Innovation Effectuation and Uncertainty
Innovation Effectuation and Uncertainty
Innovation Effectuation and Uncertainty
To cite this article: Joel A. Ryman & David C. Roach (2022): Innovation, effectuation, and
uncertainty, Innovation, DOI: 10.1080/14479338.2022.2117816
To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/14479338.2022.2117816
ARTICLE
a
College of Business, California State University, Monterey Bay, CA, USA; bRowe School of Business,
Dalhousie University, Halifax, Nova Scotia, Canada
Uncertainty. This concept has been imbedded in both the entrepreneurship and innovation
literatures dating back to classical and neoclassical economics (Casson et al., 2006). This
interdependent relationship was formalised in the works of Knight (1921) and Schumpeter
(1934), who together see the entrepreneur as bearing uncertainty in the innovation process.
The former emphasises uncertainty as a precondition for entrepreneurship, while the latter
focuses on the relationship between the entrepreneur and innovation (Antonelli, 2015;
Brouwer, 2000). Adding to the debate is that in many cases, the innovative individual is
often interpreted as the innovative entrepreneur (Varis & Littunen, 2010). This leads to
questions as to whether entrepreneurship can really exist without innovation, or whether
novelty and invention can ever be considered innovation if they are not commercially or
socially adopted? Academics (Alsos et al., 2019; McKelvie et al., 2019) and practitioners
(Drucker, 1954; Ries, 2011) alike have debated, discussed, and theorised about this relation
ship, however, there still remains much to be learned about the complex influence of
uncertainty in the innovation and entrepreneurship process.
As a result, it may be more useful to reframe the narrative of uncertainty from the
domain of entrepreneurship to that of innovation management and examine innovation
through an effectuation lens to separate uncertainty and risk, wherein innovation man
agement is about reducing uncertainty, while the entrepreneurial process is about
managing uncertainty to a point where risk can be assessed. Under this approach,
effectuation’s means (i.e., who, what and whom I know; Sarasvathy, 2001) become the
resources available to the entrepreneur to carry out their role. The firm’s ability to engage
in an iterative cycle of experimentation and to leverage contingencies then become
uncertainty management rather than risk management capabilities. Pursuing this line of
logic, managing innovation is fundamentally about reducing uncertainty (Mansoori &
Lackéus, 2019), to a point where the entrepreneur can assess the risk of the innovation-
driven venture. Paradoxically, uncertainty is necessary because it creates opportunity
from the innovation system through a process of experimentation (Thomke, 2020).
The objective of this paper is twofold. First, the entrepreneurship and innovation
literatures are reviewed to delineate the role of the entrepreneur from that of the
innovator, establishing their roles in the management of uncertainty and risk. Using
this approach, effectuation theory is disaggregated into its uncertainty and risk compo
nents in an effort to delineate their effects. Second, using data collected from the
innovation processes of 169 US SMEs, we propose and test an exploratory empirical
model which distinguishes uncertainty from risk and its impact on innovation perfor
mance. Once uncertainty and risk management aspects are isolated, their various rela
tionships to innovation and firm performance can be investigated.
Theoretical background
Innovation and entrepreneurship
The roots of innovation theory are usually attributed to Schumpeter (1934) and Knight
(1921). Schumpeter stresses innovation, while Knight emphasises uncertainty as pre
conditions for entrepreneurship (Brouwer, 2000).
At its core Schumpeter’s life works focuses on the relationship between the entrepreneur
and innovation (Antonelli, 2015), where innovation is defined in terms of product (or
service), process, organisation or markets. Furthermore, his innovative individual is often
interpreted as the innovative entrepreneur (McMullen & Shepherd, 2006; Varis & Littunen,
2010). In a Schumpeterian world, the initial innovations are first created by the most
talented and rare entrepreneurs, whose success subsequently encourages the lesser talented
to follow. Invention is the precursor to innovation and may create the components of
innovation only if these are sufficiently evolved to become viable and ready for adoption
(Casson, 1982). At some point, the stock of invention is depleted, creating a lull in waves of
innovation in a process of creative destruction. In Schumpeter’s (1947) later and lesser-
known work, he synthesises the origins, causes and consequences of innovation, emphasis
ing the concept of ‘creative reaction’ as a driver of innovation (Antonelli, 2015).
Knight on the other hand emphasises the entrepreneur as the recipient of profit for bearing
the cost of uncertainty (Casson, 1982; McMullen & Shepherd, 2006). He distinguishes
uncertainty from risk as the situation where the probabilities of alternate outcomes cannot
be determined a priori, since there is no precedent to assess probability. This uncertainty is
4 J. A. RYMAN AND D. C. ROACH
pervasive to business choices, where decisions on inputs must be made before future outputs
are known. He sees the entrepreneur as the central contractual agent who must implement an
action plan, where residual ‘pure profit’ is a return on good judgment or in some cases simply
pure luck (Casson et al., 2006). Thus, the entrepreneur’s differential quality is their good
judgment and ability to foresight, which he considers scarce.
Building upon Schumpeter, Knight and others, Shane and Venkataraman (2000) posit that
entrepreneurship is less concerned with business performance and more concerned with the
identification, evaluation and exploitation of opportunities. This opportunity-centric vision of
entrepreneurship aligns well with the Schumpeterian view that economic growth is driven by
the recognition of new opportunities, and captured through innovation (Kirchhoff et al.,
2013). They argue that entrepreneurship does not necessarily follow a rational planned
process, where identification always precedes evaluation. Missing from this argument is the
system of crafting innovations into opportunities which we contend is a process of uncertainty
reduction to a point where risk can be assessed. In his opinion, ‘all efforts to exploit
opportunities involve some innovation’ (Shane, 2012, p. 18) and those entrepreneurs are
the bearers of uncertainty and in some instances may prefer uncertainty. This perspective does
not, however, delineate innovation from entrepreneurship, leaving the emerging theory of
effectuation to shed light on the role of uncertainty in the entrepreneurial process. As a result,
we will argue that it does not fully explain the role of uncertainty in the innovation manage
ment process.
artefacts as the goal of an innovation process. These creative processes fundamentally reduce
uncertainty through what we argue are the embedded innovation practices of these effectual
firms.
What is clear from the literature is that the concept of innovation cannot be separated from
that of the entrepreneur, since they are interdependent and synergistic. Effectuation releases
entrepreneurs from specific, predetermined goals and allows them to convert uncertainty into
opportunity (Deligianni et al., 2017). Without the entrepreneur, innovations will remain
merely inventions or lost opportunities. Without innovation inputs and supporting systems,
the entrepreneur will be unable to configure the innovations into opportunities. Thus, by
integrating these arguments it may leave room for processes that allow innovations to emerge
via an effectual approach rather than a systematic causal approach. However, literature to date
has not explained how these mechanisms interact. This suggests that the main consequence of
effectuation might be the reduction of uncertainty for a given innovation and that future
research should consider how to operationalise uncertainty as a variable.
For effectuation to become a mature theory, it will have to delve deeply into uncertainty
reduction (Alsos et al., 2019). McKelvie et al. (2019) argue that in circumstances of high
uncertainty, effectuation decision-making processes may be associated with better outcomes.
Although their argument is compelling, they admit that ‘it has not been adequately adopted
in the extant literature thus far – and certainly has not been exhaustively empirically tested’
(McKelvie et al., 2019, p. 27). Loch et al. (2008), argue that research to date has insufficiently
addressed the a priori identification of the type of uncertainty faced by a new venture using
the term “unforeseeable uncertainty”, which they argue is only manageable through either
selectionism – trial and error experimentation or probe-and-learn questioning. Mansoori
and Lackéus (2019) refer to this as uncertainty management, where a condition of insuffi
cient information exists in what is referred to as blind risk (Mazzarol & Reboud, 2017) where
iterative information gathering is necessary to increase the odds. Deligianni et al. (2017)
found that effectuation may provide a helpful explanation leading them to call for transfer
ring effectuation to other areas of entrepreneurship research and call for improvements in
measurement tools to move effectuation research to a more advanced state.
With effectuation emerging as one of the few theories from within the domain of
entrepreneurship and that uncertainty is central to all of the works examined (Alsos et al.,
2019), it stands to reason that disaggregating uncertainty from other aspects, such as risk,
should make a significant contributions to both the effectuation discussion and to broader
literature on uncertainty’ (Alsos et al., 2019, p. 11).
Hypothesis development
Uncertainty reduction through flexible experimentation
Experimentation has been shown to positively affect strategic outcomes (Brettel et al., 2012)
and as a means of coping with uncertainty (Deligianni et al., 2017; Thomke, 2020).
Uncertainty thus can only be effectively managed through a flexible experimental process
that converts assumptions into facts (Mansoori & Lackéus, 2019). As a result, the application
of experimentation is the initial step in an effectual innovation process because it demarcates
the problem space. By carving out this fertile cognitive space from what Sarasvathy described
as, ‘the relatively unexplored jungle where goal ambiguity, Knightian uncertainty, and
6 J. A. RYMAN AND D. C. ROACH
endogenous markets dominate the landscape’ (Sarasvathy, 2003, p. 206), the firm can begin to
develop a variety of innovation hypotheses. The process of generating ‘ideas’ and then testing
hypotheses through collaborations with partners, is the work of the design synthesis process
(Kolko, 2010). Design synthesis, is an iterative process where novel design hypotheses are
imagined (ideation), evaluated, prioritised, and ultimately, selected. Design synthesis is
essentially a way to apply abductive logic within the confines of an innovation problem
(Coyne, 1988). Abduction has been defined as the adopting of a hypothesis that has been
inferred from incomplete (or uncertain) information (Weiss & Burks, 1958). It is effective
in situations of uncertainty because it does not rely on complete information, but instead
allows gaps in knowledge to be covered by ‘best guesses’ and logical leaps (Kolko, 2010).
According to Latham and Braun (2009) traditional structures, processes and routines tend to
suppress the flexibility required to implement innovation activities. Thus, organisational
flexibility is required to expose uncertainty in an effort to enhance innovation concepts. As
a result,
uncertainty reduction, take on a risk management role. SMEs in particular, due to their
liability of smallness, benefit from collaborations that jointly leverage resources to mitigate
risks (Gnyawali & Park, 2009). This is accomplished through distributing the risk of innova
tion to external partners.
Antecedent to these entrepreneurial pre-commitments is an innovation process that is
experimental, collaborative, and flexible. This uncertainty reducing process results in proto
types that are now increasingly viable. Thus, these pre-commitments rely upon a flexible
innovation process which has systematically reduced uncertainty to a point where risk can be
assessed, quantified, and perhaps mitigated. Thus, pre-commitments play an important role
because they rely on the discipline of the innovation process to ensure that the co-developed
innovation has greater potential to be adopted. Thus, in an effectual process, the gaining or
withholding of pre-commitments by innovation partners is based on risk assessment. Pre-
commitments thus act as an ‘investment’ of resources by the partner in an effort to reduce
their risk exposure. Thus,
Risk management
Risk management has to do with quantifying uncertainty a priori allowing firms to make
decisions divorced of much of the uncertainty surrounding the innovation. Affordable loss in
the context of effectuation presents itself as how firms proactively assume or mitigate risk
(Thaler et al., 1997). Pre-commitments on the other hand involves sharing and mitigating risk
through partnerships. In either case, these risk mitigation strategies should have little or no
impact on the performance of the innovation, thus,
managers (e.g., General Managers through to CEOs). These senior executives were
deemed the best candidates based on their familiarity with both the innovation activities
of the firm and overall organisational performance. After elimination incomplete
responses, this method resulted in 169 responses, which translates into a response rate
of 2.03% of the total population (N = 8295). This relatively low response rate is due to the
nature of the survey (i.e., an online survey to senior executives of SMEs). As a result, the
analysis was assessed for the possible occurrence of common method bias by examining
the factor-level VIFs. In every case, the related VIFs did not exceed 3.3 (Kock, 2015),
supporting that common method bias did not materially impact the results.
Table 2. Fornell-Larcker.
1 2 3 4 5 6 7
1. Affordable Loss 1.00
2. Experimentation 0.12 0.79
3. Firm Performance 0.29 0.22 0.77
4. Flexibility 0.29 0.65 0.44 0.74
5. Innovation Performance 0.23 0.34 0.35 0.73 0.72
6. Partnerships 0.16 0.27 0.29 0.45 0.31 0.71
7. Precommitments 0.19 0.09 0.29 0.29 0.16 0.56 0.74
Theoretical implications
This study is one of the few that has connected effectuation and innovation theory.
In doing so, it develops a model of innovation that connects effectual processes to
an underlying framework of innovation. It has shown that these effectual beha
viours yield the important benefit of enhanced innovation performance. This, we
believe, is a significant theoretical contribution to both the effectuation and inno
vation literatures, by creating a fledgling bridge between entrepreneurship and
innovation theory. This paper also addresses some of the shortcomings of effectua
tion theory and builds upon Sarasvathy and others (e.g., Dew et al., 2008b) who
assert that effectuation at its core involves uncertainty management. It establishes
a link between effectuation theory and the innovation process of firms (Dew et al.,
2008a) and indicates that effectuation theory has application beyond the strict
confines of entrepreneurship literature (Dew et al., 2008b). This provides an
opportunity to connect with other relevant literatures as espoused by Arend et al.
(2015).
This exploratory study also indicates that risk and uncertainty impact firm perfor
mance in different ways. Risk management impacts firm performance directly, while
uncertainty management impacts firm performance through the performance of the
innovation itself. Firms that embrace flexible experimentation and collaborative discov
ery can adapt to contingencies and enjoy higher levels of innovation performance. Firms
that manage risk throughout the innovation process perform better than those who
merely innovate for the sake of innovation. Together, these aspects appear to ultimately
amplify firm performance. This study, however, does not discern between the various
aspects of uncertainty and risk, nor the various dimensions of innovation beyond
product/service innovation. Uncertainty is a multi-dimensional construct that pervades
the literatures of entrepreneurship, innovation, and beyond. Unlike environmental
uncertainty that dominates the entrepreneurship literature (Kreiser & Marino, 2002;
Ting et al., 2012) our constructs appear to measure market and technological uncertainty
(Jalonen, 2012; Reymen et al., 2017; Song & Montoya-Weiss, 2001) as it relates to
products and services, however no effort has been made to discern between them.
Neither does our model tackle the pandora’s box of risk. In our model, risk is measured
through two narrow constructs, namely pre-commitments and affordable loss. The
former measures the partners commitment to the innovation process once risk has
been assessed, while the latter measures how much the firm is willing to bet –
a somewhat narrow and controversial aspect of risk management (Martina, 2019). In
any event, our model perhaps opens the door a crack for deeper understanding into how
uncertainty and risk interact within innovation and entrepreneurship.
INNOVATION: ORGANIZATION & MANAGEMENT 15
Managerial implications
In his aptly title article – Managers fail to innovate and academics fail to explain
how, Dougherty (2018) suggests that managers tend to avoid uncertain activities –
specifically innovation and that academics need to probe more deeply into the root
causes of this phenomena. Others contend that the main difference between non-
entrepreneurial and entrepreneurial decision-making lies in the latter’s perception of
risk from this uncertainty (Alvarez & Barney, 2005). As a result, they contend that
entrepreneurs may rely more on their perception of risk rather than the objective
properties of the risk itself.
Our results indicate that an effectual approach to innovation appears to have an
impact on innovation performance. It suggests that uncertainty reduction through
collaboration with network partners, combined with experimental and flexible processes,
leads to superior innovation performance. Our study establishes that the collaborative
and iterative ways in which firms develop their products or services should ultimately
impact the performance of their innovation. Risk on the other hand, is a necessary
process of assessing the innovation once uncertainty has been reduced to a point
where risk can be assessed in some fashion. The correct role of partners in enhancing
the innovation process is through risk reduction leading to a pre-commitment of
resources. This is central to the ultimate performance of the firm. From a practitioner’s
perspective, the right mix of partnerships, pre-commitments and risk tolerance may be
a more optimal way to approach innovation management.
Our model also suggests that it may be practical to segregate uncertainty and risk
at the entrepreneurship–innovation interface. Neither entrepreneurship nor innova
tion theory clearly delineate between the role of the innovator and that of the
entrepreneur. Much like the relationship between the entrepreneur and the capital
ist, where sometimes the entrepreneur acts as their own capitalist and assumes risk,
it could be argued that when the innovator moves from their uncertainty reduction
role into assessing risk, they cross the boundary and take on the entrepreneurship
role. Under this scenario, the individual that has the capability as an innovator, may
or may not have the capability to execute at the same level when they take on the
entrepreneurship role, or vice versa. For instance, assessing risk, with its many
dimensions, is a different skill set than, for instance, reducing technical uncertainty.
Just as the entrepreneur may not have the capability to be a capitalist, neither can
we assume that the innovator has the capability to be an entrepreneur. Thus
practitioners, whether capitalist, entrepreneurs or innovators may want to critically
assess their capabilities before taking on a role that they may be ill-suite for. This
role confusion likely affects both the performance of the innovation process and that
of the entrepreneurial firm.
Limitations
Most of the entrepreneurship literature tends to emphasise environmental uncertainty
(Bstieler & Gross, 2003; Freel, 2005; Kreiser & Marino, 2002; Milliken, 1987). Our model,
on the other hand, focuses on product or service innovation, based on technological and
market uncertainty (Reymen et al., 2017; Song & Montoya-Weiss, 2001). These uncertainty
16 J. A. RYMAN AND D. C. ROACH
themes appear to be based on both market adoption uncertainty (i.e., is there value to the end
user) and technical uncertainty (i.e., will the product or service perform as expected). As
affirmed by McKelvie et al. (2011) researchers should ‘take more care when describing the
specific type of uncertainty that is operationalized in their research’ (p. 275). Our model
unfortunately does not test other aspects of uncertainty, nor does it determine which aspects
of technological or market uncertainty drive the model. This results in a significant limitation
to the study, so care should be taken when interpreting the results of this exploratory research.
Future research should attempt to separate technological and market uncertainty as indepen
dent variables to establish their impact on innovation performance.
Also, according to Alsos et al. (2019), effectuation’s focus on reducing uncertainty may
precede causational steps such as management and optimisation of risk. Our study did not
account for the fact that effectuation and causational approaches may be used interchangeably
in an organisation depending on the outcomes sought (Reymen et al., 2017). Effectuation may
not be appropriate in all decision-making contexts that involve uncertainty and thus research
must continue to fill the gaps by more fully addressing the boundary conditions of extant
studies and measures. In circumstances of high levels of uncertainty, entrepreneurs may be
more likely to use effectual decision-making processes, preferring to use causation decision-
making processes where uncertainty is low (McKelvie et al., 2019). Lower market and
technological uncertainty is often followed by an increase in the use of causal logic (Reymen
et al., 2017). These may be associated with better outcomes, leading Alsos et al. (2019) to
suggest that entrepreneurs should ‘do effectuation when facing uncertainty and do causation
when facing risk’ (p. 11). Our study only reports on effectual outcomes and makes no attempt
to link our results to causational approaches to uncertainty and risk management.
This research also acknowledges that network collaborations change over time as the firm
develops increased capability to negotiate more attractive terms (Rosenbusch et al., 2011)
which can influence innovation performance. There are also many other internal factors that
could impact the nature of collaborations including investment structure, absorptive capacity,
collaboration experience and customer relationship capability. External factors such as net
work type, industry lifecycle and market turbulence among others could also impact results
(Fernández-Olmos & Ramírez-Alesón, 2017). Thus, the nature of the collaboration has not
been explicitly measured nor controlled for in this study.
Given the exploratory nature of our study, there are numerous other limitations. Our
results are country and industry specific, since we relied exclusively on data collected from
firms in the United States in a specific sector – namely computer and electronic product
manufacturing. Our measurement instrument (see Appendix 1) is also based on a specific
definition of innovation, namely product of service innovation. As a result, this study does not
address the breadth of innovation areas as espoused by Schumpeter (1947) including organi
sational, market or process. This study is also based on cross-sectional data and as result no
causal implications can be drawn. Future research would benefit from longitudinal research
that could reveal more detailed cause-and-effect relationships between constructs over time
(Deligianni et al., 2017). Also, as with many studies, our research suffers from survivor bias
which could impact the generalisability of our findings.
However, even given the significant limitations of this study, the authors believe that
this research provides an early insight into innovation from an effectuation perspective as
well as how uncertainty and risk affect innovation performance within the firm.
INNOVATION: ORGANIZATION & MANAGEMENT 17
Conclusion
This exploratory study has many noteworthy outcomes when kept within the context of
the study’s limitations.
This study suggests that there is a theoretical relationship between innovation and
effectuation. Specifically, innovation appears to be an uncertainty management
approach that allows the firm to manage their innovation process more successfully,
resulting in improved innovation performance. This approach is enhanced by the
means available to the firm, specifically, the role of networks and partnerships available
to it. These networks help reduce uncertainty in the innovation process through
technology collaboration, market understanding and other resource advantages. Their
alternate role can be in reducing risk by providing pre-commitments to new product
and services and reducing the firm’s entrepreneurial risk. However, uncertainty appears
to have the largest impact on innovation performance, while aspects of risks impact
overall firm performance.
In conclusion, despite its many limitations, we believe that this research is an impor
tant first step in the understanding of effectuation in the context of firm-level innovation
and the connection between uncertainty and risk in the process.
Disclosure statement
No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).
ORCID
David C. Roach http://orcid.org/0000-0002-5043-2229
References
Alsos, G. A., Clausen, T. H., Mauer, R., Read, S., & Sarasvathy, S. D. (2019). Effectual exchange:
From entrepreneurship to the disciplines & beyond. Small Business Economics, 54(3), 605–619.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-019-00146-9
Alvarez, S. A., & Barney, J. B. (2005). How do entrepreneurs organize firms under conditions of
uncertainty? Journal of Management, 31(5), 776–793. https://doi.org/10.1177/
0149206305279486
Antonelli, C. (2015). Innovation as a creative response. A reappraisal of the Schumpeterian legacy.
History of Economic Ideas, 23(2), 99–118. https://doi.org/10.4337/9781782545149.00005
Arend, R. J., Sarooghi, H., & Burkemper, A. (2015). Effectuation as ineffectual? Applying the 3E
theory-assessment framework to a proposed new theory of entrepreneurship. Academy of
Management Review, 40(4), 630–651. https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.2014.0455
Brettel, M., Mauer, R., Engelen, A., & Küpper, D. (2012). Corporate effectuation: Entrepreneurial
action and its impact on R&D project performance. Journal of Business Venturing, 27(2),
167–184. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusvent.2011.01.001
Brouwer, M. (2000). Schumpeter and Keynes on investment and entrepreneurship. Economic
Theory in the Light of Schumpeter’s Scientific Heritage. http://www1.feb.uva.nl/pp/bin/1080full
text.pdf
Bstieler, L., & Gross, C. W. (2003). Measuring the effect of environmental uncertainty on process
activities, project team characteristics, and new product success. Journal of Business and
Industrial Marketing, 18(2), 146–161. https://doi.org/10.1108/08858620310463079
18 J. A. RYMAN AND D. C. ROACH
Calantone, R. J., Cavusgil, S. T., & Zhao, Y. (2002). Learning orientation, firm innovation
capability, and firm performance. Industrial Marketing Management, 31(6), 515–524. https://
doi.org/10.1016/s0019-8501(01)00203-6
Casson, M. (1982). The entrepreneur: An economic theory. Rowman and Littlefield.
Casson, M., Yeung, B., Basu, A., Bose, A., & Wadeson, N. (Eds.). (2006). The Oxford handbook of
entrepreneurship. Oxford Handbooks.
Chandler, G. N., DeTienne, D. R., McKelvie, A., & Mumford, T. V. (2011). Causation and
effectuation processes: A validation study. Journal of Business Venturing, 26(3), 375–390.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusvent.2009.10.006
Coyne, R. (1988). Logic models of design. Pitman.
Deligianni, I., Voudouris, I., & Lioukas, S. (2017). Do effectuation processes shape the relationship
between product diversification and performance in new ventures? Entrepreneurship Theory
and Practice, 41(3), 349–377. https://doi.org/10.1111/etap.12210
Deshpandé, R., & Farley, J. (1998). Measuring market orientation: Generalization and synthesis.
Journal of Market-Focused Management, 2(3), 213–232. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1009719615327
Dew, N., Read, S., Sarasvathy, S. D., & Wiltbank, R. (2008b). Outlines of a behavioral theory of the
entrepreneurial firm. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 66(1), 37–59. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.jebo.2006.10.008
Dew, N., Sarasvathy, S. D., Read, S., & Wiltbank, R. (2008a). Immortal firms in mortal markets? An
entrepreneurial perspective on the “innovator’s dilemma”. European Journal of Innovation
Management, 11(3), 313–329. https://doi.org/10.1108/14601060810888982
Dougherty, D. (2018). Managers fail to innovate and academics fail to explain how. Management
and Organization Review, 14(1), 229–239. https://doi.org/10.1017/mor.2018.4
Drucker, P. (1954). The practice of management. Harper.
Fernández-Olmos, M., & Ramírez-Alesón, M. (2017). How internal and external factors influence
the dynamics of SME technology collaboration networks over time. Technovation, 64–65,
16–27. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2017.06.002
Fornell, C., & Larcker, D. F. (1981). Evaluating structural equation models with unobservable variables
and measurement error. Journal of Marketing Research, 18(1), 39–50. https://doi.org/10.2307/
3151312
Freel, M. S. (2005). Perceived environmental uncertainty and innovation in small firms. Small
Business Economics, 25(1), 49–64. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-005-4257-9
Gales, L., & Mansour-Cole, D. (1995). User involvement in innovation projects: Toward an
information processing model. Journal of Engineering and Technology Management, 12(1–2),
77–109. https://doi.org/10.1016/0923-4748(95)00005-7
Gatignon, H., & Xuereb, J. M. (1997). Strategic orientation of the firm and new product
performance. Journal of Marketing Research, 34(1), 77–90. https://doi.org/10.2307/3152066
Gnyawali, D. R., & Park, B. J. (2009). Co-opetition and technological innovation in small and
medium-sized enterprises: A multilevel conceptual model. Journal of Small Business
Management, 47(3), 308–330. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-627x.2009.00273.x
Grinstein, A. (2008). The relationships between market orientation and alternative strategic
orientations. European Journal of Marketing, 42(1/2), 115–134. https://doi.org/10.1108/
03090560810840934
Hair, J. F.,sJr, Matthews, L. M., Matthews, R. L., & Sarstedt, M. (2017). PLS-SEM or CB-SEM:
Updated guidelines on which method to use. International Journal of Multivariate Data
Analysis, 1(2), 107–123. https://doi.org/10.1504/ijmda.2017.10008574
Hair, J. F., Risher, J. J., Sarstedt, M., & Ringle, C. M. (2019). When to use and how to report the results
of PLS-SEM. European Business Review, 31(1), 2–24. https://doi.org/10.1108/ebr-11–2018-0203
Heavey, C., & Simsek, Z. (2013). Top management compositional effects on corporate entrepre
neurship: The moderating role of perceived technological uncertainty. Journal of Product
Innovation Management, 30(5), 837–855. https://doi.org/10.1111/jpim.12033
Henseler, J., Ringle, C. M., & Sarstedt, M. (2015). A new criterion for assessing discriminant
validity in variance-based structural equation modeling. Journal of the Academy of Marketing
Science, 43(1), 115–135. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-014-0403-8
INNOVATION: ORGANIZATION & MANAGEMENT 19
Jalonen, H. (2012). The uncertainty of innovation: A systematic review of the literature. Journal of
Management Research, 4(1), 1–47. https://doi.org/10.5296/jmr.v4i1.1039
Jaworski, B. J., & Kohli, A. K. (1993). Market orientation: Antecedents and consequences. Journal
of Marketing, 57(3), 53–70. https://doi.org/10.4135/9781452231426.n5
Kirchhoff, B. A., Linton, J. D., & Walsh, S. T. (2013). Neo-Marshellian equilibrium versus
Schumpeterian creative destruction: Its impact on business research and economic policy.
Journal of Small Business Management, 51(2), 159–166. https://doi.org/10.1111/jsbm.12018
Knight, F. H. (1921). Risk, uncertainty and profit. Hart, Schaffner and Marx.
Kock, N. (2015). Common method bias in PLS-SEM: A full collinearity assessment approach.
International Journal of e-Collaboration, 11(4), 1–10. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-64069-3_11
Kolko, J. (2010). Abductive thinking and sensemaking: The drivers of design synthesis. Design
Issues, 26(1), 15–28. https://doi.org/10.1162/desi.2010.26.1.15
Kreiser, P., & Marino, L. (2002). Analyzing the historical development of the environmental uncertainty
construct. Management Decision, 40(9), 895–905. https://doi.org/10.1108/00251740210441090
Latham, S. F., & Braun, M. (2009). Managerial risk, innovation, and organizational decline. Journal
of Management, 35(2), 258–281. https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206308321549
Loch, C. H., Solt, M. E., & Bailey, E. M. (2008). Diagnosing unforeseeable uncertainty in a new venture.
Journal of Product Innovation Management, 25(1), 28–46. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5885.2007.
00281.x
Luthfa, S. (2019). A study of how uncertainty emerges in the uncertainty-embedded innovation process.
Journal of Innovation Management, 7(1), 46–79. https://doi.org/10.24840/2183-0606_007.001_0005
Mansoori, Y., & Lackéus, M. (2019). Comparing effectuation to discovery-driven planning, pre
scriptive entrepreneurship, business planning, lean startup, and design thinking. Small Business
Economics, 54(3), 791–818. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-019-00153-w
Martina, R. A. (2019). Toward a theory of affordable loss. Small Business Economics, 54(3), 1–24.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-019-00151-y
Mazzarol, T., & Reboud, S. (2017). Entrepreneurship and innovation. Tilde Publishing. Chapter 8 –
Risk management in innovation. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-9412-6_8
McKelvie, A., Chandler, G. N., DeTienne, D. R., & Johansson, A. (2019). The measurement of
effectuation: Highlighting research tensions and opportunities for the future. Small Business
Economics, 54(3), 1–32. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-019-00149-6
McKelvie, A., Haynie, J. M., & Gustavsson, V. (2011). Unpacking the uncertainty construct:
Implications for entrepreneurial action. Journal of Business Venturing, 26(3), 273–292. https://
doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusvent.2009.10.004
McMullen, J. S., & Shepherd, D. A. (2006). Entrepreneurial action and the role of uncertainty in
the theory of the entrepreneur. Academy of Management Review, 31(1), 132–152. https://doi.
org/10.4337/9781783479801.00007
Milliken, F. J. (1987). Three types of perceived uncertainty about the environment: State, effect,
and response uncertainty. The Academy of Management Review, 12(1), 133–143. https://doi.org/
10.5465/amr.1987.4306502
Paladino, A. (2007). Investigating the drivers of innovation and new product success:
A comparison of strategic orientations. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 24(6),
534–553. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5885.2007.00270.x
Perry, J. T., Chandler, G. N., & Markova, G. (2012). Entrepreneurial effectuation: A review and
suggestions for future research. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 36(4), 837–861. https://
doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6520.2010.00435.x
Pichlak, M. (2016). The innovation adoption process: A multidimensional approach. Journal of
Management & Organization, 22(4), 476–494. https://doi.org/10.1017/jmo.2015.52
Read, S., Song, M., & Smit, W. (2009). A meta-analytic review of effectuation and venture
performance. Journal of Business Venturing, 24(6), 573–587. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbus
vent.2008.02.005
Reymen, I., Berends, H., Oudehand, R., & Stultiëns, R. (2017). Decision making for business model
development: A process study of effectuation and causation in new technology-based ventures.
R&D Management, 47(4), 595–606. https://doi.org/10.1111/radm.12249
20 J. A. RYMAN AND D. C. ROACH
Ries, E. (2011). The lean startup: How today’s entrepreneurs use continuous innovation to create
radically successful businesses. Crown Books.
Ringle, C. M., Wende, S., & Becker, J.-M. (2015). SmartPLS n3.2.9. SmartPLS. https://www.
smartpls.com
Roach, D. C., Ryman, J. A., & Makani, J. (2016). Effectuation, innovation and performance in
SMEs: An empirical study. European Journal of Innovation Management, 19(2), 214–238.
https://doi.org/10.1108/ejim-12-2014-0119
Rosenbusch, N., Brinckmann, J., & Bausch, A. (2011). Is innovation always beneficial? A
meta-analysis of the relationship between innovation and performance in SMEs. Journal of
Business Venturing, 26(4), 441–457. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusvent.2009.12.002
Sarasvathy, S. D. (2001). Causation and effectuation: Toward a theoretical shift from economic
inevitability to entrepreneurial contingency. Academy of Management Review, 26(2), 243–263.
https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.2001.4378020
Sarasvathy, S. D. (2003). Entrepreneurship as a science of the artificial. Journal of Economic
Psychology, 24(2), 203–220. https://doi.org/10.4337/9781848440197.00019
Sarasvathy, S. D., Dew, N., Read, S., & Wiltbank, R. (2008). Designing organizations that design
environments: Lessons from entrepreneurial expertise. Organization Studies, 29(3), 331–350.
https://doi.org/10.1177/0170840607088017
Sarasvathy, D. K., Simon, H. A., & Lave, L. (1998). Perceiving and managing business risks:
Differences between entrepreneurs and bankers. Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization, 33(2), 207–225. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0167-2681(97)00092-9
Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The theory of economic development (1936 ed.). Harvard University Press.
Schumpeter, J. A. (1947). The creative response in economic history. The Journal of Economic
History, 7(2), 149–159. https://doi.org/10.1017/s0022050700054279
Shane, S. (2012). Reflections on the 2010 AMR decade award: Delivering on the promise of
entrepreneurship as a field of research. Academy of Management Review, 37(1), 10–20.
https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.2011.0078
Shane, S., & Venkataraman, S. (2000). The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of research.
Academy of Management Review, 25(1), 217–226. https://doi.org/10.1007/3-540-48543-0_8
Sicotte, H., & Bourgault, M. (2008). Dimensions of uncertainty and their moderating effect on new
product development project performance. R&D Management, 38(5), 468–479. https://doi.org/
10.1111/j.1467-9310.2008.00531.x
Simon, H. (1969). The sciences of the artificial. MIT Press.
Simon, H. A. (1993). Strategy and organizational evolution. Strategic Management Journal, 14(S2),
131–142. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.4250141011
Smith, M., Busi, M., Ball, P., & Van der Meer, R. (2008). Factors influencing an organisation’s ability
to manage innovation: A structured literature review and conceptual model. International Journal
of Innovation Management, 12(4), 655–676. https://doi.org/10.1142/9781786346520_0004
Song, M., & Montoya-Weiss, M. M. (2001). The effect of perceived technological uncertainty on
Japanese new product development. Academy of Management Journal, 44(1), 61–80. https://doi.
org/10.5465/3069337
Tatikonda, M. V., & Rosenthal, S. R. (2000). Technology novelty, project complexity, and product
development project execution success: A deeper look at task uncertainty in product innovation.
IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management, 47(1), 74–87. https://doi.org/10.1109/17.820727
Tenenhaus, M., Vinzi, V. E., Chatelin, Y. M., & Lauro, C. (2005). PLS path modeling. Computational
Statistics and Data Analysis, 48(1), 159–205. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.csda.2004.03.005
Thaler, R. H., Tversky, A., Kahneman, D., & Schwartz, A. (1997). The effect of myopia and loss
aversion on risk taking: An experimental test. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2),
647–661. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355397555226
Thomke, S. H. (2020). Experimentation works: The surprising power of business experiments.
Harvard Business Press.
Ting, H., Wang, H., & Wang, D. (2012). The moderating role of environmental dynamism on the
influence of innovation strategy and firm performance. International Journal of Innovation,
Management and Technology, 3(5), 517. https://doi.org/10.7763/ijimt.2012.v3.288
INNOVATION: ORGANIZATION & MANAGEMENT 21
Varis, M., & Littunen, H. (2010). Types of innovation, sources of information and performance in
entrepreneurial SMEs. European Journal of Innovation Management, 13(2), 128–154. https://
doi.org/10.1108/14601061011040221
Verhees, F., & Meulenberg, M. (2004). Market orientation, innovativeness, product innovation,
and performance in small firms. Journal of Small Business Management, 42(2), 134–154. https://
doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-627x.2004.00102.x
Weiss, P., & Burks, A. W. (eds.). (1958). Collected papers of Charles Sanders Peirce (Vol. 8).
Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. https://doi.org/10.1038/135131a0
Wolff, J. A., & Pett, T. L. (2006). Small-firm performance: Modeling the role of product and
process improvements. Journal of Small Business Management, 44(2), 268–284. https://doi.org/
10.1111/j.1540-627x.2006.00167.x