Khin Soe Myat (MBF - 33)
Khin Soe Myat (MBF - 33)
Khin Soe Myat (MBF - 33)
DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE
DECEMBER, 2019
CENTRAL BANK INTERVENTION ON FOREIGN EXCHANGE
VOLATILITY IN MYANMAR
DECEMBER, 2019
ABSTRACT
This study tries to examine Central Bank intervention on exchange and interbank
market and to analyze the effectiveness of Central Bank intervention on exchange rate
volatility in Myanmar. This study is used to analyze effectiveness of Central Bank
intervention on exchange rate volatility by using GARCH model. The data was collected
by using weekly observations of Myanmar Kyat against US Dollar, spanning the period
from 2016 to 2018 after the adoption of floating exchange rate regime. The model
includes two exogenous variables as they can contribute to the exchange rate volatility;
interest rate differentials and trade balance. This implies that the CBM’s net sales of
foreign exchange via auctions were associated with volatility of the Myanmar kyat
against the US dollar. The results found that the net sale is positively signed, meaning
that it seems if there is more CBM intervention through FX Auction, there is more
exchange rate volatility in Myanmar. It is because FX auction is just a mechanism for
setting reference exchange rate. However, data is not significant. In addition, the interest
rate differential between Myanmar and US treasury bill is negative sign and it is
statistically significance which means interest rate had not moved the exchange rate in
the desired direction as there is no perfect capital mobility. The coefficient of trade
balance is positive sign and it is significant. Thus, increase in trade performance leads to
increase in volatility as managed float exchange rate regime is used. Therefore, Central
Bank shout find solutions to trade deficits to encourage exports and tackle down imports
can hinder exchange rate volatility in Myanmar.
i
ACKNOWLEDEMENTS
First of all, I would like to express my deep gratitude to Prof. Dr. Tin Win, Rector
of Yangon University of Economics and Prof. Dr. Ni Lar Myint Htoo, Pro-Rector for
giving me the opportunity to attend the Master course until the thesis.
I am also heartily thankful to Prof. Dr. Daw Soe Thu, Programme Director of
MBF Programme and Head of the Department of Commerce, Yangon University of
Economics.
My deepest thanks go to Prof. Dr. Tin Tin Htwe, Department of Commerce and
Prof. Dr. Su Su Myat, Department of Applied Economics for their extensive and
constructive suggestions, her supporting excellence lecturers and comments to complete
this thesis. I am heartily grateful for her guidance, advice and encouragement in
preparing to complete this study successfully.
I would like to express my sincere gratitude to all the teachers, and visiting
lecturers who have made their grateful efforts in rendering knowledge sharing of MBF
Programme during these two years.
I would like to express my heartfelt indebtedness to all Professors, Associate
Professors and Lecturers who provided supervision and fortitude to help me achieve the
course objective of the programme. In addition, I would like to extend my appreciation to
the faculty and all the staffs in the Department of Commerce who have provided me with
any administrative support and strength during my academic years.
Finally, I would like to express my gratitude to my beloved parents, family and
friends from MBF Day 1st Batch for their continuous support and patience throughout the
course of my study.
ii
Table of Contents
Page
Abstract i
Acknowledgements ii
Table of Contents iii
List of Tables v
List of Figures vi
List of Abbreviations vii
Chapter I Introduction 1
1.1 Rationale of the Study 2
1.2 Objectives of the Study 3
1.3 Scope and Method of the Study 3
1.4 Organization of the Study 4
iii
Chapter IV Analysis on The Effectiveness of Central Bank
Intervention on Foreign 26
Exchange Volatility in Myanmar
4.1 Research Methodology 26
4.2 Trade Balance of Myanmar 26
Interest Rate Trend of the Treasury Bill of Myanmar
4.3
and US 28
Analysis of Central Bank Intervention on Foreign
4.4
Exchange Rate Volatility 29
Chapter V Conclusion 34
5.1 Findings 34
5.2 Suggestions 35
5.3 Need for Further Study 36
References
Appendices
iv
List of Tables
v
List of Figures
Figure
Description Page
No.
Comparison between CBM Reference Rate and Interbank Market
3.1 21
Rate
vi
List of Abbreviations
vii
Chapter I
Introduction
The central bank is nowadays primarily regulatory for monetary policy. The
structure of Central bank roles, the responsibilities, and the functions vary between
countries. Among these roles, monetary stability is also important for economic growth in
which exchange rate policy is crucial to consider as a tool to sterilize the growth. To
stabilize the monetary policy, foreign intervention is one of the monetary policies of
central banks.
With regard to foreign intervention, the collapse of the Bretton Woods system in
1970s brought major changes and broad variety of choices for exchange rate regimes
each country had been free to choose any form of exchange arrangement, varying from
pure free floating to intermediate regimes, hard pegs, crawling pegs, currency unions and
flexible exchange rate. The determination of an exchange rate regime is key factor for
countries’ macroeconomic stability. Both fixed and flexible regimes have their pros and
cons.
Intervention is defined as official purchases and sales of foreign exchange to
moderate exchange rate fluctuations, to correct misalignment and disordered market
conditions, to accumulate foreign reserves, to supply foreign exchange to market, to
control inflation, to prevent speculation and to maintain monetary and financial stability.
Moreover, successful intervention depends on the choice of instruments, markets and
timing to maximize the impact on the exchange rate.
Intervention may affect the exchange rate through many channels. Under the
signaling channel, market participants may adjust their exchange rate expectations when
they perceive intervention as signaling a change in future monetary policy. Under the
portfolio balance channel, the change in the currency composition of asset portfolios
associated with the sterilized intervention generates a change in the risk premium, which
triggers an exchange rate adjustment as agents rebalance their portfolio with monetary
policy, to stabilize market expectations, calm disorderly markets and limit unwarranted
exchange rate movements resulting from temporary shocks.
1
One view criticized that the exchange rate should be freely determined by market
forces, independently of any intervention or targeting by Central Bank’s monetary policy,
other view confirming the Central Bank intervention and control Michael, M., Masson,
P., Swoboda, A., Jadresic, E., Mauro, P., Berg, A. (2000). Therefore, the choice of an
exchange rate regime is a critical aspect to ensure competitiveness and economic growth.
Floating exchange rate has been regarded as an automatic stabilizer, which is able in
some cases to rebalance the unbalanced economy.
2
Since one of the main CBM’s policies is to reduce the exchange rate volatility,
including some monetary policy variables in the model allows addressing the issue of
how effective they are. Therefore, this study will examine the Central Bank intervention
on foreign exchange and will analyze whether Central Bank intervention can reduce
exchange volatility in Myanmar. However, as only CBM intervention is not enough to
stable exchange rate, this study also analyzes the other factors like domestic interest rate
and trade balance of the country.
The interest rate differential between MMK and US Dollar is also major
determinant of exchange rate. In trade balance, if export exceeds import, the country will
be trade surplus and domestic currency will also be appreciated. In developing countries,
trade balance is mostly likely trade deficit because developing countries need to build up
new infrastructures which are mostly imported from other countries. Therefore, the CBM,
regulator, needs to monitor closely the trade balance, interest rate, foreign exchange
inflow and outflow to sterilize the exchange rate in stabilization.
3
intervention in interbank market are used to analyze central bank intervention on
exchange rate volatility and other influencing factors. In this study, the intervention data
series are net sales (sales less purchases) in millions of USD. This study is also used not
only CBM reference rate but also spot dealing in interbank market because the condition
of market is reflected by spot rate of interbank market. Data are obtained from CBM,
Bloomberg and Thomson Reuter.
In order to analyze Central Bank intervention on exchange rate volatility by
contributing of two exogenous variables: interest rate differentials and trade balance by
using the generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity (GARCH) process
which is often used by financial modeling professionals because it provides a more
realistic condition to predict the prices and rates of financial instruments.
4
Chapter II
Literature Review
This chapter presented the roles and functions of central banks, central policies,
intervention channel, intervention operations and previous studies.
5
2.2 Central Bank Policies
Central banks conduct in ensuring economic and financial stability. They also
play as important role for monetary policy to achieve low and stable inflation. Therefore,
Central banks adequate policy frameworks to achieve their objectives. However,
operational processes of Central Bank tailored to situation of each country to enhance the
effectiveness of the central banks’ policies. Therefore, this section explains central bank
policies which includes monetary policies, foreign exchange regimes policies,
macroprudential policies (International Monetary Fund Factsheet, 2017).
There are three basic types of monetary policy strategies, each of which uses a
different nominal anchor: 1) exchange-rate targeting; 2) monetary targeting; and 3)
inflation targeting. Emerging market countries also have used monetary targeting as it a
successful strategy. The monetary policy frameworks of most emerging countries’ central
banks have used the information conveyed by a monetary aggregate to conduct monetary
policy. However, the instability of the money-inflation relationship also has been very
visible by monetary targeting in emerging market countries. Therefore, monetary
targeting has not been attracted very seriously in these countries (International Monetary
Fund Factsheet, 2017).
With respect to exchange-rate targeting, it has been an effective way of reducing
inflation quickly in both industrialized and emerging market countries. However,
exchange-rate targeting can lose of independent monetary policy. Therefore, exchange-
rate targets may lead to higher volatility. There are two types of Exchange-rate targeting.
They are soft pegs and hard pegs. Soft pegs is the commitment to the peg is not
institutionalized, and hard peg is the institutional commitment comes either from
establishment of a currency board or from dollarization (International Monetary Fund
Factsheet, 2017).
Inflation targeting is a recent monetary policy strategy. It contains five main
elements. They are the public announcement of medium-term numerical targets for
inflation, an institutional commitment to price stability, an information inclusive strategy,
an increased transparency of the monetary policy strategy and an increased accountability
6
of the central bank for attaining its inflation objectives (International Monetary Fund
Factsheet, 2017).
The global financial crisis showed that countries need to contain risks to the
financial systems a whole with dedicated financial policies. Many central banks have
responsibilities to promote financial stability by upgrading their financial stability
frameworks and establishing macro prudential policy frameworks. Macroprudential
7
policy needs a strong institutional framework to work effectively. Central banks are well
placed to conduct macro prudential policy because they have the capacity to analyze
systemic risk. In many countries, legislators have assigned the macro prudential mandate
to the central bank or to a dedicated committee within the central bank (International
Monetary Fund Factsheet, 2017).
If macroprudential is used, the institution should be strong to counter opposition
from the financial industry and political pressures. Policy makers need to be clear
objectives and to get the necessary legal powers, and to foster cooperation on the part of
other supervisory and regulatory agencies (International Monetary Fund Factsheet, 2017).
8
credible otherwise or because it believes, based on its information advantage, that the
level and direction of the exchange rate are unwarranted (Shogo Ishii et al., 2006).
The signaling channel depends in part on the institutional and policy credibility of
the central bank. The effectiveness of intervention through signaling relies on influencing
market expectations by transmitting information on fundamentals or future policy
actions. The signaling channel is most effective when interventions are publicly
announced, which enhances the visibility of intervention, thus strengthening the central
bank’s policy signal (Shogo Ishii et al., 2006).
The signaling channel, however, may be less effective in developing countries.
First, central banks in many developing economies are at a disadvantage with respect to
institutional and policy credibility. They tend to lack the record of prudent
macroeconomic management that underpins the strong credibility of monetary authorities
in advanced economies. Ongoing structural shifts in many developing economies—
among them financial deepening, economic opening, private sector orientation, and shifts
in the exchange rate regime—make it difficult to establish predictable and stable links
between real and financial variables and, therefore, between intervention and future
monetary policies Shogo Ishii et al., (2006).
9
currency debt is an imperfect substitute for foreign currency debt, and interventions are
large relative to foreign exchange market turnover (Shogo Ishii et al., 2006).
10
channel also emphasizes that the size of intervention relative to market turnover
determines the effectiveness of that intervention. In principle, the larger the intervention
relative to market turnover, the higher its effect on the exchange rate. Thus, intervention
has the potential to be more effective in developing countries, where foreign exchange
markets are less liquid (Shogo Ishii et al., 2006).
Intervention generally should take place in the spot market rather than in the
forward market when the goal is to affect the spot exchange rate Shogo Ishii et al.,
(2006). The reasons are as follows:
a) Spot market intervention directly affects the spot exchange rate. Forward market
intervention relies on the transmission mechanism from forward to spot market
rates, which is affected by money market conditions as well as exchange and
capital controls.
b) Spot market intervention is less susceptible to liquidity risk. Spot markets are
usually more liquid and less constrained by counterparty limits than are forward
markets.
Intervention should normally take place in onshore markets where the bulk of
foreign exchange trading takes place. Concentrating interventions in the domestic market
helps maintain the primacy of the domestic market and may give the central bank greater
access to market information and intelligence. In addition, central banks can effectively
11
address the order flow imbalance created offshore by intervening onshore. In some cases,
intervention in offshore currency markets may play a useful role (Shogo Ishii et al., 2006)
In particular, the central bank may intervene in offshore currency markets when
the local currency trades offshore beyond the normal working hours in the onshore
market, exchange rate pressures emerge in offshore markets, and secret intervention is
preferred and easier to conduct offshore. Several operational issues must be addressed
when intervening in offshore markets. The central bank may have to appoint an agent to
act on its behalf, which can be a foreign central bank, the Bank for International
Settlements, or a foreign or domestic commercial bank. The central bank or its agent
would have to abide by the rules and regulations of the markets in which intervention
takes place (Shogo Ishii et al., 2006)
12
economies of scale and by avoiding transportation and warehousing costs. In the presence
of exchange controls, however, central bank intervention in the retail cash market may
rein in unwarranted depreciation expectations (Shogo Ishii et al., 2006).
The retail cash market, which is often linked to the parallel market rate, can
become the center for price discovery and the formation of exchange rate expectations,
even if it is a small fraction of trading and highly volatile. Therefore, intervention in cash
markets, including parallel markets, can sometimes help prevent unwarranted shifts in
exchange rate expectations (Shogo Ishii et al., 2006)
13
trading and are not willing to offer two-way quotes, the central bank’s direct participation
can intensify competition.
14
the impact of foreign exchange intervention on exchange rate volatility (Baillie, 1992)
and (Dominguez, 1998).
Most of these studies look at the conditional exchange rate volatility by estimating
the Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedastic (GARCH) models. Results
of these studies indicate mixed trend and some studies suggest that central bank
intervention tends to increase the conditional exchange rate volatility (Dominguez, 1998),
while other studies show that foreign exchange intervention tends to reduce exchange rate
volatility (Dominguez, 1998). In contrast, there are some studies shown that while the
impact of foreign exchange intervention on exchange rate volatility, there was no impact
of central bank interventions on exchange rate volatility (Baillie, 1992).
According to (Marwa A. Elsberif, 2016), he studied that exchange rate vitality
and central bank actions in Egypt by using GARCH in which three variables interest rate,
trade balance and official reserves were used. Results found that central bank action
impacted positively in exchange rate vitality.
Therefore, this study is based on previous studies to analyzed whether Central
Bank of Myanmar actions influence exchange rate volatility by using GARCH by using
weekly observations of Myanmar Kyat against US Dollar, spanning the period from 2016
to 2018 after the adoption of floating exchange rate regime.
15
Chapter III
Central Bank Intervention on Foreign Exchange Market in Myanmar
This chapter will discuss on roles and functions of Central Bank of Myanmar,
foreign exchange market reform before 2012 and after 2012. In addition, foreign
exchange market revolution and intervention in Myanmar.
16
e) to manage the foreign reserves of the State and to make the transactions on
behalf of the State in intergovernmental organization and
f) to undertake all the responsibilities in the name of the Government in dealing
with the aforesaid organizations on behalf of the Government.
Moreover, the CBM promotes:
a) price stability through the proper conduct of monetary policy;
b) financial stability through prudent banking supervision and regulation; and
c) an efficient payments and settlements system.
Central Bank of Myanmar used monetary targeting monetary policy framework in
2012. Under monetary targeting regime, the central bank target money supply as
intermediate and reserve money is operating target to ensure macroeconomic consistency
and to get the ultimate objective of price stability. Central Bank makes decision how
much liquidity need to inject or absorb into the market by using liquidity forecasting
framework.
In addition, CBM tried to develop Capital Market on behalf of the Government
and to give the public more opportunities to save. Therefore, the CBM has issued and
sold 3-year and 5-year Government Treasury Bonds in 1993. The Central Bank of
Myanmar has formulated and implemented the monetary policy which is consistent with
economic and production growth rates.
The CBM has been actively engaged as an independent central bank, advising and
support legislative changes related to Myanmar’s financial system as per Central Bank of
Myanmar Law (2013). Currently, the Central Bank of Myanmar mainly uses monetary
policy instruments such as reserves requirements, interest rate policy and limited open-
market operation to get financial sector stability.
17
exchange rate system to a managed floating exchange rate system. Therefore, the below
sections present about situation of before and after reform of foreign exchange in
Myanmar.
From 1977 until the recent reforms 2012, the official kyat exchange rate was fixed
to the value of the International Monetary Fund’s Special Drawing Rights. However,
Myanmar’s economy operated with a de facto multiple exchange rate system which
distorted the allocation system of foreign exchange operated by the state banks and
forced the private sector to rely on informal markets for foreign exchange because of the
unrealistic level of the official exchange rate and strict controls on foreign exchange.
Therefore, the government unified the exchange rate market by replacing the old system
with a managed float to eliminate these distortions. Kubo Koji, (2015)
However, the informal foreign exchange market and the informal fund transfer
system are a legacy of the restrictive regulations in the past. Foreign trade was legalized
for the private sector in September 1989, but there was no official channel for private
firms to convert export revenues into the local currency, the kyat. Myanmar’s citizens
were not allowed to hold foreign currency note in previous foreign exchange regulation
did not permit to hold foreign currency notes. At that time, private exporters were
required to make foreign currency transactions at two state owned banks, MFTB, MICB
by opening foreign currency deposits account. Additionally, foreign exchange certificates
(FECs) issued in 1, 5 and 10 denominations to limit circulation of US currency. Local
citizens can also use FECs, however, bank charge a 10 percent as a service fee and they
can only withdraw in kyat. The fixed exchange is end in August 2003 and the FECs was
discontinued in 2013.
Over time, the official pegged exchange became more and more divorced from
the exchange rate used by the general public in the parallel exchange markets that have
grown due to the heavily regulated use of foreign exchange in the formal market. The
parallel market eventually became the dominant medium for the Myanmar public to
satisfy their needs for foreign exchange. As this parallel market was not an official
market, the government had little ability to interact and influence the exchange rate in
18
Myanmar. Replacing the official peg to the SDR with a market-determined exchange rate
removed the large discrepancy between the official rate and the real market exchange
rates. Therefore, CBM needs to intervene in some circumstance to maintain exchange
rate stable in foreign exchange market.
In all these areas, the CBM and other Myanmar authorities worked together to
ensure that the changes are smooth and did not cause any market disruptions. Since the
official exchange rate has been used by the public sector only, while the private sector
has been already using the informal market exchange rate, any significant impact of this
change on the private sector did not found. All these areas, the CBM, domestic and
international concerned agencies are working together to ensure that the changes were
smooth.
In April, 2012, Foreign Exchange Management Law lifts restrictions on
transactions on exports and imports of goods and services. In August, 2012, Foreign
Exchange Management Law introduces managed float system. In addition, in August,
2013, Interbank foreign exchange market opened for all private banks. And in November,
2013, Financial Institutions of Myanmar Law was revised to install more efficient
banking system. In 2014, a new Banking and Financial Institutions Law reached the final
stage of drafting.
19
exchange market to influence the market exchange rate, when the CBM finds this
necessary. The kyat exchange rate versus a range of trading partner currencies will be
market determined and publicized daily by both the CBM and authorized FX dealers.
This decision was part of the reform program for modernizing the economy that the new
Government of Myanmar initiated in the second half of 2011. This program aimed to
unify the various exchange rates and gradually eliminate restrictions on current
international payments and transfers abroad.
Until February, 2019, the CBM is setting the reference exchange rate based on the
cut-off rate of its two-way foreign exchange daily auction, which was introduced in 2012.
It was in order to facilitate the development of the foreign exchange market. The two-
way foreign exchange auction worked to develop foreign exchange market and to
discover price. The size of the interbank market increased from 2013-2014 financial year
to 2017-2018 financial year. Therefore, the Central Bank of Myanmar try to setup new
development which is to determine reference exchange rate as market-based weighted
average rate in line with the international best practices of the central banks.
The market-based weighted average rate is calculated the volume weighted
average exchange rate of interbank and bank-customer deals during the day. This new
mechanism was developed to avoid this misalignment and it reference rate publishes in
the same day to reflect current market condition. According to the CBM Instruction No.
5/2019 (dated February 4, 2019), the Reference Exchange Rate of the Myanmar Kyat
equivalent to one unit of the US Dollar is computed and published by the Central Bank of
Myanmar on its website every bank business day at 16:00.
The reference exchange rate is calculated based on weighted average exchange
rate of the spot trades by the banks from 9:00 to 15:00 of that day. The trade deals
include: (i) Spot interbank trades conducted between the Authorized Dealer Licensed
banks (interbank trades); (ii) Spot trades conducted between the Authorized Dealer
Licensed banks and their customers (bank-customers trades).
The Reference Exchange Rate is calculated as 60 percent weighted from weighted
average exchange rate of the interbank trades and 40 percent weighted from the bank-
customers’ trade when the total amount of interbank trades is more than three (3) million
U.S. Dollar on that day.
20
The relative weights in calculation of the Reference Exchange Rate is reviewed
update to up based on the share of interbank trades. CBM announced that the Reference
Exchange Rate is just an indicative rate. Participants in the foreign exchange market are
not required compulsory to use it in their foreign exchange transactions.
Figure (3.1) Comparison between CBM Reference And Interbank Market Rate
1,700
1,600
Exchange Rate
1,500
1,400
1,300
1,200
1,100
I II III IV I II III IV I II III IV
21
As per data show in Figure (3.1), CBM reference rate was reflected interbank spot
rate at market as there was not significant different. However, fourth quarter of 2018,
CBM reference rate is above the interbank spot rate because the CBM also abolished the
trading band (Reference rate +/-0.8%) in August 2018.
Figure (3.2) illustrates volatility of exchange rate in interbank spot rate. Exchange
rate of MMK/USD is highly volatility in first and second quarter of 2016, first quarter of
2017 and third and fourth quarter of 2018. The sign was holding MMK to convert USD
was risk as volatile from -3 to 3 which was wide range. In addition, for exporter and
importer from Myanmar was suffered exchange risk.
ERM1
Figure (3.2) Exchange Rate Volatility in Interbank Spot Rate
4
Daily Return of the USD against MMK percent
-1
-2
-3
I II III IV I II III IV I II III IV
22
96.83 million, sale USD 19.65 million and net purchase USD 77.18 million. According to
data from survey period, CBM intervened by absorbing USD liquidity in market.
As the foreign exchange auctions are two–way, they can lead to either
accumulation or dissipation of foreign reserves. In survey period, the daily sales and
purchases of foreign exchange were net purchase USD 315.43 million, net inflow of USD
to CBM.
157.41
150
122.82
96.83
100
-100 -77.18
-115.44 -122.81
-150
In 2016, MMK was appreciated and CBM bought USD 115.44 million from
interbank market which mean market had excess USD supply. Moreover, in 2018, MMK
was depreciated and highest deprecation MMK along survey period and CBM purchased
USD 77.88 million. Although intervention amount was low in 2018, intervention times
was high because CBM sold USD in FX Auction to determine CBM daily reference rate
to reflect the market.
Figure (3.4) indicates intervention times in interbank through FX Auction.
According to data, Central Bank intervene 146 times in purchasing and 512 times selling
from 2016 to 2018.
23
Figure (3.4) Number of Transactions in FX Auction
600
512
500
No. of Transactions
400
300 251
Purchasing Selling
In 2018, 19% for purchasing and 54% for selling in FX auction of all trading days
are intervened. The single largest daily intervention, USD 37 million, occurred in fourth
quarter of 2018, and the largest yearly average intervention occurred in 2017 with USD
122.81 million. The data also suggests an asymmetry in the nature of CBM’s intervention
24
operations as there are fewer foreign exchange sales. Specifically, net sales of foreign
exchange are less frequent within 2017 and 2018.
Within 2016 and 2018, CBM intervened in market. CBM heavily purchased any
excess supply of dollars. This not only protected the export competitiveness but also
enabled CBM to build foreign exchange reserves. The total purchase amount was USD
315.43 million and exchange rate depreciated by 20.26%. Since one of the main CBM’s
policies is to reduce the exchange rate volatility, including some monetary policy
variables in the model allows addressing the issue of how effective they are.
25
Chapter IV
Analysis on the Effectiveness of Central Bank Intervention on Foreign
Exchange Volatility in Myanmar
This chapter briefly highlights the methods and procedures that were used in
carrying out the study. It includes the following; CBM intervention through FX Auction,
comparison of interest rate for US Treasury bill and Myanmar government bill,
descriptive analysis of export and import of Myanmar.
1,500
1,000
USD in Million
500
-500
-1,000
I II III IV I II III IV I II III IV
EID EX IM
NX
27
4.3 Interest Rate Trend of the Treasury Bill of Myanmar and US
From a theoretical standpoint, the increased in short-term interest rate causes
exchange rate appreciation. The interest differential is chances for arbitragers and it
induces markets to create liquidity, then raise volatility in the short period, however, it is
insignificant in the longer prospect. Therefore, greater interest rate differential, more
likely to increase exchange rate volatility Kocenda and Valachy, (2006).
Therefore, controlling for short-term interest rate and Comforting exchange
holding are desirable while investigating the effectiveness of CBM’s intervention. In this
study, the interest rate for 3 months US Treasury bill and Myanmar Government bill were
used to analyze how short-term interest rate will affect to exchange rate volatility.
According to data, the interest rate for US Treasury bill was 0.81% to 2.41% from 2016
to 2018. With regard to Myanmar Government Bill, the interest rate was 3.1% to 7.91%
from 2016 to 2018.
Figure (4.2) Interest Rate Trend of the Treasury Bill of Myanmar and US
9
6
Interest Rate (%)
0
I II III IV I II III IV I II III IV
MMT 3M UST 3M
29
4.6.1 Unit Root Test
Many economic and financial time series show trending behavior or non-
stationarity in the mean. When the data are trending, then some form of trend removal is
required. Unit root tests can be used to decide when trending data should be first
differenced or regressed on deterministic functions of time to render the data stationary.
To investigate whether the variables are stationary and to determine the order of
integration of the variables, the augmented Dickey– Fuller (ADF) test is employed.
Variables are tested in both level and 1st difference forms, with intercept The ADF test
results in Table (4.1) strongly reject the null hypothesis of a unit root (variables are
stationary) for 1st difference. The evidence of unit root test shows that return on net sale
and trade balance are stationary at level while on exchange rate, net sale, trade balance
and interest rate differential are stationary at first difference at 1% level of significance.
30
volatility by adopting the use of generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity
(GARCH) models pioneered by Engle (1982). Since then volatility can be estimated
using time series econometric techniques. GARCH family is used by many researchers
worldwide, demonstrating that there exists temporal clustering in the variances of the
exchange rate changes. Following these previous studies, this work applies GARCH
analysis to model the exchange rate volatility and how effective the Central Bank actions
throughout study period 2016-2018.
GARCH (1,1) model is used to investigate volatility characteristics using weekly
data (January 2016 to December 2018). In order to analyze Central Bank intervention on
exchange rate volatility by contributing of two exogenous variables: interest rate
differentials and trade balance by using the generalized autoregressive conditional
heteroskedasticity (GARCH) process which is often used by financial modeling
professionals because it provides a more realistic condition to predict the prices and rates
of financial instruments. GARCH (1,1) model for the weekly data is as follows;
erm is calculated by log of weekly exchange rate which indicates the volatility of
exchange rate and NSALE is sale less purchase in FX Auction by CBM from private
banks. Residual derived from mean Equation (1) is used in forming variance Equation
(2), for the variance equation. The model specification of this study is as follows:
31
ε2t−1 = the lagged squared residual derived from Equation (1)
σt−12 = the lagged conditional variance
IRD = the difference between Myanmar and US interest rates of 3-month
treasury bills
NX = the difference between merchandized value of exports and
merchandized value of imports in Myanmar (calculated in billion
USD)
β1 and β2 = coefficients of ε2t−1 and of σt−12respectively
ϒ1 and ϒ2 = coefficients of IRD and EID
C 7.214214* 0.0000
NSALE 8.73E-10 0.8971
NX 2.14E-06** 0.0381
IRD -0.000248** 0.0365
32
The coefficient of IRD is negative and it is significant. Theoretically, in the
country where is liberalized capital mobilization, when interest rate differential is high, it
leads to high exchange rate volatility. However, in this study, the results found that high
interest rate difference causes low exchange rate volatility. It is because Myanmar does
not have perfect capital mobilization. In addition, domestic and foreign investors do not
response based on sensitivity of interest rate. The reasons are investors from Myanmar
may invest within countries as domestic interest rate is higher than foreign interest rate
and foreign investors may not be interested to invest in less attractive financial markets.
33
Chapter V
Conclusion
This study analyzes empirically the impact of Central Bank actions through IRD
as well as trade balance on exchange rate volatility in Myanmar using GARCH
framework. The main results are as follows; volatility clustering exists during study
period, IRDs and trade deficits accelerates exchange rate volatility. Therefore, this
chapter presents the finding, suggestion and need for further study.
5.1 Findings
After the official peg was abolished, managed float is used since April 2012. As
per new mechanism, the Central Bank of Myanmar has operated daily foreign exchange
auctions. These auctions have had three functions: (1) providing the CBM with a market–
determined exchange rate, (2) supplying or absorbing foreign exchange in interbank
market, and (3) serving as a policy instrument to intervene in the foreign exchange
market.
According to analysis on data, MMK was depreciated 20.26% from 2016 to 2018.
Although CBM try to stable the exchange rate, the volatility of exchange rate was
continuously high in 2017 and 2018. With respect to CBM intervention on market, CBM
made net purchased from private banks through FX Auction from 2016 and 2018 to
control exchange rate volatility because CBM needed to absorb liquidity from FE market.
In addition, trade balance in Myanmar was deficit along 2016, 2017 and 2018.
Although amount of trade deficit was high in 2016 and 2017, amount of trade deficit was
declined in 2018. However, the result found that export was exceeded in first quarter of
2017 and fourth quarter of 2018. Moreover, when the interest rate differential between
US and Myanmar is analyzed, differential amount is large. The result found that US
treasury interest was constantly increasing and Myanmar Treasury Bill interest rate was
fluctuated overtime because US is developed and stable in financial market, but,
Myanmar is started trying to build financial market especially in capital market and
money market.
34
Using daily data on auctions and exchange rates for the period 2016 – 2018, the
FX auctions impacts on foreign exchange rate. The GARCH model incorporating the
variables indicate that the NSALE in FX auction is positive and it is insignificant.
Therefore, it can conclude that CBM intervention in FE market does not influence on
exchange rate volatility and CBM intervention through FX auction made to discover the
daily reference exchange rate.
Trade balance of Myanmar is positive and it is significant. It indicates that when
net export of Myanmar is high, exchange rate volatility is high. Therefore, as trade deficit
in Myanmar occurred along 2016 to 2018, exchange rate volatility is high. When IRD is
tested whether it influenced on foreign exchange rate volatility, the coefficient was
negative and it is significant. Therefore, high interest rate difference leads to low
exchange rate volatility in Myanmar because capital mobilization in Myanmar is some
extent and it is not fully liberalized. In addition, financial markets in Myanmar does not
develop well to attract the investors.
Therefore, the effectiveness of intervention on exchange rate is more difficult to
assess, since the exchange rate is more susceptible to multi-dimensional indicators and
market reactions to them. In addition, the results imply that the FX auction works as a
means of setting up reference exchange rate. According to this study, FX auction have
caused increasing the official foreign reserves. Thus, foreign exchange auctions should be
recognized as a transitory arrangement that should operate only until the interbank
foreign exchange market is developed.
5.2 Suggestions
According to analysis, MMK was depreciated and the volatility of exchange rate
is high and the demand for USD is high in end of year because the exchange rate
fluctuation has seasonal effect. Therefore, CBM should intervene to control exchange
rate volatility by injecting or absorbing foreign currency in FE market with cumulating
foreign reserves of CBM.
In the economy of developed country, interest rate differential between other
countries shall affect the value of currency. However, with regard to Myanmar, the
interest rate differential was negative on exchange rate volatility because CBM does not
35
allow perfect capital mobilization and foreign investors do not interest to invest in less
liquid market. Thus, when CBM liberalizes interest rate and ease on FDI flow, the
interest rate differential may affect the exchange rate in Myanmar. Therefore, CBM
should prepare to maintain less exchange rate volatility at that time.
With regard to trade balance in Myanmar, as domestic consumers spend more on
foreign products than domestic producers sell to foreign consumers, it can cause a trade
deficit. However, in Myanmar, demand for foreign currency is vary from the season.
When the weather is good to conduct business, the demand for foreign currency is high.
Moreover, the demand for USD is low in rainy season as farming business are run and
the export agriculture products. Therefore, CBM should monitor to balance the demand
and supply of foreign currency in country in order to stable exchange rate.
Therefore, when CBM tends to decrease exchange rate volatility, it is highly
recommended that mitigate IRDs and it is important to find solutions for trade deficit that
Myanmar encounter for long time through import substitution or export promotion trade
policies.
36
References
1. Baillie, R.T., and W.P. Osterberg (1997). Why do central banks intervene?
Journal of International Money and Finance 16(6), 909–919
2. Bank For International Settlements, 2016. Foreign Exchange Turnover in April
2016. Triennial Central Bank Survey
3. Calvo, G.A., Reinhart, C.M. (2000), Fear of floating. Quarterly Journal
Economics, 117, 379-408.
4. Canales-Krilienko, Jorge Ivan, 2003a, “Foreign Exchange Intervention in
Developing and Transition Economies: Result of a Survey,” IMF Working Paper
03/95 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
5. Central Bank of Myanmar Law, 2013
6. Dominguez, K.M. (1998), Central bank intervention and exchange rate volatility.
Journal of International Money and Finance,17(1), 161-190.
7. Foreign Exchange Management Law, 2012
8. Foreign Exchange Management Law, 2015
9. Instruction No. 5/2019 dated on 4.2.2019 from Central Bank of Myanmar
10. International Monetary Fund Factsheet, (2017)
11. International Monetary Fund. (1997), World Economic Outlook. Washington, DC:
International Monetary Fund.
12. International Monetary Fund. (2012), Annual Report on Exchange Rate
Arrangements and Exchange Rate Restrictions. Washington, DC: International
Monetary Fund.
13. Jorge Ivan, Canales-Kriljenko, Roberto Guimaraes and Cem Karacadag, “Official
Intervention in the Foreign Exchange Market: Elements of Best Practice” IMF
Working Paper 03/152 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
14. Kocenda, E., Valachy, J. (2006), Exchange rate volatility and regime change: A
Visegrad comparison. Journal of Comparative Economics, 34(4), 727-753.
15. Kubo Koji, (2015). Impacts of foreign exchange auctions on the informal market
rate in Myanmar, IDE Discussion Paper, 532, Institute of Developing Economies,
Japan External Trade Organization (IDE-JETRO)
37
16. Marwa A. Elsberif (2016). Exchange Rate Volatility and Central Bank Actions in
Egypt: Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity Analysis.
International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues. 2016, 6(3), 1209-1216
17. Michael, M., Masson, P., Swoboda, A., Jadresic, E., Mauro, P., Berg, A. (2000),
Exchange Rate Regimes in an Increasingly Integrated World Economy, IMF
Occasional Paper, 193. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Sciences,
3(2), 117-122.
18. Obstfeld, Maurice. (1994). International Capital Mobility in the 1990s.
International Finance Discussion Paper. 1994. 10.17016/IFDP.1994.472.
19. Sebastian Fristedt. (2016), Does the choice of exchange-rate regime effect
economic growth? A study across different levels of country development.
Södertörns University | Institution of Economics
20. Shogo Ishii, Jorge Iván Canales-Kriljenko, Roberto Guimarães, and Cem
Karacadag, (2006). Official Foreign Exchange Intervention. International
Monetary Fund, Occasional Paper 249
21. Simwaka, K., and L. Mkandawire (2012). The efficacy of official intervention in
the foreign exchange market in Malawi. African Development Review 24(2), 125–
136.
38
Appendices
(1) Number of Transactions and Amount Intervention in FX Auction
39
(2) GARCH estimation of the exchange rate Volatility
Dependent Variable : ERM
Method : ML ARCH- Normal distribution (BFGS/Marquardt steps)
Date: 11/19/2019 Time : 22:04
Sample : 1/01/2016 12/28/2018
Included obervations: 157
Failure to improve likelihood (non-zero gradients) after 32 iterations
Coefficient covariance computed using outer product of gradients
Per sample variance: back cast (parameter = 0.7)
GRACH = C(3) + C(4) *RESID (-1)^2 + C(5)* GARCH (-1)+
C(6)*EID + C(7) * IRD
Variance Equation
40