Ewp 662 Distributional Impacts Fiscal Policy Philippines
Ewp 662 Distributional Impacts Fiscal Policy Philippines
Ewp 662 Distributional Impacts Fiscal Policy Philippines
Hyun H. Son
The views expressed in this publication are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views and policies
of the Asian Development Bank (ADB) or its Board of Governors or the governments they represent.
ADB does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this publication and accepts no responsibility for any
consequence of their use. The mention of specific companies or products of manufacturers does not imply that they
are endorsed or recommended by ADB in preference to others of a similar nature that are not mentioned.
By making any designation of or reference to a particular territory or geographic area, or by using the term “country”
in this document, ADB does not intend to make any judgments as to the legal or other status of any territory or area.
This work is available under the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 IGO license (CC BY 3.0 IGO)
https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/igo/. By using the content of this publication, you agree to be bound
by the terms of this license. For attribution, translations, adaptations, and permissions, please read the provisions
and terms of use at https://www.adb.org/terms-use#openaccess.
This CC license does not apply to non-ADB copyright materials in this publication. If the material is attributed
to another source, please contact the copyright owner or publisher of that source for permission to reproduce it.
ADB cannot be held liable for any claims that arise as a result of your use of the material.
Please contact pubsmarketing@adb.org if you have questions or comments with respect to content, or if you wish
to obtain copyright permission for your intended use that does not fall within these terms, or for permission to use
the ADB logo.
Note:
In this publication, “P ” refers to Philippine pesos and “$” refers to United States dollars.
The ADB Economics Working Paper Series presents data, information, and/or findings from ongoing research and
studies to encourage exchange of ideas and to elicit comment and feedback about development issues in Asia and
the Pacific. Since papers in this series are intended for quick and easy dissemination, the content may or may not be
fully edited and may later be modified for final publication.
CONTENTS
ABSTRACT v
I. INTRODUCTION 1
REFERENCES 25
TABLES AND FIGURES
TABLES
FIGURES
The distributional impacts of fiscal policies are instrumental in reducing inequality in countries like the
Philippines, where inequality has been persistently high. This paper assesses how equitable various
taxes and transfers in the Philippines are by deriving the elasticities of Atkinson and Sen’s social welfare
functions and introducing a welfare reform index. Among various income sources, the paper finds that
rentals from properties, dividends from investment, incomes from construction entrepreneurial
activities, and remittances from abroad are regressive. In contrast, family sustenance activities,
entrepreneurial activities in farming and fishing, and remittances from domestic sources are found to
be progressive. The paper also finds that while direct taxes like personal income tax are overall
progressive in the Philippines, they only generate little revenues, indicating their limited impact on
inequality reduction. Furthermore, this paper shows that the poor bear much of indirect tax burden on
individual commodities such as food items largely consumed at home since they spend a greater
proportion of their expenditure on such basic commodities relative to their nonpoor counterparts.
Keywords: social welfare function, tax progressivity, redistribution, normative analysis, horizontal inequity,
fiscal policy
Economic inequality is one of the most urgent development challenges facing the Philippines. While
the country continues to solidify its position as a leader in economic growth in Southeast Asia, income
inequality remains high, with the Gini coefficient averaging 0.42 between 1985 and 2015.1 Economic
growth in the Philippines has been lopsided, favoring only a few, while leaving behind millions of
impoverished families. The richest 10% of the country’s population held 31.3% of the national income
in 2015—more than 10 times the income held by the poorest 10% of the population in the same year.2
Such a high level of inequality has reduced the responsiveness of poverty reduction to
economic growth in the Philippines. The share of the economically secure in the Philippines only
slightly rose from 37% in 2002 to 44% in 2015—lower than the increase of one-fifth to two-thirds in
East Asia and Pacific (World Bank 2018).
The nature and pattern of inequality in the Philippines has evolved over time. Urban and
nonagricultural households have benefited more from improvements in social welfare over 2000–2012
than rural, agricultural households. In the past, the highest levels of welfare accrued to households
whose main income sources were wages and salaries. More recent trends, however, show that
households relying on remittances now enjoy higher welfare levels. Moreover, poor income units have
been increasingly concentrated in the youngest cohort (30 years old and under), while the
concentrations of richer income units are older in the cohort of 60 years old and above (Valenzuela,
Wong, and Zhen 2017).
For countries with stubbornly high income inequality and wide disparities in opportunities like
the Philippines, the distributional impacts of fiscal policies are at the center of policy debates and
research work concerned with reducing inequality. The Philippine government implements tax and
transfer programs to tackle persistently high inequality, which include conditional and unconditional
cash transfer programs and the series of tax reforms that commenced in January 2018.
The extent to which a government’s fiscal system is equitable, therefore, greatly plays an
important role in curbing inequality. A trade-off between efficiency and equity usually exists in
implementing fiscal policies. Policy makers are confronted with the challenge of maximizing efficiency
through reduced costs of taxation and distortions, while ensuring equity by paying attention to the
progressivity of the tax burden. Depending on how a government collects and spends its revenues, a
fiscal system may be defined as either progressive or regressive if it redistributes income from the rich
to the poor, or vice versa.
This paper aims to assess the extent to which a government’s fiscal systems are equitable, with
the Philippines as a case study. The paper derives the welfare elasticity for the Atkinson’s class of social
welfare function. Using the idea of welfare elasticity, the paper proposes a welfare reform index, which
can be utilized to assess how equitable fiscal policies are and help make such policies more equitable
through marginal reforms.
1 Author’s estimates based on Google Public Data Explorer. 2018. Gini Index. https://tinyurl.com/ycw8omst (accessed 29
November 2018).
2 Author’s estimates based on Google Public Data Explorer. 2018. Income Distribution. https://tinyurl.com/y9nlbobo
(accessed 29 November 2018).
2 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 662
The paper also uses an interdependent social welfare function to derive the welfare elasticity.
The Atkinson welfare function encompasses a rather restrictive assumption that an individual’s
satisfaction is independent of consumptions of others in society. However, people do compare
themselves with others and feel relatively deprived when they find that a large proportion of people
have a higher income or consumption. In this context, the paper uses Sen’s social welfare function that
reflects manifestations of envy, given an individual’s and others’ positions in the income distribution.
To measure the effect of envy on the fiscal system, the paper uses Sen’s (1974) social welfare function
to capture the degree of envy. The welfare elasticity allows for assessing how the degree of envy affects
the equity of a fiscal system.
The methodology developed in the paper is applied to the Philippines’ fiscal system, utilizing
the 2017 Annual Poverty Indicator Survey (APIS).3 The paper is structured as follows: Section II
presents the literature review and discusses the Philippine fiscal system; Section III presents the data
used and the concepts for measuring individual welfare; Section IV specifies the empirical strategy for
deriving social welfare elasticities and the welfare reform index, and their application to various fiscal
instruments in the Philippines; Section V discusses the empirical findings; and Section VI presents the
conclusions and policy implications.
The distributional impacts of fiscal policies—or the extent to which a tax or transfer system reduces
income inequality—depend on the progressivity and size of taxes and transfers (Slavov and Viard
2016a). Depending on the policy objectives, policy makers can either prioritize the size of the fiscal
system or the level of its progressivity. For instance, if a policy’s focus is to improve the welfare of the
bottom 20% of households in the income distribution, a large tax system with little progressivity may
be preferred over a smaller tax system that is more progressive. This is because a larger tax system can
mobilize more revenues, which in turn can finance social programs that make larger transfers to the
poor even though the tax burden on the very rich is relatively smaller (Slavov and Viard 2016b).
Empirical research on the equity aspects of fiscal policies such as Cubero and Hollar (2010) and
Inchauste et al. (2015) use the following common indicators of the redistributive potential of fiscal policies:
(i) Tax progression, which measures the tax effectively paid relative to income—called the
effective tax ratio—per quantile (decile, quintile, or quartile) of income;
(ii) Kakwani index, which is equal to the concentration coefficient for taxes minus the Gini
coefficient for before-tax income;
(iii) Lorenz and concentration curves, which entails comparing the pre-tax Lorenz curve for
income with the concentration curve for that tax;
(iv) Quasi Gini Coefficient, which is the Gini coefficient for a tax’s concentration curve; and
(v) Reynolds-Smolensky index, which is the difference between the pre-tax Gini coefficient
and the quasi-Gini index.
3 APIS 2017 is the latest available round of APIS that contains the most up-to-date and detailed information on income
sources and expenditure items. APIS 2019 and 2020 do not provide detailed information on income and expenditure
components.
The Distributional Impacts of Fiscal Policy 3
The main methodological difference between the papers by Cubero and Hollar (2010) and
Inchauste et al. (2015), and this paper, is the former’s use of inequality measurements and the latter’s
utilization of social welfare functions. Inequality measurement is a descriptive approach that mainly
deals with how total income is divided among various individuals. In contrast, social welfare analysis
adopts a normative approach to the assessment of income distribution since it aims to find out how
total income should be divided among different individuals.
Making normative judgements is inevitable in assessing any public policy, including fiscal
policies. This is because policies may have varying impacts on different individuals. A policy that may be
detrimental to the welfare of certain groups may be beneficial to others. For instance, optimal tax theory
requires normative judgements to determine how society can improve social welfare given constraints
due to limited resources and behavior changes arising from tax policies (Diamond and Saez 2011).
Hence, assessing and reforming fiscal policies require a social welfare function that can be put
into practice and is flexible enough to accommodate changes in the weights assigned to individuals
from different segments of the income distribution. A class of homothetic social welfare functions
proposed by Atkinson (1970) for measuring inequality satisfies the two abovementioned conditions.
The paper uses Atkinson’s social welfare function, which depends on an inequality aversion parameter
through which the weights given to individuals in different segments of the income distribution can be
modified.
In the Philippines, the equity of fiscal systems has yet to be fully explored in literature,
particularly using empirical analysis. The Philippines offers an interesting case as the country has
suffered bouts of fiscal woes amid persistently high levels of inequality.
Government expenditure averaged 9.97% of the gross domestic product (GDP) and grew at
4.23% per year over 1960–2017 (Figure 1).4 A substantial decrease in government spending both in
terms of annual growth and as a percentage of GDP was observed in the mid-1980s following
economic woes caused by excessive borrowing from oil-rich countries and a volatile political
environment with the tumultuous end of then President Ferdinand Marcos’ regime. The government
was able to maintain a high level of spending by the time the Asian financial crisis hit in 1998 because
of additional revenues mobilized from the privatization of government assets. Average inequality
declined during 1985–1988 due to a rise in the income shares of the bottom 50% and a drop in income
shares of the top 1% and 10% during this period.5 The decline in the income shares of the top 1% and
10% coincided with private investments bottoming out to less than 14% of the GDP in 1985–1987
(Estudillo 1997). Government spending relative to GDP fell from 1998 to 2004 following the ouster of
then President Joseph Estrada (Sicat 2011). Most recently, the government ramped up its spending to
address the health and economic fallout from the coronavirus disease (COVID-19) pandemic through
its relief and stimulus packages, and health programs.6
4 The World Development Indicators define government final consumption expenditure as consisting of purchase of goods
and services, including compensation of employees and expenditures on national defense and security.
5 From 1985 to 1988, the income share of the top 1% decreased from 0.197 to 0.184. The income share of the top 10% also
decreased from 0.497 in 1985 to 0.487 in 1988. In contrast, the income share of the bottom 50% rose from 0.130 to 0.131
during 1985–1988. See World Inequality Database. https://wid.world/ (accessed 1 March 2022).
6 Government spending as a percentage of the GDP increased from 12.5% in 2019 to 15.3% in 2020. See World Bank. 2022.
World Development Indicators. http://databank.worldbank.org (accessed 15 January 2022).
4 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 662
Source: World Bank. World Development Indicators. https://databank.worldbank.org (accessed 15 January 2022).
Budget deficits, or the annual amount a government has to borrow to meet the shortfall
between its revenues and spending, averaged –2.08% of GDP over 1988–2017, reaching its lowest
point at –5.30% of GDP in 2002 (Trading Economics 2018).
On the revenue side, the government relies on both direct and indirect taxes, including
personal income tax, corporate income tax, value-added tax, and excise taxes. Tax revenues
accounted for 14% of GDP over 1990–2016 (Figure 2). In 2019, tax revenues contributed about 15% of
GDP (World Bank 2022), which is substantially lower compared to the Organization for Economic
Co-operation and Development (OECD) average of 34% in the same year (OECD 2021). Government
revenues took a hit amid the COVID-19 pandemic as the crisis has reduced taxes and other revenue
sources.7
The country’s fiscal policy is currently being revamped as the government started
implementing its first batch of tax reforms in January 2018. Such reforms lowered personal income
taxes, while raising or setting new excise taxes on oil products, vehicles, cigarettes, and sugar-
sweetened drinks. The revenues will be used to help fund the government’s massive infrastructure
program amounting to ₱8 trillion (about $153 billion). To help offset higher prices as a result of the tax
reforms, the Philippine government is providing unconditional cash grants worth ₱2,400 (about $46)
to each of the 10 million impoverished households and individuals. However, nearly 4 million of the
beneficiaries have yet to receive their cash grants as of September 2018 (Panti 2018).
7 According to the Philippines’ Bureau of Treasury (2020), government revenue for 2020 narrowed to ₱2.0 billion, which
was 9% lower against the ₱3.1 billion raised in 2019.
The Distributional Impacts of Fiscal Policy 5
The paper utilized APIS data to assess the distributional impacts of the Philippine fiscal system. APIS is
a nationwide household survey that gathers data on the socioeconomic characteristics and living
conditions of households across the Philippines’ 81 provinces, as well as all cities and municipalities in
the country’s National Capital Region. The paper used APIS 2017, which contains detailed information
on income sources and expenditure components for more than 10,000 households that were
successfully interviewed in 2017.
Using APIS 2017 data, the paper derives the following measures of individual welfare and
sources of income:
To assess the distributional effects of various government fiscal policies, the economic welfare of
everyone in society needs to be measured. A welfare measure for individuals reveals the degree to
which an individual is better or worse off than another individual. Two of the most common measures
of individual welfare are income and consumption. Indicators of individual welfare are derived from
information on individuals’ income or consumption collected through household income and
expenditure surveys.
Many rich industrialized countries use per capita income as an indicator of household welfare.
Income provides households with an entitlement to consume goods and services that satisfy their
needs. However, consumption is regarded as a better measure of household welfare because it reflects
6 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 662
the households’ long-term standard of living more accurately than income. The economic theory of
consumer behavior hypothesizes that individuals maximize their utility under a given budget
constraint. This theory defines individuals’ utility by a consumption basket that individuals consume.
In developing countries, studies of poverty and income inequality are generally carried out based on
household consumption expenditure. The assessment of fiscal policies is generally conducted based
on individuals’ income. Thus, in this paper, the measure of individual welfare is derived from
household income.
An ideal welfare measure should incorporate all factors that contribute to individuals’ welfare
directly and indirectly. Household income and expenditure surveys, which form the basis of most
income distribution studies, do not provide sufficient information to account for all the relevant factors
affecting economic welfare. Fortunately, the 2017 APIS used in this paper provides a comprehensive
concept of income.
Since households differ in size and composition, some adjustment is required to factor in the
different needs of household members. Per capita income, used to measure household welfare,
assumes that everyone in a household requires the same allocation of household resources. However,
children surely require less of most things than adults. Large households may also enjoy economies of
scale, which result in savings. For instance, to enjoy the same level of utility, a two-person household
does not require twice the amount of money as a one-person household. Hence, adult equivalent
scales have been devised to consider varying needs among children and adults, as well as economies of
scale within households. To account for the different needs of children and adults and economies of
scale, we have adopted the simple adult equivalent scale widely used in OECD member countries: first
adult in the household = 1.0; second and subsequent adult = 0.7 of the first adult; and each child = 0.5
of the first adult.
The number equivalent adults in the 𝑖th household consisting of 𝐴 adults and 𝐶 children are
given by 𝐸 = 1 + 0.7(𝐴 – 1) + 0.5𝐶 , where 𝐸 is the number of equivalent adults in the 𝑖th
household. Suppose a household has two adults and two children, then the number of equivalent
adults calculated using this scale is equal to 2.7. Although this household has four members, its needs
are equivalent to 2.7 adults. The household welfare is measured by dividing total household income by
the number of equivalent adults as calculated based on this scale.
Let 𝑥 be the per equivalent adult income of a household, which is a measure of household
welfare. Since households are selected randomly from the population, we can assume that 𝑥 is a
random variable with probability density function 𝑓(𝑥), then the average welfare of society is given by:
𝐸 (𝑥 ) = 𝑥𝑓 (𝑥 )𝑑𝑥 (1)
This average welfare of society gives an equal weight to each household irrespective of
household size. This implies that the weight assigned to the welfare of a single-person household is the
same as a household consisting of, say, eight persons. This approach is unsatisfactory because there
exists no welfare justification for giving a larger weight to individuals belonging to smaller households
and a smaller weight to those belonging to larger households. Individuals belonging to larger
households, therefore, are discriminated and generally poorer. Thus, giving an equal weight to every
household irrespective of their size will lead to a biased evaluation of fiscal policies.
Since our objective is to measure the distribution of welfare of individuals, it makes sense to
assign weights to everyone equally irrespective of the size and composition of households to which he
The Distributional Impacts of Fiscal Policy 7
or she belongs. This approach can be justified from the welfare point of view if we opt for an individual
social welfare (Danziger and Taussig 1979).
Under this weighting scheme, the size distribution of individual welfare is constructed by
assigning everyone in a household a welfare value equal to the income per equivalent adults for that
household. This approach will be appropriate if we assume that every household member enjoys the
same level of welfare. The validity of this assumption is difficult to assess because household surveys
do not provide any information about how households distribute their resources to their members.
However, if household members care about each other, it may be reasonable to assume that
households will allocate their resources such that each member enjoys the same level of welfare. If this
assumption is not satisfied, then the evaluation of the distribution effects of fiscal policies will be
biased. However, this assumption is unlikely to be realistic because the intra-household allocation of
resources may vary by household composition, age, gender, or other factors. Unfortunately, we have
no alternative but to make this assumption. In the measurement of inequality and poverty, studies
usually make this assumption because household surveys do not provide information on the allocation
of resources within households. None of them, however, point out this limitation.
Suppose 𝑛(𝑥) is the number of individuals in a household with per equivalent adult income 𝑥,
then the average number of individuals in society is given by:
Assuming every individual in the household enjoys the same level of welfare, the probability
density function of individual welfare will be given by:
( ) ( )
𝑔 (𝑥 ) = (3)
( ( ))
The average per person economic welfare of society is then given by:
Note that 𝐸(𝑥) given in equation (1) is the average welfare of households that weighs all
households equally, while µ in (4) is the average welfare of individuals that weighs all individuals within
the household equally. The average welfare of individuals is justifiable from a welfare point of view.
B. Sources of Income
Individuals derive their income from various sources. Suppose there are 𝑘 income sources, which add
up to the total household income. After adjusting all income sources by dividing them by the number
of equivalent adults, the household welfare can be written as:
where 𝑣 (𝑥 ) is the per equivalent adult income derived from the 𝑗th source. Substituting (5) into (4) gives:
𝜇=∑ 𝜇 (6)
8 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 662
where:
and 𝜇 is the average welfare of individuals derived from the total household income, which is the sum
of the average welfare of individuals, namely, 𝜇 derived from the 𝑘 income sources. 100 × is the
percentage contribution of the 𝑗th income source to the average welfare of individuals.
Table 1 in Section IV.A presents the average welfare of individuals by income sources and
shows the percentage contribution of each income source to the total individual household welfare.
The most dominant source of welfare are wages and salaries, which contribute 49.3% to the total
welfare. Wages and salaries cover all gross earnings including overtime, bonus, commission, and tips.
Another major income source are remittances received from abroad, which account for nearly
10% of the total welfare. Households also receive transfers from domestic sources, which contribute
4.6% to the total welfare.
Imputed rent, for those households who own houses, makes a contribution of 9.1% to the total
welfare. Although owning a house does not provide a cash income, the services of the dwelling
nevertheless have a value equivalent to the net income that could be obtained by letting the dwelling
to a tenant.
Pensions and retirement benefits contribute 3.1% to the total welfare. This income source also
includes workers’ compensation and social security payments. The Philippines implements various
cash transfer programs such as conditional cash transfers, survivor’s benefits, community-based
employment program, and disability benefits, but the contribution of such programs is small.
Personal income and other direct taxes contribute to a 4.5% reduction in total household
welfare. Thus, the direct tax revenues collected by the Philippine government is relatively small
compared to countries at similar level of income.
The main purpose of using a social welfare function is to evaluate how economic resources are
allocated with the goal of identifying which policies work and which ones do not (Kakwani and Son
2016). A social welfare function explicitly specifies normative judgments by assigning weights to
different individuals. Since policies impact the individuals differently, as some individuals might gain
from policies while others might lose, hence, normative judgments cannot be avoided and a social
welfare function must be used to evaluate policies.
In this paper, we use the social welfare functions that can be put into practice and are flexible
enough to accommodate changes in the weights assigned to individuals from different segments of the
income distribution. We employ two of the most well-known social welfare functions that can be
estimated from household surveys: Atkinson’s (1970) social welfare function, which was derived using
The Distributional Impacts of Fiscal Policy 9
the concept of an equally distributed equivalent level of income; and the Gini social welfare function
developed by Sen (1974).
Atkinson assumed that the social welfare function is utilitarian and every individual has the same utility
function. Under such restricted assumptions, the average welfare of society is given by:
where 𝑢(𝑥) is the utility derived by an individual with per equivalent adult income 𝑥 and 𝑔(𝑥)
individual density function derived in equation (3). The utility function has the following properties:
𝑑𝑢(𝑥) 𝑑 𝑢(𝑥)
> 0 and <0
𝑑𝑥 𝑑𝑥
In deriving his social welfare function, Atkinson ensured that social welfare function is invariant
with respect to any positive linear transformation of individual utilities. He derived his social welfare
function using the concept of equally distributed equivalent level of income 𝑥 ∗ , which, if received by
every individual, would result in the same level of social welfare as the present distribution:
where 𝑥 ∗ is per person social welfare of society and a money-metric measure of social welfare. Because
of the concavity of the utility function, social welfare 𝑥 ∗ is always less than the mean welfare 𝜇 defined
in (4). The inequality measure implict in this social welfare is given by:
∗
𝐴 =1− (10)
which will be referred to as Atkinson’s inequality measure. Using (10), the social welfare 𝑥 ∗ can be
written as:
𝑥 ∗ = 𝜇(1 − 𝐴) (11)
which shows that the social welfare 𝑥 ∗ depends on the two factors, mean income and inequality in
society. Since this social welfare is sensitive to inequality, it allows us to evaluate the relative impact of
government policies on the poor and nonpoor.
𝑏𝑥 ∈
𝑢 (𝑥 ) = 𝑎 + 𝑖𝑓 ∈ ≠ 1
1−∈
= 𝑎 + 𝑏 𝑙𝑛(𝑥 ) 𝑖𝑓 ∈ = 1 (12)
10 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 662
where 𝑏 > 0 and 𝑎 and 𝑏 are constants. This utility function yields a class of money-metric social
welfare 𝑥 ∗ (∈) as:
𝑥 ∗ (∈) = [ 𝑥 ∈
𝑔(𝑥 )𝑑𝑥] ∈ 𝑖𝑓 ∈≠ 1
where 𝑒𝑥𝑝 stands for exponential. Equation (13) presents a class of Atkinson’s social welfare functions.
Note that 𝑥 ∗ (∈) is independent of 𝑎 and 𝑏, which implies that Atkinson’s social welfare functions are
invariant to any positive linear transformation of the utility function.
∈
𝐴 (∈) = 1 − 𝑥 𝑔(𝑥 )𝑑𝑥 ∈
𝑖𝑓 ∈≠ 1
Normative judgments in Atkinson’s social welfare and inequality are incorporated through the
value of ∈ , which is a measure of inequality aversion. Inequality aversion captures society’s relative
sensitivity to income transfers at different income levels. As ∈ rises, more weights are given to transfers
at the lower end of the income distribution. If ∈= 0, the social welfare becomes equal to the mean
income, which reflects an inequality-neutral attitude wherein society does not care about inequality at
all but is mainly concerned with increasing its average standard of living.
To capture the idea of relative deprivation, Sen (1974) developed a social welfare function by assigning
weight to income depending on the ranking of individuals in society by a welfare measure. The lower a
person is on a welfare measure, the greater is his or her sense of deprivation with respect to others in
society.
The Gini social welfare function developed by Sen (1974) is defined as:
where 𝐺(𝑥) is the individual probability distribution function, interpreted as the proportion of
individuals who have per equivalent adult income less 𝑥. This social welfare function is the weighted
average of 𝑥, where the weight on 𝑥 is given by:
𝑣 (𝑥 ) = 2[1 − 𝐺 (𝑥 )]
such that 𝑣 (𝑥 )𝑑𝑥 = 1. According to this weighting scheme, the weight on income 𝑥 is proportional
to the number of individuals who are richer than the individual with welfare level 𝑥.
The Gini index is defined as one minus twice the area under the Lorenz curve. Following
Kakwani (1980), the Gini index can be written as:
Combining (15) and (16) yields the Gini social welfare function as:
𝑊 = 𝜇(1 − 𝐺) (17)
which demonstrates the Gini index 𝐺 is the proportional loss of social welfare caused by inequality.
This measure of inequality is relative because it remains unchanged when each income or welfare is
altered by the same proportion. On the other hand, if inequality exists, then society’s loss of social
welfare is 𝜇𝐺, which is the absolute measure of inequality because its value remains unchanged when
each income is increased or decreased by the same amount. The Gini social welfare function,
therefore, provides both relative and absolute measures of inequality. In contrast, Atkinson’s social
welfare can provide only relative measures of inequality because they are derived from a homothetic
utility function.
As discussed, the income sources in APIS 2017 include government transfers and direct taxes.
Government transfers increase the average welfare of society and affect the inequality of individual
welfare. We can capture both these effects by calculating the elasticity of social welfare with respect to
the means of various income sources. Similarly, direct taxes reduce the average welfare and affect the
inequality of individual welfare. Direct taxes are like government transfers but have a negative impact
on social welfare.
Utilizing the properties of the Lorenz curve and concertation curves given in Kakwani (1977,
1980), we obtain:
𝑥 = 𝜇𝐿 (𝑝) (18)
and
𝑣 (𝑥 ) = 𝜇 𝐶 (𝑝) (19)
where 𝐿′(𝑝) and 𝐶𝑗′(𝑝) are the first derivatives of 𝐿(𝑝) and 𝐶 (𝑝) with respect to 𝑝, respectively.8
We utilize this equation to derive the social welfare elasticity with respect to means of various
income sources.
First, we derive the social welfare elasticity for Atkinson’s social welfare function. Substituting
(20) into (9) gives:
𝑢 (𝑥 ∗ ) = 𝑢∑ 𝜇 𝐶 (𝑝) 𝑑𝑝 (21)
8 𝐿(𝑝) is defined as the proportion of welfare 𝑥 enjoyed by the bottom 𝑝 proportion of individuals, whereas 𝐶 (𝑝) is the
proportion of 𝑗th income source received by the bottom 𝑝 proportion of individuals when ranked by 𝑥. For a detailed
discussion of properties of the Lorenz curve and concentration curves, see Kakwani (1980).
12 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 662
where 𝑑𝑝 = 𝑔(𝑥)𝑑𝑥, 0 < 𝑝 < 1 and 0 < 𝑥 < ∞. This equation enables us to derive the elasticity of
Atkinson’s social welfare function with respect to the mean of the 𝑗th income source.
We assume that the mean of the jth income source changes without affecting its distribution
across individuals, i.e., 𝐶 (𝑝) does not change when 𝜇 changes. Differentiating (21) with respect to 𝜇
gives the elasticity of 𝑥 ∗ with respect to 𝜇 as:
∗
𝛿 = 𝑢 (𝑥 ∗ ) = ∗ ( ∗)
𝑢 (𝑥 ) 𝑣 (𝑥 )𝑔 (𝑥 ) (22)
In deriving this equation, we have used (18) and (19). The interpretation of this elasticity is as
follows: if the mean of the jth income component increases by 1%, social welfare will increase by 𝛿 %.
Following a similar reasoning as above, we derive the elasticity of 𝑥 ∗ with respect to µ as:
∗
𝛿= ∗ = 𝑢 (𝑥 )𝑥𝑔(𝑥 )𝑑𝑥 (23)
𝛿=∑ 𝛿 (24)
An intuitive interpretation of this equation is that if all income sources change by 1%, the social
welfare 𝑥 ∗ changes by 𝛿%.
Following Atkinson (1970), we assume that the utility function is homothetic as defined in
(12), then the elasticity in (22) becomes:
∈ ( ) ( )
𝛿 = ∈
𝑖𝑓 ∈≠ 1
( )
( )
= 𝑔(𝑥 )𝑑𝑥 𝑖𝑓 ∈= 1 (25)
and from (23) we obtain 𝛿 = 1 for all values of ∈, which from (24) implies that ∑ 𝛿 = 1. The larger
the value of elasticity, the greater the impact of that income source on social welfare. Thus, the higher
the value of elasticity, the greater the welfare superiority of that income source.
Next, we derive the social welfare elasticity for the Gini social welfare function. Kakwani
(1980) has demonstrated that 𝜇𝐺 = ∑ 𝜇 𝐶 , which 𝐶 is the concentration index of the 𝑗th income
source.6 Using this result in conjunction with (6), we can write the Gini social welfare function as:
𝑊 = 𝜇 (1 − 𝐺 ) = ∑ 𝜇 (1 − 𝐶 ) (26)
Differentiating equation (26) with respect to 𝜇 yields the social welfare elasticity of the Gini
social welfare function as:
( )
𝜗 = (27)
( )
6 The concentration index is defined as one minus the area under the concentration curve (Kakwani 1980).
The Distributional Impacts of Fiscal Policy 13
which always implies that ∑ 𝜗 =1. This elasticity like Atkinson’s welfare elasticity indicates that if all
income sources change by 1%, the Gini social welfare changes by 1%. The elasticity enables us to
measure the effect on society’s social welfare (as measured by the Gini social welfare function) for a
small change in the 𝑗th income source. The higher the value of this elasticity, the greater the welfare
superiority of that income source.
In this section, we propose a welfare reform index, which enables us to assess how equitable a
government transfer or tax is or how much it favors the poor or the nonpoor. Differentiating Atkinson’s
social welfare function defined in (11) gives:
( ∗)
𝛿 = − ∗ (28)
Equation (28) equation shows that the welfare elasticity with respect to the jth income sources
can be decomposed into two components. The first term on the right-hand side of (28) is the share of
the 𝑗th income source to total income. This is called the income component, which is the proportional
change in the mean income of society when the mean income of the 𝑗th income sources changes by
1%. The second component on the right-hand side of (28) may be called the inequality effect. It is the
proportional change in social welfare because of the change in income redistribution or inequality
caused by the change in the mean of the 𝑗th income source.
The inequality effect indicates whether an increase in 𝜇 favors the nonpoor or the poor. If this
component is positive (negative), it implies that the redistribution effect of the 𝑗th income source
increases (decreases) social welfare. This leads us to propose a welfare reform index:
𝜑 = −1 (29)
where 𝑠 = is the share of the 𝑗th income source in total income. If 𝜑 is positive (negative), any
increase in the 𝑗th income source will benefit the poor proportionally more (less) than the nonpoor. 𝜑
measures the marginal benefits in terms of the increase in social welfare per additional peso spent on
the 𝑗th income source.
Suppose 𝑖 and 𝑗 are two different government transfer programs. Given this, if 𝜑 > 𝜑 ,
₱1 spent on the 𝑖th program will lead to a greater increase in social welfare than ₱1 spent on the 𝑗th
program. In other words, we can improve social welfare by reducing expenditure on the 𝑗th program
and increasing expenditure on the 𝑖th program by the same amount. Hence, 𝜑 can be usefully
employed to design marginal reform in government tax and expenditure policies.
Similarly, differentiating the Gini social welfare function defined in (26) with respect to 𝜇 gives:
( )
𝜗 = − (30)
This decomposition has a similar interpretation as (28). Thus, the welfare reform index for the
Gini social welfare function is given by:
14 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 662
𝜌 = −1 (31)
We will evaluate the equity of the Philippines’ fiscal system using the two alternative social
welfare functions: Atkinson’s and Sen’s. The reform index for the class of Atkinson’s social welfare
functions is 𝜑 given in (29) and for the Gini social welfare function is 𝜌 given in (31).
Fiscal policies consist of direct taxes levied on individuals’ incomes and indirect taxes levied on
expenditures. In addition, individuals save part of their disposable incomes to invest in future
consumption. The government can directly tax savings through individuals’ deposits in the bank or levy
taxes on returns they derive in the future. The individual welfare can be, therefore, written as:
Assume that there are 𝑚 commodities consumed by individuals, 𝑝 is the price of the 𝑖th
commodity, and 𝑞 (𝑥) is the quantity of the 𝑖th commodity consumed by an individual with welfare 𝑥.
Given this, 𝐸 (𝑥 ) is the total expenditure incurred with mean 𝜇 , 𝑇(𝑥) is the direct tax paid with mean
𝜇 , and 𝑆(𝑥) with mean 𝜇 is the savings by an individual with welfare 𝑥. All expenditure, income tax,
and savings have been deflated by the number of equivalent adults. The average welfare 𝜇 is the sum
p14of averages of total expenditure, direct taxes, and savings.
To assess fiscal policies at the macro level, we calculate the social welfare elasticity with
respect to each of the components in (33). Suppose 𝛿 , 𝛿 , and 𝛿 are social welfare elasticities with
respect to 𝜇 , 𝜇 , and 𝜇 , respectively. Given this, the social welfare elasticity with respect to 𝜇 is
equal to 1 so that:
𝛿 +𝛿 +𝛿 =1 (34)
The welfare reform indexes for each component in (33) can be given by:
𝜑 = −1
𝜑 = −1
𝜑 = −1
such that:
+ + =0 (35)
which provides a framework for evaluating fiscal policy at the macro level.
The Distributional Impacts of Fiscal Policy 15
Indirect taxes are levied on household expenditures and, therefore, increase the prices consumers pay.
The price increases reduce social welfare. In contrast, subsidies on household expenditures increase
social welfare because they reduce the prices consumers pay. To measure the impact of indirect taxes
and subsidies, we calculate the elasticity of social welfare with respect to the price of the 𝑖th
commodity, which is taxed or subsidized.
Suppose that due to indirect taxes and subsidies, the price vector 𝑝 changes to 𝑝∗ . How will
this price change affect the individual welfare 𝑥? To answer this question, we consider the expenditure
function 𝑒(𝑢, 𝑝), which is the minimum expenditure required to maintain 𝑢 level of utility when the
price vector is 𝑝. Because of the change in prices, the real welfare of the individual will change by:
∆𝑥 = − ∑ (𝑝∗ − 𝑝 )𝑞 (𝑥)
= −𝑞 (𝑥) (37)
This equation is useful in deriving the social welfare elasticity with respect to the price of 𝑖th
commodity. First, we consider Atkinson’s social welfare function 𝑥 ∗ given in equation (9).
Differentiating (9) with respect to 𝑝 and utilizing (34) yields:
∗
𝑢 (𝑥 ∗ ) =− 𝑢 (𝑥 )𝑞 (𝑥 )𝑔(𝑥 )𝑑𝑥
where 𝑒 (𝑥) is the expenditure on the 𝑖th commodity of an individual welfare 𝑥. The elasticity 𝜏 will be
negative because any increase in price will reduce individuals’ real income, which in turn will diminish
social welfare. It will be useful to write:
̅ ̅
𝜏 =− + (𝜏 + ) (39)
The first term in (39) is the income effect of the price increase and will always be negative. The
second term is given by:
̅
𝜏 + = −( )
(40)
Equation (40) shows that the second term on the right-hand side of (39) will be positive
(negative) if the increase in the price of the 𝑖th commodity reduces (increases) income inequality.
Thus, the redistribution or inequality effect informs us whether an increase in the price of ith
commodity hurts the poor more than the nonpoor, or vice versa. If this component is positive
(negative), it suggests that the 𝑖th price increase hurts the nonpoor more (less) than the poor. This
leads us to suggest the price reform index:
𝜎 = +1 (41)
If 𝜎 is positive (negative), an increase in the 𝑖th prices hurts the nonpoor more (less) than the
poor. Thus, if 𝜎 is negative (positive), then the 𝑖th commodity should be subsidized (taxed) so that
the poor benefit (suffer) more (less) than the nonpoor. On this account, 𝜎 can be utilized to reform
tax or subsidy systems so that the maxiumum improvement in social welafre is achieved from a given
marginal reform.
A. Direct Taxes
Tables 1 and 2 present the empirical results of the analysis of the distributional impact of the
Philippines’ fiscal system. Table 1 shows the values of the welfare elasticity and welfare reform index for
different income sources using Atkinson and Sen’s social welfare functions. Atkinson’s social welfare
function enables us to assess the distributional impacts for different values of the inequality aversion
parameter. When the inequality aversion parameter is zero, society is not concerned with inequality
and focuses only on improving its average welfare. However, there can be a trade-off between the
average welfare of society and inequality. A government policy may succeed in enhancing the average
welfare of society, but at the same time may lead to stagnant or declining living standards among the
poor. To analyze the distributional impacts of government policies, we should use a social welfare
function, wherein the inequality aversion parameter should be always greater than zero.
As pointed out earlier, the higher the value of the inequality aversion parameter, the greater
the weight given to income transfers at the lower end of the income distribution. Hence, a policy
concerned with the poor’s welfare would require a higher value of the inequality aversion parameter.
How high the value should be, however, cannot be determined a priori. This paper provides the
estimates for the value of inequality aversion parameter equal to 1.
Table 1 shows that the welfare elasticity varies widely for different income sources. If, for
instance, wage and salary income increases by 1%, per capita welfare increases by 0.498%. The result
indicates that wage and salary income is a major source of household welfare among the poor. Among
the poorest 30% of households engaged in an economic activity, nearly 71% depended on their
earnings contributed by wages and salaries. The Philippines has a huge informal economy, which
accounted for 38.3% of the country’s labor force in 2017. The International Labour Organization
(2018) estimates that nearly two in five workers in the country are likely to be employed in jobs with
no formal work arrangements and social protection benefits. The country’s informal economy
The Distributional Impacts of Fiscal Policy 17
covers the so-called underground or informal micro, small, and medium-sized enterprises (MSMEs),
which are not necessarily registered with the government. MSMEs accounted for 99.5% of all
enterprises and employed 63.2% of the labor force as of end-2018 (Shinozaki and Rao 2021). The large
informal economy in the Philippines may be attributed to various reasons such as weak tax
enforcement, inefficiencies of tax administration, and tax avoidance behaviors. Economic activities
outside the government tax systems are estimated to make up 28% of the country’s GDP
(Chongvilaivan and Chooi 2021). Hence, if the Philippine government implements a labor market
policy that increases the share of wage and salary income, the poor will likely benefit more than their
nonpoor counterparts. Moreover, such a labor market policy may be well suited especially in a post-
pandemic setting as it could help bring back part of 1.7 million wage and salary jobs that were wiped out
in 2020 because of the COVID-19 pandemic, according to Asian Development Bank (ADB) estimates
(Bird, Lozano, and Mendoza 2021).
The welfare elasticity for family sustenance activities is 0.021 for both Atkinson and Gini social
welfare functions. This means that the poor depend heavily on such family sustenance activities.
Households engaged in farming and fishery—whose produce or catch are often just enough to feed
their families—comprise the poorest sections in the Philippines. Farmers and fisherfolk belong to
households with highest poverty incidences at 34% each in 2015 (PSA 2017). If the government’s
social objective is to reduce extreme poverty and inequality, it may consider providing subsidies to
poor households relying heavily on family sustenance activities as their major source of welfare.
As suggested, the welfare reform index can be employed to make government fiscal reforms
more equitable through marginal reforms. The positive value of reform index indicates that any
increase in the 𝑗th income source redistributes income from the nonpoor to the poor, resulting in
higher social welfare and lower income inequality. Moreover, the higher the value of the index, the
greater the benefits will be to the poor. The value of reform index for the family sustenance activities is
1.234 when the inequality aversion parameter is equal to 1. The family sustenance activities will
proportionally benefit the poor more than the nonpoor. The extremely poor are likely to benefit even
more from family sustenance activities.
The major source of income for the poor comes from labor earnings because they are unlikely
to possess physical assets. Any policy that increases the share of wages and salaries should, therefore,
help the poor more than the nonpoor. While our empirical results support this proposition, they are
insignificant. The welfare reform index for the wage and salary income is 0.009 when the inequality
aversion parameter for Atkinson’s social welfare function is 1. The corresponding value for the Gini
social welfare function is somewhat larger at 0.027. These results indicate that wage and salary benefit
the poor more than their nonpoor counterparts.
Income sources that disproportionally benefit the nonpoor are rentals from nonagricultural
lands, remittances from abroad, interest, dividends, construction, and social and personal services. The
reform indexes for the income source from pensions and retirement benefits have negative values,
indicating that the poor do not benefit much from this income source as compared to their nonpoor
counterparts. In most developing countries, the poor do not have access to pensions and retirement
benefits. Many workers are engaged in informal sector jobs, which do not provide retirement benefits.
Since the Philippines is now a middle-income country, the government may be in a better position to
mobilize resources for providing universal social security.
In the Philippines, income transfers from abroad contribute nearly 10% of total household
welfare and are largely perceived to help poor families. Such a perception is not supported by our
empirical results. The values of the welfare reform index for remittances from overseas are –0.305 for
The Distributional Impacts of Fiscal Policy 19
Atkinson’s social welfare and –0.349 for Gini social welfare. This suggests that international remittances
are regressive and benefit the nonpoor proportionally more than the poor. This result is consistent with
findings of studies by Pernia (2008) and Deluna and Pedida (2014) that remittances have no significant
effect on income inequality. Although remittances appear to increase average incomes for all income
groups in the Philippines, such increases seem to be greater for richer households than their poorer
counterparts—a pattern that is also observed in several Latin American countries. This is because richer
income quintiles have proportionately more households that receive remittances especially from
abroad and in bigger transfer size relative to poorer income quintiles (Pernia 2008).
By contrast, income transfers from domestic sources show the opposite effect. The values of
the welfare reform index are about 0.7 for both social welfare functions, suggesting that benefits of
domestic remittances generally accrue to the poor. Domestic income transfers are more welfare-
enhancing for poorer households and better at reducing inequality than remittances from abroad. This
may be due to the pattern of internal migration in the Philippines, wherein workers from rural areas
leave for modest jobs in urban centers. Despite this, earnings from such modest jobs serve as one of
the primary sources of support to impoverished rural households.
It is interesting to highlight that the conclusions emerging from Sen’s social welfare function are
broadly consistent with those drawn from Atkinson’s social welfare function, despite different
assumptions underpinning the two social welfare functions. The Atkinson welfare function encompasses
a rather restrictive assumption that an individual’s satisfaction is independent of others’ consumption in
society. In comparison, Sen’s social welfare function assumes that a person does compare herself with
others and feel relatively deprived when she finds her income or consumption lower.
B. Fiscal Policy
We have assessed fiscal policy largely based on three components: (i) direct taxes as mostly
represented by personal income tax; (ii) indirect taxes as captured by total expenditure; and (iii) taxes
on savings.10
The welfare reform index for direct taxes is about –0.6, which indicates that direct taxes such
as personal income tax are progressive so the nonpoor contribute proportionally more than the poor.
In the Philippines, income is taxed progressively up to 35% for the richest taxpayers or those whose
annual taxable income exceeds ₱8 million. However, with the 2018 tax reforms, the rest of taxpayers
will see lower tax rates ranging from 15% to 30% by 2023 (DOF 2022). Even so, the progressivity of the
personal income tax had been diminishing over 2003–2009 as the relative share of tax paid in total
spending of higher-income households had been decreasing compared with lower-income
households. This decline was attributed to difficulties in tax administration (Usui 2011). Since the
distributional impacts of tax depend on its progressivity and size, the overall impact of income tax on
inequality is very small. While this paper finds direct taxes progressive overall, the revenues collected
from direct taxes only account for about 4.5% of the total household welfare.
Assuming the value-added taxes are proportional to total expenditure, the progressivity of
value-added taxes can be assessed based on the welfare reform index of the total expenditure.
10 Accumulated incomes and net savings may influence wealth, which in turn could affect the distribution of inequalities. In
the Philippines, the net personal wealth share of the top 10% declined from 76.2% in 1997 to 62.8% in 2021, according to
data from the World Inequality Database. The analysis of fiscal policies’ impact on wealth is beyond the scope of this
paper and could be examined more extensively in future studies.
20 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 662
This index value as presented in Table 1 is 0.18, derived from Atkinson’s social welfare function.
Thus, we deem the value-added taxes regressive, contributing to worsening inequality, if designed
poorly. Its degree of regressivity can be reduced by giving exemptions to essential goods and services
that are consumed by the poor. Such a policy will, however, make the tax base narrower, resulting in a
smaller tax revenue for the government. A better policy would be to expand the progressive personal
income tax base, which is currently very low in the Philippines.
The welfare reform index for savings is –0.66 when Atkinson’s social welfare function is used.
The result indicates that savings are highly concentrated among rich individuals. Hence, any taxes
imposed on investment incomes will be highly progressive as the rich would bear greater tax burden
than their poor counterparts.
The Philippine government collects about 16% of its revenue from corporate income taxes.
Higher corporate taxes might lower demand for capital and hence reduce the capital stock, increasing its
return and thereby widening the income distribution. Higher corporate taxes might also result in higher
prices from manufacturing corporations, hence, shifting the burden to consumers. Further, the burden of
corporate taxes can be passed on to wages, finding that workers bear about one half of the total tax
burden. In this case, it is reasonable to assume that corporate tax is proportional to wage and salary
income. Nevertheless, our values of welfare reform index for wage and salary, close to 0, suggest that
shifting of the corporate tax burden to high wage and salary earners is rather insignificant. Horizontal
inequities exist among businesses as firms that qualify for tax incentives face effective tax rates between
6% and 14%, while businesses that do not get such incentives face rates as high as 30% (Sawada 2018).
Overall, aside from disproportionately benefiting the nonpoor and weighing down the poor, the
tax system in the Philippines generates little revenue relative to the distortions it creates. The middle
class and poorer segments of the population bear much of the burden of the country’s tax system.
As much as 20% of the total tax collected in 2013 came from only 4.66 million households comprising
the middle class (Angara 2015).
The first series of tax reforms implemented in January 2018 are expected to increase the
progressivity of the Philippines’ tax system. Multilateral development agencies such as ADB and the
World Bank have thrown their support behind these tax reforms, noting that lowering of personal
income tax rates was a right step toward progressivity by easing the tax burden on the middle class.
Moreover, the Philippine government seeks to reduce the current 30% corporate income tax rate to
20% by 2029—a move that has been welcomed by different stakeholders to improve the
competitiveness of the Philippines’ tax system (Tadalan 2019).
Table 2 presents the values of welfare elasticity with respect to prices. Since price hikes erode one’s
real income, economic theory predicts that social welfare will be lower when prices increase. All values
of social welfare elasticity are expected to be negative. Our empirical estimates of elasticity are indeed
consistent with the results anticipated by the economic theory.
The price reform index can be either negative or positive. The positive (negative) value of the price
reform index implies that the increase in prices hurts the poor proportionally more (less) than their nonpoor
counterparts. The value of reform index for food items largely consumed at home is 0.478 when Atkinson’s
social welfare function is used. This suggests that any indirect taxes on food items are highly regressive.
The poor pay a much higher proportion of their income for taxes compared to their nonpoor counterparts.
The Distributional Impacts of Fiscal Policy 21
Table 2: Elasticity and Price Reform Index for Indirect Taxes, 2017
The poorest 30% of the Filipinos spent almost 60% of their expenditures on food in 2018 (PSA 2018).
The index values for nonfood items are rather small for both Atkinson’s and Gini social welfare
functions, although they are mostly negative. This suggests that indirect taxes on most nonfood items
are modestly progressive, suggesting any price increases in nonfood items due to taxes will pass more
on to nonpoor consumers than poor ones. As indicated by the reform index value of 0.18 for the total
expenditure, indirect taxes are overall regressive. Hence, price increases caused by indirect taxes on
food and nonfood expenditure generally hurt poor consumers proportionally more than their nonpoor
counterparts.
Exempting many items largely consumed by the poor is believed to make indirect taxes
somewhat less regressive. Our empirical results do not support this belief. Nevertheless, the degree of
regressivity can be minimized by levying higher tax rates on luxuries and lower rates on necessities, or
zero tax rates on most essential goods and services. Such a tax system with multiple rates could be
designed using our proposed welfare reform index. The commodities with positive (negative) values of
the price reform index would attract lower (higher) tax rates. As our results show, there are only several
expenditure groups with a negative index value. It is indeed difficult to design an indirect tax system
that is progressive. A large number of developing countries rely heavily on indirect taxes because they
are unable to collect sufficient revenues from direct taxes.
Many governments in both developing and developed countries impose heavy excise duties on
alcohol and tobacco. These commodities are generally called “sin goods” because of their adverse
impact on people’s health. Governments, therefore, find it politically easy to sell these taxes to voters.
The values of the price reform index are 0.281 for alcohol beverages and 0.534 for tobacco. The results
suggest that excise taxes on these goods are regressive. The poor bear the heavy burden of excise taxes
on alcohol and especially on tobacco, from which 6.32% of government revenues are sourced. Among
poor households in the National Capital Region, the poor allocate a greater share of their income to
alcohol at 0.90%, compared with 0.58% for the nonpoor.
Table 2 shows that Filipino households spend over 17% of their welfare on housing utilities like
electricity, water, and other fuels. Our estimates of the price reform index suggest that price increases
stemming from taxes on these housing utilities will hurt nonpoor households proportionately more
than their poor counterparts. This is somewhat expected as nonpoor households allocate a greater
proportion of their expenditures on nonfood items like housing utilities to maintain their living
conditions.
It is also interesting to note that expenditures on education and medical services are
progressive as indicated by the negative values of the price reform index, –0.094 for health and –0.115
for education. Many governments exempt these expenditures from taxation. Some governments even
subsidize education and medical services because societies tend to value these services highly.
However, the benefits of these general subsidies largely go to the nonpoor rather than their poor
counterparts. Moreover, general subsidies are costly as well. Education and medical subsidies targeted
to the vulnerable and needy would help create fiscal space for governments.
The Distributional Impacts of Fiscal Policy 23
Fiscal policies play an indispensable role in reducing inequality by redistributing income. For taxes and
transfers to become effective tools for inequality reduction, an important first step is to determine
their distributional impacts. This paper derives the elasticities for Atkinson’s and Gini social welfare
functions and introduces a welfare reform index to assess the extent to which taxes and transfers
reduce inequality among different segments of the population in a country. The proposed
methodology is applied to the Philippines as an empirical illustration.
This paper finds that social welfare elasticity varies widely for different income sources. For
example, a 1% increase in wages and salaries raises total household welfare by 0.498% when the
inequality aversion parameter is set to 1 for Atkinson’s social welfare. This finding implies that wages
and salaries benefit the poor proportionately more than their nonpoor counterparts in the Philippines.
This is in part due to wages and salaries being a major source of income for poor households compared
with their nonpoor counterparts. Among the poorest 30% of households in 2017, more than 70% had
wage- and salary-earning members. Thus, policies seeking to increase the share of wages and salaries
in total income will help improve the overall welfare of poor households.
Family sustenance activities were found to benefit the poor proportionately more than the
nonpoor, as suggested by elasticity and welfare reform index values based on empirical results. This
finding is expected given that poor households are heavily dependent on family sustenance activities
such as farming and fishery. Nearly 75% of the poorest 30% Filipinos were engaged in family
sustenance activities in 2017.
Our findings suggest remittances from abroad to be regressive, while domestic remittances are
progressive. The welfare reform index for income transfers from abroad was –0.305 for Atkinson’s
social welfare function and –0.349 for Gini social welfare function, indicating that international
remittances benefit the nonpoor more than the poor. A similar trend is found in several Latin American
countries and may be due to top income quintiles having more households receiving remittances and
in larger amounts compared with bottom income quintiles. In contrast, the corresponding values for
domestic remittances were 0.668 and 0.696 for Atkinson’s and Gini social welfare functions,
respectively. This suggests that the benefits of remittances from domestic sources accrue more to
poor households than to their nonpoor counterparts. Earnings from rural–urban migration, even from
modest jobs, are an important income source for poor households in rural areas.
The paper also finds that while the personal income tax is progressive, revenues collected from
it account for only less than 5% of the total household welfare. This finding indicates that personal
income tax alone has a limited role to play when it comes to addressing inequality. The decrease in
personal income tax rates as part of the first set of Philippine tax reforms implemented in 2018 was
considered as a move toward progressivity since it reduces the tax burden on the middle class. Still,
more needs to be done to enhance the progressivity of the tax system. The planned reduction of the
corporate income tax rate from 30% to 20% by 2029 is, for instance, expected to make the Philippines’
tax system more progressive and competitive. Assessing the 2018 tax reforms is, however, beyond the
scope of the current paper.
Our estimated value of the price reform index for food group indicate that any indirect taxes
on food are regressive.
24 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 662
The paper’s empirical findings show excise taxes on alcohol and especially tobacco as
regressive. Since 2012, the Philippine government has adopted and repealed laws to increase taxes on
tobacco products and alcoholic beverages (Mendoza 2020). The poor bear much of the burden of
excise taxes as they tend to allocate a greater share of their income to these sin goods than the
nonpoor. In the Philippines, alcoholic beverages account for 2.45% for the total expenditure of the
poorest 30%, while for national-average households, the corresponding figure is 1.58% (Ordinario
2020).
Our focus on the equity perspective in this paper does not imply that efficiency should be
ignored entirely in analyzing fiscal policies. However, the development platforms of many
governments, including the Philippine government, usually revolve around reducing, if not eradicating,
poverty. With poverty reduction as a central development agenda, the social welfare function—which
forms the basis for assessing fiscal policies—should render a greater weight to those at the lower end
of the income distribution than those at the upper end. In such situations, the contribution of
efficiency to social welfare will be rather small as compared to that of equity.
In terms of distributional impacts, various fiscal instruments can increase the average welfare
of society but induce a decline in living standards of poor segments of the population, or vice-versa.
The appropriateness and desirability of taxes and transfers will ultimately depend on the objectives of
policies—i.e., whether they seek to prioritize the welfare of those at the lower end of the income
spectrum or increase the average welfare of the population by expanding the tax base.
Given the findings that have emerged in the paper, the following policy implications can be drawn.
One, use taxes as a platform for job creation. Wages and salaries are major sources of income
for the Filipinos including the poor. Over 70% of the poorest 30% households engaged in an economic
activity that derived their earnings contributed by wage and salary income. Given the large informal
economy in the Philippines, taxes can be used as a platform to create productive jobs. Nearly two in
five Filipino workers are engaged in the informal sector, where MSMEs are operating. The high costs of
tax compliance discourage MSMEs from complying with the rules. For example, MSMEs pay much
higher taxes relative to their income. Further, tax procedures for MSMEs are complex, requiring a
considerable amount of time and resources to comply with tax rules. The government can provide tax
incentives and simplify tax administrative procedures for MSMEs, which can help generate jobs
especially for the poor.
Two, simplify and digitalize the tax system. Digitalizing the country’s tax system can help reduce
the costs of tax administration and improve tax compliance. Greater use and adoption of electronic
services or e-services, such as e-filing and e-payment, electronic business registration and renewal, and
online registration and data management can help improve tax compliance in the Philippines.
Three, widen the tax base. The Philippines’ narrow tax base is attributed to its large informal
sector. Efforts to broaden the country’s tax base would benefit from taxing digital services and
transactions. The prolonged COVID-19 pandemic has encouraged a flourishing digital economy, such
as online selling and video streaming. To tax digital services and transactions, the government must
first adopt a standard definition of activities and transactions that fall under the digital economy. It
must also measure the size and impact of the digital economy. Further, the digital economy tends to
engage self-employed individuals. The Philippines’ Bureau of Internal Revenue estimates that only
22% of self-employed individuals file and pay their income taxes. The government can also simplify tax
procedures for self-employed individuals, including those working in the digital economy, to increase
compliance.
REFERENCES
Angara, Edgardo. 2015. “A Regressive Tax System.” Business Mirror. February 16. https://businessmirror.com.ph
/a-regressive-tax-system/
Atkinson, Anthony. 1970. “On the Measurement of Inequality.” Journal of Economic Theory 2: 244–63.
Bird, Kelly, Cristina Lozano, and Teresa Mendoza. 2021. “Philippines’ COVID-19 Employment
Challenge: Labor Market Programs to the Rescue.” Asian Development Blog, June 4.
https://blogs.adb.org/blog/philippines-covid-19-employment-challenge-labor-market-
programs-to-rescue.
Bureau of Treasury. 2020. “National Government Deficit Widens to P1,371.4 billion in 2020 Full-Year
Shortfall at 7.6% of GDP.” Press Release, February 26.
Chongvilaivan, Aekopol, and Annette Chooi. 2021. A Comprehensive Assessment of Tax Capacity in
Southeast Asia. Manila: Asian Development Bank. https://www.adb.org/publications
/assessment-tax-capacity-southeast-asia.
Cubero, Rodrigo, and Ivanna Vladkova Hollar. 2010. “Equity and Fiscal Policy: The Income Distribution
Effects of Taxation and Social Spending in Central America?” IMF Working Paper 10/112.
International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Danziger, Sheldon, and Michael K. Taussig. 1979. “The Income Unit and the Anatomy of Income
Distribution.” Review of Income and Wealth 25: 365–75.
Diamond, Peter, and Emmanuel Saez. 2011. “The Case for a Progressive Tax: From Basic Research to
Policy Recommendations.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 25 (4): 165–90.
Deluna, Roperto Jr., and Sunshine Pedida. 2014. “Overseas Filipino Workers Remittances, Inequality
and Quality of Life in the Philippines.” MPRA Paper No. 56070. Munich Personal RePEc
Archive. http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/56070.
Estudillo, Jonna P. 1997. “Income Inequality in the Philippines, 1961–1991.” The Developing Economies
XXXV-1 (March 1997): 68–95.
Kakwani, Nanak. 1980. “On a Class of Poverty Measures.” Econometrica 48 (2): 437–46.
Kakwani, Nanak, and Hyun H. Son. 2016. Social Welfare Functions and Development: Measurement and
Policy Applications. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
26 References
Inchauste, Gabriela, Nora Lustig, Mashekwa Maboshe, Catriona Purfield, and Ingrid Woolard. 2015.
“The Distributional Impact of Fiscal Policy in South Africa.” Policy Research Working Paper No.
7194. World Bank, Washington, DC.
Mendoza, Jestine. 2020. “For Universal Healthcare, the Philippines Tries ‘Sin Taxes’.” The Asia
Foundation, March 4. https://asiafoundation.org/2020/03/04/for-universal-healthcare-the-
philippines-tries-sin-taxes/.
Ordinario, Cai. 2020. “’Poorest’ households spend more on alcoholic drinks, tobacco–PSA.” Business
Mirror, February 28.
Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2021. Revenue Statistics.
https://data.oecd.org/tax/tax-revenue.htm (accessed 15 January 2022).
Panti, Llanesca. 2018. “Nearly 4-M households, senior citizens yet to receive TRAIN’s unconditional
cash grants.” GMA News Online, September 10. http://www.gmanetwork.com/news/money/
economy/667217/nearly-4-m-households-senior-citizens-yet-to-receive-train-s-
unconditional-cash-grants/story/.
Pernia, Ernesto. 2008. “Migration, Remittances, Poverty and Inequality in The Philippines.” UPSE
Discussion Papers 200801. University of the Philippines School of Economics, Quezon City.
Philippine Statistics Authority (PSA). 2018. Family Income and Expenditure Survey 2018 Final Report.
Manila.
———. 2017. Farmers, Fishermen and Children consistently posted the highest poverty incidence
among basic sectors – PSA. https://psa.gov.ph/content/farmers-fishermen-and-children-
consistently-posted-highest-poverty-incidence-among-basic.
Sawada, Yasuyuki. 2018. “TRAIN 2 and the Features of a Good Tax System.” Asian Development Bank
Op-Ed/Opinion, July 19. https://www.adb.org/news/op-ed/train-2-and-features-good-tax-
system-yasuyuki-sawada.
Shinozaki, Shigehiro, and Lakshman Nagraj Rao. 2021. “COVID-19 Impact on Micro, Small, and
Medium-Sized Enterprises Under the Lockdown: Evidence from a Rapid Survey in the
Philippines.” ADBI Working Paper No. 1216. Asian Development Bank Institute, Tokyo.
Sicat, Gerardo. 2011. “The Philippine Economy, 1998 to 2010: (Part II) Consumption and Investment
Expenditure.” PhilStar, June 1. https://www.philstar.com/business/2011/06/01/691371/philippine-
economy-1998-2010-part-ii-consumption-and-investment-expenditure#Ves7S5Lc7Gk5DTjJ.99.
Slavov, Sita, and Alan Viard. 2016a. “Taxes, Transfers, Progressivity, and Redistribution: Part 1.” Tax Notes.
Tax Analysts. Virginia.
———. 2016b. “Taxes, Transfers, Progressivity, and Redistribution: Part 2.” Tax Notes. Tax Analysts. Virginia.
References 27
Tadalan, Charmaine. 2019. “House Committee OK’s Corporate Tax Cut.” BusinessWorld, August 15.
https://www.bworldonline.com/house-committee-oks-corporate-tax-cut/.
Usui, Norio. 2011. Tax Reforms Toward Fiscal Consolidation Policy Options for the Government of the
Philippines. Manila: Asian Development Bank.
Valenzuela, Maria Rebecca, Wing-Keung Wong, and Zhu Zhen. 2017. “Income and Consumption
Inequality in the Philippines: A Stochastic Dominance Analysis of Household Unit Records.”
ADBI Working Paper Series No. 662. Asian Development Bank Institute, Tokyo.
This paper focuses on the distributional consequences of fiscal policies. It examines how fiscal policies
affect income distribution by deriving the elasticities of social welfare functions by Atkinson and Sen as well as
introducing a welfare reform index, and applying them to the Philippines’ fiscal instruments. Rentals from
properties, dividends from investment, and remittances from abroad were found regressive, while family
sustenance activities and remittances from domestic sources were found progressive. The paper also
finds the direct taxes of the Philippines to be progressive, although they have limited impact on inequality
reduction given the little revenues they generate.
ADB is committed to achieving a prosperous, inclusive, resilient, and sustainable Asia and the Pacific,
while sustaining its efforts to eradicate extreme poverty. Established in 1966, it is owned by 68 members
—49 from the region. Its main instruments for helping its developing member countries are policy dialogue,
loans, equity investments, guarantees, grants, and technical assistance.