Against The Odds Deviant Cases of Democratization
Against The Odds Deviant Cases of Democratization
Against The Odds Deviant Cases of Democratization
To cite this article: Renske Doorenspleet & Petr Kopecký (2008) Against the Odds: Deviant Cases
of Democratization, Democratization, 15:4, 697-713, DOI: 10.1080/13510340802191045
R E N S K E D O O R E N S P L E E T a n d P E T R K O P E C K Ý
Economic development and diffusion effects appear to exert substantial influence on the
success of democratization. However, large-N quantitative studies also show that there are
some ‘outliers’, or ‘deviant’ cases, which do not fit the general pattern and cannot be explained
by existing theories and models. It appears that deviant cases of democratization include Costa
Rica and India (since the 1940s), Botswana (since the 1960s) and Benin and Mongolia (since
the 1990s). This introduction focuses on important conceptual, theoretical, and methodological
problems involved when studying them. We first look at the highly contested concept of
democracy and place ‘deviant democracies’ in the framework of a minimal definition of
democracy and transition waves. We also provide a working definition for two other highly
contested concepts – democratic transition and democratic consolidation. We then go on to
briefly review existing general theories of democratization. By doing so, we lay the ground
for specifying more precisely the level of ‘deviancy’ of our cases, and offer potential expla-
nations for their unusually successful process of democratization. Finally, we outline the
nested mixed method, the logic of which we follow in this special issue.
Key words: economic development; diffusion; transition; consolidation; deviant cases; nested
mixed method
Introduction
Democracy has become the widely accepted norm within the international commu-
nity. States seeking international legitimacy are increasingly forced to embrace
democratic forms of governance, or else may face sanctions from the international
community, including exclusion from international negotiations. The diplomatic
row over the possible exclusion of Zimbabwe’s embattled President Robert
Mugabe from the European-African Union Summit in December 2007 is a good
example of the current international climate. Democracy also features prominently
on the foreign policy agenda of most western countries, including that of the
United States under George W. Bush’s two administrations. Yet, despite this
recent global democratic spirit, the idea that democracy can take root in every soil
is disputed: structural factors do matter.1 Human beings – political leaders, activists,
citizens, or foreign donors – act within a political, social and economic context that
Renske Doorenspleet is Associate Professor at the Department of Politics and International Studies at the
University of Warwick, United Kingdom. She is also director of the Centre for Studies in Democratization.
Petr Kopecký is a Research Fellow of the Netherlands Organization for Scientific Research (NWO), based
at Leiden University, the Netherlands.
Democratization, Vol.15, No.4, August 2008, pp.697– 713
ISSN 1351-0347 print/1743-890X online
DOI: 10.1080/13510340802191045 # 2008 Taylor & Francis
698 DEMOCRATIZATION
may be more or less favourable for democracy. There is strong evidence, for example,
which shows that economic factors and the presence of democratic neighbours have
substantially increased the probability of a regime becoming democratic.
However, there are important exceptions to this general pattern. These are what
we call ‘deviant democracies:’ countries that have seemingly beaten the odds and
democratized within an unfavourable structural setting. Within the so-called fourth
wave of democratization, from 1989 onwards, Benin and Mongolia represent
primary examples of deviant cases of democratization.2 Prior to this time, other
historical examples can be found: Costa Rica and India since the late 1940s, and
Botswana since the 1960s. These political systems meet the minimal criteria for
democracy3 in that they have competitive elections and inclusive suffrage. They
are ‘deviant democracies,’ however, because they lack the standard ‘requisites’ for
democracy mentioned by the modernization perspective4 and, at the same time,
they have become democratic while neighbouring countries remained undemocratic.
Deviant democracies have democratized against the odds. The collection of
articles in this special issue aims to provide a better understanding of the exceptional
and anomalous nature of democratization in these countries. It is the first time that
these special cases from different parts of the world and from different periods of
time have been brought together under a single analytical framework in order to
draw out similarities and differences in their unusual paths towards democratization.
Ultimately, the aim of the collection is to contribute to existing theories of democra-
tization by providing a more refined explanation for democratic regime change, one
which puts structural explanations alongside a systematic focus on the role of leader-
ship, civil society, and political institutions.
This paper aims to embed the five country case studies in a broader comparative
context by focusing on important conceptual, definitional, and theoretical problems
in the study of ‘deviant cases of democratization’. We first look at the highly contested
concept of democracy, and place ‘deviant democracies’ in the framework of a minimal
definition of democracy and transition waves. We provide a working definition for two
other highly contested concepts, democratic transition and democratic consolidation,
which are used as the starting point of the empirical analysis in all the country case
studies. We then go on briefly to examine existing theories of democratization.
This, in turn, will enable us both to specify more precisely the level of ‘deviancy’ of
our cases, and to offer potential explanations for their unusually successful processes
of democratization. Finally, we summarize the nested mixed method, the logic of
which we follow in this special issue. By outlining the generic theoretical, conceptual,
and methodological basis of this project on deviant democracies, we aim to provide a
general analytical framework for the subsequent articles on specific deviant cases.
many of the new democratic regimes, which emerged during the last two decades, can
be characterized by inclusive suffrage and competition but, at the same time, by
insufficient protection of civil and political liberties.11 In addition, as O’Donnell
pointed out in an influential essay, many of the long enduring polyarchies also
feature clientelism, particularism, and executive dominance, all of which severely
undermine both the horizontal accountability among the institutions and the adher-
ence to the formal rules of the democratic game.12 Consequently, Linz and Stepan
have argued that one of the more interesting subfields of contemporary democratiza-
tion studies is the focus on the rich variety of new polyarchies; i.e. regimes that fall
within the bounds of a minimal definition of democracy, but that differ in the level of
practical compliance with democratic rules.13
Clearly, minimal democracy or electoral democracy14 may be deepened into a
democratic regime which is not only competitive and inclusive, but also displays
no major violations of civil and political liberties, has little or no endemic corruption
that undermines state institutions, and ensures the rule of law for all citizens. Minimal
or electoral democracies can overcome some of the deficiencies that frequently
plague them, and may eventually develop into fully-fledged liberal democracies.
But it is, of course, equally possible that no progress from an electoral towards a
liberal democracy is made or, worse, that an electoral democracy sinks back into
some form of authoritarianism. The cases in this collection have all been minimal
democracies, although not all have necessarily developed into liberal democracies.
In other words, despite being located on different continents, having different
levels of economic and social development, and having different sizes of population,
all the countries in this collection share a successful transition to a minimal democ-
racy. Arguably, most have also succeeded in the process of democratic consolidation.
Waves of Transitions
The transitions among our ‘deviant cases of democratization’ took place during
several periods in history. Especially since the publication of Samuel Huntington’s
influential study of democratization, scholars have come to take for granted the
notion that the spread of democracy has come in waves, with bursts of progress
being succeeded by quite substantial reversals, and with the pattern of flow and
ebb marking a less than optimistic two-step forwards, one-step backwards pattern.27
It is clear that there has been a significant wave of democratization since 1974,
and an explosion of democratization since 1989. Previous study showed, however,
that, with the exception of the first wave of transition to democracy (until 1924),
Huntington’s other waves could not be distinguished clearly.28 The first reverse
wave, between 1924 and 1944, and the second wave of democratization, during
the mid-1940s and 1950s, are neither significant nor convincing. Moreover, there
is no clear second reverse wave of democratization which, according to Huntington,
should have been apparent between 1957 and 1973. In fact, this period is better
described as one of trendless fluctuation, in which there are waves of both
DEVIANT CASES OF DEMOCRATIZATION 703
time, and the communist regimes in East Germany, Czechoslovakia, and Romania
collapsed. The 1990s also saw a widespread and rapid collapse of non-democratic
regimes in Africa, where more than a dozen democracies emerged. The end of the
Cold War seems to have provided a ‘window of opportunity’ to democratize, not
only in Europe, but also in Africa and Asia. Benin and Mongolia were among the
numerous regimes that democratized during this period, with the former country at
the forefront of democratization efforts on the African continent.
Economic Development
The initial impetus for the empirical quantitative studies of democratization was
Lipset’s 1959 article, which later turned out to be of crucial importance for the rise
of studies on the relationship between economic development and democracy.
Lipset argued that when the people of a country enjoy a higher level of economic
development, they will be more inclined to believe in democratic values and will
support a democratic system. Only in a relatively wealthy society can a situation
exist in which
the mass of the population could intelligently participate in politics and could
develop the self-restraint necessary to avoid succumbing to the appeals of irre-
sponsible demagogues. A society divided between a large impoverished mass
and a small favored elite would result either in oligarchy . . . or in tyranny.32
This hypothesis that there is a positive relationship between economic develop-
ment and democracy has been replicated many times,33 and a positive correlation
between economic development and democracy has been a persistent finding in
such empirical quantitative studies. Indeed, even scholars belonging to the qualitative
research tradition have acknowledged that:
the main finding of cross-national statistical work – a positive, though not
perfect, correlation between capitalist development and democracy – must
stand as an accepted result. There is no way of explaining this robust finding,
replicated in many studies of different designs, as spurious effect of flawed
methods. Any theory of democracy must come to terms with it.34
Consequently, taking the positive relationship between economic development and
democracy as a base line, many scholars, such as Inglehart, tend to conclude that
the level of economic development also ‘helps predict which countries are most
DEVIANT CASES OF DEMOCRATIZATION 705
likely to become democratic’.35 In a similar vein, Diamond argues that ‘the more
well-to-do the people of a country, on average, the more likely they will favour,
achieve, and maintain a democratic system for their country’.36
While such scholars are generally regarded as operating within the moderniz-
ation paradigm, it is also important to point out that many have not made the dis-
tinction between transitions to democracy, on the one hand, and consolidation of
democracy, on the other, as outlined above. For example, Inglehart has implied
that economic development predicts transitions, while Diamond has positively
linked economic development to both transition and consolidation.37 It is arguable,
however, that many factors, including the level of economic development, which
might help in maintaining democracy (i.e. consolidation), are not necessarily the
same as the factors that brought democracy into existence in the first place (i.e.
transition).
Huntington was one of the first scholars working in the quantitative research
tradition to deal with the impact of economic development specifically on democratic
transitions. He argued that transitions to democracy are unlikely in poor countries,
and that they had typically occurred in rich countries. The empirical results
showed that during the so-called third wave of democratization, from 1974 till
1990, countries in the middle-income zone were most likely to make a transition to
democracy: ‘[A]s countries develop economically and move into this zone, they
become prospects for democratization’.38 Gasiorowski made a similar claim, his find-
ings supporting Lipset’s argument that economic development increases the likeli-
hood of democratic transitions from 1950 till 1990.39
These findings have not gone unchallenged, however. For example, a study
by Przeworski and others has suggested that there is no significant relationship
between economic development and transition to democracy at all, and that democ-
racies are likely to emerge at any level of economic development.40 The conventional
wisdom about a straightforward relationship between economic development and
political change has also been tested by the experiences of Eastern European
countries, which began their transition from communist regimes to democracy
amidst economic crisis and generally declining levels of economic development.41
Boix and Stokes, in turn, have reassessed Przeworski and Limongi’s findings that
economic development does not play a significant role in transitions away from
autocracy.42 Their study has convincingly challenged and criticized Przeworski
and Limongi’s results, and argues that economic development does substantially
increase the probability that a country will make a transition to democracy. They
also argue that development has a much bigger positive effect on the likelihood of
maintaining a democratic regime. All in all, therefore, it is fair to accept on the
basis of the abovementioned studies that economic development has a positive
impact both on transitions to democracy and on democratic consolidation.
Democratic Region
The dramatic changes in Eastern Europe since 1989 seem to show that countries are
both dependent on each other and influence one another during the process of
democratization. Once the non-communists came to power in Poland in August
706 DEMOCRATIZATION
neighbours do indeed have a strong and positive influence on the likelihood that
a country undertakes a democratic transition, especially during the fourth wave
since 1989.52
However, while the evidence of this correlation is convincing, the mechanisms
are not so clear. Not much has been written yet about why clustering of types of
political regimes might occur. Elkins and Simmons suggest three explanations.53
First, countries respond similarly, though independently, to similar domestic con-
ditions. This explanation is dominant in comparative politics and international politi-
cal economy, and states that countries democratize because of political and economic
pressures within their countries, and that these pressures exist simultaneously for
leaders in other countries. A second explanation for the clustering is that regime
change and consolidation are coordinated by a group of nations, a hegemonic
power, or an international organization.54 Examples of this type might include volun-
tary international cooperation, or coercion by donor countries or international finan-
cial organizations. A third explanation of the clustering of regime types is that there is
uncoordinated interdependence between the countries, what Elkins and Simmons
explicitly call ‘diffusion’.55 The actions and choices of one country affect another,
but not through direct cooperation or imposition. Instead, the kind of interdependence
is uncoordinated. Examples of this type are not only adaptation to altered conditions,
but also diffusion via the exchange of information or learning.
More research needs to be done in order to find out whether these three expla-
nations of clustering can be supported by empirical evidence, and whether we can
get more insights into the specific mechanisms that lie behind the strong finding
that there is spatial clustering of democratic regimes. It seems widely accepted,
though, that a non-democratic regime that is surrounded by democratic neighbours
will be more likely to collapse and make a transition to democracy and vice versa.
Whether the presence or absence of democratic neighbours also encourages or
hinders the process of democratic consolidation remains underinvestigated, although
preliminary research does indicate a strong impact on democratic consolidation as
well.56 In other words, empirical evidence shows that there is a clear spatial clustering
of democratization around the world. Non-democratic countries that are surrounded
by democracies are much more likely to make a transition and to consolidate than
non-democratic countries in a non-democratic region.
studies, that is, mixed methods in research designs.64 Indeed, there is a specific type
of mixed methods that is particularly interesting for political science, namely the
nested design as advocated by Lieberman and by Brady, Collier, and Seawright.65
The research process of nested analysis, which is defined by Lieberman as a
research design that involves the structured combination of statistical and case
study methods, involves two crucial steps.66 The first step of nested analysis is,
formally, a quantitative analysis or a large-N analysis. The preliminary quantitative
analyses provide insights into various plausible factors that might explain the
phenomenon of interest, and guides the further execution of the small-N analysis.
The second step involves the intensive analysis of one or more cases, the small-N
analysis. One of the possibilities is thus to study outliers (or deviant cases) in order
to discover new explanatory variables. So, if the results of the large-N studies are
not entirely satisfactory, then the goal of the case study approach is to build a
better explanatory model. The purpose of case studies is, hence, to increase the expla-
natory power and the robustness of the results of large-N quantitative studies.
An important advantage of the nested mixed method is that it may contribute to
theory development. Lieberman argues that small-N analysis can strengthen statisti-
cal analysis in two ways: by a stronger test of the statistical model and by contributing
to model-building. The promise of the nested research design is that small-N and
large-N analyses can inform each other in such a way that ‘the analytic payoff is
greater than the sum of the parts’.67
Although this method shows a lot of potential to increase our understanding of
core topics in political science, unfortunately there is a lack of studies that have
applied this method.68 This special issue follows an innovative path by mixing find-
ings from both quantitative and qualitative research in a way similar to the approach
employed by Rueschemeyer et al. in their influential book on democratization.69
First, although we do not perform our own large-N analysis, we rely on various
pre-existing quantitative studies and identify the general pattern, as has been done
in this introductory article. On the basis of such quantitative research, it appears
that both economic development and democratic diffusion play a role during the
phases of transition and consolidation. Although it is important to point out that
other factors such as class structure, economic dependency, and political culture
explain processes of democratization to some extent as well, the factors of economic
development and diffusion clearly are the most powerful ones.70 However, these
large-N studies also show that there are some ‘outliers’ or deviant cases, which do
not fit into the general pattern, and cannot be explained by the general theories and
models. The case studies in this issue – Costa Rica, Botswana, India, Mongolia,
and Benin – are examples of such deviant cases.
Therefore, second, we perform a small-N qualitative analysis, as will be done in
each of the following country articles. The goal of each individual case study is to
specify in what ways the country is an ‘outlier’, using data on economic development,
together with a short analysis of ‘democracy’ in the country’s regional context.
Importantly, each case analysis is geared towards detecting important variables
that can explain the unexpected transition to and consolidation of democracy. It is
then the goal of the concluding chapter to provide a synthesis and outline how
710 DEMOCRATIZATION
these individual explanations will increase the explanatory power and the robustness
of the results of large-N quantitative studies, and contribute in turn to theory building.
Conclusion
Numerous studies have convincingly shown that structural factors matter in the process
of democratization. Among these structural factors, it is above all the level of economic
development and the presence or absence of democratic neighbours that have had most
impact on a country’s prospects for democratization. However, there are countries that
have experienced, in various historical periods, a successful transition to democracy in
a structural context that may be considered to be unfavourable for both the launching
and the sustaining of this process of political change. Their level of economic develop-
ment was low and they were surrounded by non-democratic neighbours at the time
their own non-democratic regimes began to crumble. Yet, after transitions of different
lengths, they successfully constructed a new competitive and inclusive political
regime – i.e. a minimal or electoral democracy. Moreover, most of these countries
have also succeeded in consolidating their new democratic order; i.e. they have
sustained their minimal or electoral democracies well beyond the initial period of
transition and the first free democratic elections. They may not be perfect democracies
by western liberal democratic standards, but they represent a success story that is or
was quite unusual given the context in which their transitions took place.
As we have specified in this introduction, such deviant cases of democratization
include Costa Rica and India, which made their transition to democracy during the
second wave of democratization following the end of World War II; Botswana,
which experienced successful transition in the 1960s; and Benin and Mongolia,
which managed to make the transition to democracy in the early 1990s during the
more recent fourth wave of democratization. All these countries can be considered
as ‘democracies against the odds’. In other words, they do not fit the expectations of
modernization and diffusion theories. In the light of the exceptional and anomalous
nature of democratization in these countries, the articles that follow this introductory
article aim to bring a better understanding of political change in those deviant cases.
The collection also represents an opportunity to refine existing accounts of democra-
tization by integrating non-structural factors into explanations of political change.
Indeed, the theoretical outlook of this collection, as well as the employment of
generic concepts and working definitions that we outlined in this introduction,
should help to overcome the usual problems involved in comparing such vastly differ-
ent countries across time and space, as well as the different time periods in which these
deviant cases occurred.
NOTES
1. Cf. Renske Doorenspleet, Democratic Transitions: Exploring the Structural Sources During the
Fourth Wave (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2005).
2. Renske Doorenspleet, ‘Reassessing the Three Waves of Democratization’, World Politics, Vol. 52, No.
3 (2000), pp. 384–406. On the exact meaning of the Fourth Wave see below.
3. Doorenspleet, Democratic Transitions (note 1), Chapter 2.
DEVIANT CASES OF DEMOCRATIZATION 711
4. See Seymour M. Lipset, ‘Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic Development and Political
Legitimacy’, American Political Science Review, Vol. 53, No. 1 (1959), pp. 69– 105; Robert A. Dahl,
Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1971). For an over-
view of modernization approach and studies of democratization done in this tradition see Doorenspleet,
Democratic Transitions (note 1), Chapters 4 and 5.
5. Thomas S. Eliot, The Idea of a Christian Society (London: Faber and Faber, 1939), pp. 11–12.
6. David Collier and Steven Levitsky, ‘Democracy with Adjectives: Conceptual Innovation in Compara-
tive Research’, World Politics, Vol. 49, No. 3 (1997), pp. 403– 51.
7. Joseph A. Schumpeter, Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy (London: Unwin, 1943).
8. Dahl (note 4), pp. 2, 4.
9. See Doorenspleet, Democratic Transitions (note 1), for a classification of minimal democracies and a
list with countries who have met this criteria since 1800.
10. Francis Fukuyama, The End of History and the Last Man (New York: Free Press, 1992).
11. E.g. Fareed Zakaria, ‘The Rise of Illiberal Democracy’, Foreign Affairs, Vol. 76, No. 6 (1997),
pp. 22– 43; Andreas Schedler, ‘What is Democratic Consolidation?’, Journal of Democracy, Vol. 9,
No. 2 (1998), pp. 91–107; Larry Diamond, Developing Democracy. Toward Consolidation
(Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1999).
12. Guillermo O’Donnell, ‘Illusions about Consolidation’, Journal of Democracy, Vol. 7, No. 2 (1996),
pp. 34– 51.
13. Juan J. Linz and Alfred Stepan, Problems of Democratic Transition and Consolidation: Southern
Europe, South America, and Post-Communist Europe (Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University
Press, 1996).
14. E.g. Diamond, Developing Democracy (note 11).
15. Dankwart A. Rustow, ‘Transitions to Democracy: Towards a Dynamic Model’, Comparative Politics,
Vol. 2, No. 3 (1970), pp. 337–65; Guillermo O’Donnell and Philippe C. Schmitter, Transitions from
Authoritarian Rule: Tentative Conclusions about Uncertain Democracies (Baltimore, MD: The John
Hopkins University, 1986).
16. E.g. Gerardo L. Munck, ‘Democratic Transitions in Comparative Perspective’, Comparative Politics,
Vol. 26, No. 3, (1994), pp. 355–75; Fritz Plasser, Peter A. Ulram, and Harald Waldrauch, Democratic
Consolidation in East-Central Europe (Houndmills: Macmillan, 1998); Schedler.
17. O’Donnell and Schmitter (note 15).
18. E.g. Guillermo O’Donnell, ‘Transitions, Continuities, and Paradoxes’, in Scott Mainwaring, Guillermo
O’Donnell, and Julio Valenzuela (eds), Issues in Democratic Consolidation: The New South American
Democracies in Comparative Perspective (Notre Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press, 1992),
pp. 17– 56; Plasser, Ulram and Waldrauch (note 16).
19. Giuseppe Di Palma, To Craft Democracies: An Essay on Democratic Transitions (Berkeley, CA:
University of California Press, 1990).
20. Gerardo Munck and Carol S. Leff, ‘Modes of Transition and Democratization: South America and
Eastern Europe in Comparative Perspective’, Comparative Politics, Vol. 29, No. 3 (1997), pp. 343–62.
21. Di Palma (note 19).
22. E.g. Philippe C. Schmitter, ‘Dangers and Dilemmas of Democracy’, Journal of Democracy, Vol. 5 (1994),
pp. 57–74; Juan J. Linz, ‘Transitions to Democracy’, The Washington Quarterly, Vol. 13 (1990),
pp. 143–64; Julio Valenzuela, ‘Democratic Consolidation in Post-Transitional Settings: Notion,
Process, and Facilitating Conditions’, in Scott Mainwaring, Guillermo O’Donnell, and Julio Valenzuela
(eds), Issues in Democratic Consolidation: The New South American Democracies in Comparative
Perspective (Notre Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press, 1992), pp. 57–104; Richard Gunther,
P. Nikiforos Diamandouros, and Hans-Jürgen Puhle (eds), The Politics of Democratic Consolidation:
Southern Europe in Comparative Perspective (Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1995).
23. For example Gunther, Diamandouros and Puhle (note 22).
24. Diamond, Developing Democracy (note 11).
25. See Linz and Stepan (note 13).
26. Schedler (note 11).
27. See Samuel P. Huntington, The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century (Norman,
OK: University of Oklahoma Press, 1991); Doorenspleet, ‘Reassessing’ (note 2).
28. See Doorenspleet, ‘Reassessing’ (note 2).
29. See Doorenspleet, ‘Reassessing’ (note 2), and Doorenspleet, Democratic Transitions (note 1).
30. See Doorenspleet, ‘Reassessing’ (note 2); Doorenspleet, Democratic Transitions (note 1); Diamond,
Developing Democracy (note 11); Adrian Karatnycky, ‘The Decline of Illiberal Democracy’,
Journal of Democracy, Vol. 10, No. 1, (1999), pp. 112–25.
712 DEMOCRATIZATION
59. O’Donnell and Schmitter (note 15); Munck and Leff (note 20).
60. E.g. Linz and Stepan (note 13).
61. E.g. David C. Stark and László Bruszt, Postsocialist Pathways: Transforming Politics and Property in
East Central Europe (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998); Belinda Crawford and Arend
Lijphart (eds), Liberalization and Leninist Legacies: Comparative Perspectives on Democratic Tran-
sitions (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1997).
62. E.g. Arend Lijphart (ed.), Parliamentary versus Presidential Government (Oxford: Oxford University
Press, 1992); Juan J. Linz, ‘Presidential or Parliamentary Democracy: Does it Make a Difference?’, in
Juan J. Linz and Arturo Valenzuela (eds), The Failure of Presidential Democracy: Comparative Per-
spectives, Volume 1 (Baltimore, MD: The John Hopkins University Press, 1994), pp. 3 –90; Adam
Przeworski, Michael Alvarez, José A. Cheibub, and Fernando Limongi, ‘What Makes Democracies
Endure?’, Journal of Democracy, Vol. 7, No. 1 (1996), pp. 39–55.
63. See e.g. Jon Elster, Claus Offe, Ulrich K. Preuss, Frank Bönker, Ulrike Götting, Friedbert W. Rueb,
Institutional Design in Post-Communist Democracies: Rebuilding the Ship at Sea (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1998).
64. For an overview of this methodological developments, and for description of strengths and weaknesses
of applying mixed methods, see Ellen Mastenbroek and Renske Doorenspleet, ‘Mind the Gap! On the
Possibilities and Pitfalls of Mixed Methods Research’, Paper presented at the 4th ECPR General Con-
ference, Pisa, Italy, 6–8 September 2007.
65. Evan S. Lieberman, ‘Nested Analysis as a Mixed-Method Strategy for Comparative Research’,
American Political Science Review, Vol. 99, No. 3, (2005), pp. 435 –52; Henry E. Brady, David
Collier, and Jason Seawright, ‘Toward a Pluralistic Vision of Methodology’, Political Analysis,
Vol. 14, No. 4, (2006), pp. 353– 68.
66. Lieberman (note 65).
67. Ibid., p. 436.
68. See for exceptions the description of studies in Lieberman (note 65); Mastenbroek and Doorenspleet
(note 64).
69. Rueschemeyer, Stephens, and Stephens (note 34).
70. See for overview of other factors and theories: Doorenspleet, Democratic Transitions (note 1), chapter
4; see also Mark J. Gasiorowski and Tomothy J. Power, ‘Institutional Design and Democratic Conso-
lidation in the Third World’, in Comparative Political Studies, Vol. 30, No. 2, (1997), pp. 123– 55;
Gasiorowski (note 39); See for strength of development and diffusion effects on democracy: Doorens-
pleet, Democratic Transitions (note 1), chapter 5, 8, and 9; Boix and Stokes (note 42), and O’Loughlin
et al. (note 47).
Address for correspondence: Renske Doorenspleet, Department of Politics and International Studies,
University of Warwick, Gibbet Hill Road, Coventry, CV4 7AL, United Kingdom. E-mail: renske.
doorenspleet@warwick.ac.uk; Petr Kopecký, Department of Political Science, Wassenaarseweg, 52
2300, RB Leiden, the Netherlands. E-mail: kopecky@fsw.leidenuniv.nl