Export Orientation and Economic Growth - Thesis
Export Orientation and Economic Growth - Thesis
Export Orientation and Economic Growth - Thesis
by
CHHUOR Sryneath
DISSERTATION
Doctor of Philosophy
In International Development
NAGOYA UNIVERSITY
Naoko SHINKAI
Tetsuo UMEMURA
Sovannroeun SAMRETH
i
Export Strategy ...............................................................................................................28
2.4.1. Assessment of Competitiveness and Constraints ....................................................28
2.4.2. Dealing with Constraints .........................................................................................28
2.4.3. Export Diversification .............................................................................................29
Export Policies by Sector ...............................................................................................32
2.5.4. Agriculture ..............................................................................................................32
2.5.5. Industry ...................................................................................................................35
2.5.6. Services ...................................................................................................................35
Chapter 3: Conceptual Framework: Exports and Economic Development ......................37
Why Export? ...................................................................................................................37
3.1.1. Export Promotion vs Import Substitution ...............................................................37
3.1.2. Export Expansion and Economic Performance (Export-Led Growth Evidence) ...38
3.1.2.1. Exports as a factor of production .................................................................38
3.1.2.2. Externalities and Export-Led Growth ..........................................................40
3.1.2.3. Export and Trade: Income Distribution and Convergence ...........................40
What to Export ...............................................................................................................42
3.2.1. Exports and International Trade in Theory .............................................................42
3.2.2. Identifying Exports in Practice ...............................................................................45
3.2.2.1. The Leontief Paradox ...................................................................................45
3.2.2.2. Revealed Comparative Advantage ...............................................................45
3.2.2.3. Export and Sectoral Linkages .......................................................................47
What Makes Exports Grow ............................................................................................48
3.3.1. Export Supply Determinants ...................................................................................48
3.3.2. Policies affecting export performance ....................................................................49
3.3.2.1. Direct Policy .................................................................................................49
3.3.2.2. Indirect Policy ..............................................................................................51
Chapter 4: Specification of Key Sectors: Implications for Export Potential Industries...............55
Introduction ....................................................................................................................55
Challenges to the Performance of Export Sectors ..........................................................57
4.2.1. Slow Progress of Diversification ............................................................................57
4.2.2. Lack of Value Chains ..............................................................................................58
4.2.3. Underperformance in the Regional Market ............................................................59
Research Objective and Data..........................................................................................59
ii
Methodology...................................................................................................................62
4.4.1. Backward and Forward Linkages ...........................................................................65
4.4.1.1. Linkage Indices ............................................................................................65
4.4.1.2. Coefficients of Variation ..............................................................................66
4.4.2. Multiplier Effects ....................................................................................................67
4.4.3. Employment Intensity .............................................................................................68
4.4.4. Trade Balance .........................................................................................................69
4.4.5. Hypothetical Extraction ..........................................................................................70
Result and Discussion.....................................................................................................72
Concluding Remarks ......................................................................................................84
Chapter 5: Potential Roles of Export Orientation and Policy Options for Cambodia’s
Agriculture and Agro-industry..............................................................................................88
Introduction ....................................................................................................................88
Economic and Export Performance of Agriculture, Food and the Rubber Industry ......90
5.2.1. Agriculture ..............................................................................................................91
5.2.2. Processed food ........................................................................................................93
5.2.3. Rubber .....................................................................................................................95
Literature Reviews..........................................................................................................97
5.3.1. Non-CGE Models ...................................................................................................97
5.3.2. CGE Models ............................................................................................................98
Methodology and Data .................................................................................................100
5.4.1. Basic Characteristics of the CGE model ...............................................................100
5.4.2. Basic characteristics of the SAM ..........................................................................108
5.4.3. Economic structural features in the base scenario ................................................110
5.4.4. Household income and expenditure estimations ...................................................112
Export Orientation and its impacts: simulations and analysis ......................................114
5.5.1. Analytical Framework...........................................................................................114
5.5.2. Macro Closure .......................................................................................................116
5.5.3. Simulation Designs ...............................................................................................117
5.5.4. Results and Discussion..........................................................................................120
5.5.4.1. Impacts of External Trade Patterns ............................................................120
5.5.4.2. Impacts of Internal Shocks .........................................................................124
5.5.4.3. Impacts of Domestic Policies .....................................................................127
5.5.4.4. Sensitivity Analysis ....................................................................................132
iii
Concluding Remarks ....................................................................................................132
Chapter 6: The Impacts of Trade Facilitation on Economic and Export Structures..........135
Introduction ..................................................................................................................135
Literature reviews .........................................................................................................138
Methodology and Data .................................................................................................140
6.3.1. Incorporating trade facilitation in the CGE model................................................141
6.3.2. Data .......................................................................................................................143
6.3.2.1. The SAM structure .....................................................................................143
6.3.2.2. Tariff equivalents for time barriers ............................................................144
6.3.2.3. Tariff equivalents of export and import times of Cambodia ......................146
Simulation Results and Discussion ..............................................................................147
6.4.1. Simulation design ..................................................................................................147
6.4.2. Effects on Macro Economy...................................................................................148
6.4.3. Effects on Sectoral Trade ......................................................................................150
6.4.4. Effects on Production Factors ...............................................................................153
6.4.5. Effects on Household income and welfare ...........................................................155
Asia Experience in Export-led Growth ........................................................................156
6.5.1. Export Performance ..............................................................................................156
6.5.2. Trade Policy Reform .............................................................................................158
6.5.3. Trade and Infrastructure Environment: Cambodia and Other Countries ..............162
Concluding Remarks ....................................................................................................167
Chapter 7: Conclusion and Policy Implications .................................................................170
Main Findings ...............................................................................................................171
Policy Implications .......................................................................................................175
Limitation and Future Studies ......................................................................................179
References ..............................................................................................................................181
Appendix ................................................................................................................................ 186
iv
List of Tables
Table 1.1: Trade Performance, ASEAN, 1995-2011 ..................................................................3
Table 2.1: Foreign Direct Investment (in US$ million)............................................................15
Table 2.2: Export and Import Commodities and Partners (share in total exports), 2010 .........18
Table 2.3: Trade-related law on WTO access legal agenda .....................................................20
Table 2.4: A Few Existing Industrial Policy Instruments .........................................................22
Table 2.5: Cambodia and Intra-Regional Trade .......................................................................27
Table 2.6: Assessment of exports for the 19 products and services .........................................30
Table 2.7: Positioning Levels of the 19 Products and Services ................................................31
Table 2.8: Domestic Support Measure for Agriculture, 2007-2008 .........................................33
Table 2.9: Garment Sector, 2004-2010 .....................................................................................35
Table 2.10: Tourism Sector ......................................................................................................36
Table 4.1: Export and Import by Categories, share in total values (1995-2012)......................56
Table 4.2: Export Diversification Index, ASEAN, 2000 and 2012 ..........................................57
Table 4.3: Manufactured Exports and Value Added, Cambodia and Asia, 2000-2009 ...........58
Table 4.4: 18 Sectors of the Cambodia’s I-O Table, 2011 .......................................................60
Table 4.5: Structural Feature, Cambodian Economy, 2011 ......................................................61
Table 4.6: Basic Transaction I-O Table ....................................................................................63
Table 4.7: Backward-Forward Linkages of the Cambodian Economy by Sector, 2011 ..........72
Table 4.8: Index of Power and Sensitivity of Dispersion.............................................................74
Table 4.9: Net Exporting and Net Importing Sectors ...............................................................81
Table 4.10: Hypothetical Extraction Effect on Outputs ...........................................................82
Table 4.11: Sectoral Normalization Scores and Ranks.............................................................83
Table 5.1: Targeted share of export sectors (% of total exports) ..............................................89
Table 5.2: Agriculture value added and contribution to GDP by categories (1995-2014) .......91
Table 5.3: Agriculture export by categories (2000-2014) ........................................................92
Table 5.4: Manufacturing value added and contribution to GDP by sector (1995-2014) ........94
Table 5.5: Food-Beverage-Tobacco export by categories (2000-2014) ...................................95
Table 5.6: Cambodia’s Macro SAM, 2011 (Million USD) ....................................................109
Table 5.7: Industries and Commodities in the Cambodia’s SAM, 2011 ................................ 110
Table 5.8: Structural feature of Cambodian economy at base scenario, 2011........................111
Table 5.9: Estimation of Household income in the SAM .......................................................113
Table 5.10: Simulation designs ...............................................................................................117
Table 5.12: Simulation results (% deviation from base values) .............................................131
Table 5.11: Sensitivity Analysis for Armington and Export Elasticity ..................................132
Table 6.1: Per-day tariff equivalents, by region .....................................................................145
Table 6.2: Export and Import times in days, Cambodia, 2012 ...............................................146
Table 6.3: Simulation designs for trade facilitation ................................................................ 147
Table 6.4: Effects on exports and export prices by sector (% changes from base) ................151
v
Table 6.5: Effects on imports and import prices by sector (% changes from base) ...............152
Table 6.6: Effects on production factors (% change) .............................................................154
Table 6.7: The Effects on household welfare .........................................................................156
Table 6.8: East and South Asia Exports, 1995-2011 (US$ billion) ........................................157
Table 6.9: Timing shift in trade policy, some East Asia economies ......................................158
Table 6.10: Infrastructure, Starting a Business, Trade across Borders, Cambodia, East and South Asia
................................................................................................................................................166
Table 6.11: Infrastructure in Asia, 2001 .................................................................................167
vi
List of Figures
Figure 1.1: Structure of the dissertation......................................................................................9
Figure 2.1: Share of Sectors in Economy and GDP Growth Rate ............................................11
Figure 2.2: Trade Balance, Export and Import Figure..............................................................16
Figure 2.3: Export and Import by Sector ..................................................................................17
Figure 2.4: Share in Total Exports to ASEAN by Members ...................................................25
Figure 2.5: National Export Strategy 4-Gears ..........................................................................29
Figure 3.1: Buy-Ship-Pay Model (Process in Trade transaction) .............................................52
Figure 4.1: Linkage-Oriented Classification ............................................................................74
Figure 4.2: Multiplier Effects on Income by Sectors................................................................76
Figure 4.3: Labor Intensities (per M.US$ of Final Demand) ...................................................79
Figure 5.1: Rubber production and export (2000-2014) ...........................................................96
Figure 5.2: Nested Structure of Production Framework .........................................................101
Figure 5.3: Conceptual Framework of the Study ....................................................................114
Figure 5.4: Simulation results of Export demand shocks (% change from base data) ...........121
Figure 5.5: Simulation results of terms of trade shocks (% change from base) .....................123
Figure 5.6: Simulation results of productivity shocks (% change from base) ........................125
Figure 5.7: Simulation results of subsidy and tariff policies (% change from base) ..............128
Figure 6.1: Simplification, Harmonization and Standardization in Trade Facilitation ..........136
Figure 6.2: AVEs of time to export, AVEs of time to import, and Import tariffs ..................147
Figure 6.3: Macro effects of simulation 1: Trade facilitation (% changes from base values) 148
Figure 6.4: Macro effects of simulation 2: Trade liberalization .............................................149
Figure 6.5: Macro effects of simulation 3: Trade facilitation and investment .......................150
Figure 6.6: Logistic Performance Indicators (1-5, best) .........................................................163
Figure 6.7: Trade Facilitation Performance, OECD Indicators ..............................................164
vii
Abbreviations
ADB Asian Development Bank
AVEs Ad Valorem Equivalents
ASEAN Association of South East Asia Nations
BL Backward Linkage
CGE Computable General Equilibrium
CES Constant Elasticity of Substitution
CET Constant Elasticity of Transformation
CSES Cambodia Socio-Economic Survey
DTIS Diagnostic Trade Integration Study
EP Export Promotion
EPZs Export Processing Zones
FDI Foreign Direct Investment
FL Forward Linkage
F.O.B Freight On Board
FTA Free Trade Agreement
GDP Gross Domestic Product
GSP Generalized Special Program
GTAP Global Trade Analysis Project
HEM Hypothetical Extraction Method
IMF International Monetary Fund
I–O Input-Output
IS Import Substitution
MFA Multi-Fiber Agreement
MFNs Most Favor Nations
MOC Ministry Of Commerce
NBC National Bank of Cambodia
NIEs Newly Industrialized Economies
OECD Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development
PEP Partnership for Economic Policy Networks
R&D Research and Development
RCA Revealed Comparative Advantage
SAM Social Accounting Matrix
SEZs Special Economic Zones
SPS Sanitary and Phyto-Sanitary
TBT Technical Barriers to Trade
Trade SWAps Trade Sector-Wide Approaches
WDI World Development Indicators
WTO World Trade Organization
viii
Acknowledgement
The completion of this doctoral dissertation would not have been possible without the
continuous support from many individuals.
Professor FUJIKAWA Kiyoshi, my main academic supervisor, has given me valuable
advice, consultation and constructive comments which enabled me to broaden my understanding
of the subject and gather ideas toward the complete organization of the research. I am inspired
by and owe my profound gratitude for his immense knowledge, supportive guidance and patience
throughout the whole process of my study. Moreover, I am grateful to Professor SHINKAI
Naoko, Professor UMEMURA Tetsuo, and Professor SAMRETH Sovannroeun for their helpful
comments and advice to further improve this dissertation. Their contributions are highly
appreciated.
I gratefully acknowledge the government of Japan, through the Ministry of Education,
Culture, Sports, Science and Technology for granting me this priceless opportunity to pursue my
education in the country with highly developed educational system and human resource.
Graduate School of International Development has provided me with a wide range of
development knowledge locally and globally. My appreciation is extended to faculty members
of GSID and International Student Affair Desk for their kind administrative support. I also thank
Assistant Professor Francis PEDDIE for his English editing.
In addition, Mr. EAR Sothy has shared his data sources and research experience on
similar methodology, which has provided me with a number of priceless inputs for my study. I
am grateful for his active discussion, advice, and encouragement.
Part of the research is attributed to Prof. Decaluwe and his team who have made the CGE
model of the PEP (Partnership for Economic Policy Networks) and its GAMS code available.
Dr. PHIM Runsinarith and Dr. Christian OTCHIA, my seniors of Prof. Fujikawa’s seminar, have
given me helpful comments for my research. I am also thankful to Mr. CHHAY Vannpoly, all
other Cambodian friends and seniors, International friends, and Japanese friends for their
understanding and support.
Finally, my greatest gratitude goes to my father, CHHUOR Kim Srun, my mother,
CHHIN Sam Ang, and my sister, CHHUOR Chansryeng, for their warmest hearts and constant
support, for inspiring me to go further for academic achievement, and for being the persons I can
always reach. They give me everything I have today.
ix
Chapter 1: Introduction
Background of the Study
A strong force of economic integration has emerged during recent decades and brought
along not only physical and financial capital but also technological upgrading for economic
acceleration. The concepts of trade policy have changed over time since the 1950s, and now
trade policy has become one of the main concerns for development. Trade was once centered
on import substitution policy, in which domestic production was encouraged and protected to
replace imports to satisfy domestic demand with incentives provided to the so-called infant
industries—newly established industries with the high potential to grow (Todaro & Smith,
2009). This initiative was seen as the road to industrialization. However, another point of view
suggests export promotion policy for developing countries to stimulate growth. Lessons from
remarkably high growth countries, especially the first tier of newly industrialized economies
(NIEs), including South Korea, Hong Kong, Taiwan and Singapore, and later the second tier
NIEs, namely Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand, and Indonesia, give strong evidence of
successful export-led growth (Weiss, 2005). This strategy has also been merged into the growth
Similarly, Cambodia has incorporated trade into growth policy. During the early 1990s,
economy, and carried out several institutional and economic reforms, including in trade and
export. Trade liberalization has been one of the main driving forces for the country’s strong
economic performance. Cambodia’s trade increased from 48 percent of GDP in 1993 to 140
percent in 2013, more than half of which is accounted for by exports growing at 18 percent on
average annually (WDI, 2015). Notably, the garment industry and tourism are the leading
export sectors over the last decade (World Bank, 2009). This growth has been realized through
a combination of targeted policy—tax incentives and quota increases for the garment sector—
and horizontal policy such as tariff cuts and the accession to ASEAN in 1999 and the WTO in
1
2004. Other factors such as general macroeconomic stability and the security environment also
be defined for a better understanding. According to Todaro and Smith (2009, p. 822), exports
and others (excluding factor services such as investment receipts and remittances)—sold to the
rest of the world, whereas merchandise exports, valued f.o.b (freight on board), refer to “all
importing partners. Export promotion, on the other hand, is defined as “governmental efforts to
expand the volume of a country’s exports through incentive and other means in order to
generate more foreign exchange and improve the current account of its balance of payment”
(Todaro and Smith, 2009, p. 822). Questions emerge as to which products a country should
export, what impacts they would bring, and what factors make exports boom. Trade theories,
as well as empirical studies, strive to answer the questions, yet how to adopt and succeed in
circumstances; therefore, a comprehensive study related to the issues is needed for each
economy.
Problem Statements
Along with rapid growth, Cambodia’s exports face a number of challenges, a few of
which cannot be overlooked and for which immediate actions are needed. First, diversification
toward new goods and services has made slow progress, while manufacturing production chains
have remained low. Although the tourism sector has stayed strong, the garment industry has
slowed down, especially during the late 2000s, thus merchandise trade which depends highly
on the garment sector has been vulnerable. Because of these facts, additional strategic sectors
with export potential and export improvement techniques need to be identified. The low-end
garments and exporting markets within the garment sector itself are mainly based on the
2
advantages of quota assessment; for example, the US and EU market are the main exporting
partners due to the increased access through the quota system under the Everything-But-Arms
initiative, while intermediates are mostly imported and assembled into finished products. Other
sectors, both exporting and non-exporting, have been left unaffected, and the economic linkages
for growth seem to be ignored (World Bank, 2009). As a result, the impacts of exports on other
factors such as the employment and the creation of value chains are limited.
Second, the trade deficit has persisted over two decades. The current account deficit
peaked at ten percent of GDP in 2012, and the trade deficit has remained around eight percent
of GDP since 2005, showing that moderate exports are not enough to cover the loss of foreign
exchange because of higher imports (IMF, 2012; WDI, 2012). The deficit is currently financed
by foreign direct investment and official loans. Although it is projected that the deficit will
narrow in the medium term along with saving-investment and higher export growth, the
possibility and sustainability of deficit reduction is being questioned due to the unidentified
comparison with other ASEAN members, the level of trade openness of Cambodia, the trade-
GDP ratio, is at 1.28 on average from 2005 to 2010, which is similar to that of Thailand and
3
relatively higher than that of Indonesia and the Philippines, yet the trade deficit of Cambodia is
Third, Cambodia’s exports to the regional market have remained low. In 2011, for
instance, Cambodia’s exports to ASEAN accounted for 0.26 percent, the smallest share, of the
total exports from all of the ten countries into the region (Untactad, 2012, WDI, 2013).
regional markets—only 13 percent, against 49 percent on average (World Bank, 2009). This
may reflect the inability of the export sectors to realize the potential gain from regional free
trade while much more could be done for better performance. Last, a number of cross-cutting
business environment constraints related to trade facilitation hinder the growth of both exports
and other sectors although export potential exists. The limitations include the cost and time of
customs, standards, and logistics, together with the investment environment and trade barriers
across borders. Although the government has been working to address the problems, without
specific efforts dealing with the most crucial factors affecting exports, the outcome is doubtful.
Aspiring to address some of the challenges, the dissertation attempts to achieve three
objectives:
Objective 1: To specify Cambodia’s key sectors which are promising for exports and for
industrial connection.
- Which export sectors contribute to the highest inter-sectoral linkages in the domestic
economy?
- Which export sectors can be competitive in terms of labor intensity and which
Objective 2: To measure the potential impacts of the promising sectors—agriculture and agro-
industry (following the findings from objective 1)—on economic growth and
4
- What are the impacts of quantity and price changes of the potential export sectors
- Which policy measures can be carried out for the promotion of export orientation in
Objective 3: To quantify the impacts of trade facilitation on economic and export structures.
- To what extent does the improvement of trade facilitation impact trade and the
Research Methodology
For first objective, the study applied the Input-Output framework, which is widely used
for inter-industrial policy studies, among others. In adopting this model, the study reveals the
sectoral features of the economy and utilizes Cambodia input-output table, comprising 22
sectors, derived from the 2011 Cambodia Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) (Heng et al., 2014).
The data on employment by sector is generated from the Cambodia Socio-Economic Survey
- Backward and forward linkages: a key sector should have high backward and
forward linkages with the rest of the economy so that it contributes more favorably
- Multiplier effect on income: one sector should generate high direct and indirect
income since the prime purpose of export growth is poverty elevation and better
income distribution.
- Labor intensity: a key sector requires high labor intensity for export competitiveness
characteristic of Cambodia.
- Foreign exchange earnings: a key exporter should earn more foreign currency than
5
- Hypothetical extraction: the elimination of a sector will impact the whole economic
system. The stronger a sector impacts, the higher the level of its importance.
Sectors to be identified as promising for export should fall into most, if not all, of the
five criteria above. In other words, the key export sectors should have high linkages, generate
the highest total income multiplier, require the highest labor contents in production, earn net
The second objective examines what is going to happen if the country promotes export
orientation in the potential sectors provided by the findings from the first objective. The study
aims to move from the econometric approach, which has commonly been used to capture export
the standard model created by Partnership for Economic Policy Networks (PEP) with the data
from 2011 SAM and the Socio-Economic Survey (CSES 2009). The analysis, as the objective
suggests, focuses on the impacts of the selected export sectors and the impacts of domestic
policies that are plausible to promote export orientation in those sectors through a series of
The third objective incorporates a trade facilitation framework into the CGE model by
adding a new dataset, variables, and equations of time costs to export and import. The advantage
of integrating time costs into the model is to demonstrate further the impacts on economic
welfare, and the general equilibrium impacts on production and trade linkages of reducing time
delays in the importation and exportation of goods. Initially, the data source of time costs which
have been converted to per day ad valorem equivalents (AVEs) of time to export and import is
collected from the GTAP database. The per-day AVEs to time in trade are multiplied by the
number of days to complete export and import procedures. The study performs simulation
6
analysis to examine to what extent an improvement of trade facilitation affects trade and the
diversification structure of Cambodia, and to distinguish how the effects of trade facilitation
Each objective contributes partly to the originality of the study. Objective one uses the
I-O table which derived from the SAM; however, since there is no employment data
corresponding to the I-O table, the current study has generated employment by sector from the
National Institute of Statistic’s (NIS) Cambodia Socio-Economic Survey for the analysis. For
the methodology, to the best of my knowledge, this is the first study to combine the five
approaches to analyze potential sectors and, more importantly, to be based on both the
traditional Rasmussen’s linkages and the more current hypothetical extraction method. The
normalization approach for the ranking given to each indicator at the end of the estimation is
To make it fit with the study purpose, objective two makes some modifications to the
data and the conventional model. First, the household account is reclassified into six new
categories, distinguished by area and living standard level: Phnom Penh poor and non-poor,
other urban poor and non-poor, and rural poor and non-poor. Both the income and expenditure
(characterized by sector and skill level) of each group are generated from the CSES (2009)
dataset. This new household account contributes to the originality of the data applied in the
study. Second, standard CGE models usually determine a fixed supply of factors (labor and
capital) while wages/rental rates adjust to clear the market to achieve full employment
equilibrium. Nevertheless, to capture the labor market characteristic of Cambodia, this study
The last objective, which incorporates a trade facilitation framework into the
conventional CGE model, is the first attempt to utilize this PEP model in combination with the
7
data of tariff equivalents of time to trade database to measure the effects of trade facilitation in
Cambodia. Existing studies have explained Cambodia’s trade flows and competitiveness as
well as suggested that the country’s trade is highly concentrated in a few products and that
diversification is needed. However, few have focused on suggesting strategic sectors; even
those that have were mainly based on qualitative approaches rather than quantitative ones. This
dissertation, therefore, contributes to the empirical literature within the topic of export
orientation and economic growth, particularly for the case of Cambodia, which can be further
The dissertation comprises seven chapters, structured as sketched in Figure 1.1. Chapter
one introduces the background of export-led growth. The current export pattern of Cambodia
is briefly discussed, followed by the research problems explaining why the current challenges
should be addressed and why the study should be carried out. The chapter lists research
objectives and methodologies to be used to achieve each objective. The possible contributions
Chapter two illustrates trade in more detail, specifically the export performance of
Cambodia, and how it has been revolutionized over the last decades. This chapter is crucial to
reveal historical activities of the economy in the areas of trade and export, as well as the failures
and successes the country has experienced. The final part of this section will provide insights
about policies implemented by the government, how effective the implementation has been,
Chapter three reviews the conceptual framework related to trade in general and exports
in particular, which covers the trade theories, the roles of exports in economic development,
focusing on three aspects: why a country exports, what to export and what factors affect exports.
The chapter also summarizes different methodologies previous studies have used for the same
or similar objective of identifying potential sectors and factors effecting export expansion.
8
Chapter four, five and six are the analytical parts of the dissertation. Each chapter
discusses the three objectives, respectively. The three chapters follow a similar structure: the
introduction of the topic and objective, the problems and remaining challenges of the topic in
question, the methodology and data, the empirical estimation and discussion of the results, and
the last part of Chapter six. The first part of the section shows export performance of some high
export growth countries, and the second part discusses policy reforms for export promotion in
South East and South Asia, with a closer look at Malaysia experience. The last part of the same
The last chapter concludes the whole dissertation with the summary of main findings
and policy recommendations for Cambodia. Limitations and possible extensions for further
Source: Author
9
Chapter 2: Background: Cambodia’s Trade, Export Performance and Policy
Economic and Trade Performance
economy in the late 1980s with gradual price liberalization. Starting from the full formation of
the Royal Government of Cambodia in 1993 after the Paris Peace Accord, the country began a
broad range of actions in policy development and implementation in various sectors aimed at
achieving high growth and sustainable development. Trade openness began following trade
reforms, including the reduction of trade barriers and deregulation of export and import
procedure. Since then, Cambodia has integrated export expansion into development policy.
Going through both the difficult domestic history and the global experience of development,
Cambodia is one of the few countries to have achieved sustained rapid growth, seven percent
on average for 15 years, and its growth performance ranked seventh in the world for the period
of 1998-2008 (NIS, 2014; World Bank, 2009). Income per capita has been increasing, more
than doubling from1999, at 6.5 percent on average which is a significant achievement compared
to the past 50 years of development across countries (NIS, 2014; World Bank, 2009). Despite
the strong commitment, the progress in trade performance remains slow, and more efforts are
Total GDP has grown continuously from US$3.9billion in 1995 to US$9.9 billion
(constant 2000 USD) in 2014, with an average growth rate of 5.7 percent annually (NIS, 2014).
Despite the high growth, Cambodia, being reclassified from a low to a lower-middle income
country by the World Bank in 2016, has faced some major downturns, in particular during the
mid 1990s, when Cambodia encountered internal political instability, followed by the Asian
financial crisis in 1997. The growth rate in the subsequent years fluctuated, but peaked at 13.2
percent in 2005 as the result of industrialization, investment and the significant increase in
exports of textiles under the Multi-Fiber Agreement (MFA) quota provision of the United States
10
(US) and the European Union (EU) markets. The growth rate dropped by 10 percent from 2007
to 2009 as the consequence of the global economic crisis since overall growth had been highly
dependent on the garment industry and tourism. The impact of the crisis reduced consumption
and investment as well as exports. For instance, the decline in tourist visits, a slowdown in the
construction sector, and a sharp decrease in garment exports affected the rapid GDP growth.
Merchandise exports dropped by almost 20 percent in 2009, mainly because of the lower
number of exports of the garment industry to the US and the EU markets; meanwhile, a sharp
decrease of 27 percent in foreign investment combined with the slow growth of tourism receipts
resulted in the almost no growth of real GDP (0.1%) in that year (NIS, 2011). The growth rate,
however, started to rebound one year later, as reported by the National Institute of Statistics
(2011). The construction sector began to recover in 2010 due to the return of large investment
projects, and the tourism growth rate rose by 16 percent from the previous year. The growth
one, while the service sector has remained a major contribution, as shown in Figure 2.1.
Agriculture contributed 28 percent to GDP in 2015, an almost 20 percent decline from the mid-
Source: ADB, 2016 “Key Indicators for Asia and the Pacific”
11
90s, while the share of industry and services increased to 29 and 42 percent respectively in 2015
(ADB, 2016). Among these, growth has been mainly driven by four sectors: garment,
Although the economic structure shifted and the share of the value added dropped, the
agricultural sector remains one of the main sources of employment and income generation for
the majority of the population, especially those living in rural areas. The report of World Bank
(2009) indicated a 4.4 percent average growth rate of this sector over the past ten years, slightly
more than that of Vietnam and Lao PDR (4.0 and 3.9 percent). The gain of land resource and
productivity at approximately two percent per year has played a role in the growth of the sector.
Industry, growing at an average of 16 percent per annum from 1998 to 2007, is the fastest
growth sector and contributes to 3.4 points of growth annually (WDI, 2012; World Bank, 2009).
This has led to employment growth, creating almost 100,000 new jobs each year, yet the labor
productivity growth is stable. Textiles, wearing apparel and footwear rose dramatically from
5.7 to 58 percent from 1993 and 2010 respectively, accounting for the largest share of the total
industrial sector, followed by the construction sub-sector—driven by some major projects like
satellite city construction, tourism development sites, real estate construction, and public works
such as roads, bridges, irrigation systems and hydro-power plants. The service sector has
contributed a significant portion to the economy and ranks first in GDP share since 2000.
However, this area has not yet extended to the technological and financial sectors. Instead, the
main component of services includes trading, which remains one of the vital service subsectors
real estate and business. Employment absorption of this industry is also similar to that of the
industrial sector but with a higher level of labor productivity growth, six percent per year from
12
From the late 1990s, after the Asian economic crisis and internal political instability,
the inflation rate remained below five percent due largely to internal stability and the favorable
external environment which generated a high demand for exports and official and private capital
inflows, as well as to the contractionary policy intervention of the National Bank of Cambodia
(NBC) (Keo, 2002). The inflation rate, however, fluctuated during 2008 and 2009, impacted by
the global financial crisis. Consumer prices increased; food, electricity and gas prices doubled
with the decrease of demand for some commodities during the economic downturn. After 2009,
the inflation rate has remained stable and moderate, between four and five percent.
mainly on fiscal policy in recent years while monetary policy allowed the expansion of the
financial sector. The local currency—Cambodian Riels (R)—represents only a small part of
cash in circulation, mostly in small transactions and in the interior of the country, while a large
share of assets and currency holdings are dominated in US dollars (IMF, 2012). Since 1993,
Cambodia has followed a managed floating exchange rate regime (Keo, 2002). The official
exchange rate of Riel against USD fluctuated at around 2,600 riel/USD until 1997, but
depreciated around 27 percent after the Asian financial crisis and reached 3,800 riel/USD on
average from 1998 to 2000. Over the last ten years, the riel-dollar exchange rates have remained
stable, fluctuating mostly between 3,840 and 4,150 from 2000. Fiscal policy and monetary
policy have been used by the government and NBC to stabilize the exchange rate market.
However, Keo (2002) observed that monetary policy might not have been an effective tool due
to the high level of dollarization in the market; in contrast, dollarization has been an instrument
to lower the macroeconomic risks in the Cambodian economy and has helped stabilize the
b. Fiscal Balance
Fiscal space remains a challenging task for the Public Financial Management Reform
Program (PFMRP) although there is progress in increasing revenue and current spending has
13
been kept under control. Domestic revenue rose from 6.5 to 10 percent of GDP from 2003 to
2008 due to tax policy and administration reforms, including the establishment of a Large
Taxpayer Department (LTD) and automated customs clearance (IMF, 2012). Even with signs
of improvement, revenue has stayed low, and foreign-financed capital spending has been larger
than budgeted, making the overall fiscal balance deteriorate. IMF (2012) reported the slow
growth rate of revenue collection, which stayed lower than 0.5 percentage point of GDP in
2011, yet tax collection had a rise of almost one percentage point of GDP one year later. Weak
tax administration can be one of the causes of the low tax-to-GDP ratio in Cambodia compared
to the regional standard. Besides domestic taxes, government revenue growth slows down due
to the Free Trade Area implementation causing trade taxes in total revenue to decline. As a
integrated approach should focus on improving revenue administration, implementing fair and
efficient tax policies, and strengthening governance. In addition, measures should be taken to
prioritize policy actions to generate additional revenue, to be implemented at low cost, and to
investment. The annual average investment rose from 15 to 21 percent of GDP from 1997 to
2007, generating an average of 2.4 points of growth per annum (World Bank, 2009). Although
it is a major achievement, investment remains low compared to some high growth developing
countries, and the contribution of physical capital accumulation to growth has been limited.
FDI has played a crucial role in the process of industrialization in Cambodia since FDI does
not only increase capital accumulation to finance trade deficits and international reserves but
also brings along new technology. Moreover, most of FDIs are from large firms which absorb
more labor force than that of domestic enterprises. Investment and industrial policy attracted
FDI first in the construction and tourism industries in 1993, and a large number later in the
14
garment sector from 1996 after the bilateral agreement with the US had been signed (WTO
Secretariat, 2011a). FDIs are from various countries, including China, Hong Kong, the Republic
of South Korea, the US, Russia, and some ASEAN members. FDI-implemented projects peaked
in 2007, amounting to US$867 million, but decreased thereafter, as shown in Table 2.1, with
the total stock accounting for approximately 50 percent of total GDP (WTO Secretariat, 2011a).
The garment industry represents the largest FDI in manufacturing, and investors from China
received approximately 90 percent of investment approvals from 2005 to 2010. FDI has also
started to diversify to other exports, especially those labor-intensive products such as footwear,
wood products, and toys, and has made a significant contribution to employment.
2.1.2.Trade Performance
Trade has been playing an important role as one of the main sources of income for the
Cambodian economy. From the early 1990s to the late 2000s, trade share in the economy kept
moving upward. Figure 2.2 illustrates that both export and import values, as well as export and
import shares in GDP, have been moving along the same line and been competing for a positive
move. However, the import figure has always been higher than that of the export, resulting in a
trade deficit over the last two decades. Notwithstanding, the trade deficit has declined over the
The accession to ASEAN in 1999 was a major opening for Cambodian goods and
services in international markets. Export and import volume has increased due to regional and
sub-region free trade agreements and accelerated after 2005 with accession to the World Trade
Organization (WTO), which safeguards the access to the US and the EU market as major trade
15
partners. Nonetheless, exports were severely hit in 2007-08 during the global economic crisis,
demonstrating that Cambodia’s exports are highly vulnerable to external shocks. These two
components began to move upward again in 2010 and have recovered to the levels before the
a. Export Profile
Exports by Sector: Exports of primary goods accounted for two-thirds of total exports
during the beginning of the opening up period but declined and were replaced by exports of
manufactured goods in the late 2000s due to the process of industrialization, movement of
capital goods and technology, and the encouragement of investment in manufacturing. In 2011,
manufactured goods made up 86.8 percent of total exports, while primary goods accounted for
only 13.1 percent (UNCTAD, 2012). (Table A.1 in Appendix lists the merchandise exports by
Export Commodities: Table 2.2 presents export and import commodities and partners.
Apparel and clothing accessories are the main commodities exported, accounting for 54% of
16
the total exports in 2010 (Unctad, 2011), followed by miscellaneous manufactured articles, such
as plastic, toys, stationery supplies, works of art, and jewelry, which share a total of 32% of
total exports. Other exported goods include footwear, machinery specialized for particular
industries, such as agricultural machinery, power generating equipment, and office machines.
Cambodia also exports crude rubber, cork and wood (Table 2.2).
b. Import Profile
Imports by Sector: Manufacturing imports, including capital goods, are necessary for
industrialization, but the figure is still high, which shows a relatively high dependency on
imported intermediate goods for domestic production. The share of manufactured goods in total
imports has remained quite steady during the last 15 years, comprising 67 percent in 2011,
while there is a drop in primary imports reflecting less dependency on this item (Figure 2.3).
Import Commodities: Imports of manufactured goods include items such as iron and
steel, rubber, metal and nonmetallic items. Machinery and transportation equipment combined
with commodities and transactions are the next major import products. The rest include mineral
fuels, lubricants and related materials, chemicals, and other products as detailed in Table 2.2.
The services account has remained in surplus, growing from US$290 million in 2004 to
17
Table 2.2: Export and Import Commodities and Partners (share in total exports), 2010
Export Import Import
Export Commodity 2010 2010 2010 2010
Partners Commodity Partners
Apparel and 54.40% USA 34.10% Manufactured 33.10% China 21.63%
clothing accessories goods
Miscellaneous 32.40% Hong Kong 24.80% Machinery and 16.65% Thailand 21.40%
manufactured transport equipment
articles
Footwear 3.20% Singapore 7.70% Commodities and 13.54% Singapore 17.92%
transactions, n.e.s.
Machinery 2.50% Canada 4.90% Mineral fuels, 12.67% Vietnam 14.37%
specialized for lubricants and
particular industries related materials
Road vehicles 1.90% Netherlands 4.20% Food and live 6.64% Hong 7.12%
(parts/accessories) animals Kong
Crude rubber 1.50% United 4.20% Miscellaneous 5.84% South 3.74%
Kingdom manufactured Korea
articles
Cereals and cereal 0.70% Thailand 2.70% Chemicals and 5.73% Indonesia 2.50%
preparations related products,
n.e.s.
Cork and wood 0.70% Germany 2.00% Beverage and 4.18% Malaysia 2.30%
tobacco
Textile yarn, fabric, 0.30% Spain 1.80% Crude mineral, 1.05% Japan 1.96%
made-up articles inedible, except
and related products fuels
Other transport 0.30% Vietnam 1.70% Animal and 0.60% United 1.79%
equipment vegetable oils, fats States
and waxes
Source: UN Comtrade, 2012, “Trade Statistics”
US$663 million in 2010, accounting for six percent of GDP, due mainly to the growth of the
tourism sector (WTO Secretariat, 2011a). Cambodia’s exceptional cultural heritage, natural
endowment, and its location in a dynamic region, together with some key policies, contribute
to the rapid growth of tourism. After experiencing a contraction in 2009 due to a slowdown in
global travel, the sector has recovered in the near term. Other services, such as trade-related
services, transportation, insurance and freight, have positive prospects to contribute to the
Openness and integration are viewed as essential strategies for growth and poverty
reduction, as they were included in the Rectangular Strategy Phase II of the government,
18
emphasizing the strategies for growth, employment, equity, and efficiency. They were also the
basis of the National Strategic Development Plan of Cambodia, updated for 2015-2025, based
The trade system of Cambodia depends significantly on the ability to expand, which is
under critical consideration. Hence, identifying potential exports and increasing supply and
competitiveness are the key elements of trade and development objectives of this country. Three
- policies to develop export potential and diversify export products and export markets
Legal and regulatory reforms have been undertaken, specifically during and after the
process of international integration, to provide a better trade climate and bring trade regimes,
business, and investment into line with international norms. Necessary laws and their
implementation and enforcement, together with legislation and other administrative steps, are
needed to achieve the goals of the reforms. Trade and some trade-related laws are listed in Table
2.3, some of which are in place for implementation and some are in draft for approval. For the
trade area, a customs law was enacted in 2007 followed by laws on trade remedies, rule of
origin, and standards—created to develop standard and product conformity assessments. In the
Various business registration processes have been simplified along with the upgrade of
investment promotion and trade facilitation. For instance, a Single Window model has been
implemented to reduce the cost and time required for document processing, and an arbitration
19
center is being set up to deal with commercial disputes. The enhanced transparency,
simplification, and accountability realized from the reforms will, on the one hand, help exports
benefit from a faster process and build trust for investors, and, on the other hand, fight against
20
corruption, reduce risk to investment, and the cost of doing business. Further progress is
required. The World Bank (2009) recommends that some priorities in this area should include:
- further facilitation, in the area of business and trade, with more transparent processes
and computerization
- effective dispute resolution through an existing Labor Arbitration Council and other
alternative mechanisms
- industrial relation facilitation and improvement of incentives for labor productivity gains
improvement which include trade facilitation across ASEAN countries, facilitate transit
Some crucial measures of cross-border trade facilitation include: (1) the establishment
of the Single Administrative Document (SAD) in 2006 as the replacement for 45 documents
previously required at the border; (2) the introduction and operation of the computerization of
customs clearance through ASYCUDA at border checkpoints from 2009, which has
significantly reduced the time of customs declarations for more than 90% of import and export
clearance, and is being developed to cover transit trade and to allow direct online data entry;
(3) the introduction of risk management along with the ASYCUDA, resulting in the reduction
of the physical inspections of the import and export containers (WTO Secretariat, 2011a).
Besides, the development of Single Window and the implementation of the safe framework
The role of industrial policy, as a part of development policy, has been recognized as a
necessary instrument to address market failure because industrial policy aimed at strategic
21
collaboration and coordination between public and private sector will be an effective approach
to link this policy to exports as a key “market-based test of performance” (World Bank, 2009).
A number of industrial policies are already in place in many sectors which have received
targeted supports such as quota negotiations for garments, “Open Skies” and infrastructure
policy for tourism, and Special Economic Zones (SEZs) for assembly factories. Other existing
A finding reveals that most of the instruments seem to lack accountability, coordination,
and incentives, or appear to be poorly targeted (World Bank, 2009). Outside of the garment
sector, little progress has been achieved, particularly in investment and export promotions, land
management and SEZs. Hence, it is important to make existing policy instruments more
transparent and accountable to maximize their impacts. The World Bank (2009) suggested some
priorities: (1) streamline of institutional responsibility and standards involving the division of
22
labor; (2) linkage between potential investors and local partners; (3) integration of value chains
in agriculture through institutional models; (4) coordination in the tourism sector; (5)
exploration in the area of training and coordination mechanisms; (6) measurement of growth at
the intensive margin (i.e. growth within existing sectors); and (7) development of information
Integration Framework: To integrate more efficiently and turn trade into a source of
development partners, adopted the Trade Integration Strategy in 2000 which described a
comprehensive reform to improve the business environment, to create conditions helpful for
exporters, to strengthen supply capacity, and to improve competitiveness (MoC, 2007). The
Diagnostic Trade Integration Study 2002 (DTIS) has been implemented from this perspective.
Trade and investment facilitation, intellectual property rights, Sanitary and Phyto-Sanitary
(SPS) measures, technical barriers to trade, and the development of sectors are some actions
identified in the first DTIS. To follow up the program, the Ministry of Commerce (MOC)
launched the TRADE (Trade Related Assistance for Development and Equity) project in 2005
focusing on updating DTIS 2002 and on developing a Human Development Impact Assessment
of Trade (HDIA) which frames the country’s ability to turn trade development into poverty
Aid for Trade and Trade Sector-Wide Approaches (Trade SWAps): Trade SWAps
is a localized system providing a shared vision for the trade sector in a consultative and coherent
way, which was launched during the implementation of the DTIS. It is the approach attached
to Aid for Trade aimed at increasing trade effectiveness in line with the principles of ownership,
alignment, harmonization, management for results, and mutual accountability. According to the
23
In the next ten years, the Royal Government of Cambodia will be increasing value for its
integrity, for its capacity to articulate and implement trade policy and strategies in consultation
with all trade stakeholders and for its ability to enforce trade regulations aiming at strengthening
The expansion of the private sector is also included with the improvement of foreign
and domestic trade by strengthening effective backward linkages in the economy. For the above
objectives and vision, Trade SWAps, with the benefit maximization of Aid for Trade, is
- Legal reform and cross-cutting issues for trade development (trade facilitation, technical
barriers to trade)
The membership of Cambodia in ASEAN, which started in 1999, is the starting point
of international integration and provides some opportunities for this country to strengthen trade
development. For one thing, ASEAN can be the role model to accelerate national and
transnational reforms. The ASEAN single window is a case of reform and is applied in
Cambodia to connect the trade-related one-stop window. Furthermore, ASEAN can provide the
opportunity to outsource functions as partnership. For instance, provided that the basic SPS
management system is not in place for the time being, this function could be instead monitored
by ASEAN. As a result of the ASEAN membership, Cambodia’s trade and trade regime are
For the case of trade liberalization, Cambodia has agreed upon the schedule of reducing
tariffs among the ASEAN trade partners. Different tariff lines on the inclusion list have been
24
eliminated accordingly as scheduled in 2008, 2010 and 2015, except for a 7% of tariff line
which is expected to be removed by 2018 (WTO Secretariat, 2011a). The reduction of the tariff
has resulted in the expansion of both exports and imports with the regional partners. The annual
average rate increased by 37% and 35% for exports and imports respectively between
Cambodia and ASEAN partners compared to 14% and 25% with the rest of the world from
2006 to 2008 (WTO Secretariat, 2011a). Notwithstanding, despite the increasing rate, the
export value to ASEAN is still low, as it accounts for only 7% of the total export of Cambodia.
Figure 2.4 shows that among all of the members, Cambodia shares only 0.26 percent in total
exports to ASEAN.
Agreement on Services including the commitment to market access and national treatment of
some specific sectors. Common mutual for post-clearance customs audit and customs valuation
are among the topics of ASEAN’s harmonization policies, also covering the enforcement of
intellectual property rights. In addition, the membership connects Cambodia with the region
Brunei Cambodia
Viet Nam 0.51% 0.26%
4%
Laos
Indonesia 0.39%
Thailand 14%
17%
Malaysia
18%
Myanmar
1.5%
Singapore
41% Philippines
3%
Source: Unctad, 2012 “International Trade in Goods and Services”
25
infrastructure efforts and labor movement policies which would be useful for trade development
Cambodia has also been following Free Trade Agreements (FTAs) between ASEAN and
its dialog partners, including China, India, Japan, South Korea, and Australia/New Zealand.
The schedule of tariff reduction has also been set following the FTAs. Besides, Cambodia has
joined Greater Mekong Sub-region (GMS) group and the Cambodia - Lao PDR - Vietnam
(CLV) discussions and intra-regional trade, but has not achieved much, particularly with regard
Cambodia gained accession to the WTO in 2004, following specific commitments and
precise plans for implementation of related legislation and enforcement mechanisms. Chea and
Sok (2005) asserted that protecting the garment industry after the removal of export quotas at
the end of 2004 under the MFA was a primary objective of Cambodia to become a member of
the WTO since this industry had become significant and needed to be sustained. Moreover,
membership was expected to provide the opportunity for Cambodia to force both economic
policy and legal reforms. For one thing, Cambodia’s exports are subject to internationally
agreed rules, such as most favored nations (MFNs) and national treatment. For instance,
negotiation for tariff binding has been carried out which resulted in Cambodia in average final
tariff bound rates of 28.1% for agricultural and 17.7% for non-agricultural products, with no
export subsidies (WTO Secretariat, 2011b). Implementation of WTO agreements in areas such
as SPS, technical barriers to trade (TBT), TRIPs and customs valuation is to be undertaken
during the transition periods. Apart from this, numerous trade-related laws and legal reforms
have been accelerated to ensure compliance with WTO regulations, which create a more
investment destination. It can be seen that one of the main benefits of membership is the
improvement of governance and credibility. Besides the benefits, however, challenges ahead
26
are foreseen. Due to limited production capacity and resource mobilization, the expansion of
exports is not guaranteed. As a result, the production base needs to be improved so that the
country can realize full gains of exports to the world market, especially those of the WTO
members; meanwhile, both industries and agriculture also need to be more competitive. The
removal of trade constraints and the involvement of the private sector, farmers and civil society
Cambodia has signed trade agreements under the Generalized System of Preferences
(GSP) operated by developed countries, applying for the exemption and reduction of import
tariffs on many products that fulfill the requirements, such as rules of origin. For instance, under
the Everything-But-Arms initiation (EBA), as part of the GSP, Cambodia received in February
2001 quota-free access to the European market. Also, a Trade and Investment Framework
Agreement (TIFA) was signed between Cambodia and the United States in 2006 aimed at
greater trade and investment in both countries (WTO Secretariat, 2011a, 2011b). Additional
preferences of other countries are also entitled for duty-free status based on product quality.
27
Export Strategy
Cambodia is endowed with relative abundance of land—more than 0.25 ha of land per
capita—and labor, with some 250,000 new entrants every year, which suggests the potential
Bank, 2009). However, the number of laborers equipped with education and skills remains low
compared to other countries which have achieved the same level of development. In addition,
a number of constraints hinder Cambodia’s exports. For one thing, the country relies mostly on
a few main sectors for exports. For another thing, infrastructure is underdeveloped, contributing
to high costs and low service quality. For instance, there is a lack of adequate road networks,
highways, ports and rail services, electricity and telecommunication, while most of the available
Policy and the institutional environment facing firms have become a considerable topic,
- low productivity due to excessive regulation and weak institutions; some key factors
include corruption, weak property rights, informal practices and costly regulations
- high cost of trade and ineffective trade facilitation processes, including difficulties
Following the National Export Strategy, the MOC (2006) has committed to ensuring
competitiveness and strengthening governance. Some actions include: (1) promoting market
infrastructure and deregulation; (2) reducing transaction costs and improving efficiency of trade
facilitation; (3) enhancing the rule of law and institutions; (4) promoting small and medium-
sized enterprises, and; (5) enhancing access to information and to markets. To achieve this,
28
investment climate and customs reforms together with policy on private participation have to
be undertaken.
To stimulate the development of export sector, the 4-Gears-model has been adopted,
emphasizing four main pillars as shown in Figure 2.5. The first one is the “Border-In”
development, and marketing competencies. Second, the “Border” approach covers operational
matters targeting development and facilitation of trade and a business environment for
providing market support and identifying commercial opportunities abroad, promoting export-
oriented FDI and technology transfer. The last one is the “Development” approach concerning
socioeconomic impacts such as poverty reduction, rural and gender development, and
employment generation.
29
Initial baskets of 19 potential export products and services (in List1 and List 2, Table
2.7) have been identified following the finalization of DTIS in 2007 (MoC, 2007). The
identification of the export potentials is based mainly on the product’s current competitiveness
level, the market access condition, or the impact on poverty reduction. For the viable assessment
purpose, four indexes have been developed, three are classified as export potential and one is
classified as human development. Table 2.6 describes the export product assessment index and
attractive market identification index, while Table 2.7 lists the ranking given to indicators of
In line with the new products, attractive market analysis has been carried out for the
possibility to expand new products to the existing markets (new product-old destination) as well
as to assess new markets (new product-new destination). The US (mostly for garment sector),
30
France, Germany, the United Kingdom, Canada, Japan, South Korea (mostly for tourism), China
PRC, Singapore, Thailand and Vietnam are the current main export destinations. Some of those
markets, particularly European countries and Japan, and new destinations including Italy and
Spain are among the attractive markets for the 19 export potentials identified. Other partners
include Australia, Turkey, and Kazakhstan, as well as Taiwan and Hong Kong for East Asian
market; Singapore, Indonesia, Malaysia, and Thailand for Southeast Asia; Saudi Arabia and the
United Arab Emirates for the Gulf countries (MoC, 2007). The expanded markets have been
31
specified based on the index of Attractive Market assessment which was developed in DTIS
Although the potential export products and markets have been specified, a number of
shared challenges are reported. High production and infrastructure costs, low productivity and
competitiveness are the major constraints for export diversification. Other factors continuing to
hinder success include limited value added due to high dependency on imports of raw materials
and intermediate inputs, limited product differentiation and quality, limited access to
technology, R&D capacity, difficulties in meeting the quality standards of foreign markets and
time delivery requirements, and, equally if not more important, the limited quality of legal and
institutional frameworks for export development (MoC, 2007; World Bank, 2009; WTO
Secretariat, 2011b).
2.5.4. Agriculture
Exports of agricultural products account for only eight percent of total exports (WTO
Secretariat, 2011a). Nevertheless, the figure can be underestimated because most of the
agricultural exports are unofficial and in a non-processed state. Table 2.8 shows domestic
support was granted for agricultural products in 2007 and 2008. Over half of the total support
took the form of payments for relief from natural disasters. Other main measures receiving
support are advisory services and pest and disease control (WTO Secretariat, 2011a).
Rice: The Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fishery (MAFF) reported that the
milled rice supply had increased gradually from 2000 as a result of paddy rice production, at a
9% annual growth rate over the past decade (WTO Secretariat, 2011a). Apart from domestic
consumption, a large amount of rice surplus is available for export. Yet there is a huge
difference between the quantities of officially recorded exports by the Customs Department and
those of the exact exports due to two main reasons: informal exports of unprocessed paddy rice
32
Table 2.8: Domestic Support Measure for Agriculture, 2007-2008
Monetary value
Measure Description of measure of measure
(million Riels)
2007 2008
Research Research activities on agricultural productivity, land diversification, 183 288
plant and animal health, in accordance with Annex 2, para. 2(a) of the
Agreement on Agriculture
Pest and disease Expenditures on plant protection and animal quarantine, in accordance 1,052 1,406
control with Annex 2, para. 2(b) of the Agreement on Agriculture
Training services Training for farmers and local communities on crop productivity, 943 1,150
small-scale agri-processing and contract farming, in accordance with
Annex 2, para. 2(c) of the Agreement on Agriculture
Extension and Extension and advisory services, including transfer of information and 1,370 1,342
advisory services results of research to farmer cooperatives and farmers, in accordance
with Annex 2, para. 2(d) of the Agreement on Agriculture
Inspection services Expenditures on inspection services relating to animal health, in 157 92
accordance with Annex 2, para. 2(e) of the Agreement on Agriculture
Marketing and Marketing and promotion services, including market information and Nil Nil
promotion services market development, in accordance with Annex 2, para. 2(f) of the
Agreement on Agriculture
Infrastructural Infrastructural services including rehabilitation and maintenance of Nil Nil
services small-scale irrigation schemes, in accordance with Annex 2, para. 2(g)
of the Agreement on Agriculture
Payments for relief Expenditure for relief from natural disaster on the provision of 4,920 5,722
from natural agricultural inputs, equipment and pest and disease control to
disasters agricultural production, in accordance with Annex 2, para. 8 of the
Agreement on Agriculture
Total 8,625 10,000
Note: Measures exempt from the reduction commitment-Green Box
Exchange rate: 2007, US$1 = 4,058 Riels; 2008, US$1 = 4,003 Riels.
Source: WTO Secretariat (2011b, p. 70)
In order to improve trading in the rice sector, the Royal Government of Cambodia has
a vision to transform the country to be a major milled rice exporter and has set the year 2015 as
the target year to: (1) achieve a paddy rice surplus of more than four million tons; (2) achieve
[formal] exports of milled rice of at least one million tons, and; (3) ensure the international
are important, and it is estimated that the potential milled rice available for export (2.9 million
tonnes) will be much larger than targeted. To achieve the above vision, the strategies are
33
- Short-term and immediate strategy: increasing productivity and promoting formal
promoting the better use and lowering the cost of inputs and appropriate
facilitation
Rubber: Rubber has been one of the key crops, which increased from 19,715 tons in
2008 to 42,250 tons in 2010, of which around 70 percent was exported with an estimated value
of US$89.1 million (WTO Secretariat, 2011a). Some challenges of this sector include high
input and utility costs, lack of standard certification of exports, limited finance and cash flow
among producers and processors, relatively low yield, high transportation costs, excessive
paperwork required for exports, unofficial trading fees and low customs clearance efficiency
(WTO Secretariat, 2011a). The General Directorate of Rubber has been established to prepare
and implement policies and strategic programs to ensure development of this sector.
Forestry and Fishery: Wood production does not make a significant contribution to
national revenue. The Forest Administration, the main government agency, monitors and
implements forestry policy, including the reform process and legal framework of the forest
sector. Fisheries and livestock are among the main sources of livelihood of the rural people, but
their contribution to GDP has decreased from more than 15 percent during the 1990s to about
7.6% in 2010, with annual exports around 35,000 tons that year (WTO Secretariat, 2011a).
Market expansion of this sector would provide a better opportunity, and should be needed, to
34
2.5.5. Industry
Industry covers manufacturing, consisting of mostly small and medium enterprises with
approximately 370,000 registered and unregistered in 2010 (WTO Secretariat, 2011a). The
Garments: This sector generated 15 percent of GDP and 69 percent of total exports in
2008 and employed 320,000 labors in the formal sector, and is the country leading export sector
with a volume growth rate of an average of 11 percent per annum from 2005 to 2008 (WTO
Secretariat, 2011a). After being granted MFN in 1996 and benefiting from the development of
MFA, Cambodia’s garment industry started to develop remarkably and attracted foreign
investors taking advantage of Cambodia’s quota-free status and EBA initiative. Since then,
exports have grown rapidly. Table 2.9 presets some statistical data of the performance of this
sector. Export values increased significantly from 2004; nevertheless, the global slowdown in
2008 negatively impacted Cambodia’s garment exports in the subsequent year. The
performance of the garment exports is mainly dependent on the structural change of the market
access, with the US and the EU as the main partners, and the low costs of labor. However, a
number of features that hamper the competitiveness in comparison to neighboring countries are
low labor productivity, high costs and unreliable supply of electricity, less developed
2.5.6. Services
35
Tourism: Tourism has played an important role in foreign exchange earnings, as well
as in contribution to GDP and employment, and has attracted a high portion of foreign capital
investment. Particularly, as shown in Table 3.10, this sector has been bringing in over USD1.7
billion per year and generated employment for approximately 300,000 people directly and
indirectly. The “Open Skies” policy was initiated in 1997, for which direct flight from overseas
to Siem Reap, located in the famous tourist region, was permitted. The beach town of Sihanouk
Ville is also another popular resort among tourists and it has recently expanded with an airport
in the southern part to accommodate aircrafts and developed with many resort projects by
international and local developers. The country’s ample forested areas are also to be opened to
ecotourism.
Regulatory uncertainty and the lack of responsibility sharing are the key constraints for
the growth of this sector. The legal framework, aimed at reducing business risk, together with
the 2009 Tourism Law and the establishment of the Tourism Marketing Promotion Board, is
expected to address these issues. Promoting private sector participation can be an important
tool. For faster growth of the sector, the assurance of quality, standards, licensing, management
food hygiene and sanitation, and tourist security are priority areas.
36
Chapter 3: Conceptual Framework: Exports and Economic Development
Why Export?
The traditional trade approaches of export promotion and import substitution have been
the subjects of lively debate in development literature since the 1950s (Todaro & Smith, 2009).
The protectionists, who favor import substitution (IS), believed that an inward-looking strategy
encourages appropriate use of resources through the restriction of trade, which will result in
greater self-reliance. In contrast, the free traders, who advocate export promotion (EP), argue
that an outward-looking strategy enhances not only free trade but also movement of capital,
enterprises and labor, as well as opening a wide range for communication systems. Although
the former approach remains strong in development discourse, an emerging consensus in favor
of the latter has been witnessed among many developing and certain developed economies from
the late 1970s (Todaro & Smith, 2009). A number of countries, such as Brazil, Chile, Turkey
and Thailand, have switched from the IS strategy to the EP strategy. Given the successful
experience of the early EP-adopting economies of Hong Kong, Singapore, Taiwan, South Korea
and some others in Asia, EP promotes growth efficiency through the substitution of outside
markets for small domestic markets and reduces distorting price and cost effects of
protectionism. While trade development strategies are set by each country, the division between
the IS and EP can be less pronounced when the government promotes export expansion while
at the same time adopting protectionism that favors potential and/or infant industries. Although
the gains from EP may be limited in the first step of adoption, the economic returns of this
exports, one of which is the relationship between exports and economic growth. An empirical
study by Balassa (1978) revealed a favorable relationship between exports and growth of gross
national product and manufacturing outputs, given the direct and indirect effects of exports
37
through the contribution of domestic and foreign capital and labor. His cross-country analysis
strongly suggests that outward orientation leads to better growth performance than inward
policies since export orientation improves resource allocation with greater capacity utilization,
promotes economies of scale in the areas where countries have comparative advantage, absorbs
technological improvement to promote competition as a long term continuing effect, and at the
addition, in the countries where marginal saving ratios are higher than average, the growth rate
will be relatively and permanently higher under EP in comparison to IS. Later studies have also
included trade policy in empirical investigation to compare the impact of export expansion.
Trade policy was once divided into four groups: moderately and strongly outward, and
moderately and strongly inward. Amirkhalkhali & Dar (1995) and McNab & Moore (1998)
came to a similar conclusion that the level of economic openness did matter. In comparison, for
the sample of developing countries, strong outward policy has the highest positive impact on
average annual GDP growth (over three percent), followed by the moderately outward policy
The roles of exports have been examined and well-documented in various studies,
demonstrating their relationship with economic performance. Tyler (1981) extended the work
of Balassa and studied a cross-country analysis of 55 developing economies from 1960 to 1977
by including exports as a factor of production and found a strong association between the
economic policies. One might argue that the model (GNP = f (K+L+E)) 1 that includes exports
as a factor of production might not be perfect and there might be causality effects 2; however,
1
GNP: Gross National Production, K: capital, L: labor, E: export (Based on Cobb-Douglas production
function)
2 Exports induce growth and growth induces exports
38
the model has been supported for various reasons. For one thing, it is reasonable to state that
exports are the input of the production because the amount of exports positively affects
aggregate outputs from a given amount of capital and labor since exports increase production
efficiency and technological improvement as the result of better resource allocation and better
specialization (Balassa, 1978; Ram, 1985). In this sense, exports may raise the productivity of
capital and labor, specifically through technological transfer. In addition, the increase in exports
helps reduce the problem of foreign resource constraint, thus improving trade balance (Ram,
1985). It is useful to note that the model is used as a production relation but not the national
account identity since they have different formats for total output (Ram, 1985).
Ram (1985) suggested that during the early period (the 1960s), the significant impacts
countries, but the difference was less distinguishable in the later period (the 1970s). Other
researchers (Jung & Marshall, 1985; Yaghmaian, 1994) have claimed that export-reducing
growth and growth-reducing exports are plausible and that the effects of exports on economic
performance is generally dependent on the initial level of development and structural change,
which means that unless countries have achieved some level of development prior to becoming
Moschos (1989) rejected the above idea and concluded there is a positive relationship between
these two variables for both low- and high-income economies and is stronger in the low income
group.
It is not exceptional that the effects of exports on growth can be determined partly by
the economic structure and characteristic of individual country as well as causality effects. For
example, those who have not prepared themselves for openness or who have no available
resources to absorb capital and technological transfer might not find exports beneficial in the
first place. For another example, a country can face adverse effects from exports if it depends
too much on the increase in a specific sector while other sectors or non-exporting sectors face
39
diminishing returns and finally disappear. Nevertheless, a number of countries adopting export-
Export expansion brings more than the direct effects themselves. The indirect effects,
as mentioned, include the externalities that capture the huge increase in trade share and factor
productivity, and the strong association between productivity and externalities through various
components: capital accumulation, factor allocation effects from low to high productivity
sectors, effects from exporting light and heavy manufacturing goods, and effects from
importing capital goods (Melo & Robinson, 1992). Three interesting approaches are included
The first approach is Marshallian externalities, based on Luca (1988) and Romer (1986),
introducing the form of human capital accumulation, or complementarities between human and
physical capital as the result of externalities in such a way that they lead to increasing returns
to scale at the economy-wide level in general, and maintain constant returns to scale at a firm
level in particular. The second approach discusses how disembodied knowledge is obtained.
Exports are considered a driving force to explain the creation of new knowledge and technology
endogenously driven by investment in R&D that responds to market incentive, and by adoption
of foreign technology. The third approach incorporates the demand spillovers between sectors
as an important externality. For instance, once the domestic industry engages in export
activities, a wide range of technology is required and the acquisition will spill over across
industries. Also, the demand for improvement of infrastructure, where intervention is essential
especially to more efficient direct investment, can create an environment in which all firms can
For the discussion of the full benefits of exports, an understanding of basic concept of
trade liberalization is useful because export expansion depends greatly on the level of trade
40
liberalization. A simple notion of openness is that trade allows people to have more access to
varieties of products outside their frontier at world market prices. Empirical studies have come
to the consensus that the income of countries that trade with each other converges intensely,
and that the convergence can be achieved regardless of the initial level of development and
skills (Rassekh, 2004). This can be noted more among groups of countries that are trade
partners. For instance, the investigation of 19 OECD countries during the period of 1950 to
1985 pointed out that trade and exports contributed to income convergence among these
Exports and market integration do not only contribute to convergence across countries,
but also to income distribution within a country. According to the Stolpher-Samuelson theorem,
income redistribution is obtained even without taking into account the effect of economic
growth because market expansion redistributes income from abundant to scarce cohorts within
the economy. Evidence suggested that income inequality—measured by the Gini coefficient—
and poverty in an individual country has reduced significantly between the 1980s to the early
2000s as the result of international market transactions and globalization (Bhall, 2002, cited in
Rassekh, 2004).
Nevertheless, some studies have failed to provide unambiguous support to the above
findings. It is argued that there is no significant link between trade and convergence, while free
trade may instead reduce the investment ratio and thus lower the growth rate or leave it
unaffected instead (Slaugter, 2001, and Bhagwati, 2002, cited in Rassekh, 2004). These
opposing views may be correct in the sense that freer trade does not necessarily mean higher
volume of trade or higher volume of exports, especially for a country that enjoys the influx of
imports due to lower trade barriers but has limited capability to improve its exports. For exports
to contribute to income distribution and convergence, the link to externalities is crucial. Since
some trade-offs might appear, coordination can play a vital role in maximizing export activities
41
It can be concluded from the above discussion of the existing literature that a country
should enhance export expansion and favor export promotion policies for the reason that the
benefits of exports largely outweigh the disadvantages. Exports directly contribute to economic
growth, and especially play significant roles, directly and indirectly, in allowing countries to
capture the positive externalities in industrial development and income redistribution. However,
the promotion strategy should be planned and implemented with precautions for the possible
What to Export
Due to diverse resources, abilities and preferences in producing and consuming different
goods, individuals or countries find it beneficial to produce and export what they have in surplus
in exchange for what is not available in their domestic markets. As discussed in the previous
section, there is a general consensus that it is profitable to do so owing to the central roles of
exports. However, questions have arisen as to what determines which goods are produced and
exported, and why countries produce and export different goods. To answer these questions,
the theory and practice associated with export and trade should be reviewed. Classical trade
theory gives weight to the concept of relative cost of production and price differences, dating
back to the Absolute Advantage of Adam Smith and Comparative Advantage of David Ricardo
(Todaro & Smith, 2009). The former focuses on the ability of a country to produce something
more efficiently than another country; thus, a country should produce only the goods in which
it is most efficient and trade for the goods in which it is not. For example, Japan can produce
manufactured goods, such as automobiles, relatively cheaply, and can export these to
Cambodia, where agricultural goods, such as rice, can be produced at a lower relative cost and
The latter, however, suggests that a country should export products that it can produce
more efficiently than other products, meaning that even though the country may have an
42
absolute advantage in two commodities, it is better to specialize in one commodity in which its
comparative cost advantage lies. This principle, hence, gains momentum as it gives rise to
specialization and beneficial trade even for countries with less absolute advantage.
This theory was later modified by the Factor Endowment theory, or neoclassical trade
theory, by Eli Hecksher and Bertil Ohlin, who, instead, took into account not only the cost of
labor, but also other production factors such as capital and land (Todaro & Smith, 2009). The
theory is based mainly on two main propositions: different products require different levels of
production factors; and countries are endowed with different factors of production. Regardless
of the initial factor prices and production location, the factors will be used in different
proportions because more capital is required for certain products while more labor is required
for others. For example, manufactured goods are generally made with more machines per
worker than agricultural goods, which require a greater number of workers per unit of capital.
Countries with an abundance of labor tend to have cheaper labor costs and thus have an
advantage to produce labor-intensive products less expensively than countries with scarce
labor. The resource endowment theory assumes that countries with less capital and more labor,
as is the case in developing countries, should produce and export labor-intensive products,
they have relatively cost and price advantage in producing these types of commodities. In short,
according to the Hecksher-Ohlin factor endowment model, countries should produce and export
goods that require abundant (and thus cheaper) resources or factors, and import those goods
Several views can be drawn from the classical and neoclassical theory. First, it enables
countries access to consumption not only outside their production frontier but also at lower
world market prices. Second, specialization rewards the exporting countries with better
utilization of resources, and once the abundant resource is intensively used, higher economic
43
return is predicted, leading to the increase of labor wage rate in developing countries (Todaro
& Smith, 2009). For this, international real wage and capital cost will move toward equalization,
reducing disparities between trading partners. Nevertheless, the assumptions of two countries
and two production factors, and perfect competition embedded in the theory, have been
unrealistic. On the one hand, despite the resource endowment, labor and capital can be
mobilized across sectors and nations; meanwhile, technology is neither identical nor freely
available. On the other hand, market and competition are not always perfect because of price
and information distortion or monopoly market control. All sectors cannot always ensure trade
balance and constant returns to scale. More importantly, the suggestion that developing
countries should produce and export agricultural goods has received remarkable criticism.
Commodity terms of trade—the ratio between the price of a unit of export and the price
of a unit of import—explains the argument. The Prebisch-Singer thesis states that terms of trade
of developing countries have fallen and will continue to fall because the export price of primary
products is low in relation to the import price of manufactured products from developed
countries (Todaro & Smith, 2009). This argument is based on a combination of low income and
price elasticity of demand for primary products. These two phenomena contribute to the
instability of export earnings and the less predictable rate of economic growth in developing
nations, diverging further from the rich nations. Therefore, the Prebisch-Singer thesis suggests
that developing countries should reduce their high dependency on agricultural exports and shift
to manufacturing industries for a more favorable export growth and terms of trade.
New trade theory, linking trade to output growth, associated with the Endogenous
Growth model of Romer and Lucas, is extended from the exogenous growth model and
emphasizes the important role of human capital and learning effects that can be obtained
through investment in R&D, leading to improved innovation and skills (Rassekh, 2004).
Learning-by-doing saves cost and maximizes profit. In this sense, even if the resources are
limited and are fully employed, output growth can be realized through the accumulative factors
44
of human capital and technology, and thus increase productivity. Hence, production and exports
should be directed toward and involved in R&D and skill improvement. This can be obtained
depending partly on the significance of government intervention and strategic trade policy.
However, the issue might be subjective and hardly observable but cannot be overlooked.
By discussing trade theory starting from the classical and neoclassical framework, the
Prebisch-Singer thesis, to the new trade theory, some clues to the above question as to what
determines which goods to export should have been obtained. Over time, each model has been
modified due to its limitations and for more favorable applicability. It is advantageous,
therefore, to pose the same question in practice and to see how the theory is applied.
The examinations of labor efficiency in explaining trade between the United States and
the United Kingdom during the 1940s and 1950s, suggesting that labor cost—and labor
productivity—of the US exceeded the level of the UK so that US firms should have had export
advantage in manufacturing sectors while the UK exported labor-intensive products to the US,
supported the classical approaches (Markusen et al., 1995). Conversely, the discovery by
Leontief that the capital-labor ratio of imports was 23 percent higher than that of exports in the
US in 1947 surprised the world of economics (Markusen et al., 1995). The term Leontief
paradox is, thus, given to this unexpected outcome, which is contradictory to Heckscher-Ohlin
theorem. Markusen et al. (1995) mentioned that the Leontief paradox was not an isolated event,
country. Abidin (2000) stated that: “the RCA measures the export share of commodity i from
country j in the world market relative to its production share. An RCA value of more than unity
45
indicates that the country has captured more export share than that of production, and thus it
has a comparative advantage.” (p. 309). The case of Malaysia, for example, shows that this
country had a comparative advantage in natural resource-based production in the early 1970s,
while capital-intensive products took over by the mid-1980s (Abidin, 2000). Similarly, Taiwan
identified labor-intensive sectors as the key for export-led growth after adopting export
promotion policies in the late 1950s, expanding quickly until the 1970s (Tung, 2000). The
structural change, however, shifted key exports of this economy to sectors with high capital
intensity from the 1990s. In the case of Cambodia, traditional exports, consisting of textile
fabrics, natural rubber latex, wood and vegetable materials have maintained RCA over the
period 1990-2006, but their joint share fell and was replaced by garments and non-traditional
exports, including nuts, castor oil seeds and plywood products (World Bank, 2009).
Net export performance ratio, a model based on RCA, has been applied to identify which
industries exhibit positive net exports. In the study of Thailand’s export strength from 1979 to
1996, Warr (2000) applied this method and found that although machines, transport and
equipment exports have contributed considerably to gross exports, this industry has been
dependent largely on imports and thus faced negative balance in all periods. Instead, food and
live animals from the primary sector and miscellaneous manufactured articles are the ones with
The application of RCA basically examines commodities that have been exported to
identify products with high competitiveness. Notwithstanding, constraints appear because non-
exporting sectors usually see little progress in contribution to outputs, productivity and
efficiency when the attention is given only to those exporting sectors. Taiwan has experienced
this problem (Tung, 2000). In addition, linkages across sectors are not taken into account in the
RCA model, which can limit the export potential of different industries. For example, minimal
linkages between industries are one of the important factors limiting the exports of Malaysia
46
(Abidin, 2000). Therefore, it is of central importance that linkages between sectors should also
Other pieces of research have moved away from RCA to the sectoral linkage approach
by examining how export sectors and the whole economic system are interconnected. The
concept indicates the extent to which one industry is affected by the stimuli of another industry
through structural linkages, namely backward and forward linkages, which are defined by
The backward linkage effects refer to the input-provision, derive demand, i.e. every non primary
economic activity, will induce attempts to supply through domestic production the inputs
needed in that activity. The forward linkage effects refer to the output-utilization, i.e. every
activity that does not by its nature cater to final demands, will induce attempts to utilize its
The analysis of such linkages is of great importance to studying the role of each sector,
both exporting and non-exporting, in inducing growth (Mujeri & Alauddin, 1994). Such
interaction can be examined by using an input-output framework3 (Hazari & Kingma, 1976;
Mujeri & Alauddin, 1994; Rasmussen, 1956). The impacts of trade and linkages provide
insights into the role of the export sector in expanding necessary stimuli which, in turn, have
favorable impacts on the expansion of other sectors. This model can go further to analyze the
effect on income and employment, on factor intensity, and other assorted economic factors.
Through these analyses, one can identify which industries should be promising for exports with
potential to grow and with significant impacts on the domestic economy. The combination of
these issues is of significance in developing countries such as Cambodia. While such models
are widely applied, studies of Cambodia have been few. Kobayashi et al. (2009) studied the
industrial structure of Cambodia and the role of agriculture by measuring the gross output and
3
More details of the input-output framework are discussed in Chapter 4.
47
value added of each sector. They found that the garment industry played an important role in
GDP and self-sufficiency, yet induced smaller domestic outcome, while agriculture and food
sectors had a tendency to induce high and wide distribution of income. Nonetheless, different
measures of the importance of exporting sectors were not specifically emphasized in their study.
Even if countries understand the important roles of exports and adopt outward-looking
strategies, and even if the countries have identified their potential export sectors, not every
country succeeds in improving its export performance. It is, therefore, useful to examine why
Income elasticity of demand and price elasticity of demand are some common measures
of the demand side affecting export performance of individual countries. In contrast, export
supply has taken into account domestic factors such as domestic production, consumption and
price elasticity of supply. According to Majeed et al. (2006) (based on the argument of Funke
and Holly, 1992), previous approaches that emphasized demand factors have been rather
unsuccessful in explaining export performance in the long term trends, while supply side factors
strongly influence export behavior. Theoretically, production capacity and price determine
supply conditions and relative price between export goods and domestic goods. When the
relative price increases, export production becomes more profitable and the supply of exports
will rise. Havrila and Gunawardana (2006) studied the export supply of the Australian textile
industry, suggesting that export supply of textiles was positively and significantly related to
relative price. Atique, Ahmad, and Zaman (2003) examined the supply and demand for the
exports of Pakistan, using the polynomial distributed lag (PDL) approach. In the supply model,
domestic production, relative price (the unit value of export to domestic price), and wage rate
48
were included in the estimation. Their result gave strong support to the importance of domestic
production capacity, whereas wage rate had cumulative effects and less elasticity although it
was insignificant in the short run, while relative price did not appear important. They pointed
out that institutions (economic and political) did matter, and that policies for greater utilization
of productive capacity were needed. The significance of production capacity or production size
is also found under cross country analysis, particularly of developing countries. Athukorala and
Sen (1998) and Jongwanich and Magtibay-Ramos (2009) studied the patterns of processed food
exports of developing countries in different periods, and found that economic size was positively
Policies can be divided into direct and indirect polices. Although the distinction
between the two is arbitrary, it is useful to assess them separately to study successful export
Direct policies are important for export-oriented strategy as they impact the resource
allocation between the production of tradable and non-tradable goods. Exchange rate is known
to be one of the important direct policies influencing exports. Nominal exchange rate
determines the cost of imports and the price of exports in domestic currency per unit of foreign
currency (Krueger, 2000). Real exchange rate is more important in defining the relative price.
The depreciation of the real exchange rate, relatively more expensive traded goods in relation
to non-traded goods, shows that traded goods are more profitable in export markets than in
domestic markets. In the case of Turkey, for example, the econometric analysis discovered that
the policy allowing real depreciation of exchange rate contributed by far the most to the export
boom (Arslan & van Wijnbergen, 1993). This may not always hold. The link between real
exchange rate and export performance appeared weaker in some recent studies due to the
flexibility of export behavior in response to the market and due to the diversification towards
49
specialization within global industries, rather than relying on price (Jongwanich, 2010;
exchange rate is necessary to ensure export growth because exchange rate volatility negatively
affects exports and discourages investment (Kabir Hassan & Tufte, 1998).
Trade regime defines ease of export as well as import of capital goods to use in the
production of tradable goods. Although a unique measure of trade openness has not been
identified, several approaches have been applied. Yanikkaya (2003) measured trade openness
by (1) total trade volume and (2) trade restrictions such as tariff and export tax as barriers to
trade. Sachs et al. (1995) based their measurement on specific policy criteria such as tariffs,
black market exchange rate, economic system and state monopoly. Studying the impact of trade
regime based on these criteria, Athukorala and Sen (1998) found positive and significant impact
of the openness of exports in the food industry. Jongwanich and Magtibay-Ramos (2009)
considered total trade volume as the proxy of trade regime and also suggested a similar result.
Conversely, trade restriction is found positive in relation to economic growth in the study by
Yanikkaya (2003). However, this, as he mentioned, happened under some conditions restricted
to developing countries, in which potential sectors were protected. Krueger (2000), on the other
hand, argued that even countries favoring a “half-and-half” strategy—the strategy that
it hard to achieve successful growth in practice because the difficulty of imports occurs under
protectionism, including the imports of intermediate and capital goods in the production of the
Recent studies have included FDI as an indicator for export growth (Jongwanich, 2010;
Jongwanich & Magtibay-Ramos, 2009; Majeed et al., 2006). FDI inflow to developing
countries has been observed as export-oriented and, in general, is a driving force for technology
(Abidin, 2000). FDI in Malaysia, for instance, has helped build and greatly expand some new
50
economic sectors since the 1980s (Abidin, 2000). Similarly, the estimates by Jongwanich
(2010) revealed that FDI had increased in importance in determining exports in some East and
Southeast Asian economies. Nonetheless, the impact of FDI varies across countries. The
empirical result of Jongwanich and Ramos (2009) exhibited a positive relationship between
FDI and exports, but the coefficients appeared insignificant, suggesting that the great influence
performance; hence, the effectiveness of direct policies can be limited without the indirect
supports (Krueger, 2000). Adequate infrastructure, for example, represents an essential part of
the satisfactory growth of exports. Failure to expand infrastructure limits the potential gains
from outward promotion and can impose serious constraints on the attainable export growth
rate. A number of types of infrastructure and services are closely linked to trade and need to be
trade-related infrastructure and services are (ADB & ESCAP, 2009; Krueger, 2000):
- Transport: such as internal road networks, port and international transport links.
- Logistic: such as freight forwarders and distributors. Efficient logistic providers allow
cost and time minimization in the connection between exporters and importers.
- Electricity: electricity service greatly affects transaction cost of investment and production.
51
Another policy necessary to ensure smooth procedure of trade is trade facilitation, which
refers to the efficient and transparent implementation of rules and regulations related to trade,
and can be defined as the measures affecting the movement of goods along the international
supply chain, in a broader sense, and as the system of customs procedures and documents, in a
narrow sense (ADB & ESCAP, 2009). The scope of its general definition is displayed in Figure
3.1 which lays down the transaction of trade from “Buy”, from trading partners, to “Ship”,
preparing to export, export, transport, preparing to import and importing, to “Pay”, to the sellers.
Such procedures can sometimes be major impediments to produce and export, which arise in
response to the need of governments to monitor. As a result, one of the main objectives of
export facilitation is to minimize cost and, more importantly, to simplify, harmonize and
Trading across borders incurred in getting goods from producers in one country to
consumers in another. While trade regime is important in making this process viable, the
country cannot fully reap the gains from trade if barriers at borders are not minimized. Barriers
encountered at borders, those other than the marginal cost of production, delay export activities
and consequently reduce volume of exports. The barriers may include cost and document
52
required to export and import, and can also be broken down into policy barriers, legal and
regulatory costs, information and security barriers, and barriers associated with the use of
different currencies. A clear understanding of trading across borders and how it can be deal
with will help promote deeper trade integration. Trade costs, for example, encountered by
exporters differ across countries, starting from getting information to transferring out the goods
and getting receipt of formal payment, depending on efficiency level of traders, and specifically
on trading environment of the particular countries. More time and reflect institutional
bottlenecks such as regulatory and logistic procedures resulting in more expensive export
transaction.
In addition, the consensus over business environment has generally included the
macroeconomic aspect such as economic stability, inflation, and exchange rate. However, a
more specific measure of business regulatory aspect is of concern particularly in the area of
regulatory agenda which might be difficult to observe. The survey of Doing Business by
International Finance Cooperation has included various topics concerning the business
regulatory environment ranging from starting a business, dealing with construction permits,
registering property, getting credit, protecting investors, paying taxes, trading across borders,
demonstrates how markets function and how business profitability can be ensured. Particularly,
better business environment reduces market failures and enhances industrialization process
with sufficient public services and enforceable rules and regulation (Khondoker & Kalirajan,
2012). Nevertheless, these have often been limited in developing economies making business
procedures starting from opening a new business to licensing and contract enforcement a
challenging task. For instance, too many document requirements, power outage, delay in
custom clearance and getting telephone connections are serious problems in expanding growth
of industries. In contrast, better business regulation reduces time and operation costs barred by
53
investors making the processes faster. Starting business represents procedure and flexibility of
Jongwanich and Ramos (2009) include some policy variables such as infrastructure,
represented by road networks, and business facilitation, represented by domestic credit for the
private sector, in their empirical model. Majeed et al. (2006) also included those factors of
policies as expected to affect developing countries’ exports. Their variables are: communication
services (telephone and television) as proxies for infrastructure, and national savings, official
development assistance and indirect taxes as proxies for investment and trade facilitation, all
exports and their determinants, Ninkovic (2009) and Khondoker and Kalirajan (2012) found
that, besides resource endowment, infrastructure (road networks, electricity consumption per
capita) and the business regulatory environment (days required to start a new business) are very
important, and strongly suggested that the vital roles of the above factors were applicable to
almost all of the export products and not limited to labor-intensive ones.
In conclusion, the review of the previous studies gives insights into the numerous
general consensus gives weight to the central roles of production capacity and trade regime,
while exchange rate or relative price is somewhat unpredictable in explaining export supply
due to the structural change of exports in global markets and industries. The importance of the
FDI appears ambiguous, depending greatly on specific countries and sector orientation.
Variables of great interest should go toward indirect policies, which have little been examined
54
Chapter 4: Specification of Key Sectors: Implications for Export Potential Industries
Introduction
Cambodia’s trade increased from 48 percent of GDP in 1993 to 140 percent in 2013,
with exports accounting for 65 percent (US$7.28 billion) and growing at 18 percent on average
annually (WDI, 2015)4. The garment industry and tourism are the current leading export sectors.
This growth has been realized through a combination of targeted policy—tax incentives and
quota increases for the garment sector—and horizontal policy—tariff cuts, and the accession to
ASEAN in 1999 and to the WTO in 2004 (World Bank, 2009). Nevertheless, export growth
should be interpreted with caution, as domestic technological benefits are limited. The
important question is how much the export boom has contributed to domestic industry and vice
versa. Boosting the domestic industrial connection and the value added content of export
products may be a good option. For this reason, domestic development depends greatly on
which goods the country exports. More importantly, the slow progress of diversification and the
low value added of the main manufacturing exports, given the narrow based industrial structure,
make Cambodia’s foreign market vulnerable to external shocks and unable to contribute widely
to the domestic economy. This paper, therefore, attempts to identify additional key export
Exports of primary commodities have decreased from almost 80 percent of total exports
in 1995 to less than 15 percent in 2012—one third of which is accounted for by food items,
exports (UNCTAD, 2014). The main products are garments (apparel and clothing accessories),
footwear, and motor vehicles, which account for 66 percent, 8 percent, and 3 percent of total
exports, respectively, as shown in Table 4.1. The country depends highly on the imports of
industrial goods for domestic production, which usually happen as a start of industrialization.
4
The trade deficit has persisted over two decades. The figure slightly decreased from 11 percent of GDP in
2000 to 8 percent in 2013.
55
Table 4.1: Export and Import by Categories, share in total values (1995-2012)
Export (share in total) Import (share in total)
1995 2005 2012 1995 2005 2012
1
Primary commodities 74.71 4.95 9.79 18.41 13.21 22.28
Crude rubber 14.53 1.93 3.91
Agriculture and Food items 3.99 2.42 4.90 23.83 10.14 12.91
Milled rice 0.69 0.09 1.48
Beverage Tobacco 0.07 0.49 0.50
Low tech/Labor-intensive/
19.62 84.39 79.35 24.57 48.51 37.72
Resourece based
Garment 16.72 79.22 66.32
Footwear 0.56 3.70 8.16
2
Bicycle/Motor-vehicle 0.27 0.07 3.41
However, the imports of consumption goods surge due to the increasing income of urban
residence and higher demand for luxurious goods, which put additional pressure on trade deficit.
identifying potential exports and increasing supply and competitiveness are the key elements.
Three policy objectives have been proposed: to ensure the vitality and competitiveness of
existing exports, to develop export potential and diversify products and markets, and to
encourage investment and improve investment facilitation for exports (WTO Secretariat, 2011a).
Initial baskets of 19 potential products and services were identified following the Diagnostic
Trade Integration Strategy (DTIS) in 2007 (MoC, 2007). Garment and footwear are still the top
products in the list, followed by agricultural items. Improved market access due to a favorable
trade agreement with the EU and low labor costs, together with a relatively encouraging
business environment, are the main competitive elements of Cambodia’s exports. However,
low labor productivity and high trade facilitation costs remain critical, whereas a number of
other constraints hinder export progress, which will be discussed in the following section. The
56
chapter proceeds with a brief review of existing literature in section 3, while section 4
introduces the study objectives, original contributions, and data. The methodology is described
in section 5, followed by the discussion of the results in section 6. Section 7 concludes the
chapter.
Five main products—apparel, footwear, crude rubber, bicycle, and vegetable and fruit—
account for more than 70 percent of total exports in 2012, with articles of apparel alone sharing
more than half, remaining unchanged from 2000, which indicates that diversification towards
new products in recent years has made slow progress (UNCTAD, 2014). The low-end garments
and markets within the sector itself are mainly based on the advantages of quota assessment,
while other factors such as creation of production chains seem to be ignored (World Bank,
2009). As a result, other sectors see little progress, and the impacts of the main exports on other
factors such as employment, value added and linkages are thus limited. In addition, the
diversification index notes no significant improvement. This index, ranging from 0 (more
diversified) to 1 (less diversified), shows to what extent the country depends on specific
Cambodia stood at 0.79 in 2012, similar to that of Laos (0.77), yet higher than that of Thailand
57
(0.40), Vietnam (0.52), and other countries in ASEAN, except Brunei and Myanmar, as shown
in Table 4.25.
The country is not able to retain value added in its main manufacturing as little of the
value chain operates inside the country, where intermediate parts are imported and assembled
into finished products which are then exported. Manufacture export capacity is one of the
indicators commonly used to measure industrial performance as it shows the ability of countries
manufacturing value added (MVA) (UNIDO, 2011). Hence, it is necessary to complement the
export analysis with MVA. Cambodia has impressive growth in manufacturing exports, with
an average annual rate of 15 percent from 2000 to 2009, which is relatively higher than that of
Malaysia, Thailand and Indonesia, whereas MVA per capita in Cambodia also rose
considerably due to the low start base of manufacturing production. However, the value remains
among the lowest in the region. As shown in Table 4.3, Cambodia’s per capita MVA in 2009
still lagged behind Vietnam’s in 2005 and Indonesia’s and the Philippines’s in 2000, which
implies that Cambodia’s MVA growth should be not as impressive as it appears at first glance.
Table 4.3: Manufactured Exports and Value Added, Cambodia and Asia, 2000-2009
Manufactured exports Average annual Manuf value added per capita
(US$ million) growth rate (US$ constant 2000 prices)
2000 2005 2009 2000-09 2000 2005 2009
Malaysia 87,643 120,622 133,222 5% 1,265 1,412 1,390
Thailand 58,731 95,859 127,686 9% 680 895 1,004
China 228,407 722,628 1,155,517 20% 303 492 754
Indonesia 42,990 55,118 72,130 6% 216 258 295
Philippines 36,633 39,432 35,729 0% 221 247 258
Viet Nam 6,765 17,504 36,429 21% 73 118 171
Cambodia 1,090 2,093 3,276 15% 46 80 111
India 35,419 87,168 149,047 17% 63 80 99
5
The diversification index is calculated in UNCTADStat by measuring the absolute deviation of the trade
structure of a country from world structure. A value closer to 1 indicates greater divergence from the
world pattern (UNCTAD, 2014).
58
4.2.3. Underperformance in the Regional Market
In 2011, only 1.5 percent of Cambodia’s exports went to ASEAN countries other than
Thailand and Vietnam. Among all the members, Cambodia contributed only 0.26 percent of
total exports to the regional market in the same year, an increase from 0.14 percent in 2005,
compared to 0.34 percent in 1997 before the accession into ASEAN (UNCTAD, 2012).
markets—only 13 percent, against 49 percent on average (World Bank, 2009). This may reflect
the inability of the export sectors to realize potential gains from the regional free trade
agreement.
The comparison above shows that the competitiveness of Cambodia in the export
market does not correspond to the performance of its industries. Favorable status of market
access plays an important role in promoting garment exports; however, there are still open
questions with regard to which sectors can also take part in the world market while at the same
The chapter attempts to fulfill the first objective of the dissertation which is to identify
key sectors promising for exports, using the Input-Output model through five approaches:
backward and forward linkages, multiplier effects on income, labor intensity, foreign exchange
earnings, and hypothetical extraction. Sectors with potential for export should rank high in
most, if not all, of the five indicators. To the best of my knowledge, this is the first study to
combine the five approaches and, more importantly, to be based on both the traditional
Rasmussen’s backward-forward linkages and the more current hypothetical extraction method.
The normalization approach6 for ranking given to each indicator at the end of the estimation is
another contribution to the literature. In addition, previous studies on this topic in the case of
6
The normalization approach is discussed at the last part of section 6, under the subsection “Normalization
Values and Ranking”.
59
Cambodia are mainly based on the qualitative method (MoC, 2014; MoC, 2007; RGC, 2015;
World Bank, 2009). The quantitative approach, therefore, would contribute to widen the
The 2011 input-output table used in the study consists of 18 sectors, as given in Table
4.4. This table is derived and aggregated from the Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) of
Cambodia constructed by Heng et al. (2014). The database used in the estimation also
contributes to the originality of the study in the sense that since there is no employment data
corresponding to the I-O table, the current study has generated data on employment by sector
from the National Institute of Statistics (NIS)’ Cambodia Socio-Economic Survey (CSES,
Agriculture
1 AGR Agriculture, Hunting, Forestry, and Related Service Activities
60
Table 4.4 lists the names with the descriptions of the 18 sectors, of which two belong to
agriculture, 11 to industry, and five to service, whereas Table 4.5 shows the descriptive statistic
of the structural features of the Cambodian economy. Textile (TEXTILE) accounts for 21
percent, the largest share, of domestic production, followed by Agriculture (ARG) and
Wholesale-retail trade and transportation (WTT), respectively. These three industries are also
the top three contributing to highest value added. Top export belongs to TEXTILE, while the
Table 4.5 also lists the export and import intensity, defined as export and import share
in domestic production. Almost all (96 percent) of TEXTILE is exported, which reveals that the
foreign market plays a more vital role for this industry. Similarly, the export intensity of HR is
71 percent with imports of less than one percent, showing the importance of this exporting
61
manufacturing (572%), Fabricated metal-office-computing machine (255%), Motor vehicle-
other transport equipment (191%) and Metal (119%). These figures demonstrate that domestic
supply of these industries are far behind the level to cover self-sufficiency.
Finally, while AGR employs more than 60 percent of the total labor force, it contributes
to only 41 percent of income, illustrating that value added per worker is lower in this sector
than in the service sectors. This can be explained by the higher share of low-skilled labor in the
Methodology
Leontief in the late 1930s, with the publication of the 1919 and 1929 I-O tables of the United
States. This resulted in his being awarded the Nobel Prize in Economic Science in 1973 in
recognition of the application of I-O frameworks to economic problems (Miller & Blair, 2009).
Basically, I-O frameworks are used for inter-industry analysis, which is the analysis of the
Table 4.6 illustrates a basic sample of I-O table, which is principally the matrix of
columns and rows divided into three quadrants (Parikh, 1979). The first is the intermediate
quadrant which is comprised of all of the industries in an economy (the first to the nth industry),
such as agriculture, manufacturing and service, providing the whole picture of supply and
demand of intermediate products with transaction flows across these various industries. The
column of the table is the input flows showing that a given industry requires intermediate inputs
(xij ) from other industries to produce its output (xi ), while the row is the output flows that one
particular industry sells its final outputs to other industries (as their intermediate inputs). Within
this transaction, industries are interdependent on each other in the process of production. The
expenditure, investment (fixed capital formation), and exports, together working as the demand
62
for the final products distributed by all of the industries. The third is the primary input quadrant.
Primary inputs consist of value added (vi )—wage, tax, return to capital, operating surplus—
and import, which show the amount of each component required, in addition to intermediate
inputs, by each industry. In some cases, there is another quadrant that demonstrates the direct
xij + vi = xi (i = 1, … , n)
xij + fi = xi (j = 1, … , n)
The value added is the income part of the economy that should be equal to the final demand
as the consumption part of the same economy. That application implies consistently to the
national account identity stated GDP (Y) of an economy (looking at the consumption part) is
investment (I), and net foreign final demand (export (E) adjusted with import (M)) as appears
63
The I-O frameworks can be applied to various economic analysis such as economic
relationships, and backward-forward measures within and across regions, all of which are
useful in policy measure and planning. The direct effects on any factors, say income or
employment, can be easily estimated; nonetheless, the indirect effects are not simply observed
unless the Leontief technique and the linkages are taken into account (Valadkhani, 2003).
However, it should also be noted that analysis with I-O application is not without limitations.
Traditionally, I-O modeling assumes that there are no supply constraints, production of every
industry is subject to constant return to scales, the commodity input structure is fixed, output is
a linear function of demand, and there is only homogeneous sector output (Hara, 2008). These
Matrix Form
Intermediate goods plus final demand should be equivalent to total output. This can be
written in matrix form as x = Ax + f, where A is the input coefficient matrix representing the
input per unit of total output of each industry7, x is the total output vector and f is final demand
vector (Miller & Blair, 2009). The study applies an endogenous import model; therefore, import
is used in domestic final demand (f) but not in export (e). The matrix form of the decomposition
is derived as follows:
ˆ Ax I M
x IM
ˆ f e (4-1)
ˆ A 1 I M
x I IM ˆ f e (4-2)
x1 f1 e1 1 0 a11 a1n
e ; I ; A ; xij
where x ; f ; aij
xj
xn f n en 0 1 an1 ann
7. The term “industry” and “sector” are used interchangeably from this section.
64
m1 o b11 b1n
1
M ; I I M A
ˆ mj ˆ
mi ;
xj f j
o mn bn1 bnn
Backward and forward linkages in the I-O framework can be measured based on the
ˆ A 1 . bij denotes the elements of the Leontief inverse
Leontief inverse matrix, I I M
matrix. The backward linkages are the column sums of all of the bij elements, following Hazari
n
b b.j
i 1 ij
(4-3)
which indicates the direct and indirect input requirements for all sectors for a unit increase in
final demand for the jth sector, while the forward linkages are the raw sums of the bij elements
n
b bi.
j 1 ij
(4-4)
which indicates the output increase in the ith sector required to meet a unit increase in final
demand for all sectors. The results of the two linkages provide information about which sectors
produce the highest direct and indirect effects, yet there is no information regarding whether
there is a high interdependence among all sectors. As a result, linkage indices have to be
defined.
1
First, the average is given to the backward linkage b. j (j=1,..., n) and the forward
n
1
linkage bi. (i=1,..., n), and the overall averages are
n
1 1 1
n n n n
j 1
b
i 1 ij
b
j 1 .j
b
i 1 i.
(4-5)
n2 n2 n2
65
Next, the index of backward and forward linkages, which are termed “Index of Power
(Rasmussen, 1956):
1
b.j
uj n (4-6)
1
j1 b.j
n
n2
1
bi.
ui n (4-7)
1
n
b
i 1 i.
n2
These indices can be used to answer which industries highly depend on others. If uj is bigger
than unity (uj >1), the jth industry is highly interactive, and it is not if uj is smaller than unity
(uj<1). uj is termed “Index of Power of Dispersion” because it describes to which extent the
effects are dispersed throughout the economy. Similarly, ui is interpreted as if this index is
bigger than one (ui>1), then industry i will increase its output more than other industries. In
other words, the term “Index of Sensitivity of Dispersion” explains how the expansion of other
The indices above are unweighted averages and they do not take into account the
importance of individual sectors. For example, if one industry has a high index of power of
dispersion (uj), it does not necessarily imply that most industries will be affected if jth industry
depends heavily on only a few industries and leaves the rest unchanged. Therefore, the
coefficient of variation is needed for the measures of variability and structure of a certain
industry.
2
1 n 1 n
n 1
i 1
bij i 1 bij
n
vj (j = 1, ..., n) (4-8)
1 n
bij
n i 1
66
2
1 n 1 n
n 1
j 1
bij j 1 bij
n
vi (i = 1, ..., n) (4-9)
1 n
bij
n j 1
In the case of a relatively high value of vj, the jth industry is heavily dependent on only a few
industries, and a relatively low value of vj indicates the jth industry evenly draws on most of
other industries; similarly, in the case of a relatively high value of vi, the whole system draws
Income multipliers are used to determine which sectors generate higher income effects
if the same amount of initial effect is given (Hara, 2008). tyj denotes total income generated by
industry j, so
ty j
yj (4-10)
xj
is the income per unit of output. The direct and indirect income distributed by each sector is
derived
1
ˆ I I M
Y Y ˆ A (4-11)
where Ŷ is the diagonal matrix of income coefficient, and I I M
ˆ A
1
is the Leontief
inverse matrix, hence Y is the matrix of direct and indirect income effects per unit of final
n
demand. The column sum of Y ( y ij , j=1,…, n) denotes the total income effects for the jth
i 1
industry. To get the income multiplier, the total income effect is divided by the initial income
n
yij
y m
j i 1
(4-12)
yj
67
Income multipliers yjm therefore can imply that the US$1 increase in final demand generates
additional income of some amount of US$ for workers in one industry, plus another amount for
The result provides guidance in policy decisions, for example, which sector should
receive investment funds given limited resources if the target is to raise labor income.
Increasing final demand can be the initial attempts; nonetheless, domestic final demand may
not be easily increased, at least in the short term, given the small market size of Cambodia, so
the increase in foreign sales can be a potential target to expand the markets. Hence, the income
multipliers are considered one of the main indicators to specify key export sectors that are likely
produce and export products which require more of the factor in which the country is endowed,
either capital or labor (Todaro & Smith, 2009). Most of least developed countries are found to
be with scarce capital but excessive labor supply which can be beneficial from the countries to
intensive country with a relatively low cost of labor (World Bank, 2009). There is, therefore, a
significant concern about how the country could benefit from this endowment, as well as how
employment could be created to cope with the increasing labor supply. Recent experience from
newly industrialized economies such as South Korea, Malaysia and Indonesia has shown
increasing concern toward export promotion in labor-intensive industries during the first stage
of an export boom (Weiss, 2005). The question, however, arises as to which industries possess
the most competitiveness for exports while at the same time contributing to employment
generation.
Employment intensity analysis of foreign trade is applied to answer the above question.
Following Parikh (1979), labor content per unit of final demand can be calculated on the basis
68
of I-O model using the input coefficients and data of employment in each industry. tlj denotes
the total labor employed by the jth sector, so the direct labor requirements per unit of total
output is
tl j
lj (4-13)
xj
This is pre-multiplied by total output requirements per unit of final demand and yields total
1
L Lˆ I I M
ˆ A (4-14)
1
where L̂ is the diagonal matrix of labor coefficient, and I I M
ˆ A is the Leontief
inverse matrix, hence L is the matrix of total labor requirements per unit of final demand. The
higher the labor content, the more potential of the sector to possess comparative advantage
which, on one hand, answers the question whether this particular sector produces labor-
intensive products and should be relied on for export promotion, and on the other hand, helps
with policy making to undertake investment to maximize employment generation in the highest
Trade balance is normally examined in terms of gross export values, which does not
take into account both direct and indirect imports and, therefore, does not reflect net earnings
of each industry. Exporting sectors do not necessarily realize net foreign exchange earnings
because some sectors have to spend more on total imports than what they can earn from exports.
The analysis of net earnings is possible within an I-O framework where the direct and indirect
import requirements per unit of final demand (denoted by TM) can be derived from the
69
multiplication of the diagonal matrix of total import coefficient, M̂ , and the Leontief inverse
matrix
1
ˆ I I M
TM M ˆ A (4-15)
Net foreign exchange earnings of sector j are defined as the result of export (ej) taking out the
n
z j e j tmij f j (j=1, ..., n) (4-16)
i 1
If zj is positive, the jth sector is the net exporter or winner of foreign exchange. The net
earners should be considered as key exports as they will help secure foreign reserves and correct
the trade deficit, which has persisted for two decades in Cambodia. The result is a valuable
In addition to the linkage concept, the hypothetical extraction method (HEM) is a more
recent alternative approach used to measure key sectors and was studied by Paelinck et al.,
(1965); Strassert, (1968); and Meller & Marfán (1981) (cited in Temurshoev, 2010). HEM
refers to the “shut down” of any sector in the I-O transaction and can be used to identify key
industries through industries’ factor worth. Temurshoev (2010: 875) uses “factor” for any
indicator, which might refer to economic, social, or environmental factors. To put it another
way, HEM measures how the whole system (i.e. output, employment) is affected directly and
indirectly if one industry is extracted. If an industry is well connected with other sectors, with
high and broad linkage distribution, the shut-down of this industry will severely affect other
sectors in terms of output as well as other factors through the reduction of supply of inputs to
and demand for outputs from other industries. Even if the same amount of the reduced inputs
can be replaced by homogenous imported inputs, the effects are beyond the direct factor loss
70
itself due to the inter-sectoral relationship. In contrast, if the industry has few linkages with
Another purpose of using HEM in this study is basically to confirm whether the result
of this latter method will correspond to that of the traditional method of the Rasmussen concept
of linkages in the case of the Cambodian economy. The method will provide additional outlook
as to what sectors should be specified as key sectors, aimed at obtaining precise answers to
achieve the study objectives. To the best of my knowledge, no previous studies have combined
The differences between the total outputs before and after the extraction tell how
important each sector is in the economy. The elimination of sector j means that this sector no
longer produces outputs and no longer requires intermediate inputs from other remaining
sectors. Technically speaking, the row and column of input coefficient matrix (A) of sector j
become zero, and the new matrix is denoted A(-j). However, due to the reasons that (1) the
technological production of the other sectors (i j) remains the same, (2) the deletion of both
the row and column of j in A(-j) covers all the total linkages in which backward and forward
linkages are not divided, and (3) this total extraction might be too excessive for the economy;
it is assumed that the same amount of the required outputs formerly produced by sector j can
be imported so as to provide necessary inputs to other sectors (Miller & Blair, 2009;
Temurshoev, 2010). Using the same final demand vector (f), the model is generated from the
ˆ A(- j )
x(- j ) I I M I Mˆ f e
1
(4-17)
The difference between the total outputs before and after the extraction is
x = x – x(-j) (4-18)
and, more importantly, on the remaining sectors (i j). For the former case, two reduction
processes of sector j’s contribution are found: (1) reduction in its own final demand and (2) in
71
sector i’s final demand. For the latter case, two other important processes of the effect are also
revealed. First, sector j does not require any more contribution from sector i to produce final
demand; second, sector j does not produce any more input to sector i and, in turn, inputs from
sector i are not required (as it was in reverse before the omission of j) (Temurshoev, 2010). The
objective here is to find the sector with the highest reduction in outputs, which is the maximum
x.
Table 4.7 presents the backward and forward linkages obtained from the technological
coefficient, equation (4-3) and (4-4). On average, the direct and indirect effect of the total
linkages for Cambodia’s economy is 1.27. For the backward linkages, FBT (Food Beverage
Tobacco) stands at 1.62, which is the highest rank among all of the sectors. This figure indicates
that if final demand for this sector increases by US$1 million, total outputs of all sectors will
72
Rubber-Plastic with backward linkages of 1.54 and 1.49 respectively. Electricity-Gas-Water
and Wood-Paper are among others with moderate linkages, while MOTORT and TEXTILE have
the fewest linkages, slightly higher than 1.00. The increase in final demand for these two sectors
AGR ranks modestly for backward linkages but appears to be first for forward ones.
input for food production—and forestry, such as silviculture, logging, gathering of non-wood
forest products, and support services to forestry. The figure shows that there is a high
The result of the index of power of dispersion (uj) and sensitivity of dispersion (ui),
together with the variation of coefficients (vj, vi) in parenthesis, is presented in Table 4.8. Six
sectors have strong backward linkages. Among them, FBT has the strongest linkages with uj as
high as 1.27, and vj as small as 2.94, followed by HR and RP. On the other hand, OTHMNU,
TEXTILE and MOTORT have the weakest backward linkages. Although FBT ranks first for uj,
its vj ranks second after HR, indicating that the stimuli of FBT have the highest impacts, but the
distribution towards all sectors can be less even than that of the stimuli by HR. For the forward
linkage indices, ui reaches its highest level at 1.47 for AGR, followed by a total of seven other
sectors with strong forward linkages. The lowest ui goes to HR. It should be noticed that this
sector has relatively strong backward linkages but weak forward linkages. The increase in final
demand for this sector would result in relatively high impacts on other sectors, but not vice
versa. For instance, the higher demand for hotel and restaurant services would lead to an
increased demand for food (either raw agricultural or processed food), transportation and trade,
specifically due to tourism services, and other business services. However, the increased
73
Figure 4.1 is divided into four quadrants and locates different sectors according to the
level of both uj and ui. Part 1—in the upper right part of the Figure—locate strong linkage-
1.20 7 RP
16
8 METAL
11 9 9 FMETAL
2
14 4 10 MOTORT
1.00
18 11 OTHMNU
8 12
6 12 EGW
3
13 CON
10 13 17 15
0.80 5 14 WTT
15 HR
4 Weak linkage-oriented sectors Backward-oriented sectors 16 PFR
2
0.60 17 AEH
0.60 0.80 1.00 1.20 1.40 18 OTHSER
BACKWARD LINKAGES
74
oriented sectors. RP and FBT are the only two sectors in this part, showing that these two sectors
have strong linkages both backward and forward, while six sectors (Mining, Textile, Metal,
Motor, Construction, and Other services) located in part 4—in the lower-left part—are weak
in both of the linkages. The remaining sectors are either backward oriented (part 2) or forward
For part 1, FBT is among the strongest linkages, as it covers the manufacturing,
processing and preserving of food items, which require inputs from various sectors, especially
from agriculture. Cambodia is endowed with various types of aquatic life and rice fields for
growing crops and raising livestock, which explains the strong backward linkages of food
sectors together with the strong forward linkages of agriculture. Processed food exports remain
low but the value has increased almost four-fold from US$16 million in 2007 to US$60 million
in 2011 (MoC, 2014). The main exports in this category are unmanufactured tobacco/cigarettes,
crude palm oil and cane sugar. Other processed food produced locally includes dried fish and
meat, frozen shrimp and fish, sugar, dried packaged fruits, cookies, noodles, ready-made
canned food, and cassava preparation, whereas beverages includes spirits and non-alcoholic
drinks, rice/palm wine, beer, soybean juice, and other canned fruit juice.
Rubber plantations have increased significantly from 2009 and covered 328,771ha in
2013, comprised of Rubber Estates (former state-owned enterprises, 17 percent), economic land
concessions (41 percent), and household rubber plantations (42 percent) (MAFF, 2015). The
sector yielded 85,244 tons of dry rubber production with exports of 86,052 tons in 2013, both
increases of more than 100% from 2009. Although production is small scale, it is a long term
with inputs and workers that can be supplied locally. For instance, starting from planting, to
harvesting, tapping, and processing, the work can be done at the sites. This explains one of the
75
For part 2, HR is highly backward oriented, which is explained by the necessary
intermediate inputs from agriculture and processed food. Moreover, this industry, as the main
part of the tourism sector, connects strongly to transportation services and trade. When there is
an increase in tourist arrivals, the demand for HR will increase, which will also lead to increased
demand for other related services, including telecommunications and financial and insurance
systems. These interactions also give the reason for the strong forward-orientation of other
sectors, AGR, FISH, WTT and PFR, in part 3. In addition, PFR links forward to both public and
private sectors, specifically in the recent high-growth economy of Cambodia. The connection
is clear: the more technological and financial services needed for investment and business
activities, the more outputs will be added by the PFR sector as it plays an important role in
The estimation categorizes labor into three skill groups: low skill, medium skill and high
skill. In agriculture and industry, a significant proportion of the income is received by low-
3
Multiplier
Source: Author
76
skilled labor, while high-skilled labor takes the lead in services. The multiplier of income is
first calculated for each sector by the three skill groups separately, and later by labor as a whole,
as shown in Figure 4.2. Corresponding to the results of the linkage indices, Food-Beverage-
Tobacco has the highest income multiplier for all the skill groups. To be precise, a unity increase
of final demand for this sector would generate 4.23, 3.41, and 4.71 income multiplier to the low
skilled, medium skilled and high skilled respectively, and a 3.96 income multiplier for the total
group. In other words, labor will receive 3.96 times the income per unit of output higher than
the initial level. Meanwhile, when other industrial sectors, except Metal, contribute to the low-
skilled multiplier at a level of less than two, service sectors contribute relatively higher. Hotel-
Restaurant contributes up to 3.39. In contrast, the high-skilled worker income multipliers are
on average higher in industry than that in services. This phenomenon happens because the
former employs a lower proportion of high-skilled workers, which means that the number of
laborers and hence the income share is low for this group. Large changes will show up even
when there is a small increase; as a result, the multipliers will stand high compared to those of
the low-skilled group. Mathematically, when the denominator yj, of equation (4-12) is too small
There are not many changes in the trend of the income multipliers of the whole group
from that of the low skilled. Income multipliers of all the exporters rank from 3.96 to 1.14. FBT
is the highest contributor mainly for two reasons: 1) the linkages between this sector and the
rest are notably high (highest index of power of dispersion), and 2) the initial income level in
this sector is small, while the indirect changes are relatively large, which mathematically results
in a substantial level of multiplier. Kobayashi et al. (2009) also suggested that the food sector
has the highest value added multiplier among all industrial sectors. The direct effects on income
of AGR are rather high in comparison to industrial sectors, explained by agriculture’s large
portion of income share, yet the indirect effects from this sector are moderate. From the results,
FBT, WP and RP of merchandise, and HR service are able to induce higher domestic income
77
than the other sectors. Their growth is expected to distribute higher income to broad groups,
including low-skilled workers. Thus, it is preferable to put forward these sectors as potential
areas for stimulation in order to gain larger profits for future domestic investment.
Employment Intensity
The data of employment by sector is not provided in the I-O table; this data, thus, is
generated separately from the household survey (CSES, 2009) as it records each person’s
Rev. 4). The data of employment by occupation and age are aggregated to correspond to the
sectors of the I-O table. Figure 4.3 presents the employment intensity per unit of final demand,
based on equation (4-14). Direct labor refers to the number of workers directly employed in one
industry to produce one unit of output, while total labor refers to the number of laborers directly
and indirectly required in and out of the industry itself if there is an increase in final demand
Agriculture has the top rank due to the abundance of labor in this rural sector, yet there
is only a minor difference between the number of direct and total labor demand—1,233 and
1,474, respectively—suggesting that only 19 percent of the labor demand comes from the
sector. A similar case happens in Wood-Paper industry. In contrast, the next two sectors—
flow-on effects. For instance, the increase in one unit of output of FBT requires only 43 workers,
while 873 percent of this amount is generated throughout the remaining sectors. MINQ, FISH,
TEXTILE and OTHMNU have moderate direct labor intensity but are listed among the least in
The level of labor contents seems to be related closely to labor productivity, which can
be defined as labor requirement per one unit of final demand (Parikh, 1979). The sectors with
high labor contents are considered as having low labor productivity and vice versa, which gives
the point of view that, as suggested by Parikh (1979), countries with low unemployment rate
78
should undertake investment in low labor contents, or high productivity, sectors, while
sectors where labor intensities are higher since the rapid growth of productivity and
employment requirement per unit of investment in those sectors is viable. On the other hand,
aiming at increasing employment, foreign final demand for those sectors plays an important
role, particularly in small domestic markets like that of Cambodia. Hence, exprt promotion
should be oriented to above mentioned sectors with high labor intensities. Moreover, Cambodia,
as a labor-abundant country with a relatively low cost of labor, finds this characteristic an
advanced technologies are not much required, the production in Cambodia can be less
expensive and highly competitive. Therefore, investment planning in exports should obviously
1 AGR
6 WP
4 FBT
15 HR
17 AEH
14 WTT
12 EGW
18 OTHSER
16 PFR
13 CON
3 MINQ
2 FISH
11 OTHMNU
5 TEXTILE
9 FMETAL
8 METAL
7 RP
10 MOTORT
Source: Author
79
be devoted to the sectors with high labor intensities, where employment maximization and
Labor requirement is also related to the import structure of each sector as, in general, a
sector with relatively high imports will not generate high employment. As shown in the results,
the sectors with the least labor requirements, such as FMETAL, TEXTILE and OTHMNU, have
the sectoral import size of 12, 31, and 33 percent of total imports, respectively. In contrast, AGR
imports less than one percent of total imports. In this case, certain industries may never be able
to expand owing to the lack of sufficiently large demand for domestic products. Both the market
expansion and labor productivity can be improved, nevertheless, through trade and domestic
specialization. Parikh (1979) pointed out that relative price and productivity increase are the
two crucial elements when projecting results from a policy point of view. First, competitiveness
in relative price increases demand for the products and makes the sector more attractive
regardless of productivity level. Second, although the productivity varies across sectors, the
lower one has potential to grow over time due to technological absorption. The two factors can
be the reasons that high labor content sectors need to be promoted with a close link to external
economies because the lack of domestic final demand for the labor-intensive products makes
manufacturing—and four services are net exporters (Table 4.9). Hotel-Restaurant, with strong
backward linkages, contributes to 67 percent of total net exports even though its share in actual
exports is only 14 percent. In addition, the contribution of services such as WTT, PFR,
OTHSER to net exports are relatively high compared to manufacturing sectors. It should be
pointed out that although TEXTILE is the main exporter, covering more than 60 percent of
actual total exports, this sector, owing to the large import size, shares only six percent in total
net exports—a ten-fold drop compared to its share in actual exports. This shows the inefficiency
80
of this sector not only in linkages, but also in foreign currency earnings. This is because the
garment industry needs to import large amounts of fabric material and other inputs, causing
currency leakage, which is also consistent with previous research (Kobayashi et al., 2009). As
a result, the current largest export sector of Cambodia is unlikely to contribute enough profit to
Source: Author
The result reveals the lack of self-sufficiency of manufactured goods, as only a few can
manage to produce with low import contents. In addition, the high concentration on a few
sectors reflects Cambodia’s current trade pattern. It should also be recalled that Wood-Paper
and Hotel-Restaurant are the only sectors with positive net exports which have strong backward
linkages, while other sectors such as Food-Beverage-Tobacco and Rubber-Plastic are in the
negative net exporting category. This highlights the high dependency on imports and the neglect
of linkages. This may also happen due to the great final demand and/or the very high import
coefficients of those sectors (equations 15) (Hazari & Kingma, 1976; Mujeri & Alauddin,
1994). This requires a policy of generating adequate linkages; otherwise, the achievement of
81
Hypothetical Extraction
The impacts on total output resulting from the extraction of each exporter are ranked in
order from the largest to the smallest in Table 4.10. The abolishment of TEXTILE would result
in the highest impacts as the total outputs would decrease by 22 percent of the total outputs
before extraction. It should be noted that the hypothetical extraction in the study attempts to
estimate only the effects on aggregate outputs, while impacts on other socio-economic factors
are not examined. This may underestimate the real total impacts; therefore, interpretation of the
result should be done with caution. The second and third sectors are Trade-Transportation and
Agriculture, which are the sectors with relatively high forward linkages and considerably high
shares in total outputs. In addition, FBT ranks moderately high, while METAL and MOTORT
rank low in this exercise, which is quite consistent with the linkage indices; as a result, the
shutdown of the latter two sectors would be less consequential for the loss of aggregate outputs.
MINQ ranks at the bottom since this sector does not have any noticeable interconnection, as it
has been neither an active producer nor exporter. Manufacturing sectors, other than TEXTILE
and FBT, have modest impacts, at 2.5 percent on average. It can be concluded that Agriculture,
Source: Author
82
Normalization Values and Ranking
Since each sector has its ranking for each indicator, picking the key sectors promising
for export should be done carefully. To provide the final ranking, the study applies the
zi min z
s (0 <= si <= 1, i = 1,…, 18) (4-19)
max z min z
where z represents each indicator and zi is the value of sector i for indicator z. The normalization
value (s) gives the score to each sector in each different indicator. Finally, the study estimates
the First Principle Component to rank the sectors, as listed in Table 4.11, where FBT, HR, AGR,
Source: Author
83
Concluding Remarks
This chapter analyzed potential export sectors by applying the I-O framework, utilizing
five indicators. The study finds that Agriculture generates high employment, and Food-
Beverage-Tobacco has strong linkages, generates the largest total income multiplier, and
requires relatively high labor intensity. Textile would contribute to the highest impact on total
outputs, yet possesses weak linkages. Wood-Paper and Rubber-Plastic are moderately
important in most indicators. Trade-Transportation ranks high in the last two indicators,
whereas Hotel-Restaurant is the top foreign exchange earner and is important in a few other
indicators.
The findings suggest that high import dependency with the absence of technical inter-
industry linkages is a cause of concern for the export orientation process of Cambodia. While
the strong linkage-oriented industries, such as food and rubber, have not been able to realize
their full potential in exports, the largest current industry (textiles) is unlikely to contribute
enough profit to foster future growth due to the lack of inter-industrial linkages. This limited
interaction is evident when net exports are dominated by a few commodities and when most
sectors with relatively high linkages in both income and labor intensity are neither the net
earners of foreign exchange nor the main contributors to outputs. This underscores that the
potential of export can be realized through the requirements of not only diversification, but also
linkage creation between sectors. This finding is consistent with the previous study by
Kobayashi et al (2009) who found that agriculture, the food sector, and hotels-restaurants are
able to induce wide distribution to domestic income while the garment cannot secure long-term
distribution. After the discussion of the sectoral pattern, this current study suggests that
attention should be given to the following four key sectors for export promotion: Agriculture,
with the trade development policy of the government toward export diversification.
84
The government also recognizes the importance of the above sectors though more
attention is needed. For one thing, agriculture products, such as fishery, livestock and crops, are
among the 19 potential products in DTIS 2007. In addition, the value of agro-food exports has
increased gradually, accounting for five percent of total exports in 2011 (MoC, 2014). The main
export items are tobacco, cane sugar and palm oil. The Industrial Development Plan (RGC,
2015) also targets an increase in processed agricultural exports from eight percent of total
exports in 2015 to 12 percent in 2025. With agriculture endowment and significant changes
underway in global demand for ready-made food products in Asia, Cambodia has an
opportunity to expand its agro-food industry. However, the number of items exported has been
limited. While rice and beer are the only two products listed in the DTIS, Cambodia should be
able to enlarge further its export items in this sector. For instance, processed meat and fruit,
frozen fish and shrimp, wine, and non-alcoholic drinks have been able to enter the world market
but are still at an initial stage and require improvement. Despite its potential, the processed food
industry—other than the rice sector—has received little strategic attention, with a lack of
domestic investment along the value chain. Also, a national business association specific to this
industry does not yet exist in Cambodia (MoC, 2014). Moreover, the industry is characterized
by SMEs with emerging larger firms, both heavily focused on domestic demand, while entry
into the international market is just starting, whereas the lack of compliance with quality
standards of Sanitary and Phyto-Sanitary (SPS) measures is a key constraint. For these
challenges, encouraging investment and value addition and improving quality standards should
be priorities.
Rubber cultivation has increased during the recent years, with 86,052 tons of exports in
2013, almost all of which are in the form of natural rubber 8 (MAFF, 2105; MoC, 2014). 87
percent of formal natural rubber exports in 2007 went to Vietnam, which has suitable facilities
8
The figure may be underestimated due to significant quantities of natural rubber exported informally
across borders (MoC, 2014).
85
to process and re-export. Over the past five years, however, this figure has declined to 58
percent, as exports to other markets (China and Malaysia) have grown due to significant
investment efforts and expansion of production capacity (MoC, 2014). However, the remaining
The increase in investment and exports of hotel-restaurant services is largely due to the
strong tourism sector. International tourist arrivals increased from 2 million in 2007 to 4.5
million in 2014 with 68 percent of hotel occupancy (MoT, 2015). As of 2009, 60 percent of
hotel rooms and guesthouses were located in Siem Reap, while they are more limited in the
coastal area, and are harder to access in other areas of the country (MoC, 2014). Despite the
low cost of the services, issues around the quality of food hygiene and sanitation persist. In
addition, inadequate transport and tourism infrastructure also adversely affects hotel-restaurant
Having identified the strategic export sectors, several implications can be proposed.
First, the country should encourage production and investment of the targeted sectors,
especially the food and rubber-processing industries. This can be done through special
export-processing zones or special economic zones. Second, increasing the supply chains of
system between agriculture and manufacturing and the formation of business associations.
Investment in clearing and storage houses is vital to link potential investors with local
and local content requirements should be strictly imposed to increase local processing and value
export activities. Most domestic firms, such as food-processing, small holding rubber
86
plantations, and hotels-restaurants are SMEs which base their operation mainly on local
intermediates. Involving them in export activities, thus, will benefit localization. Some
necessary supports, such as access to subsidized credit and duty-free measures, should be
provided. Last, to achieve the objectives of export promotion, the country should seek quality
guarantees for the four proposed sectors and provide training and technical know-how to
87
Chapter 5: Potential Roles of Export Orientation and Policy Options for
Cambodia’s Agriculture and Agro-industry
Introduction
Emphasis has been given to export-led growth as a driving force for development, as
exports play crucial roles in generating income and employment in the domestic economy, as
well as in bringing investment, technical upgrades, and industrialization. In this context, the
success which is highly associated with the performance of exporting sectors is essential to
ensuring long-term growth. Various studies have measured the impacts of exports as well as
factors affecting the performance of exports. From the point of view of demand, world prices
and demand of trading partners are supposed to determine a country’s exports (Atique et al.,
2003; Jongwanich, 2010). From the supply side framework, on the other hand, production
capacity and domestic policies are necessary to explain the phenomenon. However, given
different characteristics of specific economies, the size of impacts and the effectiveness of
policies depend greatly on which sectors the countries rely on for export.
The slow progress of diversification and low value-added content of the current exports
of Cambodia makes the country vulnerable to shocks and unable to widely contribute to the
domestic economy. For instance, five products (apparel and clothing accessories, footwear,
bicycle, crude rubber, and vegetable and fruit) account for more than 70 percent of exports,
with articles of apparel alone more than half of total exports in 2012, remaining unchanged
from 2000, indicating that diversification towards new products in recent years has made slow
progress (UNCTAD, 2014). Moreover, the country is not able to retain value added in its main
manufacturing—garments, footwear, and bicycles—as little of the value chains operate inside
the country, where intermediate parts are imported and assembled into finished products which
are then exported. Despite an impressive growth of manufacturing exports, at an average annual
rate of 15 percent from 2000-2009, Cambodia’s manufacturing value added per capital
88
remained among the lowest in the region and lagged behind its neighbors such as Vietnam,
Following the results from the previous chapter, which specifies agriculture, food-
beverage-tobacco, rubber industry, and hotel-restaurant as sectors with high export potential,
this chapter further analyzes the impacts of those sectors. However, only the merchandise
exports will be taken into account in the analysis. Given the narrow based industrial structure,
this country has been depending greatly on intermediate textile imports while ignoring the
possible benefits of the agricultural endowment to create the connection between agriculture
and the industrial sector. Hang Chuon (2011) stated that economic growth during the last decade
has centered on a few urban-based sectors such as tourism and construction in addition to
garment, while creating more opportunities for trading, investment and private sector
development for urban rather than rural areas. This differentiated growth performance, as a
consequence, has widened the income and inequality gaps between the two regions (Hang
Chuon, 2011). For better income distribution, a previous study suggested that Cambodia should
manufacturing (Kobayashi et al., 2009). Consistently, agriculture, food and the rubber industry
have been found as highly linkage oriented, able to induce high multiplier on income, and
possess high labor contents, while the garment industry is unlikely to contribute profits due to
the lack of inter-industrial linkages (Chhuor, 2016). The government has also recognized the
importance of these sectors and has set in the Industrial Development Plan 2015-2025 the goal
Manufacturing
89
to increase agro-industrial exports, as listed in Table 5.1 (RGC, 2015). However, there is a lack
of impact studies and more critical policies regarding those sectors. Potential export sectors
have been identified, yet their expected impacts on the economy are ambiguous.
This study, therefore, attempts to assess the impacts on economic factors including
growth, employment, and household welfare and to seek for plausible promotion policies for
three selected main sectors: the food-beverage-tobacco industry, the rubber industry, and
agriculture, which are deemed promising for the export-orientated structure of Cambodia. A
government and labor income, household welfare, and their interactions. Section 2 discusses
the current performance, potential and remaining challenges of the three selected export sectors,
while section 3 briefly reviews previous literature. An introduction to the CGE model
characteristics and the SAM data applied in the study are given in section 4. Section 5 describes
simulation designs, followed by the discussion of the simulation results, and the last section
Economic and Export Performance of Agriculture, Food and the Rubber Industry
Cambodia has enjoyed a high growth rate of about seven percent on average during the
last decade, with the garment industry, construction, tourism and agriculture acting as the main
driving forces. The share of agriculture output in GDP fell from 44 percent in 1995 to 23 percent
in 2014, replaced by industry, which doubled to 31 percent, while the share of services has
remained relatively stable during the period (NIS, 2015). Despite the decreasing share in GDP,
agriculture and agro-related activities have played significant roles in contributing to the
employment and livelihood of more than 70 percent of the total population, to poverty reduction
in rural areas, to food security, and to equitable economic growth (Hang Chuon, 2011). Agro-
in that they are based on agricultural intermediates, except that the former should undergo some
90
degree of preserving, processing, or packaging before distributing to final domestic and foreign
markets, and thus are categorized as industrial products, according to the Ministry of Industry
(NIS, 2015).
5.2.1. Agriculture
by crop production, mainly paddy rice. Although the value added share in GDP has decreased,
agriculture maintained an average of five percent growth until 2010 and 2.3 percent during the
next four years, as shown in Table 5.2. Previously domestic-oriented, agricultural production
was exported, after the civil war and during the start of the market economy in the late 1980s,
due to a surplus of production—mostly paddy rice, corn, soybeans, cassava, and cashews.
Statistic in Table 5.3 shows that exports of agricultural products were US$35 million in 2014,
with 26 percent growth on average from 2000 (UN Comtrade, 2016). Nevertheless, the figure
can be underestimated due to informal exports crossing the borders to Thailand and Vietnam,
which have the capacity to process and re-export to third countries (MoC, 2014).
Table 5.2: Agriculture value added and contribution to GDP by categories (1995-2014)
Average Value Added
Share in GDP Share in Agriculture
Growth
1995- 2001- 2006- 2011-
1995 2000 2005 2010 2014 1995 2000 2005 2010 2014
2000 2005 2010 2014
Agriculture 3.3 4.9 5.1 2.3 44.4 35.7 29.4 27.3 22.7
Crops 4.7 6.0 10.8 2.6 16.3 15.6 15.0 14.7 12.3 36.7 43.7 50.9 53.8 54.4
Livestock & Poultry 2.5 3.0 4.6 0.3 7.7 5.5 4.5 4.1 3.1 17.4 15.5 15.4 15.0 13.9
Fisheries 3.1 2.4 3.9 3.8 13.2 10.7 7.7 6.8 6.0 29.8 30.0 26.3 24.8 26.3
Forestry & Logging -1.8 -3.0 2.1 -1.7 7.1 3.5 2.2 1.7 1.2 16.1 9.7 7.4 6.3 5.4
Paddy Rice: rice crops are the main agricultural production and continue to contribute
about 10 percent of total real growth during 2010-2012. Dry seasonal rice production increased
from 18.5 percent in 2003 to 23.3 percent in 2012 due to more access to irrigation systems. Rice
91
crops depend up to 80 percent on expanding cultivated areas, while only 20 percent on yield.
Yet, expansion of cultivated areas has decreased and is getting difficult due to land constraints.
The rice surplus was estimated at 4.7 million tons in 2012, most of which was exported
unprocessed and unrecorded given weak capacity and financing in milling (World Bank, 2013).
Livestock: Livestock business is common among rural families and local markets, and
thus constitutes one main source of income for the poor in many ways, especially as a form of
savings which can be readily turned into cash in case of emergency. Export of livestock,
including cattle, buffalos, pigs, and poultry, is expected to provide considerable opportunities,
expanding into regional markets and meeting increasing demand, particularly for cattle, in the
Middle East, in addition to limited exports to Malaysia (Ear, 2005). However, within the global
trade, where animal disease has been strictly controlled, meeting health standards is crucial,
which can be achieved by developing veterinary services and access to veterinary medicines.
Ear (2005) suggested that despite a relatively open trade condition for livestock, the cattle sector
of competitive prices for local demand for animal feed, and enhancement of the availability and
92
Fisheries: The fishery is also one of the main sources of livelihood of rural people
although the contribution of the sector to GDP has decreased from more than 13 percent during
the 1990s to about six percent in 2014, with annual exports of around 35,000 tons (NIS, 2015;
WTO Secretariat, 2011). Market expansion of this sector would provide better opportunities,
Domestic support was granted for agricultural products at Riel 8.62 billion and Riel 10
billion (approximate exchange rate US$1=Riel4,000) in 2007 and 2008, respectively. Over half
of the total support took the form of natural disaster relief and the remaining went to pest and
disease control, extension and advisory services, training services, research, and inspection
services (WTO Secretariat, 2011a). CTIS (MoC, 2014) has acknowledged that to enhance the
through formal channels, priorities should be given to two avenues: undertaking some degree
of processing inside the country, and increasing direct export to final markets. These will
domestic payments during transport and export procedures of the products should also be
deemed vital. Moreover, although increasing in value, agriculture has experienced slower
growth in the last few years, explained by depressed agricultural commodity prices and slow
yield improvements after 2013 (World Bank, 2015). Rice production and yield in the wet season
decreased by 2.5 percent and three percent respectively in 2014 from the previous year. While
production growth has depended to a large extent on cultivated area expansion, current land
constraints have become a concern. Agricultural output growth should from now on depend on
The sector achieved five percent growth on average from 2005 and had a nine-percent
share in total manufacturing output in 2014, as shown in Table 5.4. Exports remain low, but the
values have increased four-fold from US$76 million in 2010 to US$326 million in 2014,
93
accounting for three percent of total exports (UN Comtrade, 2016). Table 5.5 lists the share of
the main export items, which are milled rice, tobacco, sugar preparation, and animal and
vegetable oil. The milled rice surplus has increased gradually from 2000 as a result of paddy
production, at a nine percent annual growth rate (WTO, 2011). Milled rice exports, which
achieve a 28 percent increase year-on-year reaching 185 thousand metric tons during the first
six months of 2013, have benefited from the Everything-But-Arms initiative of the EU, the
main export partner (World Band, 2013). There is a difference between the quantities of
officially recorded exports by the Custom Department, however, and the exact figures due to
informal exports of unprocessed paddy rice and smuggling along the borders. To improve the
trade of the rice sector, the government in 2010 set the year 2015 as the target year to achieve
formal exports of milled rice of at least one million tons and to ensure the international
are essential tools to achieve this target, whereas public and private financing has moved to
agriculture and agriculture processing activities. Unfortunately, total milled rice exports at the
end of 2015 were almost 50 percent behind the target, which could be explained by the limited
Table 5.4: Manufacturing value added and contribution to GDP by sector (1995-2014)
Manufacturing 21.0 13.9 8.7 9.9 8.9 15.9 19.6 20.5 22.5
Food, Beverages & Tobacco 2.0 1.7 5.3 5.8 4.2 3.2 2.2 2.1 2.0 46.8 19.9 11.3 10.1 8.7
Textile,Wearing Apparel &
59.7 20.1 8.4 11.0 1.3 9.2 14.6 15.4 17.6 14.9 57.5 74.7 75.5 78.2
Footwear
Wood, Paper & Publishing 5.2 -5.8 5.5 4.4 1.1 0.9 0.4 0.4 0.4 12.9 5.9 2.1 1.9 1.6
Manufacture of Rubber 25.3 -5.5 8.3 11.0 0.3 0.5 0.2 0.3 0.3 2.8 3.1 1.2 1.2 1.3
Other Manufacturing 9.2 8.7 8.7 7.0 2.0 2.2 2.1 2.3 2.3 22.7 13.6 10.7 11.2 10.2
94
Table 5.5: Food-Beverage-Tobacco export by categories (2000-2014)
Product Categories 2000 2005 2010 2014
Total Agro-Food Exports (US$, Thousand) 8,482 22,130 76,201 326,908
Share in Total Exports (%) 0.61 0.73 1.36 3.06
Share in Agro-Food Exports by Categories (%)
Meat and meat preparations 0.01 0.81 0.03 0.02
Diary products 31.84 0.04 0.00 0.00
Fish products 23.80 41.14 2.64 0.04
Cereal preparations (exclude Rice) 0.43 0.26 0.26 0.07
Rice (milled, husked) 10.30 13.45 45.60 70.80
Vegetables and fruit 3.46 4.34 0.80 0.35
Sugars and Sugar preparations 0.00 0.05 6.75 10.66
Coffee, tea, cocoa, spices 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.00
Animal and vegetable oils and fats 0.00 3.48 13.17 4.94
Other animal and vegetable materials 0.13 0.00 0.00 0.07
Other food items 0.65 4.27 10.72 5.17
Beverage 3.85 3.69 4.86 2.48
Tobacco 25.51 28.44 15.18 5.39
Total 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00
The industrial development plan of the government of Cambodia also targets an increase
of agro-industrial exports from eight percent in 2015 to 12 percent in 2025 (RGC, 2015). The
opportunity of Cambodia to expand its processed food exports is viable given the increasing
demand for perishable food products in the world market, particularly in Asia where traditional
agricultural production has decreased in recent years. Cambodia should enlarge its export items
in this sectors because the agro-food industry—other than the milled rice sector—has received
little strategic attention, with the lack of domestic investment along the value chain. Moreover,
the industry is characterized by SMEs with emerging large firms both depend extensively on
domestic demand, while at an early stage breaking into the international market, whereas the
lack of compliance with quality standard of SPS and other measures is a key constraint. With
the challenges, encouraging investment and value addition, and improving the quality standards
should be a priority.
5.2.3. Rubber
Rubber plantation has soared significantly from 2007 and covered 328,771ha in 2013,
95
comprising rubber estates (former state-owned enterprises), economic land concession, and
household rubber plantation (MAFF, 2015). Figure 5.1 illustrates that the sector yielded 85,244
tons of dry rubber, with 86,052 tons of exports in 2013. Cambodia is a rubber exporting
country—almost all of the production are exported, and most of total exports are in the form of
natural rubber9 (MAFF, 2015, MoC, 2014). For example, 87 percent of formal natural rubber
exports in 2007 went to Vietnam which has suitable facility to process and re-export. However,
the figure has declined to 58 percent as exports to other markets, notably China and Malaysia,
have grown over the past five years due to significant investment efforts and expansion of the
production capacity. Notwithstanding, the remaining challenges, not different from that of other
agro-industrial products, are the difficulties in meeting international standards. Some other
constraints include high input and utility costs, limited finance and cash flow among producers
and processors, relatively low yield, excessive paperwork required for export, and low custom
clearance efficiency (WTO, 2011). The General Directorate of Rubber has been established to
prepare and implement policies and strategic programs to ensure development of this sector.
Source: Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fishery, 2014 and UN Comtrade, 2016
9 The figure may be underestimated due to significant quantities of natural rubber exported informally
across borders (MoC, 2014).
96
Literature Reviews
The roles of exports have been examined using different measures, such as the treatment
of exports as a factor of production in econometric models, the qualitative discussion, and the
Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) model (Ram, 1985; Tyler, 1981; Balassa, 1978;
Ganuza et al., 2005). The reviews of the potential impacts of sectoral export from previous
studies, therefore, should be divided into two parts: the non-CGE model (both qualitative and
empirical studies) and the CGE models. For the former, Tyler (1981) studied a cross-country
analysis from 1960 to 1977 by including exports as a factor input and found a strong association
In Cambodia’s case, a number of qualitative studies, on the one hand, proposed the
potential growth of agriculture and food sectors, following the efforts by the public and private
sectors, and the expected significant contributions of these sectors to growth and poverty
reduction. DTIS (MOC, 2007) suggested a list of 19 potential exports according to a number of
indicators based on their previous performance, one of which was their contributions to human
development 10 . The report indicated that garments and footwear rank high and medium,
respectively, in human development assessment, while most agricultural products rank from
low to medium. Nonetheless, the indicator could not quantify the prospective impacts of those
sectors. A firm-level survey, on the other hand, was conducted with 164 sample garment
companies to observe the roles of this export industry (Yamagata, 2006). The results confirmed
that the industry has contributed substantially to poverty reduction through job creation because
entry-level workers receive wages far above the poverty line, female workers predominate in
the main category jobs, and barriers to employment and promotion up to certain levels are not
high in terms of experience and education. The study, however, suggested that despite the fast
10
The summarized table of the indicators and rankings are given in Chapter 2, Table 2.7.
97
development led by labor-intensive industry, the government has lacked a strong industrial
promotion policy.
For the empirical literature, Chan and Oum (2011) studied the impacts of garment and
Similar to the above study, they found that the garment industry has contributed to above nine
percent on average of GDP growth between 1998 and 2008 and has helped reduce poverty due
to large-scale employment of rural labor. However, the paper concluded that despite its
expansion, the industry has not contributed to improving labor productivity and was not likely
to be sustainable in the medium to long term due to the severe competition with other garment
exporting countries. Similarly, applying the model of the Input-Output framework, but not
focusing on only the garment sector, Kobayashi et al. (2009) studied the industrial structure of
Cambodia as a whole and the role of agriculture by estimating sectoral gross output and value
added. They found that agriculture and the food sector had a tendency to induce high and wide
distribution of income. Nevertheless, the focus on export impacts of those sectors was not
Different measures can examine the impacts of exports on growth and other economic
factors as discussed in the above literature; however, what channels the contribution may go
through are not explicitly identified. General equilibrium approach, therefore, has been
introduced as an alternative method for country-focus studies since this approach is able to
capture the full effects on both macro- and micro-levels—changes at the economy-wide level
to resulting impacts on distribution of income (Ganuza et al., 2005). Existing research utilizing
the CGE model centers on the impacts of export orientation in general and on specific export
sectors in particular. For instance, studies of different Latin American countries—Costa Rica,
Bolivia, and Cuba—have been carried out to observe the impacts of export promotion on
growth and poverty, using the CGE model (Ferriol et al., 2006; Jiménez, 2007; Sánchez &
98
Sauma, 2006). The analysis of each country examined macroeconomic performance along with
export performance, how economic reform effects export and vice versa, by dividing export
products into different principal groups, in which both macroeconomic effects and policy
alternatives are explored through counterfactual analysis. Some of the common simulations of
the former effects include the changes in terms of trade and export demand quantity, and of the
The study of Costa Rica by Sánchez and Sauma (2006), for example, showed that the
deceleration of growth in recent years is related to the fall in exports and that the growth during
the previous decade is explained mainly by the increase in exports, especially non-traditional
trade; however, the results of the simulations revealed that the impacts, including the
distribution are ambiguous (reduced poverty but also increased inequality). Meanwhile, Cuba’s
case captured the supply side by taking into account the government’s active role in
supply than demand (Ferriol et al., 2006). Therefore, the need to increase supply, either quantity
Other studies took into account the impact of specific sectors. Banse et al. (2007)
the European Union (divided into old and new member states), applying a regional CGE model.
The food industrial harmonization and technological change simulations resulted in a limited
development, in general, such as increase in production and trade, and an improved productivity
and market integration of this sector, and on agriculture income in particular. In a broader sense
industrialization (ADLI), and (3) primary sector export-oriented strategy of the Mozambican
economy, Tarp and Tarp (2004) ran experiments to see how productivity and marketing margin
99
impacted the three strategies. The result suggested that agricultural development benefited both
agricultural and non-agricultural households, but did not reduce poverty of the rural poor, while
more income/welfare reached the rural poor in the ADLI scenario. The last strategy, on the
other hand, achieved pro-equity with limited impacts on the economy in the short to medium
Kobayashi et al. (2008) studied the economic structure and poverty reduction of
Cambodia based on the CGE model and analyzed the causes of household income gap. They
suggested that the difference in growth rate between the fishery and service sectors is one cause
of the income conflict among groups, while agricultural and food exports induce growth with
better income distribution. Meanwhile, their simulation results also revealed that for a more
efficient pro-poor growth in Cambodia, preferential treatment for food manufacturing and
textiles (categorized as light industries) is preferable. While the study discussed the economic
structure as a whole, export structure and promotion policy of strategic export sectors were not
With a limited number of empirical sectoral export impact studies, most of which take
into account the garment sector, the focus on agriculture, food and the rubber sector has been
rare despite the recognition of their potential distribution. To fill this gap, the current study aims
at analyzing the export potential roles of these three sectors: food and rubber as agro-industrial
sectors and agriculture by employing the CGE model, taking into consideration the impacts on
CGE models are used extensively in policy analysis as they capture linkages at different
levels, including sectoral levels of production structure and trade, factor levels of employment
of labor and capital, household levels of income and consumption, as well as economy-wide
changes or shocks (Hosoe, Gasawa, & Hashimoto, 2010; Vos, 2007). Producers and consumers
100
(households, government, and firms) interact through product and factor markets, buying and
selling goods and services. The CGE model applied in the study is based on the standard one-
country one-period 1-1 model of the PEP (Partnership for Economic Policy Networks),
developed by Decaluwe et al. (2013). The model captures the production and market activities
Production
At the top level of output, production technology follows Leontief production function
between different intermediates and between intermediate and production factors. Each
industry combines value added and intermediate inputs in fixed shares, strictly complementary,
without substitutability, following Leontief production function. At the second level, value
added bundle consists of composite labor and capital, which are imperfect substitutable,
101
1
VA LDC j 1 VA KDC j
VA VA
jVA
VA j B
VA
(5-1)
j j j j j
where j represents each industry, VA is value added, LDC and KDC are demand for composite
labor and capital, BVA , βVA ,and ρVA are scale, share and elasticity parameter of CES value
added.
Composite labor also follows CES function. Producers are assumed to operate in a
technology which describes how industries use inputs to produce aggregate outputs. Firms will
employ labor and capital to the point where the value marginal product of each is equal to its
price (wage rate for labor and rental rate for capital). Such function is described by the demand
for labor relative to the demand for capital. Similarly, given imperfect substitutability between
different types of labor, the firms minimizes labor costs by choosing their labor composition in
response to relative wage rates11. For the intermediate input side, intermediate consumption is
made up of domestic and imported goods and services and assumed to be perfectly
The supplies of production outputs are distributed into domestic and foreign markets
producers decide the amount of output among different products based on revenue
maximization hypothesis, given product prices. Second, the output is shared out among
markets, either domestic or export, again to maximize sale revenues, in response to demand in
XS j,i B EX j,i 1
j,i
DS j,i
X X
X X X j,i
X
(5-2)
j,i j,i j,i j,i
11
The same behavior is also applied to composite capital if there are different categories of capital
(land, machinery, etc.). However, there is only one type of capital in this study.
102
where XS is industry j production of commodity i, DS is supply of commodity i to the domestic
market, EX is export supply to foreign market, BX , βX ,and ρX are scale, share and elasticity
Trade-focused CGE specifies export supply as CET function, as it assumes that although
industries can reorganize production to change the proportion of goods between export and
domestic sales (DS), the products for different markets are not perfectly transformable, and thus
the CET function describes how the proportion can be adjusted based on price changes (export
price, PE and local price, PL) of commodity i, as depicted in the export supply equation (5-3)
(EXj,i). As for the export demand (equation (5-4): EXDi), the model adopts the small-country
hypothesis which infers that world export and import prices are exogenous. In spite of this, the
model assumes that producers cannot always sell as much as they want on the world market;
instead, domestic producers can increase their share of the world market only by offering a f.o.b
price (PEiFOB) that is advantageous relative to the world export price (PWXi). To what extend
the share can be increased depends on the degree of substitutability of the specific product (price
elasticity of export demand σiXD). Export supply and export demand are depicted in equations
below.
j,i
X
1 j,iX PE
EX j,i X i
DS j,i (5-3)
j,i PLi
iXD
ePWXi
EXDi EXDiO FOB
(5-4)
PEi
The model also assumes imperfect substitutability between imported and domestically-
produced goods, differentiated by origins, which specifies import demand following Armington
function (Ducaluwe et al., 2013; Ganuza et al., 2005). In other words, the imperfect
substitutability between import demand (shown in the equation (5-5), IMi) and demand for
domestic goods (DDi) is represented by CES (σiM ). The PEP model assumes the price elasticity
103
of import supply is infinite at the going world price, implying by the exogenous world import
price.
iM
M PDi
IMi i M DDi (5-5)
1 i PM i
Household income, YHh = YHlh + YHKh + YHTRh, comes from labor income (YHlh)
and capital income (YHKh), as factor payment, and transfers from other agents (YHTRh). After
paying taxes, transferring to government, and savings, disposable income is entirely dedicated
consumption demand follows a linear expenditure system for utility maximization subject to
income.
Government collects taxes as a source of revenues, such as income taxes (TDHT), production
taxes (TPRODN), and taxes on products, imports and exports (TPRCTS), provided that the
PEP-1-1 model takes into account a variety of tax instruments. In addition, government receives
transfers from other agents (YGTR) and remuneration of capital (YGK). Similar to household
savings, income taxes are considered as a linear function of total income. The model also
distinguishes tax rates by industry and by type of labor and capital. On the other hand,
government expenditures consist of transfer payments to other agents and current expenditure
on goods and services. The difference between its revenues and it expenditures is the current
Rest of the world: The rest of the world, the last agent in the model 12, receives income
from import payment, capital income, and transfers from domestic agents, while making foreign
spending to the domestic economy through the values of exports and transfers to domestic
12
Business is another agent in the PEP-1-1 model, but it is not characterized in the current study.
104
agents. The amount of rest of the world savings is the difference between foreign receipts and
spending, which are exactly equal to the current account balance of domestic economy but of
social programs so they are treated in the same way as income taxes. Meanwhile, transfers from
that transfers are not explicitly associated with a specific form of economic behavior in CGE
model due to the lack of precise information of the transactions, so they should be treated in the
Demand
public sector demand, and demand as transport and trade margins, all of which cover domestic
which is specified by
LES MIN
PCi Ci,h PCi Ci,h i,h CTH h PCijCij,h
MIN
(5-6)
ij
budget (CTHh). Since this assumption imposes neither zero cross-price elasticity nor unit
income-elasticity for all goods, it offers a flexibility of substitution in response to relative price
changes.
Demand for investment includes gross fixed capital formation (GFCF) and inventory
changes. The former is always positive and endogenous in this PEP model, while the latter can
105
be either positive or negative in the SAM and is usually treated as exogenous in CGE models.
endogenous. GFCF equals to the difference between total investment expenditure and the cost
of inventory changes, and is distributed in fixed shares among commodities, given by cobb-
Douglas production function. Therefore, the investment demand for each commodity is
Government consumption on goods and services follows the same hypothesis in the way
that, given current expenditure budget, quantity demand for each commodity is distributed in
Margin rates are applied to the volume of domestic production and imports which
require transport and trade services. The amount determines margin services required to move
and distribute commodities to the market. Finally, in addition to the final demand, goods and
services are used as intermediate inputs in the production. Intermediate demand for each
Price
prices of its components, in which the weights are determined by equating the value of the
aggregate to the sum of the values of its components, given the quantity of the aggregate. The
weight assigned the price of each component is the ratio of its volume to the volume of the
aggregate. In Leontief case (fixed-proportion aggregate), the weights do not change in response
to relative price changes while they do in other cases, depending on the elasticity of
substitutability and transformation. The unit cost of an industry’s output is therefore a weighted
sum of the value added prices and aggregate intermediate prices, as described by
106
The value accounting identity is therefore
The prices of other aggregates follows the same principle. For instance, the aggregate
intermediate price is a combination of the commodity prices of the industry’s intermediate, and
value added price is a combination of the prices of composite labor and capital used in the
production.
Price of international trade: Since exporting industries can sell their outputs in both
international and domestic market, the price of their aggregate production is a weighted sun of
the price obtained in each market. The weights change in relation to variation in relative price,
following CET function. The basic price (Pj,i) received by industry j is a weighted sum of its
basic price on the domestic market and on the export market, while the FOB price, include
margins (tmrgXij,i) and export taxes (ttixi), paid by purchasers on the export market is different
from the price obtained by producers. The basic price and the FOB price are given by the
following equations:
X
PE i PCij tmrg ij,i 1 ttix i
FOB
PE i (5-10)
ij
On the domestic market, the price of the composite commodities is a weighted sum of
the price paid for domestically produced goods and imported goods. The former is the sum of
the price obtained by producers, indirect taxes and margins, whereas the latter is the world price
in terms of the local currency, combined with import taxes and duties, indirect taxes and
margins.
107
There are four types of GDP in the model.
GDP at basic price is equal to payments made to value added and taxes on production other
GDP at market price is equal to GDP at basic price plus amount of taxes in products and
imports.
3. GDPFD = ∑i PCi [∑h Ci,h + CGi + INVi + VSTKi] + ∑i PEiFOB EXDi – e ∑i PWMi IMi: (5-13)
GDP at market price from the final demand perspective is the total of net final demand
GDP at market price from the income perspective is the total income of labor and capital,
The social accounting matrix (SAM) presents the system of national accounts of an
economy at a particular period and summarizes the structure of both internal and external
connections and the roles of different actors: industry, household, government and rest of the
world (Burfisher, 2011; Vos, 2007). Each entry traces the circular flow of income and payments
of all economic activities, including production, factor inputs, institutions and commodity
demand, and international trade. Since the income-expenditure accounts of each agent of
corresponding row and column must balance—the total income from all sources must be equal
to the total expenditure—SAM must balance exactly and, thus, must be a square matrix.
Although SAMs are commonly built for specific counties, they may be applied at different
108
With a few modifications, the study uses the Cambodian aggregated SAM, adopted
from Heng et al. (2014) published in the Partnership for Economic Policy Research Network
(PEP). The SAM were built following the structure of ADB’s Supply-Use Table and based on
various sources of survey data, including the National Account, Government Budget, Customs
Tariff, Balance of Payment, and Household Survey. The structure of Cambodia’s Macro SAM
is shown in Table 5.6. The final balanced SAM follows the format of SAM sample of PEP to
fit with the GAMS code of PEP 1-1 model. The number of activities, factor inputs, agents and
household types of the final SAM applied in the current study are listed below:
- Factors: one type of capital, three types of labor: low-skilled, medium-skilled, and igh-
skilled
- Households: six categories (according to living areas and living standard levels): Other
urban poor (UP), Other urban non-poor (UNP), Rural poor (RP), Rural non-poor (RNP),
109
Table 5.7: Industries and Commodities in the Cambodia’s SAM, 2011
No. Activities No. Commodities
1 AGR Agriculture 1 AGR Agriculture
2 FBT Manufacture of Food Products, Beverages, and Tobacco 2 FBT Food, Beverages, and Tobacco
3 TEXTILE Manufacture of Textiles, Wearing Apparel, and Footwear 3 TEXTILE Clothing and Wearing Apparel; and Leather and Leather Products
Manufacture of Wood, Wood Products, Paper, and Paper
4 WP 4 WP Products of Wood, Paper, and Paper Products
Products
5 RP Manufacture of Rubber and Plastic Products 5 RP Rubber and Plastics Products
6 METAL Manufacture of Basic Metals 6 METALBasic Metals
7 FMETAL Manufacture of Fabricated Metal Products; and Office and 7 FMETAL
Fabricated Metal Products, Except Machinery and Equipment
Computing Machinery 8 MACHINE
General and Special Purpose Machinery
9 OFFICE
Office, Accounting, and Computing Machinery
8 MOTORT Manufacture of Motor Vehicles and Other Transport Equipment 10 TRANSTransport Equipment
9 OTHMNU Other Manufacturing 11 OTHMNU
Other Manufacturing
12 CHEM Basic Chemicals and Other Chemicals
13 FURN Furniture and Other Transportable Goods, n.e.c.
Coal and Lignite, Peat, Crude Petroleum and Natural Gas; Other
10 MEGW Mining and Quarrying, Electricity, Gas, and Water Supply 14 MEGW
Minerals; Electricity, Gas and Water
11 CON Construction 15 CON Construction Services
12 WTT Wholesale,Retail Trade, and Transport Service 16 WTT Wholesale,Retail Trade, and Transport Service
13 HR Hotels and Restaurants 17 HR Lodging, Food, and Beverage Serving Services
Financial Intermediation-Insurance, Real Estate-Business Financial Intermediation and Insurance; Real Estate and Business
14 FBUS 18 FBUS
Services, Post and Telecommmunication Services; Post and Telecommmunication
15 AEH Public Administration and Defense, Education, Health and Social 19 ADM Public Administration and Compulsory Social Security Services
Work 20 EDU Education Services
21 HEALTH Health and Social Services
16 OTHSER Other Community Service Activities 22 OTHSER Other Services, n.e.c.
Table 5.8 shows the basic structural features of the Cambodian economy, including
share of production, domestic demand, international trade by commodity level, and value added
and factor inputs by industry level, at the base scenario of the SAM, 2011. Agriculture and
textiles account for the highest share in production, at 22 and 21 percent respectively, followed
wholesales-retail trade and transportation (WTT) has the highest output share (15 percent)
Machinery, office and transport equipment share the smallest production output. Agriculture,
WTT, CON, FBUS and FBT are also the top sectors sharing the highest domestic demand for
commodities produced locally, which also means they are less dependent on import
requirements to satisfy domestic demand. The figures, however, infer that any changes
110
occurring in these sectors would induce high impacts on total domestic production. The table
also shows export and import share in total values. Textiles alone account for 67 percent of total
exports, given the advantage of duty-free access to the EU and US markets. The next main
export sectors are in services, particularly hotel-restaurant and WTT. On the other hand,
Cambodia imports a significant amount of textiles and chemicals for both intermediate and
consumer goods, whereas high imports of other manufacturing (OTHMNU) are mainly
consumer goods such as electrical equipment and household appliances. The three sectors
For the export and import intensity, defined by export share in total production and
import share in total composite demand, textiles and office and machinery have high shares in
both export and import intensity, which reveals that these commodities are highly export
oriented, and that the foreign market plays a greater role for these industries while the domestic
market is mostly satisfied by imported goods. For these sectors, domestically produced goods
for domestic consumption are far behind the level to cover self-sufficiency. In contrast, hotel-
111
restaurant has the export intensity of 71 percent, showing the importance of this service,
especially in the tourism sector, yet with less dependence on imports for domestic consumption.
It should be noted that food-beverage-tobacco, rubber, and agriculture account for a small share
Finally, the shares of employment in total labor force vary widely between sectors,
ranging from the highest in Agriculture (48%), WTT (18%) and Textiles (6%), to the lowest in
MOTORT (0.1%) and METAL (0.4%). Each of the remaining industrial sectors, except CON
and FBT, employs less than one percent of total labor, while the rest of services share an average
sectors and not widely spread throughout the economy. Having a look at the division of labor
by skill would show a clearer industrial employment pattern. Most of the industrial sectors are
low-skilled intensive, which can be common in low-income countries, while most service
sectors, except HR and WTT, employ a larger share of high-skilled labor. However, those
services are still at a low level in their contribution to both production and exports.
To make it fit with the purpose of the analysis, the study modifies the household
account, which was previously categorized by 24 provinces, into six new categories according
to urbanization and living standard level, by generating the data of both income and expenditure
of each group from the Cambodia Socio-Economic Survey dataset (CSES, 2009). This new
household account contributes to the originality of the SAM applied in this study. The
households receive income from different sources: labor income, capital income, government
transfers, and transfers from rest of the world, each of which can be generated from the
household survey (CSES, 2009). Nonetheless, the estimation needs to be done through a
number of processes.
First, labor income is categorized by sectors and skill levels, of which years of
educational attainment is assumed to determine skill levels: low-skilled (up to grade 5),
112
medium-skilled (grades 6 to 10), and high-skilled (grade 11 and above). Second, labor income
should take into account both formal employees and self-employed workers in both primary
and secondary occupations because it is common that one person may have more than one jobs
at a time (one full-time and one part-time job) due to the low wage level in Cambodia; however,
the household survey records only the wage of employees and only the wage of their primary
jobs. To avoid underestimation of labor income, average earnings per hour of employees by
sectors and by skill level is calculated, and it is assumed that the self-employed, as well as all
workers taking secondary jobs, receive the same average wage as employees’ primary job in
the same sectors. The total income of all the groups of workers can then be calculated by
Third, this income data is differentiated by living areas (Phnom Penh, other urban, and
rural) and by living standard level (poor and non-poor), identified based on daily expenditure
following the poverty line definition by the Ministry of Planning (NIS, 2013). The same
113
Finally, shares of each category of the income sources are incorporated into the SAM by
utilizing the original table serving as control totals, as shown in Table 5.9.
The estimation is also done for the household expenditure on different items:
commodities, direct taxes, transfers to rest of the world, and saving/investment. The former
three are generated from recorded household spending on food and non-food consumptions, in
which the commodities are mapped using the corresponding table of ISIC rev.4 (applied in the
CSES) with the CPC rev.1.1 (applied in the SAM), while saving account is a residual between
The analysis follows the framework summarized in Figure 5.3. At the industry level,
the move toward export orientation is captured through the connection between foreign market
(export and import) and domestic commodity market, both links to the factor market through
industrial activities. Industries consume intermediate and factor inputs, while prices determine
114
how much production is needed. The change in production causes a change in demand for those
inputs. Industries pay factor costs to labor and capital in the factor market. At the household
level, households receive income from factor payment and consume commodities in the product
Another important account is the government, which interacts with others through
various transactions. For instance, the government receives taxes from and provides transfer
payments to households, and also spends on consumption and investment. In addition, the
government may operate some complementary policies in the factor market, such as the change
in wage policy and initiative of a special training scheme to increase productivity. More
importantly, the government is expected to play a vital role to promote the export orientation
of selected industries through various preferential policy measures, including tax/subsidy and
tariff implementation. The transactions will finally determine impacts on supplies and demand
measures household welfare through the Equivalent Variation (EV) in percentage of initial
income which estimates the differences between household minimum consumption budget and
total consumption budget available after each simulation. A higher EV represents a larger
Typical CGE models, as well as the standard PEP model, usually determine a fixed
supply of factors (capital and labor) while wages/rental rates adjust to clear the market with full
employment to achieve demand-supply equilibrium. However, to be more realistic and for the
short-run framework, the model can specify unemployment cases which are common in
developing countries (Burfisher, 2011; Vos, 2007). For instance, Sanchez and Sauma (2005)
assumed that there could be unemployment in various labor market segments in the Costa Rica
general equilibrium framework while fixing real wage and allowing labor supply to clear the
labor market. Therefore, to capture the labor market characteristic of Cambodia's economy, the
115
study assumes an unemployment labor market by introducing an unemployment variable while
keeping labor supply exogenous and wage endogenous, instead of assuming unlimited labor
supply. Following the theoretical framework of wage curve by Blanchflower & Oswald (1994),
a relationship between the wage rate and local unemployment rate can be described by:
Wl a l Ul l (5-15)
where:
changes in labor demand. This modification in the model contributes to the originality of the
current study.
For the model to project the economic outcomes, the study determines a set of macro
- Capital is immobile across sector, which means that capital is sector-specific and in full
employment
- Labor is assumed mobile across sectors. Labor in the economy is not fully employment,
- The saving rate is fixed and saving adjusts to ensure macroeconomic equilibrium
(saving-investment driven)
- World export price and world import price are exogenous (small country hypothesis)
116
- Nominal exchange rate acts as a numeraire.
To capture the full impacts of export sectors, the study performs a series of simulations
divided into three main exercises: external shocks, internal shocks, and domestic policies, each
with a set of scenario, summarized in Table 5.10. Since the study focuses on three potential
export sectors, the simulations will take into account mainly the changes that occur in those
agriculture. The first exercise focuses on the changes in world trade pattern, including two sets
of scenarios—world export demand and terms of trade shocks—each of which covers two
simulations. Scenario 1 assumes a US$10 million increase in export demand for food and rubber
products (simulation 1A), and for agricultural commodities (simulation 1B). This assumption
6C. 6A + 5B
117
owes to the prediction that world demand for these products is going to increase, specifically
for the ready-made processed food in Asia with a growing population and more households
medium and high technological industrial production while reducing their supply dependence
on agriculture and agro-processing products (food and rubber). The integration expansion in
the ASEAN Economic Community and recent cooperation with China as export partner would
Scenario 2 assumes a deterioration in the terms of trade, particularly the decrease in the
export price of textiles in simulation 2A, which reflects the current trade pattern of Cambodia
with high export dependency on the garment sector. World export price of garment products is
assumed to decline due to the increase of global competitiveness within the industry resulting
from lower labor costs in other major garment exporting countries such as Bangladesh and
Myanmar. This simulation, therefore, would reveal the impacts on the domestic economy while
Cambodia is expected to depend highly on garment exports in the next several years. Simulation
2B, on the other hand, assumes a lower world export price of food and rubber to assess the
impacts of the price shocks should the country achieve its diversification toward agro-
processing exports. The decrease in price could happen due to the price fluctuation of the
primary agricultural inputs, particularly during the harvesting period and production surplus
season, the change in other input prices such as the decrease in world fuel price which lower
The third set of scenarios assumes upward movement of labor productivity across-the-
board in all the sectors (simulation 3A) and the same movement but only of low-skilled and
medium-skilled labor in the selected sectors (simulation 3B) 15 . The increase in labor
simulations also compare skill intensity between trade and non-trade sectors. Skill intensity
15
Scenario 3 assumes labor market equilibrium (labor supply equals to labor demand).
118
refers to which types of labor (low-skilled, medium-skilled or high-skilled) are more in demand
proportionately in the production of different goods. The demand may rise or fall as a result of
the simulations depending on the types of labor that are more important in the targeted sectors.
Are agriculture, the food industry and rubber production more skill intensive? This question
can be addressed by examining what happens to labor demand when there is supply disturbance,
following the first set of scenario. In addition, capital used in production can also reveal
economic structure changes. The decrease capital endowment in the current large export sector,
textiles (simulation 4A), replaced by an increase in capital demand in food, rubber manufacture
and agriculture (simulation 4B) is also tested in scenario 4 to reveal what happens if capital
The last exercise discusses alternative export promotion policies that can be initiated by
the government. The promotion policies considered in the study are divided into three parts:
production subsidies, export subsidies and tariffs. Production subsidies (simulation 5A) can be
seen as a significant incentive for the targeted sectors to attract both local and foreign
investment, which can be provided in the form of tax exemption on value added, or on the
import of capital used as production input. While the food and rubber industries are covered
largely by SMEs and small-farm holders, it is important to attract larger firms and FDI to bring
along new technology, which does not only boost innovation and skill improvement through
spillover effects but also increase higher levels of processing before exporting to reduce
unprocessed or informal exports. Moreover, the lack of quality standards requires Cambodia to
invite FDIs that are more capable of complying with those criteria. Next, the increase of export
subsidies on the three targeted sectors (simulation 5B) is deemed crucial to have more direct
impacts on promoting exports. A more aggressive policy can also be carried out by combining
Scenario 6, on the other hand, covers the protectionism which imposes a higher import
tariffs on products to protect potential industries. Although this policy would not directly
119
generate increased exports, it is seen as a road toward industrialization to encourage domestic
industries with the high potential to grow—through protection against imports (Todaro &
Smith, 2009). The three selected sectors might not be new in the Cambodian production chain,
yet food and rubber are still at a stage where production and competitiveness levels are low and
highly vulnerable to domestic demand changes, whereas agriculture faces the challenges of the
lower price of imported produce which critically demotivate farmers and investors. For these
reasons, the three sectors, to some extent, deserve protection policy. Only with protectionism
do local producers have the incentive to upgrade production, whereas more investments can be
encouraged. The increased tariff is expected to increase the government budget with the
assumes an increase in tariff with a decrease in indirect tax to compensate for the fall in private
consumption. A more direct policy in simulation 6C is to combine a higher tariffs with export
subsidies which, on one hand, encourage local production for export rather than for the domestic
market, and, on the other hand, would not diminish the government budget.
The results from the three exercises are expected to point out the roles of the promising
sectors and the economic policy measures that can be feasible to promote export orientation.
Favorable impacts of the potential sectors on the domestic economy and employment as a result
of diversification and efficiency are desirable; however, this should not be achieved with the
high expense of household income and welfare. The interpretation of the results, therefore,
focuses on the following measures: 1) macro effects, which include real GDP and investment,
government income and consumption; 2) sectoral and employment effects, particularly exports,
imports, outputs, value added and labor demand (by sector and by skill group); and 3) household
120
Demand Shocks
The increase in export demand in the first scenario would result in an increase in GDP,
total investment, total exports, and production. Illustrated in Figure 5.4, the increase in food
and rubber exports (sim 1A) induce higher, albeit small, impacts on most of the variables
compared to the rise in agriculture exports (sim 1B) although they follow similar trends. Real
GDP would rise by US$101 million and total investment by US$38 million in simulation 1A
as opposed to US$76 million and US$22 million respectively in simulation 1B, whereas
aggregate output is one-half higher in the former compared to the latter simulation. Government
income and savings see enormous progress, which can be explained by the increase in revenue
from tax and tariff as a result of higher export supply and import demand, with bigger impacts
on imports, in both exercises. Public consumption, in contrast, faces negative impacts due to a
rise in the price index, with higher impacts in simulation 1A. However, the increase in price
does not adversely affect private consumption; instead, it surges by 0.67 and 0.58 percent in the
two exercises respectively, whereas household welfare is better off, with the highest impact on
Figure 5.4: Simulation results of Export demand shocks (% change from base data)
ExpDemFoodRubber (sim 1A)
-0.4
Total LSK MSK HSK Average RP UP UNP RNP PPP PPNP
0.6
Macro effects Employment effects Welfare effects
0.67 0.68
0.4 0.60
0.55 0.54
0.51
0.2 0.43
0.32 0.26 0.29
0.0 0.21
-0.2
Total LSK MSK HSK Average RP UP UNP RNP PPP PPNP
121
rural households, due to the significant increase in household income, especially the income
from labor as a result of wage increase. Also, income propensity to agriculture and food product
consumption can be higher among rural groups than their urban/city peers.
Higher production to meet the increase in exports requires more labor, leading to an
increase in employment by 0.64 percent in sim 1A and 0.55 percent in sim 1B, with positive
impacts on all of the skill groups, yet low-skilled labor sees higher demand due to the low-skill
intensity in agriculture and agro-related industry. It should be noted that the increase in labor
demand does not happen only in the simulated industries but also in almost all other industries
due to the flow-on effect of production. This effect means that the three targeted industries
highly connect to the rest of the economy in indirect labor demand. Another purpose of carrying
out the simulations in set 1 is to assess the level of linkages of export sectors with the rest of
the economy. The results suggest that the linkage between agriculture exports and the remaining
industries is, in fact, lower than those of agro-manufacturing. 0.18 percent of intermediate
demand is needed to achieve US$10 million agriculture export acceleration, while the same
amount of export increase in food and rubber products would consume an additional 0.42
in the terms of trade, with more severe impacts caused by the lower export price of textiles in
sim 2A than that of the lower export price of food and rubber industrial goods in sim 2B. GDP
and total investment drop by six percent and seven percent in the former against a 0.06 percent
fall in the latter, which can be explained by the relatively smaller share of the food and rubber
sectors in the economy. The lower price of textiles in the external market reduces domestic
aggregate output and value added by about 3.00 percent, with the most impact (8.00 percent
decline) on the textile industry itself, as opposed to a less than 0.05 percent decline in both
variables if there is a decrease in world price of food and rubber products. Total export reduction
122
in both simulations, with the latter seeing the smaller impact, suggests that effects of the export
price decrement of agro-industry would not be as severe as that of the garment industry, given
World price shocks would induce producers to switch their export supplies to domestic
sales following constant elasticity of transformation, which in turn results in a fall in domestic
price; thus, domestic goods become more competitive than imported goods. Import demand
decline leads to a reduction in government income from taxation. Regardless of a larger fall in
price index in sim 2A, households are not in any way better off due to a large drop in wage and
income, since a significant number of workers would lose their jobs, especially the low-skilled
and medium-skilled who were previously employed in the garment sector. To be precise, the
labor force in textiles will decrease by almost 30 percent when there is an export price shock
within the textile industry (sim 2A). However, the effects would be less than one percent when
there is an export price shock in both agro-food and the rubber industry at the same time (sim
2B).
Figure 5.5: Simulation results of terms of trade shocks (% change from base)
TotText (sim 2A)
Macro effects Employment effects Welfare effects
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-2.55
-8
-3.80 -3.48
-4.23 -4.44 -4.22 -4.16
-5.56 -5.85 -6.06 -6.55
Total LSK MSK HSK Average RP UP UNP RNP PPP PPNP
TotFoodRubber(sim 2B)
Macro effects Employment effects Welfare effects
0.02
0
-0.02
-0.04
-0.02
-0.06 -0.03
-0.03 -0.04
-0.08
-0.05
-0.05 -0.06
-0.06 -0.06
-0.07 -0.07
Total LSK MSK HSK Average RP UP UNP RNP PPP PPNP
Source: Author
123
It can be seen from the results that the effects of the fall in textile export price alone, all
other prices constant, would be more consequential than those of the declining agro-product
prices, shown in Figure 5.5. This result reflects the high concentration on garment exports of
Cambodia’s current trade pattern, in which the external price shock is extremely vulnerable for
the domestic economy. As an experience, garment exports, which accounted for 77 percent of
total exports in 2008, dropped by 20 percent, whereas total exports declined by four percent
from 2008 to 2009 as a result of the global financial crisis, compared to a 13 percent growth on
average three years earlier (UNCTAD, 2014). This consequence points out the impacts of one
short-term external shock due to the high dependency on garments as the main export sector,
as well as due to relatively higher price elasticity of demand for these products. The possible
how exports and imports react—which sectors are likely to lead to output and employment
generation—and whether the impacts will favor labor-intensive sectors (Ha & Swales, 2012).
In particular, the productivity scenario in the study attempts to measure linkage between the
targeted export sectors and employment, and their skill-type intensity (Figure 5.6). The increase
strongly positive for GDP, income, and trade in particular, with the growth of exports higher
than the growth of imports. The results of both sim 3A and 3B share a similar tendency, but
with different impact sizes. Total exports surge more significantly in sim 3A. Nonetheless, it is
interesting to note that at the sectoral level, the changes in agriculture and food exports in both
simulations do not diverge, with both accelerate within the range of 12.40 and 11.10 percent
for agriculture and 10.91 and 9.08 percent for food industrial products. It can be inferred that
124
these two sectors are more low- and medium-skilled intensive as the similar effects would
happen with the increase in productivity of either all the skill groups or only the specified low-
and medium-skilled groups. This finding is consistent with the results from the earlier scenarios
which also show that the targeted sectors are low-skilled and medium-skilled intensive, proving
-4
Average RP UP UNP RNP PPP PPNP
-8
-4
Average RP UP UNP RNP PPP PPNP
-6
Source: Author
The rise in outputs would significantly lower consumer prices and raise consumption of
both public and household agents. Higher labor productivity is accompanied by the surge in
real wages, of which high-skilled labor sees the largest impact at 8.14 percent compared to 4.35
and 0.57 for the medium- and low-skilled in sim 3A, and 5.32, 3.03, and 1.02 percent for the
three skilled groups in sim 3B. A few reasons can explain these different changes in real wages.
For one thing, wages of low-skilled labor are relatively less rigid to adjust to the labor market
given a more flexible movement of this group between sectors as they are more likely to be
employed within the informal job-contract system. Also, as opposed to their counterparts, those
125
low-skilled workers are more easily substituted with capital, which is also the reason why rates
The primary purpose of running these two simulations is to compare how the growth in
labor productivity across-the-board differs from that for only low-skilled and medium-skilled
labor in the three potential sectors. Although the impacts are more marginal in the former
simulation, the latter happens to generate higher impacts on a few main indicators. For instance,
real GDP improves by US$269 million in the former, but US$340 million in the latter
simulation. Similar effects can be seen at the household level, where household consumption
soars by 2.82 and household income by 2.50 percent in sim 3A, versus 2.93 and 2.78 percent
for the same variables in sim 3B (Figure 5.6). These suggest that households would benefit
more if the productivity attainment focuses more on the specified low- and medium-skilled
groups in the specified sectors rather than otherwise on unspecific targets. A more positive
result could happen if the improvement in labor productivity is combined with an increase in
export demand for the potential sectors. Interestingly, household welfare variations in both
simulations intertwine, with more influence on other-urban-poor and rural groups, implying
that scaling up productivity can be a valuable tool if the target is to raise the welfare of the rural
and urban-poor households. It is worth noting that the estimated labor productivity in reality
grew by 5.1 percent as an annual average during 2005-2013 (APO, 2015). This figure needs to
be significantly increased in order for the economy to capture the benefits that the productivity
generates.
production. A reduction of capital stock in textiles (sim 4A), assumed as a shrinking industry
due to lower competitiveness in the world market as well as the need for diversification toward
other exporting sectors, generates an increase in real GDP, private consumption and labor
income as a result of improved wage rates, particularly for low- and medium-skilled labor, due
126
to an increase in labor demand (0.55 percent) to substitute for the drop-off in capital. However,
exports and aggregate outputs fall. It is expected that in the long run, with the full adjustment
of factors, the impacts on exports and output would be less intense. For this reason, this exercise
also hypothesizes progress in capital stock in food and rubber industrial manufacturing and
agriculture (simulation 4B), assuming a more intensive and/or more efficient consumption of
capital in the promising sectors. The results mirror those of the previous simulation, with an
increase in aggregate outputs and value added (0.51 percent) leading to more demand for
intermediate inputs, and higher exports particularly in the three sectors, which accelerate by
3.49, 1.37 and 1.95 percent for food, rubber, and agriculture, respectively. Real GDP soars by
0.63 percent, which is about twice as much as in the previous simulation. Government income
and consumption also see positive changes, which can be explained by the increase in revenue
Nevertheless, labor demand in the three sectors declines, especially for the low-skilled
group due to the substitution effects of capital employment; yet the fall of labor demand in total
is smaller than that in the three sectors on average because some workers can move to other
sectors, whereas real wages surge. Both simulations induce upward movement in both
household consumption and welfare, which illustrates that a combination of these two
Subsidizing Policies
In the domestic policy shocks, four sets of scenarios are simulated. The first two assume
the increase in production subsidies (sim 5A) and export subsidies (sim 5B) which would
diminish government income, government savings, and investment due to the larger expense
on subsidies, yet would be beneficial for the economy, in particular for total exports, production
outputs, sectoral value added and GDP. Sim 5B seems to have higher, albeit small, impacts than
127
that of the sim 5A, in which most variables move in the same direction, except price index and
imports, which have reversing trends in the two simulations, as illustrated in Figure 5.7. The
contrasting change of price, however, does not induce noticeable difference on private
Production subsidies give incentives for producers to increase their outputs, and thus
price falls and demand for domestic goods surges to replace demand for imported goods. Export
subsidies, on the other hand, make exports more profitable than domestic sales. Both production
and exports soar at a larger scale, with a slight increase in domestic price, suggesting that export
expansion via subsidies can be achieved without deteriorating domestic supply. In addition,
both production and export subsidy initiatives require more labor to keep up with production
Figure 5.7: Simulation results of subsidy and tariff policies (% change from base)
ProdSub (sim 5A)
Macro effects Employment effects Welfare effects
0.2
0.14 0.22
0.19 0.18
0.0 0.11
0.09 0.14
-0.2 0.07 0.08 0.10
0.07
-0.4
-0.6 Average RP UP UNP RNP PPP PPNP
Total LSK MSK HSK
-0.8
Source: Author
128
level, leading to an increase in wage rate and labor income, coupled with positive changes in
private consumption, generating better welfare for all household groups, with rural areas seeing
the greatest impacts because they can benefit from decreased price of food and agricultural
The protectionist policy, on the other hand, would generate adverse effects on price and
consumption structure; however, this policy has been considered as an effective tool to
three selected sectors. GDP and total investment increase by 0.06 and 0.67 percent, while trade
decreases, with a larger decline in exports, which can be explained by an appreciation of the
real exchange rate. This experiment benefits most government income and savings, as about
US$20 million would be added to each account, resulting from higher tariff revenues. However,
import demand falls, given the higher price of imported products, replaced by higher demand
for domestically produced goods, while accelerating prices, which in turn leads to a fall in both
simulation with a five percent decline in indirect tax. Under this experiment, government
income drops slightly in exchange for a better livelihood of labor and households, including the
increase in employment, income, consumption and welfare as a whole. For further analysis,
as revenues from tariffs can be generated to provide export subsidies without diminishing the
government budget. As Figure 5.7 shows, investment improves at a larger level, whereas trade
flow rises, with exports on a larger scale; labor income and employment see positive changes,
particularly in the case of low-skilled labor. Most of the macro variables, particularly GDP and
investment, and sectoral variables such as exports, aggregate output, value added and quantity
demand are improving at a higher level than those in sim 6B. Importantly, government savings
129
and income increase greatly in this exercise, while they fall in the previous two. This can be
explained by the amount of government revenues which remain high even after being
distributed to subsidies. It can be concluded from the outcome of these scenarios that the
combination of tariffs and indirect tax policy produces satisfactory results to protect local
producers against imports as well as to maximize consumption and welfare, yet the impacts on
sectoral industries and employment are relatively smaller than the combination of tariffs and
export subsidizing policy. The latter policy, moreover, does not only generate a better outcome
for macro and sectoral effects but also keeps the household consumption and welfare at a
positive level, albeit slightly smaller than that of the previous simulation.
It should be noted that currently there has been an enormous volume of agricultural
imports from neighboring countries, particularly Vietnam, into the Cambodian market even
though this country is endowed with agricultural resources. It is reported that the imported
products are lower in price, making domestic products less competitive regardless of the
quality, which has discouraged local producers, especially small-scale holders, and thus
affected their income. Similarly, the food industry seems to face a similar challenge, with the
lower prices of imported ready-made food in comparison to products from local small or
medium enterprises with lower technology and productivity. The imposition of tariffs, which
can also be combined with subsidies, to protect local producers and to encourage more
investment before achieving export increase, therefore, can be one of the efective measures to
Table 5.11 summarizes the results of all the simulations, divided into three parts. The
first one illustrates the effects on macro economy; the second one shows the effects on factor
inputs including employment, wage rates and capital remuneration; and the last one lists the
effects on household welfare and consumption pattern, labor income and savings by different
types of household.
130
Table 5.11: Simulation results (% deviation from base values)
Macro Effects
Demand shock Terms of trade shock Productivity Capital change Subsidy Tariff
1A 1B 2A 2B 2C 3A 3B 4A 4B 5A 5B 6A 6B 6C
Real GDP (market price) 1.92 0.58 -6.19 -6.89 -3.44 1.36 2.20 0.36 0.63 0.06 0.05 0.06 0.03 0.11
Investment 2.65 0.56 -6.91 -6.96 -3.47 -1.19 -0.90 0.01 -0.15 -0.37 -0.33 0.66 -0.24 0.33
Public consumption -0.64 -0.20 2.16 2.18 1.02 5.08 0.23 -0.19 0.13 -0.03 -0.04 -0.05 -0.02 -0.10
Government income 2.77 0.44 -3.73 -4.10 -1.07 5.06 3.10 -0.68 0.71 -0.72 -0.73 0.92 -0.94 0.19
Government savings 27.38 4.99 -51.36 -50.33 -16.81 -4.30 -4.57 -3.69 -1.81 -6.19 -5.83 9.20 -6.95 3.39
Private consumption 1.67 0.58 -5.98 -6.64 -3.46 2.19 2.57 0.51 0.48 0.18 0.18 -0.07 0.17 0.11
Household income 1.67 0.57 -6.12 -6.82 -3.57 1.98 2.47 0.51 0.53 0.18 0.17 -0.08 0.18 0.09
Household savings 1.48 0.46 -6.25 -6.96 -3.63 2.08 2.95 0.41 0.99 0.15 0.12 -0.09 0.16 0.03
Export 0.28 0.14 -4.83 -4.93 -2.73 5.20 0.85 -3.99 0.29 0.01 0.09 -0.07 0.07 0.03
Import 1.59 0.43 -7.41 -8.04 -3.87 2.28 0.19 -1.87 0.06 -0.01 0.04 -0.03 0.01 0.01
Consumption price index 0.78 0.23 -3.20 -2.60 -1.25 -6.61 -4.44 0.28 -1.17 -0.06 0.01 0.28 0.11 0.29
Aggregate output 0.93 0.23 -3.39 -3.41 -1.72 4.03 1.46 -1.20 0.51 0.06 0.09 0.07 0.11 0.15
Value added 0.82 0.29 -3.01 -3.06 -1.51 3.66 1.61 -0.71 0.51 0.06 0.08 0.06 0.10 0.14
Composite quantity demand 1.27 0.32 -4.31 -4.52 -2.14 3.07 1.21 -0.59 0.42 0.05 0.06 0.07 0.09 0.14
Domestic demand for local
1.12 0.27 -2.76 -2.73 -1.27 3.50 1.74 0.04 0.60 0.09 0.08 0.13 0.13 0.20
commodities
Intermediate demand 1.05 0.18 -3.78 -3.75 -1.93 4.41 1.34 -1.69 0.51 0.07 0.10 0.07 0.13 0.17
Factor Effects
Demand shock Terms of trade shock Productivity Capital change Subsidy Tariff
1A 1B 2A 2B 2C 3A 3B 4A 4B 5A 5B 6A 6B 6C
Employment Total 1.57 0.55 -5.56 -5.66 -2.83 -2.55 -1.47 0.55 -0.74 0.11 0.15 0.12 0.19 0.27
LSK 1.79 0.67 -5.85 -5.94 -2.98 -3.80 -2.15 0.55 -1.04 0.14 0.20 0.14 0.21 0.34
MSK 1.52 0.51 -6.06 -6.15 -3.05 -1.97 -1.16 0.68 -0.63 0.09 0.13 0.12 0.18 0.25
HSK 1.07 0.32 -3.80 -3.92 -2.02 -0.20 -0.19 0.31 -0.14 0.07 0.08 0.06 0.15 0.14
Real Wage LSK 0.34 0.18 0.09 -0.58 -0.43 4.83 3.36 0.05 0.56 0.14 0.11 -0.19 0.02 -0.09
MSK 0.44 0.17 -0.76 -1.43 -0.90 5.56 3.75 0.25 0.70 0.12 0.08 -0.18 0.03 -0.10
HSK 0.46 0.13 -0.35 -1.07 -0.78 6.85 4.44 0.06 1.03 0.13 0.08 -0.21 0.05 -0.13
Capital rate of return 3.06 0.47 -4.93 -5.52 -2.85 2.38 3.56 0.72 -0.56 0.28 0.30 0.00 0.30 0.29
Household Effects
Demand shock Terms of trade shock Productivity Capital change Subsidy Tariff
1A 1B 2A 2B 2C 3A 3B 4A 4B 5A 5B 6A 6B 6C
Welfare effects
Average 1.22 0.43 -4.23 -4.73 -2.46 1.82 1.97 0.38 0.32 0.14 0.14 -0.06 0.12 0.08
(% of initial income)
RP 1.50 0.60 -4.44 -4.93 -2.60 2.05 2.41 0.48 0.02 0.19 0.20 -0.04 0.14 0.16
UP 1.43 0.54 -4.22 -4.79 -2.55 3.17 2.77 0.48 0.20 0.18 0.18 -0.07 0.12 0.11
UNP 0.84 0.26 -3.48 -3.89 -2.00 0.94 1.25 0.24 0.46 0.08 0.07 -0.06 0.08 0.01
RNP 1.91 0.68 -6.55 -7.30 -3.83 2.15 2.86 0.60 0.41 0.22 0.22 -0.08 0.21 0.13
PPP 0.63 0.21 -2.55 -2.84 -1.42 1.32 1.40 0.19 0.38 0.07 0.06 -0.04 0.06 0.02
PPNP 1.04 0.29 -4.16 -4.61 -2.37 1.29 1.10 0.30 0.47 0.10 0.09 -0.05 0.12 0.03
Consumption by household 1.67 0.58 -5.98 -6.64 -3.46 2.19 2.57 0.51 0.48 0.18 0.18 -0.07 0.17 0.11
RP 1.96 0.79 -5.81 -6.43 -3.38 2.92 3.36 0.63 0.04 0.25 0.26 -0.04 0.18 0.22
UP 1.80 0.68 -5.34 -6.03 -3.19 4.22 3.68 0.61 0.26 0.23 0.23 -0.08 0.15 0.15
UNP 1.45 0.45 -6.02 -6.70 -3.44 1.80 2.29 0.42 0.81 0.14 0.12 -0.09 0.14 0.03
RNP 1.80 0.65 -6.17 -6.85 -3.59 2.26 2.88 0.57 0.40 0.21 0.20 -0.07 0.19 0.13
PPP 1.41 0.47 -5.76 -6.38 -3.19 3.17 3.31 0.43 0.88 0.15 0.13 -0.08 0.13 0.05
PPNP 1.38 0.39 -5.56 -6.14 -3.15 1.88 1.56 0.40 0.64 0.13 0.11 -0.07 0.16 0.04
Labor income of household 1.98 0.72 -5.82 -6.56 -3.46 2.74 2.16 0.67 -0.06 0.24 0.25 -0.07 0.22 0.17
RP 2.08 0.80 -5.98 -6.71 -3.51 1.64 1.57 0.68 -0.32 0.25 0.28 -0.06 0.22 0.22
UP 1.97 0.71 -5.82 -6.56 -3.46 2.86 2.22 0.67 -0.03 0.24 0.24 -0.07 0.22 0.17
UNP 1.89 0.66 -5.70 -6.45 -3.43 3.68 2.66 0.67 0.16 0.22 0.22 -0.09 0.21 0.14
RNP 2.03 0.75 -5.98 -6.71 -3.52 2.29 1.92 0.70 -0.17 0.24 0.26 -0.06 0.22 0.19
PPP 1.88 0.65 -5.68 -6.43 -3.42 3.80 2.72 0.67 0.18 0.22 0.22 -0.09 0.21 0.13
PPNP 1.75 0.57 -5.14 -5.91 -3.20 4.89 3.30 0.57 0.45 0.21 0.20 -0.11 0.21 0.09
Savings by household 1.48 0.46 -6.25 -6.96 -3.63 2.08 2.95 0.41 0.99 0.15 0.12 -0.09 0.16 0.03
RP 2.01 0.77 -5.84 -6.54 -3.42 1.58 1.55 0.65 -0.28 0.25 0.27 -0.06 0.22 0.21
UP 1.90 0.69 -5.62 -6.34 -3.35 2.76 2.14 0.65 -0.03 0.23 0.24 -0.07 0.21 0.16
UNP 1.51 0.48 -6.32 -7.02 -3.66 1.86 2.80 0.43 0.92 0.15 0.13 -0.09 0.16 0.04
RNP 1.78 0.63 -6.08 -6.78 -3.54 1.89 2.19 0.57 0.28 0.20 0.20 -0.07 0.19 0.13
PPP 1.59 0.51 -6.34 -7.06 -3.69 2.22 2.86 0.47 0.83 0.16 0.15 -0.09 0.17 0.06
PPNP 1.48 0.46 -6.14 -6.85 -3.58 2.32 3.01 0.41 0.98 0.15 0.13 -0.10 0.16 0.03
131
5.5.4.4. Sensitivity Analysis
The study performs sensitivity tests to check the robustness of the results as the CGE
model features usually depend on some assumptions. Table 5.12 shows the comparison for
demand shock of agro-exports (simulation 1A) and terms of trade shock of textiles (simulation
2A) in response to the 20 percent changes of Armington elasticity (CES) and constant elasticity
of transformation between export and domestic sales. The results differ but keep the same
magnitude in trends and signs, which confirms that the estimations of the study are robust to
the changes in both elasticity parameters. Notwithstanding, the terms of trade shock appears to
Table 5.12: Sensitivity Analysis for Armington and Export Elasticity (result in % changes)
Demand shock (sim 1A) Terms of trade shock (sim 2A)
Armington Elasticity Export Elasticity Armington Elasticity Export Elasticity
20% increase 20% decrease 20% increase 20% decrease 20% increase 20% decrease 20% increase 20% decrease
GDP -0.01 0.01 -0.11 0.18 0.10 -0.11 0.02 -0.02
Total Investment -0.01 0.01 -0.15 0.25 0.11 -0.12 0.06 -0.08
Public consumption 0.00 -0.01 0.03 -0.05 -0.07 0.07 -0.03 0.04
Private Consumption -0.01 0.01 -0.10 0.16 0.10 -0.11 0.02 -0.02
Export 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 -0.03 0.03 0.08 -0.09
Import 0.00 0.00 -0.08 0.13 -0.02 0.02 0.03 -0.04
Household Welfare 0.00 0.01 -0.07 0.11 0.08 -0.08 0.01 -0.02
RP 0.00 0.01 -0.09 0.14 0.10 -0.11 0.03 -0.03
UP 0.00 0.01 -0.08 0.13 0.10 -0.10 0.02 -0.03
UNP 0.00 0.00 -0.05 0.08 0.05 -0.05 0.00 0.00
RNP -0.01 0.01 -0.11 0.18 0.12 -0.14 0.03 -0.03
PPP 0.00 0.00 -0.04 0.06 0.04 -0.04 0.01 -0.01
PPNP 0.00 0.00 -0.06 0.10 0.05 -0.06 0.00 0.00
Concluding Remarks
The study shows the roles of the selected sectors—food-beverage-tobacco, rubber, and
internal intervention. The impacts of the potential sectors in response to export demand
expansion bring positive economic growth and employment at the macro level, broadens
production diversification at the sectoral level, and improves welfare at the household level,
132
particularly the rural poor. The simulation results also point out that the contribution and inter-
connection of agro-manufacturing sectors are larger than that of agriculture. Therefore, priority
should be given to creating production chains from agriculture to processed food and processed
This target is also in line with the government’s aims to undertake some degree of
processing inside the country before exporting and to increase the total share of processed
agricultural exports set in the Industrial Development Plan 2015-2025 (MoC, 2014; RGC,
2015). Milled rice export policy initiated by the government in 2010, for example, has been an
important road map for a significant improvement in this sector, although the targeted export
volume was not achieved by the timeline. Besides milled rice, however, there is a lack of critical
and strategic attention to promoting other industrial food processing regardless of viable
A more critical policy toward this sector is required not only to create the value chains
from agriculture endowment, but also to reduce too much concentration on garment exports to
minimize the high vulnerability resulting from possible changes in world price and in current
pattern of competitiveness within the garment sector. These findings are also consistent with
previous studies which suggested that agriculture and the food industry contribute better to
domestic income while garment cannot secure long-term distribution and competition (Chan &
The analysis also reveals that the exporting sectors are low skilled and medium skilled-
intensive, reflecting the higher increase in demand for those two groups of laborers to keep up
with the growth in production and export supplies. Therefore, the impacts on factor market and
labor income could be larger if the efforts toward export orientation are coupled with the
initiative to increase labor productivity of those two groups. This can be done through higher
133
agriculture, and encouragement of hands-on experience exchange between local and foreign
specialists.
In addition, for the economy to expand the benefits that the productivity of labor and
capital generate, the market needs an enabling environment for more efficient utilization of
capital within the targeted sectors in the short term, and freer movement of capital endowment
in the medium term. Also, technological innovations facilitated through more investment and
Finally, the policy simulations find that the influences of the agriculture sector and agro-
industry would be greater if combined with export promotion initiatives. The study finds that
subsidizing and protectionist policies, would work as practical tools to promote the export
orientation of these sectors and bring favorable impacts on both growth and employment. The
subsidizing initiative can be done through various forms including infrastructure subsidies, tax
exemption on production or imported inputs for export production, and promotional and market
access supports.
134
Chapter 6: The Impacts of Trade Facilitation on Economic and Export Structures
Introduction
Tariff barriers, once a huge obstacle to trade, experienced a remarkable fall recently
while trade facilitation barriers remain high and impede trade between countries. Trade
facilitation has also been one of the most prominent topics in the current round of WTO
negotiations to improve global trade, which has not been shared by developing and developed
countries at the same pace even after the general decline in tariff rates (Minor & Tsigas, 2008).
This impediment to trade, therefore, becomes more apparent and need to be addressed.
While Wilson, Mass and Otsuki (2005) argued that there is no standard definition of
trade facilitation in public policy discourse, various dimensions of this term have been captured
in different works. In a broader sense, the WTO defines trade facilitation as the removal of
obstacles to the movement of goods across borders16, whereas ADB-ESCAP (2009) refers this
term as the efficient and transparent implementation of rules and regulations related to trade,
the measures that affect movement of goods along international supply chains, and the system
of customs procedures and documents, which, in short, are to simplify, harmonize and
standardize the trade process across borders, as depicted in Figure 6.1. World Customs
new transaction costs and institutional costs, which can be achieved by applying new
(Zaki, 2009). Similarly, for a modern definition, existing studies have also included
administration barriers and physical and service infrastructure when discussing trade
facilitation issues (Brooks, 2009; Zaki, 2014). These move the focus of trade simplification
efforts from the border to inside the borders of domestic institutional measures, aimed at making
135
Figure 6.1: Simplification, Harmonization and Standardization in Trade Facilitation
including large trade and export-oriented FDI, responded not only to outward policies and
international production networks but also to trade facility development where producers have
increasing access to efficient export related facilities of which cost reduction has become
relatively more important than direct policy barriers. Brooks characterized these types of non-
tariff constraints to trade as “hard” and “soft” barriers. The former is commonly referred to
physical infrastructure obstacles dealing with various measures such as transportation and
communication, while the latter focuses on the institutional and regulatory environment.
Services given by the improvement of infrastructure facilitates the production and distribution
process, lowering transaction margins and narrowing the price gap between suppliers and
consumers. Looking at the supply side factor, the reduction in transaction costs is an essential
element for the improvement of economies of scale, leading to a rise in potential for production
136
and sales in domestic markets and stimulating linkages across industries on one hand, and
In this sense, according to Brooks (2009) and Minor & Tsigas (2008), trade transaction
costs can be divided into (1) direct costs that are charged for each cross-border procedure such
as customs fees, port handlings fees, and informal payments, and (2) indirect costs which may
include three other dimensions: time costs in trade—time required to complete shipment
procedures; risks—increased losses and insurance costs due to high risk of damaged cargo when
infrastructure quality is poor; and lack of access—high opportunity costs due to lack of access
to transport and communication services. Trade facilitation, therefore, has come to determine
Numerous studies have suggested that the indirect costs from time delays across the
border are strongly associated with trade volumes and that the time costs are more likely to
have a larger impact on trade than the direct costs, especially for developing countries (Djankov,
Freund, & Pham, 2010; Minor & Tsigas, 2008). As for the case of Cambodia where trade has
been highly liberalized following the WTO negotiations, trade procedure across borders
remains a significant factor hindering export expansion. Hummels (2001) demonstrated that
time costs to trade vary significantly across countries and commodities, and that the effects of
time delays depend primarily on the export basket that the countries trade. He also suggested
that time costs in trade of most developing countries, as well as Cambodia, are higher than
tariffs. However, despite the recognition, limited work has explicitly examined through which
channels this relationship occurs and how time costs affect Cambodia’s trade and economy.
This current study therefore attempts to measure to what extent improvement of trade
facilitation affects the trade and economic structure of Cambodia by using the CGE model, in
which trade facilitation is represented by tariff equivalent of time costs to exports and imports.
Existing studies with such empirical method for the case of Cambodia are limited; hence the
current study should contribute to the existing literature discussing trade facilitation issue in
137
Cambodia and to the conventional CGE framework of the PEP (Partnership for Economic
Policy Research Networks) adopted for the analysis. The next section of this chapter briefly
reviews existing literature. Section three introduces methodologies and data utilized in the
study, followed by the discussion of simulation results in section 4. The last section concludes
the chapter.
Literature reviews
Non-CGE models
is a common approach to modelling bilateral trade flows through the relationship between trade
and geography, where adding tariffs and trade facilitation indicators and some other additional
factors are possible (Wilson, Mann&Otsuki, 2005 17 ). Earlier work use gravity models to
examine border effects or border related costs that take into account non-tariff barriers such as
quantitative restrictions, technical barriers and SPS measures (Feenstra, 2002; McCallum,
1995). Another group of empirical studies characterize one aspect of non-official trade
trading time (Djankov et al., 2010; Hummels, 2001). Subsequently, a number of studies have
Wilson, Mann, & Otsuki (2003) analyzed relationship between trade in APEC region
(APEC) and trade facilitation using four categories: port efficiency, regulatory environment,
customs environment, and e-business infrastructure. They found that the first two categories
play more significant role in trade flows and that once APEC member with below-average
indicators improve to the average level for all members, intra-APEC trade would increase by
21 percent, half of which is derived from enhancement of port efficiency. They later built on
the previous methodology and categories and extended the model to a larger sample of countries
17
Basic structure of gravity equation: Y = b+ £bZ +Ɛ, where Y is value of trade flows, and Z
corresponds to gravity variables (such as GDP, GDP per capita, tariff, trade facilitation indicators).
138
for a global perspective and suggested that improvement of global trade facilitation capacity in
the four indicators to the world average would raise world trade by US$377 billion, with exports
higher than imports in most regions. Since gains from trade simplification reform could be
substantial, policy measures to strengthen administrative and legal procedures are required even
Time and document to import and export and internet are included as trade facilitation
facets by Zaki (2009) on the sectoral level trade to assess sensitivity of each product. He noticed
that time to import and document to export have negative relationship with trade, yet the
impacts are more pronounced for trade between developed and developing countries than
between developed ones. In addition, the findings, which are also similar to that by Hummels
(2001) who studied the impacts of trading time, conclude that trading goods response differently
to trade facilitation: perishable, seasonal and high-value added products response more to
import time while hard industries do more to export documents. In short, there is a general
consensus that indirect transaction costs associated with trade facilitation have a significant
effect on trade. Meanwhile, gravity models have become an essential tool and widely employed
mainly because of their simple data requirement such as the trade data and some trade cost
proxies and because they could consistently provide evidence of positive impacts of improved
CGE Models
Despite their consistency, the gravity models face a number of limitations. For one
thing, the models leave out the heterogeneity problem, empirically, and heterogeneity of traded
goods in quality by origin and price differentials, theoretically (Wilson, Mann&Otsuki, 2005).
For the other thing, the econometric framework fail to specify channels by which trade
facilitation affect trade and to explicitly reveal insight of causation since they do not account
for the economic linkages between sectors and the restriction of resources such as labor and
capital (Minor&Tsigas, 2008). Last, the models usually link costs of trade simplification
139
indicators including waiting time, document and infrastructure without revealing the costs in
To address the weaknesses, Minor and Tsigas (2008) suggested that a combination of
econometric and CGE model is more likely to be a useful method for border trade studies since
the latter captures the causal linkages of country and sector-specific based on detailed
accounting system. Moreover, incorporating trade facilitation into CGE framework can further
demonstrate the impacts not only on trade volume but also on a wide range of other economic
indicators such as investment, production, as well as factor and household welfare. Hertel,
Walmsley & Itakura (2001) studied the impacts of Japan and Singapore free trade agreement
and trade related issues covering technical standard, e-commerce regulations and customs
procedure using GTAP model and found that the FTA increases bilateral trade and investment
flows, with customs automization playing the most crucial role. Minor and Tsigas (2008)
adopted the model yet presented border simplification using time costs to trade with available
data econometrically estimated by Hummels (2001). On the other hand, Zaki (2010, 2014)
measured the costs of trade facilitation with gravity model and integrated the results into
The new tool to studying the impacts of trade facilitation shed light for new studies to
reveal more concrete evidence of trade facilitation effects. Despite the existing literature, the
incorporation of the trade facilitation into CGE models, in general, are limited, and on the case
The CGE model is appropriate to explore trade facilitation because any changes
generated by trade facilitation measures affect not only trade but also all economic activities,
including production, employment, and welfare. To assess the impacts of trade facilitation, this
study uses the CGE model adopted from the standard one-country one-period model of the PEP,
developed by Ducaluwe et al. (2013), and determines a set of macro closure as follows:
140
- Capital is sector-specific, and in full employment
- Labor is mobile across sectors, labor supply is exogenous, and unemployment exists
- The saving rate is fixed and saving adjusts to ensure macroeconomic equilibrium
- World export price and world import price are exogenous (small country hypothesis)
The detailed structure of the model is the same as the one given in Chapter 5 of this dissertation.
However, the standard PEP model is modified to take into account the trade facilitation
framework.
To capture the impacts of trade facilitation, time delays in trade across the border are
introduced as ad valorem imposed on export price and import price, following (Chahir Zaki,
2010). The data of the ad valorem equivalents (AVEs) of time to export and import is adopted
from the GTAP database (for which the calculation is detailed in the data section below). The
AVEs of time are comparable to ad valorem tariffs and represent a shift in the export or import
demand curve in response to price changes (Minor, 2013). These new variables of time costs
enter the model as tariff equivalents which increase export price and import price that should
For the export price, export taxes and tariff equivalents of time (entering the model as
converted tax rate) increase the f.o.b prices of export commodities, given by:
Where
141
PEi: Price received for exported commodity i (excluding export taxes)
For the import price, similarly, tariff barriers and the tariff equivalents of time make
Where
Total revenues generated from the tariff equivalents of time delays in the trading
procedure are assumed to be captured by customs agents who work for the border agencies.
The model creates a new agent called “inefficiency customs agent” who receives revenues from
the total time receipts and spends those revenues on consumption of commodity i. Since this is
an extra income, all of the revenues are spent on consumption. Zaki (2010) assumed new
income is only generated by revenue from the import side while treating the revenues from the
export side as an investment transfer for trade balance. However, this study treats the receipts
142
from time barriers of both export and import sides as the income of inefficiency agent since
they are both captured by the domestic customs agents as a form of extra cost attached to
processing trade procedures or documentation. The new equations of income and consumption
Where
6.3.2. Data
With a few modifications, the study uses the 2011 Cambodian aggregated SAM,
adopted from Heng et al. (2014). The number of activities, production factors, agents and
household types of the SAM applied in the current study are listed below:18
- Factors: one type of capital, three types of labor: low skilled, medium skilled, and
high skilled
- Households: six categories (according to living areas and living standard levels):
Phnom Penh poor (PPP), Phnom Penh non-poor (PPNP), other urban poor (UP),
other urban non-poor (UNP), rural poor (RP), rural non-poor (RNP).
18 List of industries and commodities, and economic structural features at the base scenario can be found in
Chapter 5, section 5.3.
143
6.3.2.2. Tariff equivalents for time barriers
The study adopts the data from the GTAP database which records per day equivalents
of waiting time to export and import (Hummels & Schaur, 2013; Minor, 2013). To prepare this
database, Minor (2013) built on the estimation by Hummels (2001) and Hummel et al. (2007)
and mapped the commodity-specific values of the time costs onto the global database to
aggregate the particular values to the sectors and the country pairs in the GTAP. The original
estimation of time costs in trade is summarized as follow. To quantify the tariff equivalents of
(1) Estimating the value of one day saved in transit by product, which is termed "the
(2) Calculating the per-day value of time saving by country according to the
(3) Calculating tariff equivalents of time to export and import through the combination
of the per-day value of time savings of each country with its number of days required
for trading across borders, based on the data from Doing Business.
For the first step, Hummels (2001) and Hummels et al. (2007) estimated the value of
purchasers to pay for higher cost air shipping to avoid an additional day of ocean shipping,
which has a longer delivery time. While firms benefit from time saving in product transit,
measured in days, they face higher freight price for more timely delivery, measured in terms of
the price of the traded products. Since there are differences in the units of these two components,
time measured in days has to be converted into tariff equivalents. To make this conversion,
Hummels (2001) relies on the assumption that higher prices reduce consumption. The price
can represent the value that consumers tie to getting goods in a faster way, referring to the
benefit of time saving. The estimated price elasticity of demand is combined with the benefit
144
measured in days to calculate the “Ad valorem equivalents (AVEs)” of time saving to export
and import by product basis, at the HS4 level of over 600 commodities. The data for the
estimation comes from two sources: (1) the U.S. merchandise monthly import database 1991-
2005, by transportation mode, by product, by exporter, and by entry point into the U.S.; and (2)
For the second step, the values of time savings for each country are calculated for the
values of time average of the trade basket of each country. The current exports and imports for
each country and the exports and imports of the region in which the country is located are the
two alternative weighting schemes to provide estimates for exports and imports. Their findings
suggest that the estimation of the per-day values of time savings differ significantly by both
product and country. For instance, road vehicles have a time sensitivity of two percent ad-
valorem, which can be explained that each day the goods are saved from shipping time lowers
the price of the goods by two percent. While vegetables and fruit exhibit 0.9 percent of per-day
ad-valorem to trade time, bulk products such as fertilizer and crude oil are not time sensitive.
Consistently, the Middle East and North African countries are likely to have the lowest per-day
ad valorem, attributed to the crude oil and natural resource-intensive goods in the export basket
of those regions compared to the higher value-added manufacturing exports in the OECD
countries which possess the highest per-day tariff equivalents (shown in Table 6.1).
For the last step, Hummels et al. (2007) obtained the final objective of the AVEs
equivalents of the total export and import time delays for each country by multiplying the per-
145
day time values by the number of days recorded in Trading Across Borders data of the Doing
Business. The number of days required for the export and import procedure is divided into three
elements: inland transport, port and terminal handling, and customs administration. The
methods take into account activities or delays in delivery times differing from the baseline;
however, it should be noted that the data does not include time to complete documentation since
exporters and importers may begin documentation processes beforehand while production is
underway and can continue while the goods are on route to market (Hummels et al., 2007,
Minor, 2008).
Since the more updated version of the numbers of days in trade is available, this study
calculates the AVEs of time delays in exports and imports by multiplying the per-day ad
valorem with the number of days of both export and import. The number of days to trade are
weighted by trade flows—time to export is weighted by export values, and time to import is
weighted by import values (Minor, 2013). As shown in Table 6.2, total times are eight days for
export and 11 days for import procedures. Figure 6.2 presents the tariff equivalents by product,
compared to import tax rates. The table shows that the tariff equivalents of time to trade, which
are the hidden barriers, are in fact higher than the applied tariffs for almost all of the products
in Cambodia, reflecting that removing the time cost barriers is crucial and likely to have a more
Export Import
Customs administration 3 Customs administration 3
Ports handling 3 Ports handling 5
Inland transport 2 Inland transport 3
Total 8 Total 11
146
Figure 6.2: AVEs of time to export, AVEs of time to import, and Import tariffs (in percentage)
14
12
10
Source: Prepared by author, using SAM for tariffs and GTAP for AVEs to export and import
The study performs a series of simulations to assess the impacts of trade facilitation on
the economy and to determine which sectors gain most from it. The first simulation halves the
time to export and import across borders for all the products as a result of improvement of the
trading procedure. The second simulation proposes a 50 percent reduction in tariff rates across
the board as a cause of trade liberalization. These two exercises distinguish between the two
effects and how the dimensions of the effects differ. The last simulation, on the other hand,
combines the reduction of time in trade and an increase in investment in transportation and
Trade facilitation 1. Decrease time delays of export and import by 50% (TF)
147
administration, considered as a cost to achieve the improvement of trade facilitation, and
coupled with an increase in total factor productivity, assumed as a technical progress along with
investment demand.
Figure 6.3, 6.4 and 6.5 summarized the simulation results showing the effects on macro
economy of the three simulations respectively. For the first simulations, the reduction in time
delays in both export and import procedures induces positive impacts on the economy in general
as a result of an improvement in the terms of trade. GDP rises by 1.63 percent as investment
and private consumption soar by 1.20 and 1.82 percent respectively, as depicted in Figure 6.3.
The changes can be explained by two effects: exports and imports. For the export side, the
reduction in time, and thus the AVEs, saves producers’ exporting costs since F.O.B export
prices become cheaper, making export more beneficial (the world price is constant), resulting
in an acceleration in total exports by 1.30 percent. For the import side, similarly, the decrease
in tariff equivalents of time lessens prices of imported goods, and hence total imports rise by
2.43 percent. Terms of trade improve considerably when lengthy customs barriers to trade are
eased with the reduction in transaction costs. Trade facilitation, therefore, reduces trade prices
The results of the second simulation show that cutting tariffs by the same proportion
yields lower gains for most of the macro indicators. This can be primarily explained by a more
Figure 6.3: Macro effects of simulation 1: Trade facilitation (% changes from base values)
Sim 1-TF
3
0
GDP Investment Priv con Publ con Export Import Output HH Welfare
-1 income
148
modest fall in trade price in simulation two than that in simulation one since tariffs are on
average lower than time costs. For example, F.O.B export prices diminish on average by 0.15
percent in the former against 0.63 percent in the latter. GDP (at market price) sees a slight drop,
whereas investment falls marginally by almost three percent due to the major fall in government
-1
-2
-3
Source: Author
consumer price decline. The fall in prices causes exports to surge as producers find sales in the
local market less beneficial. That can be the reason why total exports accelerate higher than
total imports. These findings are also consistent with the previous study by Zaki (2014), who
revealed that in both the short and the long run, the welfare gains from trade liberalization are
lower than those of trade facilitation. He also suggested that “while welfare gains emerging
from trade liberalization are explained by a more efficient allocation of resources, those arising
from trade facilitation are primarily the result of a reduction in deadweight loss: changes in
terms of trade are far more important as a source of welfare gain in trade facilitation than trade
liberalization” (Zaki, 2014, p 121). That is the reason to suggest that when trade liberalization
is pursued with trade facilitation simultaneously, economic welfare gains are more significant.
The last simulation, which combines the reduction in trade time with an increase in
investment as a cost to improve trade facilitation quality, favors the economy at a larger scale.
149
The costs of higher investment is a sort of income redistribution done by the government as it
procedures such as through computerization, and increasing wages for the public customs
agents, although these aspects are not directly taken into account in the simulation. Hence they
are favorable for the economy and should not be treated as an actual cost perspective (Chahir
Zaki, 2010). GDP gains US$ 343million, increasing from 1.63 percent without investment to
2.64 percent with the investment to finance trade facilitation, whereas consumption surge
substantially. Trade also improves, with exports larger than imports. It is worthwhile to note
that the projects are financed without cutting the public budget because the rise in imports and
exports increases tariff revenues following the trade simplification measure, which boosts
government income and enables it to fund investment in public services. In contrast, such
projects would not be possible without putting pressure on either government income or saving
in the case of trade liberalization as tariff revenues fall and thus government income falls by
6.72 percent.
While removing time cost barriers improves total exports, it does not benefit all of the
sectors equally. Table 6.4 shows that agriculture, office equipment, machinery and metal
products see the largest export rise in simulation one, suggesting that these products are more
sensitive to trading time. This can be given by the higher willingness to pay by producers or
150
purchasers for these products to be distributed to the markets in a timely fashion to avoid
quality/price depreciation. Such results answer the trade facilitation literature which has shown
that perishable goods such as agriculture products and food, seasonal/fashion products such as
garments, and high value-added products are highly associated with transaction time (Hummels
et at., 2007, Minor&Tsigas, 2008, Zaki, 2014). Conversely, those studies found that bulk
products such as fertilizer, crude oil and natural resource-intensive goods are not time sensitive
to trade. This conclusion supports the result of the current study that rubber, which is highly
protected, does not benefit from lowering trading time barriers for export and import, showing
that trade facilitation alone does not seem to have an impact on rubber industry. Yet, this
particular industry will be significantly affected by the combination of removing time costs and
Table 6.4: Effects on exports and export prices by sector (% changes from base)
Note: Export prices are prices received for export commodities, excluding export tax and AVEs
Source: Author’s estimation
151
Table 6.5: Effects on imports and import prices by sector (% changes from base)
Imports Import Prices
sim3- sim3-
Commodity sim1-TF sim2-TLB sim1-TF sim2-TLB
TF-INV TF-INV
Total 2.43 0.23 3.81
AGR 10.27 2.54 8.20 -5.21 -1.85 -5.21
FBT 4.46 2.84 3.24 -1.59 -2.63 -1.59
TEXTILE 1.90 0.95 4.87 -3.28 -1.31 -3.28
WP 3.01 0.85 4.37 -4.09 -2.32 -4.09
RP 4.78 1.26 6.33 -5.39 -2.53 -5.39
METAL 2.55 -2.49 2.78 -5.24 -1.25 -5.24
FMETAL 4.87 -2.35 4.04 -3.94 -2.25 -3.94
MACHINE 1.71 -2.69 1.98 -4.00 -1.85 -4.00
OFFICE 2.34 -1.70 2.80 -4.33 -1.95 -4.33
TRANS 2.35 0.89 3.13 -5.14 -2.39 -5.14
OTHMNU 1.20 -0.09 3.14 -5.21 -0.70 -5.21
CHEM 1.82 0.24 2.98 -5.47 -1.80 -5.47
FURN 2.44 0.99 3.30 -5.07 -2.04 -5.07
MEGW 6.83 1.08 6.10 -4.61 -1.81 -4.61
CON 7.05 -6.41 1.46 -4.11 -0.43 -4.11
WTT 5.47 -0.06 4.09 -4.12 -0.42 -4.12
HR 5.00 1.17 1.43 -1.65 -1.07 -1.65
FBUS 7.74 0.38 5.45 -4.46 -0.49 -4.46
ADM -0.33 0.78 9.08 - -0.48 -
EDU 1.49 0.06 0.78 - - -
HEALTH 1.60 0.04 0.93 - - -
OTHSER 6.91 0.57 4.49 -3.45 -0.44 -3.45
Note: The AVEs for ADM, EDU and HEALTH are not available, neither the tariffs for ADU
and HEALTH
Source: Author’s calculation
increasing public investment (simulation 3). Despite the differences by sector, trade facilitation,
in general, has greater impacts on exports as well as export prices than trade liberalization does
Unsurprisingly, trade facilitation also reduces import prices (Table 6.5), as trade
transactions at the borders become less time consuming, hence consumption of the imported
and services such as finance and business. The results suggest that the removal of trading time
barriers leads to an improvement in the terms of trade (export price change in relation to change
152
in import price). Generally, sectoral trade increases more substantially as a result of reducing
AVEs than those of reducing tariffs because Cambodia’s trade has already been highly
liberalized, while non-tariff/administrative barriers and trade costs are quite basic.
The findings also reveal that Cambodia would experience a remarkable diversification
of exports and production directed toward those products that are sensitive to trading time
following trade facilitation reforms. Those sectors with higher exports need to increase their
production level more than others. For instance, besides textiles, which are the current major
export, office equipment increases its exports and output by about three percent, machinery by
1.90 and 1.13 percent, agriculture by almost three and 1.72 percent, and agro-food by 0.74 and
1.04 percent for export and production, respectively. As mentioned earlier, perishable (food)
and short market life (high value added) products respond more significantly to barriers
associated with trade simplification. On the other hand, these types of constraints are treated as
a part of fixed costs of exports. Lowering these fixed costs—perceived as primary determinants
of firm entry—thus expand the range of commodities that the country can export as more firms
would be able to enter into international markets (Dennis & Shepherd, 2011). Dennis and
Shepherd (2011) found that product diversity gains of the order of three to four percent once
These benefits turn even more pronounced when the improvement of trade facilitation
is financed by the investment in transportation and administration (simulation 3), as the exports
of all the sectors improve more than double compared to simulation 1. In addition, rubber
exports would increase by almost three percent, indicating that for this industry to be able to
reap the benefits, trade facilitation should be coupled with the initiation of other policies. A
similar phenomenon is applied for the output levels of all the sectors where the effects are more
153
While the importing sectors decrease their production, the exporting sectors require a
higher level of production as aggregated output soars, meaning that there would be more
demand for production factors. It should be noted that the model assumes that supply of the
production factors is exogenous and that capital is fully employed, while there is unemployment
in the Cambodian labor market. Table 6.6 presents the changes in labor employment and the
returns to wages and capital remunerations. Once trade is facilitated, total employment
increases by 1.67 percent, with greater impacts on low-skilled and medium-skilled labor since
exporting sectors with higher production are more low-skill and medium-skill intensive. In
contrast, medium skill wage progresses more than low skill wage since the former is less rigid
and the medium-skilled workers are more likely to move quicker across sectors to where the
premium is higher. Larger production also demands more capital. In accordance with the CES
function of capital and labor characterized in the model, more capital is required to substitute
labor for dealing with the progress in wages. Since capital is immobile across industries, higher
Source: Author
As for the second simulation, real wages increase in relation to the high proportion of
the decrease in price, yet employment increases minimally at 0.04 percent in total. This is
reasonable, because as domestic product becomes more expensive relative to imported goods,
consumption for locally produced goods diminishes and so does production output. The modest
154
increase in labor is, however, only required for the production for foreign market supplies, as
producers tend to export more when external sales become more beneficial in relation to
domestic revenues.
The combination of trade facilitation and investment in the last simulation produces a
more substantial improvement in the returns to both labor and capital, yet the employment
changes are moderate, except for among the high-skilled. This is because, on one hand, when
there is a higher demand for production as a result of investment and technical progress, capital
becomes more in demand and more efficient to substitute for low and medium-skilled workers;
nevertheless, capital is less likely to be substitutable with the high-skilled group as the latter is
needed to operate the highly-technical function of machinery. On the other hand, as industry
opens up to foreign markets as a result of trade facilitation, more firms become more productive
to keep up with the competition and will, therefore, hire more skilled labor at the expense of
higher premium. The results infer that trade facilitation produces greater gains for the
production factors when combined with the increase in investment in the trade-related public
Real household disposable income would increase by 1.82 percent on average as a result
of trade simplification, with the rural poor and non-poor groups and the urban poor receiving
the highest effects thanks to the rise in labor income as employment and wages increase. The
decline in import prices due to the extraction of time costs encourages private consumption of
all the household groups—Phnom Penh, urban and rural. Therefore, as listed in Table 6.7,
welfare effects for households rise by 1.55 percent of total income in the first scenario, with the
highest effects on the rural non-poor families (as percentage of initial income). The magnitudes
of the effects are lower in the free trade scenario. For instance, welfare increases by 0.58
percent, whereas both consumption and real income increase by about 0.70 percent due
155
primarily to the decrease in both domestic and import price. Labor income increased less than
the first simulation by half given the modest changes in labor demand.
The results of the last scenario, however, generate the highest impacts compared to the
previous two. Welfare grows by 2.20 percent on average, whereas real household income and
consumption progress considerably in response to the higher labor demand and wage rates,
improved productivity along with the increase in investment in public sectors, and the lower
growth and export expansion. Some remarkable changes have been seen in four Southeast Asian
People’s Republic of China (PRC) while other Asian economies, including those of South Asia,
are the later followers on this path (Das, 2000). Table 6.8 shows that exports from Eastern and
Southern Asia grew faster on average than world exports from 1995 to 2011. World exports
rose about 3.5 times while Eastern and Southern Asian exports grew almost 6-fold over the
156
A closer look at various countries can be interesting. The ASEAN-4 economies have
achieved a high export growth rate since early 1990s, and from 1995 to 2011, during which
period, the export volume grew about 4 times for Indonesia and Thailand and 3 times for
Malaysia and the Philippines. China, with exports soared 13-fold over the period, was among
the fastest export growth countries, followed by India, in the sub-region. The low-base effect
can be seen in these economies as they began their exports from a very low level. For example,
at the time of adopting the open door policy in 1979, China’s exports were only US$12.6 billion,
grew from US$6.4 billion in 1975 (Das, 2000). Although there was a reduction in import
demand from developed economies during the early 1980s due to the global recession, export
figures for China picked up to US$148.8 billion in 1995 and continued to increase sharply
afterward. This remarkable achievement in two decades reflected a change in both economic
Starting from 2000, food exports started at a similar point as or even lower than that of
textile in the ASEAN-4, but the figure surpassed textile export in the last 2000s in all the four
countries. This changes could have been caused by the diversification into agro-industry and
by the movement of textile production to lower labor cost economies such as China, with textile
the major exports. This can be a lesson for the latecomers, such as Cambodia, in the region to
follow given the competition challenges by the lower labor costs of other major textile exporters
Table 6.8: East and South Asia Exports, 1995-2011 (US$ billion)
East and
Year World Indonesia Malaysia Philippines Thailand China India
South Asia
1995 5,121.1 628.6 45.4 73.8 17.4 56.4 148.8 31.7
2000 6,367.0 869.1 62.1 98.2 38.1 68.8 249.2 42.4
2005 10,447.3 1,726.4 85.7 141.6 41.3 110.1 762.0 100.4
2010 15,221.1 3,098.7 157.8 198.8 51.5 195.3 1,577.8 220.4
2011 18,237.2 3,721.0 203.5 227.0 48.0 228.8 1,898.4 301.5
157
6.5.2. Trade Policy Reform
Trade liberalization in most of the South East Asian countries began in the early 1980s
(Santos-Paulino, 2002; Weiss, 2005). Indonesia undertook the movement from import
substitution industrialization to export promotion policy during that period, carrying the
promotion of non-traditional exports, reinforcing domestic and foreign investment and financial
markets; and later enhancing exchange rate policy to support and improve competitiveness of
Indonesia’s exporters. Similarly in Malaysia, the liberal exchange rate system was maintained,
together with the relatively low average tariff and quantitative restrictions. The Philippines once
abandoned trade liberalization due to macroeconomic problems in 1983 but reestablished the
policy in 1986 (Santos-Paulino, 2002). With inward liberalization and tariff reforms as
moderate, gradual and steady, outward-looking strategies with investment law reforms and bias
against FDI removal remarkably increased FDI and export activities in the Philippines although
Thailand carried import substitution strategy during the 1970s. Incentives were provided
to semi-manufacturing and manufacturing exports, including tinned fish, dried and preserved
fruit and vegetables. The development of agro-processing industries were firstly carried by
Table 6.9: Timing shift in trade policy, some East Asia economies
Indonesia 1948-66 Economic 1967-73 Some trade 1974-81 Oil and 1986-onwards Gradual
nationalism; liberalization commodity boom trade liberalization and
nationalization of Dutch export promotion
enterprises
Malaysia 1950-70 Natural resource 1971-85 Import 1986-onwards Gradual
based exports substitution and export trade liberalization and
promotion through EPZs export promotion
Thailand 1955-70 Natural resource 1971-80 Import 1980- onwards Trade
based exports substitution liberalization and export
promotion
158
domestic firms which established large vertically integrated agri-business groups that combined
all stages of production and different sectors including financial enterprises, transportation and
marketing (Reinhardt, 2000). Multinational firms, sometimes in the form of joint ventures with
the public sector, were deemed to play a vital role in the support and provision of marketing
by promoting private sector development and attracting inflows of FDI during the 1980s. This
could have been done mainly by the attempt to depreciate domestic currency against US dollar
due to the adoption of a more flexible exchange rate regime during the period.
Malaysia has been recognized as an export-led growth economy for the period 1965-
1996, with strong evidence during 1965-1980 (Khalafalla & Webb, 2001). The country’s
grows because the initial development from export industry lead to a widening of the export
base and growth in the size of the domestic market” (North, 1961, p.6). Hence, learning from
Malaysia’s experience would be worthy for Cambodia. According to Khalafalla and Webb
(2001) and Reinhardt (2000), Malaysia has undergone a noticeable structural changes, which
The first one dated back to before the 1980s when export growth was observed
following trade promotion initiatives. After getting independence in 1957, the economy
depended heavily on the so-called twin pillars of rubber and tin which accounted for almost
75% of total export earnings, whereas exports shared about half of national income, while
manufacturing sector accounted for less than 10% of national output, employed only 10% of
labor force. During the 1960s, the country pursued import substitution policy, in which the
industrial import substitution and tariffs were attractive to foreign investment. The government
promoted the expansion of resource based sector mainly rubber and palm oil production, while
at the same time promoting the improvement of manufacturing sector, first toward domestic
market, and then toward export market. From the early 1970s, while maintaining protectionism,
159
the country began to promote manufacturing exports, shifting gradually toward outward-
The success of the policy shift during the 1970s resulted in a change of the commodity
composition during the last 20 years with the emergence of manufacturing exports, palm oil
and petroleum products, against the decline in relative importance of natural rubber and tin.
exports. In 1971 the New Economic Policy was launched to achieve two objectives: alleviation
of poverty, and structuring of employment and the ownership of assets. From that period
development and carried out some strategic manufacturing export promotion policies which
covers two distinct features: introducing various incentive measures to stimulate domestic
industries to export part of their output, establishing Export Processing Free Zones (EPFZ) to
speed up direct exports. The first feature takes place along four categories:
- Providing an export allowance to companies that allow a reduction from taxable income
- Operating various export financing facilities that provide domestic exporters with credit
These incentives are also provided to industries of EPFZ, which started in 1972 for
exclusively export market-oriented industries and to attract FDI, together with additional
measures, including low cost infrastructure facilities, a complete free-trade regime, and
these incentives as FDI created subsidiaries, particularly for labor-intensive garment and
160
support for diversification of natural resource based industries, mainly palm oil refineries and
petroleum development.
In the early 1980s, the second period, Malaysia faced a recession which revealed the
weakness in depending on primary exports, of which price and exchange earnings are volatile.
In response to the negative growth, the government started to provide more attractive incentives
for foreign investment focusing on production of manufactured goods for exports, emphasizing
Subsequently, from the mid-1980s which marks the renewed period of export growth,
growing exports increasingly relied on imports of capital goods and manufacturing inputs to
support the manufacturing sector growth, moving away from primary commodities. The new
trend implied the greater interdependence of the exports and imports, which had not been the
case when the country was relying mostly on primary exports. The relationship between
exports, imports and economic growth were revealed as manufactures increase proportionally
to Malaysia’s exports, where policies of export base expansion were accompanied by the
dependent on imported equipment and machinery. These policies broadened both trade linkages
and domestic market as Khalafalla and Webb (2001) stated: “these measures helped assure a
broad-based participation in the nation’s economic growth leading to the emergence of a wide
array of indigenous services and manufacturing enterprises, a growing number of which are
South Asia
All countries in South Asia had exhibited import substitution policies with very high
tariffs; up to 335 percent in India and 450 percent in Pakistan, until the mid-1980s when many
countries faced current account deficit, lost foreign reserves and had high inflation rate, all of
which, in many cases, led to decline in real GDP growth rate and restriction of foreign exchange
161
markets (Santos-Paulino, 2002). In hoping to restore the macroeconomic situation, all countries
adopted some structural adjustments and received adjustment loans in the late 1980s. Many
parts of export policy have been reformed since then. Despite the different level of export taxes
and duties which remained similarly high prior to reform, incentives for exports have been
significantly increased. Some examples include the expansion of duty drawback system,
implementation of tax holidays, payment of tax rebates, and simplification of direct subsidy
schemes. In addition, direct controls on imported inputs for export sectors were reduced with
the attempt to neutralize the effects of import barriers. Quantitative restrictions, bans, quotas
and domestic content requirements were removed in Sri Lanka in 1985; whereas in India, duty
drawback compensation scheme for exports was introduced and restrictions on manufacturing
exports were finally removed by 1993 (Santos-Paulino, 2002). At the same time, incentives of
raw material and intermediate goods imports for export industries were provided in Pakistan
The experience of some countries in the region infers that despite the difference level
of development, pattern and pace of reforms, East and South Asia undertook liberalization and
common actions in the first phase of reforms including the removal of obstacles to exporting,
through exchange rate policy. The second phase of the reforms was generally taken after the
government budget balance and balance of payment were strengthened (Santos-Paulino, 2002).
The procedures returned this sub-region with a vital experience of great success.
Progress and challenges in relation to trade and business are evident from a number of
indicators. Cambodia ranked 129th among 155 countries in 2010 Logistic Performance Index
Progress and challenges in relation to trade and business are evident from a number of
indicators. Cambodia ranked 129th among 155 countries in 2010 Logistic Performance Index
162
based on indicators given in Figure 6.6. Investment climate survey showed some improvements
of average time of border clearance which went down from 4.5 days in 2003 to 4.3 days in 2007
for export and from 6.5 to 3.7 days for import (with more improvement for garment industry)
(MOC, 2012). Despite improvements, Ministry of Commerce (2012) reported that: “Feedback
from private sector points to the need to further facilitate trade, simplify processes and make
To identify areas for action and enable the impact of trade facilitation reforms to be
assessed, OECD has introduced a series of trade facilitation indicators (OECD, 2013):
ethics policy.
counties.
163
- Formalities-Procedures: Streamlining of border controls, single windows for all
risk management.
- Fees and Charges: Regulations of the fees and charges imposed on exports and imports
border agencies.
Figure 6.7: Trade Facilitation Performance, OECD Indicators, 2 represents best performance
164
specific goods at the time of importation, the rules and process applied to such
statements.
The development of the indicators are able to help governments to reduce trade costs,
improve border procedures, and thus boost trade flows and reap greater benefits from doing
trade. Using the estimates based on the indicators, the government can also prioritize necessary
actions and mobilize resources, technical assistance and capacity building efforts in a more
Figure 6.7 displays the trade facilitation performance of Cambodia. And shows that
Cambodia performs well in the area of information availability, procedure formalities, and fees
and charges. However, its performance is in general below the average level of Asian or low
internal border agency cooperation, document formalities, and advance rulings as sketched in
Figure 6.7.
environment as well as trade across borders. Table 6.10 displays some figures related to these
three areas by comparing Cambodia status with average levels of developing countries in East
and South Asia. Inadequate infrastructure in Cambodia tends to hinder export expansion. Paved
roads in East Asia and South Asia were respectively 15 and 56 percent of total roads in general
in 2004-05; it was only 6 percent in Cambodia (WDI, 2012). The level of electricity
consumption is also low in Cambodia in comparison to average levels in the two sub-regions,
while mobile subscriptions per 100 people is relatively high in Cambodia due to the high level
of involvement of the private sector in this area. A more detailed country comparison can be
found in the study by De (2006) who divided infrastructure into four indices:
165
telecommunication services), (3) social infrastructure (access to education, health care,
media) and (4) transportation infrastructure (access to roadways, ports, railways and
airways) (p.721).
These indices are helpful to understand the impact of related infrastructure on trading
behavior of major Asian nations. As given in Table 6.11, the scores range from the highest for
countries with more developed infrastructure to the lowest for countries with relatively poor
infrastructure development. Cambodia ranked low in almost all the indices suggesting that
Table 6.10: Infrastructure, Starting a Business, Trade across Borders, Cambodia, East and South Asia
East Asia
South Asia Cambodia
(Develping only)
Infrastructure
Procedures (number)
2011 8.45 7.38 10.00
2004 54.58 46.71 94.00
Time (days)
2011 45.75 24.81 102.00
2004 84.63 46.70 534.80
Cost (% of income per capita)
2011 39.38 27.21 127.50
Trading Across Borders
improvement from 2004 to 2011, Cambodia still seems to require quite a relatively complicated
procedure, and more time and cost before a firm can start to operate (Table 6.10). However, a
lower gap between trading across borders in Cambodia and that in the rest of the sub-regions
can be found, indicating that trade facilitation is quite favorable for outward in this country.
166
Table 6.11: Infrastructure in Asia, 2001
AII EII SII TII
Countries
Score Rank Score Rank Score Rank Score Rank
Brunei 1.59 9 6.09 5 13.43 3 2.09 7
Cambodia 0.38 15 0.17 15 8.02 15 0.24 13
China 2.34 5 2.46 8 11.82 6 3.12 5
Hong Kong 1.76 7 10.27 3 13.34 4 4.28 4
India 1.83 6 0.84 11 9.73 13 2.20 6
Indonesia 0.86 14 1.05 10 10.46 12 0.59 12
Japan 6.33 1 12.37 1 15.82 2 8.08 1
LaoPDR 0.97 11 0.27 14 8.05 14 0.23 14
Malaysia 0.95 12 5.60 6 10.67 10 1.40 10
Myanmar 1.01 10 0.41 13 10.48 11 0.11 15
Philippines 0.91 13 1.44 9 11.51 8 0.67 11
Singapore 5.14 2 10.43 2 12.80 5 7.57 2
South Korea 4.17 3 9.27 4 16.12 1 5.95 3
Thailand 1.63 8 2.53 7 11.70 7 2.06 8
Vietnam 2.55 4 0.74 12 10.93 9 1.42 9
AII: Agriculture Infrastructure Index, EII: Economic Infrastructure Index, SII: Social
Infrastructure Index, TII: Transportation Infrastructure Index
Source: De, 2006 (p 721)
The complicated and delayed procedures strongly affect investment decision and, in many
Concluding Remarks
This chapter studied the impacts of improvement of trade transaction across borders on
General Equilibrium (CGE) model. Tariff equivalents of time to trade enter the model to
represent trade facilitation. This study was the first attempt to measure the impacts of trade
facilitation in Cambodia utilizing the CGE model (PEP). While previous policies have usually
focused on the reduction of the direct costs, the attention on time costs or time delays for export
promotion have been limited. The current study, therefore, estimated the improvement in the
The simulation results revealed that reducing time delays in export and import
procedures would favor economic gains due to the improvement in the terms of trade. Exports
accelerate, which is explained by the fall in export costs that traders would be able to save when
167
trade is facilitated, making export more beneficial without deteriorating domestic sales,
employment and wage rates rise, particularly for low- and medium-skilled laborers, whereas
welfare progresses as private consumption surges in response to the import price fall.
Notably, saving time costs in trade does not benefit every sector in the same way. While
agriculture, office equipment, and machinery exports see the largest impacts since these
industries have a high sensitivity to trading time, rubber, other manufacturing and hotel service
see the lowest impacts. These findings are also consistent with previous studies which suggest
that perishable (food) products and high value-added products are more responsive to time
savings, while bulk products such as crude oil, fertilizer, and natural resource-intensive goods
are the opposite (Hummels et al., 2007; Zaki, 2014). The results also demonstrate that
Cambodia would be able to diversify its exports and production structure towards such trading
time sensitive products, particularly agriculture, agro-food, office equipment, and machinery,
On the other hand, the reduction of the same proportion of import tariffs leads to an
increase in household income and welfare due to the fall in prices and the rise in consumption;
yet investment declines substantially since the government budget and thus savings drop
following the decrease in tariff revenues. This suggests that gains from trade liberalization
would be more significant if combined with more efficient trade facilitation efforts.
From a policy point of view, while trade regime is critical in expanding international
sales, gains from exports cannot be fully realized if barriers at the borders are not minimized.
Time cost barriers, those other than the marginal costs of production itself, delay export
activities and consequently reduce the volume of exports. To tackle this issue, the improvement
investment related to trade public services such as the transportation and administration sectors.
168
communication, and the latter should take the form of improving customs registration and
building and higher wages of customs agent to avoid informal costs. The combination between
the two is crucial because the former cannot be developed effectively without the enhancement
of the supporting environment of the institutional procedure and risk management, which are
still in an early stage of development in Cambodia. The findings prove that the investment
initiative would enlarge further the economic gains generated by trade facilitation since it would
not only boost trade and production diversification but also upgrade economic productivity and
169
Chapter 7: Conclusion and Policy Implications
The rapid growth of the newly industrialized economies of East Asia—Hong Kong,
South Korea, Singapore and Taiwan—has influenced the economic view of the potential gains
of export orientation. Exports are no longer an element of income but a leader of growth. This
is also evidenced in the second tier of export-led growth economies such as Malaysia, Thailand,
the Philippines and Indonesia. Other countries in the region have been following this path, but
the achievements have been less pronounced. Cambodia is among them. Exports have
performed well since the start of liberalization in the early 1990s, but questions emerge as to
how robust and sustainable the performance is. The slow progress of diversification and the
low value added of the current manufacturing exports make Cambodia’s export market
vulnerable to external shocks and unable to contribute widely to the domestic economy. In
addition, a number of cross-cutting constraints related to trade facilitation hinder the growth of
both exports and other sectors although export potential exists. The limitations include the cost
and time of customs, standards, and logistics, together with the investment environment and
objectives. The first objective focused on the promotion of export expansion by identifying
what sectors would be promising for exports and connecting exports with economic linkages
through five indicators: (1) backward and forward linkages, (2) multiplier effects on income,
(3) labor intensity, (4) foreign exchange earnings, and (5) hypothetical extraction. Strategic
sectors with export potential should fall into most, if not all, of the five indicators. In another
words, strategic sectors should possess high backward and forward linkages with the rest of the
economy, should generate high income multiplier, should require high labor content, should be
net earners of foreign exchange, and should lead to an enormous impact on total outputs if the
sectors were eliminated from the economy. Given the results of the first objective, this
dissertation went further to examine the impacts of those key industries on economic growth,
170
employment and household welfare, and to measure to what extent domestic policies can work
to promote export orientation in those sectors. The last objective of the study, in addition,
measured how the improvement of trade facilitation, presented by tariff equivalents of time to
Main Findings
The results of the I-O analysis found that agriculture generates high employment, while
the food industry has strong linkages, generates substantial income multipliers and requires
relatively high labor intensity. Textiles would contribute to the greatest impacts on aggregate
output if this sector is closed down, yet possesses weak linkages. Rubber is highly linkage-
oriented and moderately significant in other indicators. For services, trade-transportation ranks
high in foreign exchange earnings and the hypothetical extraction exercise, whereas hotel-
restaurant is the top net exporter and is crucial in a few other indicators.
The findings suggested that high intermediate import dependency with the absence of
technical inter-industry linkages is a cause of concern for the export orientation process of
Cambodia. While the linkage-oriented industries, such as food and rubber, have not been able
to realize their full potential in exports, the current largest industry (textiles) is unlikely to
contribute enough profit to foster future growth due to the lack of linkages. The limited
interaction is evident when net exports are dominated by a few sectors and when most sectors
with relatively high connections in both income and labor intensity are neither the net earners
of foreign exchange nor the main contributors to outputs. This underscores that the potential of
exports can be realized through the requirements of not only diversification but also linkage
creation. According to the result of the indicators and the normalization scorings, the study
suggested that attention should be given to the following four key sectors: food-beverage-
171
The government also recognizes the importance of the above sectors, but more strategic
attention is needed. For one thing, agricultural products, particularly fishery, livestock and
crops, are in the list of potential exports of the Ministry of Commerce (2007). In addition, values
of agro-exports have increased gradually, accounting for five percent of total exports in 2011;
meanwhile, the Industrial Development Plan (RGC, 2015) also targets an increase of processed
agricultural exports to 12 percent of total exports in 2025. Cambodia has a positive prospect to
expand its food-processing exports provided the agricultural wealth and significant changes in
demand for ready-made food products in Asia. Despite its potential, this industry, other than
the rice subsector, has received little strategic attention with regard to domestic investment and
the creation of the value chains. Also, there is no national business association specific to this
Moreover, the industry is characterized by SMEs with emerging larger firms, both heavily focus
on domestic demand, while breaking into international market has just started. At the same
time, the lack of compliance with quality standards of Sanitary and Phyto-Sanitary (SPS)
measures is a key constraint. With these challenges, encouraging investment and value addition
Rubber production has increased in recent years due to investment extension and market
access. Rubber exports increased more than double from 2009 to 86,052 tons in 2013, mostly
in the form of natural rubber. 87 percent of formal natural rubber exports in 2007 went to
Vietnam, which has suitable facilities to process and re-export. Over the past five years,
however, this figure has declined to 58 percent as exports to other markets (China and Malaysia)
have grown due to significant expansion of production capacity and market diversification
efforts (MoC, 2014). However, the remaining challenge hinder rubber exports to a wider range
The increased investment and exports of hotel-restaurant services is largely due to the
strong tourism sector. International tourist arrivals increased from 2 million in 2007 to 4.5
172
million in 2014 with 68 percent of hotel occupancy (MoT, 2015). Despite the low cost of the
services, issues around the quality of food hygiene and sanitation persist. In addition, inadequate
transport and tourism infrastructure also adversely affects hotel-restaurant outputs. Leakage of
Following the findings on the promising export products, the study performed a series
of simulations to measure the impacts of those sectors on the economy, as well as to measure
the policy options to help improve the export orientation. The potential sectors in focus are
agro-industry (food and rubber) and agriculture. The results showed that export expansion of
these industries brings positive effects on economic growth and employment at the macro level,
broadens production diversification at the sectoral level, and improves welfare at the household
level, particularly for the rural poor. The simulations suggested that the contribution, including
the intermediate connection, of agro-exports were larger than that of agricultural exports.
Priority should be given to creating production chains from agriculture to processed food and
This target was also in line with the government’s aim to undertake some degree of
processing inside the country before exporting and to increase the total share of processed
agricultural exports, set in the Industrial Development Plan 2015-2025 (MoC, 2014, RGC,
2014). Milled rice export policy initiated by the government in 2010, for instance, has been a
vital road map for a significant improvement of this subsector. Besides milled rice, however,
there is a lack of practical strategies to promote other industrial food processing regardless of
viable opportunities to increase exports in the recent years. A more critical policy toward this
sector is required, not only to create the value chains from agriculture, but also to reduce too
much concentration on garment exports to minimize the high vulnerability resulting from
possible fluctuation in world price and in the current pattern of competitiveness within the
173
garment industry. As evident in the simulation results, the negative impact as a consequence of
the fluctuation in the world price of agro-exports is less severe than that of the garment exports.
These findings were also consistent with previous studies which suggested that agriculture and
the food industry contribute better to Cambodian domestic income while garments cannot
secure long-term distribution and competition (Chan & Oum, 2011; Kobayashi et al., 2009;
The analysis also revealed that the exporting sectors are low skilled and medium skilled-
intensive, reflecting an increase in demand for those two groups of workers to keep up with the
production and export supplies. Improving the productivity of these groups would further
benefit the economy. In addition, for the economy to expand the benefits that the productivity
of labor and capital generate, the market needs an enabling environment for more efficient
utilization of capital within the targeted sectors in the short term, and more flexible movement
of capital in the medium term. Finally, the influence of the potential industries would be greater
if combined with preferential treatment initiatives. The study found that the provision of export
subsidies or a combination of subsidy and protection policy would work as practical tools to
promote the export orientation of those sectors and bring favorable impacts on both growth and
employment.
While the direct policies are crucial for export promotion, the gains from trade cannot
be realized if barriers associated with trade facilitation are not addressed. There is a consensus
that trading procedures across borders plays a vital role in trade expansion as it affects both
exports and imports directly and indirectly. Notwithstanding, to what extent trade facilitation
affects the economy and export structure depends on the estimation tool. Tariff equivalents of
time to export and import represent trade facilitation in this research, and the impacts of the
174
The simulation results demonstrated that the reduction in time delays in export and
import by half would lead to an increase in GDP by 1.63 percent and export by 1.30 percent.
Household income and welfare also experience a remarkable progress. Exports accelerate,
which can be explained by the fall in F.O.B costs that traders have to pay otherwise, making
exports more beneficial without interrupting domestic sales, resulting in an increase in total
output and investment. Notably, saving time costs in trade does not benefit every sector the
same way. While agriculture, office equipment, and machinery exports see the most significant
impacts, rubber, other manufacturing and hotel services see the lowest. This shows that
agriculture and high value-added products are more sensitive to trading time, which is also
On the other hand, reduction in the same proportion of import tariffs resulted in an
increase of household income and welfare due to a fall in price and an increase in consumption,
yet GDP and investment decline. This suggested that gains from trade liberalization would be
more significant if this reform is combined with a more efficient trading environment. Finally,
facilitation improvement would be beneficial for the economy, particularly GDP and
investment. Trade surged on a larger scale, with exports greater than imports, whereas
production levels of all sectors see a more pronounced positive impact. Not only did agriculture
exports improve at a high level, processed food and rubber exports also soared significantly.
The findings reflected that the investment initiative would not only boost trade and production
diversification but would also upgrade economic productivity and public sector efficiency.
Policy Implications
Having identified the potential export sectors and having learned the impacts of
promotion policies as well as of trade facilitation, development strategies are needed to support
export performance. Some policy implications, which can be carried out by the Ministry of
175
- Prioritize three targeted export sectors—the processed food industry, rubber
for example, from crops, fish and animal products to processed food industrial
goods, from natural to processed rubber, and from forestry to wood and furniture
production.
Invest in clearing and storage houses for paddy rice and other produce to undergo
Provide subsidies to both local firms and large/foreign firms of the potential
industries. On one hand, most domestic firms, such as food processing, small
holding rubber plantations, and hotel-restaurants, are SMEs which base their
required. On the other hand, FDI in agro-food and rubber processing should also
export products, and tax exemption on imports for rubber and food
manufacturing machinery.
176
Combine subsidies with protection policy in the selected three sectors by
reducing export tax and imposing higher tariffs. The benefits are two-fold: to
- Improve trade facilitation efficiency through reduction of time delays across borders
by, at least, half of the number of days for export and import procedure. This effort
would be a crucial measure to increase agricultural and food exports and to diversify
production toward higher value-added commodities (as they are more responsive to
promote online access for customs registration and clearance, and make them
- Increase investment in transportation infrastructure and port quality and extend them
to rural and border areas to shorten time delays. The increase in investment can be
177
can be achieved through other actions such as public-private partnership and
regional cooperation.
“selective”, with some firms selected for special support, but this should be implemented with
caution to avoid high cost, rent-seeking, and un-competitiveness (Weiss, 2005). In addition to
the above recommendations, Policy experiences, which can be good lessons for Cambodia,
from some export-led growth countries are worthwhile for a review. First, Malaysia and
Thailand pursued import substitution and export promotion policy at the same time during the
production and exports grew rapidly compared to total exports. Incentive were specifically
provided to processed food sector in Thailand case, and rubber processing in Malaysia case.
Their experience shows that the development of agro-processing industries (firstly by domestic
firms in Thailand case) establishes large vertically integrated agri-business groups that
combines all stages of production and sectors, including transportation, financial and marketing
services (Reinhardt, 2000). Meanwhile, the two governments started the incentives to attract
FDIs which played a vital role in the support and provision of marketing networks and
technologies.
stimulated domestic industries to export part of their output by introducing various incentive
industries exporting at least 20% of production, allowance of promotional expense for export,
operation of various export financing facilities that provide domestic exporters with credit at
178
growing export was accompanied by imports of capital goods to support manufacturing sector
Third, successful experience in South Korea suggests that the policy implementation
can be carried out through two measures: (1) time-bound support which gives firms incentive
over time to develop competitiveness, such as the case of special tariff protection, and (2) a
form of competitiveness which comes through a series of “contests”, allowing firms to receive
special incentive, for example, according to achievement of export sales. Finally, SMEs,
accounting for a large share of enterprise (also in the case of Cambodia), should be highly
encouraged to get involved in export activities through the actions recommended above. As per
the experience of Taiwan, SMEs have been key private actors in export and in the establishment
The study is not without limitations. First, the selected key export industries, based on
the I-O analysis, which are mostly labor-intensive and with low technology, are not the best
options for long-term growth. The results of this study thus should be interpreted with caution.
central concern for development purposes. On the other hand, human capital must be improved,
and as long as this occurs, wage rates are expected to rise, making labor-intensive commodities
less competitive, and, in many cases, the investment would move to other locations with lower
wage costs. Exports would shrink unless export sectors upgrade. Hence, although the selected
industries are, to the greatest extent, important for the first stage of export-led growth, as has
been experienced by almost all of the NIEs, dependency on low-tech industries should not be
permanent.
Second, this current study has undertaken impact analysis based on macro simulations
and static modeling while microsimulations and dynamic assumption have not been taken into
account. If both assumptions were included in the estimations, the results would have been
179
more detailed and accurate. It is suggested that static models seem to underestimate the effects
of economic changes since they do not incorporate productivity and capital gains (Zaki, 2014).
Third, the 2011 SAM and 2009 household survey were used as a benchmark in the study.
Although the SAM is the most current available data during the study period, household surveys
Therefore, future studies should take into account these limitations for improvement.
For one thing, to sustain the long term growth and the technical progress, the promotion of
Cambodia’s exports should also include medium- and high-technological industries rather than
relying solely on labor-intensive sectors. The potential roles of medium-tech industries should
be on the next research agenda. In addition, the estimate of export orientation and trade
facilitation impacts on the next step of research should integrate microsimulations and dynamic
180
References
Abidin, M. Z. (2000). Case Study: Malaysia. In Asian Exports (pp. 295–329). Oxford University Press (China) Ltd.
ADB. (2013). Key Indicators for Asia and Pacific. Country Profile. Cambodia. Retrieved: November 2013
ADB, & ESCAP. (2009). Designing and Implementing Trade Facilitation in Asia and pacific. Asia Development
Bank.
Amirkhalkhali, S., & Dar, A. A. (1995). A varying-coefficients model of export expansion, factor accumulation and
economic growth: Evidence from cross-country, time series data. Economic Modelling, 12(4), 435–441.
APO. (2015). Productivity Databook 2015. Asian Productivity Organization: Keio Univeristy Press Inc., Tokyo.
Arslan, I., & van Wijnbergen, S. (1993). Export Incentives, Exchange Rate Policy and Export Growth in Turkey.
The Review of Economics and Statistics, 75(1), 128.
Athukorala, P., & Sen, K. (1998). Processed food exports from developing countries: patterns and determinants.
Food Policy, 23(1), 41–54.
Atique, Z., Ahmad, M. H., & Zaman, A. (2003). The Supply and Demand for Exports of Pakistan: The
Polynomial Distributed Lag Model (PDL) Approach [with Comments]. The Pakistan Development
Review, 961–972.
Balassa, B. (1978). Exports and economic growth: further evidence. Journal of Development Economics, 5(2),
181–189.
Bank, W. (2013). Resilience Amidst a Challenging Environment: Cambodia Economic Update, September 2013
(World Bank Other Operational Studies No. 16632). The World Bank.
Banse, M., Gay, S. H., McDonald, S., M’Barek, R., Swinnen, J. F., & others. (2007). Competitiveness in the Food
Industry: a CGE Modelling Approach to assess Foreign Direct Investment in Transition Countries. In
104th Seminar, September 5-8, 2007, Budapest, Hungary. European Association of Agricultural
Economists.
Blanchflower, D., & Oswald, A. J. (1994). An introduction to the wage curve. American Economic Association,
9(3), 153–167.
Brooks, D. H. (2009). Infrastructure’s role in lowering Asia’s trade costs. In Infrastructure’s role in lowering
Asia’s trade costs. Edward Elgar.
Burfisher, M. E. (2011). Introduction to Computable General Equilibrium Models. Cambridge University Press.
Chan, S., & Oum, S. (2011). Impact of garment and textile trade preferences on livelihood in Cambodia (Oxfam
America Research Backgrounders Series, 2011). f
Chea, S., & Sok, H. (2005). Cambodia’s accession to the WTO:“Fast track”accession by a least developed
country. Managing the Challenges of WTO Participation, 45, 120–34.
Chhuor, S. (2016). Specification of Key Sectors of Cambodian Economy: Application of Input-Output Analysis
on Export Potentials. Forum of International Development Studies, 47(7).
Das, D. K. (2000). Asian Exports: The present Predicament. In Asian Exports (pp. 1–22). Oxford University Press.
De, P. (2006). Trade, infrastructure and transaction costs: the imperatives for Asian economic cooperation.
Journal of Economic Integration, 21(4), 708.
Dennis, A., & Shepherd, B. (2011). Trade facilitation and export diversification. The World Economy, 34(1),
101–122.
Djankov, S., Freund, C., & Pham, C. S. (2010). Trading on time. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 92(1),
166–173.
181
Decaluwe, B., Lemelin, A., Robichaud, V., & Maisonnave, H. (2013, July). PEP-1-1 the PEP standard single-
country, static CGE model. Partnership for Economic Policy-PEP.
Ear, S. (2005). The Political Economy of Pro-Poor Livestock Policy in Cambodia. PPLPI Working Paper No. 26.
Feenstra, R. C. (2002). Border effects and the gravity equation: consistent methods for estimation. Scottish
Journal of Political Economy, 49(5), 491–506.
Ferriol, A., Hoang, X., Gonzalez, A., & Hernandez, A. (2006). Cuba-export promotion, poverty, inequality and
growth in the 1990s. Who Gains from Free Trade? Export-Led Growth, Inequality and Poverty in Latin
America, 231–69.
Ganuza, E., Morley, S., Piñeiro, V., Robinson, S., & Vos, R. (2005). Are Export Promotion and Trade
Liberalisation Good for Latin America’s Poor? Development Policy Review, 23(3), 385–403.
Ha, S. J., & Swales, J. K. (2012). The export-base model with a supply-side stimulus to the export sector. The
Annals of Regional Science, 49(2), 323–353.
Hang Chuon, N. (2011). Cambodian Economy: Charting the Course of a Brighter Future : a Survey of Progress,
Problems, and Prospects. Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.
Hara, T. (2008). Quantitative Tourism Industry Analysis. Routledge.
Havrila, I., & Gunawardana, P. (2006). Determinants of export supply of the Australian textiles industry.
Economic Analysis and Policy, 36(1/2), 45.
Hazari, B. R., & Kingma, O. T. (1976). Trade and Linkages in Economic Development:The Position of the
Agricultural Sector in Australia and New Zealand*. Economic Record, 52(3), 362–372.
Heng, D., Senh, S., Ngim, S., Ear, S., Em, K., & Chan, T. (2014). Impacts of Cambodia’s Trade Liberalization
on Households’s Welfare and Labor Market: A CGE Analysis. Partnership for Economic Policy-PEP.
Hertel, T. W., Walmsley, T., & Itakura, K. (2001). Dynamic effects of the“ new age” free trade agreement
between Japan and Singapore. Journal of Economic Integration, 446–484.
Hosoe, N., Gasawa, K., & Hashimoto, H. (2010). Textbook of computable general equilibrium modeling:
programming and simulations. Palgrave Macmillan.
Hummels, D. (2001). Time as a Trade Barrier. Purdue University.
Hummels, D. L., & Schaur, G. (2013). Time as a Trade Barrier. American Economic Review, 103(7), 2935–2959.
Hummels, D., Minor, P., Reisman, M., & Endean, E. (2007). Calculating Tariff Equivalents for Time in Trade.
Nathan Association Inc.
IMF. (2012). Cambodia: Staff Report for the 2012 Article IV Consultation (Country’s Report No. 13/2).
Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Jiménez, W. (2007). Bolivia–export promotion and its effects on growth, employment and poverty. Who Gains
from Free Trade: Export-Led Growth, Inequality and Poverty in Latin America, 150.
Jongwanich, J. (2010). Determinants of Export Performance in East and Southeast Asia. World Economy, 33(1),
20–41.
Jongwanich, J., & Magtibay-Ramos, N. (2009). Determinants of structural change in food exports from
developing countries. Asian-Pacific Economic Literature, 23(2), 94–115.
Jung, W. S., & Marshall, P. J. (1985). Exports, growth and causality in developing countries. Journal of
Development Economics, 18(1), 1–12.
Kabir Hassan, M., & Tufte, D. R. (1998). Exchange rate volatility and aggregate export growth in Bangladesh.
Applied Economics, 30(2), 189–201.
182
Keo, K. (2002). The Challenge of the Cambodian Economy. Centre for ASEAN Studies. Centre for International
Management and Development Antwerp.
Khalafalla, K. Y., & Webb, A. J. (2001). Export–led growth and structural change: evidence from Malaysia.
Applied Economics, 33(13), 1703–1715.
Khondoker, M., & Kalirajan, K. (2012). Determinants of Labor-Intensive Exports by the Developing Countries:
A Cross Country Analysis. ASARC Working Paper 2012/09.
Kobayashi, S., Saito, K., Tanji, H., Huang, W., & Tada, M. (2008). Economic Structure of Cambodia and
Strategies for Pro-Poor Growth: Results from a Computable General Equilibrium Analysis. Studies in
Regional Science, 38(1), 137–154.
Kobayashi, S., Tanji, H., Saito, K., Huang, W., & Tada, M. (2009). Industrial Structure of Cambodia and the Role
of Agriculture and Fishery in its Development. Japan Agricultural Research Quarterly: JARQ, 43(4),
309–316.
Krueger, A. O. (2000). Factors Affecting Export Growth and Performance and the Asian Case. In Asian Exports
(pp. 25–71). Oxford University Press.
MAFF. (2015). Agricultural Sector Strategic Development Plan 2014-2018 (Strategic Development Plan).
Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries.
Majeed, M. T., Ahmad, E., & Khawaja, M. I. (2006). Determinants of Exports in Developing Countries [with
Comments]. The Pakistan Development Review, 1265–1276.
Markusen, J. R., Melvin, J. R., Maskus, K. E., & Kaempfer, W. (1995). International trade: theory and evidence.
University Library of Munich, Germany.
McCallum, J. (1995). National borders matter: Canada-US regional trade patterns. The American Economic
Review, 85(3), 615–623.
McNab, R. M., & Moore, R. E. (1998). Trade policy, export expansion, human capital and growth. The Journal
of International Trade & Economic Development, 7(2), 237–256.
Meller, P., & Marfán, M. (1981). Small and Large Industry: Employment Generation, Linkages, and Key Sectors.
Economic Development and Cultural Change, 29(2), 263–274.
Melo, J. de, & Robinson, S. (1992). Productivity and externalities: models of export-led growth. The Journal of
International Trade & Economic Development, 1(1), 41–68.
Miller, R. E., & Blair, P. D. (2009). Input-Output Analysis: Foundations and Extensions. Cambridge University Press.
Minor, P. (2013). Time as a Barrier to Trade: A GTAP Database of ad valorem Trade Time Costs. ImpactECON,
Second Edition.
Minor, P., & Tsigas, M. (2008). Impacts of Better Trade Facilitation in Developing Countries.
MOC. (2006, July). Cambodia National Export Strategy 2007-2010. Ministry of Commerce, Cambodia and
International Trade Center, UUCTAD/WTO.
MoC. (2007, December). Trade Related Assistance for Development and Equity. Trade Related Assistance for
Development and Equity. Ministry of Commerce and United Nations Development Programme,
Cambodia.
MoC. (2012, March). Trade Sector Wide Approach. Pillars’ Road Maps. Ministry of Commerce, Royal
Government of Cambodia.
MoC. (2014). Cambodia Trade Integration Strtegy 2014-2018 (Full Report). Phnom Penh.
183
Moschos, D. (1989). Export expansion, growth and the level of economic development: An empirical analysis.
Journal of Development Economics, 30(1), 93–102.
MoT. (2015). Tourism Statistics Report. Ministry of Tourism. Staff Report.
Mujeri, M. K., & Alauddin, M. (1994). Trade and Linkages Using Input-Output Approach: An Empirical
Investigation of Bangladesh. The Pakistan Development Review, 75–92.
Ninkovic, J. (2009, February 15). What Determines Export Success in Labor-Intensive Goods?
NIS. (2011). Statistical Yearbook of Cambodia. Cambodia: National Institute of Statistic, Ministry of Planning.
NIS. (2013). Poverty in Cambodia - A New Approach. Redefining the poverty line. Ministry of Planning,
National Institute of Statistic.
North, D. C. (1961). The economic growth of the United States, 1790-1860. Prentice-Hall Englewood Cliffs, NJ.
Paelinck, J., Caevel, J. de, & Degueldre, J. (1965). Analyse quantitative de certains phénomènes du
développement régional polarisé: essai de simulation statique d’itinéraires de propagation’. Problèmes
de Conversion Economique: Analyses Théoriques et Etudes Appliquées, 341–387.
Parikh, A. (1979). An input-output approach to the estimation of employment requirements in Europe. Empirical
Economics, 4(3), 149–165.
Ram, R. (1985). Exports and economic growth: Some additional evidence. Economic Development and Cultural
Change, 33(2), 415–425.
Rasmussen, P. N. (1956). Studies in inter-sectoral relations (Vol. 15). E. Harck.
Rassekh, F. (2004). The interplay of international trade, economic growth and income convergence: a brief
intellectual history of recent developments. The Journal of International Trade & Economic
Development, 13(4), 371–395.
Reinhardt, N. (2000). Back to Basics in Malaysia and Thailand: The Role of Resource-Based Exports in Their
Export-Led Growth. World Development, 28(1), 57–77.
Royal Government of Cambodia. (2010). Policy Paper and the Prduction of Paddy Production and Rice Export.
Council of Ministries.
Royal Government of Cambodia. (2015). Cambodia Industrial Development Policy 2015-2025.
Sachs, J. D., Warner, A., Aslund, A., & Fischer, S. (1995). Economic Reform and the Process of Global
Integration. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1995(1), 1.
Sánchez, M. V., & Sauma, P. (2006). Costa Rica-export-orientation and its effect on growth, inequality and
poverty. Who Gains from Free Trade? Export-Led Growth, Inequality and Poverty in Latin America,
204–30.
Santos-Paulino, A. U. (2002). Trade Liberalisation and Export Performance in Selected Developing Countries.
Journal of Development Studies, 39(1), 140–164.
Strassert, G. (1968). Zur bestimmung strategischer sektoren mit hilfe von input-output-modellen. Jahrbücher Für
Nationalökonomie Und Statistik, 211–215.
Tarp, H., & Tarp, J. F. (2004). On the choice of appropriate development strategy: Insights gained from CGE
modelling of the Mozambican economy. Journal of African Economies, 13(3), 446–478.
Temurshoev, U. (2010). Identifying Optimal Sector Groupings with the Hypothetical Extraction Method. Journal
of Regional Science, 50(4), 872–890.
Todaro, M. P., & Smith, S. C. (2009). Economic Development (10th ed.). Addison-Wesley.
Tung, A. C. (2000). Case Study: Taipei, China. In Asian Exports (pp. 249–290). Oxford University Press.
184
Tyler, W. G. (1981). Growth and export expansion in developing countries: Some empirical evidence. Journal
of Development Economics, 9(1), 121–130. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3878(81)90007-9
UN Comtrade. (2016, June). International Trade Statistics. Retrieved from http://comtrade.un.org/data/
UNCTAD. (2012). International Trade in Goods and Services. Inited Nations Conference on Trade and
Development, UnctadStat. Retrieved from May 2013.
UNCTAD. (2014). International Trade in Goods and Services. Inited Nations Conference on Trade and
Development, UnctadStat. Retrieved from July 2014.
UNIDO. (2011). Viet Nam Industrial Competitiveness Report (Policy Advice-Industrial Policy). UNIDO and
Ministry of Industry and Trade of Viet Nam.
Valadkhani, A. (2003). Using input-output analysis to identify Australia’s high employment generating
industries. Faculty of Commerce-Papers, 392.
Vos, R. (2007). Who Gains from Free Trade: Export-Led Growth, Inequality and Poverty in Latin America.
Routledge.
Warr, P. G. (2000). Case Study: Thailand. In Asian Exports (pp. 335–380). Oxford University Press.
WDI. (2012). World Development Indicator 2013. World DataBank. World Bank. Retrieved: September 2013
WDI. (2015). World Development Indicator 2015. World Data Bank. World Bank. Retrieved: July 2015
Weiss, J. (2005). Export growth and industrial policy: Lessons from the East Asian miracle experience. Asian
Development Bank Institute.
Wilson, J. S., Mann, C. L., & Otsuki, T. (2003). Trade facilitation and economic development: A new approach
to quantifying the impact. The World Bank Economic Review, 17(3), 367–389.
Wilson, J. S., Mann, C. L., & Otsuki, T. (2005). Assessing the benefits of trade facilitation: A global perspective.
The World Economy, 28(6), 841–871.
World Bank. (2009). Cambodia Sustaining Rapid Growth in a Challenging Environment: Country Economic
Memorandum (No. No. 49158-KH). Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Sector Unit, East
Asia and Pacific Region, World Bank.
World Bank. (2015). Cambodia economic update : maintaining high growth (No. 95982) (pp. 1–35). The World Bank.
WTO Secretariat. (2011a). Trade Policy Review: Cambodia (Policy Review No. No. WT/TPR/S/253). World
Trade Organization.
WTO Secretariat. (2011b). Trade Policy Review: Cambodia (Policy Review No. No. WT/TPR/G/253). World
Trade Organization.
Yaghmaian, B. (1994). An empirical investigation of exports, development, and growth in developing countries:
Challenging the neoclassical theory of export-led growth. World Development, 22(12), 1977–1995.
Yamagata, T. (2006). The Garment Industry in Cambodia: Its Role in Poverty Reduction through Export-
Orientated Development (IDE Discussion Paper. No. 62. 2006.6).
Yanikkaya, H. (2003). Trade openness and economic growth: a cross-country empirical investigation. Journal of
Development Economics, 72(1), 57–89.
Zaki, C. (2010). Towards an explicit modeling of trade facilitation in CGE models: evidence from Egypt.
Working Paper No. 15. Economic Research Forum
Zaki, C. (2014). An empirical assessment of the trade facilitation initiative: econometric evidence and global
economic effects. World Trade Review, 13(1), 103–130.
185
Appendix
Table A.1: Merchandise exports by group of products (for Chapter 2, Section 2.1.2)
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
Table A.1: Merchandise exports by group of products
Total exports (US$ million) 2,434.60 (for Chapter
2,910.30 2, Section
2,962.50 3,456.002.1.2.1)
2,986.70 3,808.70
(% of total)
Total primary products 3.2 2.8 2.9 5.5 4.5 5.7
Agriculture 3.1 2.8 2.8 2 3.2 5.6
Food 1.2 0.8 0.9 0.8 1.3 2.1
0423 Rice, milled, semi-milled 0.1 0.1 0 0.1 0.4 0.9
Agricultural raw material 2 2 1.9 1.1 1.9 3.4
2312 Natural rubber excluding latex 1.4 1.5 1.4 0.9 1.6 2.1
2473 Wood rough, painted, preserved 0 0 0 0 0.1 0.8
Mining 0 0 0.1 3.5 1.3 0.2
Ores and other minerals 0 0 0.1 3.5 1.2 0.2
Non-ferrous metals 0 0 0 0.1 0.1 0
Fuels 0 0 0 0 0 0
186