Cambridge Core Constraining Dictatorship 9nov2022
Cambridge Core Constraining Dictatorship 9nov2022
Cambridge Core Constraining Dictatorship 9nov2022
Series Editors
Jeffry Frieden, Harvard University
John Patty, Emory University
Elizabeth Maggie Penn, Emory University
Founding Editors
James E. Alt, Harvard University
Douglass C. North, Washington University of St. Louis
ANNE MENG
University of Virginia
www.cambridge.org
Information on this title: www.cambridge.org/9781108834896
doi: 10.1017/9781108877497
© Anne Meng 2020
This publication is in copyright. Subject to statutory exception
and to the provisions of relevant collective licensing agreements,
no reproduction of any part may take place without the written
permission of Cambridge University Press.
First published 2020
Printed in the United Kingdom by TJ International Ltd. Padstow Cornwall
A catalogue record for this publication is available from the British Library.
isbn 978-1-108-83489-6 Hardback
isbn 978-1-108-79247-9 Paperback
Cambridge University Press has no responsibility for the persistence or accuracy of
URLs for external or third-party internet websites referred to in this publication
and does not guarantee that any content on such websites is, or will remain,
accurate or appropriate.
Series Editors
Jeffry Frieden, Harvard University
John Patty, Emory University
Elizabeth Maggie Penn, Emory University
Founding Editors
James E. Alt, Harvard University
Douglass C. North, Washington University of St. Louis
ANNE MENG
University of Virginia
www.cambridge.org
Information on this title: www.cambridge.org/9781108834896
doi: 10.1017/9781108877497
© Anne Meng 2020
This publication is in copyright. Subject to statutory exception
and to the provisions of relevant collective licensing agreements,
no reproduction of any part may take place without the written
permission of Cambridge University Press.
First published 2020
Printed in the United Kingdom by TJ International Ltd. Padstow Cornwall
A catalogue record for this publication is available from the British Library.
isbn 978-1-108-83489-6 Hardback
isbn 978-1-108-79247-9 Paperback
Cambridge University Press has no responsibility for the persistence or accuracy of
URLs for external or third-party internet websites referred to in this publication
and does not guarantee that any content on such websites is, or will remain,
accurate or appropriate.
Series Editors
Jeffry Frieden, Harvard University
John Patty, Emory University
Elizabeth Maggie Penn, Emory University
Founding Editors
James E. Alt, Harvard University
Douglass C. North, Washington University of St. Louis
ANNE MENG
University of Virginia
www.cambridge.org
Information on this title: www.cambridge.org/9781108834896
doi: 10.1017/9781108877497
© Anne Meng 2020
This publication is in copyright. Subject to statutory exception
and to the provisions of relevant collective licensing agreements,
no reproduction of any part may take place without the written
permission of Cambridge University Press.
First published 2020
Printed in the United Kingdom by TJ International Ltd. Padstow Cornwall
A catalogue record for this publication is available from the British Library.
isbn 978-1-108-83489-6 Hardback
isbn 978-1-108-79247-9 Paperback
Cambridge University Press has no responsibility for the persistence or accuracy of
URLs for external or third-party internet websites referred to in this publication
and does not guarantee that any content on such websites is, or will remain,
accurate or appropriate.
Series Editors
Jeffry Frieden, Harvard University
John Patty, Emory University
Elizabeth Maggie Penn, Emory University
Founding Editors
James E. Alt, Harvard University
Douglass C. North, Washington University of St. Louis
ANNE MENG
University of Virginia
www.cambridge.org
Information on this title: www.cambridge.org/9781108834896
doi: 10.1017/9781108877497
© Anne Meng 2020
This publication is in copyright. Subject to statutory exception
and to the provisions of relevant collective licensing agreements,
no reproduction of any part may take place without the written
permission of Cambridge University Press.
First published 2020
Printed in the United Kingdom by TJ International Ltd. Padstow Cornwall
A catalogue record for this publication is available from the British Library.
isbn 978-1-108-83489-6 Hardback
isbn 978-1-108-79247-9 Paperback
Cambridge University Press has no responsibility for the persistence or accuracy of
URLs for external or third-party internet websites referred to in this publication
and does not guarantee that any content on such websites is, or will remain,
accurate or appropriate.
1 Introduction 1
1.1 Two Puzzles About Authoritarian Institutions 1
1.2 Examining Regime Outcomes: Personalist Rule and
Institutionalized Systems 5
1.3 Sometimes Window Panes, But Often Window
Dressing 9
1.4 Autocratic Regime Institutionalization: A Deeper
Look 12
1.5 Causes of Regime Institutionalization 16
1.6 Consequences of Regime Institutionalization 19
1.7 This Book’s Contributions: Authoritarian Regimes 23
1.8 Why Africa? This Book’s Contributions to African
Politics 27
1.9 Plan of the Book 31
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize? 34
2.1 Institutions as Commitment Devices 36
2.2 A Theoretical Model 41
2.3 Solving the Baseline Model 44
2.4 Model Extension: Uncertainty About the Future 50
2.5 Conclusion 54
3 Two Illustrative Cases 64
3.1 The Formal Model Summarized 66
3.2 Cameroon Under Ahidjo: High Levels of Regime
Institutionalization 69
ix
Published online by Cambridge University Press
Contents
x
Published online by Cambridge University Press
Contents
References 239
Index 249
xi
Published online by Cambridge University Press
Figures
xii
Published online by Cambridge University Press
List of Figures
xiii
Published online by Cambridge University Press
Tables
xiv
Published online by Cambridge University Press
List of Tables
xv
Published online by Cambridge University Press
Acknowledgments
This project could not have come together without the support and
wisdom of a wonderful academic community. I spent eleven formative
years at UC Berkeley – both as an undergraduate and as a Ph.D. student.
I am grateful that even as a college student (one out of over 30,000
students) my professors cultivated my research interests, pushed me to
think harder and more critically, and encouraged me to pursue academia.
I took my first game theory class with Robert Powell in my junior year of
college, and it completely reoriented the ways in which I thought about
strategic interaction in politics. A seminar on Chinese politics with
Kevin O’Brien sparked my desire to understand durable forms of
authoritarianism, and a writing seminar with Steve Fish motivated me to
always write with the goal of publishing. In my junior year of college,
I begged Peter Lorentzen to let me into his Ph.D. seminar on political
economy – he did, and the exposure to graduate training and research
solidified my desire to pursue a Ph.D. Early on in graduate school, I took
a seminar with Leonardo Arriola, and his sharp insights paired with an
infectious enthusiasm to pursue new and exciting research embodied the
kind of scholar I wanted to be. These seemingly small moments early on
made lasting impacts on me, and I often think fondly of my time spent at
Berkeley.
I want to express special thanks to my dissertation cochairs, Leonardo
Arriola and Robert Powell. They truly were a dream-team of advisors. Leo
and Bob poked holes in my arguments, asked difficult questions (that
sometimes took months to adequately address), and pushed me to be the
best scholar I could be. At the same time, they championed my research,
offered their expertise when I was stuck, and provided invaluable advice
each step of the way. I am so grateful for their friendship and guidance.
Much of who I am as a scholar today has been shaped by their mentoring.
I would also like to thank other faculty members and my peers at
Berkeley who generously offered their time, insights, moral support, and
xvi
Published online by Cambridge University Press
Acknowledgments
xvii
Published online by Cambridge University Press
Acknowledgments
xviii
Published online by Cambridge University Press
Abbreviations
xix
Published online by Cambridge University Press
Published online by Cambridge University Press
1
Introduction
1
TANU was renamed Chama Cha Mapindui (CCM) in 1977, following the merger of
Tanzania and Zanzibar, although the party remained largely the same.
1
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1 Introduction
the Parti democratique de Guinee (PDG) party. PDG politicians filled the
National Assembly, which conducted two regular sessions every year.
Presidential elections were held regularly in 1961, 1968, 1974, and
1982, and National Assembly elections were held in 1963, 1968, 1974,
and 1980, as stated in the constitution.
Yet these institutions did not provide long-term stability in Guinea. In
1984, Sekou Toure died of a heart attack after being airlifted to Cleveland,
Ohio for emergency heart surgery while on a trip to Saudi Arabia. Before
succession plans could be finalized, the military seized power in a coup
d’état and the leader of the coup, Colonel Lansana Conte, claimed the
presidency. The PDG was immediately disbanded, the National Assembly
was dissolved, and the constitution was abolished. In short, the regime
died with its leader.
Why did regime outcomes in Tanzania and Guinea diverge so drasti-
cally? Why was the authoritarian system in Guinea unable to survive the
death of the leader, even with a full set of nominally democratic institu-
tions in place? Sekou Toure had a ruling party, a legislature, and regularly
held elections. He was even a socialist who aimed to replicate the Soviet
state. Nonetheless, the regime fell in Guinea, and these institutions them-
selves were swiftly wiped out after the death of the leader.
These vignettes raise the first puzzle of the book: what explains differ-
ences in authoritarian regime outcomes, if not differences in quasi-
democratic institutions?
One possible consideration is that we need to look beyond the most
common types of quasi-democratic institutions – such as parties and
legislatures, which are quite prevalent across authoritarian regimes –
and consider more subtle forms of variation. Indeed, Guinea and
Tanzania did differ in one important institution: adoption of executive
constraints.
Since independence, presidents in Tanzania have had a number of
institutional constraints on their authority. During the tenure of the
founding president Nyerere, term limits and detailed leadership
succession procedures became enshrined in the constitution, and these
rules remain in place today. According to the constitution, presidents are
limited to two terms in office (Article 40), and in the case of the president’s
death or incapacitation, the vice president is the designated successor
(Article 37). The presidential cabinet, which is filled with TANU party
elites, exists as a genuine power-sharing organization rather than a hallow
endorsement device. Since independence, all presidents have maintained
fully functional cabinets, and all key cabinet positions, such as the vice
presidency and defense ministry, have been appointed to elites on
a regular basis. Critically, appointments for the position of vice president
2
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1.1 Two Puzzles About Authoritarian Institutions
2
In fact, the constitution stated explicitly that the president may be reelected without
mention of term restrictions.
3
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1 Introduction
4
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1.2 Examining Regime Outcomes
3
I do not claim that all parties and legislatures are window-dressing institutions that
do not constrain leaders. Some autocracies, such as in China, the former Soviet
Union, or Mexico under the PRI, have well-organized parties and legislatures that
do not merely rubber-stamp legislation. However, in many autocracies, these institu-
tions are incredibly weak and do not serve to empower specific elites.
4
This book uses the terms “dictatorship,” “authoritarian regime,” and “autocracy”
synonymously.
5
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1 Introduction
5
The party was initially called the Partido Nacional Revolucionario (PNR). It was
eventually renamed the PRI in 1946.
6
It is estimated that 500,000 people were killed by the regime’s secret police during the
Trujillo era.
6
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1.2 Examining Regime Outcomes
7
I define a peaceful transition as one where the outgoing leader exits power via regular
means and the incoming leaders enters power via regular means – to be defined more
precisely later (Goemans, Gleditsch, and Chiozza 2009).
7
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1 Introduction
15
10
0
1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
year
10
Peaceful transitions
5
Number of transitions
0
Violent transitions
5
End of Cold War
10
1945
1950
1955
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
Year
8
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1.3 Sometimes Window Panes, But Often Window Dressing
8
This book uses the terms “quasi-democratic” or “nominally democratic” institu-
tions in autocracies and “authoritarian institutions” synonymously.
9
See Bracanti (2014), Gandhi and Lust-Okar (2009), Geddes, Wright, and Frantz
(2018), Gehlbach, Sonin, and Svolik (2016), Lagace and Gandhi (2015), Magaloni
and Kricheli (2010), and Pepinsky (2014) for recent surveys of the literature on
authoritarian institutions.
10
“Institutional turn” phrase borrowed from Pepinsky (2014).
9
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1 Introduction
1
.9
.8
.7
.6
.5
.4
.3
.2
.1
0
1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
year
elections were held in 124 countries – 707 presidential elections and 1,415
legislative elections (Hyde and Marinov 2012).11
These numbers are not simply being driven by a post-Cold War pro-
liferation of institutions. From 1946 to 1990, 84 percent of authoritarian
regimes had parties, 80 percent had legislatures, and 92 percent had
constitutions. Moreover, 1,165 elections were held during that time per-
iod – 338 presidential elections and 827 legislative elections. The typical
post-Second World War autocracy has had parties, legislatures, elections,
and constitutions while in power. In other words, the presence of author-
itarian institutions is simply unremarkable and there really is minimal
variation in the existence of institutions in modern autocracies.
Moreover, most ruling parties fail to outlive the death of the founder.
61 percent of ruling parties do not survive more than a year past the
founding leader’s death or departure from office, as illustrated in
Figure 1.4. Even in cases where the first leader experienced a nonviolent
exit from power, only 58 percent of ruling parties outlive the leader.
Furthermore, 43 percent of ruling parties that are coded as part of domi-
nant-party regimes fail to survive a year past the departure of the first
11
The percentage for ruling parties, legislatures, and constitutions are calculated as the
percentage of country–year observations that had the institution. The election
numbers are presented as counts.
10
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1.3 Sometimes Window Panes, But Often Window Dressing
mean +1 s.d.
90 90
80
70
60
Frequency
50
40
30
20
11
10 6 7
5 5 4 2 4 2
0
0 10 20 30 40 50
Number of years party remained in power past founding leader
Figure 1.4 Number of years ruling parties remain in power past the founding leader
leader (Meng 2019). In sum, the existence of many ruling parties seems to
rely heavily on the influence of a single leader.
We then have a contradiction. On one hand, existing theories argue
that these institutions are supposed to help regimes survive. Yet, the data
shows that authoritarian institutions are incredibly common and fre-
quently do not outlive individual leaders. The average authoritarian
regime often cannot survive independently of particular leaders and
regime instability has persisted.
I argue that this seeming contradiction exists because scholars have
been focusing on the existence of institutions, rather than the content of
these institutions – in particular whether the leader is constrained. Simply
having a ruling party or legislature does not necessarily mean that the rules
or procedures governing these organizations are institutionalized. In fact,
the appearance of democratic-like institutions, such as ruling parties,
often obscures the true lack of constraints on the executive.
This book examines the causes and consequences of autocratic regime
institutionalization. The first half of the book presents a theory of how
institutionalized regimes emerge by explaining the conditions under
which autocratic leaders choose to implement constraints on their author-
ity after coming into power. In examining the origins of institutionalized
regimes, this book provides a clear mechanism for the question of how
institutions constrain leaders in dictatorship. After all, if autocratic lea-
ders can create institutions, then they can also dismantle them as well.
11
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1 Introduction
How then, do rules and procedures have any bite within inherently weakly
institutionalized environments? The second half of the book shifts from
explaining the causes of regime institutionalization to examining the
consequences of institutionalization on key outcomes, such as leader
tenure, coup vulnerability, and leadership succession.
12
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1.4 Autocratic Regime Institutionalization
12
Jose Eduardo dos Santos, for instance, the first president of Angola, named himself
as his own vice president for a number of years while he was in power. Hastings
Banda, the first president of Malawi, appointed himself as the minister of defense
during his entire tenure, from 1964 until 1993.
13
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1 Introduction
13
Following existing studies, I define informal institutions as unwritten rules that are
“created, communicated, and enforced outside of officially sanctioned channels”
(Helmke and Levitsky 2004, 727).
14
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1.4 Autocratic Regime Institutionalization
1
.9
.8
.7
.6
.5
.4
.3
.2
.1
0
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
year
14
Although the introduction of multiparty elections was indeed an important move-
ment toward political liberalization. Prior to the end of the Cold War, single-party
elections dominated the political landscape in most African regimes.
15
This argument echoes Albertus and Menaldo’s (2018) study of elite-driven
democratization.
15
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1 Introduction
16
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1.5 Causes of Regime Institutionalization
coordinate around them. Even when leaders have the ability to choose
who they appoint to these key positions – as they often do – the simple act
of delegating authority shifts the underlying distribution of power
between the leader and her appointees. In the model, this mechanism is
formalized as a shift in the future distribution of power against the leader.
When a president institutionalizes the regime, she voluntarily helps to
solve the elite collective action problem by identifying and empowering
particular individuals who become more capable of unseating her in the
future.
If regime institutionalization seems to weaken leaders, why would any
autocrat choose to tie their own hands after coming into power? The
model shows that autocratic leaders are most likely to place constraints
on their own authority when they enter power vulnerable and highly
susceptible to being deposed. Because per-period transfers are often insuf-
ficient to buy quiescence from exceptionally strong elites, weak leaders
remain in power only by delegating authority to elites as an accountability
mechanism that guarantees their access to future rents. On the other hand,
exceptionally strong leaders who have already consolidated power by the
time they come into office have no incentives to create institutionalized
mechanisms for rent distribution because they face very low likelihoods of
being deposed. A weak autocratic leader is therefore better off taking
actions to tie her own hands because doing so lengthens her time in office.
It is important to clarify that these constraints are essentially forced on
weak incumbents; they reluctantly institutionalize under duress when
faced with elites who can credibly remove them.
My theory stresses the path dependent nature of regime institutionali-
zation. How a leader enters power and the extent to which they have
already consolidated their authority when they enter office determines, in
large part, whether regime institutionalization will occur. In the model,
even if the leader receives a particularly weak draw of power in the initial
period, and anticipates being much stronger in the future, commitment
problems that arise in the present swamp future distributive considera-
tions. Leaders make decisions about institutions at the start of their
tenure, and these institutional decisions shape the rest of their rule.16
This theory suggests an ironic twist of fate. Initially strong leaders are
never incentivized to build credible ruling organizations because they are
able to remain in power without making institutional commitments to
other elites. Yet personalist strategies of rule are ultimately destabilizing in
16
In this sense, the initial period of a leader’s tenure can also be considered a critical
juncture.
17
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1 Introduction
the long run, especially upon the death of the ruler. Conversely, initially
weak autocrats who lack a strong basis of support must pursue the
counterintuitive strategy of committing to give power away when they
are most vulnerable. Doing so allows such leaders to buy support from
elites who would otherwise jump at the opportunity to depose them. Yet
at the same time, these self-interested actions generate stable power-
sharing institutions, setting the stage for durable authoritarian rule.
Empirical patterns of institutionalization in sub-Saharan Africa sup-
port this argument. Founding presidents who came into office immedi-
ately following independence – especially those who were influential
leaders of mass independence movements – benefitted from extreme
legitimacy and high levels of popular support. Such leaders, like Félix
Houphouët-Boigny of Côte d’Ivoire or Kwame Nkrumah of Ghana, were
seen as the “founding fathers” of the newly independent African states.
Both leaders, like most other founding presidents, did not appoint a vice
president during their tenure and lacked constitutional constraints on
their power.
Presidents who came into power via coups, such as Mobutu Sese
Seko of Zaire or Gnassingbe Eyadema of Togo, were also much less
likely to institutionalize their regimes along formal and informal
dimensions. One of the most precarious risks to any civilian incum-
bent is the threat of a military takeover. When the leader is the head
of the military, however, this threat is diminished. Autocrats who
successfully come into power through coups demonstrate that they
have control over the coercive apparatus that allowed them to launch
a successful coup in the first place. Since they retain control over the
military, coup leaders do not need to institutionalize the regime in
order to remain in power.
The end of the Cold War was also a watershed event that changed
the dynamics of regime institutionalization. Beginning in the 1990s,
international norms abruptly shifted toward favoring democratization
and political liberalization. Leaders who had ruled as single strong-
man dictators were now facing condemnation in light of changing
international norms, therefore shifting the distribution of power in
favor of elites. As a result, levels of formal and informal institutiona-
lization increased sharply. This discontinuous jump in the levels of
institutionalization after 1990, as illustrated in Figure 1.5, is very
evident when graphed over time (especially when compared with
minimal changes in the existence of parties, legislatures, and constitu-
tions, as illustrated in Figure 1.3). In fact, this sharp increase in
institutionalization also explains why leadership transitions have
become increasingly peaceful in the post-Cold War era.
18
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1.6 Consequences of Regime Institutionalization
19
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1 Introduction
The first half of this book makes the case that leaders make strategic
decisions about whether to institutionalize their regimes, depending on
their strength, vis-à-vis other elites. Because institutionalization is an
endogenous process, executive constraints should only have an observable
effect when we condition on initial leader strength. Strong leaders who
have already consolidated power when they take office do not need to rely
on power-sharing institutions to remain in power. Their rule is secure with
or without institutional mechanisms. We therefore should observe little or
no effect of institutionalization on regime durability for strong leaders.
For leaders who are weak, however, building an institutionalized
regime does promote stability. Leaders who are highly vulnerable to
being deposed by their fellow elites require executive constraints in
order to make credible commitments to share power and resources.
Institutionalization should therefore lengthen the time horizons and lessen
coup risk, but primarily for weak leaders.
Since initially strong leaders are likely to be able to remain in power
regardless of whether they institutionalize or not, a regression model that
regresses institutionalization on regime stability without taking into
account differential effects based on leader type will likely result in either
a diminished effect of institutionalization or a null effect, both of which
would be inaccurate.
To address this endogenous institutional choice, I incorporate an
interaction term between regime institutionalization and leader strength
which accounts for differential effects of institutionalization based on
whether the leader was initially strong or weak. Using founding presi-
dents and postcoup leaders as proxies for strong leaders, I find when we
condition on initial leader strength, institutionalization does indeed have
a stabilizing effect for weak leaders but little or no effect for strong
leaders.
20
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1.6 Consequences of Regime Institutionalization
21
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1 Introduction
Figure 1.6 The effect of regime institutionalization on leader and regime outcomes
22
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1.7 This Book’s Contributions: Authoritarian Regimes
17
Although it is possible for countries to be coded as different regimes over time, most
are not. Furthermore, this coding scheme does not allow for variation within
regimes. See Chapter 4 for the full discussion.
23
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1 Introduction
18
Examples of subjective criteria include: “Does the party have functioning local level
organizations that do something reasonably important, such as distribute seeds or
credit or organize local government?” or “Has rule of law been maintained?”. The
possibility of measurement error based on subjective coding rules is also heightened
by the fact that the dataset spans multiple regions and time periods and often rely on
information from various country experts.
19
My approach is similar to the measurement strategies used in Gandhi (2008) and
Svolik (2012).
24
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1.7 This Book’s Contributions: Authoritarian Regimes
often data on the presence of institutions has substituted for data on the
content of institutions. However, comparisons of my institutionalization
measures with existing datasets that focus on the existence of autocratic
institutions verify that simply having parties or legislatures does not mean
that executive constraints on the leader exist. Moreover, many regimes
that have been coded as dominant-party regime types are also not very
institutionalized. Even aggregate Polity scores of executive constraints
(“XCONST”) display massive inconsistencies when compared to the
presence of constitutional term limits and succession procedures. In
sum, existing variables of autocratic institutions are poor predictors of
regime institutionalization and do not reflect the extent to which the
leader is constrained.
This book also contributes to the literature on comparative political
institutions by developing a theory of why dictatorships vary in institu-
tional strength. I build on a small but growing literature of institutional
change in developing or transitional states (Gryzmala-Busse 2007;
Helmke 2017; Levitsky and Murillo 2009; Miller 2020; Opalo 2019).
This book also highlights the role of informal institutions in regulating
political power (Gryzmala-Busse 2010; Helmke and Levitsky 2004; 2006;
Lauth 2000; Mershon 1994) – a topic that has received very limited
attention within the autocratic context (Tsai 2007). It is also in conversa-
tion with studies that examine how and when institutions become self-
reinforcing in otherwise weakly institutionalized settings (Ginsburg and
Simpser 2013; Greif and Laitin 2004; Mahoney and Thelen 2010; Nalepa
2010; Negretto 2013; Pierson 2000; Przeworski 2015; Thelen 2004).
However, while most of these studies explain why and how institutions
evolve in newly democratic or quasi-democratic settings, I focus my
attention on explaining institutional change within dictatorships.
As a second key contribution, this book ties the origins of institutions
to their consequences in a comprehensive account of the causes and
consequences of autocratic regime institutionalization. Scholars have
only recently begun to examine why some leaders create institutional
arrangements rather than relying on private transfers to maintain elite
support. Early studies either took the existence of a dominant party as
exogenous (as noted explicitly in Magaloni 2008)20 or identified multiple
strategies of rule (repression, informal cooptation, or institutions) without
20
She states: “A key question that emerges from this discussion is why not all dictators
create political parties if these play such powerful roles at minimizing their risk of
being overthrown by members of the ruling coalition. My account does not address
the question of origins – how successful and credible political parties get established
in the first place” (11).
25
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1 Introduction
specifying the conditions under which leaders would choose to rule with
or without institutions (Haber 2006). As Reuter (2017) notes, “we know
much more in political science about the equilibrium characteristics of
dominant parties . . . than we do about how these equilibria come to be
established in the first place” (13).
A growing number of studies are now considering how institutional
equilibria emerge in dictatorships. Gandhi (2008) and Gandhi and
Przeworski (2007) first highlight the notion that institutions emerge
endogenously when they benefit leaders. Brownlee (2007) argues that
intra-elite conflict during the early years of the regime necessitates the
creation of dominant parties, and Slater (2010) argues that elites create
strong states and durable parties when they face “endemic threats” to
their existences. Other studies have also highlighted the role of external
threats (Paine 2019; Smith 2005) and revolutionary conflict (Huntington
1968; Levitsky and Way 2012; 2013) in creating conditions that facilitate
the development of strong party institutions or elite power-sharing. Three
recent studies have dealt with this question of institutional creation most
directly and point to the key mechanism of commitment problems
between leaders and elites that motivates the creation of power-sharing
institutions (Boix and Svolik 2013; Gehlbach and Keefer 2011; Reuter
2017).
This book differs from these existing accounts by examining the origins
of executive constraints in constitutions and presidential cabinets rather
than the origins of the parties and legislatures. In fact, historical evidence
often suggests that many ruling parties are not strategically created, but
instead, inherited by leaders. Within my sample of African countries, for
instance, virtually all leaders came into power with a preexisting party in
place immediately following independence. These ruling parties were
created prior to decolonization not as elite power-sharing devices, but
rather as pro-independence organizations (Bienen 1970; 1978; Zolberg
1966; 1969) or parties that were used to participate in preindependence
elections (Collier 1982). Rather than arguing that leaders make strategic
decisions to create institutions, this book argues that leaders make strate-
gic decisions to institutionalize their regimes after coming into power.
In providing a comprehensive account of both the causes and conse-
quences of institutionalization, this book is able to take into account
endogenous decisions to institutionalize when estimating the effects of
these institutions. Scholarship examining the effects of institutions on
regime durability has generally developed in isolation from studies of
the origins of these institutions. Yet the consequences of institutions are
intimately related to where these institutions come from. This book con-
siders how the strategic origins of institutionalization have an effect on the
26
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1.8 This Book’s Contributions to African Politics
21
A few exceptions include Carter and Hassan (2019), Hassan (2020), and Opalo
(2019). Other studies have examined the effect of authoritarian legacies on demo-
cratization in Africa, without focusing explicitly on the politics of authoritarian rule
(Bleck and van de Walle 2018; Bratton and van de Walle 1997; Cheeseman 2015;
LeBas 2013; Posner and Young (2007); Riedl 2014).
22
Only the island of Mauritius has been considered a democracy since it gained
independence in 1968.
27
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1 Introduction
28
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1.8 This Book’s Contributions to African Politics
world) was that most African countries were in the process of democratiz-
ing. However, despite the presence of multiparty elections in much of sub-
Saharan Africa for the last 30 years, many incumbents and ruling parties
have maintained a solid grip on power (Bleck and van de Walle 2018). In
short, authoritarian regimes continue to persist, albeit under the façade of
shallow democratic institutions. Yet scholarly discussions of African pol-
itics remain centered on trying to understand problems of democratiza-
tion, rather than trying to understand how autocracies have evolved and
adapted to post-Cold War conditions.
This book proposes a radical reinterpretation of contemporary African
politics: that the institutionalization of regimes beginning in the 1990s
reinforced authoritarian rule, rather than ushering in real democracy. In
order to really make sense of African politics today, we need to stop trying
to understand these regimes as problematic democracies, and analyze
them instead as institutionalized autocracies.
As my data on executive constraints demonstrate, following the end of
the Cold War, regimes in Africa became much more institutionalized as
leaders established power-sharing mechanisms in order to maintain sup-
port from fellow elites. Rather than offering citizens true access to power,
incumbents and elites consolidated their stranglehold on political power,
all while keeping the appearance of governing through democratic-
seeming institutions. The majority of African countries have now intro-
duced term limits and succession policies in their constitutions, in addition
to regularizing the appointment of elites to key cabinet positions.
However, as I argue, the institutionalization of these regimes has resulted
in authoritarian stability, rather than regime weakness or transition to
democracy. By diffusing power among many ruling elites, leaders and incum-
bent regimes actually solidified their grip on power by maintaining elite
support through these institutionalized pacts of long-term rent distribution.
Along with the introduction of multiparty elections – which in reality did little
to threaten incumbents since most opposition forces remained weak – the
introduction of power-sharing institutions allowed authoritarian leaders to
remain in power by limiting their absolute authority. In the post-Cold War
world, constrained authoritarianism is stable authoritarianism, and this
mode of governance persists across much of sub-Saharan Africa.
There are also important advantages to theorizing about authoritarian
stability by examining African dictatorships. There have been many semi-
nal studies of authoritarian institutions and strategies of rule in twentieth-
century China and Mexico23 – countries that do indeed have exceptionally
23
One cannot say the same, for instance, of Djibouti or Mauritania.
29
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1 Introduction
30
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1.9 Plan of the Book
31
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1 Introduction
32
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
1.9 Plan of the Book
Chapter 8: Conclusion
The final chapter concludes by summarizing five key claims made in this
book. I discuss each of the claims and highlight the empirical and theore-
tical contributions of these findings. I then consider the implications of
autocratic regime institutionalization for future studies of institutional
design, democratization, and democratic backsliding.
33
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.001 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2
Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
34
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
35
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
36
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.1 Institutions as Commitment Devices
from office of autocrats resulted from coups, compared with only 11 percent
that resulted from popular uprisings (Svolik 2012). For dictators to survive
they must maintain support from their closest allies. My account therefore
focuses on how leaders maintain support from their own regime elites.
Credibility problems affect autocrats’ abilities to maintain support
from inside of the regime (Cox 2016; Gehlbach and Keefer 2011; Haber
2008; Magaloni 2008; North and Weingast 1989; Stasavage 2003). As
Magaloni notes, dictators need to commit to “not abuse their ‘loyal
friends,’ [but] this commitment is hard to establish” (2). Studies that
focus on intra-elite commitment problems argue that power sharing
between leaders and elites is sustained only when elites have mechanisms
that allow them to check predation from leaders. In order for elites to be
able to effectively hold leaders accountable, they must be able to coordi-
nate a viable threat of rebellion (Boix and Svolik 2013; Myerson 2008).
Yet, a viable threat of rebellion from elites is often far from guaranteed in
an autocratic setting.
Most existing accounts of the commitment problem within the leader’s
inner circle argue that a lack of information hinders elite collective action
(Albertus and Menaldo 2012; Boix and Svolik 2013; Gehlbach and Keefer
2011; Myerson 2008). These studies argue that secrecy within authoritar-
ian governments prevent elites from being able to coordinate and com-
municate with each other. The lack of transparency also hinders elites’
abilities to monitor leader compliance. Furthermore, in regimes where
rules and norms are not clearly established, it is difficult for elites to agree
on what exact actions constitute a transgression. In sum, these studies
argue that information problems form the key barrier for elite collective
action, therefore preventing them from effectively keeping the despot’s
absolute power in check.
37
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
1
In fact, as the model will show, commitment problems that arise due to dynamic
power shifts can occur even with full information.
2
In Acemoglu and Robinson’s model of democratization, elites cannot voluntarily
give up power in order to prevent the masses from rebelling.
38
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.1 Institutions as Commitment Devices
39
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
It is important to note that while this chapter examines why certain types
of executive constraints emerge, I do not seek to explain the creation of
parties or legislatures in dictatorships. In fact, historical evidence often
suggests that many ruling parties are not strategically created, but instead,
inherited by leaders. Within my sample of African countries, for instance,
virtually all leaders came into power with a preexisting party in place
immediately following independence. These ruling parties were created
prior to independence not as elite power-sharing devices, but rather as pro-
independence organizations (Bienen 1970; 1978; Zolberg 1966; 1969) or
parties that were used to participate in preindependence elections (Collier
1982). Similarly, autocratic legislatures do not tend to predate political
parties (Cheibub, Gandhi, and Vreeland 2010). Together, this evidence
suggests that autocratic leaders often do not have total control over the
set of institutions that are available to them when they take power.
Rather than arguing that leaders make strategic decisions to create
institutions, this book argues that leaders make strategic decisions to
institutionalize their regimes after coming into power. Importantly, insti-
tutionalization can occur with or without the presence of formal institu-
tions such as parties or legislatures (though these institutions are very
commonly found). Political parties were banned in Swaziland in 1973,
and this law remains intact today. Despite the absence of parties,
Swaziland has stable prime minister appointments and constitutional
succession rules. Parties were banned in Ethiopia from 1960 through the
early 1980s, but the prime minister and defense minister positions were
filled and remained stable during those years. Equatorial Guinea under the
rule of Teodoro Obiang Nguema Mbasogo did not have a ruling party for
the first six years the leader was in power, but the cabinet had stable vice
president and defense minister appointments. Meanwhile, Niger under
the presidency of Hamani Diori did have a ruling party, the Nigerian
Progressive Party (PPN), but no institutionalized occurred; the regime
did not have formal leadership succession policies and key cabinet
appointments were kept empty.
If the creation of formal organizations such as parties is often histori-
cally determined, do dictators really have control over the content of state
constitutions? Historical accounts of how constitutions were drafted in
the newly independent African states corroborate the claim that leaders –
especially founding presidents – were given extraordinary leeway and
authority to construct their constitutions as they desired. Zolberg’s
account of the constitutional process in the newly independent Ivory
Coast highlights the fact that founding president, Felix Houphouet-
Boigny, had total control over the contents of the document.
40
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.2 A Theoretical Model
When work began on [drafting the constitution], most opposition leaders were
either in exile or had rejoined the [ruling Parti Démocratique de la Côte d’Ivoire
(PDCI) party]. There were no organs of public opinion in which the projects might
be discussed. The constitution of 1959 was therefore framed by a government and
an assembly dominated by a single party, itself controlled by one man. The
decision-making process itself reveals that Houphouet-Boigny and his lieutenants,
accountable only to one another, were unusually free to institutionalize their own
political preferences . . . . The constitution was . . . approved with almost no debate
in the Assembly on March 26, 1959. (Zolberg 1966, 250–251)
Leaders who came after the founding presidents also had control over the
content of state constitutions. Denis Sassou Nguesso, who came to power in
the Republic of Congo in 1979, issued a presidential decree in 1984 that
created a constitutional council. This consultative body (that was, in prac-
tice, accountable only to Sassou Nguesso) determined the constitutionality
of treaties and laws before their adoption by the National People’s
Assembly. At the same time, he then shut down the constitutional chamber
of the Supreme Court (Radu and Sommerville 1989). It is important to note
that even though these leaders may have the opportunity to remove the
constitutional constraints their predecessors implemented, they will not
necessarily do so if it is not in their own best interest.
3
As I argue in Section 2 of the chapter, intra-elite commitment problems arise due to
shifts in power, rather than information problems that prevent elite coordination.
Since this model does not focus on elite collective action problems, I treat the
coalition of elites as a single player (E) in the model.
41
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
In the first period, A offers x1 to E, who can accept the division or reject
it. If E accepts A’s offer in that period, then A and E receive payoffs of
1 x1 and x1 , respectively, and A remains in power. The game continues
onto the second period, and A makes a new offer.
If E rejects A’s offer in the first period, then conflict occurs. Elite
defections are known to be one of the primary drivers of authoritar-
ian breakdown, and the removal of support can be extremely danger-
ous for incumbents (Haggard and Kaufman 1995; Reuter and Gandhi
2011). Research on military coups has shown that they rarely succeed
without substantial civilian support. Militaries often oust govern-
ments during periods of crisis when citizens express discontent with
the civilian leader’s incompetence or mismanagement of the economy
(Geddes 2009).
If conflict occurs, A will be deposed with probability pt . We
assume that p1 > p2 so that power shifts against elites in the second
period. Elites are often strongest at the start of the regime when they
are well organized, before the leader has a chance to consolidate
power (Albertus and Menaldo 2012). Conflict ends strategic decision-
making in the game, and the winner receives all future benefits. If
fighting occurs in period 1, then the winner consumes the pie for both
periods. If fighting occurs in period 2, then the winner consumes the
pie for the final period. However, fighting is costly and destroys
a fraction of the pie. If conflict occurs, then only a fraction σ2 ð0; 1Þ
of the pie remains.
At the start of the game A decides whether to institutionalize her regime
by establishing executive constraints. Since credible executive constraints
provide elites with access to the state, we model it as a shift in the future
distribution of power away from the leader. Executive constraints are
represented by the parameter g2 ½0; 1 p2 . If A selects g > 0, then
the second period distribution of power will be p2 þ g. Any positive
value of g will shift the entire distribution of power away from A in
the second period. A’s offer in period 2 is affected by the institutional
decision she makes at the start of the game.4
This setup reflects the fact that most leaders establish constraints near
the start of their tenure. Leaders frequently draft new constitutions after
4
We assume that A does not value g inherently. She does not consume g; it only affects
the extent to which the distribution of p2 shifts. In other words, A only cares about
the results of g, rather than the inherent level of g. This assumption reflects the idea
that leaders do not have a preference ordering about the strategies they use to rule.
Instead, I assume that they care only about maximizing rents and time in office,
rather than the continuation of the regime after their death.
42
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.2 A Theoretical Model
43
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
reject
reject
1 − p2 1 1
2.3.1 No Institutionalization
When will the leader decide not to institutionalize the regime? In this
section, we show that an autocrat who initially enters power strong will
not face a commitment problem in period 1. She therefore does not need to
establish constraints in order to make an offer that is acceptable to the
elite.
Assume that a commitment problem never exists. If that is the case,
then A can always make an offer xt that can always be accepted in both
periods. In period 1, A makes E indifferent between accepting and reject-
ing an offer by satisfying the following condition:
Whether A will always be able to make this offer depends on her relative
strength in period 1. The largest possible per-period offer A can make is
44
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.3 Solving the Baseline Model
equal to the entire size of the pie, which is normalized to 1.5 Since A cannot
commit to future offers, each per-period offer cannot exceed 1.
Proposition 2.3.1: When p1 ≤ 2σ 1 ^ , then A can always make
þ p22 ≡ p
an offer x1 that can induce an acceptance by E. For all p1 2 ½0; p ^ ,
there exists an xt ≤ 1 such that E½UE ðrejectÞ ≤ E½UE ðacceptÞ.
Proposition 4.1 tells us that if A is strong when she first enters power,
she will not institutionalize. Recall that p1 is the probability that A will be
deposed, therefore when p1 is sufficiently low, A enters power in
a position of strength. Because the probability that E can successfully
depose A is very low, A will be able to make an offer that will match E’s
expected utility of rejecting, and commitment problems will not occur. In
this scenario, A will not institutionalize in equilibrium because she does
not need to in order to sustain peaceful bargaining.
How does the threshold of peaceful bargaining without institutionali-
zation, denoted by p ^ , change relative to the future distribution of power?
Proposition 2.3.2: As A’s period 2 strength decreases, the range for
peaceful bargaining without institutionalization increases.
∂p ^
Formally, ∂p2
> 0.
Put together, Propositions 4.1 and 4.2 produce some interesting counter-
intuitive results. When A enters power strong, she will not institutionalize
because she can make an offer that will satisfy E. In this case, peaceful
bargaining can be sustained without institutionalization, where E has no
guarantees over future rent distribution. However, keeping A’s initial
strength constant, as p2 increases, E’s continuation value also increases.
When E can rely on future de facto power, this puts less pressure on the
period 1 offer. In this case, peaceful bargaining can also be sustained with-
out institutionalization due to a different mechanism. When E becomes
more powerful in period 2, he will not need to fight in period 1 because he is
guaranteed future rent distribution through increasing de facto power.
2.3.2 Institutionalization
Now let’s assume that p1 > p^ . An offer x1 large enough to induce an
acceptance from E cannot be made without some positive level of institu-
tionalization g > 0.
5
If p1 is very small relative to p2 , 2σp1 σp2 can actually be a negative number.
Because offers are restricted to be within ½0; 1 we must restrict x1 to nonnegative
numbers.
45
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
1
g ¼ 2p1 p2 (4)
σ
As long as A sets g ¼ g , she will be able to make an offer x1 ¼ 1 that will
satisfy E in period 1.6 In the appendix we show that A will always be able
to set g ¼ g .7
6
Changing the functional form of g does not alter the results substantively. For
instance, if g was inefficient, say some input ^ g would only shift the distribution by
gÞ < ^
f ð^g Þ such that f ð^ g , A will not be more or less likely to institutionalize. See
Appendix A at the end of this chapter for discussion.
7
Recall that g is bounded above by 1 p2 , therefore A can establish the equilibrium
level of institutionalization only if g ≤ 1 p2 .
46
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.3 Solving the Baseline Model
8
Recall that if a commitment problem occurs in period 1, then A will set x1 ¼ 1 and
consume nothing in the first period.
47
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
g*
g*
No Institution−
No Institution− institutionalization alization
institutionalization alization
^p = 0.86 1 ^p = 0.71 1
P1 P1
Note: σ = .9, p2 = .6 Note: σ = .9, p2 = .3
2.3.3 Discussion
The model makes a number of important predictions, which we summar-
ize in this section. First, the model shows that there are two different types
of autocratic rule, which differ based on the leader’s relative strength
when she first comes into office. Leaders who enter office initially strong
are never incentivized to institutionalize because their initial likelihood of
being deposed is very low. Such leaders prefer not to empower elites by
providing them access to the state because they are always able to make
a per-period transfer that elites will accept. As a result, peaceful bargain-
ing can be sustained in a no-institutionalization equilibrium where
48
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.3 Solving the Baseline Model
initially strong autocrats remain in power but do not provide elites with
access to the state.
On the other hand, leaders who enter office initially weak are incenti-
vized to institutionalize because they cannot sustain peaceful bargaining
without shifting the future distribution of power in favor of elites.
Empowering elites in the second period relaxes demands on the first
period transfer by raising the elite continuation value, which allows
initially weak autocrats to made credible future promises to elites.
Although doing so weakens the leader in the future, she is willing to
institutionalize in order to remain in power for both periods of the
game. In this case, peaceful bargaining can also be sustained in an insti-
tutionalization equilibrium where initially weak autocrats remain in
power only by providing elites with access to the state.
These two different types of autocratic rule have one very important
feature in common: both initially strong leaders and initially weak leaders
who institutionalize remain in power for both periods of the game. In
other words, conditional on the weak type institutionalizing, the leader
will be able to remain in power for the same length of time as the initially
strong type.
This feature highlights an important empirical point, which we will
return to in Chapter 6: scholars should not assume that regimes that are
long-lived have strong institutions. Leader tenure does not serve as
a useful proxy for the quality of institutions due to the strategic nature
of institutionalization. Initially weak leaders are incentivized to institu-
tionalize in order to remain in power because they would otherwise face
commitment problems in bargaining and risk being deposed by elites.
When weak leaders institutionalize, they can indeed remain in power for
longer periods of time.
Initially strong leaders, on the other hand, can remain in power regard-
less of whether they have strong institutions or not, because they do not
face commitment problems in bargaining. In fact, as the model shows,
leaders who enter power strong do not institutionalize yet are able to
remain in power for both periods of the game. We should therefore expect
to see a systematic relationship between leader tenure and institutional
strength only when we condition on initial leader strength. This may help
to explain why existing empirical studies, which do not condition on
leader strength have found inconsistent relationships between the pre-
sence of strong institutions and leader tenure (for instance, see Gandhi
2008; Lucardi 2017; Smith 2005).
These results provide some interesting contrasts with findings from
existing models. In the Acemoglu and Robinson (2006) model, a main
finding is that democratization is most likely to occur if the poor pose
49
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
9
Note that in the Acemoglu and Robinson model, elites are the analogous player as
the autocrat (A) in my model, and the poor are the analogous player as the elite (E)
in my model.
10
Unlike in the Acemoglu and Robinson model, where the probability that elites will
be unseated jumps discontinuously from 0 to 1 if the poor initiate a revolution, pt is
a continuous parameter in my model.
50
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.4 Model Extension: Imperfect Information
µ µ
pm − µ pm pm + µ
0 1
µ µ
pm − µ + g pm + g pm + µ + g
0 1
11
We assume that μ is sufficiently small, such that pm μ > 0 and pm μ < 1.
51
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
reject
1 − (pm + µ) 1 pm + µ + g 1
0 0 pm − µ + g 0
Figure 2.4 Game tree: model extension
52
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.4 Model Extension: Imperfect Information
As a result, fighting can occur in period 1. The full proofs for the modified
game are presented in Appendix B at the end of the chapter.
Similar to the baseline model, when p1 is sufficiently low, A will not
institutionalize because she is always able to make an offer x1 that E will
accept. However, when A enters power weak, a commitment problem will
arise in period 1 if g ¼ 0. We can establish that there exists some g > 0
that would allow A to make an offer x1 ¼ 1 that can satisfy E in period 1.
For this game, g ¼ 2p1 pm 1σ .
Will A always be able to set x1 ¼ 1? In the modified version of the
game, g is bounded above by 1 ðpm þ μÞ. Therefore g is feasible only if
g ≤ 1 ðpm þ μÞ.
Proposition 2.4.1: As long as p1 is sufficiently small, A will be able
to set g ¼ g in order to allow a peaceful bargain to go through in
period 1. Formally, as long as p1 ≤ 12 þ 2σ1
μ2 ≡ p, there exists a
g ¼ g such that E½UE ðrejectÞ ≤ E½UE ðacceptÞ.
A key implication of Proposition 2.4.1 is that conflict will occur in
equilibrium if p1 is not sufficiently small. When p1 > p, even if
A were to set g to the highest possible level, she still cannot prevent
conflict from occurring in period 1 because the level of institutiona-
lization (g ) necessary to allow all bargains to go through peacefully
is larger than the maximum possible value of g. We establish in
the appendix that A still always prefers to institutionalize when
faced with a commitment problem, however, now she cannot always
do so.
Proposition 2.4.2: The equilibrium of the modified game can be
characterized as following:
^ , A will set g ¼ 0. In period 1,
1. No Institutionalization: If p1 ≤ p
A will offer x1 ¼ x1 , and in period 2, A will offer x2 ¼ σp2 .
In each round, E will accept each offer if
EUE ðacceptÞ ≥ EUE ðrejectÞ and reject otherwise.
^ and p1 ≤ p, A will set g ¼ g . In
2. Institutionalization: If p1 > p
period 1, A will offer x1 ¼ maxf0; x1 g, and in period 2, A will
53
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
2 . 5 co n c l u s i o n
This chapter sought to understand why we see differences in the organiza-
tional capacity of authoritarian regimes by examining the creation of
constraints limiting executive power. Constraints bind only when they
provide elites with access to important government positions, empowering
them to hold the incumbent accountable to promises about rent distribu-
tion. Through a formal model I demonstrated that strong autocrats who
enter power with a low probability of being deposed are less likely to
institutionalize. Initially weak autocrats without such guarantees of stabi-
lity are more likely to pursue institutionalization in order to maintain
support from elites. Importantly, rather than assuming that institutions
constrain leaders, I show how institutions can provide credible commit-
ment power by shifting the future distribution of power in favor of elites.
The next chapter of the book illustrates the primary findings of the model
through two illustrative case studies of Cameroon and Côte d’Ivoire.
54
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
^ also
Proof of Proposition 2.3.2. It is easy to see that as p2 increases, p
increases:
^
∂p 1
¼ >0 (6)
∂p2 2
Proof of Lemma 2.3.1. A must choose values of x1 and g such that the
following equation is satisfied:
2σp1 ≤ x1 þ VE (7)
2σp1 ≤ x1 þ σEVðp2 Þ
2σp1 ≤ x1 þ σðp2 þ gÞ (8)
2σp1 σp2 ≤ x1 þ σg
2σp1 ≤ 1 þ VE (9)
To determine the continuation value, note that if the game moves peace-
fully onto the second period, there will never be fighting. Even if p2 ¼ 1
and σ ¼ 1, A can always offer x2 ¼ 1. Therefore we know that VE is
simply equal to E’s expected utility of rejecting in period 2, since A will
always try to make the cheapest possible offer to E.
VE ¼ EUE ðrejectÞ
¼ σEVðp2 Þ (10)
¼ σðp2 þ gÞ
We now plug E’s continuation value into the equation and solve for g.
55
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
2σp1 1 ≤ VE
2σp1 1 ≤ σðp2 þ gÞ (11)
1
g ¼ 2p1 p2
σ
We can establish that changing the functional form of g does not alter the
results substantively. Instead of assuming that wðgÞ ¼ g, let’s assume that
institutions are extremely efficient, such that hðe gÞ > e g (in other words,
hð Þ is concave). How would e g compare with g ? We know that
g ¼ 2p1 p2 1σ ¼ hðe gÞ > e
g : Therefore, g > e g . Unsurprisingly,
when institutions are efficient, lower levels of institutionalization are
required to sustain peaceful bargaining.
Interestingly, however, this does not change the threshold, p ^ of insti-
tutionalization, nor does it make A more or less willing to institutionalize,
compared with when wðgÞ ¼ g. First, note that g does not affect the
calculation of the threshold, p ^ . Second, recall that A does not value g
inherently. She does not consume g, it only affects the extent to which the
distribution of p2 shifts. In other words, A only cares about the results of g,
rather than the inherent level of g. Therefore, even if g was inefficient, say
gÞ < ^
if f ð^ g , A will still always be willing to institutionalize.
Proof. We show that A will always be able to set g ¼ g . Recall that g is
bounded above by 1 p2 , therefore A can establish the equilibrium level
of constraints if g ≤ 1 p2 .
g ≤ 1 p2
1
2p1 p2 ≤ 1 p2 (12)
σ
1 1
p1 ≤ þ
2 2σ
Since σ2 ½0; 1, equation (12) is always true.
Proof of Proposition 2.3.3. It is easy to see that as p1 increases, g also
increases:
∂g
¼2>0 (13)
∂p1
56
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
∂g 1
¼ 2>0 (15)
∂σ σ
Proof of Proposition 2.3.6. This proof follows directly from the construc-
tion of g , which is the minimal level of g that guarantees that the follow-
ing condition is true: EUE ðrejectÞ ≤ EUE ðacceptÞ. If g ≥ g , then E will
always accept in period 1. If the game makes it to period 2, then conflict
will never occur because p2 < 1 by assumption, therefore A will always be
able to make an offer x2 that can induce an acceptance by E.
Proof of Proposition 2.3.7. A’s second period consumption is simply
1 x2 , since she can always make an offer x2 that can induce an accep-
tance by E. It is easy to see that 1 x2 is decreasing in g:
∂ð1 x2 Þ
¼ σ < 0 (16)
∂g
A gets to pocket the portion of the pie that she doesn’t offer to E, therefore
her continuation value is the size of the pie minus the expected value of the
period 2 offer, x2 .
VA ¼ 1 EVðx2 Þ (20)
57
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
VA ¼ 1 EVðx2 Þ
(23)
¼ 2 2σp1
EUA ðg ¼ g Þ ≥ EUA ðg ¼ 0Þ
2 2σp1 ≥ 2σð1 p1 Þ (24)
1≥σ
58
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
σðp2 þ g Þ
EVðx2 Þ ¼
1
¼ σp2 þ σ 2p1 p2 (26)
σ
¼ 2σp1 1
59
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
expected utility for A than fighting in period 1. A’s strict best response,
given that g ¼ g is to offer x1 ¼ 1 in period 1. E’s best response is to
accept x1 ¼ 1 because by construction, g ensures that E’s expected utility
of accepting x1 ¼ 1 is greater than or equal to his expected utility of
fighting in period 1.
We now move to the very start of the game, where A decides what to set
g. We have already established that the following is always true:
EUA ðinstitutionalizeÞ ≥ EUA ðnot institutionalizeÞ. Therefore if p1 > p^,
then A’s best response is to set g ¼ g at the onset of the game.
Whether A will always be able to make this offer depends on her relative
strength in period 1. Since A cannot commit to future offers, the largest
possible period 1 offer she can make is x1 ¼ 1. We plug in x1 ¼ 1 and
solve for p1 . When p1 ≤ 2σ
1 ^ , then A can always make an offer x1
þ p2m ≡ p
that can induce an acceptance by E.
60
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
1
g ¼ 2p1 pm (31)
σ
As long as A sets g ¼ g , she will be able to make an offer x1 ¼ 1 that will
satisfy E in period 1. However, we show that A will not always be able to
set g at a high enough level if g > maxðgÞ.
Proof of Proposition 2.4.1. We established above that as long as A sets
g ¼ g , she will be able to make an offer, x1 , that E will accept and conflict
will not occur in period 1. However, g is bounded above by 1 ðpm þ μÞ
because it is drawn from the following distribution: g2 ½0; 1 ðpm þ μÞ.
To see why g is bounded above by 1 ðpm þ μÞ, refer to Figure 2.3. g
shifts the entire distribution of p2 upward, and the largest value the upper
bound of p2 can take is 1. Therefore the largest possible value g can take is
the distance between 1 and the upper bound of the original distribution of
p2 , pm þ μ.
A can set g ¼ g only when g ≤ 1 ðpm þ μÞ.
g ≤ 1 ðpm þ μÞ
1
2p1 pm ≤ 1 ðpm þ μÞ (32)
σ
1 1 μ
p1 ≤ þ ≡p
2 2σ 2
A can set g ¼ g only when p1 ≤ p. When p1 > p, even if A were to set g to
the highest possible level, it would not be high enough to prevent conflict
in period 1.
61
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
62
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
63
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.002 Published online by Cambridge University Press
2
Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
34
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
35
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
36
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.1 Institutions as Commitment Devices
from office of autocrats resulted from coups, compared with only 11 percent
that resulted from popular uprisings (Svolik 2012). For dictators to survive
they must maintain support from their closest allies. My account therefore
focuses on how leaders maintain support from their own regime elites.
Credibility problems affect autocrats’ abilities to maintain support
from inside of the regime (Cox 2016; Gehlbach and Keefer 2011; Haber
2008; Magaloni 2008; North and Weingast 1989; Stasavage 2003). As
Magaloni notes, dictators need to commit to “not abuse their ‘loyal
friends,’ [but] this commitment is hard to establish” (2). Studies that
focus on intra-elite commitment problems argue that power sharing
between leaders and elites is sustained only when elites have mechanisms
that allow them to check predation from leaders. In order for elites to be
able to effectively hold leaders accountable, they must be able to coordi-
nate a viable threat of rebellion (Boix and Svolik 2013; Myerson 2008).
Yet, a viable threat of rebellion from elites is often far from guaranteed in
an autocratic setting.
Most existing accounts of the commitment problem within the leader’s
inner circle argue that a lack of information hinders elite collective action
(Albertus and Menaldo 2012; Boix and Svolik 2013; Gehlbach and Keefer
2011; Myerson 2008). These studies argue that secrecy within authoritar-
ian governments prevent elites from being able to coordinate and com-
municate with each other. The lack of transparency also hinders elites’
abilities to monitor leader compliance. Furthermore, in regimes where
rules and norms are not clearly established, it is difficult for elites to agree
on what exact actions constitute a transgression. In sum, these studies
argue that information problems form the key barrier for elite collective
action, therefore preventing them from effectively keeping the despot’s
absolute power in check.
37
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
1
In fact, as the model will show, commitment problems that arise due to dynamic
power shifts can occur even with full information.
2
In Acemoglu and Robinson’s model of democratization, elites cannot voluntarily
give up power in order to prevent the masses from rebelling.
38
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.1 Institutions as Commitment Devices
39
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
It is important to note that while this chapter examines why certain types
of executive constraints emerge, I do not seek to explain the creation of
parties or legislatures in dictatorships. In fact, historical evidence often
suggests that many ruling parties are not strategically created, but instead,
inherited by leaders. Within my sample of African countries, for instance,
virtually all leaders came into power with a preexisting party in place
immediately following independence. These ruling parties were created
prior to independence not as elite power-sharing devices, but rather as pro-
independence organizations (Bienen 1970; 1978; Zolberg 1966; 1969) or
parties that were used to participate in preindependence elections (Collier
1982). Similarly, autocratic legislatures do not tend to predate political
parties (Cheibub, Gandhi, and Vreeland 2010). Together, this evidence
suggests that autocratic leaders often do not have total control over the
set of institutions that are available to them when they take power.
Rather than arguing that leaders make strategic decisions to create
institutions, this book argues that leaders make strategic decisions to
institutionalize their regimes after coming into power. Importantly, insti-
tutionalization can occur with or without the presence of formal institu-
tions such as parties or legislatures (though these institutions are very
commonly found). Political parties were banned in Swaziland in 1973,
and this law remains intact today. Despite the absence of parties,
Swaziland has stable prime minister appointments and constitutional
succession rules. Parties were banned in Ethiopia from 1960 through the
early 1980s, but the prime minister and defense minister positions were
filled and remained stable during those years. Equatorial Guinea under the
rule of Teodoro Obiang Nguema Mbasogo did not have a ruling party for
the first six years the leader was in power, but the cabinet had stable vice
president and defense minister appointments. Meanwhile, Niger under
the presidency of Hamani Diori did have a ruling party, the Nigerian
Progressive Party (PPN), but no institutionalized occurred; the regime
did not have formal leadership succession policies and key cabinet
appointments were kept empty.
If the creation of formal organizations such as parties is often histori-
cally determined, do dictators really have control over the content of state
constitutions? Historical accounts of how constitutions were drafted in
the newly independent African states corroborate the claim that leaders –
especially founding presidents – were given extraordinary leeway and
authority to construct their constitutions as they desired. Zolberg’s
account of the constitutional process in the newly independent Ivory
Coast highlights the fact that founding president, Felix Houphouet-
Boigny, had total control over the contents of the document.
40
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.2 A Theoretical Model
When work began on [drafting the constitution], most opposition leaders were
either in exile or had rejoined the [ruling Parti Démocratique de la Côte d’Ivoire
(PDCI) party]. There were no organs of public opinion in which the projects might
be discussed. The constitution of 1959 was therefore framed by a government and
an assembly dominated by a single party, itself controlled by one man. The
decision-making process itself reveals that Houphouet-Boigny and his lieutenants,
accountable only to one another, were unusually free to institutionalize their own
political preferences . . . . The constitution was . . . approved with almost no debate
in the Assembly on March 26, 1959. (Zolberg 1966, 250–251)
Leaders who came after the founding presidents also had control over the
content of state constitutions. Denis Sassou Nguesso, who came to power in
the Republic of Congo in 1979, issued a presidential decree in 1984 that
created a constitutional council. This consultative body (that was, in prac-
tice, accountable only to Sassou Nguesso) determined the constitutionality
of treaties and laws before their adoption by the National People’s
Assembly. At the same time, he then shut down the constitutional chamber
of the Supreme Court (Radu and Sommerville 1989). It is important to note
that even though these leaders may have the opportunity to remove the
constitutional constraints their predecessors implemented, they will not
necessarily do so if it is not in their own best interest.
3
As I argue in Section 2 of the chapter, intra-elite commitment problems arise due to
shifts in power, rather than information problems that prevent elite coordination.
Since this model does not focus on elite collective action problems, I treat the
coalition of elites as a single player (E) in the model.
41
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
In the first period, A offers x1 to E, who can accept the division or reject
it. If E accepts A’s offer in that period, then A and E receive payoffs of
1 x1 and x1 , respectively, and A remains in power. The game continues
onto the second period, and A makes a new offer.
If E rejects A’s offer in the first period, then conflict occurs. Elite
defections are known to be one of the primary drivers of authoritar-
ian breakdown, and the removal of support can be extremely danger-
ous for incumbents (Haggard and Kaufman 1995; Reuter and Gandhi
2011). Research on military coups has shown that they rarely succeed
without substantial civilian support. Militaries often oust govern-
ments during periods of crisis when citizens express discontent with
the civilian leader’s incompetence or mismanagement of the economy
(Geddes 2009).
If conflict occurs, A will be deposed with probability pt . We
assume that p1 > p2 so that power shifts against elites in the second
period. Elites are often strongest at the start of the regime when they
are well organized, before the leader has a chance to consolidate
power (Albertus and Menaldo 2012). Conflict ends strategic decision-
making in the game, and the winner receives all future benefits. If
fighting occurs in period 1, then the winner consumes the pie for both
periods. If fighting occurs in period 2, then the winner consumes the
pie for the final period. However, fighting is costly and destroys
a fraction of the pie. If conflict occurs, then only a fraction σ2 ð0; 1Þ
of the pie remains.
At the start of the game A decides whether to institutionalize her regime
by establishing executive constraints. Since credible executive constraints
provide elites with access to the state, we model it as a shift in the future
distribution of power away from the leader. Executive constraints are
represented by the parameter g2 ½0; 1 p2 . If A selects g > 0, then
the second period distribution of power will be p2 þ g. Any positive
value of g will shift the entire distribution of power away from A in
the second period. A’s offer in period 2 is affected by the institutional
decision she makes at the start of the game.4
This setup reflects the fact that most leaders establish constraints near
the start of their tenure. Leaders frequently draft new constitutions after
4
We assume that A does not value g inherently. She does not consume g; it only affects
the extent to which the distribution of p2 shifts. In other words, A only cares about
the results of g, rather than the inherent level of g. This assumption reflects the idea
that leaders do not have a preference ordering about the strategies they use to rule.
Instead, I assume that they care only about maximizing rents and time in office,
rather than the continuation of the regime after their death.
42
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.2 A Theoretical Model
43
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
reject
reject
1 − p2 1 1
2.3.1 No Institutionalization
When will the leader decide not to institutionalize the regime? In this
section, we show that an autocrat who initially enters power strong will
not face a commitment problem in period 1. She therefore does not need to
establish constraints in order to make an offer that is acceptable to the
elite.
Assume that a commitment problem never exists. If that is the case,
then A can always make an offer xt that can always be accepted in both
periods. In period 1, A makes E indifferent between accepting and reject-
ing an offer by satisfying the following condition:
Whether A will always be able to make this offer depends on her relative
strength in period 1. The largest possible per-period offer A can make is
44
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.3 Solving the Baseline Model
equal to the entire size of the pie, which is normalized to 1.5 Since A cannot
commit to future offers, each per-period offer cannot exceed 1.
Proposition 2.3.1: When p1 ≤ 2σ 1 ^ , then A can always make
þ p22 ≡ p
an offer x1 that can induce an acceptance by E. For all p1 2 ½0; p ^ ,
there exists an xt ≤ 1 such that E½UE ðrejectÞ ≤ E½UE ðacceptÞ.
Proposition 4.1 tells us that if A is strong when she first enters power,
she will not institutionalize. Recall that p1 is the probability that A will be
deposed, therefore when p1 is sufficiently low, A enters power in
a position of strength. Because the probability that E can successfully
depose A is very low, A will be able to make an offer that will match E’s
expected utility of rejecting, and commitment problems will not occur. In
this scenario, A will not institutionalize in equilibrium because she does
not need to in order to sustain peaceful bargaining.
How does the threshold of peaceful bargaining without institutionali-
zation, denoted by p ^ , change relative to the future distribution of power?
Proposition 2.3.2: As A’s period 2 strength decreases, the range for
peaceful bargaining without institutionalization increases.
∂p ^
Formally, ∂p2
> 0.
Put together, Propositions 4.1 and 4.2 produce some interesting counter-
intuitive results. When A enters power strong, she will not institutionalize
because she can make an offer that will satisfy E. In this case, peaceful
bargaining can be sustained without institutionalization, where E has no
guarantees over future rent distribution. However, keeping A’s initial
strength constant, as p2 increases, E’s continuation value also increases.
When E can rely on future de facto power, this puts less pressure on the
period 1 offer. In this case, peaceful bargaining can also be sustained with-
out institutionalization due to a different mechanism. When E becomes
more powerful in period 2, he will not need to fight in period 1 because he is
guaranteed future rent distribution through increasing de facto power.
2.3.2 Institutionalization
Now let’s assume that p1 > p^ . An offer x1 large enough to induce an
acceptance from E cannot be made without some positive level of institu-
tionalization g > 0.
5
If p1 is very small relative to p2 , 2σp1 σp2 can actually be a negative number.
Because offers are restricted to be within ½0; 1 we must restrict x1 to nonnegative
numbers.
45
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
1
g ¼ 2p1 p2 (4)
σ
As long as A sets g ¼ g , she will be able to make an offer x1 ¼ 1 that will
satisfy E in period 1.6 In the appendix we show that A will always be able
to set g ¼ g .7
6
Changing the functional form of g does not alter the results substantively. For
instance, if g was inefficient, say some input ^ g would only shift the distribution by
gÞ < ^
f ð^g Þ such that f ð^ g , A will not be more or less likely to institutionalize. See
Appendix A at the end of this chapter for discussion.
7
Recall that g is bounded above by 1 p2 , therefore A can establish the equilibrium
level of institutionalization only if g ≤ 1 p2 .
46
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.3 Solving the Baseline Model
8
Recall that if a commitment problem occurs in period 1, then A will set x1 ¼ 1 and
consume nothing in the first period.
47
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
g*
g*
No Institution−
No Institution− institutionalization alization
institutionalization alization
^p = 0.86 1 ^p = 0.71 1
P1 P1
Note: σ = .9, p2 = .6 Note: σ = .9, p2 = .3
2.3.3 Discussion
The model makes a number of important predictions, which we summar-
ize in this section. First, the model shows that there are two different types
of autocratic rule, which differ based on the leader’s relative strength
when she first comes into office. Leaders who enter office initially strong
are never incentivized to institutionalize because their initial likelihood of
being deposed is very low. Such leaders prefer not to empower elites by
providing them access to the state because they are always able to make
a per-period transfer that elites will accept. As a result, peaceful bargain-
ing can be sustained in a no-institutionalization equilibrium where
48
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.3 Solving the Baseline Model
initially strong autocrats remain in power but do not provide elites with
access to the state.
On the other hand, leaders who enter office initially weak are incenti-
vized to institutionalize because they cannot sustain peaceful bargaining
without shifting the future distribution of power in favor of elites.
Empowering elites in the second period relaxes demands on the first
period transfer by raising the elite continuation value, which allows
initially weak autocrats to made credible future promises to elites.
Although doing so weakens the leader in the future, she is willing to
institutionalize in order to remain in power for both periods of the
game. In this case, peaceful bargaining can also be sustained in an insti-
tutionalization equilibrium where initially weak autocrats remain in
power only by providing elites with access to the state.
These two different types of autocratic rule have one very important
feature in common: both initially strong leaders and initially weak leaders
who institutionalize remain in power for both periods of the game. In
other words, conditional on the weak type institutionalizing, the leader
will be able to remain in power for the same length of time as the initially
strong type.
This feature highlights an important empirical point, which we will
return to in Chapter 6: scholars should not assume that regimes that are
long-lived have strong institutions. Leader tenure does not serve as
a useful proxy for the quality of institutions due to the strategic nature
of institutionalization. Initially weak leaders are incentivized to institu-
tionalize in order to remain in power because they would otherwise face
commitment problems in bargaining and risk being deposed by elites.
When weak leaders institutionalize, they can indeed remain in power for
longer periods of time.
Initially strong leaders, on the other hand, can remain in power regard-
less of whether they have strong institutions or not, because they do not
face commitment problems in bargaining. In fact, as the model shows,
leaders who enter power strong do not institutionalize yet are able to
remain in power for both periods of the game. We should therefore expect
to see a systematic relationship between leader tenure and institutional
strength only when we condition on initial leader strength. This may help
to explain why existing empirical studies, which do not condition on
leader strength have found inconsistent relationships between the pre-
sence of strong institutions and leader tenure (for instance, see Gandhi
2008; Lucardi 2017; Smith 2005).
These results provide some interesting contrasts with findings from
existing models. In the Acemoglu and Robinson (2006) model, a main
finding is that democratization is most likely to occur if the poor pose
49
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
9
Note that in the Acemoglu and Robinson model, elites are the analogous player as
the autocrat (A) in my model, and the poor are the analogous player as the elite (E)
in my model.
10
Unlike in the Acemoglu and Robinson model, where the probability that elites will
be unseated jumps discontinuously from 0 to 1 if the poor initiate a revolution, pt is
a continuous parameter in my model.
50
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.4 Model Extension: Imperfect Information
µ µ
pm − µ pm pm + µ
0 1
µ µ
pm − µ + g pm + g pm + µ + g
0 1
11
We assume that μ is sufficiently small, such that pm μ > 0 and pm μ < 1.
51
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
reject
1 − (pm + µ) 1 pm + µ + g 1
0 0 pm − µ + g 0
Figure 2.4 Game tree: model extension
52
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.4 Model Extension: Imperfect Information
As a result, fighting can occur in period 1. The full proofs for the modified
game are presented in Appendix B at the end of the chapter.
Similar to the baseline model, when p1 is sufficiently low, A will not
institutionalize because she is always able to make an offer x1 that E will
accept. However, when A enters power weak, a commitment problem will
arise in period 1 if g ¼ 0. We can establish that there exists some g > 0
that would allow A to make an offer x1 ¼ 1 that can satisfy E in period 1.
For this game, g ¼ 2p1 pm 1σ .
Will A always be able to set x1 ¼ 1? In the modified version of the
game, g is bounded above by 1 ðpm þ μÞ. Therefore g is feasible only if
g ≤ 1 ðpm þ μÞ.
Proposition 2.4.1: As long as p1 is sufficiently small, A will be able
to set g ¼ g in order to allow a peaceful bargain to go through in
period 1. Formally, as long as p1 ≤ 12 þ 2σ1
μ2 ≡ p, there exists a
g ¼ g such that E½UE ðrejectÞ ≤ E½UE ðacceptÞ.
A key implication of Proposition 2.4.1 is that conflict will occur in
equilibrium if p1 is not sufficiently small. When p1 > p, even if
A were to set g to the highest possible level, she still cannot prevent
conflict from occurring in period 1 because the level of institutiona-
lization (g ) necessary to allow all bargains to go through peacefully
is larger than the maximum possible value of g. We establish in
the appendix that A still always prefers to institutionalize when
faced with a commitment problem, however, now she cannot always
do so.
Proposition 2.4.2: The equilibrium of the modified game can be
characterized as following:
^ , A will set g ¼ 0. In period 1,
1. No Institutionalization: If p1 ≤ p
A will offer x1 ¼ x1 , and in period 2, A will offer x2 ¼ σp2 .
In each round, E will accept each offer if
EUE ðacceptÞ ≥ EUE ðrejectÞ and reject otherwise.
^ and p1 ≤ p, A will set g ¼ g . In
2. Institutionalization: If p1 > p
period 1, A will offer x1 ¼ maxf0; x1 g, and in period 2, A will
53
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
2 . 5 co n c l u s i o n
This chapter sought to understand why we see differences in the organiza-
tional capacity of authoritarian regimes by examining the creation of
constraints limiting executive power. Constraints bind only when they
provide elites with access to important government positions, empowering
them to hold the incumbent accountable to promises about rent distribu-
tion. Through a formal model I demonstrated that strong autocrats who
enter power with a low probability of being deposed are less likely to
institutionalize. Initially weak autocrats without such guarantees of stabi-
lity are more likely to pursue institutionalization in order to maintain
support from elites. Importantly, rather than assuming that institutions
constrain leaders, I show how institutions can provide credible commit-
ment power by shifting the future distribution of power in favor of elites.
The next chapter of the book illustrates the primary findings of the model
through two illustrative case studies of Cameroon and Côte d’Ivoire.
54
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
^ also
Proof of Proposition 2.3.2. It is easy to see that as p2 increases, p
increases:
^
∂p 1
¼ >0 (6)
∂p2 2
Proof of Lemma 2.3.1. A must choose values of x1 and g such that the
following equation is satisfied:
2σp1 ≤ x1 þ VE (7)
2σp1 ≤ x1 þ σEVðp2 Þ
2σp1 ≤ x1 þ σðp2 þ gÞ (8)
2σp1 σp2 ≤ x1 þ σg
2σp1 ≤ 1 þ VE (9)
To determine the continuation value, note that if the game moves peace-
fully onto the second period, there will never be fighting. Even if p2 ¼ 1
and σ ¼ 1, A can always offer x2 ¼ 1. Therefore we know that VE is
simply equal to E’s expected utility of rejecting in period 2, since A will
always try to make the cheapest possible offer to E.
VE ¼ EUE ðrejectÞ
¼ σEVðp2 Þ (10)
¼ σðp2 þ gÞ
We now plug E’s continuation value into the equation and solve for g.
55
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
2σp1 1 ≤ VE
2σp1 1 ≤ σðp2 þ gÞ (11)
1
g ¼ 2p1 p2
σ
We can establish that changing the functional form of g does not alter the
results substantively. Instead of assuming that wðgÞ ¼ g, let’s assume that
institutions are extremely efficient, such that hðe gÞ > e g (in other words,
hð Þ is concave). How would e g compare with g ? We know that
g ¼ 2p1 p2 1σ ¼ hðe gÞ > e
g : Therefore, g > e g . Unsurprisingly,
when institutions are efficient, lower levels of institutionalization are
required to sustain peaceful bargaining.
Interestingly, however, this does not change the threshold, p ^ of insti-
tutionalization, nor does it make A more or less willing to institutionalize,
compared with when wðgÞ ¼ g. First, note that g does not affect the
calculation of the threshold, p ^ . Second, recall that A does not value g
inherently. She does not consume g, it only affects the extent to which the
distribution of p2 shifts. In other words, A only cares about the results of g,
rather than the inherent level of g. Therefore, even if g was inefficient, say
gÞ < ^
if f ð^ g , A will still always be willing to institutionalize.
Proof. We show that A will always be able to set g ¼ g . Recall that g is
bounded above by 1 p2 , therefore A can establish the equilibrium level
of constraints if g ≤ 1 p2 .
g ≤ 1 p2
1
2p1 p2 ≤ 1 p2 (12)
σ
1 1
p1 ≤ þ
2 2σ
Since σ2 ½0; 1, equation (12) is always true.
Proof of Proposition 2.3.3. It is easy to see that as p1 increases, g also
increases:
∂g
¼2>0 (13)
∂p1
56
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
∂g 1
¼ 2>0 (15)
∂σ σ
Proof of Proposition 2.3.6. This proof follows directly from the construc-
tion of g , which is the minimal level of g that guarantees that the follow-
ing condition is true: EUE ðrejectÞ ≤ EUE ðacceptÞ. If g ≥ g , then E will
always accept in period 1. If the game makes it to period 2, then conflict
will never occur because p2 < 1 by assumption, therefore A will always be
able to make an offer x2 that can induce an acceptance by E.
Proof of Proposition 2.3.7. A’s second period consumption is simply
1 x2 , since she can always make an offer x2 that can induce an accep-
tance by E. It is easy to see that 1 x2 is decreasing in g:
∂ð1 x2 Þ
¼ σ < 0 (16)
∂g
A gets to pocket the portion of the pie that she doesn’t offer to E, therefore
her continuation value is the size of the pie minus the expected value of the
period 2 offer, x2 .
VA ¼ 1 EVðx2 Þ (20)
57
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
VA ¼ 1 EVðx2 Þ
(23)
¼ 2 2σp1
EUA ðg ¼ g Þ ≥ EUA ðg ¼ 0Þ
2 2σp1 ≥ 2σð1 p1 Þ (24)
1≥σ
58
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
σðp2 þ g Þ
EVðx2 Þ ¼
1
¼ σp2 þ σ 2p1 p2 (26)
σ
¼ 2σp1 1
59
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
expected utility for A than fighting in period 1. A’s strict best response,
given that g ¼ g is to offer x1 ¼ 1 in period 1. E’s best response is to
accept x1 ¼ 1 because by construction, g ensures that E’s expected utility
of accepting x1 ¼ 1 is greater than or equal to his expected utility of
fighting in period 1.
We now move to the very start of the game, where A decides what to set
g. We have already established that the following is always true:
EUA ðinstitutionalizeÞ ≥ EUA ðnot institutionalizeÞ. Therefore if p1 > p^,
then A’s best response is to set g ¼ g at the onset of the game.
Whether A will always be able to make this offer depends on her relative
strength in period 1. Since A cannot commit to future offers, the largest
possible period 1 offer she can make is x1 ¼ 1. We plug in x1 ¼ 1 and
solve for p1 . When p1 ≤ 2σ
1 ^ , then A can always make an offer x1
þ p2m ≡ p
that can induce an acceptance by E.
60
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
1
g ¼ 2p1 pm (31)
σ
As long as A sets g ¼ g , she will be able to make an offer x1 ¼ 1 that will
satisfy E in period 1. However, we show that A will not always be able to
set g at a high enough level if g > maxðgÞ.
Proof of Proposition 2.4.1. We established above that as long as A sets
g ¼ g , she will be able to make an offer, x1 , that E will accept and conflict
will not occur in period 1. However, g is bounded above by 1 ðpm þ μÞ
because it is drawn from the following distribution: g2 ½0; 1 ðpm þ μÞ.
To see why g is bounded above by 1 ðpm þ μÞ, refer to Figure 2.3. g
shifts the entire distribution of p2 upward, and the largest value the upper
bound of p2 can take is 1. Therefore the largest possible value g can take is
the distance between 1 and the upper bound of the original distribution of
p2 , pm þ μ.
A can set g ¼ g only when g ≤ 1 ðpm þ μÞ.
g ≤ 1 ðpm þ μÞ
1
2p1 pm ≤ 1 ðpm þ μÞ (32)
σ
1 1 μ
p1 ≤ þ ≡p
2 2σ 2
A can set g ¼ g only when p1 ≤ p. When p1 > p, even if A were to set g to
the highest possible level, it would not be high enough to prevent conflict
in period 1.
61
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
62
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
63
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2
Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
34
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
35
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
36
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.1 Institutions as Commitment Devices
from office of autocrats resulted from coups, compared with only 11 percent
that resulted from popular uprisings (Svolik 2012). For dictators to survive
they must maintain support from their closest allies. My account therefore
focuses on how leaders maintain support from their own regime elites.
Credibility problems affect autocrats’ abilities to maintain support
from inside of the regime (Cox 2016; Gehlbach and Keefer 2011; Haber
2008; Magaloni 2008; North and Weingast 1989; Stasavage 2003). As
Magaloni notes, dictators need to commit to “not abuse their ‘loyal
friends,’ [but] this commitment is hard to establish” (2). Studies that
focus on intra-elite commitment problems argue that power sharing
between leaders and elites is sustained only when elites have mechanisms
that allow them to check predation from leaders. In order for elites to be
able to effectively hold leaders accountable, they must be able to coordi-
nate a viable threat of rebellion (Boix and Svolik 2013; Myerson 2008).
Yet, a viable threat of rebellion from elites is often far from guaranteed in
an autocratic setting.
Most existing accounts of the commitment problem within the leader’s
inner circle argue that a lack of information hinders elite collective action
(Albertus and Menaldo 2012; Boix and Svolik 2013; Gehlbach and Keefer
2011; Myerson 2008). These studies argue that secrecy within authoritar-
ian governments prevent elites from being able to coordinate and com-
municate with each other. The lack of transparency also hinders elites’
abilities to monitor leader compliance. Furthermore, in regimes where
rules and norms are not clearly established, it is difficult for elites to agree
on what exact actions constitute a transgression. In sum, these studies
argue that information problems form the key barrier for elite collective
action, therefore preventing them from effectively keeping the despot’s
absolute power in check.
37
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
1
In fact, as the model will show, commitment problems that arise due to dynamic
power shifts can occur even with full information.
2
In Acemoglu and Robinson’s model of democratization, elites cannot voluntarily
give up power in order to prevent the masses from rebelling.
38
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.1 Institutions as Commitment Devices
39
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
It is important to note that while this chapter examines why certain types
of executive constraints emerge, I do not seek to explain the creation of
parties or legislatures in dictatorships. In fact, historical evidence often
suggests that many ruling parties are not strategically created, but instead,
inherited by leaders. Within my sample of African countries, for instance,
virtually all leaders came into power with a preexisting party in place
immediately following independence. These ruling parties were created
prior to independence not as elite power-sharing devices, but rather as pro-
independence organizations (Bienen 1970; 1978; Zolberg 1966; 1969) or
parties that were used to participate in preindependence elections (Collier
1982). Similarly, autocratic legislatures do not tend to predate political
parties (Cheibub, Gandhi, and Vreeland 2010). Together, this evidence
suggests that autocratic leaders often do not have total control over the
set of institutions that are available to them when they take power.
Rather than arguing that leaders make strategic decisions to create
institutions, this book argues that leaders make strategic decisions to
institutionalize their regimes after coming into power. Importantly, insti-
tutionalization can occur with or without the presence of formal institu-
tions such as parties or legislatures (though these institutions are very
commonly found). Political parties were banned in Swaziland in 1973,
and this law remains intact today. Despite the absence of parties,
Swaziland has stable prime minister appointments and constitutional
succession rules. Parties were banned in Ethiopia from 1960 through the
early 1980s, but the prime minister and defense minister positions were
filled and remained stable during those years. Equatorial Guinea under the
rule of Teodoro Obiang Nguema Mbasogo did not have a ruling party for
the first six years the leader was in power, but the cabinet had stable vice
president and defense minister appointments. Meanwhile, Niger under
the presidency of Hamani Diori did have a ruling party, the Nigerian
Progressive Party (PPN), but no institutionalized occurred; the regime
did not have formal leadership succession policies and key cabinet
appointments were kept empty.
If the creation of formal organizations such as parties is often histori-
cally determined, do dictators really have control over the content of state
constitutions? Historical accounts of how constitutions were drafted in
the newly independent African states corroborate the claim that leaders –
especially founding presidents – were given extraordinary leeway and
authority to construct their constitutions as they desired. Zolberg’s
account of the constitutional process in the newly independent Ivory
Coast highlights the fact that founding president, Felix Houphouet-
Boigny, had total control over the contents of the document.
40
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.2 A Theoretical Model
When work began on [drafting the constitution], most opposition leaders were
either in exile or had rejoined the [ruling Parti Démocratique de la Côte d’Ivoire
(PDCI) party]. There were no organs of public opinion in which the projects might
be discussed. The constitution of 1959 was therefore framed by a government and
an assembly dominated by a single party, itself controlled by one man. The
decision-making process itself reveals that Houphouet-Boigny and his lieutenants,
accountable only to one another, were unusually free to institutionalize their own
political preferences . . . . The constitution was . . . approved with almost no debate
in the Assembly on March 26, 1959. (Zolberg 1966, 250–251)
Leaders who came after the founding presidents also had control over the
content of state constitutions. Denis Sassou Nguesso, who came to power in
the Republic of Congo in 1979, issued a presidential decree in 1984 that
created a constitutional council. This consultative body (that was, in prac-
tice, accountable only to Sassou Nguesso) determined the constitutionality
of treaties and laws before their adoption by the National People’s
Assembly. At the same time, he then shut down the constitutional chamber
of the Supreme Court (Radu and Sommerville 1989). It is important to note
that even though these leaders may have the opportunity to remove the
constitutional constraints their predecessors implemented, they will not
necessarily do so if it is not in their own best interest.
3
As I argue in Section 2 of the chapter, intra-elite commitment problems arise due to
shifts in power, rather than information problems that prevent elite coordination.
Since this model does not focus on elite collective action problems, I treat the
coalition of elites as a single player (E) in the model.
41
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
In the first period, A offers x1 to E, who can accept the division or reject
it. If E accepts A’s offer in that period, then A and E receive payoffs of
1 x1 and x1 , respectively, and A remains in power. The game continues
onto the second period, and A makes a new offer.
If E rejects A’s offer in the first period, then conflict occurs. Elite
defections are known to be one of the primary drivers of authoritar-
ian breakdown, and the removal of support can be extremely danger-
ous for incumbents (Haggard and Kaufman 1995; Reuter and Gandhi
2011). Research on military coups has shown that they rarely succeed
without substantial civilian support. Militaries often oust govern-
ments during periods of crisis when citizens express discontent with
the civilian leader’s incompetence or mismanagement of the economy
(Geddes 2009).
If conflict occurs, A will be deposed with probability pt . We
assume that p1 > p2 so that power shifts against elites in the second
period. Elites are often strongest at the start of the regime when they
are well organized, before the leader has a chance to consolidate
power (Albertus and Menaldo 2012). Conflict ends strategic decision-
making in the game, and the winner receives all future benefits. If
fighting occurs in period 1, then the winner consumes the pie for both
periods. If fighting occurs in period 2, then the winner consumes the
pie for the final period. However, fighting is costly and destroys
a fraction of the pie. If conflict occurs, then only a fraction σ2 ð0; 1Þ
of the pie remains.
At the start of the game A decides whether to institutionalize her regime
by establishing executive constraints. Since credible executive constraints
provide elites with access to the state, we model it as a shift in the future
distribution of power away from the leader. Executive constraints are
represented by the parameter g2 ½0; 1 p2 . If A selects g > 0, then
the second period distribution of power will be p2 þ g. Any positive
value of g will shift the entire distribution of power away from A in
the second period. A’s offer in period 2 is affected by the institutional
decision she makes at the start of the game.4
This setup reflects the fact that most leaders establish constraints near
the start of their tenure. Leaders frequently draft new constitutions after
4
We assume that A does not value g inherently. She does not consume g; it only affects
the extent to which the distribution of p2 shifts. In other words, A only cares about
the results of g, rather than the inherent level of g. This assumption reflects the idea
that leaders do not have a preference ordering about the strategies they use to rule.
Instead, I assume that they care only about maximizing rents and time in office,
rather than the continuation of the regime after their death.
42
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.2 A Theoretical Model
43
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
reject
reject
1 − p2 1 1
2.3.1 No Institutionalization
When will the leader decide not to institutionalize the regime? In this
section, we show that an autocrat who initially enters power strong will
not face a commitment problem in period 1. She therefore does not need to
establish constraints in order to make an offer that is acceptable to the
elite.
Assume that a commitment problem never exists. If that is the case,
then A can always make an offer xt that can always be accepted in both
periods. In period 1, A makes E indifferent between accepting and reject-
ing an offer by satisfying the following condition:
Whether A will always be able to make this offer depends on her relative
strength in period 1. The largest possible per-period offer A can make is
44
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.3 Solving the Baseline Model
equal to the entire size of the pie, which is normalized to 1.5 Since A cannot
commit to future offers, each per-period offer cannot exceed 1.
Proposition 2.3.1: When p1 ≤ 2σ 1 ^ , then A can always make
þ p22 ≡ p
an offer x1 that can induce an acceptance by E. For all p1 2 ½0; p ^ ,
there exists an xt ≤ 1 such that E½UE ðrejectÞ ≤ E½UE ðacceptÞ.
Proposition 4.1 tells us that if A is strong when she first enters power,
she will not institutionalize. Recall that p1 is the probability that A will be
deposed, therefore when p1 is sufficiently low, A enters power in
a position of strength. Because the probability that E can successfully
depose A is very low, A will be able to make an offer that will match E’s
expected utility of rejecting, and commitment problems will not occur. In
this scenario, A will not institutionalize in equilibrium because she does
not need to in order to sustain peaceful bargaining.
How does the threshold of peaceful bargaining without institutionali-
zation, denoted by p ^ , change relative to the future distribution of power?
Proposition 2.3.2: As A’s period 2 strength decreases, the range for
peaceful bargaining without institutionalization increases.
∂p ^
Formally, ∂p2
> 0.
Put together, Propositions 4.1 and 4.2 produce some interesting counter-
intuitive results. When A enters power strong, she will not institutionalize
because she can make an offer that will satisfy E. In this case, peaceful
bargaining can be sustained without institutionalization, where E has no
guarantees over future rent distribution. However, keeping A’s initial
strength constant, as p2 increases, E’s continuation value also increases.
When E can rely on future de facto power, this puts less pressure on the
period 1 offer. In this case, peaceful bargaining can also be sustained with-
out institutionalization due to a different mechanism. When E becomes
more powerful in period 2, he will not need to fight in period 1 because he is
guaranteed future rent distribution through increasing de facto power.
2.3.2 Institutionalization
Now let’s assume that p1 > p^ . An offer x1 large enough to induce an
acceptance from E cannot be made without some positive level of institu-
tionalization g > 0.
5
If p1 is very small relative to p2 , 2σp1 σp2 can actually be a negative number.
Because offers are restricted to be within ½0; 1 we must restrict x1 to nonnegative
numbers.
45
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
1
g ¼ 2p1 p2 (4)
σ
As long as A sets g ¼ g , she will be able to make an offer x1 ¼ 1 that will
satisfy E in period 1.6 In the appendix we show that A will always be able
to set g ¼ g .7
6
Changing the functional form of g does not alter the results substantively. For
instance, if g was inefficient, say some input ^ g would only shift the distribution by
gÞ < ^
f ð^g Þ such that f ð^ g , A will not be more or less likely to institutionalize. See
Appendix A at the end of this chapter for discussion.
7
Recall that g is bounded above by 1 p2 , therefore A can establish the equilibrium
level of institutionalization only if g ≤ 1 p2 .
46
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.3 Solving the Baseline Model
8
Recall that if a commitment problem occurs in period 1, then A will set x1 ¼ 1 and
consume nothing in the first period.
47
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
g*
g*
No Institution−
No Institution− institutionalization alization
institutionalization alization
^p = 0.86 1 ^p = 0.71 1
P1 P1
Note: σ = .9, p2 = .6 Note: σ = .9, p2 = .3
2.3.3 Discussion
The model makes a number of important predictions, which we summar-
ize in this section. First, the model shows that there are two different types
of autocratic rule, which differ based on the leader’s relative strength
when she first comes into office. Leaders who enter office initially strong
are never incentivized to institutionalize because their initial likelihood of
being deposed is very low. Such leaders prefer not to empower elites by
providing them access to the state because they are always able to make
a per-period transfer that elites will accept. As a result, peaceful bargain-
ing can be sustained in a no-institutionalization equilibrium where
48
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.3 Solving the Baseline Model
initially strong autocrats remain in power but do not provide elites with
access to the state.
On the other hand, leaders who enter office initially weak are incenti-
vized to institutionalize because they cannot sustain peaceful bargaining
without shifting the future distribution of power in favor of elites.
Empowering elites in the second period relaxes demands on the first
period transfer by raising the elite continuation value, which allows
initially weak autocrats to made credible future promises to elites.
Although doing so weakens the leader in the future, she is willing to
institutionalize in order to remain in power for both periods of the
game. In this case, peaceful bargaining can also be sustained in an insti-
tutionalization equilibrium where initially weak autocrats remain in
power only by providing elites with access to the state.
These two different types of autocratic rule have one very important
feature in common: both initially strong leaders and initially weak leaders
who institutionalize remain in power for both periods of the game. In
other words, conditional on the weak type institutionalizing, the leader
will be able to remain in power for the same length of time as the initially
strong type.
This feature highlights an important empirical point, which we will
return to in Chapter 6: scholars should not assume that regimes that are
long-lived have strong institutions. Leader tenure does not serve as
a useful proxy for the quality of institutions due to the strategic nature
of institutionalization. Initially weak leaders are incentivized to institu-
tionalize in order to remain in power because they would otherwise face
commitment problems in bargaining and risk being deposed by elites.
When weak leaders institutionalize, they can indeed remain in power for
longer periods of time.
Initially strong leaders, on the other hand, can remain in power regard-
less of whether they have strong institutions or not, because they do not
face commitment problems in bargaining. In fact, as the model shows,
leaders who enter power strong do not institutionalize yet are able to
remain in power for both periods of the game. We should therefore expect
to see a systematic relationship between leader tenure and institutional
strength only when we condition on initial leader strength. This may help
to explain why existing empirical studies, which do not condition on
leader strength have found inconsistent relationships between the pre-
sence of strong institutions and leader tenure (for instance, see Gandhi
2008; Lucardi 2017; Smith 2005).
These results provide some interesting contrasts with findings from
existing models. In the Acemoglu and Robinson (2006) model, a main
finding is that democratization is most likely to occur if the poor pose
49
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
9
Note that in the Acemoglu and Robinson model, elites are the analogous player as
the autocrat (A) in my model, and the poor are the analogous player as the elite (E)
in my model.
10
Unlike in the Acemoglu and Robinson model, where the probability that elites will
be unseated jumps discontinuously from 0 to 1 if the poor initiate a revolution, pt is
a continuous parameter in my model.
50
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.4 Model Extension: Imperfect Information
µ µ
pm − µ pm pm + µ
0 1
µ µ
pm − µ + g pm + g pm + µ + g
0 1
11
We assume that μ is sufficiently small, such that pm μ > 0 and pm μ < 1.
51
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
reject
1 − (pm + µ) 1 pm + µ + g 1
0 0 pm − µ + g 0
Figure 2.4 Game tree: model extension
52
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.4 Model Extension: Imperfect Information
As a result, fighting can occur in period 1. The full proofs for the modified
game are presented in Appendix B at the end of the chapter.
Similar to the baseline model, when p1 is sufficiently low, A will not
institutionalize because she is always able to make an offer x1 that E will
accept. However, when A enters power weak, a commitment problem will
arise in period 1 if g ¼ 0. We can establish that there exists some g > 0
that would allow A to make an offer x1 ¼ 1 that can satisfy E in period 1.
For this game, g ¼ 2p1 pm 1σ .
Will A always be able to set x1 ¼ 1? In the modified version of the
game, g is bounded above by 1 ðpm þ μÞ. Therefore g is feasible only if
g ≤ 1 ðpm þ μÞ.
Proposition 2.4.1: As long as p1 is sufficiently small, A will be able
to set g ¼ g in order to allow a peaceful bargain to go through in
period 1. Formally, as long as p1 ≤ 12 þ 2σ1
μ2 ≡ p, there exists a
g ¼ g such that E½UE ðrejectÞ ≤ E½UE ðacceptÞ.
A key implication of Proposition 2.4.1 is that conflict will occur in
equilibrium if p1 is not sufficiently small. When p1 > p, even if
A were to set g to the highest possible level, she still cannot prevent
conflict from occurring in period 1 because the level of institutiona-
lization (g ) necessary to allow all bargains to go through peacefully
is larger than the maximum possible value of g. We establish in
the appendix that A still always prefers to institutionalize when
faced with a commitment problem, however, now she cannot always
do so.
Proposition 2.4.2: The equilibrium of the modified game can be
characterized as following:
^ , A will set g ¼ 0. In period 1,
1. No Institutionalization: If p1 ≤ p
A will offer x1 ¼ x1 , and in period 2, A will offer x2 ¼ σp2 .
In each round, E will accept each offer if
EUE ðacceptÞ ≥ EUE ðrejectÞ and reject otherwise.
^ and p1 ≤ p, A will set g ¼ g . In
2. Institutionalization: If p1 > p
period 1, A will offer x1 ¼ maxf0; x1 g, and in period 2, A will
53
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
2 . 5 co n c l u s i o n
This chapter sought to understand why we see differences in the organiza-
tional capacity of authoritarian regimes by examining the creation of
constraints limiting executive power. Constraints bind only when they
provide elites with access to important government positions, empowering
them to hold the incumbent accountable to promises about rent distribu-
tion. Through a formal model I demonstrated that strong autocrats who
enter power with a low probability of being deposed are less likely to
institutionalize. Initially weak autocrats without such guarantees of stabi-
lity are more likely to pursue institutionalization in order to maintain
support from elites. Importantly, rather than assuming that institutions
constrain leaders, I show how institutions can provide credible commit-
ment power by shifting the future distribution of power in favor of elites.
The next chapter of the book illustrates the primary findings of the model
through two illustrative case studies of Cameroon and Côte d’Ivoire.
54
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
^ also
Proof of Proposition 2.3.2. It is easy to see that as p2 increases, p
increases:
^
∂p 1
¼ >0 (6)
∂p2 2
Proof of Lemma 2.3.1. A must choose values of x1 and g such that the
following equation is satisfied:
2σp1 ≤ x1 þ VE (7)
2σp1 ≤ x1 þ σEVðp2 Þ
2σp1 ≤ x1 þ σðp2 þ gÞ (8)
2σp1 σp2 ≤ x1 þ σg
2σp1 ≤ 1 þ VE (9)
To determine the continuation value, note that if the game moves peace-
fully onto the second period, there will never be fighting. Even if p2 ¼ 1
and σ ¼ 1, A can always offer x2 ¼ 1. Therefore we know that VE is
simply equal to E’s expected utility of rejecting in period 2, since A will
always try to make the cheapest possible offer to E.
VE ¼ EUE ðrejectÞ
¼ σEVðp2 Þ (10)
¼ σðp2 þ gÞ
We now plug E’s continuation value into the equation and solve for g.
55
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
2σp1 1 ≤ VE
2σp1 1 ≤ σðp2 þ gÞ (11)
1
g ¼ 2p1 p2
σ
We can establish that changing the functional form of g does not alter the
results substantively. Instead of assuming that wðgÞ ¼ g, let’s assume that
institutions are extremely efficient, such that hðe gÞ > e g (in other words,
hð Þ is concave). How would e g compare with g ? We know that
g ¼ 2p1 p2 1σ ¼ hðe gÞ > e
g : Therefore, g > e g . Unsurprisingly,
when institutions are efficient, lower levels of institutionalization are
required to sustain peaceful bargaining.
Interestingly, however, this does not change the threshold, p ^ of insti-
tutionalization, nor does it make A more or less willing to institutionalize,
compared with when wðgÞ ¼ g. First, note that g does not affect the
calculation of the threshold, p ^ . Second, recall that A does not value g
inherently. She does not consume g, it only affects the extent to which the
distribution of p2 shifts. In other words, A only cares about the results of g,
rather than the inherent level of g. Therefore, even if g was inefficient, say
gÞ < ^
if f ð^ g , A will still always be willing to institutionalize.
Proof. We show that A will always be able to set g ¼ g . Recall that g is
bounded above by 1 p2 , therefore A can establish the equilibrium level
of constraints if g ≤ 1 p2 .
g ≤ 1 p2
1
2p1 p2 ≤ 1 p2 (12)
σ
1 1
p1 ≤ þ
2 2σ
Since σ2 ½0; 1, equation (12) is always true.
Proof of Proposition 2.3.3. It is easy to see that as p1 increases, g also
increases:
∂g
¼2>0 (13)
∂p1
56
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
∂g 1
¼ 2>0 (15)
∂σ σ
Proof of Proposition 2.3.6. This proof follows directly from the construc-
tion of g , which is the minimal level of g that guarantees that the follow-
ing condition is true: EUE ðrejectÞ ≤ EUE ðacceptÞ. If g ≥ g , then E will
always accept in period 1. If the game makes it to period 2, then conflict
will never occur because p2 < 1 by assumption, therefore A will always be
able to make an offer x2 that can induce an acceptance by E.
Proof of Proposition 2.3.7. A’s second period consumption is simply
1 x2 , since she can always make an offer x2 that can induce an accep-
tance by E. It is easy to see that 1 x2 is decreasing in g:
∂ð1 x2 Þ
¼ σ < 0 (16)
∂g
A gets to pocket the portion of the pie that she doesn’t offer to E, therefore
her continuation value is the size of the pie minus the expected value of the
period 2 offer, x2 .
VA ¼ 1 EVðx2 Þ (20)
57
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
VA ¼ 1 EVðx2 Þ
(23)
¼ 2 2σp1
EUA ðg ¼ g Þ ≥ EUA ðg ¼ 0Þ
2 2σp1 ≥ 2σð1 p1 Þ (24)
1≥σ
58
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
σðp2 þ g Þ
EVðx2 Þ ¼
1
¼ σp2 þ σ 2p1 p2 (26)
σ
¼ 2σp1 1
59
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
expected utility for A than fighting in period 1. A’s strict best response,
given that g ¼ g is to offer x1 ¼ 1 in period 1. E’s best response is to
accept x1 ¼ 1 because by construction, g ensures that E’s expected utility
of accepting x1 ¼ 1 is greater than or equal to his expected utility of
fighting in period 1.
We now move to the very start of the game, where A decides what to set
g. We have already established that the following is always true:
EUA ðinstitutionalizeÞ ≥ EUA ðnot institutionalizeÞ. Therefore if p1 > p^,
then A’s best response is to set g ¼ g at the onset of the game.
Whether A will always be able to make this offer depends on her relative
strength in period 1. Since A cannot commit to future offers, the largest
possible period 1 offer she can make is x1 ¼ 1. We plug in x1 ¼ 1 and
solve for p1 . When p1 ≤ 2σ
1 ^ , then A can always make an offer x1
þ p2m ≡ p
that can induce an acceptance by E.
60
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
1
g ¼ 2p1 pm (31)
σ
As long as A sets g ¼ g , she will be able to make an offer x1 ¼ 1 that will
satisfy E in period 1. However, we show that A will not always be able to
set g at a high enough level if g > maxðgÞ.
Proof of Proposition 2.4.1. We established above that as long as A sets
g ¼ g , she will be able to make an offer, x1 , that E will accept and conflict
will not occur in period 1. However, g is bounded above by 1 ðpm þ μÞ
because it is drawn from the following distribution: g2 ½0; 1 ðpm þ μÞ.
To see why g is bounded above by 1 ðpm þ μÞ, refer to Figure 2.3. g
shifts the entire distribution of p2 upward, and the largest value the upper
bound of p2 can take is 1. Therefore the largest possible value g can take is
the distance between 1 and the upper bound of the original distribution of
p2 , pm þ μ.
A can set g ¼ g only when g ≤ 1 ðpm þ μÞ.
g ≤ 1 ðpm þ μÞ
1
2p1 pm ≤ 1 ðpm þ μÞ (32)
σ
1 1 μ
p1 ≤ þ ≡p
2 2σ 2
A can set g ¼ g only when p1 ≤ p. When p1 > p, even if A were to set g to
the highest possible level, it would not be high enough to prevent conflict
in period 1.
61
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
62
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
63
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2
Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
34
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
35
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
36
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.1 Institutions as Commitment Devices
from office of autocrats resulted from coups, compared with only 11 percent
that resulted from popular uprisings (Svolik 2012). For dictators to survive
they must maintain support from their closest allies. My account therefore
focuses on how leaders maintain support from their own regime elites.
Credibility problems affect autocrats’ abilities to maintain support
from inside of the regime (Cox 2016; Gehlbach and Keefer 2011; Haber
2008; Magaloni 2008; North and Weingast 1989; Stasavage 2003). As
Magaloni notes, dictators need to commit to “not abuse their ‘loyal
friends,’ [but] this commitment is hard to establish” (2). Studies that
focus on intra-elite commitment problems argue that power sharing
between leaders and elites is sustained only when elites have mechanisms
that allow them to check predation from leaders. In order for elites to be
able to effectively hold leaders accountable, they must be able to coordi-
nate a viable threat of rebellion (Boix and Svolik 2013; Myerson 2008).
Yet, a viable threat of rebellion from elites is often far from guaranteed in
an autocratic setting.
Most existing accounts of the commitment problem within the leader’s
inner circle argue that a lack of information hinders elite collective action
(Albertus and Menaldo 2012; Boix and Svolik 2013; Gehlbach and Keefer
2011; Myerson 2008). These studies argue that secrecy within authoritar-
ian governments prevent elites from being able to coordinate and com-
municate with each other. The lack of transparency also hinders elites’
abilities to monitor leader compliance. Furthermore, in regimes where
rules and norms are not clearly established, it is difficult for elites to agree
on what exact actions constitute a transgression. In sum, these studies
argue that information problems form the key barrier for elite collective
action, therefore preventing them from effectively keeping the despot’s
absolute power in check.
37
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
1
In fact, as the model will show, commitment problems that arise due to dynamic
power shifts can occur even with full information.
2
In Acemoglu and Robinson’s model of democratization, elites cannot voluntarily
give up power in order to prevent the masses from rebelling.
38
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.1 Institutions as Commitment Devices
39
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
It is important to note that while this chapter examines why certain types
of executive constraints emerge, I do not seek to explain the creation of
parties or legislatures in dictatorships. In fact, historical evidence often
suggests that many ruling parties are not strategically created, but instead,
inherited by leaders. Within my sample of African countries, for instance,
virtually all leaders came into power with a preexisting party in place
immediately following independence. These ruling parties were created
prior to independence not as elite power-sharing devices, but rather as pro-
independence organizations (Bienen 1970; 1978; Zolberg 1966; 1969) or
parties that were used to participate in preindependence elections (Collier
1982). Similarly, autocratic legislatures do not tend to predate political
parties (Cheibub, Gandhi, and Vreeland 2010). Together, this evidence
suggests that autocratic leaders often do not have total control over the
set of institutions that are available to them when they take power.
Rather than arguing that leaders make strategic decisions to create
institutions, this book argues that leaders make strategic decisions to
institutionalize their regimes after coming into power. Importantly, insti-
tutionalization can occur with or without the presence of formal institu-
tions such as parties or legislatures (though these institutions are very
commonly found). Political parties were banned in Swaziland in 1973,
and this law remains intact today. Despite the absence of parties,
Swaziland has stable prime minister appointments and constitutional
succession rules. Parties were banned in Ethiopia from 1960 through the
early 1980s, but the prime minister and defense minister positions were
filled and remained stable during those years. Equatorial Guinea under the
rule of Teodoro Obiang Nguema Mbasogo did not have a ruling party for
the first six years the leader was in power, but the cabinet had stable vice
president and defense minister appointments. Meanwhile, Niger under
the presidency of Hamani Diori did have a ruling party, the Nigerian
Progressive Party (PPN), but no institutionalized occurred; the regime
did not have formal leadership succession policies and key cabinet
appointments were kept empty.
If the creation of formal organizations such as parties is often histori-
cally determined, do dictators really have control over the content of state
constitutions? Historical accounts of how constitutions were drafted in
the newly independent African states corroborate the claim that leaders –
especially founding presidents – were given extraordinary leeway and
authority to construct their constitutions as they desired. Zolberg’s
account of the constitutional process in the newly independent Ivory
Coast highlights the fact that founding president, Felix Houphouet-
Boigny, had total control over the contents of the document.
40
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.2 A Theoretical Model
When work began on [drafting the constitution], most opposition leaders were
either in exile or had rejoined the [ruling Parti Démocratique de la Côte d’Ivoire
(PDCI) party]. There were no organs of public opinion in which the projects might
be discussed. The constitution of 1959 was therefore framed by a government and
an assembly dominated by a single party, itself controlled by one man. The
decision-making process itself reveals that Houphouet-Boigny and his lieutenants,
accountable only to one another, were unusually free to institutionalize their own
political preferences . . . . The constitution was . . . approved with almost no debate
in the Assembly on March 26, 1959. (Zolberg 1966, 250–251)
Leaders who came after the founding presidents also had control over the
content of state constitutions. Denis Sassou Nguesso, who came to power in
the Republic of Congo in 1979, issued a presidential decree in 1984 that
created a constitutional council. This consultative body (that was, in prac-
tice, accountable only to Sassou Nguesso) determined the constitutionality
of treaties and laws before their adoption by the National People’s
Assembly. At the same time, he then shut down the constitutional chamber
of the Supreme Court (Radu and Sommerville 1989). It is important to note
that even though these leaders may have the opportunity to remove the
constitutional constraints their predecessors implemented, they will not
necessarily do so if it is not in their own best interest.
3
As I argue in Section 2 of the chapter, intra-elite commitment problems arise due to
shifts in power, rather than information problems that prevent elite coordination.
Since this model does not focus on elite collective action problems, I treat the
coalition of elites as a single player (E) in the model.
41
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
In the first period, A offers x1 to E, who can accept the division or reject
it. If E accepts A’s offer in that period, then A and E receive payoffs of
1 x1 and x1 , respectively, and A remains in power. The game continues
onto the second period, and A makes a new offer.
If E rejects A’s offer in the first period, then conflict occurs. Elite
defections are known to be one of the primary drivers of authoritar-
ian breakdown, and the removal of support can be extremely danger-
ous for incumbents (Haggard and Kaufman 1995; Reuter and Gandhi
2011). Research on military coups has shown that they rarely succeed
without substantial civilian support. Militaries often oust govern-
ments during periods of crisis when citizens express discontent with
the civilian leader’s incompetence or mismanagement of the economy
(Geddes 2009).
If conflict occurs, A will be deposed with probability pt . We
assume that p1 > p2 so that power shifts against elites in the second
period. Elites are often strongest at the start of the regime when they
are well organized, before the leader has a chance to consolidate
power (Albertus and Menaldo 2012). Conflict ends strategic decision-
making in the game, and the winner receives all future benefits. If
fighting occurs in period 1, then the winner consumes the pie for both
periods. If fighting occurs in period 2, then the winner consumes the
pie for the final period. However, fighting is costly and destroys
a fraction of the pie. If conflict occurs, then only a fraction σ2 ð0; 1Þ
of the pie remains.
At the start of the game A decides whether to institutionalize her regime
by establishing executive constraints. Since credible executive constraints
provide elites with access to the state, we model it as a shift in the future
distribution of power away from the leader. Executive constraints are
represented by the parameter g2 ½0; 1 p2 . If A selects g > 0, then
the second period distribution of power will be p2 þ g. Any positive
value of g will shift the entire distribution of power away from A in
the second period. A’s offer in period 2 is affected by the institutional
decision she makes at the start of the game.4
This setup reflects the fact that most leaders establish constraints near
the start of their tenure. Leaders frequently draft new constitutions after
4
We assume that A does not value g inherently. She does not consume g; it only affects
the extent to which the distribution of p2 shifts. In other words, A only cares about
the results of g, rather than the inherent level of g. This assumption reflects the idea
that leaders do not have a preference ordering about the strategies they use to rule.
Instead, I assume that they care only about maximizing rents and time in office,
rather than the continuation of the regime after their death.
42
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.2 A Theoretical Model
43
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
reject
reject
1 − p2 1 1
2.3.1 No Institutionalization
When will the leader decide not to institutionalize the regime? In this
section, we show that an autocrat who initially enters power strong will
not face a commitment problem in period 1. She therefore does not need to
establish constraints in order to make an offer that is acceptable to the
elite.
Assume that a commitment problem never exists. If that is the case,
then A can always make an offer xt that can always be accepted in both
periods. In period 1, A makes E indifferent between accepting and reject-
ing an offer by satisfying the following condition:
Whether A will always be able to make this offer depends on her relative
strength in period 1. The largest possible per-period offer A can make is
44
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.3 Solving the Baseline Model
equal to the entire size of the pie, which is normalized to 1.5 Since A cannot
commit to future offers, each per-period offer cannot exceed 1.
Proposition 2.3.1: When p1 ≤ 2σ 1 ^ , then A can always make
þ p22 ≡ p
an offer x1 that can induce an acceptance by E. For all p1 2 ½0; p ^ ,
there exists an xt ≤ 1 such that E½UE ðrejectÞ ≤ E½UE ðacceptÞ.
Proposition 4.1 tells us that if A is strong when she first enters power,
she will not institutionalize. Recall that p1 is the probability that A will be
deposed, therefore when p1 is sufficiently low, A enters power in
a position of strength. Because the probability that E can successfully
depose A is very low, A will be able to make an offer that will match E’s
expected utility of rejecting, and commitment problems will not occur. In
this scenario, A will not institutionalize in equilibrium because she does
not need to in order to sustain peaceful bargaining.
How does the threshold of peaceful bargaining without institutionali-
zation, denoted by p ^ , change relative to the future distribution of power?
Proposition 2.3.2: As A’s period 2 strength decreases, the range for
peaceful bargaining without institutionalization increases.
∂p ^
Formally, ∂p2
> 0.
Put together, Propositions 4.1 and 4.2 produce some interesting counter-
intuitive results. When A enters power strong, she will not institutionalize
because she can make an offer that will satisfy E. In this case, peaceful
bargaining can be sustained without institutionalization, where E has no
guarantees over future rent distribution. However, keeping A’s initial
strength constant, as p2 increases, E’s continuation value also increases.
When E can rely on future de facto power, this puts less pressure on the
period 1 offer. In this case, peaceful bargaining can also be sustained with-
out institutionalization due to a different mechanism. When E becomes
more powerful in period 2, he will not need to fight in period 1 because he is
guaranteed future rent distribution through increasing de facto power.
2.3.2 Institutionalization
Now let’s assume that p1 > p^ . An offer x1 large enough to induce an
acceptance from E cannot be made without some positive level of institu-
tionalization g > 0.
5
If p1 is very small relative to p2 , 2σp1 σp2 can actually be a negative number.
Because offers are restricted to be within ½0; 1 we must restrict x1 to nonnegative
numbers.
45
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
1
g ¼ 2p1 p2 (4)
σ
As long as A sets g ¼ g , she will be able to make an offer x1 ¼ 1 that will
satisfy E in period 1.6 In the appendix we show that A will always be able
to set g ¼ g .7
6
Changing the functional form of g does not alter the results substantively. For
instance, if g was inefficient, say some input ^ g would only shift the distribution by
gÞ < ^
f ð^g Þ such that f ð^ g , A will not be more or less likely to institutionalize. See
Appendix A at the end of this chapter for discussion.
7
Recall that g is bounded above by 1 p2 , therefore A can establish the equilibrium
level of institutionalization only if g ≤ 1 p2 .
46
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.3 Solving the Baseline Model
8
Recall that if a commitment problem occurs in period 1, then A will set x1 ¼ 1 and
consume nothing in the first period.
47
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
g*
g*
No Institution−
No Institution− institutionalization alization
institutionalization alization
^p = 0.86 1 ^p = 0.71 1
P1 P1
Note: σ = .9, p2 = .6 Note: σ = .9, p2 = .3
2.3.3 Discussion
The model makes a number of important predictions, which we summar-
ize in this section. First, the model shows that there are two different types
of autocratic rule, which differ based on the leader’s relative strength
when she first comes into office. Leaders who enter office initially strong
are never incentivized to institutionalize because their initial likelihood of
being deposed is very low. Such leaders prefer not to empower elites by
providing them access to the state because they are always able to make
a per-period transfer that elites will accept. As a result, peaceful bargain-
ing can be sustained in a no-institutionalization equilibrium where
48
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.3 Solving the Baseline Model
initially strong autocrats remain in power but do not provide elites with
access to the state.
On the other hand, leaders who enter office initially weak are incenti-
vized to institutionalize because they cannot sustain peaceful bargaining
without shifting the future distribution of power in favor of elites.
Empowering elites in the second period relaxes demands on the first
period transfer by raising the elite continuation value, which allows
initially weak autocrats to made credible future promises to elites.
Although doing so weakens the leader in the future, she is willing to
institutionalize in order to remain in power for both periods of the
game. In this case, peaceful bargaining can also be sustained in an insti-
tutionalization equilibrium where initially weak autocrats remain in
power only by providing elites with access to the state.
These two different types of autocratic rule have one very important
feature in common: both initially strong leaders and initially weak leaders
who institutionalize remain in power for both periods of the game. In
other words, conditional on the weak type institutionalizing, the leader
will be able to remain in power for the same length of time as the initially
strong type.
This feature highlights an important empirical point, which we will
return to in Chapter 6: scholars should not assume that regimes that are
long-lived have strong institutions. Leader tenure does not serve as
a useful proxy for the quality of institutions due to the strategic nature
of institutionalization. Initially weak leaders are incentivized to institu-
tionalize in order to remain in power because they would otherwise face
commitment problems in bargaining and risk being deposed by elites.
When weak leaders institutionalize, they can indeed remain in power for
longer periods of time.
Initially strong leaders, on the other hand, can remain in power regard-
less of whether they have strong institutions or not, because they do not
face commitment problems in bargaining. In fact, as the model shows,
leaders who enter power strong do not institutionalize yet are able to
remain in power for both periods of the game. We should therefore expect
to see a systematic relationship between leader tenure and institutional
strength only when we condition on initial leader strength. This may help
to explain why existing empirical studies, which do not condition on
leader strength have found inconsistent relationships between the pre-
sence of strong institutions and leader tenure (for instance, see Gandhi
2008; Lucardi 2017; Smith 2005).
These results provide some interesting contrasts with findings from
existing models. In the Acemoglu and Robinson (2006) model, a main
finding is that democratization is most likely to occur if the poor pose
49
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
9
Note that in the Acemoglu and Robinson model, elites are the analogous player as
the autocrat (A) in my model, and the poor are the analogous player as the elite (E)
in my model.
10
Unlike in the Acemoglu and Robinson model, where the probability that elites will
be unseated jumps discontinuously from 0 to 1 if the poor initiate a revolution, pt is
a continuous parameter in my model.
50
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.4 Model Extension: Imperfect Information
µ µ
pm − µ pm pm + µ
0 1
µ µ
pm − µ + g pm + g pm + µ + g
0 1
11
We assume that μ is sufficiently small, such that pm μ > 0 and pm μ < 1.
51
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
reject
1 − (pm + µ) 1 pm + µ + g 1
0 0 pm − µ + g 0
Figure 2.4 Game tree: model extension
52
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.4 Model Extension: Imperfect Information
As a result, fighting can occur in period 1. The full proofs for the modified
game are presented in Appendix B at the end of the chapter.
Similar to the baseline model, when p1 is sufficiently low, A will not
institutionalize because she is always able to make an offer x1 that E will
accept. However, when A enters power weak, a commitment problem will
arise in period 1 if g ¼ 0. We can establish that there exists some g > 0
that would allow A to make an offer x1 ¼ 1 that can satisfy E in period 1.
For this game, g ¼ 2p1 pm 1σ .
Will A always be able to set x1 ¼ 1? In the modified version of the
game, g is bounded above by 1 ðpm þ μÞ. Therefore g is feasible only if
g ≤ 1 ðpm þ μÞ.
Proposition 2.4.1: As long as p1 is sufficiently small, A will be able
to set g ¼ g in order to allow a peaceful bargain to go through in
period 1. Formally, as long as p1 ≤ 12 þ 2σ1
μ2 ≡ p, there exists a
g ¼ g such that E½UE ðrejectÞ ≤ E½UE ðacceptÞ.
A key implication of Proposition 2.4.1 is that conflict will occur in
equilibrium if p1 is not sufficiently small. When p1 > p, even if
A were to set g to the highest possible level, she still cannot prevent
conflict from occurring in period 1 because the level of institutiona-
lization (g ) necessary to allow all bargains to go through peacefully
is larger than the maximum possible value of g. We establish in
the appendix that A still always prefers to institutionalize when
faced with a commitment problem, however, now she cannot always
do so.
Proposition 2.4.2: The equilibrium of the modified game can be
characterized as following:
^ , A will set g ¼ 0. In period 1,
1. No Institutionalization: If p1 ≤ p
A will offer x1 ¼ x1 , and in period 2, A will offer x2 ¼ σp2 .
In each round, E will accept each offer if
EUE ðacceptÞ ≥ EUE ðrejectÞ and reject otherwise.
^ and p1 ≤ p, A will set g ¼ g . In
2. Institutionalization: If p1 > p
period 1, A will offer x1 ¼ maxf0; x1 g, and in period 2, A will
53
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
2 . 5 co n c l u s i o n
This chapter sought to understand why we see differences in the organiza-
tional capacity of authoritarian regimes by examining the creation of
constraints limiting executive power. Constraints bind only when they
provide elites with access to important government positions, empowering
them to hold the incumbent accountable to promises about rent distribu-
tion. Through a formal model I demonstrated that strong autocrats who
enter power with a low probability of being deposed are less likely to
institutionalize. Initially weak autocrats without such guarantees of stabi-
lity are more likely to pursue institutionalization in order to maintain
support from elites. Importantly, rather than assuming that institutions
constrain leaders, I show how institutions can provide credible commit-
ment power by shifting the future distribution of power in favor of elites.
The next chapter of the book illustrates the primary findings of the model
through two illustrative case studies of Cameroon and Côte d’Ivoire.
54
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
^ also
Proof of Proposition 2.3.2. It is easy to see that as p2 increases, p
increases:
^
∂p 1
¼ >0 (6)
∂p2 2
Proof of Lemma 2.3.1. A must choose values of x1 and g such that the
following equation is satisfied:
2σp1 ≤ x1 þ VE (7)
2σp1 ≤ x1 þ σEVðp2 Þ
2σp1 ≤ x1 þ σðp2 þ gÞ (8)
2σp1 σp2 ≤ x1 þ σg
2σp1 ≤ 1 þ VE (9)
To determine the continuation value, note that if the game moves peace-
fully onto the second period, there will never be fighting. Even if p2 ¼ 1
and σ ¼ 1, A can always offer x2 ¼ 1. Therefore we know that VE is
simply equal to E’s expected utility of rejecting in period 2, since A will
always try to make the cheapest possible offer to E.
VE ¼ EUE ðrejectÞ
¼ σEVðp2 Þ (10)
¼ σðp2 þ gÞ
We now plug E’s continuation value into the equation and solve for g.
55
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
2σp1 1 ≤ VE
2σp1 1 ≤ σðp2 þ gÞ (11)
1
g ¼ 2p1 p2
σ
We can establish that changing the functional form of g does not alter the
results substantively. Instead of assuming that wðgÞ ¼ g, let’s assume that
institutions are extremely efficient, such that hðe gÞ > e g (in other words,
hð Þ is concave). How would e g compare with g ? We know that
g ¼ 2p1 p2 1σ ¼ hðe gÞ > e
g : Therefore, g > e g . Unsurprisingly,
when institutions are efficient, lower levels of institutionalization are
required to sustain peaceful bargaining.
Interestingly, however, this does not change the threshold, p ^ of insti-
tutionalization, nor does it make A more or less willing to institutionalize,
compared with when wðgÞ ¼ g. First, note that g does not affect the
calculation of the threshold, p ^ . Second, recall that A does not value g
inherently. She does not consume g, it only affects the extent to which the
distribution of p2 shifts. In other words, A only cares about the results of g,
rather than the inherent level of g. Therefore, even if g was inefficient, say
gÞ < ^
if f ð^ g , A will still always be willing to institutionalize.
Proof. We show that A will always be able to set g ¼ g . Recall that g is
bounded above by 1 p2 , therefore A can establish the equilibrium level
of constraints if g ≤ 1 p2 .
g ≤ 1 p2
1
2p1 p2 ≤ 1 p2 (12)
σ
1 1
p1 ≤ þ
2 2σ
Since σ2 ½0; 1, equation (12) is always true.
Proof of Proposition 2.3.3. It is easy to see that as p1 increases, g also
increases:
∂g
¼2>0 (13)
∂p1
56
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
∂g 1
¼ 2>0 (15)
∂σ σ
Proof of Proposition 2.3.6. This proof follows directly from the construc-
tion of g , which is the minimal level of g that guarantees that the follow-
ing condition is true: EUE ðrejectÞ ≤ EUE ðacceptÞ. If g ≥ g , then E will
always accept in period 1. If the game makes it to period 2, then conflict
will never occur because p2 < 1 by assumption, therefore A will always be
able to make an offer x2 that can induce an acceptance by E.
Proof of Proposition 2.3.7. A’s second period consumption is simply
1 x2 , since she can always make an offer x2 that can induce an accep-
tance by E. It is easy to see that 1 x2 is decreasing in g:
∂ð1 x2 Þ
¼ σ < 0 (16)
∂g
A gets to pocket the portion of the pie that she doesn’t offer to E, therefore
her continuation value is the size of the pie minus the expected value of the
period 2 offer, x2 .
VA ¼ 1 EVðx2 Þ (20)
57
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
VA ¼ 1 EVðx2 Þ
(23)
¼ 2 2σp1
EUA ðg ¼ g Þ ≥ EUA ðg ¼ 0Þ
2 2σp1 ≥ 2σð1 p1 Þ (24)
1≥σ
58
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
σðp2 þ g Þ
EVðx2 Þ ¼
1
¼ σp2 þ σ 2p1 p2 (26)
σ
¼ 2σp1 1
59
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
expected utility for A than fighting in period 1. A’s strict best response,
given that g ¼ g is to offer x1 ¼ 1 in period 1. E’s best response is to
accept x1 ¼ 1 because by construction, g ensures that E’s expected utility
of accepting x1 ¼ 1 is greater than or equal to his expected utility of
fighting in period 1.
We now move to the very start of the game, where A decides what to set
g. We have already established that the following is always true:
EUA ðinstitutionalizeÞ ≥ EUA ðnot institutionalizeÞ. Therefore if p1 > p^,
then A’s best response is to set g ¼ g at the onset of the game.
Whether A will always be able to make this offer depends on her relative
strength in period 1. Since A cannot commit to future offers, the largest
possible period 1 offer she can make is x1 ¼ 1. We plug in x1 ¼ 1 and
solve for p1 . When p1 ≤ 2σ
1 ^ , then A can always make an offer x1
þ p2m ≡ p
that can induce an acceptance by E.
60
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
1
g ¼ 2p1 pm (31)
σ
As long as A sets g ¼ g , she will be able to make an offer x1 ¼ 1 that will
satisfy E in period 1. However, we show that A will not always be able to
set g at a high enough level if g > maxðgÞ.
Proof of Proposition 2.4.1. We established above that as long as A sets
g ¼ g , she will be able to make an offer, x1 , that E will accept and conflict
will not occur in period 1. However, g is bounded above by 1 ðpm þ μÞ
because it is drawn from the following distribution: g2 ½0; 1 ðpm þ μÞ.
To see why g is bounded above by 1 ðpm þ μÞ, refer to Figure 2.3. g
shifts the entire distribution of p2 upward, and the largest value the upper
bound of p2 can take is 1. Therefore the largest possible value g can take is
the distance between 1 and the upper bound of the original distribution of
p2 , pm þ μ.
A can set g ¼ g only when g ≤ 1 ðpm þ μÞ.
g ≤ 1 ðpm þ μÞ
1
2p1 pm ≤ 1 ðpm þ μÞ (32)
σ
1 1 μ
p1 ≤ þ ≡p
2 2σ 2
A can set g ¼ g only when p1 ≤ p. When p1 > p, even if A were to set g to
the highest possible level, it would not be high enough to prevent conflict
in period 1.
61
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2 Why Do Leaders Institutionalize?
62
Published online by Cambridge University Press
2.5 Conclusion
63
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3
Two Illustrative Cases
1
As will be discussed later in this chapter, a small sliver of Cameroon was controlled
by the British, but the country was mostly under French colonial rule. British rule in
Cameroon was very limited, as the French took the vast majority of the land (four-
fifths of the total area of Cameroon) – including the capital city of Yaounde.
Francophile elites and politicians have always dominated the executive in Cameroon.
64
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
2000
1500
GDP per capita
1000
500
0
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020
Year
Côte d’Ivoire Cameroon
Figure 3.1 Yearly gross domestic product (GDP) of Cameroon and Côte d’Ivoire
65
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
66
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.1 The Formal Model Summarized
67
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
2
Though in recent years an anglophone separatist movement has emerged in
Cameroon. The country has also experienced insurgent violence from Boko
Haram. Cameroon experienced an unsuccessful coup attempt in 1984, as this chap-
ter will later discuss.
68
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.2 Cameroon Under Ahidjo
3
For a short period during Ahidjo’s rule, from 1973 to 1974, the office of the vice
president was eliminated from the cabinet. In 1975 the title of the office of vice
president was changed to prime minister and was added back to the cabinet. From
1975 through until the end of Ahidjo’s rule, Paul Biya was appointed as prime
minister.
69
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
For the past three years, Cameroon’s English speaking regions (the
areas formerly ruled by the British) have started to engage in separatist
conflict against the French-dominated Cameroon government. However,
for most of Cameroon’s history – and especially during the time period
that is highlighted in the case study for this book (1960–2010) – this
linguistic cleavage was not particularly salient. Moreover, I argue that
Cameroon is an example of a regime with high levels of institutionaliza-
tion, making it durable against threats. The fact that the regime in
Cameroon has persisted, despite these separatist conflicts, provides addi-
tional support for the argument that the regime is highly institutionalized.
70
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.2 Cameroon Under Ahidjo
War resulted in a partition of the territory between the French and the
British in 1916. This agreement divided the country into two territories –
the French took the vast majority of the land in the country (four-fifths of
the total area of Cameroon), and the British took the remaining land.
Under this agreement, the two Cameroons became League of Nations
mandated colonies under France and the United Kingdom (Le Vine
1964, 4–8).
4
Joseph also notes that “in view of his uncertain and controversial origins, [Ahidjo] is
not strongly identified with any particular ethnic group,” making it even more
difficult for him to have a mass popular following (77).
71
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
72
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.2 Cameroon Under Ahidjo
73
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
74
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.2 Cameroon Under Ahidjo
[Ahidjo] treated his opponents firmly, sometimes harshly, but made sure that even
his bitterest enemies had both the chance of joining his side and of actively sharing
in the perquisites of rule. That he was never vindictive is to his credit: Mbida was
repeatedly offered various portfolios, Okala came out of prison to become an
ambassador, and several former UPC leaders have taken high and well-paying jobs
in government. (Le Vine 1964, 181)
Ahidjo also took great pains to make sure that elites from various
regions, ethnicities, and religions were represented in his cabinet. “The
75
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
76
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.2 Cameroon Under Ahidjo
5
From 1977 to 1979, the succession order was changed to the president of the
National Assembly and then prime minister. In 1979, the constitution was amended
so that the prime minister was the direct successor.
77
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
remaining official title was party chairman of the CNU, asserted that the
party takes precedence over the government (Konde 2012).
As Ahidjo’s prime minister Biya had maintained an image of
a technocrat and made it clear that he had no ambitions to compete
with Ahidjo (Mbaku and Takougang 2004). After acceding to the pre-
sidency, however, Biya made a number of administrative and policy
changes that diminished the influence of Ahidjo’s allies in favor of his
own power base. This included multiple cabinet reshuffles in which most
of Ahidjo’s appointees were replaced. Within a year Biya replaced over
half the cabinet he had inherited from Ahidjo. Biya also undertook admin-
istrative reforms, most notably dividing the northern region – Ahidjo’s
home district – into three provinces (CIA 1983; 1984).
In response to Biya’s consolidation of power, Ahidjo tried to reclaim his
influence. He reportedly attempted to introduce a constitutional amend-
ment that would increase his own authority as chairman of the party while
reducing the powers of the president. He asked his remaining ministers
who had not been replaced in the cabinet reshuffle to resign in protest –
none of whom did (Ngoh 1987, 309–310).
On April 6, 1984, members of the palace guard who were loyal to Ahidjo
attempted to launch a coup against Biya. It is believed, though not verified,
that Ahidjo himself help to orchestrate the coup. This coup failed, in part
because of tactical mistakes, and also because the coup plotters failed to
gain support of key members of the armed forces. Though the constitu-
tional succession provisions was clearly not the only reason Biya was able to
retain power in light of the failed coup attempt, it conferred legality and
legitimacy to his claim to the presidency (Hughes and May 1988).
Chapter 2 opened with the following observation by Montesquieu: “At the
birth of new polities, leaders mold institutions, whereas afterwards institu-
tions mold leaders” (qtd in Putnam 1993, 26). Much like Montesquieu’s
remark, after relinquishing power to his successor, Paul Biya, Ahidjo was shut
out of returning to power by the very institutions that he put in place himself.
Moreover, the constitutionally designated succession procedures ensured that
Ahidjo could not renege on promises to transfer power to Biya. As Ngoh
(1989) argues, Ahidjo “realized that after twenty-five years as the undisputed
strongman in Cameroon, he had to play second fiddle to Paul Biya – some-
thing he was not prepared to do” (319).
Paul Biya remains in power in Cameroon today – even surviving the
introduction of multiparty elections in 1992. How did he remain in power
despite demands for political liberalization in the 1990s? In large part,
Biya benefited from the fact that the transfer of power took place long
before pressures to introduce multiparty elections arose by the end of the
Cold War. By 1991, Biya had already been in power for almost a decade.
78
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.3 Côte D’Ivoire Under Houphouët
79
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
80
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.3 Côte D’Ivoire Under Houphouët
81
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
6
There is a famous story that on the eve of independence, Houphouët met with
Kwame Nkrumah, the founding president of Ghana. Nkrumah favored a policy of
completely breaking ties with the British, while Houphouët favored a closer relation-
ship with the French. The two men agreed to meet again a decade later to see which
approach worked better. Nkrumah was deposed in a military coup six years after
independence (Woronoff 1972).
82
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.3 Côte D’Ivoire Under Houphouët
Côte d’Ivoire. The second major development was that of a bill in the
French Assembly to abolish forced labor in West Africa. Houphouët played
a major role in shepherding this bill through the legislative process. This
achievement won Houphouët the national spotlight as the Ivorian politician
who stood up to the French. From that point on, his moral and political
authority within Côte d’Ivoire would be unparalleled. I will discuss both of
these major developments in detail below.
In 1946, a law was passed that granted French citizenship to all people
living in French colonial territories. Citizenship came with the ability to
vote and participate in French elections.7 The ability to elect representa-
tives for the French Assembly provided Côte d’Ivoire limited measures
of political representation and a seat at the table. It also provided
Houphouët, who would serve for fourteen years in the French National
Assembly, with the opportunity to consolidate power as the top politician
in Côte d’Ivoire.
That same year an election was held to select a politician who would
represent Côte d’Ivoire in Paris. This was the first real opportunity that
most Africans had to express their political concerns and preferences
within the French Constituent Assembly. For these elections, European
and African politicians formed candidate lists that were composed of both
African and French representations. By contrast, Houphouët formed a list
that consisted of a coalition of Côte d’Ivoire tribes and foreign Africans,
one of the few proposals to exclude whites altogether. As a result, many
other African candidates withdrew their lists in support of Houphouët’s
slate. Houphouët’s list easily won both rounds of voting, and he was
elected to the French National Assembly (Zolberg 1969, 69).
A year later, building on the foundations of the SAA, Houphouët
formed his own political party, the PDCI. During the 1946 French
Constituent Assembly elections, Houphouët ran under his new party
label, and swept the elections, winning 98 percent of the vote in Côte
d’Ivoire districts (Zolberg 1969, 76). When Houphouët won, the PDCI
became the first successful independent African political party. Within
a year, the PDCI had an estimated 80,000 members, and from then on, the
PDCI gained so much influence that no African candidate could be elected
without the endorsement of the party, and by extension, Houphouët. The
French colonial administration often tried to undermine the PDCI. Prior
to elections, they promoted anti-PDCI candidates and tried to organize
ethnic and regional associations alliances that could challenge the PDCI’s
7
Initially, however, suffrage was far from universal. Many restrictions were placed,
for instance, French literacy was a requirement for voting. In 1956, the Loi Cadre bill
was passed, guaranteeing universal suffrage for all French citizens.
83
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
84
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.3 Côte D’Ivoire Under Houphouët
85
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
8
Though he still favored his own Baoulé group, especially for top positions.
86
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.3 Côte D’Ivoire Under Houphouët
state and head of government, is given the power to appoint a cabinet that
is not accountable to the National Assembly (Zolberg 1969, 108).
The ruling party and legislature under Houphouët was similarly weak.
The PDCI, which had been a political machine during the independence
era, began to atrophy once Houphouët came into power. Though the PDCI
routinely won all seats in the National Assembly, this was purely because
opposition parties were shut out. By the mid-1960s, party structures fell
prey to factionalism and were “inadequate instruments of control over the
administration and over the population” and “did not provide an effective
network of political communication” (Zolberg 1971, 21). Similarly, under
Houphouët the National Assembly served only to rubber stamp executive
decrees and instructions (Jackson and Rosberg 1982, 147–150).
87
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
Henri Konan Bédié had served in the Ivorian government since inde-
pendence. He was Côte d’Ivoire’s ambassador to the United States and
Canada, then the minister of economy and finance. In 1980, Bédié was
elected to the National Assembly, where he was then subsequently elected
as the president of the National Assembly, the position he served from
1980 through to Houphouët’s death in 1993.
In 1987 the constitution was amended to specify that the president of
the National Assembly would succeed the president in the event of the
incumbent’s death or incapacitation. Despite the creation of this constitu-
tional rule, Houphouët did not publicly support Bédié as his designated
successor. The lack of clear and early support from Houphouët of his
designated heir resulted in Bédié’s lack of legitimacy as the presidential
successor.
In 1991, two years before Houphouët’s death, a power struggle over
the impending presidential succession emerged between Bédié and
Houphouët’s newly designated prime minister, Alassane Ouattara. The
position of prime minister was created in 1991, and it was the first time
a second in command position had been created and filled in the presi-
dential cabinet since independence in 1960. In response to the financial
crises that had developed in the 1980s, the International Monetary Fund
(IMF) pressured Houphouët to appoint Ouattara, a former IMF econo-
mist who had been educated in the United States, as prime minister. Two
factions, one supporting Bédié and the other supporting Ouattara
emerged during this period (Konate 2004; McGovern 2011).
Houphouët died on December 7, 1993, and immediately following his
death, Bédié announced on state television that he had assumed the pre-
sidency. However, having failed to consolidate power prior to Houphouët’s
death, Bédié entered power weak. On one hand, there is some evidence that
Bédié tried to institutionalize his regime. Important cabinet positions, such
as prime minister and defense minister, were always filled and were rela-
tively stable. However, Bédié shut out one key challenger: Ouattara. He
purged the cabinet of anyone who supported Ouattara and introduced
a new electoral law that was clearly aimed at preventing Ouattara from
running in future elections (McCauley 2017; Rabinowitz 2018).
On December 23, 1999, Bédié was ousted in a coup that was staged by
members of the military who were linked to Ouattara. While Bédié was
out of the capital celebrating Christmas with his family, a group of
soldiers took over the airport, government television station, and radio
station. Many of the officers who led the coup had personal connections
with Ouattara – one officer had been a member of Ouattara’s guard. The
armed forces did not step in to defend Bédié, and the regime ended due to
the coup (Rabinowitz 2018).
88
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.4 Power Sharing in Presidential Cabinets
3 . 4 e m p i r i ca l a n al y s i s o f p o w e r sh a r i n g
in pres idential cabinets
In this final section, I analyze data on ethnicities of cabinet ministers to
demonstrate that power sharing was more prevalent in the Ahidjo regime
compared with the Houphouët regime. While ethnic favoritism prevailed
under Houphouët, Ahidjo routinely appointed non coethnics to his cabinet,
even appointing leaders from other ethnic groups to top cabinet positions,
such as prime minister, minister of finance, and minister of defense.
I use data from Francois, Rainer, and Trebbi (2015), which includes
comprehensive data on the ethnicities of cabinet ministers in fourteen
African countries from 1960 to 2010, including Cameroon and Côte
d’Ivoire. The descriptive statistics paint a clear picture of ethnic favoritism
in Côte d’Ivoire in contrast to elite power sharing in Cameroon.
Ahmadou Ahidjo, the first president of Cameroon, was an ethnic
Fulani, but he appointed many non coethnics to his cabinet. On average,
Ahidjo had twenty-three ministers in his presidential cabinet. The smallest
cabinets, from 1963 to 1964, had thirteen ministers, and the largest
cabinet, in 1982, had thirty-three ministers. There are 496 total minis-
ter–year observations (excluding the president) during Ahidjo’s rule from
1960 through 1982. Summary statistics are presented in Appendix Table
3.1.
Ahidjo did not favor ethnic Fulanis in his cabinet, only assigning
12 percent of all cabinet ministerial positions to his coethnics. The same
pattern emerges, even if we restrict the sample to top ministerial posts:
only 24 percent of top ministerial posts were assigned to ethnic Fulanis.9
9
Top ministerial posts, as defined by Francois, Rainer, and Trebbi (2015), include vice
president, prime minister, defense, budget, commerce, finance, treasury, economy,
agriculture, justice, and state/foreign affairs.
89
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
90
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.5 Conclusion
Percent coethnics appointed to top ministerial post
.8
.6
.4
.2
0
1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995
year
Cameroon Côte d’Ivoire
3.5 conclusion
This chapter presented two case studies that illustrated the mechanisms and
findings articulated by the formal model in Chapter 2. First, I discussed the
case of Cameroon, a highly institutionalized regime under the presidency of
Ahmadou Ahidjo. Ahidjo entered power weak relative to other elites,
largely because he inherited his position of power from the outgoing
French colonial authorities. I argued that in order to retain support from
other elites, Ahidjo established checks on his own authority and delegated
91
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
Appendix
Ahidjo Houphouët
(Cameroon) (Côte d’Ivoire)
92
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.003 Published online by Cambridge University Press
3
Two Illustrative Cases
1
As will be discussed later in this chapter, a small sliver of Cameroon was controlled
by the British, but the country was mostly under French colonial rule. British rule in
Cameroon was very limited, as the French took the vast majority of the land (four-
fifths of the total area of Cameroon) – including the capital city of Yaounde.
Francophile elites and politicians have always dominated the executive in Cameroon.
64
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
2000
1500
GDP per capita
1000
500
0
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020
Year
Côte d’Ivoire Cameroon
Figure 3.1 Yearly gross domestic product (GDP) of Cameroon and Côte d’Ivoire
65
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
66
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.1 The Formal Model Summarized
67
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
2
Though in recent years an anglophone separatist movement has emerged in
Cameroon. The country has also experienced insurgent violence from Boko
Haram. Cameroon experienced an unsuccessful coup attempt in 1984, as this chap-
ter will later discuss.
68
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.2 Cameroon Under Ahidjo
3
For a short period during Ahidjo’s rule, from 1973 to 1974, the office of the vice
president was eliminated from the cabinet. In 1975 the title of the office of vice
president was changed to prime minister and was added back to the cabinet. From
1975 through until the end of Ahidjo’s rule, Paul Biya was appointed as prime
minister.
69
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
For the past three years, Cameroon’s English speaking regions (the
areas formerly ruled by the British) have started to engage in separatist
conflict against the French-dominated Cameroon government. However,
for most of Cameroon’s history – and especially during the time period
that is highlighted in the case study for this book (1960–2010) – this
linguistic cleavage was not particularly salient. Moreover, I argue that
Cameroon is an example of a regime with high levels of institutionaliza-
tion, making it durable against threats. The fact that the regime in
Cameroon has persisted, despite these separatist conflicts, provides addi-
tional support for the argument that the regime is highly institutionalized.
70
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.2 Cameroon Under Ahidjo
War resulted in a partition of the territory between the French and the
British in 1916. This agreement divided the country into two territories –
the French took the vast majority of the land in the country (four-fifths of
the total area of Cameroon), and the British took the remaining land.
Under this agreement, the two Cameroons became League of Nations
mandated colonies under France and the United Kingdom (Le Vine
1964, 4–8).
4
Joseph also notes that “in view of his uncertain and controversial origins, [Ahidjo] is
not strongly identified with any particular ethnic group,” making it even more
difficult for him to have a mass popular following (77).
71
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
72
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.2 Cameroon Under Ahidjo
73
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
74
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.2 Cameroon Under Ahidjo
[Ahidjo] treated his opponents firmly, sometimes harshly, but made sure that even
his bitterest enemies had both the chance of joining his side and of actively sharing
in the perquisites of rule. That he was never vindictive is to his credit: Mbida was
repeatedly offered various portfolios, Okala came out of prison to become an
ambassador, and several former UPC leaders have taken high and well-paying jobs
in government. (Le Vine 1964, 181)
Ahidjo also took great pains to make sure that elites from various
regions, ethnicities, and religions were represented in his cabinet. “The
75
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
76
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.2 Cameroon Under Ahidjo
5
From 1977 to 1979, the succession order was changed to the president of the
National Assembly and then prime minister. In 1979, the constitution was amended
so that the prime minister was the direct successor.
77
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
remaining official title was party chairman of the CNU, asserted that the
party takes precedence over the government (Konde 2012).
As Ahidjo’s prime minister Biya had maintained an image of
a technocrat and made it clear that he had no ambitions to compete
with Ahidjo (Mbaku and Takougang 2004). After acceding to the pre-
sidency, however, Biya made a number of administrative and policy
changes that diminished the influence of Ahidjo’s allies in favor of his
own power base. This included multiple cabinet reshuffles in which most
of Ahidjo’s appointees were replaced. Within a year Biya replaced over
half the cabinet he had inherited from Ahidjo. Biya also undertook admin-
istrative reforms, most notably dividing the northern region – Ahidjo’s
home district – into three provinces (CIA 1983; 1984).
In response to Biya’s consolidation of power, Ahidjo tried to reclaim his
influence. He reportedly attempted to introduce a constitutional amend-
ment that would increase his own authority as chairman of the party while
reducing the powers of the president. He asked his remaining ministers
who had not been replaced in the cabinet reshuffle to resign in protest –
none of whom did (Ngoh 1987, 309–310).
On April 6, 1984, members of the palace guard who were loyal to Ahidjo
attempted to launch a coup against Biya. It is believed, though not verified,
that Ahidjo himself help to orchestrate the coup. This coup failed, in part
because of tactical mistakes, and also because the coup plotters failed to
gain support of key members of the armed forces. Though the constitu-
tional succession provisions was clearly not the only reason Biya was able to
retain power in light of the failed coup attempt, it conferred legality and
legitimacy to his claim to the presidency (Hughes and May 1988).
Chapter 2 opened with the following observation by Montesquieu: “At the
birth of new polities, leaders mold institutions, whereas afterwards institu-
tions mold leaders” (qtd in Putnam 1993, 26). Much like Montesquieu’s
remark, after relinquishing power to his successor, Paul Biya, Ahidjo was shut
out of returning to power by the very institutions that he put in place himself.
Moreover, the constitutionally designated succession procedures ensured that
Ahidjo could not renege on promises to transfer power to Biya. As Ngoh
(1989) argues, Ahidjo “realized that after twenty-five years as the undisputed
strongman in Cameroon, he had to play second fiddle to Paul Biya – some-
thing he was not prepared to do” (319).
Paul Biya remains in power in Cameroon today – even surviving the
introduction of multiparty elections in 1992. How did he remain in power
despite demands for political liberalization in the 1990s? In large part,
Biya benefited from the fact that the transfer of power took place long
before pressures to introduce multiparty elections arose by the end of the
Cold War. By 1991, Biya had already been in power for almost a decade.
78
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.3 Côte D’Ivoire Under Houphouët
79
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
80
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.3 Côte D’Ivoire Under Houphouët
81
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
6
There is a famous story that on the eve of independence, Houphouët met with
Kwame Nkrumah, the founding president of Ghana. Nkrumah favored a policy of
completely breaking ties with the British, while Houphouët favored a closer relation-
ship with the French. The two men agreed to meet again a decade later to see which
approach worked better. Nkrumah was deposed in a military coup six years after
independence (Woronoff 1972).
82
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.3 Côte D’Ivoire Under Houphouët
Côte d’Ivoire. The second major development was that of a bill in the
French Assembly to abolish forced labor in West Africa. Houphouët played
a major role in shepherding this bill through the legislative process. This
achievement won Houphouët the national spotlight as the Ivorian politician
who stood up to the French. From that point on, his moral and political
authority within Côte d’Ivoire would be unparalleled. I will discuss both of
these major developments in detail below.
In 1946, a law was passed that granted French citizenship to all people
living in French colonial territories. Citizenship came with the ability to
vote and participate in French elections.7 The ability to elect representa-
tives for the French Assembly provided Côte d’Ivoire limited measures
of political representation and a seat at the table. It also provided
Houphouët, who would serve for fourteen years in the French National
Assembly, with the opportunity to consolidate power as the top politician
in Côte d’Ivoire.
That same year an election was held to select a politician who would
represent Côte d’Ivoire in Paris. This was the first real opportunity that
most Africans had to express their political concerns and preferences
within the French Constituent Assembly. For these elections, European
and African politicians formed candidate lists that were composed of both
African and French representations. By contrast, Houphouët formed a list
that consisted of a coalition of Côte d’Ivoire tribes and foreign Africans,
one of the few proposals to exclude whites altogether. As a result, many
other African candidates withdrew their lists in support of Houphouët’s
slate. Houphouët’s list easily won both rounds of voting, and he was
elected to the French National Assembly (Zolberg 1969, 69).
A year later, building on the foundations of the SAA, Houphouët
formed his own political party, the PDCI. During the 1946 French
Constituent Assembly elections, Houphouët ran under his new party
label, and swept the elections, winning 98 percent of the vote in Côte
d’Ivoire districts (Zolberg 1969, 76). When Houphouët won, the PDCI
became the first successful independent African political party. Within
a year, the PDCI had an estimated 80,000 members, and from then on, the
PDCI gained so much influence that no African candidate could be elected
without the endorsement of the party, and by extension, Houphouët. The
French colonial administration often tried to undermine the PDCI. Prior
to elections, they promoted anti-PDCI candidates and tried to organize
ethnic and regional associations alliances that could challenge the PDCI’s
7
Initially, however, suffrage was far from universal. Many restrictions were placed,
for instance, French literacy was a requirement for voting. In 1956, the Loi Cadre bill
was passed, guaranteeing universal suffrage for all French citizens.
83
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
84
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.3 Côte D’Ivoire Under Houphouët
85
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
8
Though he still favored his own Baoulé group, especially for top positions.
86
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.3 Côte D’Ivoire Under Houphouët
state and head of government, is given the power to appoint a cabinet that
is not accountable to the National Assembly (Zolberg 1969, 108).
The ruling party and legislature under Houphouët was similarly weak.
The PDCI, which had been a political machine during the independence
era, began to atrophy once Houphouët came into power. Though the PDCI
routinely won all seats in the National Assembly, this was purely because
opposition parties were shut out. By the mid-1960s, party structures fell
prey to factionalism and were “inadequate instruments of control over the
administration and over the population” and “did not provide an effective
network of political communication” (Zolberg 1971, 21). Similarly, under
Houphouët the National Assembly served only to rubber stamp executive
decrees and instructions (Jackson and Rosberg 1982, 147–150).
87
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
Henri Konan Bédié had served in the Ivorian government since inde-
pendence. He was Côte d’Ivoire’s ambassador to the United States and
Canada, then the minister of economy and finance. In 1980, Bédié was
elected to the National Assembly, where he was then subsequently elected
as the president of the National Assembly, the position he served from
1980 through to Houphouët’s death in 1993.
In 1987 the constitution was amended to specify that the president of
the National Assembly would succeed the president in the event of the
incumbent’s death or incapacitation. Despite the creation of this constitu-
tional rule, Houphouët did not publicly support Bédié as his designated
successor. The lack of clear and early support from Houphouët of his
designated heir resulted in Bédié’s lack of legitimacy as the presidential
successor.
In 1991, two years before Houphouët’s death, a power struggle over
the impending presidential succession emerged between Bédié and
Houphouët’s newly designated prime minister, Alassane Ouattara. The
position of prime minister was created in 1991, and it was the first time
a second in command position had been created and filled in the presi-
dential cabinet since independence in 1960. In response to the financial
crises that had developed in the 1980s, the International Monetary Fund
(IMF) pressured Houphouët to appoint Ouattara, a former IMF econo-
mist who had been educated in the United States, as prime minister. Two
factions, one supporting Bédié and the other supporting Ouattara
emerged during this period (Konate 2004; McGovern 2011).
Houphouët died on December 7, 1993, and immediately following his
death, Bédié announced on state television that he had assumed the pre-
sidency. However, having failed to consolidate power prior to Houphouët’s
death, Bédié entered power weak. On one hand, there is some evidence that
Bédié tried to institutionalize his regime. Important cabinet positions, such
as prime minister and defense minister, were always filled and were rela-
tively stable. However, Bédié shut out one key challenger: Ouattara. He
purged the cabinet of anyone who supported Ouattara and introduced
a new electoral law that was clearly aimed at preventing Ouattara from
running in future elections (McCauley 2017; Rabinowitz 2018).
On December 23, 1999, Bédié was ousted in a coup that was staged by
members of the military who were linked to Ouattara. While Bédié was
out of the capital celebrating Christmas with his family, a group of
soldiers took over the airport, government television station, and radio
station. Many of the officers who led the coup had personal connections
with Ouattara – one officer had been a member of Ouattara’s guard. The
armed forces did not step in to defend Bédié, and the regime ended due to
the coup (Rabinowitz 2018).
88
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.4 Power Sharing in Presidential Cabinets
3 . 4 e m p i r i ca l a n al y s i s o f p o w e r sh a r i n g
in pres idential cabinets
In this final section, I analyze data on ethnicities of cabinet ministers to
demonstrate that power sharing was more prevalent in the Ahidjo regime
compared with the Houphouët regime. While ethnic favoritism prevailed
under Houphouët, Ahidjo routinely appointed non coethnics to his cabinet,
even appointing leaders from other ethnic groups to top cabinet positions,
such as prime minister, minister of finance, and minister of defense.
I use data from Francois, Rainer, and Trebbi (2015), which includes
comprehensive data on the ethnicities of cabinet ministers in fourteen
African countries from 1960 to 2010, including Cameroon and Côte
d’Ivoire. The descriptive statistics paint a clear picture of ethnic favoritism
in Côte d’Ivoire in contrast to elite power sharing in Cameroon.
Ahmadou Ahidjo, the first president of Cameroon, was an ethnic
Fulani, but he appointed many non coethnics to his cabinet. On average,
Ahidjo had twenty-three ministers in his presidential cabinet. The smallest
cabinets, from 1963 to 1964, had thirteen ministers, and the largest
cabinet, in 1982, had thirty-three ministers. There are 496 total minis-
ter–year observations (excluding the president) during Ahidjo’s rule from
1960 through 1982. Summary statistics are presented in Appendix Table
3.1.
Ahidjo did not favor ethnic Fulanis in his cabinet, only assigning
12 percent of all cabinet ministerial positions to his coethnics. The same
pattern emerges, even if we restrict the sample to top ministerial posts:
only 24 percent of top ministerial posts were assigned to ethnic Fulanis.9
9
Top ministerial posts, as defined by Francois, Rainer, and Trebbi (2015), include vice
president, prime minister, defense, budget, commerce, finance, treasury, economy,
agriculture, justice, and state/foreign affairs.
89
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
90
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3.5 Conclusion
Percent coethnics appointed to top ministerial post
.8
.6
.4
.2
0
1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995
year
Cameroon Côte d’Ivoire
3.5 conclusion
This chapter presented two case studies that illustrated the mechanisms and
findings articulated by the formal model in Chapter 2. First, I discussed the
case of Cameroon, a highly institutionalized regime under the presidency of
Ahmadou Ahidjo. Ahidjo entered power weak relative to other elites,
largely because he inherited his position of power from the outgoing
French colonial authorities. I argued that in order to retain support from
other elites, Ahidjo established checks on his own authority and delegated
91
Published online by Cambridge University Press
3 Two Illustrative Cases
Appendix
Ahidjo Houphouët
(Cameroon) (Côte d’Ivoire)
92
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4
How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
One of the core arguments of this book is that autocratic regimes vary
drastically in the extent to which they are institutionalized. This chapter
lays the empirical groundwork for this claim by presenting detailed data on
regime institutionalization. In doing so, I also provide a discussion of how
we should define and measure autocratic regime institutionalization – a key
concept often used, but not well operationalized – in the literature.
I define regime institutionalization as the creation of rules and proce-
dures that structure the distribution of power and resources within the
ruling coalition. In an autocratic setting, regime institutionalization serves
to tie the leader’s hands. This chapter presents an original time-series
cross-sectional dataset measuring regime institutionalization in forty-six
countries in sub-Saharan Africa from 1960 to 2010. I discuss my coding
strategy in detail and present examples of each type of executive
constraint. I also summarize general trends and patterns in the data to
provide a broad perspective of what institutionalization looks like within
sub-Saharan Africa and how it differs across countries.
This chapter also compares this dataset against other commonly used
datasets of authoritarian institutions, such as regime typologies (Geddes,
Wright, and Frantz 2014). I show that regime typologies often do not reflect
the extent to which executive constraints are in place, and many countries
coded as party-based regimes are not very institutionalized at all. In addi-
tion, I also compare my measures of institutionalization against other
commonly used datasets of institutional strength – Polity (Marshall,
Gurr, and Jaggers 2016) and V-Dem (Coppedge et al. 2016).
Another important implication that emerges from this chapter is that
countries in sub-Saharan Africa vary widely in their level of institutiona-
lization, even during the decades of authoritarian rule following indepen-
dence. A small number of recent studies document that African countries
have become more institutionalized over time, especially after the end of
the Cold War (Posner and Young 2007). Others show that African party
93
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
4 . 1 co n c e p t u a li z i n g au t h o r i ta r i a n r e g i m e
i n s t it u t i o n a l iz a t i o n
Before I define regime institutionalization it is first helpful to note what I
mean by “regime.” I consider a regime as the set of rules, norms, and
institutions that govern the way in which the government is run. Most
relevant for this study, these rules determine the way in which leaders
enter and exit office. A regime can have multiple leaders, as long as these
leaders enter and exit office according to established rules and norms. I
consider an irregular leadership turnover – often due to the forced exit of a
leader and/or the entry of a leader via a coup – as signaling a break in the
regime (Goemans, Gleditsch, and Chiozza 2009).1
For instance, the Gambia experienced a regime change in 1994 when
the armed forces staged a coup and deposed Gawda Jawara – the leader
who had been in power since 1962. Ghana also experienced a regime
change in 1993 when it became classified as a democracy (more on how I
define democracy later) – though the leader did not change. Flight lieute-
nant Jerry Rawlings took power via a coup in Ghana in 1979. In the early
1990s, in response to increasing pressures to democratize, Rawlings lega-
lized political parties and allowed for multiparty elections to occur in
1992. Although Rawlings won the elections, and remained the president
of Ghana, these elections were considered free and fair, and importantly -
there has been party and leadership turnover since then. Ghana is there-
fore coded as having a regime break in 1993. Finally, Tanzania has
remained the same regime since independence, despite having multiple
1
This definition of an autocratic regime is similar to Svolik’s (2012) definition of a
“ruling-coalition spell.”
94
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.1 Conceptualizing Regime Institutionalization
leaders. Since independence was granted in 1961, Tanzania has had five
different presidents, but the same ruling coalition has remained in power,
and the ways in which the incumbent is selected has not drastically
changed.2
I define autocratic regime institutionalization as the creation of rules,
procedures, and hierarchies that structure the ways in which power and
resources are distributed within the ruling coalition. Examples of this
include establishing leadership succession procedures or creating rules
that govern elite promotion. When a leader institutionalizes the regime,
she takes actions that constrain her ability to take arbitrary actions in the
future. Autocratic regime institutionalization occurs when executive
constraints are created that tie the leader’s hands.
My conceptualization of institutionalization closely follows Huntington’s
(1968) definition of political institutionalization as “the process by
which organizations and procedures acquire value and stability” (12).
In particular, Huntington identifies several key features of institutiona-
lization that are most relevant for the survival of authoritarian regimes.
First, adaptability and the ability to outlive the founder is a key char-
acteristic of institutionalized organizations (13). Second, autonomy and
the ability of an organization to exist independently of particular actors
is a key feature of institutionalization. According to Huntington, an
organization that is merely an instrument of a leader lacks autonomy
and institutionalization (20).
This discussion is also related to Levitsky and Murillo’s (2009) discus-
sion of institutional strength.3 They argue that institutional strength
should be judged across two dimensions: enforcement and stability.
Strong institutions are those that political elites comply with in practice.
This conceptualization of institutional strength ties directly with my dis-
cussion of regime institutionalization. Regimes with institutionalized
2
Note that this conceptual discussion of “regime” does not affect the coding decisions
for this project because the measures of institutionalization I construct operate at the
country–year level, not at the regime level.
3
Much of the discussions of institutionalization has centered around the institutiona-
lization of political parties, rather than regimes. Huntington (1965), for instance,
defines party institutionalization as the process by which parties become established
and acquire value and stability. Levitsky (1998) likens institutionalization to the
entrenchment of the “rules of the game” that shape the expectations, payoffs, and
behavior of actors in his discussion of the Peronist party in Argentina (p. 80).
Panebianco (1988) argues that institutionalization transfers authority from the
leader to the party, and very few charismatic parties survive this transfer. Research
on party system institutionalization also describes strong party organizations as
having independent status and value, not subordinated to the interests of ambitious
leaders (Mainwaring and Scully 1995).
95
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
practices – those governed by stable rules that do not shift with changing
circumstances – are durable regimes that are likely to survive leadership
transitions precisely because they have rules that can outlast the circum-
stances in which they were initially created.4
In the context of an authoritarian regime, institutionalization has
several important implications. First, the creation of rules and procedures
depersonalizes the ways in which the regime operates by constraining the
autocratic leader’s ability to make arbitrary decisions in the future. This is
especially relevant in dictatorships, where power is often concentrated in
the hands of a single leader. When a leader establishes term limits, for
instance, she loses the ability to decide arbitrarily when and whether she
will step down from office. This kind of depersonalization can also hap-
pen through the creation of merit-based promotion within the executive.
Regimes with set rules, procedures, and hierarchies that regulate elite
promotion are more institutionalized compared with systems in which
a single incumbent can appoint or purge elites at any time without
constraint.
Second, institutionalization can empower other elites by establishing
hierarchical positions and rules regarding the appointment of elites to
important positions. A regime with a presidential cabinet in which elites
are appointed to important ministerial portfolios, such as defense or
finance, represents a regime in which power and resources are not entirely
concentrated within the hands of the leader. Such a regime is more
institutionalized compared with a presidential cabinet in which the incum-
bent holds all the important portfolios herself, and there are no estab-
lished rules or norms for the appointment of these positions.
However, it is important to note that institutionalization does not
always result in the empowerment of other elites. Some types of executive
constraints only limit the incumbent. Term limits on their own create
restrictions on the length of time that the incumbent can remain in office,
but do not specify who will replace the incumbent or how that replace-
ment process will occur.
Third, institutionalization separates the ruler from the regime.
Importantly, an institutionalized regime is one that can perpetuate its
own existence beyond the influence of an individual leader. A regime
that is not institutionalized is a government of one: the ruler. The ability
4
My conceptualization differs from Slater’s (2003) view that highly institutionalized
regimes do not necessarily have to contain institutions that constrain leaders, as long
as the institutions have “infrastructural power” – the ability to implement and
execute the leader’s demands. By contrast, I argue that the ability to keep the
executive in check is a necessary and central component of institutionalization.
96
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.1 Conceptualizing Regime Institutionalization
97
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
5
As a parallel example, a country might be stuck in an equilibrium where there are
high levels of corruption that operate in defiance of formal regulatory institutions,
but I would not consider corruption practices to be a set of institutions.
98
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.1 Conceptualizing Regime Institutionalization
6
Formal rules include state institutions (parties, legislatures, and courts) as well as
state-enforced rules (constitutions and legislation).
99
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
7
Recall that in the formal model presented in Chapter 2, positive levels of institutio-
nalization increase the likelihood that the autocrat would be deposed if fighting were
to occur in the second period.
100
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.2 Measuring Regime Institutionalization
101
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
8
See Diamond 2002; Gandhi 2008; Geddes 2003; Pzeworski 2000; Svolik 2012.
102
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.2 Measuring Regime Institutionalization
9
The CCM was created in 1977 after the former ruling party, the Tanganyika
African National Union (TANU), merged with the ruling party of Zanzibar, follow-
ing the merger of the two countries.
10
Using this coding scheme, the following countries and time periods are considered
democratic and therefore dropped from the sample: Benin after 1991, Cape Verde
after 1990, Ghana after 1993, Kenya after 1998, Madagascar after 1993, Malawi
after 1994, Mali after 1992, Mauritius for the whole period, Nigeria after 1999, Sao
Tome and Principe after 1991, Senegal after 2000, and Sierra Leone after 1998.
11
Only Ghana and Guinea gained independence a few years prior to 1960. Liberia and
Ethiopia were never colonized. Each of these three countries enter the dataset in 1960.
103
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
competition and institutions are taken into account. However, I do not base
my coding of authoritarian regimes on Polity scores for three main reasons.
First, the vast majority of countries in Africa do not meet the minimalist
definition of contestation of power through competitive elections, at least
not until the 1990s. The “less stringent” criterion is sufficient to identify the
authoritarian sample of cases in this region. Second, Polity uses criteria
about the quality of executive constraints and competitiveness to create an
aggregated score.12 Since I am examining constraints on executive power, I
do not want to eliminate cases by using a coding scheme that takes into
account the quality of institutions and constraints on the executive. Doing
so would risk eliminating cases of highly institutionalized authoritarian
regimes in my final sample. Third, Polity scores do not reflect party alter-
nation; therefore, a case such as Botswana can score exceptionally high
despite not having had party alternation in the executive.
12
One of the component variables of Polity scores is “XCONST,” which reflects the
extent to which there are institutionalized constraints on the decision-making
powers of the executive. A comparison of my measures of executive constraints
and XCONST is discussed later in this chapter.
104
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.2 Measuring Regime Institutionalization
105
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
106
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.2 Measuring Regime Institutionalization
13
Vice presidents and prime ministers are functional equivalents within this particular
context. All the countries in my sample either have one or the other. No cabinet has
both a vice president and a prime minister, although a small number of countries
have multiple vice presidents.
14
In fact, many presidents were extremely hesitant to assign the second-in-command
position to another party elite. Jose Eduardo dos Santos, the first president of
Angola, named himself as his own vice president for a number of years while he
was in power. Felix Houphouet-Boigny, the first president of the Ivory Coast,
created a vice-president position, but kept the post empty the entire time he was in
power. These two cases (and other similar instances) are coded as not having the
second-in-command position filled by another elite.
107
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
Notes: The leaders included in this table entered office through regular means, so coups and
irregular leader entries are excluded from this sample. The first president of each country is
not included in this sample because I am interested in the path of promotion after
independence was granted. Only leaders who were in office for three years or longer are
included in this sample. Leaders sometimes have multiple positions before entering office.
For example, Festus Mogae, who was the president of Botswana from 1998 to 2007 had
multiple cabinet positions from 1990 until 1997. He was the minister of finance from 1990
to 1997, minister of development and planning from 1990 to 1997, and vice president from
1992 to 1997. Each of these portfolios are recorded in this table.
their ascension to power, the most frequently held positions were the
minister of defense, vice president, or prime minister.
In addition, I document whether the person in the vice president or
prime minister position remains fairly constant over time, or whether the
person in this position is rotated very frequently. Accounting for cabinet
rotation rates is particularly important in the context of elite politics in
sub-Saharan Africa. African leaders routinely practiced the “revolving
108
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.2 Measuring Regime Institutionalization
Notes: The leaders included in this table entered office through irregular means – the modal
method of irregular leader entry is via a coup. The first president of each country is not included
in this sample because I am interested in the path of promotion after independence was granted.
Only leaders who were in office for three years or longer are included in this sample.
109
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
110
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.3 General Trends and Patterns
15
Because a number of the variables are highly correlated with each other (as I will
discuss below), I only include successor policy, term limits, VP/PM same, and
defense same in these graphs.
111
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
Number of constraints 0 1 2 3 4
illustrates the proportion of years for which each country had one, two,
three, or all four dimensions of institutionalization in place. Black sections
represent the proportion of years for which the country had all four
dimensions in place. Dark grey sections represent the proportion of
years for which the countries had three dimensions in place, and so on.
White sections represent the portion of years for which the country had no
dimensions in place.
112
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.3 General Trends and Patterns
Zimbabwe
16
Appendix Table 4.2 includes a summary of institutionalization scores by country.
113
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
114
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.3 General Trends and Patterns
1
.9
.8
.7
.6
.5
.4
.3
.2
.1
0
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
Year
115
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
Successor policy 1
Successor (strict) 0.855 1
Term limits 0.413 0.424 1
VP/PM appoint 0.187 0.238 0.292 1
VP/PM same 0.159 0.166 0.192 0.618 1
Defense appoint 0.209 0.221 0.186 0.203 0.122 1
Defense same 0.199 0.190 0.120 0.134 0.239 0.644 1
Note: Bolded numbers indicate two dimensions that are highly correlated (r > 0.6)
116
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.4 Regime Typologies
17
According to Google Scholar, Geddes (1999a) has been cited almost 300 times.
Geddes (1999b), an annual review article covering the same material as Geddes
(1999a), has been cited over 1,500 times.
18
The PRI was in power from 1929–2000 and the CCP has been in power since 1949.
19
Known as the Partido Nacional Revolucionario (PNR) at the time.
117
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
where power was handed over to the successor after the president’s term
ended (Buchenau 2006).
Mao was a similarly personalist founding leader. He promoted and
purged elite politicians at will and launched political campaigns, such as
the Hundred Flowers Movements and Cultural Revolution, during which
he arbitrarily purged officials who he deemed critical of the regime
(Meisner 1986). Over time, as Deng Xiaoping came into power, the CCP
eventually became an organization in which party promotion followed
established norms and procedures. In sum, many regimes change drastically
over time, and this is impossible to capture using a single time-invariant
regime category.20
Second, categorical distinctions between authoritarian regime types are
often insufficiently nuanced and obscure variation in institutional strength
within regime types. Take the category of dominant-party regimes. The
Soviet Union and China are coded as dominant-party regime types, and
they indeed were ruled by strong parties with organizational autonomy that
lasted through several leadership transitions. However, the category of
dominant-party regimes also includes cases such as the PDG in Guinea or
Communist Party of Kampuchea (CPK, also known as the Khmer Rouge)
in Cambodia. These parties, unlike the highly institutionalized communist
parties, were entirely concentrated around a single charismatic leader and
were not able to survive past the death and ousting of the leader.21
Third, regime typologies are composite indices that aggregate various
dimensions of leaders, institutions, and military structures into a single
category. As a result, it is difficult for researchers to identify the effects of
individual institutions (Pande and Udry 2006). Some regimes, for
instance, appear to be party-based, when in actuality the party is attached
to a strong and charismatic leader who merely exploits the party as a
personal vehicle to amplify his authority.
The Union Soudanaise – Rassemblement Democratique Africain (US-
RDA) under Modibo Keita in Mali, for instance, is coded as part of a
dominant-party regime. Yet national policies were determined entirely at
the discretion of Keita alone, and the US-RDA lacked institutionalized
rules and permanent structures. Eight years after taking power, Keita was
deposed in a coup and the party was banned. Although Keita, who was
20
It is possible for countries to be coded as different regime types over time, but most
countries are not coded as very many different types. The average country is coded
as two different types of regimes over an average time span of forty-four years, and
the average regime coding lasts about eighteen years.
21
The opposite scenario is sometimes true as well: not all cases coded as military or
personalist regimes are equally unconstrained.
118
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.4 Regime Typologies
119
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
22
I only focus on comparisons of pure regime types, leaving out hybrid regime types, such
as party-personal, party-military, military-personal, or triple hybrid types. These types
of hybrid regimes are excluded because it is not clear whether these regimes are highly
institutionalized or not. For instance, should a researcher expect a party-personal
regime to be highly institutionalized (due to the presence of some party attributes) or
not institutionalized (due to the presence of some personalist attributes)?
23
Formally, the measure is calculated as following:
X
years with institutionalization
percent years with institutionalization ¼ X
years in power
120
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.4 Regime Typologies
GWF case Regime type Success Success Term VP/PM VP/PM Defense Defense
rules (strict) limits appoint same appoint same
Party-based regimes and monarchies <50% <50% <50% <70% <50% <70% <50%
(institutionalized)
Angola 75–NA Party
Botswana 66–NA Party
Ethiopia 91–NA Party
Gambia 65–94 Party
Guinea 58–84 Party
G. Bissau 74–80 Party
Ivory Coast 60–99 Party
Kenya 63–02 Party
Madagascar 60–72 Party
Mali 60–68 Party
Mozambique 75–NA Party
Namibia 90–NA Party
Niger 60–74 Party
Rwanda 62–73 Party
Senegal 60–00 Party
Sierra Leone 68–92 Party
Tanzania 64–NA Party
Zambia 67–91 Party
Zambia 96–NA Party
Zimbabwe 80–NA Party
Ethiopia 89–74 Monarchy
Swaziland 68–NA Monarchy
Personalist and military regimes >50% >50% >50% >70% >50% >70% >50%
(not institutionalized)
Benin 60–63 Personal
Benin 63–65 Personal
Benin 72–90 Personal
Burkina Faso 60–66 Personal
Burkina Faso 66–80 Personal
Burkina Faso 82–87 Personal
Burkina Faso 87–NA Personal
Cameroon 83–NA Personal
CAR 03–NA Personal
CAR 60–65 Personal
CAR 79–81 Personal
Chad 82–90 Personal
Chad 90–NA Personal
Rep Congo 60–64 Personal
Rep Congo 97–NA Personal
DRC 60–97 Personal
DRC 97–NA Personal
Gambia 94–NA Personal
Ghana 81–00 Personal
Guinea 08–10 Personal
Guinea 84–09 Personal
G. Bissau 02–03 Personal
G. Bissau 80–99 Personal
Ivory Coast 00–NA Personal
Ivory Coast 99–00 Personal
121
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
GWF case Regime type Success Success Term VP/PM VP/PM Defense Defense
rules (strict) limits appoint same appoint same
Personalist and military regimes >50% >50% >50% >70% >50% >70% >50%
(not institutionalized)
Liberia 80–90 Personal
Liberia 97–03 Personal
Madagascar 09–NA Personal
Madagascar 75–93 Personal
Malawi 64–94 Personal
Mali 68–91 Personal
Mauritania 08–NA Personal
Mauritania 60–78 Personal
Mauritania 78–05 Personal
Niger 96–99 Personal
Sierra Leone 97–98 Personal
Somalia 69–91 Personal
Sudan 69–85 Personal
Sudan 89–NA Personal
Togo 60–63 Personal
Togo 63–NA Personal
Uganda 66–71 Personal
Uganda 71–79 Personal
Uganda 80–85 Personal
Uganda 86–NA Personal
Benin 65–67 Military
Benin 67–69 Military
Benin 69–70 Military
Burkina Faso 80–82 Military
Burundi 87–93 Military
Chad 75–79 Military
Ghana 66–69 Military
Ghana 72–79 Military
Madagascar 72–75 Military
Mauritania 05–07 Military
Nigeria 66–79 Military
Nigeria 83–93 Military
Sierra Leone 67–68 Military
Sudan 58–64 Military
Sudan 85–86 Military
Note: Shaded cells represent dimensions of party institutionalization that are in disagreement with the regime typology
coding. For example, for party-based regimes, “Second Appoint < 70%” means that the regimes listed in this column
are coded as party-based regimes, but have a second in command appointed less than 70 percent of the time.
For non party-based regimes, “Second Appoint >80%” means that the regimes listed in this column are NOT coded
as part of party-based regimes, but have a second in command appointed more than 80 percent of the time.
NA refers to regimes that were still in power as of 2010.
122
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.5 Comparisons with Other Existing Datasets
of Staff ousted the civilian government[…] . (Geddes, Wright, and Frantz 2012,
82)
24
Recall that the data goes up until 2010, though Compaore was in power until 2014.
123
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
0.75
Type of constraint
Succession rules
Term limits
0.50 Stable VP appoint
Stable Defense appoint
0.25
1 2 3 4 5 6 7
POLITY "XCONST" score
124
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.5 Comparisons with Other Existing Datasets
Proportion of observations with constraint (author’s data)
0.8
Type of constraint
0.6
Succession rules
Term limits
Stable VP appoint
Stable Defense appoint
0.4
0.2
coded by asking experts the following question: “To what extent is the
legislature and government agencies (e.g. controller general, general pro-
secutor, or ombudsman) capable of questioning, investigating, and exer-
cising oversight over the executive?”
Figure 4.4 provides a comparison of the legislative constraint scores
against my regime institutionalization measures. While the two vari-
ables appear generally correlated, some important differences arise.
For instance, a greater proportion of countries in my sample that
score a 0.5 on the V-Dem legislative constraint index have constitu-
tional succession rules in place compared with countries that score a
0.75 on the V-Dem legislative constrain index. This suggests that
simply having legislative constraints in place does not automatically
guarantee the existence of certain executive constraints, such as con-
stitutional succession rules.
Finally, I also conduct a comparison of my institutionalization mea-
sures against the “judicial constraints on the executive index” variable.
This question was coded by asking experts the following question: “To
what extent does the executive respect the constitution and comply with
court rulings, and to what extent is the judiciary able to act in an inde-
pendent fashion?”
125
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
0.6
Type of constraint
Succession rules
Term limits
Stable VP appoint
Stable Defense appoint
0.4
0.2
0 0.25 0.5 0.75 1
Level of judicial constraint on the executive
“Ordinal judicial constraints on the executive” variable
from V−DEM used. Five level ordered variable, with 0
being weakest constraints and 1 being strongest constraints.
4 . 6 co n c l u s i o n
This chapter presented an original dataset of autocratic regime insti-
tutionalization in all sub-Saharan regimes from 1960 to 2010. First I
discussed how I conceptualize and operationalize autocratic regime
institutionalization more generally, then I presented the dataset by
explaining my coding strategy and showing descriptive findings.
Finally I compared my dataset to other commonly used datasets of
authoritarian institutions, such as regime typologies, Polity scores,
and V-Dem measures.
The rest of the book will be primarily empirical and will use this dataset
to test my arguments about the causes and consequences of regime insti-
tutionalization. The next chapter will test the theoretical argument made
in Chapter 2 and show that there is a relationship between initial leader
126
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.6 Conclusion
Appendix
Appendix Table 4.1 List of countries and leaders included in this study
127
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
128
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.6 Conclusion
129
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
130
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.6 Conclusion
131
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.004 Published online by Cambridge University Press
Appendix Table 4.2 Summary of institutionalization scores by country
Term
Country Successor policy Successor (strict) limits VP/PM appoint VP/PM same Defense appoint Defense same
(continued)
Lesotho 1 1 0 1 0.818 0 0
Liberia 0.860 0.860 0.560 0.640 0.460 1 0.680
Madagascar 0.380 0.380 0.260 0.920 0.620 0.700 0.420
Malawi 0.733 0.733 0.355 0.377 0.266 0.288 0.133
Mali 0.380 0.380 0.500 0.460 0.260 0.580 0.320
Mauritania 0.380 0.380 0.100 0.460 0.240 0.660 0.320
Mozambique 1 0.571 0.571 0.742 0.600 1 0.885
Namibia 1 1 1 1 0.857 1 0.761
Niger 0 0 0.140 0.580 0.300 0.600 0.280
Nigeria 0.560 0.500 0.420 0.600 0.460 0.660 0.380
Rep Congo 0.400 0.340 0.280 0.780 0.500 0.560 0.320
Rwanda 1 1 0.416 0.395 0.229 0.625 0.458
Sao Tome 1 1 0.571 0.771 0.285 0.828 0.514
Senegal 1 1 0.319 0.680 0.468 0.957 0.659
Sierra Leone 0.708 0.708 0.708 0.958 0.479 0.083 0.041
Somalia 0.176 0 0.235 0.970 0.617 1 0.529
South Africa 1 1 0.882 1 0.647 1 0.705
Sudan 0.440 0.440 0.240 0.860 0.420 0.660 0.340
One of the core arguments of this book is that autocratic regimes vary
drastically in the extent to which they are institutionalized. This chapter
lays the empirical groundwork for this claim by presenting detailed data on
regime institutionalization. In doing so, I also provide a discussion of how
we should define and measure autocratic regime institutionalization – a key
concept often used, but not well operationalized – in the literature.
I define regime institutionalization as the creation of rules and proce-
dures that structure the distribution of power and resources within the
ruling coalition. In an autocratic setting, regime institutionalization serves
to tie the leader’s hands. This chapter presents an original time-series
cross-sectional dataset measuring regime institutionalization in forty-six
countries in sub-Saharan Africa from 1960 to 2010. I discuss my coding
strategy in detail and present examples of each type of executive
constraint. I also summarize general trends and patterns in the data to
provide a broad perspective of what institutionalization looks like within
sub-Saharan Africa and how it differs across countries.
This chapter also compares this dataset against other commonly used
datasets of authoritarian institutions, such as regime typologies (Geddes,
Wright, and Frantz 2014). I show that regime typologies often do not reflect
the extent to which executive constraints are in place, and many countries
coded as party-based regimes are not very institutionalized at all. In addi-
tion, I also compare my measures of institutionalization against other
commonly used datasets of institutional strength – Polity (Marshall,
Gurr, and Jaggers 2016) and V-Dem (Coppedge et al. 2016).
Another important implication that emerges from this chapter is that
countries in sub-Saharan Africa vary widely in their level of institutiona-
lization, even during the decades of authoritarian rule following indepen-
dence. A small number of recent studies document that African countries
have become more institutionalized over time, especially after the end of
the Cold War (Posner and Young 2007). Others show that African party
93
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
4 . 1 co n c e p t u a li z i n g au t h o r i ta r i a n r e g i m e
i n s t it u t i o n a l iz a t i o n
Before I define regime institutionalization it is first helpful to note what I
mean by “regime.” I consider a regime as the set of rules, norms, and
institutions that govern the way in which the government is run. Most
relevant for this study, these rules determine the way in which leaders
enter and exit office. A regime can have multiple leaders, as long as these
leaders enter and exit office according to established rules and norms. I
consider an irregular leadership turnover – often due to the forced exit of a
leader and/or the entry of a leader via a coup – as signaling a break in the
regime (Goemans, Gleditsch, and Chiozza 2009).1
For instance, the Gambia experienced a regime change in 1994 when
the armed forces staged a coup and deposed Gawda Jawara – the leader
who had been in power since 1962. Ghana also experienced a regime
change in 1993 when it became classified as a democracy (more on how I
define democracy later) – though the leader did not change. Flight lieute-
nant Jerry Rawlings took power via a coup in Ghana in 1979. In the early
1990s, in response to increasing pressures to democratize, Rawlings lega-
lized political parties and allowed for multiparty elections to occur in
1992. Although Rawlings won the elections, and remained the president
of Ghana, these elections were considered free and fair, and importantly -
there has been party and leadership turnover since then. Ghana is there-
fore coded as having a regime break in 1993. Finally, Tanzania has
remained the same regime since independence, despite having multiple
1
This definition of an autocratic regime is similar to Svolik’s (2012) definition of a
“ruling-coalition spell.”
94
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.1 Conceptualizing Regime Institutionalization
leaders. Since independence was granted in 1961, Tanzania has had five
different presidents, but the same ruling coalition has remained in power,
and the ways in which the incumbent is selected has not drastically
changed.2
I define autocratic regime institutionalization as the creation of rules,
procedures, and hierarchies that structure the ways in which power and
resources are distributed within the ruling coalition. Examples of this
include establishing leadership succession procedures or creating rules
that govern elite promotion. When a leader institutionalizes the regime,
she takes actions that constrain her ability to take arbitrary actions in the
future. Autocratic regime institutionalization occurs when executive
constraints are created that tie the leader’s hands.
My conceptualization of institutionalization closely follows Huntington’s
(1968) definition of political institutionalization as “the process by
which organizations and procedures acquire value and stability” (12).
In particular, Huntington identifies several key features of institutiona-
lization that are most relevant for the survival of authoritarian regimes.
First, adaptability and the ability to outlive the founder is a key char-
acteristic of institutionalized organizations (13). Second, autonomy and
the ability of an organization to exist independently of particular actors
is a key feature of institutionalization. According to Huntington, an
organization that is merely an instrument of a leader lacks autonomy
and institutionalization (20).
This discussion is also related to Levitsky and Murillo’s (2009) discus-
sion of institutional strength.3 They argue that institutional strength
should be judged across two dimensions: enforcement and stability.
Strong institutions are those that political elites comply with in practice.
This conceptualization of institutional strength ties directly with my dis-
cussion of regime institutionalization. Regimes with institutionalized
2
Note that this conceptual discussion of “regime” does not affect the coding decisions
for this project because the measures of institutionalization I construct operate at the
country–year level, not at the regime level.
3
Much of the discussions of institutionalization has centered around the institutiona-
lization of political parties, rather than regimes. Huntington (1965), for instance,
defines party institutionalization as the process by which parties become established
and acquire value and stability. Levitsky (1998) likens institutionalization to the
entrenchment of the “rules of the game” that shape the expectations, payoffs, and
behavior of actors in his discussion of the Peronist party in Argentina (p. 80).
Panebianco (1988) argues that institutionalization transfers authority from the
leader to the party, and very few charismatic parties survive this transfer. Research
on party system institutionalization also describes strong party organizations as
having independent status and value, not subordinated to the interests of ambitious
leaders (Mainwaring and Scully 1995).
95
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
practices – those governed by stable rules that do not shift with changing
circumstances – are durable regimes that are likely to survive leadership
transitions precisely because they have rules that can outlast the circum-
stances in which they were initially created.4
In the context of an authoritarian regime, institutionalization has
several important implications. First, the creation of rules and procedures
depersonalizes the ways in which the regime operates by constraining the
autocratic leader’s ability to make arbitrary decisions in the future. This is
especially relevant in dictatorships, where power is often concentrated in
the hands of a single leader. When a leader establishes term limits, for
instance, she loses the ability to decide arbitrarily when and whether she
will step down from office. This kind of depersonalization can also hap-
pen through the creation of merit-based promotion within the executive.
Regimes with set rules, procedures, and hierarchies that regulate elite
promotion are more institutionalized compared with systems in which
a single incumbent can appoint or purge elites at any time without
constraint.
Second, institutionalization can empower other elites by establishing
hierarchical positions and rules regarding the appointment of elites to
important positions. A regime with a presidential cabinet in which elites
are appointed to important ministerial portfolios, such as defense or
finance, represents a regime in which power and resources are not entirely
concentrated within the hands of the leader. Such a regime is more
institutionalized compared with a presidential cabinet in which the incum-
bent holds all the important portfolios herself, and there are no estab-
lished rules or norms for the appointment of these positions.
However, it is important to note that institutionalization does not
always result in the empowerment of other elites. Some types of executive
constraints only limit the incumbent. Term limits on their own create
restrictions on the length of time that the incumbent can remain in office,
but do not specify who will replace the incumbent or how that replace-
ment process will occur.
Third, institutionalization separates the ruler from the regime.
Importantly, an institutionalized regime is one that can perpetuate its
own existence beyond the influence of an individual leader. A regime
that is not institutionalized is a government of one: the ruler. The ability
4
My conceptualization differs from Slater’s (2003) view that highly institutionalized
regimes do not necessarily have to contain institutions that constrain leaders, as long
as the institutions have “infrastructural power” – the ability to implement and
execute the leader’s demands. By contrast, I argue that the ability to keep the
executive in check is a necessary and central component of institutionalization.
96
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.1 Conceptualizing Regime Institutionalization
97
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
5
As a parallel example, a country might be stuck in an equilibrium where there are
high levels of corruption that operate in defiance of formal regulatory institutions,
but I would not consider corruption practices to be a set of institutions.
98
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.1 Conceptualizing Regime Institutionalization
6
Formal rules include state institutions (parties, legislatures, and courts) as well as
state-enforced rules (constitutions and legislation).
99
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
7
Recall that in the formal model presented in Chapter 2, positive levels of institutio-
nalization increase the likelihood that the autocrat would be deposed if fighting were
to occur in the second period.
100
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.2 Measuring Regime Institutionalization
101
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
8
See Diamond 2002; Gandhi 2008; Geddes 2003; Pzeworski 2000; Svolik 2012.
102
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.2 Measuring Regime Institutionalization
9
The CCM was created in 1977 after the former ruling party, the Tanganyika
African National Union (TANU), merged with the ruling party of Zanzibar, follow-
ing the merger of the two countries.
10
Using this coding scheme, the following countries and time periods are considered
democratic and therefore dropped from the sample: Benin after 1991, Cape Verde
after 1990, Ghana after 1993, Kenya after 1998, Madagascar after 1993, Malawi
after 1994, Mali after 1992, Mauritius for the whole period, Nigeria after 1999, Sao
Tome and Principe after 1991, Senegal after 2000, and Sierra Leone after 1998.
11
Only Ghana and Guinea gained independence a few years prior to 1960. Liberia and
Ethiopia were never colonized. Each of these three countries enter the dataset in 1960.
103
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
competition and institutions are taken into account. However, I do not base
my coding of authoritarian regimes on Polity scores for three main reasons.
First, the vast majority of countries in Africa do not meet the minimalist
definition of contestation of power through competitive elections, at least
not until the 1990s. The “less stringent” criterion is sufficient to identify the
authoritarian sample of cases in this region. Second, Polity uses criteria
about the quality of executive constraints and competitiveness to create an
aggregated score.12 Since I am examining constraints on executive power, I
do not want to eliminate cases by using a coding scheme that takes into
account the quality of institutions and constraints on the executive. Doing
so would risk eliminating cases of highly institutionalized authoritarian
regimes in my final sample. Third, Polity scores do not reflect party alter-
nation; therefore, a case such as Botswana can score exceptionally high
despite not having had party alternation in the executive.
12
One of the component variables of Polity scores is “XCONST,” which reflects the
extent to which there are institutionalized constraints on the decision-making
powers of the executive. A comparison of my measures of executive constraints
and XCONST is discussed later in this chapter.
104
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.2 Measuring Regime Institutionalization
105
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
106
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.2 Measuring Regime Institutionalization
13
Vice presidents and prime ministers are functional equivalents within this particular
context. All the countries in my sample either have one or the other. No cabinet has
both a vice president and a prime minister, although a small number of countries
have multiple vice presidents.
14
In fact, many presidents were extremely hesitant to assign the second-in-command
position to another party elite. Jose Eduardo dos Santos, the first president of
Angola, named himself as his own vice president for a number of years while he
was in power. Felix Houphouet-Boigny, the first president of the Ivory Coast,
created a vice-president position, but kept the post empty the entire time he was in
power. These two cases (and other similar instances) are coded as not having the
second-in-command position filled by another elite.
107
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
Notes: The leaders included in this table entered office through regular means, so coups and
irregular leader entries are excluded from this sample. The first president of each country is
not included in this sample because I am interested in the path of promotion after
independence was granted. Only leaders who were in office for three years or longer are
included in this sample. Leaders sometimes have multiple positions before entering office.
For example, Festus Mogae, who was the president of Botswana from 1998 to 2007 had
multiple cabinet positions from 1990 until 1997. He was the minister of finance from 1990
to 1997, minister of development and planning from 1990 to 1997, and vice president from
1992 to 1997. Each of these portfolios are recorded in this table.
their ascension to power, the most frequently held positions were the
minister of defense, vice president, or prime minister.
In addition, I document whether the person in the vice president or
prime minister position remains fairly constant over time, or whether the
person in this position is rotated very frequently. Accounting for cabinet
rotation rates is particularly important in the context of elite politics in
sub-Saharan Africa. African leaders routinely practiced the “revolving
108
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.2 Measuring Regime Institutionalization
Notes: The leaders included in this table entered office through irregular means – the modal
method of irregular leader entry is via a coup. The first president of each country is not included
in this sample because I am interested in the path of promotion after independence was granted.
Only leaders who were in office for three years or longer are included in this sample.
109
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
110
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.3 General Trends and Patterns
15
Because a number of the variables are highly correlated with each other (as I will
discuss below), I only include successor policy, term limits, VP/PM same, and
defense same in these graphs.
111
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
Number of constraints 0 1 2 3 4
illustrates the proportion of years for which each country had one, two,
three, or all four dimensions of institutionalization in place. Black sections
represent the proportion of years for which the country had all four
dimensions in place. Dark grey sections represent the proportion of
years for which the countries had three dimensions in place, and so on.
White sections represent the portion of years for which the country had no
dimensions in place.
112
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.3 General Trends and Patterns
Zimbabwe
16
Appendix Table 4.2 includes a summary of institutionalization scores by country.
113
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
114
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.3 General Trends and Patterns
1
.9
.8
.7
.6
.5
.4
.3
.2
.1
0
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
Year
115
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
Successor policy 1
Successor (strict) 0.855 1
Term limits 0.413 0.424 1
VP/PM appoint 0.187 0.238 0.292 1
VP/PM same 0.159 0.166 0.192 0.618 1
Defense appoint 0.209 0.221 0.186 0.203 0.122 1
Defense same 0.199 0.190 0.120 0.134 0.239 0.644 1
Note: Bolded numbers indicate two dimensions that are highly correlated (r > 0.6)
116
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.4 Regime Typologies
17
According to Google Scholar, Geddes (1999a) has been cited almost 300 times.
Geddes (1999b), an annual review article covering the same material as Geddes
(1999a), has been cited over 1,500 times.
18
The PRI was in power from 1929–2000 and the CCP has been in power since 1949.
19
Known as the Partido Nacional Revolucionario (PNR) at the time.
117
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
where power was handed over to the successor after the president’s term
ended (Buchenau 2006).
Mao was a similarly personalist founding leader. He promoted and
purged elite politicians at will and launched political campaigns, such as
the Hundred Flowers Movements and Cultural Revolution, during which
he arbitrarily purged officials who he deemed critical of the regime
(Meisner 1986). Over time, as Deng Xiaoping came into power, the CCP
eventually became an organization in which party promotion followed
established norms and procedures. In sum, many regimes change drastically
over time, and this is impossible to capture using a single time-invariant
regime category.20
Second, categorical distinctions between authoritarian regime types are
often insufficiently nuanced and obscure variation in institutional strength
within regime types. Take the category of dominant-party regimes. The
Soviet Union and China are coded as dominant-party regime types, and
they indeed were ruled by strong parties with organizational autonomy that
lasted through several leadership transitions. However, the category of
dominant-party regimes also includes cases such as the PDG in Guinea or
Communist Party of Kampuchea (CPK, also known as the Khmer Rouge)
in Cambodia. These parties, unlike the highly institutionalized communist
parties, were entirely concentrated around a single charismatic leader and
were not able to survive past the death and ousting of the leader.21
Third, regime typologies are composite indices that aggregate various
dimensions of leaders, institutions, and military structures into a single
category. As a result, it is difficult for researchers to identify the effects of
individual institutions (Pande and Udry 2006). Some regimes, for
instance, appear to be party-based, when in actuality the party is attached
to a strong and charismatic leader who merely exploits the party as a
personal vehicle to amplify his authority.
The Union Soudanaise – Rassemblement Democratique Africain (US-
RDA) under Modibo Keita in Mali, for instance, is coded as part of a
dominant-party regime. Yet national policies were determined entirely at
the discretion of Keita alone, and the US-RDA lacked institutionalized
rules and permanent structures. Eight years after taking power, Keita was
deposed in a coup and the party was banned. Although Keita, who was
20
It is possible for countries to be coded as different regime types over time, but most
countries are not coded as very many different types. The average country is coded
as two different types of regimes over an average time span of forty-four years, and
the average regime coding lasts about eighteen years.
21
The opposite scenario is sometimes true as well: not all cases coded as military or
personalist regimes are equally unconstrained.
118
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.4 Regime Typologies
119
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
22
I only focus on comparisons of pure regime types, leaving out hybrid regime types, such
as party-personal, party-military, military-personal, or triple hybrid types. These types
of hybrid regimes are excluded because it is not clear whether these regimes are highly
institutionalized or not. For instance, should a researcher expect a party-personal
regime to be highly institutionalized (due to the presence of some party attributes) or
not institutionalized (due to the presence of some personalist attributes)?
23
Formally, the measure is calculated as following:
X
years with institutionalization
percent years with institutionalization ¼ X
years in power
120
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.4 Regime Typologies
GWF case Regime type Success Success Term VP/PM VP/PM Defense Defense
rules (strict) limits appoint same appoint same
Party-based regimes and monarchies <50% <50% <50% <70% <50% <70% <50%
(institutionalized)
Angola 75–NA Party
Botswana 66–NA Party
Ethiopia 91–NA Party
Gambia 65–94 Party
Guinea 58–84 Party
G. Bissau 74–80 Party
Ivory Coast 60–99 Party
Kenya 63–02 Party
Madagascar 60–72 Party
Mali 60–68 Party
Mozambique 75–NA Party
Namibia 90–NA Party
Niger 60–74 Party
Rwanda 62–73 Party
Senegal 60–00 Party
Sierra Leone 68–92 Party
Tanzania 64–NA Party
Zambia 67–91 Party
Zambia 96–NA Party
Zimbabwe 80–NA Party
Ethiopia 89–74 Monarchy
Swaziland 68–NA Monarchy
Personalist and military regimes >50% >50% >50% >70% >50% >70% >50%
(not institutionalized)
Benin 60–63 Personal
Benin 63–65 Personal
Benin 72–90 Personal
Burkina Faso 60–66 Personal
Burkina Faso 66–80 Personal
Burkina Faso 82–87 Personal
Burkina Faso 87–NA Personal
Cameroon 83–NA Personal
CAR 03–NA Personal
CAR 60–65 Personal
CAR 79–81 Personal
Chad 82–90 Personal
Chad 90–NA Personal
Rep Congo 60–64 Personal
Rep Congo 97–NA Personal
DRC 60–97 Personal
DRC 97–NA Personal
Gambia 94–NA Personal
Ghana 81–00 Personal
Guinea 08–10 Personal
Guinea 84–09 Personal
G. Bissau 02–03 Personal
G. Bissau 80–99 Personal
Ivory Coast 00–NA Personal
Ivory Coast 99–00 Personal
121
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
GWF case Regime type Success Success Term VP/PM VP/PM Defense Defense
rules (strict) limits appoint same appoint same
Personalist and military regimes >50% >50% >50% >70% >50% >70% >50%
(not institutionalized)
Liberia 80–90 Personal
Liberia 97–03 Personal
Madagascar 09–NA Personal
Madagascar 75–93 Personal
Malawi 64–94 Personal
Mali 68–91 Personal
Mauritania 08–NA Personal
Mauritania 60–78 Personal
Mauritania 78–05 Personal
Niger 96–99 Personal
Sierra Leone 97–98 Personal
Somalia 69–91 Personal
Sudan 69–85 Personal
Sudan 89–NA Personal
Togo 60–63 Personal
Togo 63–NA Personal
Uganda 66–71 Personal
Uganda 71–79 Personal
Uganda 80–85 Personal
Uganda 86–NA Personal
Benin 65–67 Military
Benin 67–69 Military
Benin 69–70 Military
Burkina Faso 80–82 Military
Burundi 87–93 Military
Chad 75–79 Military
Ghana 66–69 Military
Ghana 72–79 Military
Madagascar 72–75 Military
Mauritania 05–07 Military
Nigeria 66–79 Military
Nigeria 83–93 Military
Sierra Leone 67–68 Military
Sudan 58–64 Military
Sudan 85–86 Military
Note: Shaded cells represent dimensions of party institutionalization that are in disagreement with the regime typology
coding. For example, for party-based regimes, “Second Appoint < 70%” means that the regimes listed in this column
are coded as party-based regimes, but have a second in command appointed less than 70 percent of the time.
For non party-based regimes, “Second Appoint >80%” means that the regimes listed in this column are NOT coded
as part of party-based regimes, but have a second in command appointed more than 80 percent of the time.
NA refers to regimes that were still in power as of 2010.
122
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.5 Comparisons with Other Existing Datasets
of Staff ousted the civilian government[…] . (Geddes, Wright, and Frantz 2012,
82)
24
Recall that the data goes up until 2010, though Compaore was in power until 2014.
123
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
0.75
Type of constraint
Succession rules
Term limits
0.50 Stable VP appoint
Stable Defense appoint
0.25
1 2 3 4 5 6 7
POLITY "XCONST" score
124
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.5 Comparisons with Other Existing Datasets
Proportion of observations with constraint (author’s data)
0.8
Type of constraint
0.6
Succession rules
Term limits
Stable VP appoint
Stable Defense appoint
0.4
0.2
coded by asking experts the following question: “To what extent is the
legislature and government agencies (e.g. controller general, general pro-
secutor, or ombudsman) capable of questioning, investigating, and exer-
cising oversight over the executive?”
Figure 4.4 provides a comparison of the legislative constraint scores
against my regime institutionalization measures. While the two vari-
ables appear generally correlated, some important differences arise.
For instance, a greater proportion of countries in my sample that
score a 0.5 on the V-Dem legislative constraint index have constitu-
tional succession rules in place compared with countries that score a
0.75 on the V-Dem legislative constrain index. This suggests that
simply having legislative constraints in place does not automatically
guarantee the existence of certain executive constraints, such as con-
stitutional succession rules.
Finally, I also conduct a comparison of my institutionalization mea-
sures against the “judicial constraints on the executive index” variable.
This question was coded by asking experts the following question: “To
what extent does the executive respect the constitution and comply with
court rulings, and to what extent is the judiciary able to act in an inde-
pendent fashion?”
125
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
0.6
Type of constraint
Succession rules
Term limits
Stable VP appoint
Stable Defense appoint
0.4
0.2
0 0.25 0.5 0.75 1
Level of judicial constraint on the executive
“Ordinal judicial constraints on the executive” variable
from V−DEM used. Five level ordered variable, with 0
being weakest constraints and 1 being strongest constraints.
4 . 6 co n c l u s i o n
This chapter presented an original dataset of autocratic regime insti-
tutionalization in all sub-Saharan regimes from 1960 to 2010. First I
discussed how I conceptualize and operationalize autocratic regime
institutionalization more generally, then I presented the dataset by
explaining my coding strategy and showing descriptive findings.
Finally I compared my dataset to other commonly used datasets of
authoritarian institutions, such as regime typologies, Polity scores,
and V-Dem measures.
The rest of the book will be primarily empirical and will use this dataset
to test my arguments about the causes and consequences of regime insti-
tutionalization. The next chapter will test the theoretical argument made
in Chapter 2 and show that there is a relationship between initial leader
126
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.6 Conclusion
Appendix
Appendix Table 4.1 List of countries and leaders included in this study
127
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
128
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.6 Conclusion
129
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4 How Should Institutionalization Be Measured?
130
Published online by Cambridge University Press
4.6 Conclusion
131
Published online by Cambridge University Press
Appendix Table 4.2 Summary of institutionalization scores by country
Term
Country Successor policy Successor (strict) limits VP/PM appoint VP/PM same Defense appoint Defense same
(continued)
Lesotho 1 1 0 1 0.818 0 0
Liberia 0.860 0.860 0.560 0.640 0.460 1 0.680
Madagascar 0.380 0.380 0.260 0.920 0.620 0.700 0.420
Malawi 0.733 0.733 0.355 0.377 0.266 0.288 0.133
Mali 0.380 0.380 0.500 0.460 0.260 0.580 0.320
Mauritania 0.380 0.380 0.100 0.460 0.240 0.660 0.320
134
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5.1 Reviewing the Theoretical Argument
1
It is helpful to remind the reader that we are interested in the leader’s relative level of
strength compared with elites. While the first strategy compares founders and successors
in the entire sample of leaders, the second strategy focuses on variation in leader strength
within the subset of leaders who took power immediately following independence.
135
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5 What Are the Causes of Regime Institutionalization?
The model showed that leaders who enter power initially strong vis-à-
vis other elites are less likely to institutionalize the regime. This is
because initially strong leaders do not have to worry about commitment
problems arising in the future bargaining round. Commitment problems
arise only when elites are very strong relative to the leader in the first
period because are likely to succeed in a rebellion if they were to try to
depose the leader. In such circumstances, leaders need to institutionalize
the regime in order to remain in power because doing so effectively
transfers access to the state to elites, therefore guaranteeing their future
rents.
If instead, the leader enters power relatively strong, then elites cannot
demand a large share of rents because they do not have a credible threat of
rebellion in the first period. In this case, the leader does not have to
institutionalize the regime in order to remain in power because she can
make a distributive offer that elites will accept in the first period of
the game.
In short, the model argues that levels of regime institutionalization are
determined primarily by initial leader strength. This chapter will test the
following hypothesis:
Hypothesis 1: Initially strong autocratic leaders are less likely to
institutionalize their regimes.
5 . 2 j u s t i f y i n g t h e m o d e l ’ s as s ump ti ons
Before turning to the empirical test, I will first provide some empirical
evidence of two key assumptions made in the model. The first key assump-
tion the model makes is that leaders institutionalize at the beginning of
their tenure. Recall that the model assumes that leaders make decisions
about institutionalization after observing the initial draw of power. If this
is the case, then we should expect to see institutionalization occur near the
beginning of leaders’ tenures.
I provide empirical evidence that the creation of constitutional succes-
sion procedures and term limits do indeed occur within the first few years of
leaders coming into power. In fact, about half of these rules are created
within the leader’s first year of entering power. To show this, I calculate the
number of years into the leader’s tenure constitutional succession rules or
term limits were created. For example, Agostinho Neto, the first leader of
Angola, implemented formal succession rules the first year he came to
power, in 1976. Aristides Pereira, who became the first president of Cape
Verde in 1975, created formal succession rules in 1981 – six years after
taking power.
136
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5.2 Justifying the Model’s Assumptions
I limit the time frame to rules created between 1960 and 1990,
since the end of the Cold War provided an exogenous shock to the
distribution of power of leaders, resulting in renewed incentives to
institutionalize (as this chapter will later discuss). I also focus primar-
ily on the creation of formal rules in this subsection because informal
power-sharing measures – the designation of vice presidents, prime
ministers, and defense ministers – are much more likely to have
interruptions or gaps. For example, Hamani Diori, the first president
of Niger, appointed a defense minister for about 60 percent of the
time he was in office. He began to appoint a defense minister six
years after the start of his term, but there was a one-year gap in 1971
in which a defense minister was not appointed. Similarly, Denis
Sassou Nguesso, who was president of the Republic of Congo from
1979 to 1992, appointed a defense minister from 1981 to 1984, and
again from 1991 to 1992.
From 1960 to 1990, I recorded all instances of “institutional
spells” for constitutional succession procedures and term limits. For
instance, succession procedures have existed within the Cameroon
constitution since 1960. These rules remained in place through
2010. Succession rules in Cameroon from 1960 to 2010 constitute
one institutional spell. For each institutional spell, I then recorded
when during the leader’s tenure that particular rule was created.
Returning to the Cameroon example, succession rules were created
in 1960, the first year of Ahmadou Ahidjo’s rule. That observation
would therefore score a 1 because the rule was created in the
first year of Ahidjo’s tenure.
Table 5.1 displays summary statistics of the number of years into the
autocrat’s tenure the rule was implemented.
The data shows that where formal executive constraints exist, they
are usually created within the first few years of the leader’s tenure.
From 1960 to 1990, there were fifty-three instances in which
Table 5.1 How long into their tenure do leaders create formal executive
constraints?
137
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5 What Are the Causes of Regime Institutionalization?
138
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5.2 Justifying the Model’s Assumptions
Constitution 83 42 51%
139
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5 What Are the Causes of Regime Institutionalization?
140
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5.3 Cross-sectional Design: Data and Measurement
141
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5 What Are the Causes of Regime Institutionalization?
142
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5.3 Cross-sectional Design: Data and Measurement
2
In fact, prior to independence, Moi cofounded the Kenya African Democratic Union
(KADU), a rival political party to KANU, which advocated for a federal system. He
also harbored rebel fighters on his farm during the Mau Mau Uprising that was
fought against the British in the 1950s (Widner 1992, 135).
143
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5 What Are the Causes of Regime Institutionalization?
“since the first stirrings of nationalist politics in 1946,” controlling the state
bureaucracy and National Assembly with “stern and unrelenting control”
(145–147). The government of the Ivory Coast under Houphouet-Boigny
was the government of “virtually one man” (145).
Conversely, in states in which active independence movements did not
emerge, preindependence parties existed to participate in elections that were
overseen by the colonial authorities. In such organizations, high-ranking
politicians were often perceived as part of the colonial bureaucracy. Such
politicians essentially inherited their positions of power after decolonization
but were not shielded by the same influence and mass following that
surrounded pro-independence leaders. I interpret these preindependence
statesmen who did not lead mass movements as weak autocrats compared
to independence leaders.
Ahmadou Ahidjo, the first president of Cameroon, is a prime example
of such a case. In the decades prior to independence, Ahidjo was encour-
aged to run for office by the French authorities, who viewed him as
a politician who would act in the interest of the colonial state. In fact,
the colonial administration even referred to the “Ahidjo option” – given
that independence seemed to be increasingly inevitable, the French
authorities preferred to have Ahidjo as head of state (Joseph 1978, 46).
Ahidjo did indeed take the office of the presidency upon independence,
but experienced very low levels of popular support. “In spite of the
efforts of the propagandists of the regime, President Ahidjo cannot be
considered a heroic figure from the nationalist past . . . it is a matter of
historical fact that he was initially “fabricated” and brought to power by
the colonial regime” (Joseph 1978, 76).3 As a result, upon taking power
Ahidjo needed to create official structures that would allow him to buy
the support of key elites – the lamidos (chiefs) who still controlled much
of the northern regions. He created a constitutional stipulation that
stated traditional chiefs would be protected, and filled key cabinet
appointments with elites that the lamidos favored. However, Ahidjo
made it clear that in exchange for these benefits, he expected the lamidos
to support his rule.
To sum, within the sample of founding presidents, there is
variation in terms of the strength of these leaders upon taking office.
Presidents such as Ahmadou Ahidjo who came to power by inheriting
their positions from the colonial state tended to lack the popularity
3
Joseph also notes that “in view of his uncertain and controversial origins, [Ahidjo] is
not strongly identified with any particular ethnic group,” making it even more
difficult for him to have a mass popular following (77).
144
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5.3 Cross-sectional Design: Data and Measurement
4
For my coding of independence leaders and preindependence statesmen, I rely on
Morrison (1989), Clodfelter (1992), and historical accounts.
145
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5 What Are the Causes of Regime Institutionalization?
5
To code this variable, I relied on Goemans, Gleditsch, and Chiozza 2009, Powell and
Thyne 2011, and various leaders biographies.
146
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5.4 Empirical Strategy and Findings
6
Formally, the measure is calculated as following:
X
years with institutionalization
percent years with institutionalization ¼ X
years in power
7
Details on this method are included in the Appendix at the end of this chapter.
147
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5 What Are the Causes of Regime Institutionalization?
148
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5.4 Empirical Strategy and Findings
8
I only exclude leaders who came into power via coups – I do not exclude leaders who
have a military background who did not come into power via coups.
149
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5 What Are the Causes of Regime Institutionalization?
Figure 5.2 Strong nationalist leaders versus presidents allied with outgoing colonial
powers
150
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5.4 Empirical Strategy and Findings
151
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5 What Are the Causes of Regime Institutionalization?
152
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5.4 Empirical Strategy and Findings
9
In all the models, I also control for the number of years in power.
10
This information is available from the Europa World Year Book (1960–2010).
Military commissions may have various names: “revolutionary council,” “national
redemption government.” However, as long as it is clearly a body composed only of
military elites whose authority supersedes the state executive, I consider this body
a type of military commission.
153
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5 What Are the Causes of Regime Institutionalization?
I find that the majority of coup leaders who do not appoint a vice
president or prime minister also do not create military commissions. Out
of ninety-one total leader–year units, military commissions are created
only 36 percent of the time. Out of twenty-nine leaders in this sample who
were in power for more than one year, only nine had commissions the
entire time.11
Importantly, for all of these observations, cabinets were never comple-
tely suspended. In other words, coup leaders who did decide to establish
military commissions kept the executive cabinets alongside the commis-
sions – although the military commissions appear to have taken prece-
dence over civilian institutions. However, coup leaders are more likely to
have removed key appointments within the cabinet – suggesting a lower
level of institutionalization along these dimensions.
11
The average size of a military commission is sixteen members.
154
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5.4 Empirical Strategy and Findings
155
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5 What Are the Causes of Regime Institutionalization?
armed rivals within the government by the time they take power.12
Moreover, the elites who take control of the regime after the conflict ends
tend to be the military leaders who were responsible for winning the
independence wars; in these cases, civilian elites either do not exist or are
irrelevant. These leaders tend to be extremely popular and influential,
similar to strong nationalist figures that emerge out of peaceful indepen-
dence movements. Levitsky and Way (2012) note that armed conflict
produces revolutionary leaders with “extreme legitimacy and unquestioned
authority.” It is precisely this “unquestioned authority” that allows leaders
that emerge out of independence wars to be strong relative to other elites.
Based on this logic, we would therefore expect these leaders to be less likely
to institutionalize their regimes.
However, unlike nationalist figures or founding presidents that came
into power after peaceful independence movements, former rebel-group
leaders have a distinct weakness – the existence of other military elites
who have the capacity to overthrow them. Unlike coup leaders, who tend
to act with the assistance of very few other actors, independence wars
require extensive rebel groups that are led by multiple military actors.
Leaders of rebel-group regimes need to ensure that they retain the sup-
port of military leaders who participated in the independence wars and
do so by institutionalizing along dimensions particularly relevant for
coercive actors: the defense minister cabinet post (Meng and Paine
2020).
I argue that leaders of regimes that came into power by fighting
independence wars should be more likely to institutionalize their regime
along two particular dimensions: the appointment of a defense minister
and the appointment of a stable defense minister. I test this argument by
creating a dummy variable, “rebel group,” that takes a value of 1 if the
regime came into power by fighting an independence war. For my coding
of rebel-group parties and independence wars, I refer to Clodfelter
(1992) and the UCDP/PRIO Armed Conflict Dataset (Gledditsch et al.
2002). I refer to the UCDP definition of conflict as “a contested incom-
patibility that concerns government and/or territory where the use of
armed force between two parties, of which at least one is the government
of a state, results in at least 25 battle-related deaths” (Gledditsch et al.
2002). Countries with rebel-group governments include Angola, Cape
12
Although in some of these countries, there are multiple rebel-groups that fought for
independence. Angola, for instance, had UNITA (National Union for the Total
Independence of Angola) in addition to the MPLA and Mozambique had
REMANO (Mozambican National Resistance) in addition to FRELIMO. These
other rebel-groups, however, did not take office or have any say in the government
after independence was granted.
156
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5.5 Differences-in-differences Design
5 . 5 di f f e r e n ce s - i n- d i f f er e n c e s d e s i g n : the e n d
of the cold war
I also use the end of the Cold War as an exogenous shock to test
my argument about institutionalization and leader strength using
a differences-in-differences approach. While the regressions reported
157
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5 What Are the Causes of Regime Institutionalization?
158
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5.5 Differences-in-differences Design
159
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5 What Are the Causes of Regime Institutionalization?
Figure 5.5 Were leaders with access to oil revenues less likely to institutionalize after the end
of the Cold War?
13
USAID, https://explorer.usaid.gov/.
14
To the best of my knowledge reliable aid data from the Soviet Union is not available.
160
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5.6 Conclusion
The first striking finding is that virtually every country within sub-
Saharan Africa has received foreign aid from the United States during
the Cold War period, and these countries continue to receive foreign aid
from the United States. The second striking finding is that aid flows from
the United States have actually increased since the end of the Cold War,
and this is true for all but two countries in my sample.15 On average, for
countries that received more aid following the end of the Cold War, the
rate of foreign aid received increased by 30 percent. To sum, the United
States provided foreign aid to all countries in sub-Saharan Africa during
the Cold War and continues to provide aid to these countries. Due to the
steady flow of aid from the United States, we cannot use a shock in access
to foreign aid as a proxy for a shift in the distribution of power because an
abrupt shock did not occur.
5.6 conclusion
This chapter provided empirical evidence of the theoretical claims made in
Chapter 2 that there is a systematic relationship between initial leader
strength and levels of regime institutionalization. Using my dataset of
regime institutionalization and several proxies of leader strength based
on the way in which leaders came to power, I tested my theoretical
argument using a cross-sectional approach and a differences-in-
differences approach. I showed that founding presidents, nationalist lea-
ders, and postcoup leaders (all of whom can be interpreted as initially
strong) were less likely to institutionalize their regimes. I also showed that
following the end of the Cold War, leaders with access to oil rents were
less vulnerable in facing pressures to institutionalize.
This chapter treated regime institutionalization as the main depen-
dent variable and addressed the question of under what conditions
leaders will institutionalize. By contrast, the next two chapters will
treat regime institutionalization as the main independent variable and
ask the question of whether institutionalized regimes actually perform
better on a number of key outcomes. We now turn to examining the
effects of regime institutionalization.
15
Togo and Mauritius are the only two countries for which the total amount of aid
received from 1991 to 2010 was lower compared with total amount of aid received
from 1960 to 1990. However, both of these countries continue to receive substantial
foreign aid from the United States.
161
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
5 What Are the Causes of Regime Institutionalization?
162
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.005 Published online by Cambridge University Press
Appendix Table 5.1 Founding leaders
First president −0.054** −0.152 −0.287** −0.240** −0.092 −0.075 −0.106 −0.103
(0.025) (0.158) (0.140) (0.093) (0.110) (0.112) (0.136) (0.110)
Military −0.108*** −0.434*** −0.351** −0.224* 0.049 0.001 −0.398** −0.250**
(0.024) (0.151) (0.156) (0.116) (0.193) (0.159) (0.160) (0.119)
Party 0.074*** 0.330* 0.063 0.120 −0.024 −0.069 −0.027 0.041
(0.025) (0.163) (0.199) (0.143) (0.140) (0.125) (0.143) (0.130)
Years in power 0.001 0.011 0.013* −0.004 −0.006 0.003 0.007 0.010
Notes: Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses. The sample only includes observations from 1960 to 1991 and coup leaders are excluded for comparability
since first presidents were never coup leaders. All models use OLS. The dependent variable for model 1 is a continuous score that was created by the IRT model. The dependent
variable for models 2–8 are the disaggregated dimensions of institutionalization. All the dependent variables are the percentage of years in which the leader institutionalized.
Significance levels: ***p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10
Appendix Table 5.2 Strong nationalist leaders
Nationalist leaders −0.050** −0.200 −0.229* −0.094 −0.306* −0.240* 0.056 −0.022
(0.020) (0.124) (0.125) (0.071) (0.154) (0.132) (0.140) (0.104)
Party 0.057** 0.241 −0.083 0.142 −0.037 0.019 0.064 0.132
(0.025) (0.159) (0.198) (0.120) (0.149) (0.114) (0.199) (0.163)
Years in power 0.001 0.010 0.013* −0.002 −0.005 0.001 0.001 0.004
(0.002) (0.009) (0.006) (0.003) (0.009) (0.007) (0.008) (0.006)
GDP per capita 0.051*** 0.194*** 0.017 0.146* 0.113* 0.127** 0.032 −0.006
(0.016) (0.061) (0.066) (0.078) (0.060) (0.052) (0.082) (0.037)
Ethnic fractionalization −0.043 0.015 0.142 −0.364 0.235 0.067 −0.163 −0.015
(0.077) (0.447) (0.406) (0.370) (0.404) (0.298) (0.470) (0.320)
Constant 0.028 −1.618*** −1.323** 0.018 −0.227 −0.474 −0.925 −0.828*
(0.101) (0.563) (0.607) (0.424) (0.600) (0.501) (0.667) (0.453)
Observations 41 41 41 41 41 41 41 41
R-squared 0.465 0.384 0.262 0.270 0.245 0.265 0.214 0.301
Nationalist leaders −0.058** −0.275** −0.218* −0.064 −0.263 −0.218 −0.011 −0.092
(0.022) (0.128) (0.125) (0.067) (0.155) (0.132) (0.126) (0.093)
Participation in war 0.064* 0.499* 0.060 −0.072 −0.164 −0.020 0.071 0.140
(0.035) (0.290) (0.492) (0.160) (0.257) (0.222) (0.249) (0.264)
Party 0.018 0.034 0.012 0.144 −0.082 −0.082 −0.131 −0.082
(0.039) (0.189) (0.289) (0.219) (0.174) (0.138) (0.166) (0.143)
Years in power 0.002 0.016* 0.010 −0.004 −0.007 0.001 0.009 0.012***
(0.002) (0.009) (0.008) (0.006) (0.009) (0.007) (0.007) (0.004)
Ethnic fractionalization −0.023 0.128 0.070 −0.389 0.235 0.095 0.006 0.155
(0.078) (0.450) (0.441) (0.307) (0.406) (0.274) (0.502) (0.265)
Constant 0.018 −1.936** −1.541* 0.176 0.150 −0.193 −0.805 −0.750*
(0.131) (0.718) (0.861) (0.488) (0.521) (0.388) (0.593) (0.370)
Observations 41 41 41 41 41 41 41 41
R-squared 0.513 0.473 0.283 0.404 0.429 0.458 0.393 0.554
Notes: Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses. Sample includes only observations from 1960–1991 and only includes leaders from the first regime.
Coup leader −0.08*** −0.31*** −0.23*** −0.15** −0.20** −0.18*** −0.19*** −0.16***
(0.020) (0.080) (0.080) (0.070) (0.080) (0.064) (0.061) (0.045)
Military (non-coup) −0.026 −0.198** −0.106 0.020 0.045 0.079 −0.133 −0.046
(0.025) (0.091) (0.088) (0.111) (0.091) (0.072) (0.093) (0.068)
Party −0.005 0.103 0.010 −0.045 −0.144 −0.157 −0.157 −0.152*
(0.034) (0.131) (0.162) (0.135) (0.115) (0.097) (0.146) (0.086)
Years in power 0.001 0.010** 0.007* −0.004 −0.005 0.004 −0.003 0.006**
(0.001) (0.004) (0.004) (0.005) (0.004) (0.003) (0.004) (0.002)
Ethnic fractionalization 0.003 0.025 0.027 −0.018 −0.012 0.038 −0.091 0.001
(0.059) (0.254) (0.269) (0.174) (0.123) (0.092) (0.195) (0.129)
Constant 0.313*** 0.236 0.139 −0.034 0.592** 0.104 −0.104 −0.261
(0.087) (0.349) (0.366) (0.283) (0.273) (0.233) (0.418) (0.284)
Observations 158 158 158 158 158 158 158 158
R-squared 0.210 0.224 0.136 0.117 0.136 0.195 0.144 0.166
Coup leader −0.06*** −0.29*** −0.17** −0.03 −0.25*** −0.20*** −0.18** −0.18***
(0.014) (0.073) (0.073) (0.068) (0.085) (0.064) (0.079) (0.052)
Military (non-coup) −0.062*** −0.347*** −0.196* −0.058 0.059 0.058 −0.313* −0.183*
(0.020) (0.099) (0.108) (0.100) (0.158) (0.138) (0.157) (0.095)
Party 0.081*** 0.429*** 0.206 0.155 0.049 −0.002 −0.054 0.011
(0.025) (0.116) (0.160) (0.118) (0.121) (0.109) (0.104) (0.095)
Years in power −0.000 0.004 0.004 −0.006 −0.012** −0.002 −0.005 0.003
(0.001) (0.007) (0.005) (0.004) (0.006) (0.004) (0.005) (0.004)
Ethnic fractionalization −0.006 −0.006 0.058 −0.040 0.109 0.006 −0.037 −0.020
(0.038) (0.227) (0.244) (0.171) (0.240) (0.160) (0.271) (0.148)
Constant 0.231*** −0.323 −0.224 −0.068 0.478 0.062 −0.298 −0.328
(0.069) (0.353) (0.311) (0.279) (0.404) (0.299) (0.439) (0.278)
Observations 107 107 107 107 107 107 107 107
R-squared 0.375 0.385 0.158 0.145 0.162 0.176 0.153 0.192
Coup leader −0.068** −0.249** −0.211* −0.196 −0.009 −0.067 −0.152 −0.123
(0.028) (0.111) (0.112) (0.131) (0.081) (0.095) (0.104) (0.085)
Military (non−coup) −0.040 −0.225* −0.191 −0.066 0.017 0.033 0.048 −0.035
(0.036) (0.114) (0.117) (0.173) (0.056) (0.076) (0.097) (0.100)
Party −0.059 −0.005 0.025 −0.275 −0.276 −0.248** −0.208 −0.334***
(0.048) (0.183) (0.182) (0.204) (0.196) (0.113) (0.229) (0.120)
Years in power 0.004* 0.018** 0.017** −0.000 −0.000 0.013** 0.000 0.015**
(0.002) (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) (0.007) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006)
Ethnic fractionalization 0.040 0.086 0.074 0.126 0.071 0.137 0.004 0.152
(0.080) (0.274) (0.274) (0.335) (0.124) (0.101) (0.162) (0.150)
Constant 0.529*** 1.233** 1.184** 0.366 1.203*** 0.369 0.706 0.054
(0.118) (0.472) (0.494) (0.471) (0.327) (0.283) (0.424) (0.284)
Observations 80 80 80 80 80 80 80 80
R-squared 0.234 0.272 0.199 0.120 0.136 0.231 0.100 0.236
High rank −0.034 −0.167 −0.168 −0.085 −0.012 −0.036 0.166* 0.085*
(0.022) (0.106) (0.109) (0.077) (0.097) (0.065) (0.084) (0.049)
Yrs in power 0.003** 0.013** 0.013** 0.001 −0.001 0.009** −0.011** 0.004
(0.001) (0.005) (0.005) (0.006) (0.006) (0.004) (0.004) (0.003)
Constant 0.360*** 0.190*** 0.182** 0.237*** 0.586*** 0.169*** 0.585*** 0.148**
(0.017) (0.063) (0.065) (0.063) (0.091) (0.044) (0.077) (0.054)
Observations 69 69 69 69 69 69 69 69
Notes: Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses. This sample includes only coup leaders. The dependent variable is the percentage of years during which
the leader had a constitution in place. For the independent variable, “high rank” refers to coup leaders with a “general” ranking. OLS used. Significance levels: *** p < 0.01,
** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10
Appendix Table 5.8 High-ranking coup leaders only
High-rank coup leader −0.087*** −0.355*** −0.288*** −0.150* −0.165 −0.183** −0.088 −0.127**
(0.024) (0.104) (0.098) (0.075) (0.104) (0.084) (0.077) (0.057)
Military (non−coup) −0.004 −0.119 −0.053 0.061 0.104 0.126* −0.067 0.001
(0.024) (0.086) (0.084) (0.105) (0.092) (0.071) (0.089) (0.064)
Party −0.003 0.108 0.011 −0.041 −0.135 −0.153 −0.144 −0.145
(0.036) (0.137) (0.164) (0.137) (0.115) (0.094) (0.150) (0.090)
Years in power 0.002 0.011*** 0.009* −0.004 −0.004 0.005 −0.003 0.006***
Notes: Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses. This sample includes the entire time period. “High-rank coup leader” is a dummy variable that takes
a value of 1 only if the coup leader held the rank of general at the time of the coup; all other observations (including low-ranking coup leaders) are coded as a 0 for this variable.
All models use OLS. The dependent variable for model 1 is a continuous score that was created by the IRT model. The dependent variable for models 2–8 is the disaggregated
Rebel group 0.066* 0.222* 0.153 0.125 −0.051 −0.005 0.343*** 0.352***
(0.034) (0.114) (0.098) (0.132) (0.089) (0.094) (0.066) (0.067)
Military −0.050*** −0.221*** −0.146** −0.082 −0.102 −0.072 −0.130* −0.070
(0.016) (0.068) (0.063) (0.062) (0.072) (0.063) (0.066) (0.049)
Party −0.013 0.075 −0.008 −0.060 −0.117 −0.140 −0.217 −0.212***
(0.038) (0.136) (0.172) (0.153) (0.132) (0.106) (0.135) (0.077)
Years in power 0.001 0.010** 0.007 −0.005 −0.006 0.003 −0.003 0.005*
Notes: Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses. This sample includes the entire time period. All models use OLS. The dependent variable for model 1 is
a continuous score that was created by the IRT model. The dependent variable for models 2–8 is the disaggregated dimensions of institutionalization. All the dependent
Rebel group 0.036 0.305** −0.021 −0.133 −0.202 −0.109 0.333** 0.349**
(0.032) (0.134) (0.234) (0.141) (0.138) (0.102) (0.158) (0.145)
Military −0.067*** −0.290*** −0.203*** −0.109 −0.204** −0.145* −0.218** −0.160***
(0.016) (0.069) (0.070) (0.067) (0.090) (0.077) (0.090) (0.051)
Party 0.071** 0.336** 0.216 0.194 0.151 0.064 −0.167 −0.096
(0.032) (0.131) (0.180) (0.148) (0.150) (0.125) (0.114) (0.091)
Years in power 0.001 0.010 0.006 −0.006 −0.014** −0.003 0.001 0.008**
(0.001) (0.006) (0.005) (0.004) (0.007) (0.005) (0.005) (0.003)
Notes: Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses. This sample includes observations from 1960 to 1991. All models use OLS. The dependent variable for
model 1 is a continuous score that was created by the IRT model. The dependent variable for models 2–8 is the disaggregated dimensions of institutionalization. All the
Rebel group 0.038 0.108 0.187* 0.082 −0.027 −0.004 0.338*** 0.284***
(0.026) (0.098) (0.101) (0.149) (0.092) (0.112) (0.096) (0.072)
Military −0.049* −0.219** −0.168* −0.122 −0.002 −0.022 −0.000 −0.032
(0.025) (0.095) (0.099) (0.123) (0.051) (0.058) (0.105) (0.080)
Party −0.067 −0.023 −0.005 −0.295 −0.273 −0.253** −0.272 −0.384***
(0.047) (0.185) (0.182) (0.204) (0.195) (0.111) (0.201) (0.104)
Years in power 0.003 0.016* 0.014 −0.003 −0.000 0.012** −0.008 0.009
Notes: Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses. This sample includes observations from 1992 to 2010. All models use OLS. The dependent variable for
model 1 is a continuous score that was created by the IRT model. The dependent variable for models 2–8 is the disaggregated dimensions of institutionalization. All the
Cold War −0.112*** −1.888*** −2.721*** −3.684*** −2.856*** −1.067*** −1.873*** −0.844***
(0.014) (0.536) (0.539) (0.571) (0.508) (0.245) (0.411) (0.233)
Constant 0.646*** 2.581*** 3.415*** 4.378*** 4.107*** 3.631*** 4.512*** 1.537***
(0.014) (0.536) (0.539) (0.571) (0.479) (0.245) (0.411) (0.233)
Observations 1,751 1,198 1,280 1,517 1,468 1,664 1,477 1,660
Country FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Notes: Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses. For models 2–8, pseudo R-square statistics are reported. I retained the panel structure of the data for these
regressions. Model 1 uses OLS and models 2–8 are logit models. The dependent variable for models 2–8 is a dummy that takes a value of 1 if that dimension of
institutionalization was in place for that year. The dependent variable for model 1 is a continuous score that was created by the IRT model. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, *
p < 0.10
Appendix Table 5.13 Differences-in-differences test
Post-Cold War 0.121*** 2.640*** 4.757*** 3.913*** 3.457*** 1.302*** 2.301*** 0.855***
(0.020) (0.893) (0.994) (0.810) (0.634) (0.296) (0.594) (0.277)
Oil −0.013 −0.439 −0.286 0.367 1.205*** 1.189*** 0.077 0.601**
(0.013) (0.305) (0.240) (0.990) (0.129) (0.273) (0.228) (0.266)
Oil*post-Cold War −0.027 −1.848* −3.57*** −0.512 −1.578 −0.643 −1.038 −0.029
Constant 0.390*** −0.126 −0.44*** −3.596*** 0.134* −1.753*** 0.148 −1.619***
(0.011) (0.230) (0.064) (0.747) (0.074) (0.212) (0.160) (0.184)
Notes: Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses. Model 1 uses OLS and models 2–8 are logit models. The dependent variable for models 2–8 is a dummy
that takes a value of 1 if that dimension of institutionalization was in place for that year. The dependent variable for model 1 is a continuous score that was created by the
IRT model. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10
6
What Are the Consequences of Institutionalization
on Autocratic Stability?
This book has so far been primarily been concerned with explaining the
emergence of institutionalized autocratic rule. We now return to the first
central puzzle presented at the very onset of Chapter 1: What explains
differences in authoritarian regime stability? Why is it that some dictator-
ships are subject to constant coup attempts and regime change, while
others withstand multiple peaceful leadership transitions and remain
stable over long periods of time?
The next two chapters will examine the effects of institutionalization on
regime durability. Do institutionalized regimes actually perform better on
a number of key outcomes, such as leader longevity, the prevention of coups,
and the promotion of peaceful leadership succession? This chapter will focus
on estimating the effects of regime institutionalization on key leader out-
comes: the length of leader tenure and susceptibility to coups attempts. The
next chapter will focus on estimating the effects of institutionalization on key
regime outcomes: leadership succession and regime survival.
This chapter will show that leaders who institutionalize their regimes
tend to remain in office for longer periods of time and face fewer coup
attempts. The next chapter will demonstrate that institutionalized regimes
are significantly more likely to undergo peaceful leadership transitions.
Together these two chapters demonstrate that executive constraints are
not simply empty parchment rules. Institutionalization does indeed have
consequences for regime stability.
However, estimating the effects of endogenously created institutions is not
as straightforward as it may seem. In determining the effects of institutions,
these chapters will take into consideration the subject of the first half of this
book – the fact that leaders choose whether to institutionalize based on
underlying threats to their rule. Since constitutional rules and cabinet
appointments are not randomly assigned across regimes, we must consider
the types of leaders who choose to create these institutions when examining
whether such rules have an independent effect on regime durability.
186
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6.1 Are Rules Followed in Dictatorships?
187
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6 Consequences on Autocratic Stability
188
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6.2 Do Institutions Promote Regime Stability?
6 . 2 e m p i r i cal d i s ag re em en t : do i ns t i t ut i ons
promote regime s tabili ty?
Despite the general consensus that institutionalized forms of dictatorship
tend to be more stable, the empirical record of the relationship between
institutions and regime stability has been surprisingly mixed. In a seminal
study, Geddes (1999a) finds that single-party regimes remain in power for
longer periods of time compared to personalist regimes. Military regimes,
which tend to have weak or no civilian institutions, are less durable
compared with personalist regimes. This study catalyzed the idea that
institutionalized forms of authoritarianism tend to be most durable.
Geddes’ empirical analysis was replicated by Brownlee (2007), who
found similar effects. Since then, many scholars have made the theoretical
argument that institutions, such as parties and legislatures, can prolong
the lifespan of authoritarian regimes (Boix and Svolik 2013; Gandhi 2008;
Geddes, Wright, and Frantz 2018; Gandhi and Przeworski 2007;
Magaloni 2008; Svolik 2009).
However, a number of subsequent studies have since challenged this
initial finding. Smith (2005), for instance, shows that the significant effect
of single-party regimes is driven primarily by two outliers: Mexico and the
Soviet Union. He replicates Geddes’ original analysis, producing similar
results, but then demonstrates that when the two longest-living regimes
are dropped from the analysis, single-party regimes are no longer signifi-
cantly more durable compared with personalist regimes.
A small number of studies have also pointed out that autocratic leaders
endogenously respond to threats with “appropriate” degrees of institutiona-
lization, therefore we should not expect to see a relationship between institu-
tions and stability. Gandhi (2008), for instance, finds that leaders with ruling
parties do not tend to survive in office longer compared with those without
parties, “suggesting that most authoritarian incumbents are able to perceive
with some accuracy the threats germinating within society and to respond
with the appropriate degree of institutionalization” (176–177). According to
this study, leaders institutionalize optimally, and therefore there should be no
observable effect between institutions and stability.
Boix and Svolik (2013) also present a study in which institutional choice
is endogenous. They argue that power-sharing institutions, such as parties
or legislatures, can be established only when backed by a credible threat of
elite rebellion. However, despite the fact that their theory endogenizes the
creation of institutions, two observable implications of their study are that
regimes with institutions should be longer lived and experience fewer
coups. Using data on the existence of parties and legislatures in autocra-
cies, they find empirical support for their arguments.
189
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6 Consequences on Autocratic Stability
190
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6.3 Problems with Existing Approaches
Strong No
leader Stable regime
institutionalization
No Unstable
Institutionalization regime
Weak
leader
Institutionalization Stable regime
1
It is important to note that it is possible for strong leaders to institutionalize, even
though this would be out-of-equilibrium behavior according to the model. I would
expect institutionalized regimes, even if the leader was initially strong, to be more
stable due to the fact that the creation of constitutional rules and cabinet appoint-
ments creates mechanisms for credible power-sharing and patronage distribution.
191
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6 Consequences on Autocratic Stability
6.4.1 Data
The outcome variable of interest in this chapter is autocratic stability,
particularly with respect to leader outcomes.2 Leader stability will be
measured via two dependent variables: the length of a leader’s tenure
and the number of coup attempts a leader faces during her tenure.
“Years in power” is a variable that counts the number of years a leader
remained in power. “Coup attempts” records the percent of the number of
office years for which a leader faced coup attempts. This variable is
presented as a percent, rather than a count of the number of coup attempts
a leader faced in order to take into account the fact that various leaders
remained in office for different lengths of time.
There are two primary independent variables of interest: leader
strength and regime institutionalization. Leader strength will be proxied
using two measurement strategies from Chapter 5: founders versus suc-
cessors and coup leaders versus noncoup leaders. “Founder” is a dummy
variable that takes a value of 1 if the leader was the first leader of the
country after independence and 0 otherwise. As Chapter 5 argued, found-
ing leaders tended to enjoy special legitimacy and mass support, and this
was especially true for these leaders who rose to power in the immediate
aftermath of independence. Founding presidents can therefore be inter-
preted as stronger leaders compared with subsequent presidents. “Coup
2
The next chapter will examine the effect of institutionalization on leadership succes-
sion and regime survival.
192
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6.4 Estimating Effects of Endogenous Institutions
3
The reader may recall that in Chapter 5 I presented a third strategy for measuring
leader strength by looking at the subset of founding leaders, and comparing strong
nationalist leaders against those who were close allies of the colonial state. Since this
strategy requires looking within the subset of independence regimes, the number of
observations available for this strategy are much more limited. I therefore exclude
this strategy from the empirical tests in this chapter.
4
Since the strict and weak version of the successor rule are highly correlated, I exclude
the “strict successor” variable from the analysis in this chapter. Since “VP/PM
appoint” and “VP/PM same” as well as “defense appoint” and “defense same” are
also highly correlated, I also exclude the “VP/PM appoint” and “defense appoint”
variables from the analysis in this chapter. Since term limits were generally not
implemented until after the 1990s and are not frequently adhered to, I exclude it
from the analysis in this chapter.
193
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6 Consequences on Autocratic Stability
194
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6.5 Empirical Analysis and Findings
with a weak leader. For x1 =0, the subset of weak leaders (recall that x1 is
a dummy variable representing leader strength or weakness), the equation
reduces to the following:
Y ¼ α þ β2 x2 þ ε
I hypothesize that when the leader is weak, institutionalization should
have a positive and significant effect on leader outcomes. Since x2 denotes
levels of regime institutionalization, we should expect β2 to be signifi-
cantly different than zero.5
For x1 =1, the subset of strong leaders, the equation reduces to the
following:
Y ¼ α þ β1 þ ðβ2 þ β3 Þx2 þ ε
I hypothesize that when the leader is strong, there should be no effect of
institutionalization on leader stability. Since x2 denotes levels of regime
institutionalization, then the coefficients ðβ2 þ β3 Þ should not be signifi-
cantly different from 0.
To summarize, if my theory is correct, then we should expect β2 to be
significantly different from 0 and ðβ2 þ β3 Þ not to be significantly different
from 0.
6 . 5 e m p i r i c a l ana l y s i s a n d fin d i n g s
I use two different proxies of leader strength to condition the differential
effects of institutionalization on length of leader tenure and vulnerability to
coups: (1) founding leaders versus subsequent leaders and (2) coup leaders
versus noncoup leaders. I will present results using both of these strategies
separately.
5
Whether β2 should be greater than or less than 0 depends on the outcome we are
examining. A lower number of coup attempts denotes a more stable regime, so for
that analysis, we should expect β2 < 0: Longer leader tenure denotes a more stable
regime, so for that analysis, we should expect β2 > 0.
195
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6 Consequences on Autocratic Stability
6
Recall that (ß2) is the relevant coefficient for weak leaders. These rows are
highlighted in Appendix Table 6.3.
7
Recall that the effect of institutionalization for strong leaders is denoted by ß2 + ß3.
This row is highlighted in Appendix Table 6.3.
196
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6.5 Empirical Analysis and Findings
Figure 6.3 What is the effect of institutionalization on leader tenure (coup leaders)?
Note: 90 percent confidence intervals reported. Proxy for leader strength is coup leaders
versus noncoup leaders. The dependent variable is the number of years for which a leader
was in power. Our hypothesis predicts a positive relationship between institutionalization
and leader tenure for weak leaders.
error for the leader strength variable. It could be the case that founding
leaders does not serve as a perfect proxy for initial leader strength. On other
hand, it is also possible that having a leadership succession policy in place
does indeed lengthen the tenure of all leaders, even those who enter office
initially strong. Chapter 7 provides an extensive discussion of leadership
succession.
I also analyze the relationship between institutionalization and leader
tenure using coup leaders as a proxy for initially strong leaders. The
results are illustrated in Figure 6.3 and the full regression results are
reported in Appendix Table 6.4. Once again, I find that when initially
weak leaders (noncoup leaders) institutionalize, they tend to remain in
office for longer periods of time, and this finding is statistically significant
along cabinet stability dimensions.
For initially strong leaders (coup leaders), institutionalization – particu-
larly the stable appointment of VP/PMs and the creation of succession
policies – does appear to have effects on leader tenure. It is possible that
coup leaders, while having consolidated authority over the coercive appara-
tus of the regime, have vulnerability along other nonmilitary dimensions, and
therefore benefit from the stabilizing effect of institutionalization along such
dimensions. Coup leaders who institutionalize along civilian dimensions may
197
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6 Consequences on Autocratic Stability
experience more stable rule, even if they took power having already con-
solidated power along coercive dimensions.
Figure 6.4 What is the effect of institutionalization on the frequency of coup attempts?
Note: 90 percent confidence intervals reported. Proxy for leader strength is founders versus
subsequence leaders. The dependent variable is the percentage of years for which a leader
faces a coup attempt. Our hypothesis predicts a negative relationship between
institutionalization and coup attempts for weak leaders.
198
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6.6 Conclusion
6.6 conclusion
This chapter examined the effect of institutionalization on autocratic sta-
bility, particularly the length of leader tenure and frequency of coup threats.
I argued that in estimating the effect of institutionalization on these out-
comes we need to take into account the fact that initially strong and initially
weak leaders make different institutionalization decisions, depending on
threats to their rule. Weak leaders institutionalize in order to alleviate
threats to their rule, and therefore we should expect to see an effect of
institutionalization on stability for initially weak leaders. Initially strong
leaders are able to remain in power whether they institutionalize or not, so
199
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6 Consequences on Autocratic Stability
Appendix
Note: Dependent variable is a count variable of the number of years the leader was in power.
Note: Dependent variable is the percentage of years in which a leader faced a coup attempt
while in power.
200
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6.6 Conclusion
201
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6 Consequences on Autocratic Stability
202
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6.6 Conclusion
203
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6 Consequences on Autocratic Stability
204
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.006 Published online by Cambridge University Press
6
What Are the Consequences of Institutionalization
on Autocratic Stability?
This book has so far been primarily been concerned with explaining the
emergence of institutionalized autocratic rule. We now return to the first
central puzzle presented at the very onset of Chapter 1: What explains
differences in authoritarian regime stability? Why is it that some dictator-
ships are subject to constant coup attempts and regime change, while
others withstand multiple peaceful leadership transitions and remain
stable over long periods of time?
The next two chapters will examine the effects of institutionalization on
regime durability. Do institutionalized regimes actually perform better on
a number of key outcomes, such as leader longevity, the prevention of coups,
and the promotion of peaceful leadership succession? This chapter will focus
on estimating the effects of regime institutionalization on key leader out-
comes: the length of leader tenure and susceptibility to coups attempts. The
next chapter will focus on estimating the effects of institutionalization on key
regime outcomes: leadership succession and regime survival.
This chapter will show that leaders who institutionalize their regimes
tend to remain in office for longer periods of time and face fewer coup
attempts. The next chapter will demonstrate that institutionalized regimes
are significantly more likely to undergo peaceful leadership transitions.
Together these two chapters demonstrate that executive constraints are
not simply empty parchment rules. Institutionalization does indeed have
consequences for regime stability.
However, estimating the effects of endogenously created institutions is not
as straightforward as it may seem. In determining the effects of institutions,
these chapters will take into consideration the subject of the first half of this
book – the fact that leaders choose whether to institutionalize based on
underlying threats to their rule. Since constitutional rules and cabinet
appointments are not randomly assigned across regimes, we must consider
the types of leaders who choose to create these institutions when examining
whether such rules have an independent effect on regime durability.
186
Published online by Cambridge University Press
6.1 Are Rules Followed in Dictatorships?
187
Published online by Cambridge University Press
6 Consequences on Autocratic Stability
188
Published online by Cambridge University Press
6.2 Do Institutions Promote Regime Stability?
6 . 2 e m p i r i cal d i s ag re em en t : do i ns t i t ut i ons
promote regime s tabili ty?
Despite the general consensus that institutionalized forms of dictatorship
tend to be more stable, the empirical record of the relationship between
institutions and regime stability has been surprisingly mixed. In a seminal
study, Geddes (1999a) finds that single-party regimes remain in power for
longer periods of time compared to personalist regimes. Military regimes,
which tend to have weak or no civilian institutions, are less durable
compared with personalist regimes. This study catalyzed the idea that
institutionalized forms of authoritarianism tend to be most durable.
Geddes’ empirical analysis was replicated by Brownlee (2007), who
found similar effects. Since then, many scholars have made the theoretical
argument that institutions, such as parties and legislatures, can prolong
the lifespan of authoritarian regimes (Boix and Svolik 2013; Gandhi 2008;
Geddes, Wright, and Frantz 2018; Gandhi and Przeworski 2007;
Magaloni 2008; Svolik 2009).
However, a number of subsequent studies have since challenged this
initial finding. Smith (2005), for instance, shows that the significant effect
of single-party regimes is driven primarily by two outliers: Mexico and the
Soviet Union. He replicates Geddes’ original analysis, producing similar
results, but then demonstrates that when the two longest-living regimes
are dropped from the analysis, single-party regimes are no longer signifi-
cantly more durable compared with personalist regimes.
A small number of studies have also pointed out that autocratic leaders
endogenously respond to threats with “appropriate” degrees of institutiona-
lization, therefore we should not expect to see a relationship between institu-
tions and stability. Gandhi (2008), for instance, finds that leaders with ruling
parties do not tend to survive in office longer compared with those without
parties, “suggesting that most authoritarian incumbents are able to perceive
with some accuracy the threats germinating within society and to respond
with the appropriate degree of institutionalization” (176–177). According to
this study, leaders institutionalize optimally, and therefore there should be no
observable effect between institutions and stability.
Boix and Svolik (2013) also present a study in which institutional choice
is endogenous. They argue that power-sharing institutions, such as parties
or legislatures, can be established only when backed by a credible threat of
elite rebellion. However, despite the fact that their theory endogenizes the
creation of institutions, two observable implications of their study are that
regimes with institutions should be longer lived and experience fewer
coups. Using data on the existence of parties and legislatures in autocra-
cies, they find empirical support for their arguments.
189
Published online by Cambridge University Press
6 Consequences on Autocratic Stability
190
Published online by Cambridge University Press
6.3 Problems with Existing Approaches
Strong No
leader Stable regime
institutionalization
No Unstable
Institutionalization regime
Weak
leader
Institutionalization Stable regime
1
It is important to note that it is possible for strong leaders to institutionalize, even
though this would be out-of-equilibrium behavior according to the model. I would
expect institutionalized regimes, even if the leader was initially strong, to be more
stable due to the fact that the creation of constitutional rules and cabinet appoint-
ments creates mechanisms for credible power-sharing and patronage distribution.
191
Published online by Cambridge University Press
6 Consequences on Autocratic Stability
6.4.1 Data
The outcome variable of interest in this chapter is autocratic stability,
particularly with respect to leader outcomes.2 Leader stability will be
measured via two dependent variables: the length of a leader’s tenure
and the number of coup attempts a leader faces during her tenure.
“Years in power” is a variable that counts the number of years a leader
remained in power. “Coup attempts” records the percent of the number of
office years for which a leader faced coup attempts. This variable is
presented as a percent, rather than a count of the number of coup attempts
a leader faced in order to take into account the fact that various leaders
remained in office for different lengths of time.
There are two primary independent variables of interest: leader
strength and regime institutionalization. Leader strength will be proxied
using two measurement strategies from Chapter 5: founders versus suc-
cessors and coup leaders versus noncoup leaders. “Founder” is a dummy
variable that takes a value of 1 if the leader was the first leader of the
country after independence and 0 otherwise. As Chapter 5 argued, found-
ing leaders tended to enjoy special legitimacy and mass support, and this
was especially true for these leaders who rose to power in the immediate
aftermath of independence. Founding presidents can therefore be inter-
preted as stronger leaders compared with subsequent presidents. “Coup
2
The next chapter will examine the effect of institutionalization on leadership succes-
sion and regime survival.
192
Published online by Cambridge University Press
6.4 Estimating Effects of Endogenous Institutions
3
The reader may recall that in Chapter 5 I presented a third strategy for measuring
leader strength by looking at the subset of founding leaders, and comparing strong
nationalist leaders against those who were close allies of the colonial state. Since this
strategy requires looking within the subset of independence regimes, the number of
observations available for this strategy are much more limited. I therefore exclude
this strategy from the empirical tests in this chapter.
4
Since the strict and weak version of the successor rule are highly correlated, I exclude
the “strict successor” variable from the analysis in this chapter. Since “VP/PM
appoint” and “VP/PM same” as well as “defense appoint” and “defense same” are
also highly correlated, I also exclude the “VP/PM appoint” and “defense appoint”
variables from the analysis in this chapter. Since term limits were generally not
implemented until after the 1990s and are not frequently adhered to, I exclude it
from the analysis in this chapter.
193
Published online by Cambridge University Press
6 Consequences on Autocratic Stability
194
Published online by Cambridge University Press
6.5 Empirical Analysis and Findings
with a weak leader. For x1 =0, the subset of weak leaders (recall that x1 is
a dummy variable representing leader strength or weakness), the equation
reduces to the following:
Y ¼ α þ β2 x2 þ ε
I hypothesize that when the leader is weak, institutionalization should
have a positive and significant effect on leader outcomes. Since x2 denotes
levels of regime institutionalization, we should expect β2 to be signifi-
cantly different than zero.5
For x1 =1, the subset of strong leaders, the equation reduces to the
following:
Y ¼ α þ β1 þ ðβ2 þ β3 Þx2 þ ε
I hypothesize that when the leader is strong, there should be no effect of
institutionalization on leader stability. Since x2 denotes levels of regime
institutionalization, then the coefficients ðβ2 þ β3 Þ should not be signifi-
cantly different from 0.
To summarize, if my theory is correct, then we should expect β2 to be
significantly different from 0 and ðβ2 þ β3 Þ not to be significantly different
from 0.
6 . 5 e m p i r i c a l ana l y s i s a n d fin d i n g s
I use two different proxies of leader strength to condition the differential
effects of institutionalization on length of leader tenure and vulnerability to
coups: (1) founding leaders versus subsequent leaders and (2) coup leaders
versus noncoup leaders. I will present results using both of these strategies
separately.
5
Whether β2 should be greater than or less than 0 depends on the outcome we are
examining. A lower number of coup attempts denotes a more stable regime, so for
that analysis, we should expect β2 < 0: Longer leader tenure denotes a more stable
regime, so for that analysis, we should expect β2 > 0.
195
Published online by Cambridge University Press
6 Consequences on Autocratic Stability
6
Recall that (ß2) is the relevant coefficient for weak leaders. These rows are
highlighted in Appendix Table 6.3.
7
Recall that the effect of institutionalization for strong leaders is denoted by ß2 + ß3.
This row is highlighted in Appendix Table 6.3.
196
Published online by Cambridge University Press
6.5 Empirical Analysis and Findings
Figure 6.3 What is the effect of institutionalization on leader tenure (coup leaders)?
Note: 90 percent confidence intervals reported. Proxy for leader strength is coup leaders
versus noncoup leaders. The dependent variable is the number of years for which a leader
was in power. Our hypothesis predicts a positive relationship between institutionalization
and leader tenure for weak leaders.
error for the leader strength variable. It could be the case that founding
leaders does not serve as a perfect proxy for initial leader strength. On other
hand, it is also possible that having a leadership succession policy in place
does indeed lengthen the tenure of all leaders, even those who enter office
initially strong. Chapter 7 provides an extensive discussion of leadership
succession.
I also analyze the relationship between institutionalization and leader
tenure using coup leaders as a proxy for initially strong leaders. The
results are illustrated in Figure 6.3 and the full regression results are
reported in Appendix Table 6.4. Once again, I find that when initially
weak leaders (noncoup leaders) institutionalize, they tend to remain in
office for longer periods of time, and this finding is statistically significant
along cabinet stability dimensions.
For initially strong leaders (coup leaders), institutionalization – particu-
larly the stable appointment of VP/PMs and the creation of succession
policies – does appear to have effects on leader tenure. It is possible that
coup leaders, while having consolidated authority over the coercive appara-
tus of the regime, have vulnerability along other nonmilitary dimensions, and
therefore benefit from the stabilizing effect of institutionalization along such
dimensions. Coup leaders who institutionalize along civilian dimensions may
197
Published online by Cambridge University Press
6 Consequences on Autocratic Stability
experience more stable rule, even if they took power having already con-
solidated power along coercive dimensions.
Figure 6.4 What is the effect of institutionalization on the frequency of coup attempts?
Note: 90 percent confidence intervals reported. Proxy for leader strength is founders versus
subsequence leaders. The dependent variable is the percentage of years for which a leader
faces a coup attempt. Our hypothesis predicts a negative relationship between
institutionalization and coup attempts for weak leaders.
198
Published online by Cambridge University Press
6.6 Conclusion
6.6 conclusion
This chapter examined the effect of institutionalization on autocratic sta-
bility, particularly the length of leader tenure and frequency of coup threats.
I argued that in estimating the effect of institutionalization on these out-
comes we need to take into account the fact that initially strong and initially
weak leaders make different institutionalization decisions, depending on
threats to their rule. Weak leaders institutionalize in order to alleviate
threats to their rule, and therefore we should expect to see an effect of
institutionalization on stability for initially weak leaders. Initially strong
leaders are able to remain in power whether they institutionalize or not, so
199
Published online by Cambridge University Press
6 Consequences on Autocratic Stability
Appendix
Note: Dependent variable is a count variable of the number of years the leader was in power.
Note: Dependent variable is the percentage of years in which a leader faced a coup attempt
while in power.
200
Published online by Cambridge University Press
6.6 Conclusion
201
Published online by Cambridge University Press
6 Consequences on Autocratic Stability
202
Published online by Cambridge University Press
6.6 Conclusion
203
Published online by Cambridge University Press
6 Consequences on Autocratic Stability
204
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7
What Are the Consequences of Institutionalization
on Leadership Succession?
205
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
rewards from the succession order. Term limits, on the other hand, are
much less effective in facilitating peaceful leadership transitions because
they do not empower specific elites in the way that succession policies do
by designating an heir apparent. Because term limits do not identify an
alternative leader that elites can coordinate around, term limits do not
resolve the collective action problem elites face in holding the incumbent
accountable.
Importantly, the argument made in this chapter departs from the
argument made in Chapter 6 in the following way. In this chapter,
I argue that when estimating the effect of institutionalization on leader-
ship succession outcomes, we do not need to condition on the initial
strength of the leader. This is because peaceful succession outcomes are
an unintended consequence of regime institutionalization. As Chapter 6
demonstrated, self-interested leaders institutionalize their regimes in
order to insulate themselves against coup attempts. At the same time,
these measures – namely the creation of constitutional succession rules
and the appointment of a de facto successor – create certainty surrounding
the line of succession, therefore paving the way for a peaceful leadership
transition. While leaders do not necessarily care about the outcome of the
regime after their death, the measures they take to stabilize their rule while
in power nonetheless create conditions for the peaceful transfer of power.
This chapter makes two important contributions to theories of leader-
ship succession in dictatorships. First, it is one of the few studies to test
mechanisms of peaceful leadership change in autocracies. Though the
politics of succession is considered to be one of the central challenges of
autocratic rule, the mechanisms that facilitate peaceful leadership transi-
tions are not well understood for modern dictatorships. A limited number
of studies on this topic have focused on the role of hereditary succession
and ruling parties.
Early studies of leadership succession by Tullock (1987) focused on
importance of hereditary succession and primogeniture, and his the-
ories have since been extended and tested on pretwentieth century
European monarchies (Kurrild-Klitgaard 2000; Kokkonen and
Sundell 2014). However, the vast majority of authoritarian regimes
today are not monarchies. In fact, only 7 percent of all autocratic
regimes from 1946 to 2010 are coded as monarchies, and out of those
monarchies only two remain in power today (Geddes, Wright, and
Franz 2014).1 Furthermore, I show in this chapter that hereditary
succession is incredibly rare in modern dictatorships. Within my
1
Out of 280 autocratic regimes from 1946 to 2010, nineteen are coded as monarchies.
206
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.1 Do Dictators Care About Leadership Succession?
207
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
2
This argument is also related to Fearon’s (2011) concept of “self-enforcing democ-
racy” whereby elections provide citizens with a commonly understood set of rules
and procedures that allow them to credibly protest if the leader violates election
principles.
208
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.2 How Succession Planning Promotes Regime Stability
209
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
210
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.2 How Succession Planning Promotes Regime Stability
3
Two of the leaders of the Change the Constitution movement were Dr. Njoroge
Mungai, Kenyatta’s nephew and personal doctor, and Mbiyu Koinange, his brother-
in-law.
211
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
4
Mutharika could not simply remove Banda as vice president because the Malawi
constitution mandates that the vice president can only be removed by impeachment
(Dionne and Dulani 2013).
212
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.4 Succession Policies Versus Term Limits
213
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
214
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.5 Endogenous Institutionalization Reconsidered
215
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
5
Archigos breaks down leader exit into the following main categories: assassination,
popular protest, removed by military, removed by other government actors, removed
by rebels, removed through threat of foreign force, regular, still in office. I consider
all exit codes other than assassination, regular, and still in office as an instance of
“irregular” leader exit. I exclude assassination from my list of irregular leader exits
because Archigos codes assassination attempts only by unsupported individuals.
U.S. presidents, for instance, have been assassinated but were peacefully succeeded
by their vice presidents. For leader entry, Archigos uses the following categories:
foreign imposition, irregular, regular, unknown. I only consider cases coded as
“regular” as peaceful entry.
216
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.6 Data and Descriptive Statistics
and Biya took office that same day. On the other hand, from 1960 through
1970, Benin experienced six leadership changes, all of which were driven
by coups. Finally, a number of incumbents were in power through the end
of the dataset in 2010, and I exclude such observations from the analysis
in this chapter. Robert Mugabe of Zimbabwe is such an example.
217
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
the transfer of power occurs between two family members. I include blood
ties and ties via marriage and do not exclude irregular transfers of power.
I also create a set of variables to test the party hypothesis. Ruling parties
are thought to provide a clear mechanism for leadership succession, and
this effect is likely to be stronger for more established parties. For data on
ruling parties, I merge the time-series version of my dataset on transitions
with the dataset on institutions from Svolik (2012). Using the party
variable from Svolik, I create the variable “party years,” which documents
the number of years the leader had a ruling party prior to the leadership
transition.6
7 . 7 des c r i p ti v e s t a t i s t i c s
The resulting data for this chapter includes 144 leadership transitions that
occurred between 1960 and 2010 in sub-Saharan Africa. Out of these
transitions, fifty-seven were peaceful and eighty-seven were not.7 As
documented in the literature on authoritarian rule, smooth leadership
transitions do not occur easily; only 40 percent of the transitions in this
sample were peaceful.
A number of interesting descriptive findings emerge from the data. The
first striking observation is that hereditary succession in sub-Saharan
Africa is surprisingly rare. Only 5 percent of power transfers (whether
peaceful or not) occur between family members.8 Out of these nine cases,
four were peaceful,9 and four were not,10 and one leader is still in power.
This finding is similar to patterns of hereditary succession in the global
sample of all authoritarian regimes. Out of all autocratic leadership
6
In order for the party to be included in this variable, I require that (1) The party must
be in power up until the transition. If, for instance, a leader bans a party prior to the
leadership transition, then the party could not have facilitated the transition. (2)
I also require that the party be in power for at least three years. In establishing the
three-year cutoff, I follow conventions in the literature (for example, see Geddes
1999), with the goal of excluding parties that were so new that they most likely did
not have the capacity to play a meaningful role in the leadership transition.
7
There were twenty-seven leaders still in power as of 2010, and I exclude these units
from the analysis.
8
It is useful to recall that I am using a broad definition of the term “family”; I include
relatives who are related by marriage in addition to blood relations.
9
For instance, in 1999, Ismail Omar Guelleh came to power as the president of
Djibouti, following his uncle Hassan Gouled Aptidon who had been the first pre-
sident of Djibouti from 1977 to 1999. Guelleh was the handpicked successor of
Aptidon and took over when his uncle retired.
10
For example, in 1966, Jean-Bedel Bokassa seized power from David Dacko in the
Central African Republic in a military coup. Bokassa was Dacko’s uncle.
218
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.8 Empirical Analysis
transitions that occurred between 1946 and 2016, power was handed
between family members less than 3 percent of the time.
Even family “dynasties” occur very infrequently. In my sample of
African leaders, only 6 percent of leaders have any family ties with earlier
incumbents.11 Once again, this statistic mirrors general patterns of family
dynasties found in the global sample of all autocratic leaders. Summary
statistics of all variables are reported in Appendix Table 7.1.
7 . 8 em p i r i c a l a n a l y s i s
To test the hypotheses presented in this chapter, I estimate a logit model
predicting peaceful transitions for each leadership transition i in country j.
It is represented as the following:
11
By family “dynasty” I am referring to leaders who have a familial connection with
an earlier incumbent, but did not immediately come into office following the family
member. For instance, Ian Khama, the current president of Botswana, came into
office in 2008. His father, Sereste Khama, left office in 1980.
219
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
Pr(peaceful succession)
.8 .8
.6 .6
.4 .4
.2 .2
0 0
0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .9 1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .9 1
Proportion of years in power with Proportion of years in power with
stable VP/PM constitutional succession rules
Figure 7.2 Marginal effects of having a succession policy and designated successor on
likelihood of peaceful transition
peaceful transitions, but this effect is not robust to the addition to controls
(see Appendix Table 7.2).
The presence of a ruling party does not appear to have a significant
effect in any of the model specifications. In fact, the ruling party
variable is never significant in any subsequent models or robustness
checks presented in this chapter. In addition, because there are so few
cases of familial transfers of power (less than 5 percent of the sam-
ple), I drop this variable from the results presented in this chapter.
When included in the models, this variable is never significant.
One potential concern is that parties may be especially weak in
sub-Saharan Africa, particularly during the early decades
immediately following independence. To show that the absence of
a party effect is not simply an artifact of weak parties in Africa,
I analyze a global sample of leadership transitions from 1946 to
2008 and find that the presence of a ruling party does not increase
the likelihood of a peaceful leadership transition. I also find no
effect of hereditary succession on the likelihood of a peaceful
transition in the global sample. Appendix Table 7.3 reports these
results.
220
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.9 Conclusion
7.9 conclusion
This chapter examined the effect of institutionalization on leadership
succession outcomes. I argued that the creation of constitutional
succession procedures and the designation of a de facto successor
(through the appointment of a stable vice president or prime minister)
plays a critical role in regulating peaceful leadership turnover.
Although leaders institutionalize out of self-interest, these measures
inadvertently create conditions for peaceful succession. The creation
of a clear line of succession provides certainty of the chain of com-
mand. Designated successors have an incentive to uphold the existing
regime since preserving the status quo is the best guarantee that they
will become the next incumbent.
I also argued that term limits, unlike succession rules, should not
have strong effect on succession outcomes. This is because term limits
do not solve the elite collective action problem by identifying
a specific elite challenger. Whereas the designation of a vice president
or prime minister or the designation of a line of succession in the
constitution identifies specific elites as a clear alternative leader, term
limits place constraints on the leader without empowering a specific
elite.
I analyzed all postindependence leadership transitions within sub-
Saharan Africa and provided empirical evidence for these arguments.
Altogether, Chapters 6 and 7 show that institutionalization does indeed
have stabilizing effects on key leader and regime outcomes.
221
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
Appendix
222
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.9 Conclusion
223
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
Note: Units without constitutions for the entire period are excluded
from this analysis.
Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses
*** p < 0.001, ** p < 0.01, * p < 0.05
224
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.9 Conclusion
225
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.007 Published online by Cambridge University Press
7
What Are the Consequences of Institutionalization
on Leadership Succession?
205
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
rewards from the succession order. Term limits, on the other hand, are
much less effective in facilitating peaceful leadership transitions because
they do not empower specific elites in the way that succession policies do
by designating an heir apparent. Because term limits do not identify an
alternative leader that elites can coordinate around, term limits do not
resolve the collective action problem elites face in holding the incumbent
accountable.
Importantly, the argument made in this chapter departs from the
argument made in Chapter 6 in the following way. In this chapter,
I argue that when estimating the effect of institutionalization on leader-
ship succession outcomes, we do not need to condition on the initial
strength of the leader. This is because peaceful succession outcomes are
an unintended consequence of regime institutionalization. As Chapter 6
demonstrated, self-interested leaders institutionalize their regimes in
order to insulate themselves against coup attempts. At the same time,
these measures – namely the creation of constitutional succession rules
and the appointment of a de facto successor – create certainty surrounding
the line of succession, therefore paving the way for a peaceful leadership
transition. While leaders do not necessarily care about the outcome of the
regime after their death, the measures they take to stabilize their rule while
in power nonetheless create conditions for the peaceful transfer of power.
This chapter makes two important contributions to theories of leader-
ship succession in dictatorships. First, it is one of the few studies to test
mechanisms of peaceful leadership change in autocracies. Though the
politics of succession is considered to be one of the central challenges of
autocratic rule, the mechanisms that facilitate peaceful leadership transi-
tions are not well understood for modern dictatorships. A limited number
of studies on this topic have focused on the role of hereditary succession
and ruling parties.
Early studies of leadership succession by Tullock (1987) focused on
importance of hereditary succession and primogeniture, and his the-
ories have since been extended and tested on pretwentieth century
European monarchies (Kurrild-Klitgaard 2000; Kokkonen and
Sundell 2014). However, the vast majority of authoritarian regimes
today are not monarchies. In fact, only 7 percent of all autocratic
regimes from 1946 to 2010 are coded as monarchies, and out of those
monarchies only two remain in power today (Geddes, Wright, and
Franz 2014).1 Furthermore, I show in this chapter that hereditary
succession is incredibly rare in modern dictatorships. Within my
1
Out of 280 autocratic regimes from 1946 to 2010, nineteen are coded as monarchies.
206
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.1 Do Dictators Care About Leadership Succession?
207
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
2
This argument is also related to Fearon’s (2011) concept of “self-enforcing democ-
racy” whereby elections provide citizens with a commonly understood set of rules
and procedures that allow them to credibly protest if the leader violates election
principles.
208
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.2 How Succession Planning Promotes Regime Stability
209
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
210
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.2 How Succession Planning Promotes Regime Stability
3
Two of the leaders of the Change the Constitution movement were Dr. Njoroge
Mungai, Kenyatta’s nephew and personal doctor, and Mbiyu Koinange, his brother-
in-law.
211
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
4
Mutharika could not simply remove Banda as vice president because the Malawi
constitution mandates that the vice president can only be removed by impeachment
(Dionne and Dulani 2013).
212
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.4 Succession Policies Versus Term Limits
213
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
214
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.5 Endogenous Institutionalization Reconsidered
215
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
5
Archigos breaks down leader exit into the following main categories: assassination,
popular protest, removed by military, removed by other government actors, removed
by rebels, removed through threat of foreign force, regular, still in office. I consider
all exit codes other than assassination, regular, and still in office as an instance of
“irregular” leader exit. I exclude assassination from my list of irregular leader exits
because Archigos codes assassination attempts only by unsupported individuals.
U.S. presidents, for instance, have been assassinated but were peacefully succeeded
by their vice presidents. For leader entry, Archigos uses the following categories:
foreign imposition, irregular, regular, unknown. I only consider cases coded as
“regular” as peaceful entry.
216
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.6 Data and Descriptive Statistics
and Biya took office that same day. On the other hand, from 1960 through
1970, Benin experienced six leadership changes, all of which were driven
by coups. Finally, a number of incumbents were in power through the end
of the dataset in 2010, and I exclude such observations from the analysis
in this chapter. Robert Mugabe of Zimbabwe is such an example.
217
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
the transfer of power occurs between two family members. I include blood
ties and ties via marriage and do not exclude irregular transfers of power.
I also create a set of variables to test the party hypothesis. Ruling parties
are thought to provide a clear mechanism for leadership succession, and
this effect is likely to be stronger for more established parties. For data on
ruling parties, I merge the time-series version of my dataset on transitions
with the dataset on institutions from Svolik (2012). Using the party
variable from Svolik, I create the variable “party years,” which documents
the number of years the leader had a ruling party prior to the leadership
transition.6
7 . 7 des c r i p ti v e s t a t i s t i c s
The resulting data for this chapter includes 144 leadership transitions that
occurred between 1960 and 2010 in sub-Saharan Africa. Out of these
transitions, fifty-seven were peaceful and eighty-seven were not.7 As
documented in the literature on authoritarian rule, smooth leadership
transitions do not occur easily; only 40 percent of the transitions in this
sample were peaceful.
A number of interesting descriptive findings emerge from the data. The
first striking observation is that hereditary succession in sub-Saharan
Africa is surprisingly rare. Only 5 percent of power transfers (whether
peaceful or not) occur between family members.8 Out of these nine cases,
four were peaceful,9 and four were not,10 and one leader is still in power.
This finding is similar to patterns of hereditary succession in the global
sample of all authoritarian regimes. Out of all autocratic leadership
6
In order for the party to be included in this variable, I require that (1) The party must
be in power up until the transition. If, for instance, a leader bans a party prior to the
leadership transition, then the party could not have facilitated the transition. (2)
I also require that the party be in power for at least three years. In establishing the
three-year cutoff, I follow conventions in the literature (for example, see Geddes
1999), with the goal of excluding parties that were so new that they most likely did
not have the capacity to play a meaningful role in the leadership transition.
7
There were twenty-seven leaders still in power as of 2010, and I exclude these units
from the analysis.
8
It is useful to recall that I am using a broad definition of the term “family”; I include
relatives who are related by marriage in addition to blood relations.
9
For instance, in 1999, Ismail Omar Guelleh came to power as the president of
Djibouti, following his uncle Hassan Gouled Aptidon who had been the first pre-
sident of Djibouti from 1977 to 1999. Guelleh was the handpicked successor of
Aptidon and took over when his uncle retired.
10
For example, in 1966, Jean-Bedel Bokassa seized power from David Dacko in the
Central African Republic in a military coup. Bokassa was Dacko’s uncle.
218
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.8 Empirical Analysis
transitions that occurred between 1946 and 2016, power was handed
between family members less than 3 percent of the time.
Even family “dynasties” occur very infrequently. In my sample of
African leaders, only 6 percent of leaders have any family ties with earlier
incumbents.11 Once again, this statistic mirrors general patterns of family
dynasties found in the global sample of all autocratic leaders. Summary
statistics of all variables are reported in Appendix Table 7.1.
7 . 8 em p i r i c a l a n a l y s i s
To test the hypotheses presented in this chapter, I estimate a logit model
predicting peaceful transitions for each leadership transition i in country j.
It is represented as the following:
11
By family “dynasty” I am referring to leaders who have a familial connection with
an earlier incumbent, but did not immediately come into office following the family
member. For instance, Ian Khama, the current president of Botswana, came into
office in 2008. His father, Sereste Khama, left office in 1980.
219
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
Pr(peaceful succession)
.8 .8
.6 .6
.4 .4
.2 .2
0 0
0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .9 1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .9 1
Proportion of years in power with Proportion of years in power with
stable VP/PM constitutional succession rules
Figure 7.2 Marginal effects of having a succession policy and designated successor on
likelihood of peaceful transition
peaceful transitions, but this effect is not robust to the addition to controls
(see Appendix Table 7.2).
The presence of a ruling party does not appear to have a significant
effect in any of the model specifications. In fact, the ruling party
variable is never significant in any subsequent models or robustness
checks presented in this chapter. In addition, because there are so few
cases of familial transfers of power (less than 5 percent of the sam-
ple), I drop this variable from the results presented in this chapter.
When included in the models, this variable is never significant.
One potential concern is that parties may be especially weak in
sub-Saharan Africa, particularly during the early decades
immediately following independence. To show that the absence of
a party effect is not simply an artifact of weak parties in Africa,
I analyze a global sample of leadership transitions from 1946 to
2008 and find that the presence of a ruling party does not increase
the likelihood of a peaceful leadership transition. I also find no
effect of hereditary succession on the likelihood of a peaceful
transition in the global sample. Appendix Table 7.3 reports these
results.
220
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.9 Conclusion
7.9 conclusion
This chapter examined the effect of institutionalization on leadership
succession outcomes. I argued that the creation of constitutional
succession procedures and the designation of a de facto successor
(through the appointment of a stable vice president or prime minister)
plays a critical role in regulating peaceful leadership turnover.
Although leaders institutionalize out of self-interest, these measures
inadvertently create conditions for peaceful succession. The creation
of a clear line of succession provides certainty of the chain of com-
mand. Designated successors have an incentive to uphold the existing
regime since preserving the status quo is the best guarantee that they
will become the next incumbent.
I also argued that term limits, unlike succession rules, should not
have strong effect on succession outcomes. This is because term limits
do not solve the elite collective action problem by identifying
a specific elite challenger. Whereas the designation of a vice president
or prime minister or the designation of a line of succession in the
constitution identifies specific elites as a clear alternative leader, term
limits place constraints on the leader without empowering a specific
elite.
I analyzed all postindependence leadership transitions within sub-
Saharan Africa and provided empirical evidence for these arguments.
Altogether, Chapters 6 and 7 show that institutionalization does indeed
have stabilizing effects on key leader and regime outcomes.
221
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
Appendix
222
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.9 Conclusion
223
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7 Consequences on Leadership Succession
Note: Units without constitutions for the entire period are excluded
from this analysis.
Robust standard errors clustered by country in parentheses
*** p < 0.001, ** p < 0.01, * p < 0.05
224
Published online by Cambridge University Press
7.9 Conclusion
225
Published online by Cambridge University Press
8
Conclusion
226
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.008 Published online by Cambridge University Press
8.1 Taking Stock
227
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.008 Published online by Cambridge University Press
8 Conclusion
1
Yet these studies still do not link the emergence of strong ruling parties to regime
outcomes and instead focus primarily on explaining the origins of party-based
regimes.
228
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.008 Published online by Cambridge University Press
8.2 Empirical Contribution
229
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.008 Published online by Cambridge University Press
8 Conclusion
230
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.008 Published online by Cambridge University Press
8.2 Empirical Contribution
231
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.008 Published online by Cambridge University Press
8 Conclusion
power, and this is true even during the most authoritarian decades prior
to the end of the Cold War. Institutions are not uniformly weak in sub-
Saharan Africa.
The data also highlights that patterns of institutionalization change
over time. There is a clear difference between the modal African autocracy
before and after the end of the Cold War. In the decades from the 1960s
through the 1980s, weak leaders were compelled to institutionalize their
regimes during the independence era. As a result, about half of African
autocracies during this time established institutionalized power-sharing
mechanisms through cabinet ministerial appointments and roughly
a quarter created constitutional succession procedures. Following the
end of the Cold War from the 1990s through the present, most African
autocrats were forced to institutionalize their regimes and we see a sharp
increase in the creation of constitutional rules and stable cabinet
appointments.
Moreover, this book provides an alternative perspective on democra-
tization in Africa. I contend that trends toward institutionalization in the
1990s were an attempt by incumbents to recalibrate the political system in
order to entrench authoritarian stability, rather than genuine movement
towards political liberalization. Despite the introduction of multiparty
elections across most African nations following the end of the Cold War,
democratic consolidation remains stubbornly out of reach in most coun-
tries within the region. This book demonstrates how regime institutiona-
lization allowed incumbents and elites to strike credible and lasting
bargains of joint rule, even as external conditions changed. Rather than
ushering in real citizen-led democracies, the institutionalization of African
regimes in the 1990s introduced more durable rule-based forms of author-
itarian rule.
232
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.008 Published online by Cambridge University Press
8.3 Theoretical Contribution
233
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.008 Published online by Cambridge University Press
8 Conclusion
elites. Providing elites with access to the state shifts the distribution of
power away from the autocrat in favor of her appointees, providing them
with an institutional mechanism to guarantee their access to future rents.
Leaders who enter power extremely strong and having already consoli-
dated power have no incentives to create institutionalized mechanism for
rent distribution because they do not face credible threats to their rule.
Initially weak autocrats therefore adopt institutional constraints under
duress. They trade absolute power for regime stability.
This theory presents an interesting twist of fate. Initially strong leaders
are not incentivized to invest in mechanisms of joint rule because they are
able to remain in power without making institutional commitments to
other elites. Yet, this strategy of one-man rule is ultimately destabilizing
and does not last beyond the founding leader. On the other hand, initially
weak leaders must pursue the strategy of empowering other elites in order
to buy their support. These self-interested actions generate power-sharing
institutions, which can last beyond the tenure of that particular leader.
Durable authoritarianism emerges out of initial leader weakness.
My theory also stresses the path dependent nature of regime institutio-
nalization. Because violence is an ever-present option in autocracies,
incumbents necessarily worry about being deposed from the day that
they enter office. The initial distribution of power between the incumbent
and her elites shape her decision about the types of institutions to set up at
the very start of her rule. However, as institutionalization empowers other
elites, it becomes self-reinforcing and difficult to remove. Even if the
incumbent becomes stronger in later periods, she remains constrained by
the very rules she implemented at the start of her tenure.
This argument attempts to address critiques of the authoritarian institu-
tions literature as being overly functionalist. Although in my account, leaders
are indeed making strategic decisions to institutionalize or not, these deci-
sions have a “lock-in” effect and are not easily disposable. Leaders cannot
construct and disassemble institutions on a whim. Whether a leader is
especially vulnerable to being deposed at the start of her tenure is historically
determined by the way in which she obtained power. This initial distribution
of power affects her decision to institutionalize, which in turn has long-
lasting consequences on the institutional makeup of the regime.
234
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.008 Published online by Cambridge University Press
8.3 Theoretical Contribution
235
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.008 Published online by Cambridge University Press
8 Conclusion
Finally, I also show that highly institutionalized regimes are more likely
to survive peaceful leadership transitions. However, the book notes that
peaceful transitions of power are an unintended consequence of strategic
institutionalization by leaders. Incumbents create constitutional rules
designating the succession order and appoint elites to high-ranking posi-
tions within the presidential cabinet not necessarily out of concern for the
stability of regime after they die. Instead, they make these institutional
decisions to stabilize their own rule and prevent elites from preemptively
trying to depose them. Yet these self-interested actions empower the
designated successor, who has every incentive to remain loyal to the
current regime in the hope of being the next incumbent.
The findings from these two chapters produce two distinct types of
autocratic regimes. The first is that of the institutionalized dictatorship.
Such regimes may appear initially weak due to the absence of
a charismatic and influential figurehead. Yet, durable institutions emerge
out of autocratic weakness. Since initially weak leaders cannot rely on
personalist strategies of rule to stay in power, such leaders must necessa-
rily delegate authority to other elites. These institutional arrangements
become self-reinforcing over time and joint rule allows the regime to
survive past the tenure of a single leader.
The second is that of the strongman dictatorship. This leader enters
office having already consolidated power and is often a charismatic
“founding father” figure. Strongman leaders do not need to institutio-
nalize their regimes in order to maintain support from other elites
because they do not face any viable elite challengers of equal status.
However, due to the lack of succession planning and absence of institu-
tionalized rules and organizational structure that can operate indepen-
dently of the ruler, these regimes fall apart upon the death of the
strongman leader.
Yet it is important to note that personalist dictators can often remain in
power for very long periods of time and in fact often die in office. Dictators
such as Francisco Franco who ruled Spain from 1939 until his death in
1975 or Mobutu Sese Seko who ruled Zaire from 1965 to 1997, remained
in power for decades. Because leaders endogenously respond to threats,
regime institutionalization and the length of leader tenure are not strongly
correlated. However, this mode of personalist rule generally cannot be
passed on beyond the tenure of one leader. While strongman dictatorships
appear stable while the incumbent is still alive, such regimes do not survive
leadership transitions. As a result, institutionalized regimes do indeed
survive longer than uninstitutionalized regimes by solving the leadership
succession problem. The longest surviving autocracies, such as those in
China, Tanzania, and Mexico under the PRI, reflect this pattern.
236
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.008 Published online by Cambridge University Press
8.4 Looking Ahead
237
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.008 Published online by Cambridge University Press
8 Conclusion
institutions are in place (Posner and Young 2007). These themes suggest
that future scholarship on democratic transitions and consolidation
should pay more attention to the conditions under which the introduction
of multiparty elections actually produce electoral turnover.
Finally, this book also provides insights that address growing concerns
about democratic backsliding. Democratic backsliding, also referred to as
democratic erosion, broadly describes the process of “state-led debilita-
tion or elimination of any of the political institutions that sustain an
existing democracy” (Bermeo 2016, 5). It is a topic that has gained
increasing attention but has received little scholarly research in political
science thus far. Scholars are now in the early stages of conceptualizing
and measuring democratic backsliding in addition to understanding the
causes and consequences of it.
On this topic, this book offers two important perspectives. First, any
regime – whether democratic or authoritarian – can have institutions that
constrain executive power. Therefore, the debilitation or elimination of
political institutions is not and should not be limited to the study of
democracies. Institutionalized forms of dictatorship can backslide as
well. This has been demonstrated by the removal of constitutional term
limits by President Xi Jinping of China in 2018 and President Paul Biya of
Cameroon in 2008. Scholars should therefore pursue the study of de-
institutionalization across all regime types, without restricting analysis
of institutional erosion to democracies.
Second, this book demonstrates that institutional constraints are most
effective when they empower specific political actors who can check the
authority of the president. Not all constitutional rules have the same stick-
ing power, and certain types of institutions may be easier to remove or
weaken than others. As Chapter 7 argued, term limits are easier to ignore or
remove compared with constitutional succession procedures because term
limits do not empower particular elite challengers. Therefore when an
incumbent violates term limits, elites have a more difficult time overcoming
coordination problems required to sanction the incumbent because it is not
clear who exactly is losing out the most. Future research can consider this
mechanism of elite empowerment when trying to understand the conditions
under which leaders can weaken or remove institutional constraints on
their power. Constitutional rules matter, not because they exist on paper,
but only when they reshape political power.
238
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.008 Published online by Cambridge University Press
References
239
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.009 Published online by Cambridge University Press
References
240
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.009 Published online by Cambridge University Press
References
241
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.009 Published online by Cambridge University Press
References
242
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.009 Published online by Cambridge University Press
References
243
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.009 Published online by Cambridge University Press
References
244
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.009 Published online by Cambridge University Press
References
245
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.009 Published online by Cambridge University Press
References
246
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.009 Published online by Cambridge University Press
References
247
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.009 Published online by Cambridge University Press
References
Treisman, D. (2007). What have we learned about the causes of corruption from
ten years of cross-national empirical research? Annual Review of Political
Science 10(1), 211–244.
Tsai, L. L. (2007). Accountability Without Democracy: Solidary Groups and
Public Goods Provision in Rural China. Cambridge University Press.
Tullock, G. (1987). Autocracy. Berlin: Springer.
Van de Walle, N. (1993). The politics of non-reform in Cameroon in
T. M. Callaghy and J. Ravenhill (eds.) Hemmed In: Responses to Africa’s
Economic Decline. New York: Columbia University Press. 357–397.
Vogt, M., N.-C. Bormann, S. Raijegger, L.-E. Cederman, P. Hunziker, and
L. Girardin (2015). Integrating data on ethnicity, geography, and conflict: the
ethnic power relations data set family. Journal of Conflict Resolution 59(7),
1327–1342.
Welch, C. E. (1970). Soldier and State in Africa: A Comparative Analysis of
Military Intervention and Political Change. Evanston, IL: Northwestern
University Press.
Widner, J. A. (1992). The Rise of a Party-State in Kenya: From “Harambee!” to
“Nyayo!”. Berkeley: University of California.
World Bank (2016). Cameroon. https://data.worldbank.org/country/cameroon.
World Bank (2017). Côte d’Ivoire. https://data.worldbank.org/country/cote-
divoire.
Woronoff, J. (1972). West African Wager: Houphouet Versus Nkrumah.
Metuchen, NJ: Scarecrow Press.
Zolberg, A. (1966). Creating Political Order: The Party-States of West Africa.
Chicago: Rand McNally.
Zolberg, A. (1969). One Party Government in the Ivory Coast. Princeton
University Press.
Zolberg, A. (1971). Political development in the Ivory Coast since independence in
P. Foster and A. Zolberg (eds.) Ghana and the Ivory Coast: Perspectives on
Modernization. University of Chicago Press. 22–23.
248
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.009 Published online by Cambridge University Press
Index
249
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.010 Published online by Cambridge University Press
Index
250
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.010 Published online by Cambridge University Press
Index
251
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.010 Published online by Cambridge University Press
Index
252
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.010 Published online by Cambridge University Press
Index
253
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.010 Published online by Cambridge University Press
Index
254
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.010 Published online by Cambridge University Press
Index
255
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.010 Published online by Cambridge University Press
Index
256
https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108877497.010 Published online by Cambridge University Press