EDITORIAL……………………………………………………………………………………………………………….viii
Andreas Papatheodorou, Kostas Iatrou and Zheng Lei
vi
airports. Many central airports had very little flexibility and capacity necessary to
facilitate additional timeslots. As an answer to inadequate capacity combined with
higher taxes and fees, most LCCs have chosen to use secondary or regional airports.
This choice has altered the balance and strategic importance between airports and
increased their importance for air carriers. This paper examines the evolution and
development of LCCs globally, along with the consequences of their expansion to the
traditional carriers, the market and the passengers. Emphasis is given to the
relationship between LCCs and airports which has resulted in an additional increase
in air travel. The prospects of Greece as a market for LCCs are also being discussed.
vii
Editorial
This issue of the Journal of Air Transport Studies includes five papers. Evangelinos,
Stangl and Obermeyer examine peak-load pricing and airline reactions at European
airports. They find that airlines would subsidize price reductions at off-peak times with
price increases during peak times on certain routes, suggesting a peak-load pricing regime
would encourage new competitors to enter the market at off-peak times. Subsequently,
Polydoropoulou, Chortatsiani and Kamargianni consider airline customer satisfaction
and loyalty. The results of the research indicate that the majority of passenger complaints
are not communicated to the airline; this finding has significant implications for customer
loyalty.
In the following contribution, Ben Amor and Bui adopt a complex system approach to
model airspace congestion dynamics. The test scenario shows a phase transition
phenomenon towards the congestion of the European airspace at the resulting traffic
threshold of circa 50,000 flights. Then, Katarelos and Koufodontis provide useful
insights into the business relations between the low-cost carriers and airports in the context
of the air transport deregulation. Finally, Bandeira and Correia explore the relationship
between the profile of departing passengers and their perception of the airport terminal.
The research shows that the check-in counters and the departure lounge are considered to
be the most important areas in the airport terminal by passengers. The age and reason for
travel influence the passengers’ perception about the check-in area, while the frequency of
flying influences the perception of the departure lounge.
May we take this opportunity to thank all our authors and referees for their support in
publishing this fifth issue of our Journal. Our continuing partnership with Air Transport
News in conjunction with the open access character of the journal aim at ensuring that JATS
can get a significant exposure to the academic and business audience and raise its profile
accordingly. Enjoy reading!
viii
PEAK- LOAD PRI CI NG AND AI RLI NE REACTI ONS AT EUROPEAN AI RPORTS
Christos Evangelinosa,
Institute for Transport and Economics, “Friedrich List” Faculty of Transportation Sciences,
Dresden University of Technology, Germany
Jacqueline Stanglb,
Deutsche Flugsicherung GmbH (DFS), Germany
Andy Obermeyer c
Institute for Transport and Economics, “Friedrich List” Faculty of Transportation Sciences,
Dresden University of Technology, Germany
ABSTRACT
Conventional wisdom in the economics of pricing holds that peak-load pricing can enhance
welfare in cases where demand peaks are clearly identifiable and highly predictable.
However, this pricing tool has not found acceptance among airlines in the past. In the very
few cases in which peak-load pricing has been introduced, regulators have faced strong
opposition from airlines. Recent research has focused on whether airlines could pass the
additional costs associated with peak-load pricing on to passengers. Expanding on this work,
this paper assesses how peak-load pricing would impact airline costs and forecasts how
airlines would react to the implementation of a peak-load pricing regime. We use a
simultaneous autoregressive model to predict airline pricing reactions. Our findings indicate
that for certain routes, airlines would subsidize revenue decreases in off-peak times with
price increases during peak times. This finding corroborates the perception held by airlines
that a peak-load pricing regime would encourage new competitors to enter the market at
off-peak times.
Keywords: Price differentiation, peak-load pricing, special interest groups, pricing behaviour,
airline reactions
a
Christos Evangelinos is currently researcher at the Dresden University of Technology’s Institute for
Transport and Economics, where he also studied. His research interests revolve around
infrastructure charging, airline pricing and valuation techniques for transportation relevant topics,
such as travel time, externalities etc. Corresponding author: Christos Evangelinos
(Christ os.Evangelinos@tu-dresden.de), Phone: + 49 351 463 36708. We wish to thank the
anonymous referees for their helpful comments. Any errors remain our responsibility.
b
Jacqueline Stangl is currently working at the DFS Deutsche Flugsicherung GmbH as a team
member of the Operational Requirement Management. Before, she studied Transport Economics at
the Dresden University of Technology. Her research interests focus on Air Transport and Air Traffic
Control. The paper represents her personal views and not those of the DFS.
c
Andy Obermeyer is a research assistant at the Dresden University of Technology’s I nstitute for
Transport and Economics. He studied Transport and Economics in Dresden and at the University of
Kent at Canterbury. His research interests are valuation of travel time savings and airline pricing.
1. I NTRODUCTI ON
Although the global financial crisis has had a negative impact on the aviation sector, one can
assume that a return to stability will lead the long-run growth trends in air transport to
continue. According to I CAO forecasts (2007) the air transport passenger market is expected
to increase at the rate of 4.6 per cent annually (in terms of passenger-kilometres). The
problems associated with managing this growth are even more acute if one considers air
freight, which is expected to expand at 6.6 per cent annually. I n the absence of sufficient
capacity expansion, this demand growth may be counterproductive for air transport. First,
passengers will likely deal with considerable delays. Second, environmental costs are
expected to rise. Third, air carriers will bear additional costs resulting from delays. At present,
several European Airports already face severe capacity problems. A forecast of demand
growth to the year 2025 without additional capacity growth predicts excess demand of
around 3.7 million flights (see EUROCONTROL, 2004, pp. 2-11). In concrete terms, this
means that in year 2025, more than 60 European airports are expected to face severe
capacity problems in their peak hours and at least 20 airports will have to cope with capacity
problems not only during a few peak hours, but around 10 hours per day. In Germany, for
instance, this would translate in a situation in which all six major airports (including Berlin-
Brandenburg International Airport, which is currently under construction) face excess
demand during peak times (see Röhl, 2007, p. 8). In light of these expected supply
bottlenecks, it is highly necessary to introduce capacity management systems that will
mitigate the negative impacts of excess demand.
From an economic perspective, pricing measures are another means of handling excess
demand. Efficient airport pricing is a well analysed topic in the literature. Wolf (2003, pp.
In addition, slot allocation mechanisms, such as auctions or slot trading, are also widely
discussed in the economic literature on scarcity at airports. The current administrative
system in Europe for allocating slots based on grandfather rights is problematic from an
economic perspective, since it does not ensure that slots are allocated to those who value
them most (Menaz & Matthews, 2008). Furthermore, administrative rationing has been
criticised by anti-trust authorities (see Starkie, 1998, p. 113). The auctioning or trading of
slots can, however, generate an efficient (1st Best) outcome as shown, for instance, in
Brueckner (2009), Verheof (2010) and Basso & Zhang (2009). Despite their theoretical
efficiency these mechanisms have been barely applied at all in practice. This might be due to
practical barriers such as the complementary nature of slots or market power concerns (see
Menaz & Matthews, 2008). Furthermore, Forsyth and Niemeier (2008) point out that the
structure of the airport charges is of similar importance as efficient slot allocation processes.
In particular they show that a combination of a slot allocation process and peak-load pricing
can lead to more efficient airport utilisation. In this paper we do not cover the slot allocation
process itself but focus on peak-load pricing instead.
However, pricing measures such as peak-load pricing are extremely difficult to implement.
This is mainly due to lack of acceptance by existing users. Schank (2005, pp. 417-425)
demonstrates that peak-load pricing in Boston and London failed because of lack of
1
For an in-depth treatment of peak-load pricing, see e.g. Crew et al., 1995.
Journal of Air Transport Studies, volume 3, Issue 1, 2012 Page 3
acceptance by user groups, who managed to form effective opposition to the pricing scheme.
In New York, peak-load pricing at La Guardia airport resulted in the relocation of almost all
commuter flights to Teterboro, a regional airport located in New Jersey. These empirical
findings are not only confirmed in individual cases. In general, peak-load pricing is officially
opposed by the IATA (2000, p. 1; Forsyth & Niemeier, 2003, p. 16) based on the argument
of cross-subsidization.
Starkie (2005, p. 6-7) gives the following reasons for the failure to implement efficient
pricing structures:
Ü Second, it is very difficult for airport managers to reject the traditional charging
scheme, which is based on the partly erroneous assumption that aircraft weight
correlates with runway damage;
Ü Third, airlines oppose such pricing instruments, although they use similar pricing
schemes themselves (yield management);
Ü Fourth, airport managers are unwilling to adopt such pricing schemes as they are
thought to undermine capacity expansion efforts, in turn preventing higher
passenger volumes over the long run.
One institutional argument in particular should be pointed out. The nature of the regulatory
regime in place can play an important role for efficient pricing (see Laffont & Tirole, 2000, pp.
66-67). In this regard, Starkie (2005) highlights the possible inefficiencies of price-cap
regulation. According to empirical observations, price-cap regulated airports tend to engage
in capacity expansion programmes rather than implement peak-load pricing. The regulatory
environment may weaken incentives for the adoption of efficient pricing structures. First, in
several cases, airport price-cap regulations have been accompanied by the introduction of
sliding scales. Second, the majority of price-cap regulated airports are subjected to single-till
regulation. Regardless of the specific regulatory conditions, the role of special interest
groups is essential. In other words, carriers (especially legacy carriers) attach high
importance to the prevention of peak-load pricing and to the preservation of the existing
2
pricing scheme. Looking for reasons as to why carriers oppose peak-load pricing,
researchers have focused lately on the impact that peak-load pricing has on airline profits. I n
2
For an overview of positive economic theory in transport infrastructure pricing, see e.g. Knockaert
et al., 2009.
Journal of Air Transport Studies, volume 3, Issue 1, 2012 Page 4
this respect, it is crucial to identify whether airlines can shift additional cost burdens to
passengers or not. Forsyth (2008) notes in this connection that additional costs during peak
times cannot be fully passed on to passengers, at least not in all cases. By contrast, savings
from lower charges at off-peak times can be fully passed through to passengers (due to
competitive pressures), thus resulting in lower air fares. I t is therefore essential to study the
impact of peak-load pricing on airlines’ costs as well as to analyze which business strategies
can help airlines to cope with peak-load pricing. This paper is organized as follows: Section
2 identifies the effects of peak-load pricing on airline costs; section 3 addresses possible user
reactions (including pricing reactions) to peak-load pricing; and section 4 concludes.
I n order to study the effects of peak-load pricing to airline costs, we must first classify airline
costs. Traditionally, the ICAO takes into account only operating costs and leaves out
extraordinary costs. Operating costs can be useful in benchmarking airline cost efficiency,
and, at the same time, reveal differences between airlines. Table 1 shows the main elements
of airline operating costs for international scheduled operations, for US and European airlines.
‚ flight crew
Flight operations 41.7 40.5
‚ cabin staff
Passenger-services 5.6 12.3
Direct operating costs are mainly related to aircraft type and represent almost two third of all
operating costs. Within this cost category, flight operations represent the highest cost
An alternate, highly instructive approach for classifying costs employs the standard notion of
fixed and variable costs and is grounded in the concept of escapability. According to this
concept, costs are classified into three maj or categories:
‚ The first category is costs related to flight hours (flying costs, representing around 30 to
45 per cent of total costs). These include expenditures for fuel, flight personnel, direct
maintenance, passenger services and finally airport and ATM charges. Such expenditures
are mainly related to aircraft use, which means that they are escapable if a flight does
not take place.
‚ The second category is fleet-related standing costs (representing around 25 to 30 per
cent of total costs). These costs are only escapable in the medium term, which is
typically one year. This cost category includes aircraft capital expenditures, wages, as
well as overhead costs for maintenance. These costs correlate positively with the activity
level of the carrier, which means carriers can save on these expenses only by reducing
their activity level.
‚ The third cost category is fixed indirect costs (representing around 25 to 35 per cent of
total costs). These costs are only escapable in the long run, and include expenses for
administration, sales, marketing as well as ground station activities.
This cost classification scheme seems to be more useful for assessing the impact of peak-
load pricing on airline costs. For ultimately, carriers pay close attention to the revenues
generated by each single flight when scheduling their networks. In order to keep a certain
city pair on a flight schedule, it is essential that the flight cover at least flying costs. 3 For this
reason, carriers aim to achieve high load factors. The introduction of peak-load pricing would
therefore cause a shift in the break-even point towards higher load factors in the peak period
3
Due to the fixed nature of schedules, short run marginal costs are very low. Therefore, every
additionally ticket sold makes an additional contribution to cost recovery. Peak-load pricing is,
however, a pricing scheme which cannot be implemented in the short run, but rather in the
medium run. We therefore regard flying costs to be the relevant factor for airlines in decisions
concerning when to schedule flights under a peak-load pricing scheme.
Journal of Air Transport Studies, volume 3, Issue 1, 2012 Page 6
and vice versa in the off-peak period, since peak-load pricing raises costs for the airline in
the peak period and reduces them in the off-peak period.
However, the additional cost burdens of peak-load pricing will impact carriers in different
ways. To evaluate these impacts, we must therefore begin by differentiating air carriers
according to the following criteria:
1. the degree of slot scarcity faced by the carrier at the airport in question;
The degree of slot scarcity is the first criterion that can have a decisive impact on the level of
peak-load pricing.4 As excess demand at peak times varies at different airports, the amount
of the charge during the peak period will vary respectively. 5 We therefore conclude that
carriers using an airport as their home base that is slot congested at certain times of day will
bear greater financial burdens than other carriers. In addition, when comparing two airports
that both have excess demand in the peak period, we conclude that the carrier at the airport
with higher peak demand will have to pay more for airport charges if peak-load pricing is
implemented. Finally, due to the cost relatedness of the pricing scheme, airport cost
efficiency can result in cost differences for carriers even if airports have similar slot scarcity.
The second criterion is the share of airport charges as a percentage of airline operating costs.
As shown in table 1, airport charges (including ATM charges) represent 9.8 per cent of total
operating costs. This figure is an average value and reflects predominantly the cost situation
of an international carrier. Depending on geographical factors and the carrier’s business
model, this cost share can increase up to 20 per cent. First, airport-charges cost share
increases for short-haul flight operations and decreases for long-haul operations.6 Therefore,
if a carrier offers predominantly short-haul flights, it is expected that the airport-charges cost
share will rise for operating decisions and vice versa. Second, airport charges are the
dominating factor when low-cost carriers decide whether a destination will be served or not.
4
We regard in this case only airports at which peak-load pricing can bring desirable results. This
does not include airports without any capacity problems, or airports with permanent excess
demand.
5
We note in this case that the form of regulation in place can be a serious barrier to the
implementation of peak-load pricing. There are also many cases in which peak-load pricing could
lead to huge profits. Regulatory regimes aiming at cost recovery would prevent the implementation
of peak-load pricing.
6
For the short-haul operations of British Midland and KLM UK, the airport-charge cost shares in
1999 were 15 and 23.4 per cent, respectively (see Doganis, 2002, p. 146).
Journal of Air Transport Studies, volume 3, Issue 1, 2012 Page 7
Third, despite the internationally similar tariff structure (two-part tariff), the charge level
varies immensely from airport to airport. Table 2 shows these differences for a standard
aircraft type.
As depicted in table 2, the implementation of peak-load pricing at a high cost airport like
Paris CDG or Vienna would burden carriers operating from these airports more than others.
In addition to table 2, US carriers have lower airport-charge cost shares (currently 2.2
percent of total operating costs, see ATA, 2010). The reason for this is twofold: First, carriers
in the US often operate their own terminals. Second, parts of airport charges are paid
directly by passengers. I n this way, US carriers currently have a cost advantage compared to
European carriers.
Table 2: Representative Airport Charges for a B747- 400 with 395t MTOW, 335
passengers and 3h parking time for w inter 2010/ 11, in USD
Charge in US $
Ratio of the
Total Charge
Airport Weight based Passenger based Components
The third criterion is the extent to which the peak-load pricing scheme is applied. As table 2
shows, the degree of variability – that is, the ratio between the fixed (aircraft-related) and
variable (passenger-related) components of the charge – fluctuates significantly between
airports. Although lately a shift towards greater variability has occurred, European airports
still charge a certain fixed amount based on aircraft MTOW. Applying peak-load pricing only
to the fixed cost component would severely discourage full-service carriers (FSCs) from
In spite of the fixed nature of airport charges over the short run, airlines have certain
opportunities for countering their impact on cost structures. Over the medium-term carriers
can implement various strategies to steer direct and indirect operating costs, thus allowing
the impact of additional peak-load expenses to be mitigated. In this regard, we draw a
distinction between operational measures (such as the choice of aircraft size and location
effects) and pricing measures. In particular, we discuss how airlines can evaluate the best
strategies to implement.
From the regulator’s point of view, one of the desirable airline reactions would be the use of
larger aircraft 7 combined with a reduction in flight frequency during peak periods. Aircraft
size is an important determinant of unit costs per passenger, because it has a direct
influence on operational costs and hourly productivity. Cost advantages are achieved with
larger aircraft due to several factors; aerodynamic benefits and larger, more efficient engines,
for example, reduce fuel consumption per weight unit. Furthermore, a larger aircraft also
leads to higher labour productivity. Thus, costs per seat-kilometre decrease with increasing
aircraft size. Figure 1 illustrates this interrelation.
The average cost curve for smaller aircraft (AC1) reaches its minimum at the point of
maximum seat load capacity. Assuming a utilization factor beyond X, the use of the larger
aircraft would decrease average costs. In addition, the extent to which it is possible to
compensate for increased airport charges depends not only on the cost advantages attained
but also on prevailing passenger preferences and demand characteristics. If the increase in
charges is very large compared to total costs, then these charges can only be offset through
7
A better usage of airport capacity would be achieved not only by a cutback in frequency, but also
by the fact that larger aircraft have lower wake-vortex separation requirements and lower runway
occupancy times. Consequently, larger aircraft typically occupy runways for a shorter time than
lighter ones (see Wolf, 2003, p. 65 ff.; Doganis, 1992, p. 83).
Journal of Air Transport Studies, volume 3, Issue 1, 2012 Page 9
sufficient passenger load and adequate marginal return per seat. 8 Hence, a half-empty
aircraft would be less cost efficient than two smaller, highly utilized aircrafts.
EUR
AC1
AC2
X
} max. saving
potential
If an airline pools two flights together during the peak period (assuming identical demand for
each flight), it can be expected that some time-sensitive passengers will be lost. To pre-empt
this disadvantage it is necessary to choose an aircraft according to the future demand
situation. Based on current average load factors of 70–80 per cent (see AEA, 2008, p. 8),
this would mean additional cost benefits (see Wei, 2006). However, if an airline loses many
time-sensitive passengers, financial penalties are likely. In this regard, so-called high-yield
traffic is the most likely customer segment to be lost, as these customers are more sensitive
to flight frequencies (see Hanlon, 1996, p. 167; NERA, 2004, p. 83 ff.). Yet a cutback in
frequencies seems to be a reasonable option for certain sub-segments. On routes dominated
by business travellers or hub flights with quick transfer guarantees, frequency reductions
would lead to lower revenues. In such markets, airlines will be unwilling to change
frequencies. The implementation of such strategies is more probable in the case of point-to-
point short-haul flights due to the larger impact of increased charges.
8
The most cost-effective combination in general is maximum range with a full payload. Hence, a
suitable traffic density is necessary to tap the full cost advantages from maximum load (see
Doganis, 2002, p. 122).
Journal of Air Transport Studies, volume 3, Issue 1, 2012 Page 10
High frequencies imply both greater flexibility and more flight hours. The higher the aircraft
utilization, the lower the average costs. Consequently, lower frequencies are more costly and
a cutback in frequency can have negative effects on productivity, especially on short- and
medium-haul flights (see Doganis, 2002, p. 133 ff.). Ultimately, therefore, the airline reaction
will be determined by the interplay of these various factors. However, there are two
additional factors that hinder a possible implementation of lower frequencies:
2. Large aircraft availability: Not all carriers can switch to larger aircraft. Because of
their homogenous fleet structures, low-cost carriers in particular have a limited
ability to introduce larger aircraft compared to FSCs.
In summary, the feasibility of introducing lower frequencies and larger aircraft depends
strongly on specific market and demand characteristics. For example, Givoni & Rietveld
(2009) have shown that service frequencies are not only significant in terms of the time and
price elasticity of passengers. 9 They are also an important instrument in competition, and
can strongly influence a carrier’s choice of aircraft.
I n general, peak flights are strongly favoured by passengers. Therefore, the loss in revenue
connected with rescheduling to off-peak times should not be underestimated. Alongside this
expected commercial disadvantage, aircraft size is also of importance. On routes with high
demand, rescheduling to lower demand periods can require flights to be combined or the
operation of smaller aircraft in order to reach an adequate load factor. Hence, extensive
9
For a theoretical discussion, see Fischer, 1997, pp. 101-114.
Journal of Air Transport Studies, volume 3, Issue 1, 2012 Page 11
rescheduling towards off-peak periods would be connected with demand losses and cost
disadvantages due to a decrease in the usage of aircraft and flight crews. Because of the
required adjustment in fleet structure, rescheduling seems to be a less attractive solution as
a response to peak charges. Savings in the off-peak period have to be substantial to
compensate for the operational and commercial disadvantages.
According to the current allocation principles air carriers can claim slots in the next
scheduling period if they are utilized for at least 80% otherwise the slots will be returned to
the slot pool for reallocation to competitors (so-called grandfather right and use-it-or-lose-it
rule). From this it follows that, because of competition issues, there are serious doubts that
airlines will be willing to give up their valuable peak-time slots. There is evidence that
established carriers use slots as a barrier to entry in order to increase demand for their own
services (see Starkie, 1998, p. 113). This argument is even stronger if one takes into account
that during peak periods, carriers realize scarcity rents (see for instance Menaz and
Matthews, 2008).
10
The mentioned regulation act should ensure, that the allocation happens in a neutral, transparent
and non-discriminatory way. For further details see Council Regulation (EEC) No 95/ 93 of January
1993 on common rules for the allocation of slots at Community airports and amending acts,
basically Regulation (EC) No 793/ 2004.
Journal of Air Transport Studies, volume 3, Issue 1, 2012 Page 12
only shown minor interest in pursuing such a strategy to date. The use of peripheral airports
is a reasonable alternative only for charter airlines or some low-cost airlines, as their supply
of short- and medium-haul point-to-point flights is mainly directed at the price-sensitive
segment of leisure travellers. We would not expect FSCs that use the airport as base station
to implement such a strategy.
In terms of demand characteristics, it is assumed that long- and short-haul passengers will
be affected differently depending on the customer segment and airline business model in
question. The share of business and leisure travellers that fly a route determines to large
degree how much an airline can increase fares without incurring revenue losses. Low-cost
and charter airlines, which cater first and foremost to the price-sensitive group of leisure
travellers, would be particularly limited in their ability to pass additional costs to passengers.
Therefore, compared to FSCs, they would have to bear a large proportion of increased costs
themselves, which also means they would be faced with a competitive disadvantage (for an
analytical and simulative analysis, see e.g. Fu et al., 2006).
Differences may also arise in the ability to shift costs in relation to route distance. Given the
fixed character of airport charges, a peak premium will affect ticket prices very differently.
First, in the case of long-haul flights, supplementary charges represent a lower percentage of
the overall ticket cost, and there are possible advantages due to economies of size and fill.
Apart from this, flight distance is a key determinant of demand elasticity, which is lower for
long-haul flights because of the limited number of alternatives (see e.g. Brons et al., 2002,
p. 172). As a result, in long-haul markets the potential to pass on costs is much larger than
in short-haul ones. For short-haul operations, it is crucial to consider both the degree of
competition with other modes of transport as well as the ratio of business to leisure
passengers on a certain route. The higher the share of business travellers, the easier it is to
shift additional costs. In domestic markets with a low share of business travellers, cost
Journal of Air Transport Studies, volume 3, Issue 1, 2012 Page 13
shifting is apparently difficult to implement. Here, complete cost shifting to passengers would
imply that the required price premium per passenger is sufficiently high enough to offset
both the peak charge and losses due to decreased demand. If the cost increase is really high
(and this can be expected in short-haul markets), then a result would be the phasing out of
some routes, especially point-to-point flights without a commuter function.
Aside from demand related issues, factors like market structure and competitive behaviour
can considerably affect an airline’s scheduling and pricing policy. The oligopolistic market
structures and tendencies towards collusive behaviour that often characterize the airline
sector (see Starkie, 2002, p. 64) seem in general to provide carriers with possibilities for fare
increases. Depending on the commercial importance of a route and the intensity of
competition, certain strategic relationships among the actors can also limit the potential for a
rise in prices. If there is a leader–follower situation, the follower would prefer a limited scope
for cost shifting, because this would compel the leader to maintain fare levels. Such a
dynamic can be observed in the case of feeder flights (see Stangl, 2008. pp. 75–88). I n
addition, the current slot allocation system in Europe seems to enhance airlines’
opportunities for increasing fares. Quite in contrast to other situations of scarcity, the slot
allocation system has the ability to weaken competition among carriers, thus offering a
certain leeway for price increases (see Lüking, 1993, p. 271).
The complete transfer of savings to passengers in the off-peak period also seems to be an
unlikely outcome. A carrier has little motivation to reduce fairs if sufficient load at current
fares can be achieved. In this regard, competition takes place predominantly with regard to
non-pricing criteria such as flight frequency and service amenities. However, market entries
can change such an equilibrium (e.g. when low-cost airlines enter the market; see Forsyth &
Niemeier, 2003, p. 11). Furthermore, if sub-markets are characterized by low passenger
volumes, then a partial pass-through of cost savings would seem to be reasonable in order
to capture additional demand. In-house capacity policies as well as strategic interactions
among market actors are thus significant determinants of airline behaviour. The extent to
which an airline is ultimately able to pass on cost increases to customers in the medium to
the long term therefore varies according to the structure of the market and demand factors,
which vary in relation to the sub-market.
For this reason, conclusions about the degree of cost shifting that will be possible can only
be drawn for the different sub-markets. Conceivably, carriers might prefer to first exploit
As pointed out previously, the introduction of peak-load pricing schemes at airports can
reduce profits if the airlines are unable to offset additional capacity costs in the peak period
by means of operational cost reductions or pricing measures. Yet the fact that airlines
oppose the introduction of peak-load pricing might also be driven by additional competitive
considerations. Under a peak-load pricing scheme, airport capacity during off-peak periods is
priced only at marginal costs. Airlines may fear that this will encourage additional carriers,
particularly low-cost airlines, to enter the market.
We hypothesize that airlines face tough competition over passengers in off-peak periods.
Consequently, each airline will react to a competitor’s price adjustments. If so, we should
observe significant pricing interdependencies in off-peak periods, with this effect weakening
during peak periods. To test our hypothesis, we investigated the pricing behaviour of
Lufthansa (LH) and Air Berlin (AB) for the airport-pair Berlin-Tegel (TXL) – Frankfurt/Main
(FRA). For this purpose, we collected the lowest offered fares of both airlines in a peak and
an off-peak period starting three months prior to departure. 11 The main elements of the
chosen flights can be seen in table 3.
11
More precisely, we collected prices over 91 days prior to departure for flights on 25 August 2008.
Journal of Air Transport Studies, volume 3, Issue 1, 2012 Page 15
Table 3: Flight times and aircraft types for the Berlin- Tegel – Frankfurt/ Main route
Airport Pair Peak Flight Time Off- Peak Flight Time Carrier
( Aircraft) ( Aircraft)
17: 20 (A 321) 21: 15 (A 321) Lufthansa (LH)
TXL - FRA
16: 55 (B 737-800) 21:25 (B737-800) Air Berlin (AB)
Figure 2: Plotted peak and off- peak prices of Lufthansa and Air Berlin
400
Ticket price in €
350
300
100
50
0
91 84 77 70 63 56 49 42 35 30 27 24 21 18 15 12 9 6 3 0
Days before departure
The gathered peak and off-peak ticket prices for Lufthansa and Air Berlin are plotted in
Figure 2. From the figure it is evident that the peak and off-peak prices follow nearly the
same trend line until three weeks before departure. Furthermore, as the departure date
comes closer, peak prices rise faster than off-peak prices. I n terms of differences,
Lufthansa’s prices increase very sharply as the departure comes closer, while Air Berlin
increases its prices more gradually. The summarized statistics in table 4 shed light on the
average price and distribution. Average peak prices are higher than average off-peak prices.
Lufthansa’s average prices and price dispersion are generally higher than Air Berlin’s.
Table 4: Descriptive statistics of peak and off- peak prices for Lufthansa and Air Berlin
凋喋 凋喋 凋喋 凋喋 凋喋 凋喋 凋喋 挑張
(1) 喧墜捗捗 = 糠墜捗捗 + 紅墜捗捗 穴欠検嫌痛 + 紅墜捗捗 穴欠検嫌 態痛 + 紅墜捗捗 喧墜捗捗 + 紅墜捗捗 喧墜捗捗 +
痛 怠 態 戴 痛貸怠 替 痛貸怠
凋喋 凋喋 凋喋 挑張
紅墜捗捗 喧椎勅銚賃 + 紅墜捗捗 喧椎勅銚賃
泰 痛貸怠 滞 痛貸怠
挑張 挑張 挑張 挑張 挑張 凋喋 挑張 挑張
(2) 喧墜捗捗 = 糠墜捗捗 + 紅墜捗捗 穴欠検嫌痛 + 紅墜捗捗 穴欠検嫌 態痛 + 紅墜捗捗 喧墜捗捗 + 紅墜捗捗 喧墜捗捗 +
痛 怠 態 戴 痛貸怠 替 痛貸怠
挑張 凋喋 挑張 挑張
紅墜捗捗 喧椎勅銚賃 + 紅墜捗捗 喧椎勅銚賃
泰 痛貸怠 滞 痛貸怠
凋喋 凋喋 凋喋 凋喋 凋喋 凋喋 凋喋 挑張
(3) 喧椎勅銚賃 = 糠椎勅銚賃 + 紅椎勅銚賃 穴欠検嫌痛 + 紅椎勅銚賃 穴欠検嫌 態痛 + 紅椎勅銚賃 喧墜捗捗 + 紅椎勅銚賃 喧墜捗捗 +
痛 怠 態 戴 痛貸怠 替 痛貸怠
凋喋 凋喋 凋喋 挑張
紅椎勅銚賃 喧椎勅銚賃 + 紅椎勅銚賃 喧椎勅銚賃
泰 痛貸怠 滞 痛貸怠
挑張 挑張 挑張 挑張 挑張 凋喋 挑張 挑張
(4) 喧椎勅銚賃 = 糠椎勅銚賃 + 紅椎勅銚賃 穴欠検嫌痛 + 紅椎勅銚賃 穴欠検嫌 態痛 + 紅椎勅銚賃 喧墜捗捗 + 紅椎勅銚賃 喧墜捗捗 +
痛 怠 態 戴 痛貸怠 替 痛貸怠
挑張 凋喋 挑張 挑張
紅椎勅銚賃 喧椎勅銚賃 + 紅椎勅銚賃 喧椎勅銚賃
泰 痛貸怠 滞 痛貸怠
沈 沈
The variables 喧墜捗捗 and 喧椎勅銚賃 denote the price charged by carrier i in time period t for an
痛 痛
off-peak and a peak flight, respectively. Each single price is regressed on the number of days
until departure as well as on the lagged off-peak and peak prices of the considered carrier
and its competitor. This allows us to investigate the airline’s price responses in the short-run.
The estimation results are shown in table 5. A regression of the residuals on the lagged
residuals and the other explanatory variables does not reveal any autocorrelation.12 The high
values for the adjusted R² imply a good fit of the model.
12
For details on the methodology, see Pels & Rietveld, 2004. Results are not presented here but are
available upon request.
Journal of Air Transport Studies, volume 3, Issue 1, 2012 Page 17
The constants are highly significant except for Lufthansa in the peak period. The number of
days until departure and its squared value are significant only for Lufthansa in the peak
period. However, the p-value for the respective parameter of Air Berlin is close to the 10%
significance level. Therefore, it seems that Air Berlin and Lufthansa significantly adjust their
prices in the peak period but not in the off-peak period according to the number of days
before departure. Even though, this adjustment process is different for the two carriers;
Lufthansa increases its price in a quadratic fashion as the departure day comes closer while
Air Berlin follows a more linear price trend.
While in the peak period the number of days before departure but not the lagged prices of
the competing carrier seem to be the predominant influence on price setting, this picture
reverses in the off-peak period. In the off-peak period Air Berlin adjusts its price in period 建
according to its own prices in the former peak and off-peak period as well as in response to
the off-peak price of Lufthansa. Moreover, Lufthansa reacts to the off-peak price of Air Berlin
and to its own peak and off-peak prices. In the peak period Air Berlin independently sets its
own peak and off-peak prices and does not react to Lufthansa’s price while Lufthansa takes
both Air Berlin’s peak price and its own lagged prices into account. Apart from the two
挑張 凋喋
exceptions 紅墜捗捗 and 紅椎勅銚賃 , all significant price reactions on the lagged variables are
滞 戴
positive.
We can draw three major conclusions from these results. First, in the peak period Lufthansa
as well as Air Berlin increase their prices significantly as the departure date comes closer.
This effect is reinforced by the positive reactions to their own lagged peak-period prices.
Second, both carriers are close competitors in the off-peak since they react on each other’s
prices positively, e.g. if Lufthansa reduces its price in the off-peak period Air Berlin will follow
and vice versa. But this effect is less significant in the peak period, when only Lufthansa
reacts to Air Berlin’s price but Air Berlin does not react to Lufthansa’s price. Third,
interpreting the negative impact of the Lufthansa’s lagged peak price on its off-peak price
and the negative impact of Air Berlin’s off-peak price on its peak price is less obvious. These
price trends are an indication of cross-subsidization between off-peak and peak flights.
The results support our thesis that airlines try to attract passengers in off-peak periods by
adjusting prices according to the prices of their competitors. This effect is less evident during
peak periods. Furthermore, the results indicate that tickets during off-peak periods might be
cross-subsidized by higher prices during the peak period. Hence, we can infer from this
4. CONCLUSI ONS
In this paper we sought to identify the reasons for airline opposition to peak-load pricing.
We first considered the effects of peak-load pricing on airline costs. Due to varying business
models and differences in route networks, airlines have different cost structures. This, in
turn, means the introduction of peak-load pricing will “hurt” carriers in different ways. Trip
length (short haul vs. long haul), service quality (FSC vs. LCC) and the geographic base
(European vs. non-European) are significant factors that lead to different cost structures.
We subsequently reviewed possible airline reactions to peak-load pricing. Although airlines
have a relatively strong ability to influence direct operational costs, they often face diverse
external constraints, which hinder an effective response to pricing signals. Due to operational
factors (e.g. fleet management and vehicle schedules), regulatory conditions, as well as
company-specific restrictions, carrier freedom of action is constrained in the near term.
However, in the medium to long run, airlines have a wide spectrum of opportunities to react
effectively to the implementation of peak pricing structures at airports.
Given the very low marginal costs for the transport of additional passengers and the
relevance of pricing policies that encourage high load, demand circumstances play a key
role. They define not only the potential for price reductions, but also the extent to which
price adjustments are feasible. Furthermore, carrier flexibility to introduce route and flight
time changes varies considerably. It is assumed that carriers who offer international long-
haul services are less flexible with respect to flight time adjustments. However, due to the
lack of travel alternatives for passengers, there is greater flexibility for pricing measures in
the long-haul market than there is in the short-haul one.
13
Here, for instance, we think of routes with a low share of business customers and a high share of
leisure customers, respectively.
Journal of Air Transport Studies, volume 3, Issue 1, 2012 Page 19
In contrast to the use of larger aircraft, there is little practical incentive to rescheduling
operations to off-peak periods. The operational and commercial disadvantages of
rescheduling to off-peak turn out to be higher than the operating cost savings. The
disadvantages also tend to outweigh the benefits in the case of secondary airport use; only
cost-oriented carriers, such as charter airlines or LCCs, can be expected to derive a net
benefit from relocating flights to secondary airports.
A key constraint to the implementation of operational changes is the current slot allocation
procedure. Because of the existence of so-called “grandfather rights” and resulting
tendencies to strategically hoard slots, legacy carriers in particular have few incentives to
adjust their operating schedules. If the monetary inducements of peak charges are not
sufficient to mitigate hoarding behaviour, subsidiary measures such as a slot reservation fee,
the tightening of the so called “use-it-or-lose-it” rule, as well as the allowance of slot trading
would be beneficial. Such measures would augment the monetary incentives of peak
charges. 14 Taking into account these difficulties, it is assumed that under the current
regulatory environment, limited options are available to motivate carriers to change their
operations. In this connection, additional important factors include the role of an airport in a
carrier’s network as well as the availability and accessibility of adequate secondary airports.
The ability of carriers to implement price changes hinges to large extent on the sub-market
in question. If increases in costs can be passed along to customers, carriers will probably
prefer to do this rather than extensively re-structure their operations. Consequently, given
the unchanged slot rents during peak periods, rescheduling to less usage intensive times
probably won’t take place. The goal of peak charges – to force the effective rationing of
demand – would not be achieved.
14
Furthermore, remuneration mechanisms are possible, e.g. certain discounts, bonuses, or a
lowering of other charging elements would offer additional incentives towards a modification of
operating patterns.
Journal of Air Transport Studies, volume 3, Issue 1, 2012 Page 20
losses. 15 Precisely this finding seems to be in-line with Forsyth’s (2008) conclusion that the
introduction of peak-load pricing leads to higher consumer surpluses and lower airline
profits.
REFERENCES
‚ AEA- Association of European Airlines (2008), State of the Industry, Brussels: May 2008.
‚ AEA-Association of European Airlines (2007), Operating Economy of AEA Airlines 2007,
Brussels: December 2007. URL: http:/ /files.aea.be/RI G/Economics/DL / SumRep07.pdf.
‚ ATA-Air Transport Association (2010), ATA Quarterly Cost Index: U.S. Passenger Airlines,
Washington DC. URL: http:// www.airlines.org/ Economics/ DataAnalysis/Pages/Quarterly
CostIndex.aspx
‚ ATA-Air Transport Association (2007), 2007 Economic report , Washington DC. URL:
http://www.airlines.org/Economics/ReviewOutlook/Documents/ 2007AnnualReport.pdf.
‚ Basso, L.J., Zhang, A. (2009), ` Pricing vs Slot Policies When Airport Profits Matter´ , CTS
Working Paper 2009-1.
‚ Brons, M., Pels, E., Nijkamp, P., Rietveld, P. (2002), ` Price elasticities of demand for
passenger air travel: A meta-analysis´ , Journal of Air transport Management, 8, 165-175.
‚ Brueckner, J.-K. (2010), ` Schedule Competition Revisited´ , Journal of Transport
Economics and Policy, 44, 261-285.
‚ Brueckner, J.-K. (2009), ` Price vs. Quantity-Based Approaches to Airport Congestion
Management´ , Journal of Public Economics, 93, 681-690.
‚ Button, K.J. (1982), Transport Economics, London: Heinemann.
‚ Crew, M.A., Fernando, C.S., Kleindorfer, P.R. (1995), ` The Theory of Peak-Load pricing: A
Survey´ , Journal of Regulatory Economics, 8 (3), 215-248.
‚ De Wit, J., Borghouwt, G. (2007), ` The impact of secondary slot trading at Amsterdam
Airport Schiphol´ , SEO Economic Research, 957, A report for The Netherlands Ministry of
Transport, DGTL, Amsterdam, March.
‚ Doganis, R. (2002), Flying off course: The economics of international airlines, 3rd edition,
London: Routledge.
‚ Doganis, R. (1992), The airport business, London/ New York: Routledge.
‚ Eurocontrol (ed.) (2004), Challenges to Growth 2004 Report (CTG04) , Brussels:
December. URL: http:/ /www.eurocontrol.int/eatm/gallery/content/public/ library/CTG04
_report.pdf.
‚ European Economic Community, (1993), Council Regulation (EEC) No 95/ 93 of 18 January
1993 on common rules for the allocation of slots at Community airports, official journal L
014, 22/ 01/ 1993, Brussels, as well as amending acts. URL: http://eur-
15
This result also suggests that there are some possible demand interdependencies between peak
and off-peak periods, an issue which is not touched in this paper, however.
Journal of Air Transport Studies, volume 3, Issue 1, 2012 Page 21
lex.europa.eu/smartapi/ cgi/ sga_doc?smartapi!celexplus!prod!CELEXnumdoc&numdoc= 39
3R0095&lg= en.
‚ Fischer, R. (1997), ` Time Sensitivity of Passengers and Market Structure in the Airline
Industry: A Model of International Air Transport´ , In Lang, P. (ed.), Europäische
Hochschulschriften, V, Volks- und Betriebswirtschaft, 2135, Bern/Berlin.
‚ Forsyth, P., Niemeier, H.-M. (2008), Prices and Regulation in Slot Constrained Airports. I n
Czerny, A.I., Forsyth, P., Gillen, D., Niemeier, H.-M. (ed.), Airport Slots, International
Experiences and Options for Reform, Aldershot: Ashgate, 127-148.
‚ Forsyth, P. (2008), ` The I mpact of Emerging Aviation Trends on Airport Infrastructure´ ,
Journal of Air Transport Management , 13, 417-425.
‚ Fu, X., Lijesen, M., Oum, T. H. (2006), ` An Analysis of Airport Pricing and Regulation in
the Presence of Competition Between Full Service Airlines and Low Cost Carriers´ , Journal
of Transport Economics and Policy, 40 (3), 425-447.
‚ Givoni, M., Rietveld, P. (2009), ` Airline’s choice of aircraft size – Explanations and
implications´ , Transportation Research Part A, 43, 500-510.
‚ Hanlon, P. (1996), Global Airlines: Competition in a Transnational Industry, 1st ed.,
Oxford: Butterworth Heinemann.
‚ International Air Transport Association (IATA) (2000), ` Peak/Off-Peak Charges´ , Ansconf
Working Paper, 82, ICAO, Montreal.
‚ International Civil Aviation Organization (ICAO) (2007), I CAO Environmental Report 2007.
URL: http:/ /www.icao.int/icao/en/env/pubs/env_report_07.pdf
‚ Knockaert, J., Evangelinos, C., Rietveld, P. and Wieland, B. (2009), ` Differentiated
Infrastructure Charging: A Comparison of Theory and Practice´ , European Transport/
Transporti Europei, 43, 4-34.
‚ Laffont, J.-J. and Tirole, J., (2000), Competition in Telecommunications, , Cambridge,
Massachusetts: MIT Press.
‚ Lüking, J. (1993), ` Angebotsplanung und Fluggastverhalten im überlasteten
Luftverkehrssystem´ , In Lang, P. (ed.), Europäische Hochschulschriften, V, Volks- und
Betriebswirtschaft, 1409, Bern.
‚ Menaz, B., Matthews, B. (2008), Economic Perspectives on the Problem of Slot Allocation,
In Czerny, A.I., Forsyth, P., Gillen, D., Niemeier, H.-M. (ed.), Airport Slots, International
Experiences and Options for Reform, Aldershot: Ashgate, 21-39.
‚ NERA – National Economic Research Associates (ed.) (2004), ` Study to assess the effects
of different slot allocation schemes´ , A Report for European Commission, DG TREN,
January.
‚ Pels, E., Rietveld, P. (2004), ` Airline Pricing Behaviour in the London-Paris Market´ ,
Journal of Air Transport Management , 10, 279-283.
‚ Röhl, K.-H. (2007), ` Das System der deutschen Flughäfen – fit für die Zukunft?´ I W –
Trends, March.
Amalia Polydoropoulou1
Department of Shipping, Trade and Transport (STT), University of the Aegean, Greece
Evangelia Chortatsiani 2
Department of Shipping, Trade and Transport (STT), University of the Aegean, Greece
Maria Kamargianni 3
Department of Shipping, Trade and Transport (STT), University of the Aegean, Greece
ABSTRACT
Airlines in a state of crisis need to take steps to ensure revenues keep coming in. Repeat
business and eventually loyalty is critical in that respect. This paper considers airline customer
buying behaviour and preferences and post-flight attitudes with a view to identifying what
makes the air travel product more appealing to customers. A structured web-based purpose-
designed instrument was used to collect travel and traveller data and perceptions and the
findings are prioritised using a consensus decision making approach. A major issue is identified
and a two-step model is developed to demonstrate its significance for airline customers’ loyalty.
Specific airline customer communications and other priorities and preferences are identified. In
addition, it is found that airline customers have a number of complaints, many of which are not
communicated to the airline, and it is demonstrated that these complaints impact on loyalty. It is
therefore argued that airlines and researchers alike need to study customer complaints in
relation to loyalty in greater detail. In view of both the economic situation in Greece and airline
deregulation, this research is of significance to Greek airlines seeking to “tie” their customers
and maintain market presence.
1
Amalia Polydoropoulou is a Professor at the Department of Shipping Trade and Transport of the
University of the Aegean. She received a Civil Engineer Diploma from NTUA, and a MSc. and PhD
in Transportation Systems and Decision Sciences from MIT. Her areas of research include transportation
systems analysis, transportation demand modeling, market research and econometrics. Contact details:
polydor@aegean.gr
2
Evangelia Chortatsiani holds a lectureship at the Department of Shipping, Trade and Transport of the
University of the Aegean. She is a services economist, graduate of the Aristotle University of Thessaloniki,
holds an MSc from the London School of Economics and a PhD in Marketing and I nnovation Management
from I mperial College. She specializes in product development, costing and marketing, competition and
market regulation in telecommunications, transport, shipping and financial services. Contact details:
echor@aegean.gr
3
Maria Kamargianni is a PhD candidate at the Department of Shipping Trade and Transport of the
University of the Aegean. She received a Diploma in Business Administration from University of
Macedonia, and a MSc. in Shipping, Trade and Transport from STT. Her areas of research include travel
behavior, transportation demand modeling and sustainable transport systems analysis. Contact details:
kamargianni@aegean.gr
1. I NTRODUCTI ON
For a great deal of sectors, “crisis” is interpreted as a sharp decline in GDP or indeed spending
specific to the sector. A “crisis” may be seen as the end of a business cycle, provided this is
signalled by some prominent event or events. Depending on sector among others, it can be
overcome in due course, aided by such initiatives as Keynesian approaches (Keynes, 1936;
Woodford, 1999), or other government or corporate efforts to re-establish equilibrium.
For the aviation world and commercial airlines in particular, crisis may mean a sharp change in
revenue or cost streams or volatility that may last from a few weeks to more than a year. These
can have a multitude of originating factors. Reduced load factors of some duration, due to a
broader economic “crisis” or downturn (with their impact exacerbated by the significant fixed
cost element of aircraft leases, trained personnel payroll, slots rental and the like), fuel price
volatility, industrial action, airspace disruptions (such as those that resulted from the Icelandic
volcano eruption in 2010 or the World Trade Centre attacks in 2001) can all lead to a “crisis”.
This paper builds upon the multi-step airline choice (Suzuki, 2007) and traveller perception,
satisfaction and loyalty models (Gomez et al. 2006; Oyewole, 2001; Hess et al., 2007; Espino et
al., 2008) literature to explore the real issues of concern to travellers. It is argued that there is a
significant wealth of information on matters of interest to travellers (delays, luggage handling
etc.) that can affect re-purchase and loyalty. This takes the shape of complaint material and
appears to be understudied in terms of utilizing models for traveller behaviour. One or a series
of specific negative travel experiences, it is argued, can act as a disincentive to repurchase or
recommend an airline that can easily counterbalance costly positive actions such as price
discounts or incentive programmes.
2. RESEARCH METHODOLOGY
To collect the data, a structured web-based purpose-designed instrument was used. It begins by
collecting some general information about respondent's general profile and long distance travel
behavior. The second questionnaire section asks about the airline travel offering, as perceived
by the traveller, including her involvement in its production/consumption. The third section
focuses on the respondent's last trip. This helps to sharpen information and perception
recollections, an approach used extensively in the transportation literature (Ben-Akiva et al.,
2002). The fourth section considers matters to do with the current economic crises. The last
section collects socioeconomic control data identified by the literature as pertinent to air travel
analysis (Dolan et al., 2006; Polydoropoulou et al. 2010). Most questions were either multiple
choice or answerable on a 7-point scale (from -3: not at all to + 3: completely).
The data was collected in May 2011 and 188 responses were received, essentially from within
Greece. As can be seen from Table 1, a reasonably stratified sample was achieved according to
a number of dimensions, except for a higher than average number of student traveller cases
(48% ). These are not necessarily all from the authors' research location base (i.e. the island of
Chios) since only 8.5% of reported “last trips” landing or departing at Chios. Given sufficient
controls, these were all maintained in the sample. With an average of 8 trips in the last year,
respondents generally appear to be experienced air travellers, although most of them (62%) are
not Frequent Flyer Programme (FFP) (incentive programme) members.
In the exploratory section of the study, tabulation based diagrams were used to aid concept
presentation. To prioritise the issues to consider, a consensus decision making approach was
employed, with people combining transport research skills, air traveller profiles and general
business acumen singling-out those results that appear below. Tests were subsequently carried
out to discern the robustness of results where named factors were ranked and the significance
of any differences to the values attached to each studied.
In the explanatory section of the study, a two-step model is used to demonstrate factor
interaction.
Percent Percent
( N. obs. 18 8) ( N. obs. 1 88)
Gender Male 55% Complaints Yes 13%
Female 45% No 87%
Age 18-26 54% Satisfaction 1 (Dissatisfied) 10%
27-40 23% 2 (Quite satisfied) 19%
More than 41 23% 3 (Satisfied) 26%
Educational level Bachelor 66% 4 (Very satisfied) 45%
Master 27% Air Company Aegean 40%
( last trip)
Doctoral 7% Olympic 27%
Occupation Public Services 10% Other 33%
Trips in the 8 trips
Private sector 30%
last 1 2 months on average
Businessperson 12% FFP Yes 38%
membership
Student 48% No 62%
Monthly family < €1000 22% Monthly family
income income ( cont.)
€1000-€2000 16% €3000-€4000 18%
€2000-€3000 18% More than €4000 26%
3. DATA ANALYSI S
From the airline customers' views, the current economic crisis (in Greece) has affected both the
demand for air travel and the price sensitivity of travellers. Experienced travellers (incentive
programme members) exhibit those behaviours marginally less, as they report tougher time
constraints and a lower transport mode substitution (Figure 1).
3.2 BOOKI NG
The front end of the air travel business has clearly moved to the e-business era. Some 94% of
respondents use the web to inform themselves about available flights and fares while 53% use
it to book a flight (Figures 2, 3). Interestingly, it is not young age that makes the “modern”
traveller, with on-line buyers being on average older (at 33 years) than traditional buyers (at
29.5 years).
To the extent that e-booking can reduce airline costs and that extending it does not lead to
reduced availability of more traditional ways of booking for those that need them, there is still
ample scope for increasing the take-up of e-booking.
Subsequent research can look into ways of encouraging this, including dealing with price
incentives, differential approaches to cancellations and ticket modifications, trust and confidence
issues with regard to e-payments and other similar parameters (Papola and Polydoropoulou,
1996).
Flyers feel that traditional advertising is inconsequential for services pertaining to a specific
journey. Any impact should therefore probably be sought in brand profile building (Figure 4).
Passengers have clear and specific preferences on advertising communications. They wish to
receive ticket offer information by email (75% overall and 90% for incentive programme
members) and incentive programme information on their mobile telephone (88%) (Figures 5, 6).
Given that incentive programme information is generally not more urgent or critical than ticket
offers, an explanation might be that programme members are prepared to allow a more
“intimate” or close communication with their airline. Carefully designed such communications
can logically be expected to positively impact loyalty among others.
Air travellers consider multiple factors each time they select an airline carrier (Polydoropoulou et
al., 2007; Hess et al., 2007; Nako, 1992).
Interestingly, this research shows that incentive programme membership is ranked lower than
even environmental footprint. This is likely the result of a moderately experienced (in terms of
average trips per year or incentive programme membership) air travel study sample, as
described in section 2, and the recent redesign of major Greek airlines' incentive programmes to
essentially reward only truly regular or premium class flyers, or in non-financial ways (eg. lounge
access). If it takes some 25 low cost fares to accumulate incentive mileage sufficient for a 26th
journey (equivalent to a 4% discount) and then fees and charges are still due, the discount may
fall to under 3% or even 2% in some cases. Hardly an incentive to stick to a carrier and allowing
3.5 SATI SFACTI ON FROM AI RLI NE SERVI CES AND COMPLAI NTS
Passenger satisfaction is a compound concept (Figure 7). There exists a very interesting
combination of generally reported satisfaction (Figure 8) and a strong stream of airline reported
and non-reported complaints (Figure 9).
Airlines are apparently leaving flyers content with overall service provision, the highest scoring
factors being booking, welcoming on board and the courtesy of stewardesses, and the lowest
scoring being price, food & beverages and on-board entertainment. The booking process, in
particular, is an excellent example of how the sector can push forward on matters it sets its
mind to (en bloc, as Ott (1993) found). A key component is automated reservation systems,
which was one of the early tools airlines used to (perhaps forcefully) enhance customer loyalty
with the onset of deregulation in Europe and elsewhere (Lee et al., 1996). This was seamlessly
evolved to the e-business era with the advent of (cost reducing) e-booking and more recently
and for limited circumstances, e-check in. Another example is the development of (the now
omni-present) incentive programmes (Clemes et al., 2008; Miller, 1993). In both cases, the
initiatives were taken in the early 1990s in response to deregulation and rising competition, so
The arguably unfinished state of this process then, perhaps so ad-infinitum, or indeed
management or other issues, may be among the reasons why, at the same time, travellers have
a significant number of concerns and complaints. Indeed, some 13% of respondents reported a
Customer complaints are personal. They can be voiced to company staff or even put on paper.
They are also by their nature specific, much more so that “low satisfaction” is. This means they
are to easier understand and, more importantly, set about to dealing with them, although as the
data collected during this study suggests, they remain largely (61%) unreported and therefore
outside the sphere of airline knowledge.
It was therefore decided to take this finding one step further and consider whether complaints
affect customer loyalty. There is significant academic scope for research in this area, with
current research carefully mapping complaints without linking them to subsequent subject
behaviours (eg. Özlem, 2007).
This section presents a preliminary model developed for predicting a customer loyalty. A loyalty
index is created as the outcome of a two-step process. In the first step a factor analytic model is
estimated to produce a factor from two variables namely customer repurchase and
recommendation to others. In the second step the fitted values of the loyalty index is used as
the dependent variable of a regression model. Independent variables are travel characteristics
(chosen airline company), satisfaction level (overall satisfaction, complaints) and socioeconomic
characteristics (income).
Coefficient
Coefficient Names t-test
Estimates
Satisfaction (overall satisfaction)
0.459 8.001
(7pt Likert Scale: -3= completely dissatisfied,..,+ 3= completely satisfied)
Complaints
-.567 -3.155
(1= yes, 0= o/ w)
I ncome (Monthly Family Income more than €4000)
-0.329 -2.64
(1= yes, 0= o/w)
Aegean (passengers who travelled with Aegean at their last trip)
0.612 4.566
(1= yes, 0= o/w)
Olympic (passengers who travelled with Olympic at their last trip)
0.374 2.495
(1= yes, 0= o/w)
Constant -1.860 -4.638
Statistics
Number of Observations 188
R-square 0.403
Adjusted R-square 0.387
Although the sample used in this research is not extensive, on the basis of the above there is
evidence to suggest that customer complaints do have a predictive value for airline passenger
behavioural loyalty, as satisfaction does. Moreover, the results obtained create several avenues
for future research.
5. CONCLUSI ONS
Airlines in a state of crisis need to take steps to ensure revenues keep coming in. Repeat
business and eventually loyalty is critical in that respect. This paper considers airline customer
buying behaviour and preferences and post-flight attitudes. Specific communications and other
priorities and preferences are identified.
Analysis shows that the current economic crisis has affected both the demand for air travel and
the price sensitivity of travellers. However, experienced travellers and incentive programme
members exhibit those behaviours marginally less, due to tougher time constraints and limited
travel mode alternatives.
Concluding, it is found that airline customers have many complaints, many of which are not
communicated to the airline, and it is demonstrated that these complaints impact on loyalty. It is
therefore argued that airlines and researchers alike need to study customer complaints in
relation to loyalty in greater detail. Such efforts may benefit from methodological approaches
segmenting customers and/or providing value-added propositions based on the Delta Model
(Hax et al., 2001) or the Rhombus Model (Litinas et al., 2010).
REFERENCES
‚ Anderson, E., Fornell, C., and Lehmann, D.R. (1994). Customer satisfaction, Market share,
and Profitability: Findings from Sweden. Journal of Marketing , Vol. 58 (July), pp. 53-66.
‚ Athanassopoulos, A.D. (2000). Customer Satisfaction Cues to Support Market Segmentation
and Explain Switching Behavior. Journal of Business Research, Vol. 47 (3), pp. 191-207.
‚ Bailey, E. R., Graham, D.R. and Kaplan, D. (1985). Deregulating the Airlines. MIT Press
Series on Regulation of Economic Activity, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
‚ Ben-Akiva, M., Walker, J., Bernardino, A.T., Gopinath, D.A., Morikawa, T., and
Polydoropoulou, A. (2002). Integration of Choice and Latent Variable Models. In Perpetual
Motion: Travel Behaviour Research Opportunities and Application Challenges. Editor: Hani
Mahmassani. Publisher: Elsevier Science, May 2002.
‚ Boshoff, C., 2005. A re-assessment and refinement of RECOVSAT. Managing Service Quality,
15, pp. 410-425.
‚ Clemes, M.D., Gan, C., Kao, T. H., and Choong, M. (2008). An empirical analysis of customer
satisfaction in international air travel. Innovative Marketing, Vol. 4, (2), pp. 49-62.
‚ Clemes, M.D., Ozanne, L.K., and Laurenson, W.L. (2001). Patients’ Perceptions of Service
Quality Dimensions: An Empirical Examination of Health Care in New Zealand. Health
Marketing Quarterly, Vol. 19 (1), pp. 3-22.
Marc Bui2
Complex Systems Modelling and Cognition, Eurocontrol and EPHE Joint Research Lab
ABSTRACT
The dynamical behaviour of groups of airspace sectors, e.g. Functional Airspace Blocks, is
not trivial to be analysed without appropriate theoretical tools. In this paper, we suggest a
discrete model based on cellular automata and multi agent systems to express the
congestion dynamics and complexity in the controlled airspace. Discrete time simulations
have been performed with random selected scenarios of traffic and with independent sector
parameters to investigate the impact of availability of local sectors on the whole state of the
airspace. Obtained results show the existence of a traffic threshold that leads to a theoretical
saturation of airspace. The test scenario showed a phase transition phenomenon towards
the congestion of the European airspace at the resulting traffic threshold circa 50 000 flights.
Validation using real data shows the predictive abilities of the model.
Keywords: Air Traffic Management, Air Traffic Control, Complex Systems, Airspace
availability, complex networks, Multi Agent Systems, cellular automata.
"""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""" """"""""""""""""
1
Soufian Ben Amor received his PhD in Computer Science in 2008 from Ecole Pratique des Hautes
Etudes. His PhD was performed at EUROCONTROL (the European Organisation for the Safet y of Air
Navigation). He is currently Assistant Professor at University of Versailles Saint-Quentin-en-Yvelines.
He is author and co-author of more than 27 papers and conference papers on the topics complex
systems modeling and operation research. Contact Details: soufian.ben-amor@uvsq.fr
2
Marc Bui received his PhD in Computer Science in 1989 from University Paris 11. He is full
professor of Computer Science at University of Paris 8 and at the Ecole Pratique des Hautes Etudes,
where he is the head of a research team, the CSMC. Prof. Marc Bui is co-editor for Studia Informatica
Universalis journal. He has chaired and/ or served on the advisory boards and program committees of
various international conferences and workshops. He is author and co-author of more than 60 papers
and conference papers on the topics of distributed systems and complex systems modelling. Contact
Details : marc.bui@ephe.sorbonne.fr
"
1. I NTRODUCTI ON
Most of new policies trying to improve the Air Traffic Management (ATM) system tend to
maintain its classical structure. Innovation in this field is basically focused on equipment,
information and communication technologies, task automatization and improvement of
Human-machine interfaces [Watkins et al., 2002] . Nevertheless, different actors of airspace
traffic consider that the current system has attained its limits and congestion is more and
more difficult to resorb. Empirical studies show that more and more network-effects are
observed in the operational context demonstrating the qualitative changes in the airspace
availability ([Mayer et al., 2003], [Daniel, 1995], [ Brueckner et al., 1992]).
Delay cost is evaluated to be between 7 and 11 billion euros per year and according to the
I nstitute of Air Transportation (I AT) 60% is due to ATC (Air Traffic Control) [ITA, 2000]. The
ATM system is composed of numerous processes and various actors having different and
divergent objectives: pilots try to be on time, companies focus on economic aspects
(reducing costs and maximizing benefits) and controllers must guarantee the security of the
traffic. In our approach, even if we tried to include indirectly some ATM aspects, we are
basically concerned with the ATC subsystem, in particular the en route control. In fact, en
route control in Europe is the main responsible of traffic delays leading to costs of several
billion euros per year [Golaszewsk, 2002]. This is not the case in the USA where delays are
caused by the airport saturation.
"
related to the following factors: system size, diversity of users, safety constraints and
uncertainty (weather, human factor, technical factor...). This complexity can be also related
to the Air Traffic Control (ATC) subsystem representing the rigidly structured air space and
the largely centralised, human operated control hierarchy ([Delahaye et al., 2005], [Histon et
al., 2002]). ATC, in which we observe complex phenomena, is composed of services
provided by the controllers on the ground to ensure the safety and the efficiency of aircraft’s
motion, and are provided throughout the controlled sectors. I n fact, aircraft tend to fly along
fixed corridors and at specific altitudes, depending on their route. The entire path of the
aircraft is pre-planned (flight plan) and only minor changes are permitted online. The ATC is
in complete command of the air traffic and ultimately responsible for safety. All requests by
the aircraft have to be cleared by the ATC.
Aircraft follow a planned trajectory to join two airports. They are monitored and guided
throughout the whole flight time by air traffic controllers. Computers, communication links
and radar screens all provide up-to-date information. Technology quite often has not one but
two back-up systems to cover any possible breakdowns. The whole organisation is based
upon international regulations and determined routines. During the flight different services
are furnished by three kinds of control activities: Tower Control where controllers direct
aircraft that are taking off or landing at airports, Approach Control where controllers handle
aircraft that are transitioning from the en-route portion of flight into the airspace around or
near an airport and En-route Control where controllers handle aircraft that are operating on
the main travel portion of their flights, typically at a high altitude.
As specified in the introduction, in this work, we are especially interested in the study of the
behaviour of the en route sectors because, in Europe, en route control is the main
responsible for the airline delays and traffic congestion. We include the effects of approach
"
and tower control sectors using a non-local interaction rules. As we can see in Figure 1, the
initial traffic demand exceeds the declared capacity of a sector at a specific moment. The
Central Flow Management Unit (CFMU), an operational unit of EUROCONTROL3, manages air
traffic demand in order to avoid airspace congestion due to this difference and to optimize
the utilization of resources. Despite the regulation and the planning made by the CFMU there
are always differences between planned and real traffic. These differences are specific to
each sector and the resulting effect of these local states and their interactions between them
on the whole availability of airspace are difficult to determine.
"""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""" """"""""""""""""
3
EUROCONTROL is the European Organization for the Safety of Air Navigation
"
3. BOTTOM- UP MODELI NG OF THE ATM SYSTEM
ATM simulation requires a modelling approach and simulation framework taking into account
particularities and properties of this system. ATM being a complex system where the
objective is to guarantee the security and fluidity of the traffic by optimizing the use of the
shared resources between different actors having divergent constraints (companies, air
traffic controllers, pilots, passengers...) needs to be studied using appropriate Tools
[Boccara, 2004].
According to Wolfram [Wolfram, 1986], [ Wolfram, 1994] Cellular Automata (CA) are
microscopic models for complex natural systems containing large numbers of simple identical
components with local interactions. Even if the construction of the cellular automata is very
simple, their behaviour can be very complex [Wolfram, 1994], [Wolfram, 2002]. There are
fundamental reasons showing that there is no general method which can universally be
applied to predict the behaviour of these systems. Compared with reality the cellular
automata appear simplistic. However, they are currently considered as a fundamental tool in
modelling and simulating complex phenomena, in particular concerning the auto-organized
systems. The use of the cellular automaton makes it possible to reduce the complexity of
modelling to what is necessary to generate the phenomenon. It is a paradox of complex
"
systems: the behaviour of the system is unpredictable and complex (at a long term level)
whereas the laws (or rules) which controlling it are simple and deterministic. Moreover,
cellular automata represent a powerful simulation tool. In fact a convincing simulation of
large dataset requires computing power of parallel computers. However, the local nature of
interactions between cells makes the programming of cellular automata easy “to be
parallelized”. The dynamic theory of systems was developed to describe the global properties
of the solutions of equations.
A combination of Cellular Automata (CA) formalism and Multi Agent Systems (MAS) allows a
coherent mathematical and computational representation of the physical model. In fact, CA
permit the representation of the entities composing the system and the evolution of their
state over time whereas MAS are well adapted to express the interactions between the
entities and their behaviour [ Weiss, 1999] , [ Fikes, 1982] . We will use in our model this
combination to rebuild the real system from the basic components.
‚
‚
structure dynamics : evolution of the merging and splitting schemes of the sectors.
routes and sectors topology (shape of the sectors, average number of neighbours,
‚
routes configuration,...).
‚
the technical system : aircrafts, communication systems...
In order to provide an efficient and realistic simulation of the ATM behaviour it is important
"
to include the relations between its three basic subsystems. In fact, the components of
technical subsystem (aircrafts) interact with the physical subsystem (sectors) and the human
subsystem (controllers, pilots). The human subsystem is particularly important because it
supervises the two other subsystems in order to accomplish the global mission of the ATM
system: manage the continuous increase of the traffic volume while guaranteeing the
security and the fluidity of the traffic. These aspects can be easily integrated by combining
CA and the multi agent paradigm.
Here is the list of the important aspect which must be considered in the modelling of the
ATM system:
‚ the different kind of entities in the system;
‚ the different hierarchical levels in the system;
‚ the topology of the entities;
‚ the different kind of relations between the entities;
‚ the process determining the state of the entities;
‚ the process determining the changes in their spatial location.
The simulation of the behaviour of such a system needs a rigorous formulation of these
aspects. The simulation of the management of shared resources requires also the integration
of the interaction between the agents and the dynamical resources. A first method that could
be used to represent these interactions emphasize on processes determining interactions
between agents and resources. These agents are cognitive agents having a representation of
the resource and possess their own rules to reach their objectives. Each agent acts on the
resource according to his rules and modify the resource for other agents. In our context we
are facing the problem of the management of renewable common resources (airspace) in
confrontation with different actions and situations which may lead to a satisfactory use (or
not) of the resource for the different agents (pilots, controllers, companies,...).
"
The multi-agents universe offers also an interesting ability to simulate the message
exchange in communication networks (controller/controller communication and
pilot/controller communication). These communications may represent information
exchange, negotiation between the agents (collaborative decision making) or services
exchange.
As seen in section 2, there is a significant difference between the planned traffic and the
realized one [Gwiggner et al., 2006]. This difference leads to the congestion of a certain
number of control sectors. I n order to reduce the congestion and to keep a certain fluidity of
the traffic, the controllers in the saturated sectors may reduce the speed of the aircraft or
deviate from its trajectory to an available control sector. To be able to take into account
these particularities of the ATC system, we integrated these aspects in the rules
implemented in the cellular automaton where cells represent the controlled sectors.
"
‚ Each sector is an agent modelling its behaviour of air traffic control in the operational
context.
‚ The state of this binary valued agent: 0 if it is available (able to provide control service to
an entering aircraft) and 1 if not (the sector is congested).
‚ An aircraft entering in sector sa at time t is transferred to the following sector sb
Fa Fa
according to the flight plan and the following rules :
– at time t + if sb is available; where is the needed time to cross the
sector sa ;
– if sb is congested at time t + F a , the aircraft is delayed (by decreasing the
time t + Fa + 1;
‚ Otherwise, the aircraft is rerouted to one of the neighbouring and non-congested sectors
with probability p1 .
‚ An aircraft may be subject to delays other than those imposed by sectors for security
reason. That is why an aircraft may have randomly a delay while arriving to a sector with
probability p2 (this allows to take into account uncertainties related to the
meteorological conditions, take-off delays, ...)
‚ The aircraft may increase its speed if it was already delayed with probability p3 .
Traffic pattern was generated randomly. The variable nbPairsOrigDest represents the
number of origin-destination couples ( input-cell, output-cell ). The trajectory obtained is a
"
segment having as extremities Orig. cell and Dest. cell. The flight plan generated is
consequently composed of the list of sectors crossed by the segment. In order to take into
account the fluctuation of the traffic during the day we used a particular distribution of
flights where the traffic is doubled in two different time windows.
ÂN
24
Let nbFlights = t be the total number of flight of the day (crossing the studied en route
0
airspace). The distribution of the flights is introduced such that the traffic is doubled during
the intervals (Figure 3): [ t1 = 6h; t2 = 8h] and [ t3 = 18h; t4 = 20h].
The simulation shows the existence of a phase transition phenomenon concerning the
congestion of the airspace due to a critical density of the traffic [Ben Amor et al., 2007]. For
example, for a given parameterization we notice that while varying the number of flights we
obtain a behaviour of the system totally different when a certain threshold is reached. In
fact, for n < 50,000 (in particular for n = 30000 representing the mean volume of the daily
traffic in Europe) and the other parameters being fixed according to the mean observed
values in the real operational context, we obtain some local congestions that are quickly
resorbed by the collaboration between sectors (Figure 4). When n 50,000, we can identify
a phase transition phenomenon where the system is trapped in a situation where the
congestion propagates through the whole area and local rules are unable to resorb this
congestion (Figure 5). This phenomenon reflects situations where the system needs an
external help to resorb the congestion (delaying take-off at the airports, change the routing
plans for aircrafts on the ground, etc...)
"
Figure 4: The system absorbs the local congestion w hen nbFlights
is inferior to the threshold
"
4. VALI DATI ON WI TH REAL DATA
In order to validate the model, from the qualitative point of view4, we used the real data
relative to a one-day traffic. To be useful we applied some treatments on these data in order
to gather from different files the needed information implementing the model. We used in
particular the following files:
‚ the file ALL-FT.20070624,traffic file of the CFMU giving the profile of all flight of the day
(June 24th 2007). This file contains among other information the following parameters
for each flight: departure and arrival airport, aircraft identity, company, type of aircraft,
followed route, requested flight level, regulations (in particular rerouting), ATFM sent and
received messages.
‚ the file Airblock.296, environment file of the CFMU giving the set of the elementary
structural units of airspace, and their geographical coordinates.
‚ the file Aircraft.296 giving for each aircraft its identity, type and performance.
‚ the file Airport.296 containing the name, ICAO code and geographical coordinates of all
airports in the world.
‚ the Airspace.296 giving for each airspace entity its identity, name, type and the number
of elementary sectors composing it.
‚ the file Capacity.296 giving the capacity and specifying the type of the concerned
element (control centre, elementary sector, composed sector...) and the time unit.
‚ the file Configuration.296 giving for each control centre its configurations during the day
and the name of the sectors in the different configurations.
‚ the file Flow.296 giving the traffic flows existing between the different airports.
‚ the file NavPoint.296 giving the number of beacons and for each its name, type and
coordinates.
‚ the file OpeningScheme.296 giving the opening schemes (merging and splitting of the
sectors) of different control centres during the day.
‚ the file routes.296 giving the available routes network during the day.
‚ the file Sector.296 giving the number of the elementary sectors and for each its name
and air blocks composing it.
‚ the file TrafficVolume.296 dividing the traffic into traffic volumes and giving
complementary information about the flows.
‚ the file reroutingStats giving statistics about the realized rerouting procedures.
"""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""""" """"""""""""""""
4
Correspondence concerning the simulated scenario and the realized traffic between the shape of the graphs
giving the evolution of the number of congested sectors.
Journal of Air Transport Studies, volume 3, Issue 1, 2012 Page 50
"
‚ the file OverloadHourly giving the total number of hours of congestion where the traffic
exceeded the capacity by 1%, 20%, 40%, 60% et 80%. It provides also the different
kind of regulation procedures realized to resorb the exceeding traffic.
In order to rebuild the realized traffic and represent the evolution of congestion level over
time we need to elaborate a simulation scheme and manage the dependencies between the
data contained in the different files. For example, the evolution of capacity depends on the
opening schemes of the different centres which implies the reading of the file
OpeningScheme and determine the structural entity to which the capacity is applied.
Similarly, to determine the geographical location of a sector we need to open the file
containing the list of airblocks composing it. More generally, the figure 6 gives the global
map of dependencies between the different files. The figure 7, provides a general view of
the simulation interface.
"
Figure 7: Evolution of the Congestion in the Airspace
The simulation using real data showed a similarity between the shape of the graph giving
the observed congestion level of en route sectors in the European airspace (figure 9) and the
graph given by the simulated scenario of the model using the following parameterization
(figure 8) :
‚ probability of delay of aircraft on take-off : 0,25.
‚ capacity interval : [ 12-20].
‚ probability of regulation using speed : 0,15.
‚ sector crossing time interval : [ 5-15].
‚ rerouting probability : 0,18.
Nevertheless, even if the two graphs (observed and simulated congestion) are similar, they
have mainly two differences:
‚ at the quantitative level, there is an important difference between the observed and
the simulated congestion. By comparing the graph representing the evolution of the
real number of congested sectors to the graph simulated congestion, we notice that
the real congestion level is clearly inferior to the simulated congestion.
‚ the sharpness of certain peaks in the congestion are more important in the simulated
Journal of Air Transport Studies, volume 3, Issue 1, 2012 Page 52
"
congestion.
The difference between the observed congestion and the simulated one is not surprising.
Considering the sensitivity of the ATM system (as any complex system) to the initial
conditions, the quantitative prediction is very hard to establish. The main objective of our
model is essentially oriented to the reconstruction of congestion dynamics (the aspect of the
congestion graph).
This quantitative difference may be explained also by the use of the instantaneous capacity
(number of aircraft simultaneously present in the sector) and we do not integrate the hourly
capacity (amount of the traffic that could be managed by a sector in one hour). Concerning
the small differences in the peaks related the abrupt changes in the number of congested
sectors we can provide these two elements of explanation:
1) the difference is basically due to the difference in the rerouting procedure used in the
model compared to the real procedures. In fact, in the model we considered only the tactical
rerouting but in the real operational context the flow managers using short term predictive
tools are able to display specific online procedures to apply strategic rerouting schemes.
2) other real factors which are difficult to capture in the model may also provide a part of
the explanation of this difference, e.g. the traffic management by controllers. Actually,
controllers do not systematically apply a rerouting scheme when the sector is overloaded. It
was shown by empirical studies that controllers are able to manage sometimes a certain
traffic load which is more important than the declared theoretical capacity.
Despite these differences, our proposed model reproduced dynamics of the congestion which
is very close to the real context. More, it allows testing hypothesis and different scenarios by
varying the simulation parameters. Thus we noticed concordant observations with empirical
studies. In particular, we tested the effects of the variation of the size of the sectors and
noticed that there is a minimal size of sectors under which the propagation is amplified.
"
Figure 8: Simulated congestion - Traffic of June 24th 2007
Validation using real data of sectors shows the ability of the model to reproduce congestion
dynamics similar to the real system. In a future work we aim to provide a mathematical
model providing more precise quantitative predictions. To achieve this goal we need, from a
mathematical point of view, to formalize and generalize the neighbourhood concept using
pre-topology theory in order to express different kind of connections between sectors and to
consider a more realistic neighbourhood basis.
Journal of Air Transport Studies, volume 3, Issue 1, 2012 Page 54
"
Although airspace is a common resource, ATM in the European Union is still organised in a
fragmented way. Every time a plane enters the airspace of a Member State, it is serviced by
a different air navigation service provider on the basis of different rules and operational
requirements. In order to improve capacity and efficiency while minimizing costs of air
navigation services, European Member States provided a key mechanism integrated to Single
European Sky (SES) and called Functional Airspace Blocs (FABs). This implies an operational
organisation of airspace independently from country boundaries.
From a managerial and operational point of view, our model showed in particular the interest
of the single sky and Functional Airspace Blocs (FABs) concepts. In fact, according to the
simulations it is clear that a functional and operational segmentation of the controlled
airspace is more efficient to guarantee a performing traffic management, by reducing
conflicts due the heterogeneity of rules and operational requirements.
REFERENCES
‚ Ben Amor S., Tran Dac H., Bui M., & Duong V., (2007) Simulating Dynamic ATM Network
Effects Using Cellular Automata, In Proceedings of the European Conference on Complex
Systems, ECCS’07, Dresden, Germany, October.
‚ Boccara N., (2004) Modeling complex systems. Springer-Verlag, New York.
‚ Brueckner J.K., Nichola J. D., and Pablo T. S., (1992), Fare Determination in Airline Hub-
and-Spoke Networks, Rand Journal of Economics, 23(3), 309-34.
‚ Daniel, J.I., (1995), Congestion Pricing and Capacity of Large Hub Airports: A Bottleneck
Model with Stochastic Queues, Econometrica, 63(2), 327-70.
‚ Delahaye, D., Puechmorel, S. (2005) Air Traffic Complexity Map based on Non Linear
Dynamical Systems. In 4th EUROCONTROL Innovative Research Workshop & Exhibition,
12/ 2005, Brétigny sur Orge, France.
‚ Fikes R.E., (1982) A Commitment-Based Framework for Describing Informal Cooperative
Work. Cognitive Science 6, pp. 331-347.
‚ Golaszewsk R., (2002) Reforming air traffic control: an assessment from the American
perspective, Journal of Air Transport Management, Volume 8, Issue 1, January 2002,
Pages 3-11.
‚ Gwiggner, C., Duong, V., (2006) Averages, Uncertainties and Interpretation in Flow
Planning. Second International Conference on Research in Air Transportation,
"
ICRAT2006, 06/2006, Belgrade.
‚ Histon, J. M., Hansman, R. J, (2002) The Impact of Structure on Cognitive Complexity in
Air Traffic Control . Report No. ICAT-2002-4June 2002, MIT International Center for Air
Transportation, Cambridge, United States.
‚ ITA, (2000) Costs of air transport delay in Europe, Rapport technique, Institut du
Transport Aérien, novembre 2000.
‚ Mayer C., Sinai T., (2003) Network Effects, Congestion Externalities, and Air Traffic
Delays : Or Why Not All Delays Are Evil The American Economic Review, Vol. 93, No. 4
(Nov., 2003), pp. 1194-1215.
‚ North, M.J., Collier, N.T., Vos, J.R., (2006) Experiences Creating Three Implementations
of the Repast Agent Modeling Toolkit . ACM Transactions on Modeling and Computer
Simulation, Vol. 16, I ssue 1, pp. 1-25, ACM, New York, New York, USA.
‚ Tran Dac H. T., (2004) Sectorisation contrainte de l’espace aérien, thèse de Doctorat de
l’Universié de Technologie de Compiègne.
‚ Watkins O. J., Lygeros J., (2002) Safety relevant operational cases in Air Traffic
Management , Report D1.1 HYBRIDGE, IST-2001-32460, Distributed Control and
Stochastic Analysis of Hybrid Systems Supporting Safety Critical Real-Time Systems
Design.
‚ Weiss, G., (1999) Multi-agent Systems, A Modern Approach to Distributed Artificial
Intelligence, The MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
‚ Wolfram, S. (1984) Universality and complexity in cellular automata, Physica D, 10.
‚ Wolfram, S. (1986) Theory and Application of Cellular Automata. Reading, MA: Addison-
Wesley.
‚ Wolfram, S. (1994) Cellular Automata and Complexity: Collected Papers. Reading, MA:
Addison Wesley.
‚ Wolfram, S. (2002) A New Kind of Science. Champaign, I L: Wolfram Media.
"
BUSI NESS RELATI ONS BETWEEN THE LOW COST CARRI ERS AND AI RPORTS AS A
CONSEQUENCE OF THE AI R TRANSPORT DEREGULATI ON
Eleftherios D. Katarelos, 1
Department of Shipping Trade and Transport, University of the Aegean, Greece
Iason Koufodontis, 2
Department of Business Administration, University of the Aegean, Greece
ABSTRACT
The deregulation of air transport has increased competition between air carriers, resulting in
lower fares and increased volumes of passengers. Subsequently, the fare reduction has
altered the market structure with the establishment of new carriers, strategic alliances and
mergers, and the bankruptcy of several traditional airlines which were unable to adapt to
the new environment. The emergence of low cost carriers (LCCs) is one important outcome
of the deregulation. LCCs entered the market by offering a differentiated product based on
bare services offered at significantly lower prices. The main target was travelers with
increased sensitivity in pricing and less demand for all-around services. The rise in terms of
passengers and flights dictated a better utilization of the fleet, requiring reduced turnaround
times at airports. Many central airports had very little flexibility and capacity necessary to
facilitate additional timeslots. As an answer to inadequate capacity combined with higher
taxes and fees, most LCCs have chosen to use secondary or regional airports. This choice
has altered the balance and strategic importance between airports and increased their
importance for air carriers. This paper examines the evolution and development of LCCs
globally, along with the consequences of their expansion to the traditional carriers, the
market and the passengers. Emphasis is given to the relationship between LCCs and airports
which has resulted in an additional increase in air travel. The prospects of Greece as a
market for LCCs are also being discussed.
1
Eleftherios D. Katarelos (corresponding author) is Adjunct Lecturer at the University of the
Aegean and also Air Traffic Controller at the Hellenic Aviation Authority. Contact details:
e.kat arelos@stt.aegean.gr
2
I ason Koufodontis is Adjunct Lecturer at the University of the Aegean. His research focuses in the
utilization of information technologies and air transportation in the fields of tourism and development
in island regions. Contact details: ikouf@aegean.gr
1. I NTRODUCTI ON
The new global regulations have effectively deregulated the air transport market. The
establishment of a competitive environment opened the way for Low Cost Carriers (LCCs) as
a cheaper and simpler alternative model for passengers choosing air travel. Passengers as
consumers have now more choices between different service levels and corresponding
prices. LCCs appeared first in US market and later in Europe and the rest of the world.
Today most countries and regions are served by LCCs together with traditional carriers,
altering the industry structure in a global scale. In order to achieve low cost, LCCs have
formed strategies that either reduce any cost that can be trimmed down or completely
remove parts of their services.
For LCCs, airports were initially a substantial obstacle; costs were too high to suit their
business model and operation from many airports was very limiting, especially in saturated
markets. Airports located in capitals and other maj or cities could not offer capacity at
reasonable pricing, usage period and hours. On the other hand, secondary and regional
airports had both the unused capacity and the willingness to negotiate and offer competitive
low fees. Any cost reduction achieved through better contracts with the airports allows LCCs
to offer lower ticket fares. Lower fares combined with the use of additional airports and the
enlargement of catchment areas has resulted in increasing of the passenger volume. Of
course traditional carriers have also taken measures to remain competitive in the evolving
market conditions. This paper examines the emergence and expansion of LCCs, their effect
on traditional carriers’ strategies, on consumer habits, on airport strategies, and finally their
entrance and presence in the Greek market.
2. AI R TRANSPORT DEREGULATI ON
Since 1944 air transport is regulated by the Chicago Convention. The deregulation started at
national level, first from the USA, followed from Canada, Australia, Japan, Taiwan, South
Korea, and UK. Gradually most countries allowed the operation of new airlines along with
their flag carriers. Deregulation was introduced in order to create “more competitive
aviation services” (Iatrou and Oretti 2007). The main idea was to establish a global aviation
market without entry restrictions. This would allow free and open competition, leading to
more efficient airlines and improved consumer choices (Iatrou and Oretti 2007).
The cost strategy adopted by LCCs is based in a simpler service model. Any service that can
be avoided or reduced is not included in the base price of the ticket. Typical examples are
flight with only one seating class (economy), dense seating pitch, limited additional services
during flights, and abandonment of the transfer concept (Pels et al 2009). The choice of
favorite seat, the free newspapers, the baggage handling between carriers, the frequent
flyer rewards, and the dedicated airport lounges are all sacrificed in order to keep cost as
low as possible. Wherever some additional services are still offered they are charged as
extras. The distribution and sales cost is also kept at a minimum by the use of internet
sales, proprietary boarding control, and limited marketing budget. Fleet is typically based on
a single aircraft type allowing for more efficient maintenance and lower operational costs.
The intensive negotiations between LCCs and airports for fees and itineraries are in contrast
with the previously nonexistent competition between airlines and airports (Barrett 2004).
Increased levels of competition have led to very low airfares especially for destinations that
are simultaneously served by LCCs and traditional carriers. This observation is also true for
adjacent airports (Lian and Rønnevik 2010). Many flag carriers were not prepared to
compete in a deregulated market and soon they were facing serious problems. Sabena and
Swissair declared bankruptcy in 2001, followed by other national carriers, with most recent
example that of Malev in 2012. Other traditional airlines adjusted their strategies and
concentrated in cost reductions as an answer to the LCCs (Barrett 2004). Charter airlines
were also affected and in many cases they are facing direct competition by LCCs. In many
popular vacation destinations, LCCs offer frequent and flexible itineraries allowing shorter
vacations with smaller budget. In areas such as coastal Spain, LCCs are the preferred
method of air travel, further limiting the market share of both flag carriers and charter
airlines (Martinez-Garcia and Royo-Vela 2010). Affordable prices and frequent connections
have contributed to the popularity of weekend travel in Europe and have influenced
Personnel and aircraft Use of single aircraft type and interchangeable crews with
common type ratings
For many decades European flag carriers enjoyed several privileges, including the de facto
control of major airports. Since they had been operating on marginal profitability, it has
often been argued that high salaries, benefits, and pensions combined with governmental
protection resulted in very low productivity. At the same time, possibilities for entrance of
competitors and introduction of cost strategies were practically nonexistent (Barrett 2004).
According to data from ACI (2010) the LCCs’ market share increased from approximately
10% to over 30% in 2006. In regions such as Asia and Australia the trend remains
significant. During 2001 and 2009 LCCs had a steady increase of 38% on average annually,
compared to the total increase in the region that did not exceed 6%. During the same
period, the number of cities connected by LCCs increased from 48 to 576. LCC expansion is
In any case, LCCs seem to have acquired a reasonable share that is steadily around 30% of
the total intra-European capacity (EFLAA 2010b). LCCs managed to seize most of the
capacity growth in Europe between 2000 and 2009. Focus has now moved to the promising
markets of Eastern Europe. According to Boeing Corporation, the global expansion of LCCs is
one of the main reasons for the predicted growth of aviation (Boeing 2010). Growth rates
are expected to be much higher for LCCs compared to traditional carriers and charter
companies, based on recent analysis released by Boeing and other stakeholders. The
following table (2) shows the airline market status before and after the deregulation.
The above examples show that in both sides of the Atlantic the experiments of the
traditional carriers with their own LCCs were disappointingly unsuccessful. Part of the result
can be explained by the fact that operation of these LCCs was newer low enough, especially
in terms of labor cost. Since this strategy did not bring the expected results, the next
approach was to limit their service contents. However, providing a stripped product would
bring their services closer to the ones offered by LCCs. Since LCCs had a much lower
structural and operational cost, this would have been a very risky strategy. As most
reactions towards LCCs proved to be partly or completely futile, many traditional carriers
tried to compete them by actually avoiding competition; concentrating on long haul flights
and international routes where LCCs were in disadvantage due to legal restrictions. (Vasigh
et al 2008).
6. EUROPEAN AI RPORTS
In ACI’s statistics for 2010, five European airports are among the 15 largest ones. The sizes
of the airports seem to be directly related to long distance flights. Recent research (Gillen
2007), argues that European airports as a whole have three distinct characteristics. First,
there are a large number of airports with scheduled flights, disproportionate to the size or
population of the countries. Countries like Greece, Norway, or Sweden have 38, 51 and 44
airports respectively, while France and Germany have 68 and 48. Second, the density of the
airports results in low utilization. In Ireland, two thirds of the airports serve less than
100,000 passengers annually and this is also true for most French airports. Third, the major
central airports depend on an effective and extensive rail network that expands their
catchment area and allows for combined air and high speed ground travel. The ownership of
the airports varies; Spain, Portugal, Sweden or Greece have publicly funded and operated
airports, while UK has privatized them. In Germany and France airports are in the
responsibility of the local governments.
At regional airports the low revenues are not Airports start t o see passengers as their own
enough t o cover operational expenses. customers as well
Regional airports act as feeders to major Regional airports support their own networks.
airports. Their location is turned into an asset.
After deregulation, airports have started transforming themselves from state controlled and
financed facilities into competitive business units. Flag carriers that enjoyed a dominant
position in major airports and monopolies in regional ones are now forced to share their
former back yard with other carriers, including LCCs (Fageda and Fernandez-Villadangos
2009). This interaction is often accompanied by tension and disagreement (Barrett 2004).
Although LCCs are attractive for airports, they do not have the stability associated with flag
carriers. Airports have to develop scenarios and assess the possibilities of LCcs withdrawing
from destinations or from the market altogether (Gillen and Morrison 2003).
Whatever they may chose airports have no other option than to adjust into the new highly
competitive environment of deregulation and LCCs (Barrett 2004). The value and importance
of an airport for a LCC is based on its location and catchment area. When two or more
airports share the same area, they directly compete with each other. During 2002 Southwest
was invited by more than 140 airports and only very few “lucky ones” were included in the
company’s network (Fageda and Fernandez-Villadangos, 2009). In Europe, LCCs such as
Ryanair are in continuous negotiations with airports. Large airports in the vicinity of
metropolitan areas often sign up attractive contracts with favorable terms and acceptable
collectable fees. On the other hand, abandonment of Rimini in favor of Ancona in Italy by
Ryanair demonstrates the power LCCs exercise over smaller airports. (Fageda and
Fernandez-Villadangos, 2009). Table 4 shows what LCCs demand and what they offer to an
airport in order to establish cooperation.
Traditionally, secondary airports have a limited role either as passenger feeders to central
airports, or as points serving seasonal charter flights (Fageda and Fernandez-Villadangos
2009). LCCs offer the possibility of a more autonomous development with increased
passenger volume and larger catchment area (Lei g Papatheodorou 2010). Airport
managing companies favor the use of secondary airports as supplemental to their main
hubs. This can be observed in cases such as Stansted for Heathrow and Hahn for Frankfurt
(Barrett 2004).
From the passengers’ point of view, the selection of remote airports by LCCs in conjunction
with the other existing airport and airline management strategies has both positive and
negative outcomes. First, it has made lower airfares a reality. Second, it has moved
passengers from congested central hubs to smaller and friendlier facilities. And third, in
many cases it has increased the land travel distances and time (Barrett 2004). Passengers,
including both leisure and business travelers have in general accepted the inconvenient
locations even though many secondary airports are very far away from the metropolitan
areas they are supposed to serve (Lawton 2004). Additionally, the expansion of the
catchment area can lead to overlapping between airports, causing intense competition not
only between main and secondary airports but between regional airports as well. Although
the situation may not be desirable for the airports, it does offer more choices to the
passengers (Francis et al 2003).
The seasonality can also be observed in figure 2, especially in the island airports of
Zakynthos, Santorini, Corfu, and Kos.
It could be argued that even if Ryanair or any other LCC manages to pay very low fees for
the use of the airport of Volos, or if the construction of specific infrastructure becomes an
indirect form of subsidies, the investment could still have significant long term benefits for
the region. This is true for other continental Greek airports as well. Most of them are in
parallel use by civil aviation and military with limited commercial infrastructure. The cost to
further develop these airports is not prohibiting and the excess capacity can be utilized with
relatively limited efforts. Since they are not attractive for traditional carriers and some of
them are not near popular tourist destinations, they could be a good choice for LCCs for two
reasons. First, especially in Greece, even less favorable regions have great potential for
development and are near various interesting sites. Both conditions are met by the airport of
Volos and obviously Ryanair and Air Berlin have taken them into account. Second, charter
operators and mostly the big tour operators do not offer any guarantees or stability
The above example of Volos describes the local perspective and the effects of the local
airport. On the other side of the same issue are the European airports and their prospective
to remain competitive. Any new destination linked to them, is measured in additional
aeronautical and commercial revenues as explained earlier. The strategy of expansion to
new destinations is more critical for secondary airports that have committed to LCCs in order
to remain viable. According to the point-to-point model, the second European member of
the link will be another secondary airport in another country. For each flight from Volos to
Frankfurt Hahn or Milano Bergamo, all three airports have their share in benefits and
revenues. The main items of the negotiations between LCCs and airports and possible
outcomes for each issue are summarized in Table 5.
What LCCs ask from Greek Airports Estimate of Greek airports’ potential
Excess capacity to accommodate increased
Exists or may increase
demand
Fast and effective ground facilities Exist or can be created
Exist due to seasonality and excess
Suitable time slots
capacity
Good local connections I n some cases needs improvement
Limitations in pricing policies due to
Lower airport fees current legislation and ownership of the
airports
Capital assets Can be raised
Enhanced facilities for ground transportation Possible to develop
As a general conclusion from the above table, Greek airports seem to have the potential for
cooperation with LCCs. During the recent past, one of the reasons limiting the ability or the
willingness of the local airports to negotiate openly with LCCs was the legal actions of many
traditional airlines against any contract between LCCs and airports. Their main argument
was that the low fees were in fact disguised public subsidies, forbidden by European aviation
Currently, the initiative is in the hands of the airlines. LCCs evaluate and select routes and
airport pairs based on their own cost and efficiency targets. The authors suggests that it is
in the best interest of the airports to become actively involved in this process and interact
dynamically with airlines and local communities in order to promote or support the
expansion of suitable connections with other cities.
A central issue that determines the relationship between LCCs and airports is the fact that
LCCs demand a long term contract to be signed. Under current legislation, most Greek
airports cannot sign such contracts which may additionally include special clauses. If and
when these obstacles are removed it would be possible for regional airports to offer
incentives to LCCs in order to attract them, as it has happened in other European countries.
Under current status, both the autonomy of the airports as well as their readiness to enter a
more competitive market is questionable. The centrally organized and applied state
management and development schema is considered to be both restrictive and ineffective.
Each airport should be assessed and as a unique business unit in order to select the most
suitable long term strategy.
REFERENCES
‚ ACI (2010), Airports Council International. Official website, last accessed 15/ 09/ 2010
‚ Barrett, S.D. (2004) How do the demands for airport services differ between full-service
carriers and low-cost carriers? Journal of Air Transport Management 10 (2004) pp 33–39
‚ Boeing (2010). Boeing Current Market Outlook 2010-2029, July 2010
‚ Centre for Asia Pacific Aviation (2010). Official website, last accessed 23/ 08/ 2010
‚ Chang, Y., Lee, N. (2010) A Multi-Objective Goal Programming airport selection model
for low-cost carriers’ networks. Transportation Research Part E (2010) (I n press)
‚ Delfmann, W., Baum, H., Auerbach, S. and Albers, S. (2005) Strategic Management in
the Aviation Industry. Ashagate Publishing Company, pp 1-2
‚ European Low Fare Airline Association - EFLAA (2010a). Official website, last accessed
12/07/2010
Michelle Bandeira 1
Department of Air Transport, Aeronautics Institute of Technology, Sao Jose dos
Campos, SP, Brazil
Anderson Correia 2
Department of Air Transport, Aeronautics Institute of Technology, Sao Jose dos
Campos, SP, Brazil
ABSTRACT
1
Michelle Carvalho Galvão da Silva Pinto Bandeira, MSc, is a PhD student at the Aeronautics
I nstitute of Technology. Cont act Details: mgalvao@ita.br.
2
Anderson Ribeiro Correia, PhD, is Professor of Air Transportation and Airports at the
Aeronautics Institute of Technology. Contact Details: correia@ita.br.
1. I NTRODUCTI ON
The airport terminal may be considered a set of subsystems that interact between
themselves to allow a change from land mode to air and vice versa. Various
components are installed and different services are produced around these movements
– passenger departure and/ or arrival – in order to meet client expectations. Some
services and areas of the terminal on general are used by passengers, following the
flow of departure or arrival. A low level of service can result in, besides inconvenience
to terminal users, the waste of resources and increased costs if there is no adequate
planning. Hence, service level targets are important because they have serious
implications for costs and the airport’s economy, as well as the “image” transmitted to
the clients and to society (Bandeira, 2008; Ashford et. al., 1997).
Besides the operational and financial concerns, outlining the profile of passengers at
the airport contributes to the drawing up of a strategic plan for the management of
airport activities. I t is believed that individual characteristics related to the frequency of
flying, the reason for flying, income, age, and other factors may influence the opinion
of the degree of importance or the quality of the services in an airport. The answers to
these questions make all the difference in airport planning and in this article are
expected to broaden this understanding.
2. LI TERATURE REVI EW
Brink and Madison (1975) presented one of the first studies done in the area of airport
service levels. They considered that passengers’ perceptions of the airport terminal,
Despite the important effort made by the researchers and entities cited above, there is
a major lack of studies which research and identify whether there is a significant
relationship between the evaluation of the service level and the social and economic
profile of the users interviewed. This study intends to approach this question, the
development of which will be detailed in the following sections.
3. RESEARCH METHODOLOGY
Field research was carried out through interviews with 270 passengers in departure
lounges at the São Paulo/Guarulhos International Airport between August 2006 and
October 2007. For the size of the sample a 6% error margin was allowed and a
confidence interval of 95%. Initially the degree of importance of the passenger
departure terminal areas at the airport in question was sought, and their respective
indicators. The Analytic Hierarchy Process (AHP) method was employed to get the
degrees of importance for the attributes according to the passengers’ opinion.
A statistical treatment was applied to the sample (for each variable used) to identify
whether the responses were significant as regards the degree of importance of the
indicators linked to these areas. As of this point, it was possible to compare
passengers’ opinions against their different profiles through the AHP method. In
addition, it was checked whether these qualitative variables influenced or not opinion
as to the degree of importance. In this case, the independence test from the Chi-
squared method was used. There follows a description of the methods used for the
current study.
The individual values for each passenger were aggregated in this research in a
geometric average. In the case of an arithmetic average, which gives equal weight to
all the averages, the results would be biased, as there would be a tendency to
disproportionately value a set of weights supplied by the passengers. The Equation (1)
shows the geometrical average used to get the final average of the weights given by
the passengers.
w f (C i ) ? R Pd k
s
s (1)
k ?1
In which:
Ci: Component i;
Pd k : Weight given by the passenger dk;
dk: Passenger (1...k)
s: Number of passengers;
As the AHP method is based on peer to peer comparisons, judgments are put in a
squared matrix n x n, where the lines and columns correspond to the n criteria
analyzed for the problem in question.
supplies the reasons between the weight of the criterion or sub-criterion for the index i
for all the rest. The matrixes are always reciprocal, such that a ? 1 , and positive.
ij
a ji
given the criterion for the column j , where only the principal diagonal assumes values
equal to 1. Peer to peer comparisons are made at all levels of the matrix A. Therefore,
if all the judgments are perfect, in all comparisons it would be possible to see that
a ij · a jk ? a ik , for any i, j, k = 1. ..., n, therefore, following this procedure, matrix A,
would be consistent.
The inconsistency can be measured in the following way: the closer the nmáx value is to
n , the greater the consistency of the judgments. Saaty (1980) showed that A being a
value matrix, the vector that satisfies Equation (2) will be found.
CW ? nmáxxW (2)
In which:
A: Decision matrix;
máx: Maximum autovalue of A;
W: Autovector of A associated to máx.
After the normalization of W, in (2), the auto-value máx is gotten from Equation (3).
n máx ? Â
1 n [ Aw]i
(3)
n i?1 wi
In which:
A: Decision matrix;
máx: Maximum autovalue of A;
W: Autovector of A associated to máx;
n: Order of the decision matrix;
Wi: Normalized Vector W.
It was observed, furthermore, that small variations in aij caused small variations in
nmáx, in which the auto-vector’s deviation in regard to n (the order of the matrix
number) is considered a measurement of consistency. I t can be said that the auto-
vector gives the order of priority and the auto-value is the measurement of consistency
So, if “ A is consistent if, and only if máx = n”, the value ( máx – n) is an indicator of the
consistency of judgments after the formation of A and the obtaining of normalized W.
The closer to zero such a difference is, the greater the consistency of judgments will
be. It must be stressed that this value must serve as a warning to the decider and/or
analyst, not only as an excluding situation. Therefore, the magnitude of the
perturbation in matrix A is calculated using the relation of the Equation (4).
n máx / n
CI ?
n /1
(4)
Based on the theorems describes, Saaty (1980) proposed the calculation of the reason
of consistency (CR) for the decision matrix A in Equation (5).
CR ?
CI
(5)
IR
In which:
CR: Consistency ratio;
CI : Consistency Index;
IR: Random Index.
The greater the CR, the greater the inconsistency of the matrix will be. Generally, an
inconsistency considered acceptable for n > 4 is a CR 0.10. The random index has
been calculated for matrixes squared by an order of n by the Oak Ridge National
Laboratory, in the United States (Saaty, 1991; 2005). Table 3 shows the values for IR
for the matrixes of order n x n.
nxn 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
IR 0 0 0.58 0.89 1.11 1.25 1.35 1.40 1.45 1.49
p i ( A1 ) ?
Âa
a ij
n
(6)
i ?1
ij
Âpi( A )
n
p i ( Aj ) ?
j ?1
j
(7)
n
In which:
p:
i: 1...., n;
Vector ;
A: Criterion for the second level (sub-criterion s);
n: Nº of criteria for one and the same level.
x j (C i ) ?
ÂC
C ij
m
(8)
i ?1
ij
x (Ci ) ? Â
m
x i (Ci )
(9)
j ?1 m
In which:
x :
j: 1...., m;
Vector;
C: First level criterion;
m: Nº of criteria for one and the same level.
Finally, a process of aggregation allows the generation of final values for the weights
of the airport components, ordering them through the following additive function of the
Equation (10).
f (Aj ) = Â w(Ci ) · vi ( Aj )
m
(10)
i ?1
In which:
j: 1...., m;
For the purposes of calculation, the areas of the terminal were designated with criteria
for the first level, and their respective indicators in criteria for the second level or sub-
criteria. The modeling indicated the importance and intensity of each one of the airport
terminal components.
The first situation was to verify whether the percentage of equivalence found in the
binary comparisons was statistically significant. Hence, a designation was made for
each binary correlation for the number n of interviews in the sample and the
parameters m, P1 e P2. which were calculated according to the frequency f observed for
a certain airport component, if it was equivalent or preferable to the other.
In which:
P1: Population proportion regarding the first element of the binary comparison;
P2: Population proportion regarding the second element of the binary
comparison;
m: Population proportion regarding the equivalence of the binary comparison;
In this case, there is the first test of the hypothesis, in which the nullity hypothesis is
H0: m P1 + P2 and the alternative hypothesis is H1: m > P1 + P2. where P1 and P2 are
popuational proportions from the sample, and m is equal to the proportion of the
sample when in comparison between two airport components. This test evaluated
whether the degree of equivalence (equality) between the components was statistically
significant, considering g = 5%. Therefore, the nullity hypothesis was only rejected if
Z* < - Z5% ., where Z* is the confidence interval.
For the rejected hypothesis H0. the second hypothesis test is applied, with H0’: P1 = P2
e H1’: P1"Œ P2. to verify whether there had been any significant differences between the
proportions isolated for preference in airport components observed in the binary
comparisons. Hence, the nullity hypothesis was rejected if ÍZÍ > Z2.5% , with g = 5%.
Therefore, in this second situation the hypothesis H0’: P1 = P2 is accepted if a
component does not present relative preponderance in a comparison; or H0’ is rejected
if one component is preferable to another one.
The main principle of this method is to compare proportions; that is, the possible
divergences between the frequencies observed and expected for a certain event.
Hence, it can be said that two groups behave in a similar way if the differences
between these frequencies in each category are very small or close to zero (Spiegel,
1972).
One measurement of the discrepancy between the frequencies observed and those
expected is provided by the statistic e2. expressed by Equation 11. The results obtained
are in the Contingency Table.
*oi / ei + 2
e2sample Â
k
= (11)
i ?1 ei
In which:
oi : Frequency observed;
ei : Frequency expected;
k: 1...., k;
i: 1...., i;
For the application of the method, it is necessary that the sample be relatively large
with sample N > 40 or at least 5 observations in each plot formed by the variable
analyzed. Furthermore, the data analyzed must be independent of each other and the
observations must have frequencies or counts where each observation belongs to one
and only one category.
It is stressed that if the significant value of e2 was gotten from one small sample (N <
40) and/or from a small expected frequency in a plot (typically when less than 5) for
formula for the obtaining of e2 may produce a greater-than-real value (Spiegel, 1972).
In this case the Yates Correction must be applied (or a continuity correction). The
statistics for the test are shown in Equation 12.
So that ec2 is the critical Chi-squared measurement with degrees of liberty GL given as
in Equation 13:
GL = (l-1)* (c-1) (13)
In which:
l: Number of lines formed by the classes for one variable x;
c: Number of columns formed by classes for a variable y;
That is, for the current research, the hypotheses cited indicated:
The inherent characteristic for the passenger does not influence the
H0:
opinion given to the degree of importance of the airport component.
The inherent characteristic for the passenger does influence the opinion
H1:
given to the degree of importance of the airport component.
So, from the null independence hypothesis, H0 is accepted when the value of e2sample
found is less than or equal to the value of ec2 designated. H0 is rejected when the value
of e2sample is greater than the value of ec2 designated. In the latter, H1 is accepted and
it is assumed that the variables in question present a dependency relationship.
Through analysis of these results it was possible to ascertain that the consistency
ration (CR) for the resultant matrixes is within the limit recommended by Saaty (1990;
1991). Hence, the results found through the AHP method are significant.
The check-in and departure lounge areas were given the highest values; that is, both
areas jointly represent 58% of the degree of global importance for TPS. This is why
the next step is to analyze whether the qualitative characteristics (income, age, travel
frequency, and reason for travel) have an influence in passengers’ decision making as
to the degree of importance.
Firstly, the percentages “greater importance” and “equal importance” among the
indicators were observed in terms of how significant they were. This analysis was
necessary, as the intention was to demonstrate whether there is a dependency
association in the results of these observations and the passenger’s qualitative
characteristics. Finally, the “Chi-Squared Method” was used by means of the
independence test, for the composition of the final results.
CHECK IN
41.85%
40.74%
17.41%
In which:
Figure 3 indicates the percentage of importance for the indicators for the departure
lounge area. Most interviewees attributed greater importance to comfort in relation to
the service offered by the airline’s staff.
29.26%
25.93%
I s Z significant for c =
Number of Passengers 5% ?
A M B n ( A+ B) m ( P1+ P2) Z* Results
DEPARTURE
comfort equivalence service
LOUNGE
121 79 70 270 191 0.293 0.707 -14.982 Reject H0
Tables 6 and 7 present the hypotheses tests that proved the significant difference in
the percentages found for the departure lounge area. The results indicate that there is
In which:
At the check in, the group of people with an income above US$ 80,000/ year gave
greater importance to the indicator for processing time, while the group of people with
an income of up to US$ 40,000/year gave greater importance to service. In the
departure lounge the group of people with an income above US$ 80,000/year gave
greater importance to the indicator comfort; while the group of people with an income
of up to US$ 40,000/ year gave greatest importance to service.
Given the preference among passengers according to the classes designated for
household income, the Chi-Squared Method was used to ascertain whether this
variable influenced passengers’ opinion. To such an end, contingency tables were
drawn up with the expected and observed values – Tables 8 and 9 – for the check-in
and departure lounge areas. All the results in both tables accept the hypothesis H0
concluding that passenger income does not influence opinion on the degree of
importance given to indicators for the check-in and departure lounge.
e4 Total= 6.99
Total 113 110 47 270
e4 Tabled g= 5% = 9.48 e GL = 4
1
wait time é less important than the service at the counter
2
wait time and service at the counter are of equal importance
3
wait time is more important than the service at the counter
e4 partial
Expected value 21.26 23.99 36.75
0.03 0.37 0.14
More than US$ 80,000 11 22 34 67 0.25
e4 partial
Expected value 17.37 19.60 30.03
2.34 0.29 0.53
Total 70 79 121 270
e4 Total= 5.43
e4 Tabled g= 5% = 9.48 e GL = 4
1 comfort is less important than the service at the counter
2 comfort and service at the counter are of equal importance
3 comfort is more important than the service at the counter
Given the preference among passengers according to the classes designated for age,
the Chi-Squared Method was used to ascertain whether this variable influenced
passengers’ opinion. To such an end, contingency tables were drawn up with the
expected and observed values – Tables 10 and 11 – for the check-in a departure
lounge areas.
e4 partial
Expected value 37.37 42.77 17.86
1.45 1.58 0.04
e4 partial corrected 1.26 1.40 0.01
Between 30 and 50 46 50 20 116 0.49
e4 partial
Expected value 44.24 50.63 21.14
0.07 0.01 0.06
e4 partial corrected 0.04 0.00 0.02
Over 50 14 2 6 22 0.09
e4 partial
Expected value 8.39 9.60 4.01
3.75 6.02 0.99
e4 partial corrected 3.11 5.25 0.55
e4 Tabled g= 5% = 9.48 e GL = 4
1
wait time é less important than the service at the counter
2
wait time and service at the counter are of equal importance
3
wait time is more important than the service at the counter
e4 partial
Expected value 27.82 30.31 39.86
0.17 0.18 0.00
Between 30 and 50 46 50 20 116 0.49
Expected value 44.24 50.63 21.14
e4 partial 0.07 0.01 0.06
Over 50 4 6 12 22 0.09
e4 partial
Expected value 6.25 6.81 8.95
0.81 0.10 1.04
e4 Total= 2.77
Total 67 73 96 236
e4 Tabled g= 5% = 9.48 e GL = 4
1
comfort is less important than the service at the counter
2
comfort and service at the counter are of equal importance
3
comfort is more important than the service at the counter
The result presented in Table 10 for the check-in area rejects the nullity hypothesis
and accepts hypothesis H1. That is, it concludes that age interferes in passengers’
opinion about the degree of importance of the indicators wait time and service at the
counter. For the departure lounge area the result in Table 11 accepts the hypothesis
H0, where we can conclude that passenger age does not influence opinion about the
degree of importance given to the indicators for the departure lounge.
In the departure lounge area, while the passengers travelling for family reasons gave
greater importance to the indicator service, others, traveling for business and pleasure,
preferred comfort. Given the preference among passengers according to the classes
designated for the reason for travelling, the Chi-Squared Method was used to ascertain
whether this variable influenced passengers’ opinion. To such an end, contingency
tables were drawn up with the expected and observed values – Tables 12 and 13 – for
the check-in and departure lounge areas.
e4 Tabled g= 5% = 9.48 e GL = 4
1
wait time is less important than the service at the counter
2
wait time and service at the counter are of equal importance
3
wait time is more important than the service at the counter
The result presented in Table 12 for the check-in area rejects the nullity hypothesis
and accepts hypothesis H1. That is it concludes that the reason for traveling – Business,
Pleasure or Family - interferes in passengers’ opinion about the degree of importance
of the indicators wait time and service at the counter.
e4 partial
Expected value 25.84 30.07 45.10
0.18 0.85 0.19
Pleasure 18 29 41 88 0.41
e4 partial
Expected value 22.51 26.20 39.29
0.90 0.30 0.07
Family 7 15 4 26 0.12
e4 partial
Expected value 11.13 10.16 4.72
1.53 2.31 0.11
e4 Total= 5.82
Total 55 64 96 215
e4 Tabled g= 5% = 9.48 e GL = 4
1
comfort is less important than the service at the counter
2
comfort and service at the counter are of equal importance
3
comfort is more important than the service at the counter
It was noted that in the check-in area the group that travels only 1 time/ year gave
greater importance to service, unlike the other groups. In the departure lounge area it
was noted that people who travelled more than 6 times/ year gave greater importance
to the indicator comfort, unlike those who travelled only 1 time/year. Such a difference
could be explained by the greater demands made by passengers that travel more
frequently, as they spend longer inside the terminal.
Given the preference among passengers according to the classes designated for age,
the Chi-Squared Method was used to ascertain whether this variable influenced
passengers’ opinion. To such an end, contingency tables were drawn up with the
expected and observed values – Tables 14 and 15 – for the check-in and departure
lounge areas.
e4 partial
Expected value 26.23 25.76 11.01
2.58 1.51 0.36
From 2 to 6x/ year. 71 63 25 159 0.59
e4 partial
Expected value 66.20 65.02 27.78
0.35 0.06 0.28
More than 6x/ year 23 15 9 47 0.17
e4 partial
Expected value 19.57 19.22 8.21
0.60 0.93 0.08
e4 Total = 6.74
Total 112 110 47 269
e4 Tabled g= 5% = 9.48 e GL = 4
1
wait time is less important than the service at the counter
2
wait time tem equal importance than the service at the counter
3
wait time is more important than the service at the counter
The result indicated in Table 14 for the check-in area accepts hypothesis H0, where we
can conclude that frequency of travel for passengers at São Paulo / Guarulhos
International Airport does not influence opinion on the degree of importance for the
indicators wait time and service at the counter.
For the departure lounge area, the result found in Table 15 rejects the nullity
hypothesis and accepts hypothesis H1. That is, it concludes that frequency of travel at
the airport studied does interfere in passengers’ opinion on the degree of importance
of the indicators wait time and service at the counter.
e4 partial
Expected value 16.39 18.50 28.10
5.63 0.66 1.33
From 2 to 6x/ year. 35 50 74 159 0.59
e4 partial
Expected value 41.38 46.70 70.93
0.98 0.23 0.13
More than 6x/ year 9 14 24 47 0.17
e4 partial
Expected value 12.23 13.80 20.97
0.85 0.00 0.44
e4 Total= 10.26
Total 70 79 120 269
e4 Tabled g= 5% = 9.48 e GL = 4
1
comfort is less important than the service at the counter
2
comfort is of equal importance to the service at the counter
3
comfort is more important than the service at the counter
7. CONCLUSI ONS
The passengers’ opinions on the degree of importance of the components are required
in order to be able to prioritize services. Furthermore, it has become necessary to get
information on the quality of the services and/ or map the profile of the passengers
interviewed in order to contribute to the management of the airport as regards
decision making.
There have been many studies that have reported the relationship that exists between
individual characteristics and the perception of passengers about the degree of
importance or about the quality of the services at an airport. However, these studies
have not statistically proven whether this hypothesis is significant in their analyses.
This proof could make a big difference when resources are limited or if a new airport
terminal is being planned. Therefore, knowing that individual characteristics influence
passengers’ perception contributes more precisely to airport planning.
Unlike other studies, this article has presented, in a pioneering form, a qualitative
analysis of the relationship between the passengers’ profiles and their perception of
the airport terminal. The results obtained have made it possible to ascertain whether
there was dependency or independency between the individual characteristics of the
Finally, it can be said that this kind of analysis can achieve great results in airport
planning projects which are designed to direct their resources to a certain passenger
audience or to attract potential clients with a certain profile. We suggest that airport
operators develop this kind of analysis periodically, since variations on the competitive
scenario, economic development, and airport passengers´ profile might have an
important influence on the passenger perceptions. However, the methodology provided
in this paper is robust and valid under different scenarios.
REFERENCES
‚ Ashford, N.; Stanton, H. P. M.; Moore, C. A. (1997), Airport Operations. New York:
McGraw-Hill, 2nd. Ed.
‚ Airports Council I nternational (2000), Quality of service at airports: standards &
measurements. Geneva, Switzerland: ACI World Headquarters.
‚ Bandeira, M. C. G. da S. P. (2008) Análise do nível de serviço em terminais de
passageiros aeroportuários. Tese de Mestrado. Instituto Tecnológico de
Aeronáutica, São José dos Campos, pp.134.
‚ Bandeira, M. C. G. da S. P. ; Correia, A.R. ; Wirasinghe, S. C. (2007), Degree of
importance of airport passenger terminal components and their attributes. In: Air
Transport Research Society, Annual World Conference, Berkeley, CA, v.1, pp.1-13.
‚ Brink, M.; Maddison, D. (1975), Identification and measurement of capacity levels
of service of landside elements of the airport. In Airport Landside Capacity.
Transportation Research Board, Washington, D.C., TRB, Special Report 159: pp.92-
111.
‚ Correia, A. R. (2009), Evaluation of level of service at airport passenger terminals.
Koln: Lap Lambert, 1st. Ed.
‚ Gomes. L. F. A. M.; Araya, M. C. G.; Carignano, C. (2004), Tomada de decisões em
cenários complexos: introdução aos métodos discretos do apoio multicritério de
decisão. São Paulo: Thomson.