Principle of Economics
Principle of Economics
OF
ECONOMICS
Disclaimer: All are samples - Writers are not liable for these questions and answers.
Economic models are used in economics to study a wide range of issues, such as how markets allocate
resources, the effects of government policies on the economy, and the behavior of consumers and firms.
They can be used to make predictions about economic outcomes, test theories, and evaluate the impacts
of different policies or economic conditions.
Economic models typically involve identifying key variables and assumptions that are relevant to the issue
being studied. These variables can include things like prices, quantities, production levels, and consumer
behavior. Assumptions are made about how these variables interact with one another, and how they
respond to changes in other economic factors.
Once a model has been constructed, it can be used to analyze different scenarios and evaluate the likely
outcomes of different policy choices or economic conditions. For example, an economic model might be
used to predict the impact of a tax increase on consumer behavior and the overall economy. By examining
how changes in tax rates affect key economic variables like consumer spending and investment,
economists can make informed predictions about the likely outcomes of different policy choices.
In summary, economic models are simplified representations of economic systems or processes used to
analyze and understand economic phenomena. They are an important tool in economics, allowing
economists to make predictions, test theories, and evaluate the impacts of different policies or economic
conditions. By making assumptions about key economic variables and their interactions, economic models
help to simplify complex economic interactions and highlight key relationships between economic
variables.
In contrast, a regulated economy is an economic system in which the government plays an active role in
controlling and regulating economic activity. In a regulated economy, the government may set prices,
regulate production levels, or control the distribution of goods and services.
The main differences between a market economy and a regulated economy are as follows:
Resource allocation: In a market economy, resources are allocated through the price mechanism,
which is determined by supply and demand. In a regulated economy, the government determines
how resources are allocated.
Efficiency: A market economy is generally considered to be more efficient than a regulated
economy, as prices provide incentives for firms to produce goods and services at the lowest
possible cost. In a regulated economy, government regulations can create inefficiencies and reduce
the incentives for firms to innovate.
Equity: A regulated economy may be better at ensuring a more equitable distribution of resources,
as the government can use regulations and policies to promote social welfare goals such as income
redistribution. In a market economy, the distribution of resources is determined by the forces of
supply and demand, which may result in greater income inequality.
Innovation: A market economy is typically more conducive to innovation and technological
progress, as firms have a greater incentive to innovate in order to stay competitive. In a regulated
economy, government regulations and bureaucracy may stifle innovation.
Economic growth: A market economy is generally associated with higher rates of economic
growth, as the incentives for innovation and efficiency lead to increased productivity and output.
In a regulated economy, government control and regulation may restrict economic growth.
Therefore, the key difference between a change in quantity demanded and a change in demand is that the
former is caused by a change in the price of a good, while the latter is caused by other factors that affect
the entire demand curve.
MD SAIDUL ALAM RJAN 7
Principle of Economics
Question 2. How do market forces of demand and supply determine
the price and quantity of goods in a competitive market?
Answer: Forces of demand and supply determine the equilibrium price when they are same and
graphically the point at which demand and supply intersect is equilibrium point and price is determined.
The demand curve represents the quantity of a good that consumers are willing and able to buy at different
prices, while the supply curve represents the quantity of the same good that producers are willing and able
to sell at different prices.
Conversely, if the price of the good is initially above the equilibrium price, then the quantity supplied
exceeds the quantity demanded, leading to excess supply or a surplus in the market. This creates downward
pressure on the price, as producers compete to sell their excess supply, and consumers respond by
decreasing their demand due to the higher price.
In both cases, the market forces of demand and supply interact to adjust the price and quantity of the good
until the equilibrium point is reached, where the quantity demanded equals the quantity supplied, resulting
in a stable market price and quantity for the good.
Simultaneous shifts in demand and supply: When both demand and supply shift at the same time, the
resulting changes in price and quantity are dependent on the magnitude and direction of the shifts. If both
demand and supply increase, then the equilibrium quantity will increase, but the price change will depend
on which shift is larger. If demand increases more than supply, then the equilibrium price will also
increase. If supply increases more than demand, then the equilibrium price will decrease. Similarly, if both
demand and supply decrease, then the equilibrium quantity will decrease, but the change of price will
depend on larger shift.
In summary, shifts and changes in demand and supply can affect the equilibrium price and quantity of a
good in different ways, and the resulting changes in price and quantity depend on the magnitude and
direction of the shifts.
Utility analysis assumes that consumers have a certain level of satisfaction or utility from consuming
goods and services. The utility analysis is done by measuring the utility that a consumer receives from
consuming a good or service, and this is typically done using a utility function. A utility function is a
mathematical representation of the consumer's preferences, and it shows the amount of utility the
consumer receives from different combinations of goods and services. The utility function helps to
determine the level of satisfaction or utility that the consumer derives from consuming a particular
combination of goods and services.
To determine consumer equilibrium, both utility analysis and indifference curve analysis are used
together. Consumer equilibrium occurs at the point where the budget constraint is tangent to the highest
possible indifference curve. In other words, the consumer is choosing a combination of goods that provides
the highest possible level of satisfaction or utility, given their budget constraint.
The budget constraint is determined by the consumer's income and the prices of the goods and services
that they consume. The budget constraint represents all the possible combinations of goods and services
that the consumer can purchase given their income and the prices of the goods and services.
By analyzing the consumer's preferences and budget constraint, utility analysis and indifference curve
analysis help to determine the optimal combination of goods and services that a consumer can purchase
to maximize their satisfaction or utility. This combination is the consumer equilibrium, and it is
determined by the intersection of the budget constraint and the highest possible indifference curve.
Consumer surplus is calculated in microeconomics as the area between the demand curve and the actual
market price of a good or service. To calculate consumer surplus, we first need to know the demand curve
for the good or service, which shows the quantity of the good or service that consumers are willing and
able to buy at different prices.
Next, we need to determine the actual market price of the good or service. Consumer surplus is the
difference between the maximum price that consumers are willing to pay for the good or service, as
indicated by the demand curve, and the actual market price of the good or service.
The consumer surplus can be calculated as the area between the demand curve and the market price, up to
the quantity that is actually purchased. Mathematically, it can be represented as:
Consumer surplus always increases as the price of a good falls and decreases as the price of a good rises.
For example, suppose consumers are willing to pay $50 for the first unit of product A and $20 for the 50th
unit. If 50 of the units are sold at $20 each, then 49 of the units were sold at a consumer surplus, assuming
the demand curve is constant. Consumer surplus is zero when the demand for a good is perfectly elastic.
But demand is perfectly inelastic when consumer surplus is infinite.
Price ceilings and floors can have unintended consequences, such as creating shortages or surpluses,
reducing the quality of the goods or services provided, or leading to black markets where the good or
service is sold at a higher price. Overall, price controls can distort the functioning of the market and reduce
overall welfare for both consumers and producers.
This formula measures the percentage change in the quantity demanded of a good or service in response
to a percentage change in its price. If the elasticity of demand is greater than one, the good or service is
considered to be elastic, meaning that a small change in price leads to a large change in the quantity
demanded. If the elasticity of demand is less than one, the good or service is considered to be inelastic,
meaning that a change in price has a small impact on the quantity demanded.
Let us take the simple example of gasoline. Now let us assume that a surge of 60% in gasoline price
resulted in a decline in the purchase of gasoline by 15%. Using the formula as mentioned above, the
calculation of price elasticity of demand can be done as:
The law of demand states that as the price of a good or service increases, the quantity demanded will
decrease, and as the price decreases, the quantity demanded will increase. This relationship is due to the
fact that consumers are generally willing to purchase more of a good or service when it is cheaper, and
less of it when it is more expensive.
When people are thirsty, the highest level of satisfaction they gain is from the first glass of water or juice
they consume. However, as they proceed to the glass of water or juice for the second time, it is less
satisfying as they are not as thirsty as they were before having the first glass of water/juice. Thus, their
urge to consume it reduces with every additional glass.
Units Total Utility Marginal Utility
1 10 10
2 19 9
3 27 8
4 22 5
5 20 2
6 19 1
‘Too many cooks spoil the broth’. The law of diminishing returns discusses this in the context of
production. The law of diminishing marginal productivity helps in understanding why increased
manufacturing is not always the best way to increase profitability.
For example, Dominos opens for business but with a single worker. The worker produces six pizzas
in a day. However, the business owner decides to add workers to increase productivity. The table
below shows the schedule of hired workers and the input:
Input Output
Marginal
(No. of (No. of
Product
workers) Pizzas)
0 0 –
1 6 6
2 14 8
3 17 3
4 19 2
5 19 0
6 16 -3
From the table, we can see that marginal product began to diminish from the third worker until it
became negative by the sixth worker. On the other hand, total output began to stagnate at the fifth
worker and fell at the sixth worker. It could be that as the workers increased, the space in the kitchen
became smaller. As such, the productivity of each worker fell because they started getting in each
other’s way.
B 2 9 100
C 3 8 100
D 4 7 100
Iso-quant Map: An iso-quant map shows the different iso-quant curves representing the different
combinations of factors of production, yielding the different levels of output. Thus, higher the iso-quant
curve, the higher is the level of output.
MRTSLK = – ∆K/∆L
Where,
∆K = is the change in capital and
AL = is the change in labor.
Equation states that for an increase in the use of labor, fewer units of capital will be used. In other words,
a declining MRTS refers to the falling marginal product of labor in relation to capital. To put it differently,
as more units of labor are used, and as certain units of capital are given up, the marginal productivity of
labor in relation to capital will decline.
Marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS): The slope of an iso-quant curve is called the rate of
technical substitution, which means how much capital are to be substituted for the labor to give the same
quantity of production if the labor is reduced by 1 unit. MRTS, on the graph shows the rate at which a
given input, either labor or capital, can be substituted for the other while keeping the same output level.
The MRTS is represented by the absolute value of an isoquant's slope at a chosen point. A decline in
MRTS along an isoquant for producing the same level of output is called the diminishing marginal rate of
substitution.
Perfect competition: This market structure is characterized by a large number of small firms that
produce identical products and have no market power. Firms in perfect competition are price takers,
meaning they must accept the market price and cannot influence it.
Monopoly: A monopoly is a market structure in which there is only one seller of a particular product,
and no close substitutes are available. This gives the monopolist substantial market power and the
ability to set prices above the competitive level.
Oligopoly: An oligopoly is a market structure in which a few large firms dominate the market. Each
firm has some degree of market power, and their behavior is interdependent, meaning that they must
take into account the actions of their rivals when making strategic decisions.
These market structures differ from one another in terms of the number and size of firms, the degree
of market power they have, and the level of product differentiation. The characteristics of each market
structure have important implications for the behavior of firms and the outcomes of markets.
Long Run Equilibrium: Firms’ supernormal profits in the short run will encourage other
firms to enter in the long run. As a result, the supply of the group increases, and the market share of
individual firms will decline. So, the demand curve of the firms will shift down, implying that each
firm can sell less quantity at every price than he sold in the short run. The market will be at equilibrium
in the long run only if there is no exit or entry in the market anymore. The firms will not exit or enter
the market only if every firm makes zero profit. This is the reason why we name this market structure
monopolistic competition.
If we want to calculate the profit, normally we take the difference between the demand curve and the
average total cost and multiply the difference with the equilibrium output. However, the difference is
0 since the curves are tangent. As we expect, the firm is making zero profit in the equilibrium.
Cartels are difficult to maintain. The problem is that cartel members will be tempted to cheat on their
agreement to limit production. By producing more output than it has agreed to produce, a cartel
member can increase its share of the cartel's profits. Some following obstacles for Oligopoly cartel:
In both cases, externalities can result in a misallocation of resources since the costs or benefits are not
fully accounted for in the market price. Governments and policymakers often intervene to address
these externalities through regulations, taxes, subsidies, or other measures to internalize the costs or
benefits and promote a more efficient allocation of resources.