Price Setting and Price Regulation in Health Care: Lessons For Advancing Universal Health Coverage
Price Setting and Price Regulation in Health Care: Lessons For Advancing Universal Health Coverage
Price Setting and Price Regulation in Health Care: Lessons For Advancing Universal Health Coverage
3. Payment methods 15
References79
Australia:
Jane Hall, Maryam Naghsh Nejad, Kees Van Gool and
Michael Woods
England:
Sue Nowak and Alberto Marino
France:
Zeynep Or and Coralie Gandré
Germany:
Jonas Schreyögg and Ricarda Milstein
Japan:
Naoki Ikegami
Malaysia:
Chiu Wan Ng
Republic of Korea:
Soonman Kwon
Thailand:
Viroj Tangcharoensathien, Walaiporn Patcharanarumol,
Taweesri Greetong, Waraporn Suwanwela,
Nantawan Kesthom, Shaheda Viriyathorn,
Nattadhanai Rajatanavin, Woranan Witthayapipopsakul
nited States of America and Maryland:
U
Luca Lorenzoni
vi
Under international commitments to Universal Health Coverage,
the Member States of the World Health Organization are
obligated to strengthen their financing systems to ensure that
all people have access to health services and are protected
against financial hardship in paying for these services. While
payment methods have received a great deal of attention
among policy-makers and practitioners, less attention has been
paid to price setting and how it can also contribute to broader
system objectives. However, if prices are set too high or too
low, they can easily overshadow the incentives in payment
mechanisms.
vii
Glossary and
Abbreviations
Balance billing - When a health care provider bills a patient for a price beyond what is
reimbursable from the patient’s health insurance.
Base for payment - The base or unit of activity on which prices are set. Common base for
payments are fee-for-service, diagnosis related groups, per diem, and
capitation, for example.
Base rate - The standardized payment amount that a provider receives for covered
services. The rate could be adjusted by differences in the cost of living or
other factors.
Bundled payment - A single payment covering a bundle of distinct goods and services
required for the treatment of a given medical condition based on clinical
practice guidelines.
Capitation (also per capita CAP Prospective fixed lump-sum payment per person enrolled for care with a
payment) provider within a given period (typically one year) covering a defined set
of services, independent of whether the services are provided.
Charge - The amount that a provider sets for services before applying any
discounts. The charge can be different from the amount paid.
Coinsurance - Percentage that the insurer pays after the individual deductible is
exceeded, with the intention of joint risk sharing between the insured
individual and the insurer.
Copayment - Fixed payment paid by an individual for health care services at the point
of seeking care, which is not covered by insurance, regardless of the kind
of services provided during the visit.
Contributory health coverage - Coverage paid through employee payroll contributions with employer
cost sharing.
Cost - (For the provider), the total amount incurred in providing a service,
including procedures, therapies, and medications. The actual cost is
typically lower than the price paid.
Cost based reimbursement - Retrospective payments to health care providers based on the cost of
care provided to patients and allowable covered costs.
Cost centre - A defined entity to which direct costs are assigned and indirect costs are
allocated (i.e., organizational or management unit).
Cost object (also cost objective) - A defined entity for which cost information is sought (i.e., patient, service,
department).
Diagnosis Related Group DRG Payment paid to hospitals per admission or discharge, whereby patients
payment (also case-based are classified into groups (DRGs) based on diagnosis and procedures.
payment)
Extra billing - Billing for services or drugs that are not included in the benefits package.
This differs from balance billing, where the amount billed for covered
service is higher than the regulated price.
Fee-for-service FFS Fixed payment for each unit of service without regard to outcomes. It is
typically paid retrospectively by billing for each individual service or
patient contact.
Global budget - Prospective lump-sum payment to a health care provider to cover
aggregate costs over a specific period for a set of services independent
of the actual volume provided.
Line-item budget - Fixed payment to a health care provider to cover specific input costs (i.e.,
personnel, utilities, medicines, supplies, etc.) for a specific period.
Long-term care LTC Activities undertaken to ensure that people can maintain levels of
functional ability consistent with basic rights, fundamental freedoms, and
human dignity.
Multiple payer system - A system in which multiple entities set prices to pay health care
providers.
Pay for performance (also P4P Payments to health care providers for meeting specific performance
results based financing) targets, such as process quality or efficiency measures, or penalties for
poor outcomes, such as medical errors or avoidable readmissions.
Payment for procedure or - Fixed payment for each unit of service or procedure, whereby
service adjustments to prices may reflect substantial additional work as
measured by increased intensity, time, technical difficulty of the
procedure, severity of the patient condition, or physical and mental
effort required.
Per diem - Fixed amount per day for inpatient stay, which may vary by department,
patient, clinical characteristics, or other factors.
Price (also fee, rate, tariff) - Financial amount that a purchaser (i.e., health insurer) or individual pays
to a provider to deliver a service.
Price discrimination - Occurs when an identical service is sold to different consumers at
different prices.
Price schedule (also fee - Detailed list of prices for all providers and hospitals, usually by a coding
schedule) system, i.e., Healthcare Common Procedure Coding System in the United
States of America, by diagnosis-related groups (DRGs).
Residence based coverage - Coverage based on legal residence financed with general tax revenues.
Resource based relative value RBRV A unit of measure that indicates the value of procedures conducted by
physicians, midlevel and other health care providers.
Single payer system - A system in which one entity (the single payer) set prices to pay health
care providers. The payer is typically government.
United States of America USA Abbreviation of the official World Health Organization member state
name for the United States of America.
Universal Health Coverage UHC Commitment made by United Nations Member States to extend coverage
to needed health care services for the whole population, without people
suffering from high health care payments or poverty because of getting
the health care that they need.
User fee (also user charges, - Payment made by a patient to access a service or facility.
cost-sharing)
Voluntary Health Insurance VHI Insurance plans where the decision to join and the payment of a
premium is voluntary. Coverage may be complementary or
supplementary to the basic (primary) benefit package or duplicate it.
Sources: Cashin, 2015; OECD, 2016; WHO, 2017; Le Grand and Bartlett,
1993; authors.
Health care is far from being a classic market for goods and
services. Individuals are usually represented by a purchasing
agent (i.e., health insurers) instead of operating by themselves,
and do not have complete information. This makes people less
sensitive to prices. However, prices provide important signals to
Executive summary health care providers, given that they determine the level of
financial resources to deliver health care services.
Among the case studies reported, the base for payment for
primary care is primarily fee-for-service and capitation; fee-for-
service is typically used in outpatient settings; and diagnosis
related groups are commonly used in hospital settings.1
Increasingly, payment methods have been combined with
specific performance-based rewards or penalties; they have
also been combined across providers to facilitate a more
coordinated and flexible approach to care. All payment models
have strengths and weaknesses; therefore, the impact of each
depends not only on the method chosen but also the price
paid. The price not only ensures that the costs of delivering
services are covered, but also provides incentives for health
care providers. Price adjustments are typically made to ensure
coverage and access, for example, to health care providers in
rural and remote areas; those treating disproportionately high
numbers of low-income or high-cost patients to ensure
coverage and quality; and for facilities providing medical
education. Prices are also adjusted to attain broader health-
related goals.
1 In this study, we use the term “base for payment” for the unit of activity upon which
prices are set (i.e., fee-for-service, diagnosis related groups, per diem, and capitation).
This differs from the “base rate” or the standardized payment that a hospital receives for
covered services.
Why pricing
is important
If the price set is too high or too low, it can easily overshadow
the incentives in payment mechanisms. Prices should reflect
actual costs and take into consideration broader health system
goals and health outcomes. If not, unintended negative
consequences could arise. In example, if prices are set too low
for capitation payments, this could result in low quality care,
provider selection of healthier patients, or referral of complex
cases that require a higher intensity of services to another
service provider. Where the FFS payment is low, providers may
try to compensate by increasing volume and providing
additional (unnecessary) services. If prices are not fair, service
quality, efficiency, and sustainability also suffer. In some
settings, low prices that do not sufficiently reward health care
providers are blamed for informal fees to patients, in which the
financial burden falls on individuals and society.
1.3
Relevance to low- and middle-income
settings
Low- and middle-income countries represent a diverse group of
nations. The 34 poorest countries in the world differ greatly
from high-income countries. Low-income countries focus on
extending access to basic services and, in some cases, rely on
external funding for health (WHO, 2018). Experimentation in
financing health services is also being done as a part of donor
contributions. Health systems challenges in middle-income
countries are similar to those in high-income settings. Middle-
income countries with a gross national income between
US$1006 and $12,235 per capita represent more than 70% of
the world’s population and a large share of the disease burden
(World Bank, 2019). Increases in public spending on health2 are
2 For ease of reading, we refer in this paper to spending by government and compulsory
health insurance as “public” spending on health.
250 10%
150 6%
50 2%
0 0
2000
2016
Figure 2
Moving from passive to strategic purchasing
Comparison of
case studies
Figure 3
Characteristics of case study settings
Setting Population 2015 % of population GDP per capita, Physicians Nurses and Hospital
>=60 years US$ 2016 midwives beds
Australia 23,799,556 21 54,069 3.5 12.4 3.8
Sources: UN, 2017, 2019; United States Census Bureau, 2019; World Bank,
2019.
16
14
12
10
8
% of GDP
0
USA France Germany Japan United Australia Republic Thailand Malaysia
Kingdom of Korea
compulsory
voluntary
2.2
Health care coverage
The nine settings included in the study each represent
variations in the main source of health care coverage. Australia,
Malaysia, England, and Thailand’s Universal Coverage Scheme
have systems of health coverage based on residence or
citizenship. The other settings have employment-based
contributory health coverage and vary by the number of payers.
In the Republic of Korea, there is a single payer system,
whereas in France and Japan, multiple payers exist with
automatic (compulsory) affiliation. In Germany and the USA,
multiple payers exist with choice of affiliation (Figure 5).
Sources: Paris, Devaux and Wei, 2010; Jongudomsuk et al., 2015. Note:
UCS: Universal Coverage Scheme; CSMBS: Civil Servant Medical Benefits
Scheme; SHI: Social Health Insurance.
France 13 95 Covers copayments for services included in the social insurance basket
based on regulated prices; varying coverage of extra billing and extra
services. Deductibles cannot be covered.
Germany 9 27 Outpatient care, per diem cash benefits for hospitalization.
Republic of 7 >70 Copayment for public insurance and payment for uninsured services.
Korea
Germany 8.9 27 Dental and eye care, more extensive ranges of services not covered by
social health insurance; in addition to full coverage for self-employed.
United 3.4 5 Dental care, complementary and alternative medicines, more rapid and
Kingdom convenient access to care, especially for elective hospital procedures.
Japan 2 88.5 Copayments; lump-sum payments when insured persons are hospitalized
or diagnosed with cancer or another specified chronic disease, or through
payment of daily amounts during hospitalization over a defined period.
USA 50 14.6 Persons eligible for public benefits, i.e., Medicare can purchase VHI for
additional coverage including long-term care; spending figures also
include primary care for people covered through employers.
United 3.4 9 Faster access, choice of private provider and of specialist acting in a
Kingdom private capacity, better amenities.
Australia 9 47 (hospital) Choice of providers (particularly in hospitals), faster access for
56 (general nonemergency services, and rebates for selected services.
treatment)
Malaysia 10 NA Private hospital access, faster access.
Thailand 7 24 Exclusion of prior conditions and older persons; private hospital and
faster access although more expensive.
Figure 7
Mechanisms to nudge values towards Universal Health Coverage
Command and Control Clinical guidelines and standards Standard of care usually not complete
Command and Control Issuance of license Can be based on geographical location and
needs
Command and Control Accreditation Done by professional body and tie to health
insurance payment eligibility
Financial Incentives Funding to private general practitioners, Will need mechanism to monitor if service is
(including price control) hospitals, labs, pharmacies, etc. of good quality
Self Regulation Professional subcommittee function Professional associations provide training,
empowerment, etc.
Payment methods
3.1
The base for payments
Building on existing studies (Berenson et al., 2016, Miller,
2007), the base for payments are described by the main
category of payment and the extent to which they contribute to
(or detract from) broader health systems objectives (Figure 8).
Base for payment Increasing Increasing Controlling Promoting Promoting Administrative Transparency
utilization volume expenditures efficiency quality of ease
(number of (number of care
cases) services)
Budget
Activity based
Fee-for-service + + – – unclear + +
Per diem + + – – unclear + –
Diagnosis Related + – unclear + unclear – +
Groups (DRG)
Population based
Capitation – – + + unclear + –
Consolidated
Incremental
Figure 9
Predominant base for payment for primary care, by type of
provider
Australia x x x
Japan x x x
USA x x
France x x x x x x
Germany x x x
England x x
Republic of Korea x x x
Thailand (SHI) x x
Thailand (UHC) x x
C. Public clinics
Thailand x x
Malaysia x x
Sources: case studies (see annexes). Note: FFS: fee-for-service; P4P: pay for
performance; Cap: capitation; SHI: Social health insurance; UCS: Universal
Coverage Scheme. Primary care and outpatient specialists are not
differentiated in Japan or the Republic of Korea. In England, block contracts
are still the predominant payment mechanism for the community sector
and mental health sector. In Thailand, SHI FFS refers to subcontractors; for
UHC and public clinics, capitation is inclusive of salaries.
3.2
Primary care and outpatient specialists
The most common means of purchasing primary care services is
through capitation and FFS; and outpatient services are
commonly purchased through FFS, in which health care
providers are reimbursed for the activities that they carry out
(Figures 9 and 10). FFS schedules are used in France, Japan,
Australia, Republic of Korea, the Thai Social Health Insurance
scheme, and the USA. In Germany, physicians (especially
general practitioners) receive a capitation or lump-sum
payment per patient. In countries such as Germany and the
USA, the schedule may vary by payer or region.
Figure 10
Predominant base for payment for outpatient specialist care,
by type of provider
Australia x x
Japan x x x
USA x x x x
France x x x
Germany x x x
England x x
Republic of Korea x x x
Thailand (SHI) x x
Australia x x
Thailand (UCS) x x x
Malaysia x x
Source: case studies (see annexes). Note: FFS: fee-for-service; P4P: pay for
performance; Cap: capitation; SHI: Social health insurance, UCH: Universal
coverage scheme. In Thailand, capitation payments are inclusive of salary.
In Japan, payment is made to the facility and not to individual physicians.
Figure 11
Predominant base for payment for acute inpatient hospital
services, by type of provider
France DRG, bundled payments for DRG, bundled payments for public DRG, P4P
public health services, P4P health services, P4P
Germany DRG DRG DRG
Japan Case-weighted per diem Case-weighted per diem (non- Case-weighted per diem (non-
(non-acute); Diagnosis acute); Diagnosis procedure acute); Diagnosis procedure
procedure combination (acute); combination (acute); FFS combination (acute); FFS
FFS (Outpatient) (Outpatient) (Outpatient)
Malaysia Global budget FFS FFS
Source: case studies (see annexes). Note: DRG: Diagnosis Related Group;
FFS: fee-for-service; P4P: pay for performance.
The Republic of Korea primarily uses FFS for both public and
private hospitals, with limited use of DRGs. Malaysia also uses
FFS in private hospitals. Japan uses diagnosis procedure
combination for acute care and case-weighted per diem for
non-acute care in both public and private hospitals, which can
be combined with FFS. By bundling together hospital and
physician payments into one unit, Japan addresses the problem
of volume and substitution (Ikegami and Anderson, 2012).
Other predominant base for payments include combinations
such as DRGs, bundled payments for public health services and
P4P in France; DRGs, global budget, central reimbursement in
Thailand; and global budget in Malaysian public hospitals. In
settings that use global budgets, prices are similarly estimated
for budget allocations.
Source: case studies (see annexes). Note: LTC: Long-term care; P4P: pay for
performance; NHS: National Health Service.
Process by
which price is
determined
4.1
Individual negotiations
Under individual negotiations, prices are agreed upon through
negotiations between individual health insurers or self-paying
patients and individual providers of health care services.
Transaction prices are the result of many discrete negotiations
often unknown to final consumers and to the public, and the
results may be treated as commercially sensitive (Reinhardt,
2006). In the USA, this is changing with recent pressures to
increase price transparency and promote consumer sensitivity
to prices (CMS, 2018).
4.2
Collective negotiations
Under collective negotiations, associations of payers (i.e.,
health insurers) negotiate with associations of hospitals doctors
or other health providers. The outcome of these negotiations
would typically be a uniform fee schedule that would apply to
all payers and providers. In some settings, overall growth in
health care spending is constrained by using macro-economic
metrics, i.e., economic growth rates, expected payroll increases,
inflation rates, increases in health care utilization, and
population growth and ageing (Reinhardt 2012b).
4 This benchmark (or shadow firm) may be set by averaging the choice among other firms in
the group. Each firm is thus forced to compete with its shadow firm. If firms are identical
or if heterogeneity is accounted for correctly and completely, the equilibrium outcome is
efficient.
5 Strictly speaking, collective negotiations and agreements prices may also follow a form of
yardstick competition.
6 These loadings may also apply to collective negotiations/agreements.
7 The all-payer approach refers to a hospital payment system in which all payers (both
public and private) pay the same rates.
Figure 13
Methods of determining price levels by base for payment and
how they may contribute to health systems objectives
Method for Controlling Avoiding price Improving Expanding Increasing price Reducing
determining price levels discrimination quality choice transparency/ administrative
price levels information costs
Individual
negotiations
0 0 ? + 0 0
Collective
negotiations
+ + ? + + +
Unilateral
administrative
++ ++ ? + + +
4.4
Process of price setting by base for payment
Using the base for payment as the starting point, Figure 14
illustrates the relationships between the base for payment and
the three administrative and economic processes by which the
price level is determined. Using this framework, we can identify
examples from the case studies and elsewhere to illustrate the
process of price setting.
Figure 14
Method of determining price levels by base for payment
Individual negotiations
between providers and A B C D
payers
Collective negotiations
between associations E F G H
of providers and payers
Unilateral administrative
I J K L
price setting
Individual negotiations USA (private health The Netherlands: USA (private health
between providers and care): outpatient hospitals. B-segment care): inpatient
payers clinics, hospitals activity services
Thailand: private The Netherlands: GPs. Germany: nursing care
for-profit hospitals for (Bundled payments for
certain conditions diabetes, COPD and
asthma)
Collective negotiations Japan, Republic of Germany: hospitals for England: primary care Japan: hospitals
between associations Korea, France: local rates (after DRG (medical, dental, eye (diagnosis procedure
of providers and payers outpatient and primary weights are set health and pharmacy) combination+ fee-for-
care unilaterally) service)
Republic of Korea: England: hospitals Thailand: primary
hospitals (blended health care
fee-for-service and
case-based payments)
England: outpatient France: acute care
care hospitals
Germany: outpatient Thailand: hospitals
care (FFS+ lump sum)
Unilateral USA (Medicare, USA (Medicare): USA (Medicaid): USA (Medicare and
administrative price Medicaid): primary care hospital inpatient and managed care Medicaid): skilled
setting outpatient care, and nursing facilities
ambulatory surgical
centres
Australia: outpatient Maryland (preferred
and primary care providers): hospital
inpatient and
outpatient care
The Netherlands: Germany: hospitals
general practitioner (DRG-weights)
payments
Australia and France:
public hospitals and
private patients in
public hospitals
The Netherlands:
hospitals. A-segment
activity (more complex
cases)
Technical process
of setting the
price per unit of
payment
5.1
Costing methods
Price levels that are too low or too high create incentives for
over- or under-utilization. This gives an incentive for purchasers
to estimate prices that reflect the actual costs of the given
service across a set of providers. There are different kinds of
costing such as activity-based costing, average costing,
standard costing, economic methods, and others. The
methodology chosen is based on the context and information
needs. For example, cost accounting methods use accounting
principles to classify and measure all costs incurred in carrying
out an activity. For provider payment purposes, decisions
usually require total or average cost information – and thus cost
accounting methods are typically applied (Cashin, 2015).
Sources: case studies (see annexes). Note: DRG: Diagnosis related group;
NHS: National Health Service; UCS: Universal Coverage Scheme in
Thailand. Information for Thailand covers hospitals and other settings.
5.2
Process of collecting information
The process of data collection for hospital activity and costs
varies widely across settings in terms of the scope of the
exercise, grouping of clinical conditions, definition of costs for
inclusion and exclusion, and sample size and frequency of data
collection (Figure 16).
In the USA, prices are established for DRGs for the Medicare
program primarily based on data about charges from individual
cost centres and costs obtained from participating accredited
providers (approximately 88% of hospitals and 40% of all
health care providers). The acute inpatient prospective
payment system pays per discharge rates based on two
national base for payment rates covering operating and capital
expenses, adjusted for patient condition and treatment
strategy. From these data, the cost per charge unit can be
generated for cost- and charge-based weights. The final cost
depends on the cost and the hospital’s ratio of cost to charges.
The DRG weights are recalibrated annually, without affecting
overall payments, based on standardized costs for all cases in
each grouping. Wage adjustments are based on market
conditions among other factors.
5.4
Changing the cost structure
Cost accounting exercises have limitations. They result in an
estimate of the average cost of service production under the
assumption that cost and production functions for health
services are fixed. They reflect how efficiently services are
being produced, existing prices, and the level of capacity and
utilization at one point in time. However, the unit costs reflect
one point on a cost curve that is unobserved. Therefore, the
“true” costs cannot be known. What may be observed is an
estimate of unit cost at one point along a function.
Aligning pricing
with overall
policy goals
Australia Adjustments are made for Adjustments are made for For population based services that
approximately 400 hospitals long-stays receiving a per diem are not described in terms of
serving small, rural or remote rate. activity, block funding is directed to
populations based on size, location states and territories to allocate to
and type of services. hospitals.
England Costs are multipled by nationally Adjustments are made for long or Adjustments are made to support
determined market forces factor short stays and specialised specific policy goals, such as
(MFF), which is unique to each services. providing care that is compliant with
provider and reflects relative best practices.
costs of care across the country.
Providers in London attract the
highest MFF.
France Geographic adjustments are made Adjustments are made both for Add-on payments are made for
only for the Parisian area (Ile-de- long and very short stays and medical education, research, and
France) and for overseas territories. specialised services. investments for improving quality of
care. Add-on payments are also
made for local public policy goals,
such as prevention, out-reach to
populations in need, etc.
Germany Recently, the government has Since 2018, 205 add-on Add-on payments are made for
initiated add-on payments to payments were made for patients medical education, specialised units
hospitals if they are located in with high needs for nursing care, and medical centres, and the
financially unattractive regions or the provision of additional delivery of care to medically
but are vital to providing medical services and pharmaceuticals, demanding patients.
services to the region. which are not included in the
DRG system yet.
Japan None. Adjustments are made for long None. Public health goods are
stays. funded from different sources (i.e.,
screening is funded by health plans
directly contracting providers, and
public health and immunizations
while funded directly by
government and through user
charges).
Republic None. Adjustments are made for long Information not available.
of Korea stays.
Thailand Adjustments are made for districts No adjustment for outliers are No adjustments are made. Such
(UCS) having higher unit costs due to made. services are mostly funded by the
sparse populations such as Ministry of Public Health.
mountainous areas or island
districts to ensure adequate
funding for operations.
USA The Medicare Wage Index accounts Outlier payments are added for Operating and capital payment rates
(Medicare) for local market conditions, by cases that are extraordinarily are increased for facilities that
adjusting national base payment costly. operate an approved resident
rates to reflect the relative input- training program (on the basis of
price level in the local market. hospital’s teaching intensity), or that
treat a disproportionate share of
low-income patients.
Australia Doctors can charge any fee to any patient at any time with
the gap between the regulated fee and the actual price
paid by the patient. In most cases, the fees charged by
general practitioners are equal to the established fees and
the patient incurs no out-of-pocket payments. For
specialists, fees are higher than regulated prices for 59%
of services.
England Published mandated prices for hospital-based care must
be used unless providers have agreed to an alternative
price, payment approach, or to a different service delivery
model. In very exceptional circumstances, providers can
make an application to National Health Service
Improvement for an increase to a nationally determined
price. Only one application has been approved to date.
France Physicians and dentists working as sector 2 contractors can
balance bill or charge higher than the regulated fees based
on their level and experience. In some cases (but not all)
the amount above the regulated price can be covered by
private complementary health insurance. Balance billing is
prohibited for emergency care and low-income patients.
USA Health providers participating in Medicare cannot balance-
bill. Non-participating providers are allowed to balance-bill
beneficiaries, but the amount cannot exceed 15% of the
Medicare-approved payment amount for non-participating
providers for each service (95% of the Medicare fee
schedule amount). For privately insured individuals, in 29
states and the District of Columbia, there are no state laws
or regulations that protect individuals from balance billing
by out-of-network providers in emergency departments or
in-network hospitals.
Infrastructure
for costing and
pricing
England National Health Service NHS Improvement regulates resource use, NHS England and NHS
(NHS) Improvement, NHS financial levers and operational performance Improvement employs
England using a shared definition of quality and efficiency approximately 7500 staff, and
by the Care Quality Commission. Their some 75 staff work in the two
responsibilities include commissioning health pricing teams.
care services in England; contracting for general
practitioners, pharmacists, and dentists;
supporting Clinical Commissioning Groups that
plan and pay for local services such as hospitals
and ambulance services; and calcuating prices.
Japan Ministry of Health, The Prime Minister sets the global revision rate Staff in the Medical Affairs
Labour and Welfare in the bieenial revision of fees and the Division number 84 in total,
(MoHLW), under the conditions of billing that establish the human including 20 physicians, 2
Bureau of Medical Affairs resource requirements and patient conditions. dentists, 2 pharmacists, 2 nurses,
The Bureau of Health Insurance serves as the and 12 career bureaucrats, with
secretariat to ensure that the cumulative effect the rest being administrative
on item revisions are made equal to the global staff.
budget. It negotiates with the Japanese Medical
Associations, hospital associations, and specialist
groups about the details of the revisions.
Republic National Health The HIRA costs and analyses provider behaviour The NHIS has about 14,000
of Korea Insurance Corporation related to pricing. One of the key institutions workers. HIRA has about 2500
(NHIS), Health Insurance under HIRA is the Healthcare Review and staff, one headquarters (22
Review and Assessment Assessment Committee, which plays an departments), one research
(HIRA), Insurance Policy important role in the benefits design, review, and institute, and seven regional
Deliberation Committee assessment. The HIPDC approves major decisions offices. The Health care Review
(HIPDC), National Health about health insurance, including contribution and Assessment Committee
Insurance Service (HIRA), rates, benefit packages, pricing, etc. The HIRA consists of approximately 1,050
Ministry of Health and each provider association (for physicians, members, with a maximum 50
hospitals, pharmacists, etc) negotiate fees. full-time members. HIRA also has
various expert committees to
support technical decisions.
Thailand National Health Security The NHSO is a state agency under the NHSO has 881 staff (464 in the
Office (NHSO), National supervision of the Public Health Minister, HQ office, and 467 in 13 regional
Health Security Board working towards the implementation of the offices). Staff generate the annual
(NHSB) Universal Coverage Scheme. The sub committee budget, monitor and purchase
on financing under the NHSB analyses the unit services, improve access and
costs, utilization rates, high cost interventions financial risk protection to its 47
and all other benefit packages as approved by million members. The total
the NHSB, and proposes a capitation budget. administrative cost is 1.49% of
total budget (average 2003-19).
Australia Independent The IHPA’s role is price determination. It takes responsibility for the For the financial year
Hospital ongoing development of the component parts required by activity- 2017/18, the IHPA’s total
Pricing based costing, the classification system (AR-DRGs and for sub-acute expenses were AUS
Authority and non-acute services in the Australian National Sub-acute and $17.9 million and 42
(IHPA) Non-Acute Patient Classification), data collection on activity (the staff were employed.
National Hospital Data Collection), calculating costs (with a standard
framework for costing activities, i.e., the Australian Hospital Patient
Costing Standards).
France Technical The ATIH is an independent public administrative institution For the financial year
Agency for co-funded by the government and national health insurance funds, 2017, the ATIH employed
Hospital under the control of the Social and Finance Ministries. It collects 118 staff and its
Information data on hospital activity in order to establish a national schedule, expenses amounted to
(ATIH) and undertakes financial analysis of health care facilities and of the EUR 29.4 million.
health system.
Germany Institute for The INEK is jointly supported by the Federal Association of Sickness All hospitals pay a DRG
the Hospital Funds, the Association of Private Health Insurance, and the German system contribution per
Remuneration Hospital Federation. It receives data from hospitals annually to hospital case, and the
System (INEK) develop the Case Fee Catalogue for the following year. A total of InEK receives 1/3rd of
253 hospitals (13% of the total) share data that follow a the total contribution to
standardized cost accounting approach to calculate the costs of fund their activities. In
treating individual patients. Participating hospitals receive a fixed 2017, the INEK’s
allowance for sharing the cost accounting data. estimated budget was
EUR 5 million. It employs
approximately 50 staff.
Maryland, Health The HSCRC works closely with the Maryland Department of Health, The HSCRC employs 39
USA Services Cost and its seven commissioners are appointed by the Maryland full-time staff, with a
Review governor. It is authorized to establish hospital rates to promote cost budget of $14.1 million
Commission containment, access to care, equity, financial stability and hospital funded by fees collected
(HSCRC) accountability. It is given broad responsibility regarding the public from hospitals.
disclosure of hospital data. All Maryland hospitals are paid on the
basis of the rates established by the HSCRC. These rates are
updated each year based on multiple factors, including the
Medicare “market basket” forecast, economic conditions,
productivity improvements, changes in case mix and the previous
year’s performance.
7.2
Formal stakeholder consultation
Many stakeholders have an interest in the outcomes of price
setting and regulation, particularly medical doctors and health
care provider associations. Lack of formal consultation and
stakeholder engagement can lead to stalemates in the price
setting process. In the case of the USA, political challenges led
to the downfall of price regulation in many states in the 1980s,
despite the positive impact of fixed prices on cost savings
(Hadley and Swartz, 1989). Feedback from health care
providers involved in care provisions may ensure acceptability
of the regulated fees. A balance must be found between
maintaining dialogue with stakeholders, including the health
industry, while also observing objectivity and independence. To
address this challenge, formal consultation processes have
been implemented that involve stakeholders in the discussion
of the base price and the cost elements that it covers.
7.3
Investments in data collection
The determination of the payment method and the collection
of data for costing is closely linked with the information that is
available. Each approach to costing requires different
information and inputs (Figure 21). Top-down costing
approaches, for example, require the availability of health
provider cost information by department and major categories
(i.e., salaries and medicines). The availability and accuracy of
this information is a determinant of how costs and prices are
calculated. Recognizing the incentives inherent in the
traditional line-item budgets, and to be able to modify payment
methods over time, investments have been made into data
collection systems to collect input costs, output volumes, and
outcomes.
One of the critical decisions in the new scheme is the decision about
provider payment mechanisms. The government decided to use a system
of package rates, whereby a fixed rate for each procedure is paid to the
hospital. The rate is fixed by the government in advance, and hospitals
are not allowed to charge any other money from the patient. No cash is
exchanged as a part of obtaining care. For medical conditions, a fixed per
day rate is paid. Similar provider payment mechanisms have been used in
India across many government funded health insurance schemes.
Currently almost 1400 packages and their rates have been fixed in
advance by the National Health Authority, an independent agency under
the Ministry of Health and Family Welfare (MoHFW) that was set up to
manage PM-JAY.
This system of package rates is a simplistic one but, at the same time, it
prevents the huge variations in prices charged by the health care
providers and keeps the cost of the scheme under the control of the
government. The government is now working on further refining these
rates and creating a mechanism for regular feedback with respect to the
list and rates. This will ensure that the rates are in sync with market
conditions. In addition, new conditions are added regularly through a
systematic process and conditions that are not required are removed.
Australia National Hospital Cost Data Detailed and average costs per episode National Indicators of Safety and
Collection Cost Reports for acute care admissions, emergency Quality in Health Care
department, non-admitted patient
(https://www.ihpa.gov.au/ (https://www.safetyandquality.gov.
expeditures, sub-acute and other
publications) au/our-work/indicators/)
products, and the pricing framework
England National Tariff Payment Costs from all secondary care providers Individual provider level reports and
System and Published Costs against currencies where they exist; broader reports from the Care
National prices for acute services and Quality Commission
(https://improvement.nhs.uk/
local pricing rules for services without
resources/national- (https://www.cqc.org.uk/)
national prices in secondary care
tariff-1719/)
France DRG prices, reimbursement DRG prices for public and private Quality, satisfaction and safety
rates for ambulatory services, hospitals for acute (non-psychiatric) indicators collected from all
and average prices charged by care, and range of prices and most hospitals and published by the
hospital/health professionals frequent amounts for out-of-pocket national health authority (HAS)
costs (before complementary health
(https://www.atih.sante.fr/ (https://www.has-sante.fr)
insurance coverage) for each hospital
tarifs-mco-et-had)
and health professionals
Germany Public reporting of DRGs, For hospital prices: relative weights All hospitals are required to
hospital base rates, hospital per condition, average length of stay, document quality information on
add-on payments, physician outlier adjustments and add-on 250 selected indicators
fee schedules, and nursing payments; for physician fees: the
(https://g-ba-qualitaetsberichte.
home rates reports on points and eurocents per service,
de/#/search)
websites of each nursing definition, detailed information on
home minimum required services and
billing restrictions
(https://www.g-drg.de)
Japan Outline of Health Care (In English), published descriptions Patient satisfaction indicators are
Insurance Systems, Ministry include patient co-payments, medical collected from all hospitals and
of Health, Labour and Social care benefits, cash benefits, premium clinics and published by the Ministry
Welfare rates and government subsidies of Health, Labour, and Welfare
(http://www.mhlw.go.jp/ (https://www.mhlw.go.jp/toukei/
english/wp/wp-hw6/dl/02e. saikin/hw/jyuryo/17/dl/kakutei-
pdf) kekka-gaiyo.pdf)
Maryland Price Transparency, Maryland Average hospital price per case, Maryland Health Care Quality
state, USA Health Care Commission’s average length of stay in the hospital, Reports
(MHCC) consumer website average hospital charges by certain
(https://healthcarequality.mhcc.
types of payers (i.e., Medicare,
(https://healthcarequality. maryland.gov)
Medicaid, Commercial, and other)
mhcc.maryland.gov)
USA Physician Fee Schedule Provides information for >10,000 Measure Management System,
Look-up, Centres for Medicare physician services, relative value units, Centres for Medicare and Medicaid
and Medicaid Services fee schedule status indicator, and
(https://healthcarequality.mhcc.
indicators needed for payment
(https://www.cms.gov/apps/ maryland.gov)
adjustment. Prices are adjusted to
physician-fee-schedule/
reflect regional variations
overview.aspx)
Republic Health Insurance and Review – Health Insurance and Review
of Korea Assessment Service Assessment Service
(http://www.hira.or.kr/) (http://www.hira.or.kr/)
Thailand Guidelines for obtaining Price, fee schedule, central price for Annual consumer satisfaction survey
health care expenses in reimbursements by Academic Network for Community
Universal Health Coverage Happiness Observation and
Scheme published annually Research, Assumption University of
by NHSO in the Thai language Thailand; NHSO Annual Fiscal Report
on accessibility and quality
(https://www.nhso.go.th/eng)
Sources: IHPA, 2019; AIHW, 2019; CMS, 2019d, 2019e; MHCC 2019;
MHLW, 2019a, 2019b; case studies (see annexes).
8.1
Investing in data infrastructure
Sound pricing and payment systems require accurate
information about costs, utilization, and quality of care.
Information systems can be one of the most important barriers
to the implementation of provider payment mechanisms in
low- and middle-income settings. DRG-based financing for
public hospitals requires substantial investments in data
collection and hospital coding. Data collection infrastructure,
coding of key information, including procedures and diagnoses,
and skilled human resources in hospitals are needed
investments for generating the minimum dataset required for
accurate analysis.
One public clinic that uses electronic medical records was selected to
conduct a costing exercise to determine the cost per visit for patients
with specific conditions. Four people developed a costing template for
each service using the patient as the cost object and collected data about
staffing medicines, medical and non-medical consumables, and
equipment and devices. The team calculated the cost of 310 separate
services grouped into 11 visit categories. The visit categories were acute
upper respiratory tract infection, prenatal care, routine child health
examination, primary care for hypertension and Type 2 diabetes, dental
exam, dental caries, fever, contraceptive management, nail removal, and
dengue rapid test. They added up the costs of services in each category
to arrive at an average cost per patient visit per category. Included in the
costs were services and supplies, assets, grants and fixed charges,
building, and land. Overhead costs were distributed by assuming average
resource use across patient types, and personnel costs were assigned
based on the average staff time spent on specific procedures.
For establishing DRGs in hospitals, the team costed all hospital inpatient
cases using a top-down approach to measure and value personnel,
medical products, overheads, and capital resource use. They plan to cost
intensive care unit stays because those stays are known to be
heterogeneous in their resource use. The team also plans to use the
bottom-up approach to cost expensive laboratory tests and radiological
interventions. Between 12 to 50 staff at ten hospitals were required to
complete the exercise over a four-month period, including one month for
verification.
8.2
Building institutional capacities
Given the technical and political complexities of price
regulation, in several settings, entities with the legal authority
to set up and control payment rates have been established. The
mandate of these agencies is to develop a credible price
schedule. This includes grouping and ordering services based
on their complexity, taking into consideration the available
health resources, burden of disease, and clinical protocols and
pathways.
8.3
Planning sequenced implementation
Particularly for settings that employ line-item budgets,
substantial long-term planning is needed to change payment
systems, estimate prices, and use prices and payment systems
to reach policy goals. Figure 25 illustrates an example of a
planning exercise to implement such changes over a period
of a few years including investing in institutional capacities
to sustain changes in how providers are paid (Özaltın and
Cashin, 2014).
Planning Analyse utilization of health Plan new formula for setting budget Establish caps and budgets based
activities services across providers. caps that gradually introduces on data about activities and
volumes. population.
Plan to gradually consolidate and Begin consolidating and reducing Flexibility given to providers to
reducing budget line items. line items for budget formulation move budgets across line items.
and implementation.
Primary Estimate population for capitation. Introduce new formula for Initiate electronic registration for
health care calculating base payment. population database for capitation.
capitation
Conduct cost analysis of PHC Introduce mechanisms to account Expand incentives for health
benefits package to estimate base for mobile and migrating promotion and disease prevention.
payment. populations.
Estimates adjustments for different Apply geographic adjustments.
regions.
Outpatient Analyse volumes and delivery for Explore bundled payment options Introduce bundled payments with
bundled acute outpatient services: day for episodes of care among different a cap, and incentives for the
payments surgery, dialysis, cancer. providers. management of chronic conditions.
Hospital Analyse current case-based Develop new case groups and Expand number of groups, adjust
payments groupings and cost per case adjustable base payments. for severity and comorbidities.
(based on distribution within each group.
DRGs)
Conduct simulations.
8.4
Establishing prices that approximate the
most efficient way of delivering care
Prices should approximate the cost of delivering services in the
most efficient way that enables quality and health outcomes.
This minimizes incentives for inappropriate levels of care and
enables accurate budget projections. Costing aims to collect
information that reveals the costs of delivering services and
providing quality patient care. To do this, different
methodologies have been used to approximate the costs of
health services and allocate indirect costs. Costing studies
should be sufficiently large to capture cost variations. In
instances where unit costs are not available, other options
include using information and experiences from other settings.
8.6
Strengthening the national role in setting
prices
While the methods for setting prices vary and are grounded in
historical developments, we can conclude that unilateral price
setting by a regulator eliminates price discrimination and
performs better in controlling growth in health care costs. In
contrast, individual negotiations between buyers and sellers
are the weakest along these same parameters. Both collective
negotiations and unilateral administrative price setting also
have the potential to improve quality better than individual
negotiations. Generally, macro-budgeting tools and limits on
the rate of budget growth have provided strong controls on
expenditures under different payment systems.
8.7
Establishing systems of ongoing revision,
monitoring and evaluation
Payment systems and price levels are being continuously
revised, particularly because there are many factors driving
prices that are not under control of health care providers such
as input costs. When a new technology is introduced,
evaluations are required to compare its impact with existing
technology. In addition, the total fiscal resources for health
continually change. At the same time, health care providers and
other stakeholders quickly adapt to the incentives (and
disincentives) inherent in each payment mechanism and try to
“game” the system to their benefit.
Anderson GF. All-payer rate setting: down but not out. Health
Care Financing Review. 1992;1991 (Suppl):35-41.
Anderson GF. From ‘Soak the Rich’ to ‘Soak the Poor:’ Recent
Trends in Hospital Pricing. Health Affairs. 2007; 26(3):780–89.
Cooper Z, Craig SV, Gaynor M, Reenen JV. The price ain’t right?
Hospitals prices and health spending on the privately insured.
National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 21815;
2018.
Wong CY, Greene J, Dolja-Gore X, van Gool V. The Rise and Fall
in Out-of-Pocket Costs in Australia: An Analysis of the
Strengthening Medicare Reforms. Health Economics. 2016;
26(8): 962-979.
www.who.int/kobe_centre/en/
Case studies
Price setting and price regulation in health care:
lessons for advancing Universal Health Coverage
Sarah L Barber, Luca Lorenzoni, Paul Ong
ISBN 978-92-4-151592-4 (WHO)
WHO/WKC-OECD/K18014
© World Health Organization and the Organisation for Economic Co-operation
and Development, 2019
Some rights reserved. This work is available under the Creative Commons
Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 3.0 IGO licence (CC BY-NC-SA 3.0 IGO;
https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/3.0/igo).
Under the terms of this licence, you may copy, redistribute and adapt the work for
non-commercial purposes, provided the work is appropriately cited, as indicated
below. In any use of this work, there should be no suggestion that the World
Health Organization (WHO) and the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development (OECD) endorse any specific organization, products or services. The
use of the WHO or OECD logo is not permitted. If you create a translation of this
work, you should add the following disclaimer along with the suggested citation:
“This translation was not created by the World Health Organization (WHO) and the
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). WHO and OECD
are not responsible for the content or accuracy of this translation. The original
English edition shall be the binding and authentic edition”.
Any mediation relating to disputes arising under the licence shall be conducted
in accordance with the mediation rules of the World Intellectual Property
Organization (http://www.wipo.int/amc/en/mediation/rules).
Suggested citation. Barber SL, Lorenzoni L, Ong P. Price setting and price regulation
in health care: lessons for advancing Universal Health Coverage. Geneva: World
Health Organization, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development;
2019. Licence: CC BY-NC-SA 3.0 IGO.
Cataloguing-in-Publication (CIP) data. CIP data are available at http://apps.who.
int/iris.
Sales, rights and licensing. To purchase WHO publications, see http://apps.who.
int/bookorders. To submit requests for commercial use and queries on rights and
licensing, see http://www.who.int/about/licensing.
Third-party materials. If you wish to reuse material from this work that is
attributed to a third party, such as tables, figures or images, it is your responsibility
to determine whether permission is needed for that reuse and to obtain permission
from the copyright holder. The risk of claims resulting from infringement of any
third-party-owned component in the work rests solely with the user.
WHO Photographs. WHO photographs are copyrighted and are not to be
reproduced in any medium without obtaining prior written permission. Requests
for permission to reproduce WHO photographs should be addressed to: http://
www.who.int/about/licensing/copyright_form/en/
General disclaimers. The designations employed and the presentation of the
material in this publication do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever
on the part of WHO and OECD concerning the legal status of any country, territory,
city or area or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers or
boundaries. Dotted lines on maps represent approximate border lines for which
there may not yet be full agreement.
The mention of specific companies or of certain manufacturers’ products does not
imply that they are endorsed or recommended by WHO and OECD in preference to
others of a similar nature that are not mentioned. Errors and omissions excepted,
the names of proprietary products are distinguished by initial capital letters.
All reasonable precautions have been taken by WHO and OECD to verify the
information contained in this publication. However, the published material is
being distributed without warranty of any kind, either expressed or implied. The
responsibility for the interpretation and use of the material lies with the reader. In
no event shall WHO and OECD be liable for damages arising from its use.
The opinions expressed and arguments employed herein do not necessarily reflect
the official views of the OECD member countries, or those of WHO.
The named authors alone are responsible for the views expressed in this
publication.
Designed and artworked in United Kingdom. Printed in Japan.
Case studies
Australia
England
France
Germany
Japan
Malaysia
Republic of Korea
Thailand
United States of America
Price setting and price regulation in health care:
Lessons for advancing Universal Health Coverage
Australia 1
Jane Hall, Maryam Naghsh Nejad, Kees Van Gool
and Michael Woods
England 31
Sue Nowak and Alberto Marino
France55
Zeynep Or and Coralie Gandré
Germany89
Jonas Schreyögg and Ricarda Milstein
Contents Japan133
Naoki Ikegami
Malaysia165
Chiu Wan Ng
Thailand219
Viroj Tangcharoensathien, Walaiporn Patcharanarumol,
Taweesri Greetong, Waraporn Suwanwela,
Nantawan Kesthom, Shaheda Viriyathorn,
Nattadhanai Rajatanavin, Woranan Witthayapipopsakul
Australia
Jane Hall, Maryam Naghsh Nejad, Kees Van Gool
and Michael Woods
University of Technology
Sydney, Australia
1
Price setting and price regulation in health care:
Australia
Abbreviations 3
Abstract 4
Background 5
1 Hospital care 9
2 Primary care 13
3 Outpatient care 17
4 Residential/long-term care 22
References 28
GP General Practitioners
Figure 1
Source of funding as share of total health expenditures
2006–07
2007–08
2008–09
2009–10
2010–11
2011–12
2012–13
2013–14
2014–15
2015–16
2016–17
0 20 40 60 80 100
1 In 2016-2017, this number was 68.7% (AIHW, 2018). The other 31.3% of total health
care expenditure in those years was funded by individuals, private health insurers, and
non-government organizations.
Figure 2
Total health expenditure percentages by funding source across
areas of expenditure (%), 2016-2017
Areas of Federal State/ Total Private Individual Other Total non- Total health
expenditure local government health government expenditures
funds expenditures
Hospitals 0.343 0.67 0.461 0.57 0.109 0.534 0.298 0.411
Public hospital 0.292 0.646 0.42 0.076 0.049 0.328 0.088 0.319
services
Private hospitals 0.051 0.023 0.041 0.494 0.06 0.206 0.21 0.093
Primary health care 0.369 0.223 0.316 0.176 0.678 0.364 0.488 0.369
Dental services 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.12 0.196 0.008 0.152 0.06
Other services 0.046 0.087 0.061 0.15 0.111 0.039 0.115 0.077
Patient transport 0.004 0.066 0.027 0.014 0.014 0.017 0.015 0.023
services
Aids and appliances 0.011 0.007 0.044 0.096 0.022 0.072 0.027
Total recurrent 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
expenditure
Source: AIHW, 2018. Note: Each column shows the share of each health
expenditure item as a total of each funding source expenditure.
Areas of Federal State/ Total Private Individual Other Total non- Total health
expenditure local government health government expenditures
funds expenditures
Hospitals 0.369 0.409 0.778 0.131 0.047 0.044 0.222 1
Primary health care 0.444 0.152 0.595 0.045 0.326 0.033 0.405 1
Source: AIHW, 2018. Note: Each column shows the share of health
expenditure item as a total of each funding source expenditure.
Figure 4
Health price index
140
130
120
110
100
2006–07 2007–08 2008–09 2009–10 2010–11 2011–12 2012–13 2013–14 2014–15 2015–16 2016–17
(a)
implicit price deflator (IPD): An index obtained using the ratio of current
price expenditure to constant price expenditure, constructed by the AIHW.
(b)
Chain price index, constructed by the AIHW.
Source: Authors using data from AIHW, 2018. Note: The implicit price
deflator (IPD) is an index obtained using the ratio of the current price
expenditure to the constant price expenditure. (a) IPD constructed by the
AIHW. (b) Chain price index constructed by the AIHW.
2 SNAP is applied to admissions for rehabilitation care, palliative care, geriatric evaluation
and management, or maintenance care.
The MBS funds primary care for all Australian citizens and
permanent residents. Under this scheme, patients are entitled
to a rebate for treatment from eligible providers who have been
issued a Medicare provider number. In the case of primary care,
providers are usually medical practitioners as well as nurse
practitioners working directly under the supervision of a
general practitioner.
3 Since 2004, Australians have also been eligible to receive benefits under the Extended
Medicare Safety Net (EMSN). This program exists for those families who have incurred
very high out-of- pocket costs during a year for out-of-hospital services. Once a family
qualifies, they are eligible to receive an amount that is higher than 100% the MBS fee.
Approximately 5% of the Australian population qualifies for the EMSN each year. Whilst
primary care consultations are covered by the EMSN, the majority of benefits (90%) are
actually directed towards specialists’ services. Further details of the EMSN and its effect
on prices will be provided in the outpatient’s specialist section of the Australian case
study.
The MBS rebate acts as a floor price for doctor fees. If the
doctor charges a fee that is equal to the MBS rebate, the patient
faces a copayment amount of zero. From the doctor’s
perspective, there is no financial reason to charge less than the
rebate. If they were to do so, the patient copayment would still
be zero, and hence would not affect demand for their service.
However, it would reduce their revenue. Although doctors have
complete discretion over their fees, it turns out that in most
cases, the fees charged by GPs are, in fact, equal to the MBS
fee. This practice is commonly known as ‘bulk-billing’. In 2017-
2018, 86% of all primary care consultations were bulk- billed,
indicating that in all these instances, the MBS fee acts as an
effective floor price and the patient incurs no out-of-pocket-
cost for the consultation.
The main difference between these items and those that were
previously listed on the MBS is that new items are more
prescriptive. The new items tend to define the type of medical
services and/or are targeted at particular types of patients
before patients are eligible to make a Medicare claim. For
example, some items can only be claimed by patients of a
certain age or with certain conditions. Items have also been
added that expand the types of professions able to claim
Medicare benefits including nurse practitioners and
psychologists working alongside GPs.
3
Outpatient care
Outpatient care in Australia is funded through a myriad of
public and private financial sources. As such, the price setting
arrangements depend very much on the funding source. In this
section, we will cover price setting arrangements for:
__ Outpatient services covered by the MBS
When doctors charge fees that are higher than the Medicare
rebate, the government’s control over pricing is limited.
per capita % $A $A $A $A
Total 15.3 86.4 53.33 61.87 8.54 63.47
While MSAC may give advice on MBS fees, it does not set them.
Once MSAC makes a positive recommendation to list a service
on the MBS, the DOH will consult with stakeholders to finalize
the MBS fee. If the final fee greatly differs from the proposed
fee considered by MSAC, then DOH reserves the right to
redirect the proposed fee back to MSAC for further
consideration.
Although the MBS covers some allied health services, these can
only be accessed under strict conditions and constrained to a
limited number of allied health professions. For example, the
MBS will cover up to 10 consultations per year with a clinical
psychologist if the patient is referred by a medical practitioner
and has a GP Mental Health Treatment Plan. Coverage of allied
health services by the MBS is a relatively recent addition, and
coverage is by no means complete. Dental and physiotherapy
services, for example, are mostly excluded from the MBS.
4
Residential/long-term care
The Aged Care Act 1997 provides the legislative authority for
funding and price setting. The next two sections describe the
relevant funding and fee setting arrangements, and the final
section explains the legal instruments and institutions.
Funding arrangements
There are four main forms of funding for residential aged care:6
__ Paying for basic daily services. This covers day-to-day living
costs such as meals, cleaning, laundry and air-conditioning.
With minor exceptions, all residents are required to pay a
basic daily fee.
__ Care funding. This is the amount received by a provider for
delivering care to the residents according to their needs.
Apart from residents with low income and assets, nearly all
residents make a financial contribution for their care
according to their capacity to pay. The government makes a
balancing subsidy payment.
Care funding
Care fee
Aged care homes can, within a wide limit, set the price of their
accommodation in the market. They must publish their
maximum accommodation prices on the government’s My Aged
Care website, their own website (if they have one), and in other
relevant materials they provide to people who are considering
becoming residents. There may be different maximum
accommodation prices for different room types in an aged care
home. The published accommodation prices are the maximum
a provider can charge, but a lower price can be negotiated.
The Aged Care Act 1997 established the position of the Aged
Care Pricing Commissioner. The Commissioner is an
independent statutory office holder appointed under the Act
who reports to the Minister.
The functions of the Commissioner are set out in the Act and
are to consider and approve extra service fees and
accommodation payments that are higher than the maximum
amount of accommodation payment determined by the
Minister.
Wong CY, Greene J, Dolja-Gore X, van Gool K. The Rise and Fall
in Out-of-Pocket Costs in Australia: An Analysis of the
Strengthening Medicare Reforms. Health Economics
2017;26(8):962-979.
England
Sue Nowak
National Health Service, England
Alberto Marino
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development, France
31
Price setting and price regulation in health care:
England
Abstract 33
Primary care 40
Acute services 42
Community and mental health 46
Contents Nursing and care home funding 47
3 Discussion 48
References 52
With a broadly static health budget in real terms over the five
years leading to 2015-2016, the NHS was asked to make
efficiency savings of 4% per year over this period, equating to
a total of £15-20 billion. A key tool for incentivising higher
efficiency has been the payment system through which NHS
commissioning bodies purchase health care from hospitals,
general practitioners (GPs) and other providers (King’s Fund,
2017a).
140
120
100
80
£ billions
60
40
20
0
2009/10 2010/11 2011/12 2012/13 2013/14 2014/15 2015/16 2016/17 2017/18 2018/19 2019/20 2020/21
Actual spending
Planned spending
Source: King’s Fund, 2018. Note: Figures are expressed in real terms at
2017-2018 prices using deflators published by the Office of Budget
Responsibility in November 2017.
£105.9 billion
£76.6 billion
1
All figures are for 2016/17.
2
Public health grant.
3
With the aim of integrating health and social care services, NHS
commissioners and local authorities pool some of their annual budgets
(around £5.8 billion in 2016/17) to create the Better Care Fund.
4
From April 2017, all CCGs have assumed some responsibility for
commissioning primary medical care services. Sixty-three have taken on
full delegated responsibility; the rest have joint responsibility with NHS
England.
5
NHS England transfers money to those CCGs that have taken on full
delegated commissioning of primary medical care services.
Directly Commissioned
100% NHS Commissioning Public Health (screening programmes, 1%
child health info, immunisation, sexual
assault) prison healthcare, armed forces
families, some specialized services 5%
87%
3.4% DH programmes
Other Primary Care
Community pharmacy, dental services,
4%
ophthalmic (eye tests, glasses)
NHS Support 5.3%
Activity
Total CCG place-based allocations
Section 7a
Public Health
Public Social Care Community Health
health including care homes, Community nursing/ other support 6%
grants drop-in centres,
Continuing Healthcare 4%
2.7% voluntary sector
Mental Health
Treatment in dedicated facilities and
other care settings, Improving Access
to Psychological Therapies (IAPT) 6.5%
2 In 2016, the NHS and local councils came together in 44 areas covering all of England to
develop proposals to improve health and care. They formed new partnerships – known as
STPs – to run services in a more coordinated way, to agree on system-wide priorities and
to plan collectively how to improve residents’ day-to-day health.
Figure 4
Commissioner-provider structure in the NHS
£
Clinical Private providers Care Quality Commission
commissioning Independent regulator for quality
groups (CCGs)
Voluntary sector
NHS England
Sustainability
and NHS Improvement
transformation GPs and other Brings together the functions previously
partnerships1 primary care undertaken by Monitor and the NHS Trust
Local authorities development Authority. it is responsible
for the financial regulation, performance
management and governance of NHS
NHS trusts and
trusts and foundation trusts, and also
foundation trusts supports service improvement
Greater
Manchester Accountable
devolution3 care systems2
1
ince December 2015 NHS providers, CCGs, local authorities and other
S
health care services have come together to form 44 STP ‘footprints’.
These are geographic areas that are co-ordinating health care planning
and delivery, covering all areas of NHS spending on services from
2016/17 to 2020/21.
2
From mid-2017, eight areas of England are evolving into accountable
care systems. This involves commissioners and providers assuming
responsibility for a budget to deliver integrated services for a defined
population.
3
From April 2016, leaders in Greater Manchester have taken greater
control of the region’s health and social care budget. This includes
taking on delegated responsibility for several commissioning budgets
previously controlled by NHS England. Other areas – including London
and parts of Surrey – are also pursuing devolved arrangements.
2
Price setting across NHS services
In this section, the current price-setting mechanisms for
primary care, acute services and community and mental health
services are described, with an emphasis on how these systems
have changed in the past decade to better align with the
objectives set out at the national level.
Primary care
Figure 5
GP practices by contract type
Acute services
The last decade has seen major reforms to the payment system
for acute and emergency services. Before 2003, hospitals in
England were paid through block contracts for most services.
These contracts specified minimum and maximum levels of
provision, with activity falling above or below these thresholds
triggering actions such as renegotiation or data validation
(Marshall, Charlesworth and Roberts, 2014). A series of reforms
in 2002 introduced the current dominant activity-based
payment scheme, initially known as Payment by Results (PbR),
and now called the National Tariff. It initially financed a small
proportion of inpatient elective hospital care, was expanded to
cover all elective care by 2006, and by 2007 covered most
acute activity, including non-elective, outpatient, and accidents
and emergencies (A&E) (Department of Health, 2012). By
2014-2015, PbR covered 67% of acute income and 60% of the
total income received by all NHS trusts (Wright et al., 2017).
3 Currencies are the unit for which a payment is made. They take a number of forms
covering different time periods from an outpatient attendance to a year of care for a
long-term condition. They include Health Resource Groups (HRGs) for inpatient spells.
Tariffs are the set prices for each currency.
Figure 6
Best Practice Tariffs
For the tariff which took effect from April 2019, England has
introduced a ‘blended’ payment approach for emergency care
taking place in acute hospitals. This comprises a fixed amount
(linked to expected levels of activity) and a volume-related
element that reflects actual levels of activity, as well as some
4 NHS Improvement is the organisation responsible for overseeing foundation trusts and
NHS trusts, as well as independent providers that provide NHS-funded care. NHS
Improvement offers support to give patients consistently safe, high quality,
compassionate care within local health systems that are financially sustainable.
Figure 7
Payment by Results (PbR) from treatment to payment
1 Treatment
– Admitted patient care, outpatients, A&E
2 Coding
– On discharge, care is coded by clinical coders
– There are separate classification systems for diagnoses
and interventions
– These codes, and other data including age and length of
stay, are recorded on the hospital’s computer system
3 Grouping
– Data are submitted to the Secondary Uses Service
– SUS assigns an HRG based on clinical codes and other
patient data
4 Tariff
– Tariff price depends on the HRG and type of admission
– There are tariff adjustments for long or short stays,
specialized care and best clinical practice
5 Money
– Providers may be paid a variable amount based on the
activity undertaken as reported through SUS
– Alternatively, monthly payments from commissioner to
provider may be agreed in advance based on an estimated
activity plan in the NHS standard contract
– Actual activity transmitted from provider to commissioner
via SUS is used to adjust these payments
5 The Mental Health Five Year Forward View (MH FYFV) sets out the plans for improving and
expanding mental health care, which continues to be central to the NHS as part of the
Long-Term Plan. The MH FYFV dashboard brings together key data from across mental
health services to measure the performance of the NHS. The dashboard provides
transparency in assessing how NHS mental health services are performing, alongside
technical details explaining how mental health services are funded and delivered.
https://www.england.nhs.uk/mental-health/taskforce/imp/mh-dashboard/
6 This is a forthcoming green paper for which no publication date has yet been decided
https://researchbriefings.parliament.uk/ResearchBriefing/Summary/CBP-8002
The current NHS payment system has evolved greatly over the
last decade and employs a mix of different payment methods
across different services and sectors. Moves away from block
budgets to activity-based payment approaches have improved
provider productivity in the acute sector. However, block
contracts are still the predominant payment mechanism for the
community and mental health sectors. Moreover, the structure
of incentives across services does little to support policy
ambitions to shift care that does not need to be delivered in
hospitals into a community setting, with the payment systems
often giving conflicting signals. The predominance of activity-
based payment in the acute sector, introduced at a time of long
waiting lists, encouraged activity in hospitals; at the same time,
block budgets in community services and capitated budgets in
primary care offer little incentive to increase activity or
enhance efficiency in these settings (Marshall, Charlesworth
and Hurst, 2014).
Figure 8
Policy objectives for DRG payment in European countries
Increase efficiency √ √ √ √
Expand activity √
Improve quality √ √ √
Control costs √
Bostock N. Map: Find out where GPs are on APMS, PMS and GMS
contracts. GPOnline; 2016. (https://www.gponline.com/map-
find-gps-apms-pms-gms-contracts/article/1401067, Accessed
1 May 2019).
King’s Fund. The NHS budget. In: The NHS in a Nutshell. King’s
Fund; 2018. (https://www.kingsfund.org.uk/projects/nhs-in-a-
nutshell/nhs-budget, Accessed 14 March 2019).
OECD. Better Ways to Pay for Health Care. OECD Health Policy
Studies, OECD Publishing. Paris; 2016.
France
Zeynep Or and Coralie Gandré
Institute for Research and Information in
Health Economics
Paris, France
55
Price setting and price regulation in health care:
France
Abstract 57
Health status 58
Health care financing 58
Health care provisions 59
Regulation and management 59
Macro-level cost containment 59
2 Price setting for ambulatory services 61
Hospital context 73
Price setting in acute care hospitals: the
DRG payment model 74
Definition of GHM tariffs 75
Using prices to regulate hospital activity 79
Payments for acute psychiatric hospital care 79
5 Price setting for rehabilitation
and long-term care (LTC) 80
Annex 1
Indicators taken into account for bundled
payments to physicians 83
References 84
Health status
France is a high-income country with relatively good health
outcomes. Compared with other industrialized countries, France
ranks high in terms of life expectancy both at birth and at
advanced age. In particular, older persons remain in better
health with one of the highest life expectancies at the age of
65 over among OECD countries (24 years for women and 19
years for men) (OECD, 2018a; 2018b). Cancer survival rates,
which are often used as a more direct indicator of the
performance of the health care system, are also high compared
with most other European countries (Eurocare, 2014). At the
same time, France suffers from a high rate of premature male
deaths from accidents and unhealthy habits (smoking and
alcoholism), and social and geographic inequalities in health
remain substantial (Lang and Ulrich, 2017).
Figure 1
Evolution of health expenditure growth against ONDAM targets
% 6
2004
5
2007
2005
4
2009
2011
3
2008 2014
2006
2017 2018
2 2010 2016
2012 2015
2013
1
0
125 135 145 155 165 175 185 195
1 When patients do not respect the gate-keeping system (médecin traitant) developed
under the 2004 Social Security Finance Act to support coordinated care pathways, the
physician is allowed to charge a supplemental fee (maximum 17.5% of the nationally
negotiated fees) that complementary insurances are not allowed to cover.
2 The attributes of doctors allowed to work in sector 2 are listed in the national agreement
and include doctors with previous public hospitals positions (former medical chief
resident, former hospital assistant, hospital practitioner appointed permanently, and
part-time practitioner with at least five years of experience) and physicians or surgeons in
the army.
Figure 2
Evolution of ambulatory care spending
Medical fees
General practitioners 5889 6054 2.8 8.1 8.4 2.6
Medical laboratories
Total 2899 2935 1.2 1.8 4.1 1
Health products
Drugs 19361 19595 1.2 11.5 27.2 1.4
First, for emergency care and when patients are covered under
low-income schemes (couverture maladie universelle
complémentaire, CMU-C, or aide au paiement d’une
complémentaire santé, ACS), balance billing is not allowed.
These schemes are partly funded by the state with the
objective of reducing the burden of cost-sharing for these
populations. Sector 2 doctors have to charge national/
negotiated tariffs to patients with CMU-C and ACS.
France
Norway
Italy
Spain
Finland
UK
Germany
Netherlands
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70
Generics as a percent of market share
2011
2015
8000
7000
6000
5000
Millions of EUROs
4000
3000
2000
1000
0
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
Figure 5
Trends in drug prices over time (Price in 2008=100 as
reference)
130
Non-reimbursed drugs
120
110
Year 2008=100
100
90
80 All drugs
70
Reimbursed drugs
60
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
1.0
Drug prices relative to the price in the USA (=1)
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
Source: Commonwealth Fund, 2019. Note: USA prices are set as reference
at 1.0
4
Price setting for acute hospital care
Hospital context
Until 2004, public and private hospitals were paid under two
different schemes. On the one hand, public and most private
not-for-profit hospitals had global budgets mainly based on
historical costs, making little adjustment for hospital efficiency.
The actual prices per GHM are not exactly equal to reference
costs. They are determined by the Ministry of Health taking into
Price setting and price regulation in health care 75
account the overall budget for the acute hospital sector
(ONDAM target expenditure) and public health priorities. In
order to contain the level of hospital expenditure, national-
level expenditure targets for acute care (with separate targets
for the public and private sector) are set by the Parliament each
year. If the actual growth in total hospital volume exceeds the
target, prices go down the following year. The growth of activity
volumes is not regulated at the individual hospital level but at
an aggregate level (separately for the public and private sector).
Prices have been adjusted downwards quite regularly since
2006, since the hospital activity volumes have been increasing
consistently faster than the targets set. Furthermore, GHM
reference costs (“raw” tariffs) are modified in an opaque way to
integrate various objectives set by the government and the SHI
fund each year when computing actual prices. For example, in
2009, ATIH noted that GHM prices were modified to adjust for
the increase in the additional budgets for specific ‘missions’,
including education, research and innovation related activities,
the growth of expenditures for additional payments on
expensive drugs, and national priorities (for cancer treatment
and palliative care) as well as the evolution of overall activity
volumes. However, it is not entirely clear how these different
elements influenced the prices of different GHM.
4
Percent annual growth
2000/05 2006/07 2007/08 2008/09 2009/10 2010/11 2011/12 2012/13 2013/14 2014/15 2015/16 2016/17
4 4
3 3
2 2
In % increase
1 1
0 0
-1 -1
-2 -2
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
Volume
Price
5
Price setting for rehabilitation and long-
term care (LTC)
4 This evaluation has to be validated by two other external medical doctors appointed by
the local county (département) and the regional health authority.
5 The GMPS score of a facility is the average pathos score (PMP) plus the average GIR score
of all residents.
Germany
Jonas Schreyögg and Ricarda Milstein
University of Hamburg
Germany
89
Price setting and price regulation in health care:
Germany
Abbreviations91
Abstract92
1 Introduction 94
3 Conclusions 125
References 129
FFS - Fee-for-service
Figure 1
Total health expenditures in current prices and price-indexed
(2000=100) from 2000-2017
400 200
350
300 150
250
Percentages
€ billions
200 100
150
100 50
50
0 0
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
10
4
Changes in %
-2
-4
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
250,000 7
200,000 5
3
150,000
2
1
100,000
0
-1
50,000 -2
-3
0 -4
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
Figure 4
SHI and PHI inpatient expenditures in current prices and
price-indexed (2000=100) from 2000 to 2017 (or latest year
available)
80 180
170
70
160
60
150
50
140
Percentages
Billion Euros
40 130
120
30
110
20
100
10 90
0 80
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
Sources: BMG, 2018a; PKV-Verband, 2017. Note: PHI expenditure data for
2017 is not available.
4
Percentage
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
Sources: BMG, 2018a; PKV-Verband, 2017. Note: PHI expenditure data for
2017 is not available.
Figure 6
Number of hospitals and total beds by bed category (2017)
Bedsize 0 1-49 50-99 100-149 150-199 200-299 300-399 400-499 500-599 600-799 800+
No. of hospitals 65 365 236 252 187 243 185 129 105 78 97
Total Beds - 7374 17 063 30 894 32 452 60 141 63 209 57 165 57 148 53 729 118 007
Figure 7
From price to budget calculation in the inpatient sector
DRG
Local Arbitration board?
Budget negotiations:
Budget generally based on last year’s budget plus 1-2% increase.
Negotiations between individual hospital and all sickness funds whose
enrollees contribute to at least 5% of bed occupancy rate.
Source: authors.
The InEK can mandate hospitals to submit cost data and select
hospitals randomly. Hospitals can sue the InEK at the
administrative court and some have made use of that option. In
2017, the InEK mandated 120 hospitals to submit data; 28
hospitals did not submit data, and 13 hospitals filed lawsuits
against the InEK. However, the first court ruling on that matter
has dismissed the case.
Once the federal base rate has been defined, each of the 16
states define their state base rates. They can deviate from the
federal base rate by -1.02% to +2.5% (€3431.93 or €3553.98).
In practice, the states increase their state base rate by the
growth factor of the federal base rate. The so-called “corridor”
within which states can deviate from the federal base rate is
also calculated by the InEK and negotiated between the DKG,
the GKV-Spitzenverband, and the PKV-Verband. It forms part of
the negotiations on the federal base rate.
Once both the state base rate and cost weights are defined,
each hospital negotiates with sickness funds, which enrol at
least 5% of the cases of the hospital’s patients, on the
hospital’s annual budget. The budget has to be approved by the
State Ministry of Health. If the parties fail to reach an
agreement, an arbitration board decides on the budget. As in
the preceding steps, parties can sue one another or the
arbitration board. In theory, budget negotiations should be
concluded prospectively for the following year. In practice,
however, this is seldom the case and negotiations tend to be
finalized between March and September of the given year. By
and large, the prospective budget equals the budget of the year
before plus 1-2%.
Figure 8
SHI and PHI outpatient expenditures in current prices and
price-indexed (2000=100) from 2000 to 2017 (or latest year
available)
40 200
190
180
30 170
160
150
Percentages
Billion Euros
20 140
130
120
10 110
100
90
0 80
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
Sources: BMG, 2018a; PKV-Verband, 2017. Note: PHI expenditure data for
2017 was not available.
12
10
6
Percentage
-2
-4
-6
-8
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
Sources: BMG, 2018a; PKV-Verband, 2017. Note: PHI expenditure data for
2017 was not available.
Figure 11
From aggregate price setting to the individual physician’s
reimbursement in the SHI system
Element Actors
Definition and interpretation of SHI’s uniform fee schedule. Assessment board of KBV
Calculation of change rate in morbidity (based on sum of and GKV-Spitzenverband.
points in preceding years, ICD codes, age and gender) and Ministry can intervene.
in investment and operating costs (Orientierungswert)
Laboratory services
Emergency services
Depreciation if necessary
Individual
Source: Adapted by the authors based on KVRLP, 2017, and KVT, 2017.
In the first step, services are split into four subgroups, namely
laboratory, emergency, primary care, and specialist services.
Primary care services are subdivided into GP services and
paediatrics, whereas specialist services are subdivided into 14
medical speciality groups. The financial volume of these groups
is distributed separately from one another. There is no financial
The medical fee schedule for PHI services is set by the German
Federal Government and has to be approved by the Bundesrat.
In 2018, one point equals €0.0582873. This value dates back
to 2001, when prices in Deutsche Mark had to be converted
into euros. It has not been adjusted since then. The PHI medical
fee schedule consists of roughly 2000 services and more than
900 add-ons for the provision of services to children, during
out-of-office hours, additional diagnostic services, and use of
additional technologies. It functions like the SHI medical fee
schedule.
The BÄK and the PKV-Verband officially began revising the fee
schedule in 2013. This reform attempts to update the schedule
to the latest state of medical innovation. It shall make the
billing of services more transparent, less disputable, and easier
to understand. Furthermore, it is expected to properly reflect
expenditures physicians incur without putting a necessary
financial burden on patients. In a first step the BÄK, the PKV-
Verband, and state representatives (on behalf of civil servants)
agree on a draft proposal which is then reviewed by the Federal
Ministry of Health. All partners have to agree on one joint
proposal, with the German Federal Ministry of Health having
the final decision-making power on the proposal. Upon
approval by that Ministry, the German Government and the
German Bundesrat jointly adopt the new medical fee schedule.
Thus far, 137 medical associations have revised the fee
schedule in working groups and commented on proposals. The
latest proposal adds 2444 new services, increasing the number
of services from 2916 to 5360 (Rheinhardt, 2018). In late 2017,
negotiations on the schedule concluded.
4
Conclusions
Thus far, Germany has given preference to high volumes and low
waiting times over cost containment and potential overprovision
of care. It entertains a high density of providers, comparatively
low prices, and reimbursement systems that support high
turnover of patients. This combination has ensured that the
country’s targets are met. This approach works well if countries
want to explore the full potential of the service provision of
their health care providers, but less so if cost containment is a
higher priority.
For the time being, the growth rate of the health care sector and
its subsectors is not anchored to the federal level as it is in the
case of England, France, or the Dutch inpatient sector. Instead,
the growth rates of the inpatient and outpatient sectors are an
aggregate of budget negotiations at lower levels. Germany
records three different ways of negotiating its healthcare
budgets. Budget negotiations in the inpatient sector and nursing
homes take place at the individual level between the respective
hospital or nursing home and the sickness funds or LTF care
funds that cover their residents or patients and are largely based
Japan
Professor Naoki Ikegami
St. Luke’s International University,
School of Public Health
Professor Emeritus, Keio University
Japan
133
Price setting and price regulation in health care:
Japan
Abstract 135
References 162
Figure 1
Defining appropriate treatment
Abstract
Always
appropriate
Sometimes
appropriate
Inappropriate
Source: author.
1 The percentage of total health expenditures (THE) to GDP jumped from 9.2% in 2010 to
10.6% in 2011. This occurred only in Japan and is probably due to the fact that virtually
all LTC insurance expenditures were first included in THE from 2011 (IHEP, 2016).
3. All CHI plans must adopt the Fee Schedule of the EHI
2 Those on public assistance are not enrolled in SHI. However, they are entitled to the same
benefits, and the providers are paid according to the fees set in the Fee Schedule.
Defines benefits
Sets price and
conditions for
billing
90%+ of providers’ revenue from
services delivered at prices set by
Fee Schedule
Source: author.
The fees are officially set by the Ministry of Health, Labour and
Welfare (MHLW) and are revised every two years based on the
decisions made by the Central Social Insurance Medical Council
of the MHLW.3 This Council is composed of seven members
from payers (SHI plans, business and labour groups), seven
members from providers, and six members who represent
public interests (academics), plus ten specialist members
(representing nurses, pharmaceutical and device industries,
etc.). However, council members do not vote. Indeed, the six
members representing public interest are not allowed to speak
unless asked by the chair (Morita, 2016). The Council exists to
authorize negotiations that the MHLW officials in the Medical
Affairs Division of the Health Insurance Bureau have made with
provider organizations, such as the JMA, hospital associations,
and specialist groups.
3 Services not listed in the Fee Schedule include normal delivery (when SHI was first
legislated, the enrollees were manual workers and male) and preventive services such as
health screening. Services covered by accident insurance and other publicly funded
programs use the fee schedule.
4 The revenue from extra-charge beds and from preventive screening services are 1% each.
8% comes from non-health care activities. This ratio is 16% in local government
hospitals because of subsidies, but is only 2% in private hospitals (earnings from
investments). Disease-specific hospitals (such as for psychiatry) and hospitals that derive
2% or more of their revenue from LTC Insurance services are excluded from these data
(MHLW, 2017b).
The same fee is set for the same service throughout Japan. As
previously explained, when the Fee Schedule was first
introduced, the conversion rate of the points to yen differed
according to the volume of services that had been delivered in
each prefecture. However, the conversion rate became fixed in
1943 regardless of the volume. At that time, there were three
rates reflecting urban-rural differences in the cost of living. This
was reduced to two rates in 1948 and became one rate in 1963.
The fact that fees are nationally uniform may have contributed
to a more equitable distribution of physicians and nurses. All
facilities receive the same fee for delivering the same service.
Out of this revenue, big city hospitals can recruit physicians at
relatively low wages because they offer non-monetary rewards,
such as allowing them to focus on their sub-specialty and to
use high-tech equipment. However, they must pay nurses
higher wages because the cost of living is higher. In rural
hospitals, the reverse is true: there are higher wages for
physicians and lower wages for nurses. Supporting data are
available from public hospitals. In hospitals established by big
cities (over 700 000 inhabitants), the annual wages were 13.6
million yen for physicians and 5.1 million yen for nurses. In
hospitals that are established by towns and villages (less than
30 000 inhabitants), the wages were 17.9 million yen for
physicians and 4.6 million yen for nurses (MIAC, 2017).
Although there are no data for private sector hospitals, the
differences are likely to be greater because their wages tend to
be less seniority based.
The extent to which paying the same fee for the same service
item has contributed to a more equitable geographical
distribution of physicians and nurses is difficult to evaluate.
However, as a method, it is simpler than setting fees to reflect
the cost of living and then paying a bonus to physicians who
work in rural hospitals. Currently, the age-adjusted per capita
__ E. Imaging
__ G. Injections
__ H. Rehabilitation
__ I. Psychiatric treatment
__ K. Surgical operations
__ M. Anesthesia
__ L. Radiation therapy
__ M. Pathological diagnosis
For equipment, fees are based more on their efficacy and less
on costs. When magnetic resonance imaging (MRI) was first
listed in 1982, its fee was set at twice that of computed
tomography (CT) scans. At that time, the price of purchasing a
MRI equipment was more than ten times that of purchasing a
CT scanner (Hisashige, 1994). However, despite the low fee,
providers purchased MRI equipment because it attracted more
physicians and patients to the hospital. Meanwhile, the
manufacturers gradually lowered the price of MRI equipment,
which led to more hospitals purchasing the equipment. Thus,
market forces have worked even when fees were regulated, and
probably worked better because they were regulated.
6 For this reason, dispensing used to be done by hospitals and clinics. However, the profit
margin has decreased, while the fee that physicians can bill if they dispense to a
free-standing pharmacy has increased. The ratio of prescriptions dispensed within
hospitals and clinics has declined to 30% of the outpatients’ prescriptions (Federation of
Social Insurance Associations). However, many of the pharmacies have strong ties with the
hospitals and clinics that write the prescriptions. To discourage this trend, dispensing fees
are reduced if the proportion of prescriptions from one hospital or clinic is more than
70% of the total number.
Medical devices
7 The method for revising pharmaceutical Fee Schedule prices has changed. When the
survey-based method was first introduced in 1967, it was set at the 90th percentile from
the lowest price; it became the 81st percentile in 1983 and, from 1987, was based on the
volume-weighted average. The allowable margin (the “reasonable” zone concept) was
introduced in 1994 in response to demands from the United States to make the
transaction process more transparent as part of the Market Oriented Sector Selective
negotiations. The “reasonable” zone was initially set at 15% but has since been gradually
decreased to the present 2% from 2000.
The first step is deciding the global revision rate, which sets a
de facto global budget for all SHI and public expenditures in
the next fiscal year. Next year’s expenditures are determined by
the equation below:
This year’s expenditures Ú[1 + (the
increase rate from population ageing
Next year’s expenditures =
+ the increase rate from “other”
factors) ± (global revision rate)]
8 Pharmaceutical and device prices will be revised annually from 2018 so that any
decreases in market price are reflected more quickly in the Fee Schedule. The first
revision in which they are revised independently from service fees will be made in 2019.
100~
95-99
90-94
85-89
80-84
75-79
70-74
65-69
60-64
55-59
50-54
45-49
40-44
35-39
30-34
25-29
20-24
15-19
10-14
5-9
0-4
0 20 40 60 80 100 120
(in 10,000 Yen)
9 The greatest decrease so far was in 2006. The -3.16% revision rate was blamed for the
closing of hospitals, resulting in newspaper headlines such as the “collapse of the
healthcare system.” Decreases of this magnitude would be politically difficult to make in
the future.
In making this decision, the following two factors play key roles.
One is the market survey of pharmaceutical prices. If the survey
shows that the cumulative volume weighted market price of
pharmaceuticals is 8% below the Fee Schedule price, then
after allowing for the 2% margin, cumulative prices will be
reduced by 6%. This 6% reduction will increase the global
budget for medical services by 1.5%, because pharmaceuticals
compose about one quarter of medical expenditures. In
addition, there will be further savings by reducing the prices of
new products that have sold more than the amount estimated
by the manufacturer. These savings have been used to negate
or soften the impact of decreases in the global revision rate.
However, in the 2020 Fee Schedule revision, they would have
less impact because pharmaceutical prices would already have
been revised in 2019 to reflect the results of the 2019 market
price survey.10
10 Service fees will be revised together with pharmaceutical prices in October 2019,
because of the introduction of the consumer tax. This tax is not levied on health care
services so that fees and prices listed in the fee schedule must be increased to pay for the
additional costs incurred by the providers.
11 With the exception of local government hospitals (as noted in reference 4), the proportion
of subsidies is small. National hospitals have not received subsidies after they were
reorganized into the National Hospital Organization in 2004 (Ikegami, 2014).
Note that even small changes would have a big impact on costs
if the volume is large (such as repeat consultations), while big
changes would have little impact if the volume is small (such as
complicated surgical procedures). Revisions could be targeted
on specific items. For example, MRI fees have generally been
decreased because their volume has increased rapidly, and
because the price of purchasing a MRI equipment had been
driven down as manufacturers competed to sell their products.
The MHLW reported that increases in expenditures were
blunted when fees were reduced by 30% in 2006 (MHLW,
2018c). Reductions of this magnitude had to be made to
contain expenditures to the amount set by the global revision
rate of -3.16%. Since then, fees have been increased for MRI
equipment that have higher density in their imaging. These
increases have been offset by reducing the fees of MRI
equipment that have low density.
Note that the lobbying continues to the last minute so that the
precise details of the conditions of billing may not be finalized
Price setting and price regulation in health care 153
until the middle of March annually, just before the revision is
implemented in April 1, when the new fiscal year begins. This
means that software vendors of claims data must work day and
night to reprogram their claims software. Hospital directors
must estimate their revenue in the revised Fee Schedule, which
may change the method of billing or how services are
delivered.
12 Because service fees and pharmaceuticals are combined in DPC, the global revision rate is
used for revising the DPC base rate.
A } 15% A=B
B
15% or the average input amount of medical
50 percentile
Fee-for-service
15 Only hospitals that have less than 200 beds may bill these higher fees. Small hospitals
had insisted sub-acute and post-acute care should be reserved for them and not for units
in big hospitals.
Malaysia
Chiu-Wan Ng
Centre for Epidemiology and Evidence Based
Practice
Department of Social and Preventive Medicine
Faculty of Medicine
University of Malaya
Malaysia
165
Price setting and price regulation in health care:
Malaysia
Abbreviations 167
Abstract 168
1 Introduction 169
5 Conclusions 192
References 193
B40 Bottom 40
RM Ringgit Malaysia
UM University of Malaya
By and large, fees are set by the Ministry of Health (MoH), and
the fees are enforced through legislations. Health care in the
public sector is subsidized by the GoM using general taxation
(Ministry of Health, 2017b). Such public funding is substantial
and over the past two decades has paid for more than half of
the annual total health expenditures (THE) of the country. The
application of user fees in the public sector has enabled cost
sharing to be progressively increased over time, although to
date, such fees are still much lower than needed for cost
recovery.1 This is in line with GoM’s stated welfare objectives of
affordable public care and the need to maintain the public
sector as the safety net for the poor (Rohaizat, 2004). The basis
for the regulation of user fees in the private sector, which is
predominantly funded through out-of-pocket payments
(OOPPs), was to ensure the affordability of care. However,
legislated private medical fees cover only the professional
fees2 charged by health care professionals. Thus, only a portion
of total bills incurred by patients using private health care
facilities is regulated. It has become apparent that the
regulation of private medical fees as practiced in Malaysia has
not been able to contain rising costs of private health care and
that high private medical bills are a barrier to private health
care for many (The Edge Financial Daily, 2017).
1 For example, the fee for a general outpatient clinic visit obtained from a public clinic was
just RM (Ringgit Malaysia) 1, or approximately US$ 0.23, in 2017. Payment of this fee
would entitle the patient to a medical consultation, simple laboratory investigations and
medication for two weeks.
2 Fees paid to health care professionals, predominantly doctors and dentists for the
conduct of medical consultations or procedures, including the interpretation of radiology
and laboratory tests. Professional fees exclude that portion of hospital bills for hotel
services such as for food and accommodation and fees for the use of equipment and
facilities such as operating rooms and drugs.
2
Malaysian healthcare system
3 All 13 states were former British colonies. In 1957, the 11 states in the Malay Peninsula
achieved independence from British rule and formed the Federation of Malaya. Malaysia
was formed in 1963 when Sabah, Sarawak and Singapore joined the federation. In 1965,
Singapore left the federation.
4 The other four states are ruled by Governors who are appointed by the Yang di-Pertuan
Agung.
5 Bumiputera, a Malay term meaning ‘prince of the earth’, refers to the combined grouping
of the orang asli and people from the Malay ethnic group. The term orang asli refers to
diverse groupings of indigenous tribes residing in the Malay Peninsula as well as in the
states of Sabah and Sarawak.
6 Majlis Amanah Rakyat (MARA), or People’s Trust Council, is a government agency set up to
aid, train and guide bumiputeras in the areas of business and industry.
Figure 1
Distribution of hospitals and doctors working in the public and
private sectors in Malaysia, 2016
7 GLCs are defined as companies that have a primary commercial objective and in which the
GoM has a direct controlling stake and not just percentage ownership.
8 These GLCs include IHH Healthcare Berhad, a subsidiary of the Khazanah Nasional Berhad,
the federal government sovereign wealth fund and KPJ Healthcare Berhad, a public-listed
company belonging to the Johor Corporation, the investment arm of the Johor state
government. Other state governments, including the Terengganu and Malacca state
governments, are also involved in providing private health care. Sime Darby, another GLC,
owns hospitals through Ramsay Sime Darby, a joint venture with Ramsay Health Limited,
an Australian company.
9 Mahathir Mohammad first served as the fourth Prime Minister of Malaysia from 1981 to
2003. In May 2018, he was again appointed to the same position as the seventh Prime
Minister of the country.
10 The full speech can be downloaded from http://unpan1.un.org/intradoc/groups/public/
documents/apcity/unpan003223.pdf.
Figure 2
Public and private health financing sources, Malaysia 1997 to
2015
30 5
24 4
Real health expenditures (billion 2010 RM)
18 3
12 2
6 1
0 0
1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
The rapid expansion of private health care since the 1980s has
generally been welcomed. The GoM intends for the private
sector provision to complement the public sector provision of
medical services especially for those who can afford private
care. However, the GoM saw fit to add that legislations should
be reviewed to ensure that the profit motive would not
compromise quality and accessibility to private care.
Subsequently, a new legislation governing the provision of
private medical care, the Private Healthcare Facilities and
Services Act (PHFSA), was enacted in 1998 to “improve access
to health care, correct imbalances in standards and quality of
care as well as to rationalize medical charges in the private
health sector to more affordable levels” (Government of
Malaysia, 1996: p. 549). The GoM also made known its intention
to reform the country’s health care financing system to provide
“consumers with a wider choice in the purchase of health
services from both the public and private sectors” (Government
of Malaysia, 2001: p. 495). However, to date, there has been no
major reforms to the country’s financing system which has
provided public funding to support the public provision of care
and in turn, contributed to the achievement of universal health
coverage (UHC).
3
Setting medical fees in the private sector
13 Information on MAS within the MoH was obtained from a paper entitled, “Micro
Accounting System for Costing of Services” presented by Mr Tan Eng Hock, Secretary of
the Finance Division, MoH at the Conference of Directors, MoH held from 15th to 17th April
1998.
14 Information on the use of case-mix systems was obtained from the MoH.
15 An exception was made for fees collected from the FPP scheme. The Ministry of Finance
has clarified that the portion of fees meant to be paid to attending doctors could be
maintained in a trust fund and eventually be disbursed to the doctors concerned.
3. Fees for patients using the Full Paying Patients (FPP) services
18
were gazetted in 2007 (Government of Malaysia, 2007).
16 T&CM based on Malay, Chinese, Indian, Orang Asli and complementary medical practices
co-exist with Western allopathic medical practices in Malaysia. T&CM care is mainly
available in the private sector and is mostly paid for using OOPPs. The MoH has provided
a limited range of T&CM services, such as Chinese acupuncture, Malay massage, Indian
ayurvedic therapy, chiropractic and Chinese herbal oncology services in selected
hospitals since 2007. It was only in 2017 that the fees for these services had been
gazetted. Prior to that, the services had been provided for free.
17 All citizens above the age of 12 years are issued a Malaysian Identity Card, known as
MyKad. These cards are used as proof of citizenship during patient registration processes.
Birth certificates are used for the same purpose in the case of children.
18 Patients who choose to use the FPP services in MoH hospitals are provided with
additional services such as being allowed to choose their doctors and staying in better
appointed rooms.
Outpatient Care
Clinica RM 1 RM 40 nab
For the 2017 fee revision, a policy decision was made to focus
on revising the fees set for patients in first and second class
wards. Since the precise cost of providing MoH services is not
known, the general principle guiding the exercise had been that
patients should not have to pay higher fees for care in MoH
hospitals compared to private hospitals for the same medical
condition. MoH officers had surveyed fees charged in private
hospitals for a sample of common medical conditions. In 2017,
the fees for services provided to patients opting for first class
wards were eventually raised by 50% and fees for patients in
second class wards were raised by 25% from the fees set in
1982 (figure 4).
1982 2017
Outpatient Care
Clinica RM 1 RM 1
- Single bed RM 60 RM 90
- Two beds RM 40 RM 60
Second Class RM 20 RM 25
Third Class RM 3 RM 3
22 Since the actual cost of care in MoH hospitals is not fully known.
23 Consultation fees are fees for consultation by a specialist to any patient that may include
examination or comprehensive treatment planning.
24 Treatment fees are fees for any therapeutic service provided to any patient.
The first edition of the MMA fee schedule was released in 1987
(Committee on Health Insurance, 1987) and listed professional
fees in four categories outpatient primary care consultations,
outpatient specialist consultations, procedural fees charged by
doctors and miscellaneous services such as the preparation of
medical reports. The second edition of the fee schedule was
released in 1992, the third in 1997, the fourth in 200226 and
the fifth in 2008 (Malaysian Medical Association, 2008).
27 GPs refer to non-specialist doctors who provide private primary care services usually on
outpatient basis.
Outpatient Care
Non-specialist RM 10 – RM 35 RM 10 – RM 35 RM 30 – RM 125
consultation
Specialist RM 60 – RM 180 RM 60 – RM 180 RM 80 – RM 235
consultation
(1st visit) (1st visit) (1st visit)
RM 35 – RM 90 RM 35 – RM 90 RM 40 – RM 105
28 In general, profits from the sale of pharmaceuticals are retained by the private hospitals
and not shared with health care professionals.
Discussion
Private hospital bills affect not just the patients who pay OOPP
for care, but also health insurers. The most common form of
medical and health insurance (MHI) is hospitalisation and
surgical indemnity insurance policies, which provide for the
reimbursement of medical, surgical and hospitalisation
expenses incurred by those insured. In 2005, about 15% of the
population had some form of health insurance cover (Central
Bank of Malaysia, 2005: p. 58). By 2014, the coverage increased
to 45% of the population, or about 14.7 million people
(Malaysian Productivity Corporation, 2016: p.112). It is
important to note that people in Malaysia buy health insurance
mainly to gain access to private care (Chan, 2014). This is due
to the general perception that private care is of higher quality
compared to care received from public providers. Private
insurers are wary of private hospitals charging insured patients
higher fees for the same level of care compared to those who
do not have insurance coverage (Chan, 2014; Lee et al., 2018).
Thus far, the law has not provided protection from such
practices since legislated professional fees cover only a portion
of total hospital bills. The MoH is aware of the need to close
this loophole in the law, not just to protect third party payers
such as insurers but also the public at large. In 2018, the
previous Minister of Health announced that the ministry is
exploring the option of a ‘bundling system’ for private hospital
fees (Sundaily, 18th January 2018). Such ‘bundles’ would
include all fees, professional or otherwise, for a package of
care. He acknowledged that the task was not easy and involved
consultations with all stakeholders, including the Central
30 The rest mainly by-passed one category of public facilities for another.
Insurers may feel that they have valid reasons to call upon the
MoH to help them control patient bills. On the flip side, some
doctors have also raised concerns that certain insurance
practices place them at a disadvantage resulting in an unfair
reduction of income. This issue relates to their dealings with
Managed Care Organisations (MCOs), which include insurers.
MCOs in Malaysia work on behalf of companies or insurers to
help them contain health care costs of their employees or
those insured. It has been estimated that the market for MCO
services grew from a coverage of 300 000 persons in 1997 to
16.36 million in 2014 (Malaysian Productivity Corporation,
2016: p. 99). The modus operandi of MCOs is to recruit and
appoint private hospitals and clinics as their panel providers to
service their enrollees. In return for the promise of high patient
volume, these companies would negotiate for lower fees, which
invariably affect the professional fees charged by doctors. This
is permitted under the law, as legislated private fees are the
maximum allowed for the service charged. Doctors under
contract to work in private hospitals have no choice but to
accept the lower fees negotiated by the hospital management.
In order to gain a share of the patient pool, GPs have had to
acquiesce to the MCOs’ demand for lower fees as well. GPs
working in standalone clinics are particularly hit hard. GP fees
were legislated in 2006, and the fees for GP consultations were
between RM 10 to RM 25 (Government of Malaysia, 2006b).
Unlike legislated fees for private hospitals, which were revised
in 2013, GP fees have remained unchanged since 2006. It was
claimed that the allowable fees have not kept up with the
increasing clinic maintenance costs (Malaysian Productivity
Corporation, 2016: p.106). To make matters worse, there is now
a discrepancy in GP fees between doctors who work in private
hospitals (RM 35 to RM 125, as stated in the 2013 private
hospital fee revision) and those working in standalone clinics
(RM 10 to RM 35, as per the 2006 private GP regulations). The
MoH has announced that it will look into revising these fees to
assuage discontent among GPs (The Star, 5th October 2018). In
January 2019, the MoH announced a scheme to buy care from
GPs as a move to expand health screening services for the poor.
However, progress has stalled because the GPs rejected the
proposal by the MoH to use the 2006 fees as the basis for
negotiations (The Malay Mail, 2nd February 2019).
31 Bank Negara Malaysia, or the Malaysian Central Bank, is the regulator of all banking and
insurance activities in the country.
Lee KH, Raja Ariffin RN, Nik Rosnah WA. The implications of
legislative controls on private hospitals in Malaysia. Institutions
and Economies 2018;10:62-94.
The Star. Dad to donate kidney to son but needs RM100,000 for
transplant. 4th November 2011.
The Star. Babies need funds for heart operations. 22nd April
2012.
The Star. A father pleads for help to save his baby. 24th June
2009.
Republic
of Korea
Soonman Kwon
Seoul National University
Republic of Korea
197
Price setting and price regulation in health care:
Republic of Korea
Abstract 199
References 216
Abstract Since 2000, the National Health Insurance Service (NHIS) and
each provider association (physicians, hospitals, pharmacists,
etc.) negotiate the fees. When negotiations fail, the tripartite
Health Insurance Policy Deliberation Committee (HIPDC)
decides the fee. Health Insurance Review and Assessment
(HIRA) also plays an important role in costing and analyzing
provider behaviour related to pricing. Pricing for health care is
based predominantly on FFS, with the exception of Diagnosis
Related Group (DRG)-based payment for six disease categories
and per-diem case-based payment for long-term care (LTC)
hospitals as well as the piloting of a mixed payment of DRG,
FFS and per-diem payment. There is no bundled payment
system to cover the services given by the different levels of
providers.
2
Governance of Price Regulation
In the single insurer system established after the merger, major
decisions on health insurance, such as contributions and
benefits coverage, became a national agenda and required a
new policy framework (Kwon, 2003a). NHI introduced an annual
price negotiation between the insurer and provider associations,
replacing the unilateral price setting by the insurer and the
MoHW. Initially, NHIS negotiated the annual increase in fee with
the coalition of provider associations, i.e., both medical and
hospital associations. Because it was difficult to get consensus
among all provider associations, these negotiations rarely
succeeded. This condition changed after negotiations were
changed to occur between the NHIS and individual provider
associations. The negotiation is on price only, without
consideration of volume or a sectoral/overall spending cap.
Price setting and price regulation in health care 201
After experiencing a big financial deficit in 2001 as a result of a
fee hike for physicians after their strikes against pharmaceutical
reform (Kwon, 2003b), the health insurance system introduced
HIPDC, which approves major decisions on health insurance,
such as the contribution rate, benefit packages, pricing, etc.
When the annual negotiation on price increase fails between
NHIS and each provider association, e.g., medical, hospital,
dental, traditional medical, pharmaceutical, etc., HIPDC makes
the final decision on fees.
3
Provider Payment Systems and Pricing
The FFS system has led not only to an increase in volume and
intensity of services, but also to the provision of services with a
greater margin and even a distortion in the supply of medical
specialties in the long run. For insured services, physicians are
not allowed to charge more than the fee schedule set by NHI
(i.e., no balance billing). However, physicians can provide both
insured and uninsured services in the same episode of care/
visit and charge high fees for uninsured services (so called,
extra billing) to compensate for the low pay by the tight fee
schedule for insured services.
Case-based Payment
The current P4P model focuses too much on clinical quality and
should be extended to other important performance measures
such as the length of stay, intensity of care, etc. How to use the
P4P framework to improve the quality of primary care is a
concern too. P4P in Korea currently targets areas where it is
easier to measure performance, rather than areas that have the
most serious quality issues. Furthermore, participants are
mainly big hospitals, not because they have the most serious
quality problem, but because their performance is easier to
assess or they have less problems of reporting compared to
small-scale providers. In the future, P4P based on hospitals
should take into account the performance of individual
physicians.
4
Institutions for Cost Estimation and Price
Setting
Price reimbursement to providers by NHIS is supposed to cover
both capital and operating costs, although providers argue that
the price is below the cost of production such that they incur a
loss. Physicians argue that they have incentives to provide
uninsured services, for which they can charge market/
customary prices, to compensate for losses from insured
services. However, there is little scientific evidence to support
the providers’ argument regarding the fairness of NHIS
payments. To the contrary, admission to medical schools has
become more and more competitive, and the entry into the
hospital market has increased with a comparatively very small
number of exits, all of which indicate that the physician and
hospital services markets are very lucrative.
5
Review and Monitoring of Provider
Behaviour
Currently, Korea has a sufficient supply of providers who cannot
survive without participating in NHI (in the system of universal
population coverage). However, NHI needs to re-consider the
mandatory participation of providers. The policy of mandatory
participation and no selective contracting limits the single
payer NHI to exercise its bargaining power in the selection of
providers and maintaining quality of care. The compulsory
participation of providers in NHI has been a politically sensitive
and controversial issue. Progressive civic groups are worried
that the abolition of the mandate on providers will lead high-
quality hospitals to not join NHI. Under universal coverage of
the whole population, even leading tertiary care hospitals do
not have financial incentives to opt out of NHI.
6
Performance and Effects of Price Setting
The effect of price setting seems limited, as providers can
increase volume under FFS. In health systems where FFS is the
major type of provider payment system without a macro-level
spending cap and where the majority of providers are private,
cost containment is a huge challenge. The number of outpatient
visits in Korea is the highest and the length of stay for inpatient
care is the second highest (after Japan) among OECD countries
Figure 1
Average number of outpatient visits per patient per year
(2015)
Korea
Japan*
Hungary
Slovak Republic
Germany
Turkey
Netherlands
Canada
Spain*
Australia
Poland
Belgium
Slovenia
Austria
Estonia
France*
Iceland*
Latvia
Luxembourg
Ireland
Denmark
Finland
Norway
Chile*
Sweden
Mexico
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16
Japan
Korea
France*
Hungary
Finland
Czech Republic
Luxembourg
Germany
Portugal
Austria
Switzerland
Latvia
Italy
Belgium*
Estonia
Poland
Spain
Slovak Republic
United Kingdom
Israel
New Zealand*
Slovenia
Norway
Ireland
Iceland
United States*
Sweden
Chile*
Australia*
Denmark
Mexico
Turkey
0 5 10 15 20 25 30
Number of days
212
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Australia
Austria
Belgium
Canada
Chile
Czech Republic
Denmark
Estonia
Finland
France
Germany
Greece
Hungary
Iceland
Ireland
Tax
Israel
Figure 3
Italy
Japan
Out-of-pocket
Korea
Latvia
Luxembourg
Norway
Other
Private Insurance
Slovenia
Spain
Sweden
Switzerland
Turkey
United Kingdom
United States
Figure 4
Average annual rate of increase in health expenditure (2007-
2016)
Chile
Korea
Sweden
Australia
Israel
Poland
Switzerland
Japan
United Kingdom
Ireland
Czech Republic
New Zealand
Norway
Estonia
Canada
United States
Belgium
Turkey
Germany
Luxembourg
Netherlands
Mexico
Slovak Republic
Austria
France
Slovenia
Finland
Denmark
Spain
Hungary
Iceland
Italy
Latvia
Portugal
Greece
-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
7
Key Lessons
Many middle-income countries (MICs) are experiencing an
increase in private providers. Because the majority of health
providers are private in Korea, the Korean experience of pricing
of health services can provide important policy lessons for
MICs. From the very beginning of NHI, Korea implemented a
strict price regulation with no balance billing, and providers
were not allowed to opt out of NHI. Since the merger of all
insurance funds to a single insurer system in 2000, a
specialized agency was introduced, which has sophisticated
systems of claim review and assessment based on state-of-the-
art ICT. However, a private sector-oriented health system, where
providers are paid by fee-for-service and price regulation does
not take volume into consideration, seems vulnerable to cost
inflation.
Thailand
Universal
Coverage Scheme
Viroj Tangcharoensathien*
Walaiporn Patcharanarumol*
Taweesri Greetong **
Waraporn Suwanwela**
Nantawan Kesthom**
Shaheda Viriyathorn*
Nattadhanai Rajatanavin*
Woranan Witthayapipopsakul*
219
Price setting and price regulation in health care:
Thailand Universal Coverage Scheme
Abbreviations 221
Glossary of terms 222
Abstract225
Background 227
Objective and scope 227
Annexes 251
References 253
RW Relative Weight
Blend model: The blend model is the way public and private
providers are paid by NHSO and uses multiple methods that
have policy goals for improved access and cost containment in
mind. The main modes of the blend model are age-adjusted
capitation for outpatients, DRG and global budget for inpatient
care, fee schedule for specific high cost interventions outside
capitation and DRG systems, and disbursement of high cost
medicines and certain medical devices by NHSO. These fee
schedules also apply to the global budget.
Full cost subsidy: The money paid to health care providers for
the full cost of production including salary, material and capital
depreciation. Balance billing is not allowed.
The per capita UCS budget is estimated based on the unit cost
of a comprehensive benefits package (outpatient, inpatient,
Abstract high cost care, prevention and health promotion) and the
respective utilization rates. The annual UCS budget is a full cost
subsidy, as the unit cost covers labour, material and capital
depreciation cost, and no copayment. Balance billing is not
allowed and strictly monitored and sanctioned. The full cost
subsidy has justified the termination of supply-side financing
since the inception of UCS. Annual budget allocations to
government health facilities are curtailed except for major
capital outlays. NHSO and partner institutes have developed
skills in conducting conventional costing exercises and quick
methods for annual adjustments of unit costs and
strengthening data on utilization rates.
When the budget estimate for UCS is a full cost subsidy to all
providers for the agreed benefits packages, there is no need for
copayment by users. Hence, balance billing is forbidden and
made known to both providers and patients. In the case of
balance billing, the hospitals are legally enforced to return the
amount to patients. Although a copayment of B 30
(approximately US$ 1) per outpatient visit or per admission
with an exemption to the poor was introduced in 2002, it was
terminated in 2006 due to political reasons and also to protect
the borderline poor from copayment and facilitate improved
access. The revenue from copayment was small, around 1-2%
of the total UCS annual budget, while the administrative cost of
copayment collection and the exemption mechanism of the
poor (which must be reviewed every three years through means
testing surveys) was much larger. Unlike fee-for-service, the
closed end provider payment does not send any signal towards
supplier-induced demand; therefore, copayments to discourage
unnecessary service utilization by patients are not required,
since abuse by the providers is not expected. The monitoring of
balanced billing was managed through a consumer voice
hotline, 1330, which is a twenty-four-hour service provided by
the NHSO and effective sanction for demanding copayment.
The NHSO manages successfully so that the amount of balance
billing or copayment is returned to the patients. Full payment
by offering services outside the benefits package was
uncommon, as UCS benefits packages had covered almost all
cost-effective high cost interventions through regular updating
of the benefits package.
Unit cost
The unit cost for outpatient and inpatient services is a full cost
estimation based on a conventional costing method (cost
centre approach and simultaneous equation of indirect cost
allocation), which includes staff costs, all operating costs such
as medicines and diagnostics, and capital depreciation cost
(Ngamkiatphaisan, 2005). The unit cost for the estimate of B
1202 per capita budget was based on the cost weight
generated from conventional costs in less than 20 public
hospitals to allow for a quick costing method.
The cost weight, a ratio between unit cost per admission and
unit cost per visit from conventional costing, is applied to
estimate the unit cost using the “Quick Costing Method”
principle, as expressed in the following formula:
unit cost per admission = cost weight x unit cost per outpatient visit
Institutional capacities
Stakeholder Involvements
Figure 2
Stakeholder participation in the UCS budget
General opinion
[S.18(10) (13)] The draft of Suggestion and
annual UCS Recommendation
budget proposal [S.39]
Other
Financial management Standard and Quality Ministry of
Subcommittees
Subcommittees under Control Board Finance
under NHSB
NHSB
The Budget
Bureau
The draft of annual
Suggestion
Academic and
Stakeholder
Source: Authors’ synthesis from National Health Security Act B.E. 2545
(A.D. 2002)
In 2016, the per capita budget approved by the Budget Bill was
B 3,344.17. This consisted of the core benefits package of
B 3,028.94 per capita (Item A in Figure 3) and specific
interventions of B 315.23 per capita (Item B in Figure 3).
A6. Thai Traditional Medicines 0.3 Point system with Global Budget
B6. Long-term care, home-based services 0.4 Fixed fee per patient
Total budget approval B 163,152 million For 48.787 million UCS members
Figure 4
Age-adjusted cost index for outpatient care
Age group (years)
All age
<3 3 – 10 11-20 21 - 40 41 - 50 51 - 60 61 – 70 >70 groups
0.464 0.364 0.306 0.407 0.789 1.348 1.972 2.351 1
The NHSO pays the cost of ambulance services for the referral
of patients requiring emergency attention (not only A&E)
between hospitals. The cost of pre-hospital care and ambulance
services from the spot events to hospitals are paid by the
National Institute of Emergency Medicines through its network
of telecommunications and systematic commanding systems.
Certain local governments also subsidize ambulance services
(first responders only).
Fiscal sustainability
Between 1996 and 2010, cataract lens replacement was paid based on
DRG weights, with hospitals being compensated for the lens cost of B
4000. To solve the problem of the long waiting list, the private sector was
encouraged to provide lens replacement for a lump sum payment of B
7000 inclusive of lens cost during 1997-2000.
Since 2011, cataract lens replacement has been unbundled from DRG
systems and paid on a fee schedule of B 7000 and 9000 per case
(without and with complication, respectively) and a lens cost of B 700
and 2800 for hard and foldable lens, respectively. This innovation
boosted access to lens replacement, using an interrupted time series,
from 0.8 lens per 100 000 population in 2005-2006 to 64.9 per 100 000
population (p<0.01) in 2009-2013.
3,500
3,000
2,500
THB/Person
2,000
1,500
1,000
500
2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019
Figure 6
Percent of UCS budget compared with total government
budget
4,000,000 8
3,500,000 7
3,000,000 6
2,500,000 5
2,000,000 4
1,500,000 3
1,000,000 2
500,000 1
0 0
2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019
20
15
10
% Growth
-5
2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019
Figure 8
Growth of Annual GDP per capita and Annual UCS per capita
budget
4,000 250,000
200,000
3,000
UCS per capita budget (THB/person)
2,000
100,000
1,000
50,000
0 0
2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019
Efficiency
Figure 9
Financial risk protection from healthcare costs: catastrophic
health expenditure using a threshold of more than 10% of
household consumption expenditure on health (left) and
household impoverishment (right)
5
% of household
1990 1993 1996 1999 2002 2005 2008 2011 2014 2017 1990 1993 1996 1999 2002 2005 2008 2011 2014 2017
Challenges lie with the fact that, despite the three insurance
schemes applying similar benefits packages, each pays
providers differently. For example, SHI pays inclusive
capitation, though it recently has gradually adopted DRG for
high cost inpatient services of relative weights more than two
while still paying capitation if inpatient relative weights are less
than two.
Capitation
1,202 Baht/capita/year in 2002
255
Price setting and price regulation in health care:
The United States of America
Abstract 257
Overview 258
1 Medicare 262
Contents
Quality Payment Program
Medicare value-based purchasing
270
271
Bundled payments 272
2 Medicaid 276
7 Maryland 290
References 294
1 CMS is an operating division within the Department of Health and Human Services (HHS).
HHS is the United States government’s principal agency for protecting the health of all
Americans and providing essential human services.
2 The Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, signed into law in March 2010, made
broad changes to the way health insurance is provided and paid for in the United States.
In 2014, state and federally administered health insurance marketplaces (or Exchanges)
were established to provide additional access to private insurance coverage, with
income-based premium subsidies for low- and middle-income people. In addition, states
were given the option of participating in a federally subsidized expansion of Medicaid
eligibility.
Privately insured
Federal government State government individuals
Veterans Indian
health health Medicare Medicaid Private
TriCare
administration services and CHIP insurance
Hierarchical Overseeing
Contract Regulation
3 The Indian Health Service, an agency within the Department of Health and Human
Services, is responsible for providing federal health services to Native Americans and
Alaska Natives.
4 The Military Health System - the global health system of the Department of Defense
- operates a worldwide health care delivery system that includes care delivered in over
50 military hospitals and over 600 clinics, as well as a supporting network of private
sector providers offered under its health insurance system known as Tricare. This system
provides health services to approximately 9.6 million beneficiaries — active duty service
members, military retirees, their eligible family members and survivors.
5 The Veterans Health Administration (VHA) is the largest integrated health care system,
providing care at 1243 health care facilities, including 172 medical centres and 1062
outpatient sites of care of varying complexity (VHA outpatient clinics), serving 9 million
enrolled Veterans each year.
6 This approach is called “price discrimination” in economist jargon. It means that an
identical service is sold to different buyers at different prices.
Figure 3
Number of accredited providers by program type
Source: Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services, 2018. Note: Deemed
are those providers that received accreditation from an Accrediting
Organization. Non-deemed are those providers that received accreditation
by a state survey agency.
10 Those “conditions” refer to health and safety standards which are the foundation for
improving quality and protecting the health and safety of beneficiaries.
11 When services are furnished through institutions that must be certified for Medicare, the
institutional standards must be met for Medicaid as well. In general, the only types of
institutions participating solely in Medicaid are (unskilled) Nursing Facilities, Psychiatric
Residential Treatment Facilities and Intermediate Care Facilities for the Mentally
Retarded. Medicaid requires Nursing Facilities to meet virtually the same requirements
that Skilled Nursing Facilities participating in Medicare must meet. Facilities for the
Mentally Retarded must comply with special Medicaid standards.
12 “Provider entities” include providers of services, suppliers, facilities, clinics, agencies or
laboratories. Physicians, as well as nurses and many allied health professionals are
accredited by licensing boards in the state in which they practice. In addition to
state-level regulations, physicians are also regulated at the federal level by CMS criteria
for reimbursing providers.
13 The process of recognition of an AO by CMS is called “deeming”.
Figure 4
Approved Medicare accrediting organizations by type of care
Accrediting organization Hospital Psychiatric CAH HHA Hospice ASC OPT RHC
hospital
Source: Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services, 2018. Note: CAH:
critical access hospitals; HHA: home health agency; ASC: ambulatory
surgical centre; OPT: outpatient physical therapy, RHC: rural health clinics.
14 Eligible hospitals must meet the following conditions to obtain CAH designation: have 25
or fewer acute care inpatient beds; be located more than 35 miles from another hospital;
maintain an annual average length of stay of 96 hours or less for acute care patients and
provide 24/7 emergency care services.
15 Equity in payment — which means that hospitals in similar situations get paid the same
price for the same service — is an underlying key principle of the IPPS design framework.
This also means that payment is not hospital specific.
16 The MS-DRGs system has 335 base DRGs, most of which are split into two or three
MS-DRGs based on the presence of either a comorbidity or complication or a major
comorbidity and complication.
17 Medicare pays separately for the direct costs of operating approved training programs for
residents.
Hospital
wage MS-DRG
index
Full
Policy adjustments for hospitals that qualify length
Per case
of stay
payment
rate High-cost
Adjusted Indirect medical Disproportionate
outlier: payment
base + education + share payment Short LOS or = Payment ** + outlier
payment rate payment discharged
Per diem payment
to other
acute payment
rate If case is
hospitals or extraordinarily
post-acute costly
care *
CMS reviews and revises the APCs and their relative weights
annually. The review considers changes in medical practice,
changes in technology, addition of new services, new cost data
and other relevant information. CMS consults with a panel of
outside experts as part of this review. CMS also annually
updates the conversion factor by the hospital market basket
index minus a multi-factor productivity adjustment.
18 A new case-mix classification system — the Patient-Driven Payment Model (PDPM) — will
be used as from October 1 2019. In the PDPM, there are five case-mix adjusted
components: Physical Therapy (PT), Occupational Therapy (OT), Speech-Language
Pathology (SLP), Non-Therapy Ancillary (NTA), and Nursing. Each resident is to be
classified into only one group for each of the five case-mix adjusted components. For
each of the case-mix adjusted components, there are a number of groups to which a
resident may be assigned: 16 PT groups, 16 OT groups, 12 SLP groups, six NTA groups and
25 nursing groups. As opposed to RUG, in which a resident’s classification into a single
group determines the case-mix indexes and per diem rates for all case-mix adjusted
components, PDPM classifies residents into a separate group for each of the case-mix
adjusted components, which each have their own associated case-mix indexes and per
diem rates. Additionally, PDPM applies variable per diem payment adjustments to three
components, PT, OT, and NTA, to account for changes in resource use over a stay. The
adjusted PT, OT, and NTA per diem rates are then added together with the unadjusted SLP
and nursing component rates and the non-case-mix component, as is done under RUGs, to
determine the full per diem rate for a given resident.
19 Services remain in these APCs for two to three years, while CMS collects the data
necessary to develop payment rates for them.
Managed care
22 See https://qpp.cms.gov/mips/overview
23 See https://qpp.cms.gov/apms/overview
Bundled payments
24 The 29 Inpatient Clinical Episodes are the following: disorders of the liver excluding
malignancy, cirrhosis, alcoholic hepatitis; acute myocardial infarction; back & neck except
spinal fusion; cardiac arrhythmia; cardiac defibrillator; cardiac valve; cellulitis; cervical
spinal fusion; COPD, bronchitis, asthma; combined anterior posterior spinal fusion;
congestive heart failure; coronary artery bypass graft; double joint replacement of the
lower extremity; fractures of the femur and hip or pelvis; gastrointestinal haemorrhage;
gastrointestinal obstruction; hip & femur procedures except major joint; lower extremity/
humerus procedure except hip, foot, femur; major bowel procedure; major joint
replacement of the lower extremity; major joint replacement of the upper extremity;
pacemaker; percutaneous coronary intervention; renal failure; sepsis; simple pneumonia
and respiratory infections; spinal fusion (non-cervical); stroke; and urinary tract infection.
The Outpatient Clinical Episodes are the following: percutaneous coronary intervention;
cardiac defibrillator; and back & neck except spinal fusion.
25 Federal poverty levels are a measure of income issued every year by the Department of
Health and Human Services (HHS). They are used to determine eligibility for certain
programs and benefits, including savings on Marketplace health insurance, and Medicaid
and CHIP coverage.
26 In January 2015, the U.S. Supreme Court heard arguments in the case of Armstrong v.
Exceptional Child Care, Inc. and determined that only CMS has the authority to decide
whether Medicaid rates are sufficient and that the private parties may not bring suit.
27 Some states use the All-patient refined (APR), others the Medicare severity (MS) and a few
the All-patient (AP) DRG classification system.
28 UPL payments are lump-sum payments that are intended to fill in the difference between
FFS base payments and the amount that Medicare would have paid for the same service.
29 Medicaid DSH payments are statutorily required payments to hospitals that serve a high
share of Medicaid and low-income patients.
Managed care
3
Private health insurance
States are the primary regulators of private health plans. Each
state requires insurance issuers to be licensed to sell health
plans in the state, and each state has a unique set of
requirements that apply to state-licensed issuers and the plans
they offer. State insurance laws have sought to keep insurance
companies financially solvent, protect against fraud, ensure
that consumers receive the benefits promised under their
insurance policies and promote the spreading of health risks
(Corlette et al., 2017). State regulation of insurance is grounded
in laws enacted by each state, and as a result can vary
significantly. State Departments of Insurance (DoI) are the
primary entities that work directly with insurers to ensure
compliance with federal and state standard. The range of
regulatory and oversight tools provided via state laws includes
in most cases licensing (insurance companies are required to
apply for a “certificate of authority”), rate review (DoI have the
authority to review premium rates before they are
implemented), policy review (DoI review and approve insurers’
policy forms before they can be sold), network adequacy,
marketing practices and market oversight.
30 The federal government adopted the requirement for hospitals — as of 1 January 2019
— to post list prices for all their services to promote “transparency” in health care in the
belief that health markets would work better if consumers had more information.
4
Reference pricing
Reference pricing is a type of health benefit design that gives
consumers seeking health care services an incentive to shop
around for the best deal. Under reference pricing, the health
insurer sets a cap — or “reference price” — for certain elective
treatments and procedures (e.g., knee replacement) that
represents the maximum amount the insurer will pay for the
treatment or procedure regardless of the health care provider
selected by the patient. If the patient selects a provider who
has negotiated a price with the insurer that is at or below the
reference price, the entire price is covered by the insurer and
the patient owes nothing. If the patient selects a provider
whose price is higher than the reference price, the insurer will
pay the reference amount, leaving the patient responsible for
the difference.
33 Medicare participating providers are those that have signed an agreement to accept the
Medicare-approved amount as full payment for covered services, whereas non-
participating providers are those that haven’t signed an agreement to accept Medicare
rates but they can still choose to accept Medicare rates for individual services.
34 https://www.medicare.gov/your-medicare-costs/part-a-costs/lower-costs-with-
assignment.
The HSCRC then sets rates for services that Maryland hospitals
use to bill all payers so that total payments (based on expected
utilization) will match the global budget. As under Maryland’s
previous hospital payment system, each hospital bills payers
38 The global budgets encompass 95% of hospital revenues.
Cooper Z, Craig SV, Gaynor M, Reenen JV. The price ain’t right?
Hospital prices and health spending on the privately insured.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics 2019;134(1):51-107.
Frakt AB. The End of Hospital Cost Shifting and the Quest for
Hospital Productivity. Health Services Research 2014;49(1):1-10.
www.who.int/kobe_centre/en/