1901 6336 1 PB
1901 6336 1 PB
1901 6336 1 PB
To cite this article: J. van den Bergh, J. Castro, S. Drews, F. Exadaktylos, J. Foramitti, F. Klein,
T. Konc & I. Savin (2021): Designing an effective climate-policy mix: accounting for instrument
synergy, Climate Policy, DOI: 10.1080/14693062.2021.1907276
SYNTHESIS ARTICLE
1. Introduction
Many academic writings on climate policy are concerned with the performance of single instruments targeting
greenhouse gas emission reduction. In reality, however, one typically finds an extensive set of policy instru-
ments implemented simultaneously, often on different regulatory levels. There are many potential reasons
for using multiple instruments. The instruments might be complementary or even create positive synergy in
terms of the associated goal. More specifically, they might deal with distinct market failures (Freire-González,
2018; Jaffe et al., 2005). Another important reason for combining instruments is that they can accomplish mul-
tiple objectives, such as effectiveness, efficiency and equity. In more abstract terms, a policy mix can reflect a
second-best (non-optimal) response to a first-best (theoretically optimal) single instrument not being feasible –
because of monitoring of pollution being imperfect, the control span of policy being limited, or the existence of
political constraints. The additional instruments then compensate for the non-optimal level of the main policy
instrument (Bennear & Stavins, 2007). More practically, multiple instruments might arise from political compro-
mises between stakeholders with distinct policy preferences, or from adding instruments to compensate for the
insufficiency of already available instruments (Bouma et al., 2018). Finally, in line with the Tinbergen (1952) rule,
a distinct type of policy mix results from the presence of multiple objectives, such as climate change mitigation
and limiting biodiversity loss (Braathen, 2007; Sterner et al., 2019).
There are also several reasons to be careful about combining instruments into a policy mix. As will be illus-
trated for various cases in Section 3, policies may overlap or create negative synergies. This can even lead them
to offset each other in terms of emissions reduction. In such cases, a policy mix would perform no better or even
worse than a single instrument. Taking into account that each policy instrument generates an additional cost
for the regulator or government in terms of expenditures and human resources – including transaction costs of
political and policy processes until implementation, cost of monitor and control, and sometimes serious bud-
getary sacrifices (such as with subsidies) – policy-makers may want to limit the number of instruments in the
policy mix. Moreover, given that policy instruments often cause unintended market distortions, employing mul-
tiple instruments runs the risk of introducing potentially multiple distortions into the economy. Finally, policy
mixes complicate the comparison of policy stringency among regions and countries compared to single instru-
ments. Schmidt and Sewerin (2019) demonstrate this for renewable-energy policy mixes in nine OECD
countries. Difficulty to compare policies in turn confounds policy integration between distinct governance
levels within a country or within a supra-national system like the European Union (Howlett et al., 2017). As
we argue in Section 4, reducing the complexity of climate policy might increase the feasibility of international
policy harmonization.
In view of these contrasting arguments, this article examines the synergy of combining specific instruments
in a policy mix aimed at effectively reducing greenhouse gas emissions. To this end, we consider both theor-
etical arguments and empirical or experimental evidence from a variety of disciplines that have devoted atten-
tion to policy mixes, notably economics, psychology, and innovation and transition studies (Bulkeley & Kern,
2006; Howlett & Rayner, 2007; Jaffe et al., 2005; Mundaca et al., 2019; Oikonomou & Jepma, 2007; Oikonomou
et al., 2010; Rogge et al., 2017; Somanathan et al., 2014, Section 15.7.3). This allows us to obtain a comprehen-
sive picture of possible combinations of climate policy instruments that can achieve non-negative or even posi-
tive interactive effects on emissions reduction. Most of the aforementioned reviews do not focus on
systematically assessing synergy of particular instrument combinations as we do here, nor do they include
all the instrument combinations we address. Hence our study adds to the existing literature. While we focus
on climate mitigation policy in the context of emission reduction, there are also reviews or synthetic studies
of policy mixes for energy-efficiency (Boonekamp, 2006; Hood, 2013; Rosenow et al., 2017; Wiese et al.,
2018), renewable energy (Pitelis, 2018), accelerating technological change (Rogge & Reichardt, 2016), or
broader environmental issues (Lehmann, 2012).
Following the logic of Bowles (2016, Appendix 1) for the relationship between incentives and social pre-
ferences, we distinguish between four cases of interaction between policy instruments, namely (i) no (zero)
synergy, (ii) positive synergy, (iii) (moderately) negative synergy, and (iv) backfire. The first case indicates
that the overall effect of a policy mix is the sum of the individual instrument effects, meaning there are
no synergistic interaction effects, or the instruments are independent and complementary. This is also
known as additive separability. The second case describes cases in which one instrument reinforces
another, meaning a positive interaction effect is at stake. This case is sometimes referred to as super-addi-
tivity, super-modularity and crowding-in.1 An example is information provision creating awareness which in
turn strengthens an incentive effect. The third case reflects that one instrument weakens another, such as
when monetary incentives crowd-out intrinsic pro-environmental preferences. Here the interaction is nega-
tive, and the outcome is variably known as substitutability, sub-additivity or crowding-out. This happens, for
CLIMATE POLICY 3
instance, if instruments overlap in their impact on particular decisions by agents and associated emissions,
so that the effect of the policy mix is lower than the sum of the isolated effects. The instruments are then
(partial) substitutes of one another. An extreme version of this is the fourth case of ‘backfire’, denoting that
one of the instruments offsets the effect of the other, causing the policy mix to perform worse than the
best-performing instrument alone. This differs from moderate negative synergy, which is still reasonably
effective in that it means that the combination of instruments reduces emissions more than a single instru-
ment alone. The boundary between these two cases is what we will call ‘compensating negative synergy’:
here negative synergy results in overall emissions reduction equalling B, i.e. the level achieved by the most
effective instrument alone. Figure 1 illustrates these various potential outcomes of interactions between two
policy instruments.
The remainder of this article is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the approach, consisting of identify-
ing main categories of instruments and assessing possible interactions between these. Section 3 examines the
performance of specific instrument combinations in terms of emissions reduction. Section 4 summarizes the
findings and generalizes these for more than two instruments, discussing relative advantages and disadvan-
tages of a set of potential climate policy mixes. Further, it pays attention to the international context of
climate policy and its implications for policy mixes. Section 5 concludes.
2. Approach
There are many classifications of environmental and climate policy instruments aimed at altering behaviour of
firms and households to achieve reductions in carbon emissions (Bulkeley & Kern, 2006; Goulder & Parry, 2008;
Somanathan et al., 2014; Sterner, 2002). Here we focus on a set of instruments that has received considerable
attention in the literature on policy mixes:
1. Performance and technical standards. Performance standards can take various forms, such as a quota on a
sector’s emissions, a renewable energy portfolio target (e.g. a certain share of renewables in electricity gen-
eration), phasing out fossil fuels (e.g. coal), or banning the use of high-emission cars in cities. Technical stan-
dards specify minimum criteria for consumer or production technologies, such as fuel-efficiency standards
for cars or best available technologies for pollution abatement.
Figure 1. Potential outcomes of instrument interactions. Note: Adapted from Drews et al. (2020). The horizontal dashed line on top separates
between positive and negative synergy, and the one underneath between backfire and other negative synergy.
4 J. VAN DEN BERGH ET AL.
2. Carbon pricing means incorporating the direct and indirect external costs of CO2(-eq) emissions in the prices
of fuels, resources, intermediate products, and final goods and services. This can be done through a carbon
tax or emissions trading (market creation or tradable permits), which do not necessarily generate identical
outcomes (Foramitti et al., 2021; Goulder & Schein, 2013).2
3. Adoption subsidies encourage the adoption and diffusion of energy-efficient or low-carbon products by
financially rewarding the purchase of energy-efficient or low-carbon products (e.g. hybrid or electric cars).
4. Innovation support aims to increase private investment in, and success of, research and development (R&D)
on energy-efficient and low-carbon technologies and products. A common way to do this is through R&D
subsidies. Many other instruments fall into this broad category (Dolfsma & Dongback, 2013): e.g. green pro-
curement, funding basic research at universities and in research centres, or legislation on intellectual prop-
erty rights.
5. Information provision and nudges address lack of information – such as limited awareness of environmental
challenges, solutions or associated behavioural options – and behavioural barriers – such as limited atten-
tion, self-control issues and status concerns. Instruments of the first type include providing basic infor-
mation, often in a simplified form (e.g. eco-labels and energy certificates). Instruments of the second
type, targeting specific behaviours, entail reminders of excessive energy use, commitment devices, and
feedback about choices of others (e.g. smart electricity metres).
One can distinguish symmetric from asymmetric instruments mixes: while in the former case all sectors are
subject to the instruments, in the latter case some sectors receive different treatment than others. For example,
renewable electricity is subject to future targets and feed-in-tariffs, EU-ETS is limited to large industrial and
energy power firms, a carbon tax is often focused on non-export sectors, and concrete technical standards
apply to particular sectors – such as fuel-efficiency standards in car manufacturing.
The approach we followed to select studies for review consists of two parts. The first is a snowball method:
we looked for relevant studies in existing reviews which offered a good entry point into the literature. From
there we skimmed the reference lists of all identified papers until we did not find additional suitable papers.
The second part involved a search in Scopus, using the following search terms:
(“policy interaction” OR “policy synergy” OR “instrument combination” OR “instrument mix” OR “instrument interaction” OR
“instrument synergy” OR “instrument combination” OR “instrument mix”) AND (“climate” OR “energy” OR “emission*”).
This generated a list of 273 studies of which a little over ten percent were considered relevant to our specific
purpose of assessing instrument synergy in regard to emission reduction. Most of these studies are from
environmental economics, while additional ones come from energy studies, environmental science, psychology
and other policy areas. We excluded studies that did not focus on instrument synergy, did not provide a clear
basis for their claims, or did not relate directly to climate policy and emission reduction.
overall abatement cost will come out higher (OECD, 2011; Sijm, 2005). This holds equally for countries and mul-
tilevel systems. Well-intended energy policies by states or countries, respectively, can undercut the consistent
approach aimed for by a national or supra-national policy such as the EU-ETS, frustrating the effectiveness and
efficiency of emissions reduction. An assessment for the EU by Böhringer and Rosendahl (2011) finds more than
60% cost increase of achieving 25% CO2 reductions when a renewable energy quota is set 10% points higher
than the endogenous renewable energy deployment level under the EU-ETS, and that the permit price falls
from €41 to €16 per ton of CO2.
Table 1 clarifies how synergy resulting from adding renewable energy policy (REP) in the form of standards
or targets to carbon pricing differ between a carbon tax and carbon market creation (such as emission trading).
With a carbon market, the outcome is compensating negative synergy (on the boundary of backfire; see discus-
sion of Figure 1) making the second instrument unnecessary, while with a carbon tax synergy can range from
negative to zero (complementarity). For maximum effectiveness REP is thus best combined with a carbon tax
rather than carbon market creation. Moreover, as explained by the difference between the two cases in the
columns, such policy should avoid targeting relatively cheap options that are already triggered by the
carbon tax.3
The previous problem pertains to California, China and the EU given that they all have climate policies com-
bining emissions trading and sector-specific targets or standards (Duan et al., 2017; Fankhauser et al., 2010;
Schatzki & Stavins, 2012). Many more studies report the same finding (e.g. del Río, 2011; Delarue & Van den
Bergh, 2016; Görlach, 2014; Tu & Mo, 2017). The overall policy mix will then perform equal to emissions
trading on its own.4 Evidence for various countries is summarized in Fankhauser et al. (2010).
Finally, low-carbon technical standards on technologies for adoption may suffer from energy/carbon
rebound in the user phase, causing a loss in overall effectiveness of emissions reduction. Combining standards
with carbon pricing will limit such rebound by making energy and emissions during the use phase more
expensive, thus discouraging more intense use and associated rebound (Font Vivanco et al., 2016; Freire-Gon-
zález, 2020; van den Bergh, 2011). As a result, technical standards and carbon pricing have positive synergy in
terms of emissions reduction.
Table 1. Emissions reduction (and synergy) of combining carbon pricing and renewable energy policy.
Combined effect (emissions reduction and synergy) with renewable energy policy
MAC > p MAC < p
Carbon market emissions reduction X implying synergy -Y emissions reduction X implying synergy -Y
Carbon tax emissions reduction X + Y implying synergy 0 emissions reduction X implying synergy -Y
Note: X denotes emissions reduction of carbon pricing on its own (isolated carbon market and tax are equivalent in terms of emissions
reduction, i.e. tax = market price = p); Y is emissions reduction of renewable energy policy (REP) on its own. MAC denotes the marginal abate-
ment costs of renewable energy investment. Of course, a part (say a, with 0<a<1) of renewable energy investments could have a MAC below
and the rest above p, in which case the negative synergy of tax and REP will be -a·Y. Since a in general will be non-negative, some degree of
negative synergy is likely here.
6 J. VAN DEN BERGH ET AL.
may be hampered by behavioural factors such as myopia, warranting tailored incentives like adoption sub-
sidies. An alternative to overcome behavioural barriers is information provision, as discussed in Section
3.4.5
Despite these advantages, adoption subsidies for low-carbon options are best not implemented on their
own, but complemented by carbon pricing. Support of investment in renewable energy capacity through
subsidies alone makes energy use overall generally cheaper and can thus increase demand for energy,
thus limiting overall emissions reduction (Murray et al., 2014). In particular, while adoption subsidies stimu-
late purchase of low-carbon options (e.g. low-carbon vehicles), they effectively lower energy costs per unit
of use (e.g. km driven). This in turn tends to give rise to energy/carbon rebound through more intense use
(more trips or longer distances travelled with the vehicle). As argued in Section 3.1, carbon pricing will limit
such rebound and thus generate positive synergy. Hence, one should be careful using adoption subsidies to
stimulate the purchase of products whose use causes carbon emissions, such as electric vehicles running on
electricity that is not entirely carbon-free; without a carbon price in place emissions could rebound and
even rise.
According to Fankhauser et al. (2010), feed-in tariffs (FITs) to support renewable energy obligations for a
sector that is also subject to a cap-and-trade system will weaken the carbon price and thus decrease emissions
reduction, compared to the sum of emission reduction potential for each instrument in isolation (see also
Sorrell et al., 2009; and Twomey, 2012). Fais et al. (2015) analyse interdependencies between the EU-ETS and
the German FITs for renewable electricity using a bottom-up energy system model. They find that permit
prices decline by between 1.9 and 6.1 €/tCO2 and the burden sharing between participating countries
changes, distorting the cost-effectiveness of cap and trade, with additional costs under FIT between €44
billion and €57 billion over the period 2013–2020. To this, one has to add the pure cost of the FIT which is
€320 billion in the same period. So, while not adding extra emissions reduction, i.e. causing negative
synergy, the FITs also contribute to significant additional costs.
Feebates (fee + rebate) or bonus-malus schemes combine a carbon tax (or a sales tax with a carbon com-
ponent) on high-carbon options with an adoption subsidy for low-carbon alternatives. The simple idea
behind it is that the high-carbon option is discouraged and the low-carbon one encouraged. However, like a
pure adoption subsidy, a feebate suffers from the above-discussed rebound problem (Haultfœuille et al.,
2014) and requires a consistent price on all carbon to limit more intense use of the low-carbon option. An
advantage of feebates is that, instead of requiring a high carbon tax to shift consumer decisions to low-
carbon options, which has been politically infeasible so far, one can combine a lower carbon tax with a
rebate, which might be more politically acceptable. Ideally, the combination of these instruments creates
the same price gap between high- and low-carbon options as achieved by the high carbon tax alone.
Another advantage is that the system can be self-financing, namely the subsidy (rebate) can be paid out of
the fee revenues. However, it may be impossible to satisfy the two conditions – i.e. an optimal price gap
and revenue or budget neutrality – simultaneously. In addition, governments have to address the challenge
that an effective carbon tax erodes the emissions base of tax revenues, requiring them to think about timely
implementation of additional revenue-raising taxes.
A disadvantage of feebates, and adoption subsidies generally, is that overall consumption is encouraged
compared to an equivalent carbon tax (i.e. with the same price gap between low- and high-carbon), given
that low-carbon usually also involves carbon emissions (in production and use phases).6 However, as
diffusion may go faster, there is uncertainty about the net effect on emissions in the long run. Exact out-
comes depend on the precise design including whether it satisfies self-financing or not. For instance, Durr-
meyer (2018) finds that under a flat rate tax, the feebate scheme favours individuals in the middle-income
class, while if the tax is proportional to income, the feebate redistributes some income from the richest to
the poorest households. Unlike a pure carbon tax, where revenues can be used to compensate lower-
income households, in the feebate approach no funds are automatically generated to pay for such compen-
sation. Note that both instruments have a rebound effect: carbon-tax revenue recycling to poor households
creates a positive income effect on consumption; and the feebate’s rebate stimulates consumption of the
low-carbon option.
CLIMATE POLICY 7
to innovation speed and direction as these not only depend on innovation policies but also on regulation or
pricing (Aghion et al., 2016; Popp, 2002). This is because innovating firms take expectations about future
costs and prices into account. Therefore, regulation and pricing are not only relevant for short-term emissions
reduction but also for the speed and direction of innovation, and hence long-term emissions reduction.
landlord may be required to inform the tenant about the energy efficiency of his building by way of an energy
certificate. Empirical studies show such measures can reduce energy use, depending on the market, technology
and the overall policy mix (Lehmann, 2012). According to Sorrell and Sijm (2003) information provision is most
useful as an additional instrument for households and small or medium-sized firms as these tend to have little
knowledge about relevant options, large energy-saving potential, and low energy-price elasticities.
Studies using mostly field experiments to test synergy between incentives and information provision or
nudges offer mixed evidence: positive synergy (Hilton et al., 2014; List et al., 2017), negative synergy (Dolan
& Metcalfe, 2015; Sudarshan, 2017), no synergy (Handgraaf et al., 2013; Mizobuchi & Takeuchi, 2013;
Panzone et al., 2018; Pellerano et al., 2017; Schall et al., 2016; Tørnblad et al., 2014). For example, a study by
Panzone et al. (2018) examined how a carbon tax combined with a moral nudge affects food choices in an
online supermarket in the UK. When considering the instruments in isolation, both the carbon tax and, to a
lesser extent, the nudge encouraged people to choose food products with a lower carbon footprint.
However, the study found no positive synergy from combining the instruments. An important caveat is that
only a minority of studies include a full analysis required to arrive at robust conclusions. Drews et al. (2020)
propose how to improve this kind of experimental research, recognizing that not only monetary incentives
may crowd-out non-economic motivations, but also nudges or information provision can crowd out the effec-
tiveness of monetary incentives. What matters further is how information is framed and provided, such as
through feedback, advertising, contextual information, descriptive social norms, etc. (Abrahamse et al., 2007).
Another example of particular instrument mixes concerns fleet standards and policies encouraging adoption of
low-emission vehicles. Jenn et al. (2016, 2019) show that state mandates (zero-emissions vehicle policy) increas-
ing alternative-fuel vehicle sales are counteracted by federal policy requiring automakers to meet aggregate
criteria for fleet-fuel efficiency, such as ‘Corporate Average Fuel Economy’ (CAFE) standards. The authors find
that these standards are relaxed when more alternative-fuel vehicles are sold to the extent that overall emis-
sions increase considerably.
synergy between the tax and standard (see Table 1), making it less effective than A. Note that renewable energy
targets and adoption subsidies are excluded from policy mix C as they interact negatively with the carbon
market (Sections 3.1 and 3.2). This means the long-term effectiveness of emissions reduction may be lower
than that of policy mix D, which combines adoption subsidies with a carbon tax.10
Finally, we discuss a neglected but relevant consideration in the literature on climate-policy mixes, namely
the political feasibility of stringent climate policy. Since climate policy is an international challenge with the
characteristics of a public good that invite free-riding by national governments, achieving stringent policies
in all countries requires global upscaling, harmonization or integration of national policies (Jordan & Lenschow,
2010). This holds especially true for regulatory and pricing instruments, as these affect competitive positions
(and thus exports) of countries. Motivations for this view are diverse – see, e.g. Fowlie (2009), Fischer and
Fox (2012), and Al Khourdajiea and Finus (2020). For alternative, minority views see, e.g. Bernstein and
Hoffmann (2019) and Jordan et al. (2018).
While international competitiveness effects of climate policies have been found to be rather weak overall
(Aldy & Pizer, 2015), two comments are in order. First, national policies so far have been lax everywhere,
meaning that differences in stringency among countries have not been pronounced. In a study focused on
carbon pricing, Venmans et al. (2020) conclude that ‘When statistically significant results have been found,
the magnitude of such effects tends to be small […] These findings are in part because carbon price levels
have been low.’ Indeed, a recent assessment of carbon pricing found that the average price of carbon in
countries where it is implemented is about 7.90€ per ton CO2 (Finch & van den Bergh, 2020). Hence, one
cannot extrapolate empirical findings about competitiveness effects to carbon price ranges (or trajectories) rec-
ommended as needed to meet the Paris targets, i.e. US$50–100 by 2030 (HLCCP, 2017; IMF, 2019) or even US
$245–14300 tCO2e (Masson-Delmotte et al., 2018). Second, perceptions matter: politicians fear for competitive-
ness effects and business lobby to strengthen this. Note that the EU is seriously deliberating a border carbon
tariff to protect its economy for competitiveness effects of its relatively stringent climate policy. Harmonization
will take away politicians concerns and thus can encourage more stringent national policies.
Such a need for global policy harmonization can be seen as an argument for limiting the number of policy
instruments, or striving towards a transparent and simple policy mix that can be more easily compared and
integrated among countries. If, on the other hand, countries have very complex policy mixes, it might be
difficult for them to judge, compare and match these (del Río, 2014; Howlett et al., 2017; Schmidt & Sewerin,
2019), in turn possibly discouraging them to implement strong regulation/pricing instruments (Weitzman,
2014). A rich policy mix, as is common worldwide, moreover can be used as an excuse for politicians to
claim ‘we are doing a lot already’, even when the overall effectiveness of the policy mix is disappointing.
These considerations suggest limiting the number of regulatory/pricing instruments, which means a trade-
off with reasons for additional policy instruments, such as positive instrument synergy.11
If we judge how the four policy mixes in Table 3 perform on capacity for global harmonization, then option C
comes out best, given that harmonization so far has been more successful with carbon markets than carbon
taxation (options B and D). Indeed, such markets have been integrated among regions or countries in North
America and Europe, while the same has not happened with carbon taxes, possibly as governments are unlikely
to hand over control over taxes to a supranational body (van den Bergh et al., 2020). Finally, achieving harmo-
nization with options A and B seems also difficult given they involve a multidimensional challenge of harmo-
nizing many performance and technical standards next to various subsidies, while the latter would also involve
the problem of supranational financing.
CLIMATE POLICY 13
Considering all criteria together then, options C and D perform well on effectiveness, and C best on harmo-
nization. A and B performs worst of the four options, and choosing between them is difficult in general as A may
perform better on effectiveness (if B suffers seriously from negative synergy between the standard and tax)
while B performs better on efficiency (so there is a trade-off then between effectiveness and efficiency to be
made). This suggests that a ranking of options from most to least attractive is: C, D, B, A. However, a provision
is needed, as we only consider two values for each criterion. Since it is possible that two ‘high’ scores on effec-
tiveness are not exactly the same, we cannot derive a definite ranking. This would require a trade-off between
the exact performance in terms of each criterion (moving beyond the general instrument categories to specific
instruments), as well as weights or priorities assigned to the different criteria. If one believes, for instance, that
without harmonization significantly raising the carbon price over time to meet ambitious emissions reduction
goals will be very difficult if not impossible, it would make sense to weight the final criterion more heavily. This
then would result in a preference for policy mix C. Although this is not a complete assessment, it indicates how
one can integrate insights to decide about well-performing policy mixes.
5. Conclusions
It is important to seriously consider climate-policy mixes as recommended on the basis of insights about instru-
ment interactions. The reason is that the practice of climate policy is strongly driven by political and stakeholder
processes that easily result in what Bouma et al. (2018) call a ‘policy mess’. As noted by Bennear and Stavins
(2007), there is no evidence that implemented policy mixes are the most effective.
This study has collected insights and evidence from theoretical modelling and empirical and exper-
imental studies to assess the negative or positive synergy of combining instruments in climate policy,
aimed at achieving effective emissions reduction. This involved a more focused and concrete approach
than in previous studies on climate policy mixes (listed in Section 1). We synthesized the findings on
dual instrument synergies by formulating and comparing more complex policy mixes. We conclude that
the most promising packages would be to combine innovation support and information provision with
either a carbon tax and adoption subsidy, or with a carbon market and no adoption subsidy. We
further argue that the latter could have stronger potential with respect to harmonization of international
policy and thus the strengthening of mitigation policy over time.
Given its complexity, this topic merits further research. Quantification and weighting of policy-mix perform-
ance on multiple criteria, including notably equity, can help to provide more definitive advice. In addition, pol-
itical feasibility of policy mixes deserves more attention in a dynamic setting of policy sequencing, transitions
and coalition formation (Edmondson et al., 2019; Gerlagh et al., 2009; Herrmann & Savin, 2017; Meckling et al.,
2015; Skovsgaard Aidta & Duttab, 2004). Finally, research is welcome beyond dual instrument interactions,
namely on the magnitude of synergy between three or more instruments.
Notes
1. Note that cases (i) and (ii) are sometimes also referred to as instruments being complementary. To avoid confusion, we use in
this paper the term ‘complementary’ strictly for case (i).
2. A cap-and-trade system can itself already be regarded as a mix of policy instruments, namely a quantity-based instrument (i.e.
a cap to emissions, defining the sum of all emission permits) and a price-based instrument (i.e. variable price due to trade of
permits). Such a hybrid policy has various advantages (Hepburn, 2006; Grülla & Taschinibc, 2011). Specific additional elements
add further benefits, such as limiting volatility of the carbon price through a minimum price or price floor, and avoiding
unsurmountable costs for emitters through a maximum price or ‘safety valve’ (Jacoby & Ellerman, 2004; Philibert, 2009).
3. A few studies claim that despite negative synergy, the combination of carbon market and renewable energy policy can be
useful: e.g., if the design of the permit market is imperfect (Lecuyer & Quirion, 2013, p. 2019) or energy market are imperfect
(Lehmann & Gawel, 2013). Others point at long-term innovation benefits (del Río, 2017; Fagiani et al., 2014). However, direct
innovation support seems more effective for this purpose and will avoid negative synergy with carbon markets (Section 3.3).
4. This can be compensated by a market stability reserve, as in the EU-ETS (Perino et al., 2019). Reducing the cap over time is
another way to reduce negative synergy; more specifically, deducting the emissions reduced by the standards from the cap
neutralizes the leakage (Richstein et al., 2015). A third option is installing a carbon price floor (Flachsland et al., 2020). Perino
(2018) warns, though, that this may not be a permanent solution.
14 J. VAN DEN BERGH ET AL.
5. Stoneman and David (1986) compare adoption subsidies and information provision in their role as instruments to encourage
diffusion.
6. An overall comparison of feebate and carbon tax should also account for any emissions reduction or increase due to use of
carbon tax revenues.
7. This is one of the few studies that includes the four required treatments: no policy, either instrument in isolation, and their
combination. Note that crowding-out (in) means that the combined effect is smaller (larger) than the sum of the two isolated
effects.
8. With regard to the trade-off between effectiveness and efficiency, the prices-vs-quantities debate started by Weitzman (1974)
is relevant. It distinguishes between uncertainty about effectiveness of price instruments versus uncertainty about the costs
of quantity instruments. While this debate is more about instrument choice and incentives than about a policy mix, it has
been connected – even in the context of climate policy – to hybrid instruments such as tradeable permits with a price
floor (kind of a policy mix). Such hybrids are found to perform better than each instrument alone (Pizer, 1997). Considering
a setting with multiple pollutants, Ambac and Coria (2013) find that the desirable policy mix depends on whether pollutants
are complements or substitutes.
9. We considered adding equity to the set of performance criteria. However, it has not received much attention in studies asses-
sing synergy of policy instruments, while its assessment requires information about generally unknown factors, such as
wealth and income distribution, prices, sector shifts and associated unemployment. In addition, it depends on how revenues
of carbon pricing are used (Klenert et al., 2018; Hafstead, 2019).
10. One might, as a transition approach, combine a carbon tax for small emitters with a carbon market for large emitters, as
already happens in various EU countries. This evidently complicates the policy mix while adding the challenge of multiple,
incongruent carbon prices.
11. Among the various instruments, global carbon pricing enjoys the advantage that negotiating it is relatively simple as it means
a one-dimensional negotiation challenge (Weitzman, 2014, 2017). Instead, negotiating national emission targets among 200
countries implies a 200-dimensional coordination problem, while negotiating technical standards for n products or technol-
ogies would mean an n-dimensional challenge (with n possibly being very large). In addition, a carbon market can harmonize
national climate policies. Indeed, most current harmonized carbon prices are due to carbon markets (Haites, 2018).
Acknowledgements
This study has received funding through an ERC Advanced Grant from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European
Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation programme (grant agreement n° 741087). IS acknowledges financial support from
the Russian Science Foundation (RSF grant number 19-18-00262).
Disclosure statement
No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors.
Funding
This work was supported by H2020 European Research Council [grant number 741087]; Russian Science Foundation [grant number
19-18-00262].
ORCID
J. van den Bergh http://orcid.org/0000-0003-3415-3083
References
Abrahamse, W., & Steg, L. (2013). Social influence approaches to encourage resource conservation: A meta-analysis. Global
Environmental Change, 23(6), 1773–1785. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2013.07.029
Abrahamse, W., Steg, L., Vlek, C., & Rothengatter, T. (2007). The effect of tailored information, goal setting, and tailored feedback on
household energy use, energy-related behaviors, and behavioral antecedents. Journal of Environmental Psychology, 27(4),
265–276. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvp.2007.08.002
Aghion, P., Dechezleprêtre, A., Hémous, D., Martin, R., & Van Reenen, J. (2016). Carbon taxes, path dependency, and directed technical
change: Evidence from the auto industry. Journal of Political Economy, 124(1), 1–51. https://doi.org/10.1086/684581
Aldy, J., Krupnick, A., Newell, R., Parry, I., & Pizer, W. (2010). Designing climate mitigation policy. Journal of Economic Literature, 48(4),
903–934. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.48.4.903
CLIMATE POLICY 15
Aldy, J. E., & Pizer, W. A. (2015). The competitiveness impacts of climate change mitigation policies. Journal of the Association of
Environment and Resource Economists, 2(4), 565–595. https://doi.org/10.1086/683305
Al Khourdajiea, A., & Finus, M. (2020). Measures to enhance the effectiveness of international climate agreements: The case of border
carbon adjustments. European Economic Review, 124, 103405. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2020.103405
Allcott, H., Knittel, C., & Taubinsky, D. (2015). Tagging and targeting of energy efficiency subsidies. American Economic Review, 105(5),
187–191. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.p20151008
Ambac, S., & Coria, J. (2013). Prices vs quantities with multiple pollutants. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 66(1),
123–140.
Andor, M. A., & Fels, K. M. (2018). Behavioral economics and energy conservation – A systematic review of non-price interventions
and their causal effects. Ecological Economics, 148, 178–210. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2018.01.018
Arthur, B. (1989). Competing technologies, increasing returns, and lock-in by historical events. The Economic Journal, 99(394),
116–131. https://doi.org/10.2307/2234208
Axsen, J., Plötz, P., & Wolinetz, M. (2020). Crafting strong, integrated policy mixes for deep CO2 mitigation in road transport. Nature
Climate Change, 10(9), 809–818. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41558-020-0877-y
Beckenbach, F., Daskalakis, M., & Hofmann, D. (2018). Agent-based analysis of industrial dynamics and paths of environmental policy:
The case of non-renewable energy production in Germany. Computational Economics, 52(3), 953–994. https://doi.org/10.1007/
s10614-017-9773-6
Bennear, L. S., & Stavins, R. N. (2007). Second-best theory and the use of multiple policy instruments. Environmental and Resource
Economics, 37(1), 111–129. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-007-9110-y
Bernstein, S., & Hoffmann, M. (2019). Climate politics, metaphors and the fractal carbon trap. Nature Climate Change, 9(12), 919–925.
https://doi.org/10.1038/s41558-019-0618-2
Böhringer, C., & Rosendahl, K. E. (2011). Greening electricity more than necessary: On the cost implications of overlapping regulation
in EU climate policy. Schmollers Jahrbuch: Journal of Contextual Economics, 131(3), 469–492. https://doi.org/10.3790/schm.131.3.
469
Bollinger, B., & Gillingham, K. (2012). Peer effects in the diffusion of solar photovoltaic panels. Marketing Science, 31(6), 900–912.
https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1120.0727
Boonekamp, P. (2006). Actual interaction effects between policy measures for energy efficiency—a qualitative matrix method and
quantitative simulation results for households. Energy, 31(14), 2848–2873. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2006.01.004
Borrás, S., & Edquist, C. (2013). The choice of innovation policy instruments. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 80(8), 1513–
1522. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2013.03.002
Bouma, J. A., Verbraak, M., Dietz, F., & Brouwer, R. (2018). Policy mix: Mess or merit? Journal of Environmental Economics and Policy, 8
(1), 1–16. https://doi.org/10.1080/21606544.2018.1494636
Bowles, S. (2016). The moral economy: Why good incentives are no substitute for good citizens. Yale University Press.
Bozeman, B. (2000). Technology transfer and public policy: A review of research and theory. Research Policy, 29(4-5), 627–655. https://
doi.org/10.1016/S0048-7333(99)00093-1
Braathen, N. A. (2007). Instrument mixes for environmental policy: How many stones should be used to kill a bird? International
Review of Environmental and Resource Economics, 1(2), 185–235. https://doi.org/10.1561/101.00000005
Brandon, A., List, J. A., Metcalfe, R. D., Price, M. K., & Rundhammer, F. (2019). Testing for crowd out in social nudges: Evidence from a
natural field experiment in the market for electricity. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 116(12), 5293–5298. https://
doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1802874115
Bulkeley, H., & Kern, K. (2006). Local government and the governing of climate change in Germany and the UK. Urban Studies, 43(12),
2237–2259. https://doi.org/10.1080/00420980600936491
Christiansen, V., & Smith, S. (2012). Externality-correcting taxes and regulation. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 114(2), 358–
383. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9442.2012.01701.x
Christiansen, V., & Smith, S. (2015). Emissions taxes and abatement regulation under uncertainty. Environmental and Resource
Economics, 60(1), 17–35. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-013-9755-7
Cowan, R., & Hulten, S. (1996). Escaping lock-in: The case of the electric vehicle. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 53(1),
61–79. https://doi.org/10.1016/0040-1625(96)00059-5
David, P. A. (1985). Clio and the economics of QWERTY. American Economic Review, 75(2), 332–337. https://www.jstor.org/stable/
1805621?seq=1
Delarue, E., & Van den Bergh, K. (2016). Carbon mitigation in the electric power sector under cap-and-trade and renewables policies.
Energy Policy, 92, 34–44. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2016.01.028
Delmas, M., Fischlein, M., & Asensio, O. (2013). Information strategies and energy conservation behavior: A meta-analysis of exper-
imental studies from 1975 to 2012. Energy Policy, 61(C), 729–739. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2013.05.109
del Río, P. (2011). Interactions between climate and energy policies: The case of Spain. Climate Policy, 9(2), 119–138. https://doi.org/
10.3763/cpol.2007.0424
del Río, P. (2014). On evaluating success in complex policy mixes: The case of renewable energy support schemes. Policy Sciences, 47
(3), 267–287. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11077-013-9189-7
del Río, P. (2017). Why does the combination of the European Union emissions trading scheme and a renewable energy target makes
economic sense? Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, 74, 824–834. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2017.01.122
16 J. VAN DEN BERGH ET AL.
Di Stefano, G., Gambardella, A., & Verona, G. (2012). Technology push and demand pull perspectives in innovation studies: Current
findings and future research directions. Research Policy, 41(8), 1283–1295. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2012.03.021
Dolan, P., & Metcalfe, R. (2015). Neighbors, knowledge, and nuggets: Two natural field experiments on the role of incentives on
energy conservation. SSRN paper. doi:10.2139/ssrn.2589269
Dolfsma, W., & Dongback, S. (2013). Government policy and technological innovation—a suggested typology. Technovation, 33(6-7),
173–179. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2013.03.011
Drews, S., Exadaktylos, F., & van den Bergh, J. C. J. M. (2020). Assessing synergy of incentives and nudges in the energy policy mix.
Energy Policy, 144, 111605. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2020.111605
Duan, M., Tian, Z., Zhao, Y., & Li, M. (2017). Interactions and coordination between carbon emissions trading and other direct carbon
mitigation policies in China. Energy Research & Social Science, 33, 59–69. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.erss.2017.09.008
Durrmeyer, I. (2018). Winners and losers: The distributional effects of the French Feebate on the automobile market (TSE Working Papers
18-950). Toulouse School of Economics (TSE).
Edmondson, D. L., Kern, F., & Rogge, K. (2019). The co-evolution of policy mixes and socio-technical systems: Towards a conceptual
framework of policy mix feedback in sustainability transitions. Research Policy, 48(10), 103555. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.
2018.03.010
Ergas, H. (1987). The importance of technology policy. In P. Dasgupta & P. Stoneman (Eds.), Economic policy and technological per-
formance (pp. 51–96). Cambridge University Press.
Fagiani, R., Richstein, J. C., Hakvoort, R., & De Vries, L. (2014). The dynamic impact of carbon reduction and renewable support policies
on the electricity sector. Utilities Policy, 28, 28–41. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jup.2013.11.004
Fais, B., Blesl, M., Fahl, U., & Voß, A. (2015). Analysing the interaction between emission trading and renewable electricity support in
TIMES. Climate Policy, 15(3), 355–373. https://doi.org/10.1080/14693062.2014.927749
Fankhauser, S., Hepburn, C., & Park, J. (2010). Combining multiple climate policy instruments: How not to do it. Climate Change
Economics, 1(3), 209–225. https://doi.org/10.1142/S2010007810000169
Finch, A., & van den Bergh, J. (2020). Assessing the authenticity of national carbon prices. Unpublished working paper, ICTA-UAB.
Fischer, C., & Fox, A. K. (2012). Comparing policies to combat emissions leakage: Border carbon adjustments versus rebates. Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management, 64(2), 199–216. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2012.01.005
Flachsland, C., Pahle, M., Burtraw, D., Edenhofer, O., Elkerbout, M., Fischer, C., Tietjen, O., & Zetterberg, L. (2020). How to avoid history
repeating itself: The case for an EU emissions trading system (EU ETS) price floor revisited. Climate Policy, 20(1), 133–142. https://
doi.org/10.1080/14693062.2019.1682494
Font Vivanco, D., Kemp, R., & van der Voet, E. (2016). How to deal with the rebound effect? A policy-oriented approach. Energy Policy,
94, 114–125. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2016.03.054
Foramitti, J., Savin, I., & van den Bergh, J. (2021). Emission tax vs. permit trading under bounded rationality and dynamic markets.
Energy Policy, 148, 112009. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2020.112009
Fowlie, M. (2009). Incomplete environmental regulation, imperfect competition, and emissions leakage. American Economic Journal:
Economic Policy, 1(2), 72–112. https://doi.org/10.1257/pol.1.2.72
Freire-González, J. (2018). Environmental taxation and the double dividend hypothesis in CGE modelling literature: A critical review.
Journal of Policy Modeling, 40(1), 194–223. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpolmod.2017.11.002
Freire-González, J. (2020). Energy taxation policies can counteract the rebound effect: Analysis within a general equilibrium frame-
work. Energy Efficiency, 13(1), 69–78. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12053-019-09830-x
Geels, F., Sovacool, B. K., Schwanen, T., & Sorrell, S. (2017). Sociotechnical transitions for deep decarbonization. Science, 357(6357),
1242–1244. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.aao3760
Gerlagh, R., Kverndokk, S., & Rosendahl, K. E. (2009). Optimal timing of climate change policy: Interaction between carbon taxes and
innovation externalities. Environmental and Resource Economics, 43(3), 369–390. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-009-9271-y
Glaeser, E., & Ujhelyi, G. (2010). Regulating misinformation. Journal of Public Economics, 94(3-4), 247–257. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
jpubeco.2010.01.001
Görlach, B. (2014). Emissions trading in the climate policy mix — understanding and managing interactions with other policy instru-
ments. Energy & Environment, 25(3-4), 733–749. https://doi.org/10.1260/0958-305X.25.3-4.733
Goulder, L. H., & Parry, I. W. (2008). Instrument choice in environmental policy. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 2(2),
152–174. https://doi.org/10.1093/reep/ren005
Goulder, L. H., & Schein, A. R. (2013). Carbon taxes versus cap and trade: A critical review. Climate Change Economics, 04(03), 1350010.
https://doi.org/10.1142/S2010007813500103
Grülla, G., & Taschinibc, L. (2011). Cap-and-trade properties under different hybrid scheme designs. Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management, 61(1), 107–118. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2010.09.001
Gsottbauer, E., & van den Bergh, J. C. J. M. (2014). Environmental policy when pollutive consumption is sensitive to advertising:
Norms versus status. Ecological Economics, 107, 39–50. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2014.07.001
Hafstead, M. (2019). Carbon pricing 102: Revenue use options. Resources for the Future, September 26, 2019. https://media.rff.org/
documents/Carbon_Pricing_Explainer_102.pdf
Haites, E. (2018). Carbon taxes and greenhouse gas emissions trading systems: What have we learned? Climate Policy, 18(8), 955–966.
https://doi.org/10.1080/14693062.2018.1492897
Handgraaf, M. J. J., Van Lidth de Jeude, M. A., & Appelt, K. C. (2013). Public praise vs. private pay: Effects of rewards on energy con-
servation in the workplace. Ecological Economics, 86, 86–92. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2012.11.008
CLIMATE POLICY 17
Haultfœuille, X., Givord, P., & Boutin, X. (2014). The environmental effect of green taxation: The case of the French bonus/malus. The
Economic Journal, 124(578), F444–F480. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecoj.12089
Hepburn, C. (2006). Regulating by prices, quantities or both: An update and an overview. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 22(2),
226–247. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxrep/grj014
Herrmann, J. K., & Savin, I. (2017). Optimal policy identification: Insights from the German electricity market. Technological Forecasting
and Social Change, 122(C), 71–90. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2017.04.014
Hilton, D., Charalambides, L., Demarque, C., Waroquier, L., & Raux, C. (2014). A tax can nudge: The impact of an environmentally
motivated bonus/malus fiscal system on transport preferences. Journal of Economic Psychology, 42, 17–27. https://doi.org/10.
1016/j.joep.2014.02.007
HLCCP. (2017). Report of the high-level commission on carbon prices. World Bank.
Hood, C. (2013). Managing interactions between carbon pricing and existing energy policies: Guidance for policymakers. http://
www.indiaenvironmentportal.org.in/files/file/ManagingInteractionsCarbonPricing_FINAL.pdf
Hoppmann, J., Peters, M., Schneider, M., & Hoffmann, V. H. (2013). The two faces of market support—how deployment policies affect
technological exploration and exploitation in the solar photovoltaic industry. Research Policy, 42(4), 989–1003. https://doi.org/10.
1016/j.respol.2013.01.002
Howlett, M., & Rayner, J. (2007). Design principles for policy mixes: Cohesion and coherence in ‘new governance arrangements. Policy
and Society, 26(4), 1–18. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1449-4035(07)70118-2
Howlett, M., Vince, J., & del Rio, P. (2017). Policy integration and multi-level governance: Dealing with the vertical dimension of policy
mix designs. Politics and Governance, 5(2), 69–78. https://doi.org/10.17645/pag.v5i2.928
IMF. (2019). Fiscal policies for Paris climate strategies—from principle to practice. Fiscal Affairs Department, International Monetary
Fund.
Jacobsson, S., Bergek, A., & Sandén, B. (2017). Improving the European Commission’s analytical base for designing instrument mixes
in the energy sector: Market failures versus system weaknesses. Energy Research & Social Science, 33, 11–20. https://doi.org/10.
1016/j.erss.2017.09.009
Jacoby, H. D., & Ellerman, A. D. (2004). The safety valve and climate policy. Energy Policy, 32(4), 481–491. https://doi.org/10.1016/
S0301-4215(03)00150-2
Jaffe, A., Newell, R. G., & Stavins, R. N. (2005). A tale of two market failures: Technology and environmental policy. Ecological
Economics, 54(2), 164–174. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2004.12.027
Jenn, A., Azevedo, I. L., & Michalek, J. J. (2016). Alternative fuel vehicle adoption increases fleet gasoline consumption and green-
house gas emissions under United States corporate average fuel economy policy and greenhouse gas emission standards.
Environmental Science & Technology, 50(5), 2165–2174. https://doi.org/10.1021/acs.est.5b02842
Jenn, A., Azevedo, I. L., & Michalek, J. J. (2019). Alternative-fuel-vehicle policy interactions increase U.S. Greenhouse gas emissions.
Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice, 124, 396–407. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tra.2019.04.003
Jordan, A., Huitema, D., van Asselt, H., & Forster, J. (Eds.). (2018). Governing climate change: Polycentricity in action? Cambridge
University Press.
Jordan, A., & Lenschow, A. (2010). Environmental policy integration: A state of the art review. Environmental Policy and Governance, 20
(3), 147–158. https://doi.org/10.1002/eet.539
Klenert, D., Mattauch, L., Combet, E., Edenhofer, O., Hepburn, C., Rafaty, R., & Stern, N. (2018). Making carbon pricing work for citizens.
Nature Climate Change, 8(8), 669–677. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41558-018-0201-2
Konc, T., Savin, I., & van den Bergh, J. (2021). The social multiplier of environmental policy: Application to carbon taxation. Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management, 105, 102396. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2020.102396
Lecuyer, O., & Quirion, P. (2013). Can uncertainty justify overlapping policy instruments to mitigate emissions? Ecological Economics,
93, 177–191. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2013.05.009
Lehmann, P. (2012). Justifying a policy mix for pollution control: A review of economic literature. Journal of Economic Surveys, 26(1),
71–97. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6419.2010.00628.x
Lehmann, P., & Gawel, E. (2013). Why should support schemes for renewable electricity complement the EU emissions trading
scheme? Energy Policy, 52, 597–607. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2012.10.018
Li, S., Linn, J., & Muehlegger, E. (2014). Gasoline taxes and consumer behavior. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 6(4), 302–
342. https://doi.org/10.1257/pol.6.4.302
Lindman, Å, & Söderholm, P. (2016). Wind energy and green economy in Europe: Measuring policy-induced innovation using patent
data. Applied Energy, 179, 1351–1359. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2015.10.128
List, J. A., Metcalfe, R. D., Price, M. K., & Rundhammer, F. (2017). Harnessing policy complementarities to conserve energy: evidence from
a natural field experiment (NBER Working Paper No. 23355). doi:10.3386/w23355
Martin, B. R. (2012). The evolution of science policy and innovation studies. Research Policy, 41(7), 1219–1239. https://doi.org/10.
1016/j.respol.2012.03.012
Masson-Delmotte, V., Zhai, P., Pörtner, H.-O., Roberts, D., Skea, J., Shukla, P. R., Pirani, A., Moufouma-Okia, W., Péan, C., Pidcock, R.,
Connors, S., Matthews, J. B. R., Chen, Y., Zhou, X., Gomis, M. I., Lonnoy, E., Maycock, T., Tignor, M., & Waterfield, T. (Eds.). (2018).
Global Warming of 1.5°C. An IPCC Special Report on the impacts of global warming of 1.5°C above pre-industrial levels.
Geneva: IPCC.
18 J. VAN DEN BERGH ET AL.
Matthies, E., Kastner, I., Klesse, A., & Wagner, H. J. (2011). High reduction potentials for energy user behavior in public buildings: How
much can psychology-based interventions achieve? Journal of Environmental Studies and Sciences, 1(3), 241–255. https://doi.org/
10.1007/s13412-011-0024-1
Meckling, J., Kelsey, N., Biber, E., & Zysman, E. J. (2015). Winning coalitions for climate policy. Science, 349(6253), 1170–1171. https://
doi.org/10.1126/science.aab1336
Mercure, J.-F., Pollitt, H., Chewpreecha, U., Salas, P., Foley, A. M., Holden, P. B., & Edwards, N. R. (2014). The dynamics of technology
diffusion and the impacts of climate policy instruments in the decarbonisation of the global electricity sector. Energy Policy, 73,
686–700. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2014.06.029
Mizobuchi, K., & Takeuchi, K. (2013). The influences of financial and non-financial factors on energy-saving behaviour: A field exper-
iment in Japan. Energy Policy, 63, 775–787. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2013.08.064
Mundaca, L., Sonnenschein, J., Steg, L., Höhne, N., & Ürge-Vorsatz, D. (2019). The global expansion of climate mitigation policy inter-
ventions, the Talanoa dialogue and the role of behavioural insights. Environmental Research Communications, 1(6), 061001.
https://doi.org/10.1088/2515-7620/ab26d6
Murray, B. C., Cropper, M. L., de la Chesnaye, F. C., & Reilly, J. M. (2014). How effective are US renewable energy subsidies in cutting
greenhouse gases? American Economic Review, 104(5), 569–574. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.5.569
Nisa, C. F., Bélanger, J. J., Schumpe, B. M., & Faller, D. G. (2019). Meta-analysis of randomised controlled trials testing behavioural
interventions to promote household action on climate change. Nature Communications, 10(1), 1–13. https://doi.org/10.1038/
s41467-018-07882-8
Nyborg, K., Howarth, R. B., & Brekke, A. (2006). Green consumers and public policy: On socially contingent moral motivation. Resource
and Energy Economics, 28(4), 351–366. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2006.03.001
OECD. (2011). Interactions between emission trading systems and other overlapping policy instruments. General Distribution
Document, Environment Directorate. Paris: OECD, www.oecd.org/env/taxes
Oikonomou, V., Flamos, A., & Grafakos, S. (2010). Is blending of energy and climate policy instruments always desirable? Energy Policy,
38(2010), 4186–4195. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2010.03.046
Oikonomou, V., & Jepma, C. (2007). A framework on interactions of climate and energy policy instruments. Mitigation and Adaptation
Strategies for Global Change, 13(2), 131–156. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11027-007-9082-9
Osorio, S., Pietzcker, R. C., Pahle, M., & Edenhofer, O. (2020). How to deal with the risks of phasing out coal in Germany. Energy
Economics, 87, 104730. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2020.104730
Palage, K., Lundmark, R., & Söderholm, P. (2019). The innovation effects of renewable energy policies and their interaction: The case
of solar photovoltaics. Environmental Economics and Policy Studies, 21, 217–254.
Panzone, L. A., Ulph, A., Zizzo, D. J., Hilton, D., & Clear, A. (2018). The impact of environmental recall and carbon taxation on the
carbon footprint of supermarket shopping. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
jeem.2018.06.002
Pellerano, J. A., Price, M. K., Puller, S. L., & Sánchez, G. E. (2017). Do extrinsic incentives undermine social norms? Evidence from a field
experiment in energy conservation. Environmental and. Resource Economics, 67(3), 413–428. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-016-
0094-3
Perino, G. (2018). New EU ETS phase 4 rules temporarily puncture waterbed. Nature Climate Change, 8(20), 262–264. https://doi.org/
10.1038/s41558-018-0120-2
Perino, G., Panzone, L. A., & Swanson, T. (2014). Motivation crowding in real consumption decisions: Who is messing with my gro-
ceries? Economic Inquiry, 52(2), 592–607. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecin.12024
Perino, G., Ritz, R. A., & van Benthem, A. (2019). Understanding overlapping policies: Internal carbon leakage and the punctured
waterbed (NBER Working Paper No. 25643).
Philibert, C. (2009). Assessing the value of price caps and floors. Climate Policy, 9(6), 612–633. https://doi.org/10.3763/cpol.2008.0586
Pitelis, A. T. (2018). Industrial policy for renewable energy: The innovation impact of European policy instruments and their inter-
actions. Competition and Change, 22(3), 227–254.
Pizer, W. A. (1997). Prices vs. quantities revisited: The case of climate change (Discussion paper 98-02). Resources for the Future,
Washington, DC.
Popp, D. (2002). Induced innovation and energy prices. The American Economic Review, 92(1), 160–180. https://doi.org/10.1257/
000282802760015658
Richstein, J. C., Chappin, ÉJL, & de Vries, L. J. (2015). Adjusting the CO2 cap to subsidised RES generation: Can CO2 prices be decoupled
from renewable policy? Applied Energy, 156, 693–702. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2015.07.024
Roberts, M. J., & Spence, M. (1976). Effluent charges and licenses under uncertainty. Journal of Public Economics, 5(3-4), 193–208.
https://doi.org/10.1016/0047-2727(76)90014-1
Rogge, K. S., Kern, F., & Howlett, M. (2017). Conceptual and empirical advances in analysing policy mixes for energy transitions. Energy
Research & Social Science, 33, 1–10. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.erss.2017.09.025
Rogge, K. S., & Reichardt, K. (2016). Policy mixes for sustainability transitions: An extended concept and framework for analysis.
Research Policy, 45(8), 1620–1635. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016.04.004
Rosenow, J., Kern, F., & Rogge, K. (2017). The need for comprehensive and well targeted instrument mixes to stimulate energy tran-
sitions: The case of energy efficiency policy. Energy Research & Social Science, 33, 95–104. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.erss.2017.09.
013
CLIMATE POLICY 19
Schall, D. L., Wolf, M., & Mohnen, A. (2016). Do effects of theoretical training and rewards for energy-efficient behavior persist over
time and interact? A natural field experiment on eco-driving in a company fleet. Energy Policy, 97, 291–300. https://doi.org/10.
1016/j.enpol.2016.07.008
Schatzki, T., & Stavins, R. N. (2012). Implications of policy interactions for California’s climate policy. 23 pp. https://www.
analysisgroup.com/globalassets/content/insights/publishing/implications_policy_interactions_california_climate_policy.pdf
Schmidt, T. S., & Sewerin, S. (2019). Measuring the temporal dynamics of policy mixes – an empirical analysis of renewable energy
policy mixes’ balance and design features in nine countries. Research Policy, 48(10), 103557. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2018.
03.012
Schubert, C. (2017). Green nudges: Do they work? Are they ethical? Ecological Economics, 132, 329–342. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
ecolecon.2016.11.009
Seto, K. C., Davis, S. J., Mitchell, R. B., Stokes, E. C., Unruh, G., & Ürge-Vorsatz, D. (2016). Carbon lock-in: Types, causes, and policy impli-
cations. Annual Review of Environment and Resources, 41(1), 425–452. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-environ-110615-085934
Sijm, J. (2005). The interaction between the EU emission trading scheme and national energy policy schemes. Climate Policy, 5(1), 79–
96. https://doi.org/10.1080/14693062.2005.9685542
Silvia, C., & Krause, R. M. (2016). Assessing the impact of policy interventions on the adoption of plug-in electric vehicles: An agent-
based model. Energy Policy, 96, 105–118. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2016.05.039
Sinn, H. W. (2015). Introductory comment–the green paradox: A supply-side view of the climate problem. Review of Environmental
Economics and Policy, 9(2), 239–245. https://doi.org/10.1093/reep/rev011
Skovsgaard Aidta, T., & Duttab, J. (2004). Transitional politics: Emerging incentive-based instruments in environmental regulation.
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 47(3), 458–479. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2003.07.002
Somanathan, E., Sterner, T., Sugiyama, T., Chimanikire, D., Dubash, N. K., Essandoh-Yeddu, J., Fifita, S., Goulder, L., Jaffe, A., Labandeira,
X., Managi, S., Mitchell, C., Montero, J. P., Teng, F., & Zylicz, T. (2014). National and Subnational Policies and Institutions. Chapter 15
In Climate Change 2014: Mitigation of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fifth Assessment Report of the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [Edenhofer, O., R. Pichs-Madruga, Y. Sokona, E. Farahani, S. Kadner, K. Seyboth,
A. Adler, I. Baum, S. Brunner, P. Eickemeier, B. Kriemann, J. Savolainen, S. Schlömer, C. von Stechow, T. Zwickel and J.C. Minx
(Eds.)]. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Sorrell, S., Harrison, D., Radov, D., Klevnas, P., & Foss, A. (2009). White certificate schemes: Economic analysis and interactions with the
EU ETS. Energy Policy, 37(1), 29–42. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2008.08.009
Sorrell, S., & Sijm, J. (2003). Carbon trading in the policy mix. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 19(3), 420–437. https://doi.org/10.
1093/oxrep/19.3.420
Stern, P. C. (1999). Information, incentives, and proenvironmental consumer behavior. Journal of Consumer Policy, 22(4), 461–478.
https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1006211709570
Stern, P. C. (2020). A reexamination on how behavioral interventions can promote household action to limit climate change.
Nature Communications, 11(1), 1–3.
Sterner, T. (2002). Policy instruments for environmental and natural resource management. RFF Press.
Sterner, T., Barbier, E. B., Bateman, I., van den Bijgaart, I., Crépin, A.-S., Edenhofer, O., Fischer, C., Habla, W., Hassler, J., Johansson-
Stenman, O., Lange, A., Polasky, S., Rockström, J., Smith, H. G., Steffen, W., Wagner, G., Wilen, J. E., Alpízar, F., Azar, C., …
Robinson, A. (2019). Policy design for the anthropocene. Nature Sustainability, 2(1), 14–21. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41893-018-
0194-x
Stiglitz, J. E. (2019). Addressing climate change through price and non-price interventions. European Economic Review, 119, 594–612.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2019.05.007
Stoneman, P., & David, P. A. (1986). Adoption subsidies vs. information provision as instruments of technology policy. The Economic
Journal, 96(Supplement), I42–I5I.
Sudarshan, A. (2017). Nudges in the marketplace: The response of household electricity consumption to information and monetary
incentives. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 134, 320–335. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2016.12.015
Thurber, M. C., Davis, T. L., & Wolak, F. A. (2015). Simulating the interaction of a renewable portfolio standard with electricity and
carbon markets. The Electricity Journal, 28(4), 51–65. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tej.2015.04.007
Tinbergen, J. (1952). On the theory of economic policy. North-Holland Publishing Company.
Tørnblad, S. H., Kallbekken, S., Korneliussen, K., & Mideksa, T. K. (2014). Using mobility management to reduce private car use: Results
from a natural field experiment in Norway. Transport Policy, 32, 9–15. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tranpol.2013.12.005
Trencher, G., & van der Heijden, J. (2019). Instrument interactions and relationships in policy mixes: Achieving complementarity in
building energy efficiency policies in New York, Sydney and Tokyo. Energy Research & Social Science, 54(2019), 34–45. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.erss.2019.02.023
Tu, Q., & Mo, J.-L. (2017). Coordinating carbon pricing policy and renewable energy policy with a case study in China. Computers &
Industrial Engineering, 113, 294–304. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cie.2017.09.026
Twomey, P. (2012). Rationales for additional climate policy instruments under a carbon price. The Economic and Labour Relations
Review, 23(1), 7–31. https://doi.org/10.1177/103530461202300102
van den Bergh, J. C. J. M. (2011). Energy conservation more effective with rebound policy. Environmental and Resource Economics, 48
(1), 43–58. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-010-9396-z
van den Bergh, J. C. J. M. (2013a). Policies to enhance economic feasibility of a sustainable energy transition. Proceedings of the
National Academy of Sciences, 110(7), 2436–2437. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1221894110
20 J. VAN DEN BERGH ET AL.
van den Bergh, J. C. J. M. (2013b). Environmental and climate innovation: Limitations, policies and prices. Technological Forecasting
and Social Change, 80(1), 11–23. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2012.08.004
van den Bergh, J. C. J. M., Angelsen, A., Baranzini, A., Botzen, W. J. W., Carattini, S., Drews, S., Dunlop, T., Galbraith, E., Gsottbauer, E.,
Howarth, R. B., Padilla, E., Roca, J., & Schmidt, R. C. (2020). A dual-track transition to global carbon pricing. Climate Policy, 20(9),
1057–1069. https://doi.org/10.1080/14693062.2020.1797618
van der Ploeg, R., & Withagen, C. (2015). Global warming and the green paradox: A review of adverse effects of climate policies.
Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 9(2), 285–303. https://doi.org/10.1093/reep/rev008
Venmans, F., Ellis, J., & Nachtigall, D. (2020). Carbon pricing and competitiveness: Are they at odds? Climate Policy, 20(9), 1070–1091.
https://doi.org/10.1080/14693062.2020.1805291
Vilchez, J. J., Jochem, P., & Fichtnera, W. (2020). Interlinking major markets to explore electric car uptake. Energy Policy, 144, 111588.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2020.111588
Way, R., Lafond, F., Lillo, F., Panchenko, V., & Farmer, D. (2019). Wright meets Markowitz: How standard portfolio theory changes when
assets are technologies following experience curves. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 101, 211–238. https://doi.org/10.
1016/j.jedc.2018.10.006
Weitzman, M. L. (1974). Prices vs. quantities. The Review of Economic Studies, 41(4), 477–491. https://doi.org/10.2307/2296698
Weitzman, M. L. (2014). Can negotiating a uniform carbon price help to internalize the global warming externality? Journal of the
Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, 1(1/2), 29–49. https://doi.org/10.1086/676039
Weitzman, M. L. (2017). On a world climate assembly and the social cost of carbon. Economica, 84(336), 559–586. https://doi.org/10.
1111/ecca.12248
Whistance, J., Thompson, W., & Meyer, S. (2017). Interactions between California’s low carbon fuel standard and the national renew-
able fuel standard. Energy Policy, 101, 447–455. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2016.10.040
Wiese, C., Larsen, A., & Pade, L. L. (2018). Interaction effects of energy efficiency policies: A review. Energy Efficiency, 11(8), 2137–2156.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s12053-018-9659-z
Wynes, S., Nicholas, K. A., Zhao, J., & Donner, S. D. (2018). Measuring what works: Quantifying greenhouse gas emission reductions of
behavioural interventions to reduce driving, meat consumption, and household energy use. Environmental Research Letters, 13
(11), 113002. https://doi.org/10.1088/1748-9326/aae5d7
Zeppini, P., & van den Bergh, J. (2020). Global competition dynamics of fossil fuels and renewable energy under climate policies and
peak-oil: A behavioural model. Energy Policy, 136, 110907. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2019.110907