Various A-Level Economics Notes
Various A-Level Economics Notes
Various A-Level Economics Notes
An indifference curve shows the different combinations of two goods say x apples and
y oranges which yield equal utility to the consumer. Since all the combinations on an
indifference curve yield the same utility, the consumer is indifferent to what
combination he consumes. In other words, all the combinations of the goods lying on
a consumer’s indifference are equally desirable to or equally preferred by him.
From the indifference curve IC given above the consumer derives the same
satisfaction from combination S and T and is therefore indifferent from S or T.
2. Indifference curves slope downwards from the left to the right. They must be
negatively sloped.
3. Indifference curves are convex to origin. Indifference curves must be relatively
flatter on its right hand side and relatively steeper on its left hand side.
4. A higher indifference curve represents a higher level of satisfaction than a
lower indifference curve.
14
12
10
Oranges
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6
Apples
From the diagram above, it is deduced that the marginal rate of substitution of apples
for oranges declines. In other words, MRS Apples Oranges falls, as a consumer increases his
consumption of apples. Consider the indifference schedule given below.
2. Perfect Complements
Indifference curves for perfect complements are ‘L-shaped’. Examples of perfect
complements are left and right hands gloves. There is no rate at which a consumer
would be willing to substitute one kind of glove for another.
3. An absolute necessity
Water is a necessity and there is a minimum amount of water essential to sustain life.
As the consumption of water falls towards W0, increasingly amounts of other goods
has to be sacrificed to increase the amount of water even by a small amount.
All points on the budget line represent bundles of goods that a household can
consume using his complete income. It implies that when the household moves from
one point on the budget line to another, the change in expenditure on apples must be
of equal value but opposite sign to the change in expenditure on oranges. Assume ∆A
and ∆O is the change in quantities of apples and oranges and Pa and Po stand for the
prices of apples and oranges. The above relationship can be mathematically
represented as
(∆O x Po) = - (∆A x Pa)
The formula states that if any amount more spent on a good, the same amount less must
be spent on the good. By dividing the above equation by ∆A, it is reduced to
(∆O x Po)/ ∆A = - (∆A x Pa)/ ∆A
∆O/∆A = -Pa/Po
Therefore, the slope of the budget line is the negative of the ratio of the two prices
(with the price of the good on the horizontal axis appearing on the numerator and that
of the vertical axis on the denominator). Hence it can be concluded that the slope of
the budget line depends only on the relation between the two prices. In fact, the slope
represents the opportunity cost of apples in terms of oranges.
Consumer Equilibrium
A rational consumer is in equilibrium when given his budget line he maximises his total
utility. A consumer is in equilibrium when he is buying such a combination of goods
that reallocation and increasing total utility is impossible. Diagrammatically, this is
shown when his budget line is tangent to the highest indifference curve.
In the diagram above, the x-axis represents the quantity of apples and the y-axis the
quantity of oranges. The rational consumer is in equilibrium when the budget line AB
is tangent to the highest possible indifference curve IC 2.At equilibrium the consumer
demands ON of apples and OM of oranges.