Grantham DoctrinalBasisRights 1998
Grantham DoctrinalBasisRights 1998
Grantham DoctrinalBasisRights 1998
REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
https://www.jstor.org/stable/4508493?seq=1&cid=pdf-
reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
and Cambridge University Press are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to The Cambridge Law Journal
Year 1998
Based in Great Britain
Ross Grantham*
I. Introduction
554
the Theorv of Companv Law (Clarendon, Oxford, 1993) pp. 33-40; Reich, "The New
(1974) 73 Yale L.J. 733.
The assumption is even more prevalent amongst business commentators. For a ran
indicative selection of recent comments which rely upon or discuss this assum
"Reforming the Firm", The Economist, 9 August 1997, p. 14; "Kid's Stuff", 77m? E
21 June 1997, pp. 74-75; Bughin and Copeland, "The Virtuous Cycle of Shareho
Creation" (1997) McKinsey Quarterly 156; Geddes, "Ownership, Regulation, and M
Monitoring in the Electric Utility Industry" (1997) 40 J. of Law and Economics 261; Fr
"New World Order in the Board Room" (1996) 20 Directors and Boards 6; Useem a
"Employee Shareholders or Institutional Investor?" (1996) 33 J. of Management Stu
Samuels, Greenfield and Piper, "The Role of Non-Executive Directors Post-Cadbury"
J. of General Management 1; Boatright, "Fiduciary Duties and the Shareholder-Man
Relation: Or, What's So Special About Shareholders?" (1994) 4 Business Ethics Quart
"Shareholders of the Nations, Unite!" (1994) 108 Investors Chronicle 12.
' Parkinson, op. cit. n.4, pp. 75-76. See also, Morse (ed.), Palmer's Company Law (25th
& Maxwell. London, 1992) Vol. 1, para. 6.001: "the shareholder is the proportionate
the company ..."
Ford, Austin and Ramsay, Ford's Principles of Corporations Law (8th ed., Butterworth
1997) para. 8.095. See also, Gilles, The New Corporations Law (2nd ed., Federat
Sydney, 1992) p. 22. As for New Zealand, see Beck et al. (eds.), Morison's Com
Securities Law (Butterworths, Wellington, 1997) Vol. 2, para. 13.1.
! Welling, Corporate Law in Canada: The Governing Principles (2nd ed., Butterworths
1991) p. 456. See also, Buckley, Corporations: Principles and Policies (3rd ed.,
Montgomery, Toronto, 1995) p. 185; Canada Corporations Law Reporter (CCH Canad
Ontario, 1997) para. 7000: "the shareholders of a corporation are the owne
corporations ..."
1 Sappideen, "Ownership of the Large Corporation: Why Clothe the Emperor?" (19
King's Coilege L.J. 27.
' Berle and Means, The Modern Corporation and Private Property (rev'd ed., Harcourt, B
World, New York, 1967)
1 Werner, "Corporation Law in Search of its Future" (1981) 81 Columbia L.R. 1161.
Generally, see Dan-Cohen, Rights, Persons, and Organizations: A Legal Theory for Bureaucratic
Society (University of California Press, 1986) pp. 21-22.
Closely held companies are excused many of the formalities and reporting requirements of larger
companies (see, for example, section 381A of the Companies Act 1985) and, through section 459
When Queen Victoria ascended the throne in 1837 there were two
principal vehicles for the conduct of large scale business ventures-the
corporation and the joint stock company.17 The corporation owed its
existence to Royal Charter or an Act of Parliament and, like its
predecessors dating back at least two centuries, it had a separate
legal existence.'8 By far the most important vehicle, however, was the
joint stock company. In law the joint stock company was nothing
more than a large partnership.'9 While it had shares that were freely
transferable,20 a board of directors and a constitution still recognisable
as such today,21 the joint stock company did not enjoy a separate
of the Companies Act, the law will give effect to the actual agreement or expectations of the
"quasi-partners".
'4 Freedman, "Small Businesses and the Corporate Form: Burden or Privilege?" (1994) 57 M.L.R.
555, chronicles these attempts both in the United Kingdom and elsewhere. See also, Hicks,
"Corporate Form: Questioning the Unsung Hero" [1997] J.B.L. 306.
5 It is arguable that incorporation was not intended for, and should not be made available to,
small business ventures. While it is clear that Robert Lowe, the architect of the early companies
statutes, wanted limited liability extended to small traders, a wish frustrated for a short time by
the Lords, it seems that he did not feel it appropriate to allow small traders to be incorporated.
As discussed below, one of the central features of the 1844 Companies Act was to restrict
incorporation to large enterprises. See also Hicks, ibid., pp. 311-316.
6 Sealy, "Perception and Policy in Company Law Reform" in Feldman and Meisel (eds.), Corporate
and Commercial Law. Modern Developments (Lloyd's of London Press. London, 1996) p. 26;
Freedman, n.14 above.
17 See generally, Grantham and Rickett, "The Bootmaker's Legacy to Company Law Doctrine" in
Grantham and Rickett (eds.), Corporate Personality in the 20th Century (Hart, Oxford, 1998)
Chapter 1.
ts Halsbury's Laws of England, (4th ed.), Vol. 9, para. 1209.
'9 Sealy, "Perception and Policy in Company Law Reform" in Feldman and Meisel (eds.), Corporate
and Commercial Law: Modern Developments (Lloyd's of London Press, London, 1996) pp. 11-13;
Davies, Gower's Principles of Modern Company Law (6th ed., Sweet & Maxwell, London, 1997)
p. 31; Lobban, "Corporate Identity and Limited Liability in France and England 1825-67"
(1996) 25 Anglo-American L.R. 397, 401. It is of course true that there were differences between
ordinary partnerships and the large joint stock form (see Ireland, "The Triumph of the Company
Legal Form 1856-1914" in Adams (ed.), Essays for Clive Schmitthoff (Professional Books,
Abingdon, 1985) p. 32. The difficulty for the courts was to find a legal structure between an
incorporated entity and a partnership without the assistance of Parliament.
20 Although the creation of freely transferrable shares was prohibited by the Bubble Act 1720, this
did not prevent the creation of "companies" with shares that were, at least in substance if not
formally, freely transferrable.
21 See Du Bois, The English Business Company after the Bubble Act 1720-1800 (New York
Commonwealth Fund, New York, 1938) p. 291 and Davies, op. cit. n.19, p. 29.
Joint stock
company and
application of This content downloaded from
partnership 14.139.58.153 on Fri, 18 Aug 2023 09:12:32 +00:00
justification All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
for ownership
558 The Cambridge Law Journal [1998]
perspective ofthe rights, inter alia, to determine how the property should be u
from the
44 Generally see, Davies, op. cit. n.19, p. 299; Rice, "The Legal Nature of a Share" (1957) 2
(N.S.) 433; Pennington, "Can Shares in Companies Be Defined?" (1989) 10 Co. Lawyer 1
45 Buckeridge v. Ingram (1795) 2 Ves. Jun. 652; Howse v. Chapman (1799) 4 Ves. Jun. 542. Se
Rice, ibid. pp. 433-434 and Pennington, ibid. p. 140.
46 Suttons Hospital Case (1612) 10 Co. Rep. I; Salmon v. Hamborough Co. (1671) 1 Ch. Ca
Navlor v. Cornish (1648) l Vern. 311. See also Pennington, ibid.\ Davies, op.cit. n.19, p. 299
47 Child v. Hudson's Bay Co. (1723) 2 P. Wms. 207; Harrison v. Pryse (1740) Barn. Ch. 324
48 (1836) 2 Y. & C. 268. See also Myers v Pcrigal (1852) 2 De G.M. & G. 599; Watson v. Sp
(1854) 10 Ex. 222; Edwards v. Hall (1855) 6 De G.M. & G. 74; Linley v. Taylor (1859) 1 Gi
Entwistle v. Davis (1867) 4 Eq. 272.
49 Rice, "The Legal Nature of a Share" (1957) 21 Conv. (N.S.) 433, 434-435.
50 [1901] 1 Ch. 279, 288.
51 Davies, op. cit. n.19, p 301. See also Beck et al. (eds.), Morison's Company and Securit
(Butterworths, Wellington, 1997) para. 13.1. Thus, although it is often cited for the propo
that shareholders do not own the company (see, for example, WelHng, Corporate Law in C
The Governing Principles (2nd ed., Butterworths, Toronto, 1991) p. 602; Wishart, Compan
in Context (O.U.P., Auckland, 1994) p. 110), it is not clear that Borland's Trustees stands for th
proposition.
(1939) 61 C.L.R. 457, 503-504. See also the comments of Lord Wrenbury in Bradbury v. English
Sewing Cotton Co. Ltd. [1923] A.C. 744, 767: "A share . . . forms, however, a separate right
property. The capital is the property of the corporation. The share . . . is the property of the
corporator."
[1977] 2 N.Z.L.R. 225, 295 (H.C).
See also I.R.C. v. Crossman [1937] A.C. 26, 66, where Lord Russell described the share as an
"interest being composed of rights and obligations which are defined by the Companies Act and
by the memorandum and articles of association of the company."
This focus also manifested itself in the largely instrumentalist conferral of proprietary status on
the share. The share was treated as property not because it was an interest in the company, but
simply in order to secure the shareholders' rights and to emphasise that shareholders might
pursue their own self-interest in the exercise of these rights. See, Peters' American Delicacv v.
Heath (1939) 61 C.L.R. 457, 504; Carruth v. Imperial Chemical Industries Ltd. [1937] A.C. 707,
765; Pennington, Company Law (7th ed., Butterworths, London, 1995) p. 70.
' [1948] 1 K.B. 122. In Mellon v. Alliance Textiles Ltd. (1987) 3 N.Z.C.L.C. 100,086, 100,092.
Hardie Boys J. said "when the subject matter is a holding in a large public company, the share
can only be regarded as an investment
' This conclusion also seem to be reflected in the principles which govern the valuation of shares.
The shares will only be valued on an asset-backing basis where the company is unlikely to
continue as a going concern.
For example, the right to vote on matters such as the alteration of the constitu
ratification of irregular transactions. See section V(A) below.
Ford, Austin and Ramsay, op. cit. n.7, pp. 224-225. See also Davies, op. cit. n.19, p. 18
Du Bois, The English Business Company After the Bubble Act 1720-1800 (N
Commonwealth Fund, New York, 1938) p. 291.
Davies, op. cit. n.19, pp. 14-15; Ford, Austin and Ramsay, op. cit n.7, p. 220.
Stokes, "Company Law and Legal Theory" in Twining (ed.), Legal Theorv and Comm
(Blackwell, Oxford, 1986) p. 163.
{1906] 2 Ch. 42 (C.A.). In this line of authorities see also: Thomas Logan Ltd. v. Dav
104 L.T. 14; Scott v. Scott [1943] 1 All E.R. 582; Breckland Group Holdings Ltd. v. L
Suffolk Properties Ltd. (1988) 4 B.C.C 542; Black White and Grey Cabs Ltd. v. F
N.Z.L.R. 824; Clifton v. Mount Morgan Ltd. (1940) 40 S.R.(N.S.W) 31; Winthrop Inve
Ltd. v. Winns Ltd. [1975] 2 N.S.W.L.R. 666.
[1909] 1 Ch. 311 (C.A.), affirmed [1909] A.C. 442 (H.L.).
The comments of the Court of Appeal in Gramophone and Typewriter Ltd. v. Stanley [1908]
K..B. 89, which are often taken to contrary effect, must be seen in their special context. The cas
involved an attempt by the Revenue to lift the veil and assess the shareholders for the profits o
the company. To succeed it was necessary for the Revenue to establish that it was th
shareholders in their personal capacity that controlled the company, not merely that the genera
meeting had authority to direct the board. As it is to this that the comments of the Court wer
addressed the case says little about the internal division of power.
Stokes, "Company Law and Legal Theory" in Twining (ed.), Legal Theory and Common Law
(Blackwell, Oxford, 1986) pp. 163-164.
Davies, op. cit. n.19, pp. 14-16.
See, for example, Brennan J.'s description in Northside Developments Ltd. v. Registrar-General
(1990) 170 C.L.R. 146, 172, of the source and delegation of power within the company. As Ford
Austin and Ramsay (op. cit. n.7, p. 221) note. on this approach "company law vests in certai
groups of people an original authority to commit the company or delegate to others. . . . Th
relationship between the board and general meeting is not hierarchical. According to the organ
approach, whatever may have been the case in the past, the power to bind the modern company
is divided between the board and the general meeting . . .".
1 Clifton v. Mount Morgan Ltd. (1940) 40 S.R. (N.S.W.) 31.
Until changed in 1985 (Art. 70, Table A, Companies (Tables A to F) Regulations 1985 (S.I
805, 1985)), the articles conferring power on the board (Art. 80 of Table A of the First Sched
to Companies Act 1948) qualified the conferral by providing that it was "subject nevertheles
any regulation of these articles, to provisions of the Act and to such regulations, being
inconsistent with the aforesaid regulations or provisions, as may be prescribed by the compa
in general meeting". As other commentators have pointed out (Goldberg, "Article 80 of
A of the Companies Act 1948" (1970) 33 M.L.R. 177; Sullivan, "The Relationship Between
Board of Directors and the General Meeting in Limited Companies" (1977) 93 L.Q.R. 569
article seemed to provide for sharehoider control of management. However, the case law
century deprived the words quoted above of any meaning. The difiiculties with the wording
the empowering article, however. indicates how strong was the courts* resolve to exclu
shareholders from any involvement in the management of the company.
HowardSmith Ltd. v. Ampol Petroieum Ltd. [1974] A.C 821, 837.
Grantham, "The Unanimous Consent Rule in Company Law" [1993] C.L.J. 245.
Timstall v. Steigmatm [1962] 2 Q.B. 583; Timaru Herald Co. Ltd. v Commissioner of Taxes [19
RZ.L.R. 978 (C.A.).
[1935] 2 K.B. 113, 134. For a recent example of how entrenched this view is see the decision of
the Supreme Court of New South Waies in N.R.M.A. v. Parker (1986) N.S.W.L.R. 517.
definition of the term to avoid the illogical insistence that shareholders act in the interests of the
entity when the dispute is essentially about the personal rights of shareholders.
82 Rixon, ibid., p. 467.
83 [1942] Ch. 304 (C.A.).
4 [1920] I Ch. 154 (C.A.).
85 [1971] Ch. 317.
8 (1938) 60 C.L.R. 150.
87 [1985] B.C.L.C. 11.
8 Rixon, op. cit n.81., p. 473. See also Sealy, "Company Law-When Discrimination is Legitimate"
[1985] C.L.J. 365, 367. In Ganbotto v. WCP Ltd. (1995) 182 C.L.R. 432, 446, the High Court
held that a benefit to the entity was not sufficient to justify expropriation of minority shares.
This aspect of the decision was based more on what the Court held were the proper purposes
of the power to expropriate than a position indicating that the interests of the company should
be equated with the interests of shareholders. Thus, the Court accepted that potential harm to
the entity would justify expropriation.
89 [1982] 3 All E.R. 1016 (Ch.D.).
(1986) 4 N.S.W.L.R. 22 (S.C., N.S.W).
' (1939) 61 C.L.R. 457.
92 It was precisely because the dispute to which the test related was between shareholders that
Dixon J. felt it inappropriate. In such a dispute the interests of the company are not at stake.
Dixon J.'s approach has recently been affirmed by the High Court of Australia in Gambotto v.
WCP Ltd. (1995) 182 C.L.R. 432.
93 See the famous debate between Professors Adolf Berle and Merrick Dodd: Berle, "Corporate
Powers as Powers in Trust" (1931) 44 Harv. L.R. 1049 and "For Whom Corporate Managers
-Are Trustees: A Note" (1932) 45 Harv. L.R. 1365; Dodd. "For Whom are Corporate Managers
Trustees? (1932) 45 Harv. L.R. 1145. See also. Davies, op. cit. n.19, p. 602.
94 Professor Berle's point in the aforementioned debate was not whether management should
consider the interests of other stakeholders, but whether the price of doing so was too high.
Berle later conceded the argument to Dodd (Berle, "Corporate Decision Making and Social
Control (1968) 24 Bus. Lawyer 149, 150), though his concession was somewhat premature. See
also Prentice, "Directors, Creditors, and Shareholders" in McKendrick, (ed.), Commercial Aspects
of Trusts and Fiduciary Obligations (Clarendon, Oxford. 1992) pp. 76-77. and Dickerson, Howard
and Getz, Proposals for a Newt Business Corporations Law for Canadla (Information Canada.
Ottawa, 1971) Vol. 1, para. 32.
95 Sealy, "Directors 'Wider' Responsibilities-Problems Conceptual, Practical and Procedural"
(1987) 13 Monash U.L.R. 164, 184; Boyle. Gore-Browne on Companies (44th ed., Jordans, Bristol.
1986) para. 27.4 and 27.4.1; Parkinson, op. tit. n.4, p. 82; Xuereb, "The Juridification of
Industrial Relations Through Company Law Reform" (1988) 51 M.L.R, 156.
[ (19921 B.C.C. 863.
"7 bid., p. 876. See also, Re Saul D. Harrison plc [1994] B.C.C. 475 (Ch.D. and C.A.) where a
petition under section 459 of the Companies Act 1985 was dismissed on the basis that the
directors were entitled to act in the interests of employees.
Section 309(2) of the Companies Act 1985 provides that the duty is "owed to the company (and
the company alone) and is enforceable in the same way as any other fiduciary duty owed to a
company by its directors".
See note 97.
0 Generally see, Prentice, "Creditor's Interests and Director's Duties" (1990) 10 O.J.L.S. 265;
Prentice, "Directors, Creditors, and Shareholders" in McKendrick (ed.), Commercial Aspects of
Trusts and Fiduciary Obligations (Clarendon, Oxford, 1992) p. 73; Sappideen, "Fiduciary
Obligations to Corporate Creditors" [1991] J.B.L. 365; Wishart, "Models and Theories of
Directors' Duties to Creditors" (1991) 14 N.Z.U.L.R. 323. Grantham, "The Judicial Extension
of Directors' Duties to Creditors" [1991] J.B.L. 1.
1 Prentice, "Creditor's Interests and Director's Duties" (1990) 10 O.J.L.S. 265; Grantham, ibid.
2 Parkinson, op. cit. n.4, p. 77.
3 The shareholders of the target company do in fact benefit from the bid. As Gordon,
"Corporations, Markets, and Courts" (1991) 91 Columbia L.R. 1931, 1949, notes "empirical
evidence available to the court overwhelmingly shows that shareholders make out exceedingly
well in takeovers, that shareholders of firms that successfully rebulT a hostile bid lose out on
average. and that shareholders sufler significant losses when states adopt more protective anti-
takeover regimes". See also, Black, "Bidder Overpayment in Takeovers" (1989) 41 Stanford
L.R. 597, and Jarell et al., "The Market for Corporate Control: The Empirical Evidence Since
1980" (1988) 2 J. Econ. Persp. 49.
14 For an overview of the history and general thrust of these provisions see, Millon, "Redefining
Corporate Law" (1991) 24 Indiana L.R. 223; Gordon, "Corporations, Markets, and Courts"
(1991) 91 Columbia L.R. 1931; Henning, "Corporate Law After the Eighties: Reflections on the
Relationship Between Management, Shareholders, and Stakeholders" (1992) 36 St. Louis
University L.J. 519; Tyson, "The Proper Relationship between Federal and State Law in the
Regulation of Tender OfTers" (1990) 66 Notre Dame L.R. 241; Chandy, Foster, Braswell and
Poe, "The Shareholder Wealth EfTects of the Pennsylvania Fourth Generation Anti-Takeover
Law" (1995) 32 American Bus. L.J. 399.
While often formulated in permissive terms and ostensibly limited in application to the takeover
context, the effect of these statutes is, as Millon notes, to "reject the orthodox shareholder
primacy principle. . . . By decentering the shareholder, these statutes also reject corporate law's
traditional fixation with the shareholder-manager relationship thrust non-shareholders into
the limelight as legitimate objects of corporate law's attention": Millon, "Redefining Corporate
Law" (1991) 24 Indiana L.R. 223, 277.
Generally see, Fink, "The Rebirth of the Tender Offer? Paramount Communications Inc v. QVC
Network Inc." (1995) 20 Delaware J. of Corp. Law 133; Millon, "Redefining Corporate Law"
(1991) 24 Indiana L.R. 223; Gordon, "Corporations, Markets, and Courts" (1991) 91 Columbia
L.R. 1931; Henning, "Corporate Law After the Eighties: Reflections on the Relationship
Between Management, Shareholders, and Stakeholders" (1992) 36 St. Louis University L.J. 519.
493 A.2d. 946(1985).
Ibid., p. 955.
571 A.2d. 1140(1990).
Although in Paramount Communications Inc. v. QVC Network Inc. 637 A.2d. 34 (1994) the
Court has refined the boundary it set in Time between Unocal and Revlon Inc v. MacAndrews
& Forhes Holdings Inc. 506 A.2d. 173 (1986) (which requires the directors to get the best price
where they have resolved that the company should be sold), by accepting that the directors
might unintentionally put the company up for sale, the decision does not indicate a recantation
of the rejection of the principle of shareholder primacy.
This embraces both hostile takeovers as well as any situation where shareholders seek to remove
the incumbent board.
Carracher, "Takeovers, Directors and Auctions: A Duty to Sell?" (1991) 7 Australian Bar Rev.
75, considered the application of the Revlon "auction duty" to the Commonwealth. He
concludes that "Australia is on the cusp of rejecting the Easterbrook and Fischel approach and
accepting the legitimacy of defensive tactics simpliciter to defeat takeovers." (p. 82)
1 (1986)2 B.CC 99,024.
1 (1988) 4 B.CC 305, 314 (Outer House).
' [1983] B.CL.C 244 (CA.).
129 For example, it was quite consistent with the view of incorporation as a concession f
state that the members were not permitted to change the nature of the company'
(initially changes were possible only by Royal Charter or special Act of Parliament)
permitted to only within limits set by the state (even when alteration of the memora
permitted via the Companies Act state scrutiny of the alteration remained). The state's
over the type of business carried on by the company also entailed that the members c
ratify transactions beyond the powers afforded the company by the state.
30 Thus, the members could not ratify a breach of the directors' duty which in
expropriation of the company's property (Cook v. Decks 11916] 1 A.C. 554 (P.C.)), be
was something in which the other shareholders had a stake by virtue of their shareho
Davies, op. cit. n.19, p. 646.
T' Theseus Exploration N. L v. Mining and Associated Industries Ltd. [19731 Qld. Rep. 8
Standard Charterel Bank v. Walker 11992] I W.L.R. 561 (Ch.D.). See also, Yeung, "C
Groups: Legal Aspects of the Management Dilemma" [1997] L.M.C.L.Q. 208, 243
Grantham, "The Liability of Parent Companies for the Actions of the Director
Subsidiaries" (1997) 18 Co. Lawyer 138, 146.
132 Allen. v. Gold Reef. of West Africa Ltd. [1900] 1 Ch. 656; Peters' American Delicacy C
Heath. (1939) 61 C.L.R. 457; Gamnhotto. v. WCP Ltd. (1995) 182 C.L.R. 432.
133 In the recent Australian case of Miller v. Miller (1995) 16 A.C.S.R. 73, 86-87 Santo
"Ratilication is not available where it would constitute a fraud on the minorit
misappropriation of company resources . . .or was entered into by an insolvent com
the prejudice of creditors . . . or defeated a member's personal right . . . or was opp
where the majority in general meeting acted for the same improper purpose as directo
'34 Generally on this subject see: Farwell, A Concise Treatise on Powers. (3rd ed., Stevens,
1916). Chapter 10: Sugden, A Practical Treatise of Powers. (7th ed., Sweet, London.
II p. 181; Finn, Fiduciary Obligations. (Law Book Co., Sydney, 1977) paras. 84 and
Grbich, "Fraud on a Power: Judicial Control of Appointments by Discretionary T
(1977) 3 Monash U.L.R. 210; Benas, "The Nature of Fraud of a Power" (1947) 12 C
106; Hanbury, "Frauds on a Power-An Opportunity for Stocktaking" (1948) 64 L.Q
Grantham. "The Powers of Company Directors and the Proper Purposes Doctrine" (1
5 King's College L.J. 16.
G. Summary
Viewed with the benefit of hindsight, the position and influ
shareholders has undoubtedly undergone a radical change. W
shareholders once stood at the centre of the corporate univer
the undisputed right to control the management and direction
company and to have it run for their exclusive benefit, this
shareholders have become little more than bystanders.136 Wh
to the methodology of the common law latent inconsistencies rem
the law has rejected or limited those rights which were crucia
shareholders' claims to proprietorship. In doing so, while it
clear what, if anything, has replaced it, it is clear that the
rejected the 19th century image of the company as a q
partnership.
Wedderburn, "Shareholders' Rights and the Rule in Foss. v. Harbottle." [1957] C.L.J. 194. 198
Welling, Corporate Law in Canada: The Governing Principles. (2nd ed., Butterworths, Toronto.
1991) p. 637.
Bratton, "The New Economic Theory of the Firm: Critical Perspectives From History" (1989
41 Stanford L.R. 1471, 1475-6.
Hart, "Definition and Theory in Jurisprudence" (1954) 70 L.Q.R. 37; Hohfeld, Fundamental
Legal Conceptions as Applied in Judicial Reasoning. (Yale Uni. Press, New Haven, 1923) Chapters
6 and 7; Radin, "The Endless Problem of Corporate Personality" (1932) 32 Columbia L.R. 643.
Northside Developments Pty. Ltd. v. Registrar-General (1990) 170 C.L.R. 146.
Re Supply of Ready Mixed Concrete (No. 2) [1995] 1 A.C. 456 (H.L.).
Mcridian Global Funds Management Ltd. v. Securities Commission [1995] 2 A.C. 500 (P.C.).
Meridian Global Funds Management Ltd. v. Securities Commission, ibid., p. 506.
Hart, Kelsen, Radin, Manne, above; "The Limits and Rationale of Corporate Altruism: An
Individualistic Model" (1973) 59 Virginia L.R. 708, 709.
Welsh, "The Criminal Liability of Corporations" (1946) 62 L.Q.R. 345, 346.
While vicarious liability was not employed in English law (Davies, op. cit. n.19, p. 229), it
served as the doctrinal basis for the imposition of corporate criminal liability in the United
States of America: Khanna, "Corporate Criminal Liability: What Purpose Does It Serve?"
(1996) 109 Harv. L.R. 1477, and Walsh and Pyrich, "Corporate Compliance Programs as a
Defense to Criminal Liability: Can a Corporation Save Its Soul?" (1995) 47 Rutgers L.R. 605.
Re Supply of Ready Mixed Concrete (No. 2} [1995] 1 A.C. 456 (H.L.); Meridian Global Funds
Management Ltd. v. Securities Commission [1995] 2 A.C. 500 (PC).
duty to is to act in, and only in, the beneficiary's interests.'46 The
beneficiary's interest thus not only defines the goal toward which the
fiduciary must work, but also provides an objective yardstick against
which to test the fiduciary's assertions of loyalty. When applied to
natural persons these principles work well enough: the beneficiaries
have real interests, independent of the fiduciary's discretion. Their
application to companies, however, poses difficulties. The company as
an artificial entity does not have real interests. If, therefore, the
beneficiaries' interest is to give a justiciable content to the duty, it is
necessary for the law to ascribe to the company the real interests of
some person or group.'47
From this perspective the central issue is: which individuals
should be treated as the company for this purpose? Historically
shareholders were treated as the beneficiaries of the duty because of
their status as ultimate proprietors.'48 It would, however, still be
rational for a system that has never treated shareholders as owners
to make shareholders' interests central. Thus; for example, it may still
be appropriate to treat shareholders as the company because of the
policy of the particular rule being applied'49 or because the selection
of sharcholders is likely to promote the efficient operation of the
company. As residual claimants, shareholders have the greatest
incentive to monitor the conduct of management. Their selection as
donees of rights such as those to appoint and remove the board
could. therefore, be justified on the basis that they are the most likely
to act to prevent managerial abuse and shirking.150
The point of the foregoing discussion is merely to demonstrate
that whatever may have been the historical reasons for vesting rights
in shareholders, their status as proprietor is not a necessary
consequence of their possessing these rights. The important rights
46 For recent statements to this effect see Bristol and West Building Society v. Mothew [1997] 2
W.L.R. 436. 449 per Millett L.J.; Aritage v. Nurse [1997] 3 WL.R. 1046, 1053 per Millett L.J.
See also Finn. Fiduciary Obligations (Law Book Co., Sydney, 1977) p. 15; Finn, "Fiduciary Law
and the Modern Commercial World" in McKendrick (ed.), Commercial Aspects of Trusts and
Fiduciary Obligations (Clarendon, Oxford, 1992) p. 9; Finn, "The Fiduciary Principle" in
Youdan (ed.), Equity, Fiduciaries and Trusts (Carswell, Toronto, 1989) p. 24
'7 Finn, Fiduciary Obligations (Law Book Co., Sydney, 1977) p. 17, says that the fiduciary
obligation is premised upon the "notion that those who are, as a matter of law, the beneficiaries
of a relationship do have also, as a matter of fact, a real interest in the product of the
fiduciaries' activities . . ." See also Grantham, "Reforming the Duties of Company Directors"
(1991) 12 Co. Lawyer 27.
'u Ford, Austin and Ramsay, op. cit. n.7, p. 303; Sealy, "The Director as Trustee" [1967] C.L.J. 83,
89.
'49 Thus in Equiticorp Industries Group Ltd. (in stat. man.) v. Attorney-General (No. 47 [1998] 2
N.Z.L.R. 481, 729-730 Smellie J. explained the power of shareholders to ratify a breach of
directors' duties in terms of the policy of the fiduciary duty and how, since to vest that power
in directors would frustrate that policy, it followed that shareholders should be the donees of
that power.
50 This is most clearly articulated in the modem contractual analysis of the company. See note
152 below.
151 Equiticorp Industries Group Ltd. (in stat. man.) v. Attorney-General (No. 47), above.
The leading advocates of this approach are Easterbrook and Fischel, The Economic Structu
Corporate Law (Harvard Uni. Press, Cambridge, 1991) and "The Corporate Contract"
89 Columbia L.R. 1416. See also Macey and Miller, "Corporate Stakeholders: A Contra
Perspective" (1993) 43 Uni. Toronto L.J. 401; Jensen and Meckling, "The Theory of the
Managerial Behaviour, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure" (1976) J. Fin. Econ. 3
Cheffins, Company Law: Theory Structure and Operation (Clarendon, Oxford, 1997). For ou
of the history and structure of the contractual analysis by non-believers see: Bratton, "Th
Economic Theory of the Firm: Critical Perspectives from History" (1989) 42 Stanfor
1471 and Parkinson, "The Contractual Theory of the Company and the Protection o
Shareholder Interests" in Feldman and Meisel, Corporate and Commercial Law: M
Developments (Lloyd's of London Press, London, 1996) p. 121.
Easterbrook and Fischel. "Voting in Corporate Law" (1983) 26 J. of Law and Econ. 39
Fama. "Agency Problems and the Theory of the Firm" (1980) 88 J. of Political Econ. 28
Parkinson, "The Contractual Theory of the Company and the Protection of Share
Interests" in Feldman and Meisel (eds.), Corporate and Commercial Law (Lloyds o( Lo
Press. London. 1996) p. 123.
Cheflins, op. cit. n. 152, Chapter 6.
At least in the hands of Easterbrook and Fischel, The Economic Structure of Corpora
(Harvard Uni. Press, Cambridge, 1991) the contractual analysis is intended as both a norm
principle as well as an explanatory one: DeMott. "Trust and Tension Within Corpora
(1996)81 Cornell L.R. 1308. 1312.
156 See the essays in Mitchell, Progressive Corporate Law (WestView, Colorado, 1995) and the
scholarship collected in the bibliography in Millon, "New Directions in Corporate Law:
Communitarians, Contractarians, and the Crisis in Corporate Law" (1993) 50 Wash. and Lee
L.R. 1373.
157 Branson, "The Death of Contractarianism and the Vindication of Structure and Authority
Corporate Governance and Corporate Law" in Mitchell, Progressive Corporate Law (WestVie
Colorado, 1995) p. 93.
158 Cheffins, op. cit. n.152, p. 32.
159 The consensual attributes of the "contract" are important to the Nexus theory. It is from th
that it is possible to infer that the corporate structure is efficient.
160 Coffee, "No Exit?: Opting Out, the Contractual Theory of the Corporation, and the Spe
Case of Remedies" (1988) 53 Brooklyn L.R. 919, 937. Generally, see Atyiah, The Rise and F
of Freedom of Contract (Clarendon, Oxford, 1979) and "Contracts, Promises and the Law
Obligations" (1978) 84 L.Q.R. 193. See also, Treitel, The Law of Contract (9th ed., Sweet
Maxwell, London, 1995) pp. 1-7.
161 Eisenberg. "The Structure of Corporation Law" (1989) 89 Columbia L.R. 1641; Brudn
"Corporate Governance, Agency Costs, and the Rhetoric of Contract" (1985) 85 Colum
L.R. 1403.
162 If the corporate governance structure does not result from a bargain, it is difficult to infer t
the resulting structure is efficient. Contract theorists have responded, however, that so long
the governance structure is "priced", through the value of the shares on the stock market, th
it is possible to infer efficiency. The validity of this assumption depends on two furthe
assumptions. First, that the stock market is efficient and, secondly, that shareholders trade o
the basis of this information rather than "noise". Both assumptions are controversial. Se
Cheffins, op cit. n.152, pp. 55-58.
163 That a fiduciary's obligations are not entirely excludable was confirmed recently by
of Appeal in Armitage v. Nurse [1997] 3 W.L.R. 1046, 1056 where Millett L.J. said: "th
irreducible core of obligations owed by trustees ..." For an overview of the argu
CofTee, "The Mandatory/Enabling Balance in Corporate Law: An Essay on the Jud
(1989) 89 Columbia L.R. 1618.
164 For example, the requirement in the City Code on Takeovers and Mergers of equal t
shareholders (General Principle I) and mandatory bids (General Principle 10 and R
165 Cheffins, op cit. n.152, p. 228.
166 Easterbrook and Fischel, The Economic Structure of Corporate Law (Harvard U
Cambridge, 1991) p. 15.
167 This largely conceded by Cheffins, op. cit. n.152, p. 142rT.
168 Ibid.
169 Cheffins, op.cit. n.152, p. I42ff.
170 For example, the concern with the position of employees reflected -in section 309 of the
Companies Act 1985.
171 This seems to underlie the anti-takeover statutes in America. In particular, the effect on the
state economy of takeovers which may result in a relocation of the business in another state:
Henning, "Corporate Law After the Eighties: Reflections on the Relationship Between
Management, Shareholders, and Stakeholders" (1992) 36 St. Louis L.J. 519, 526.
172 Wheeler, "Directors' Disqualification: Insolvency Practitioners and the Decision-Making
Process" (1995) 15 Legal Studies 283, 289.
173 Elder v. Elder & Watson Ltd. [1952] S.C. 49, 55 per Lord Cooper, speaking of an earlier
formulation.
Thus, the reformation of both the ultra vires doctrine and the rule in Turquand's C
35 and 35A of the Companies Act 1985) reflects a desire to protect those dealin
company from all the consequences of the corporate form. See Prentice, Reform of
Vires Rule: A Consultation Paper (D.T.I., London, 1986) p. 14. This policy is also expli
First Directive on Company Law.
Pursuant to section 432 of the Companies Act 1985 the Secretary of State m
inspectors to investigate the arTairs of the company.
Generally see, Ayres and Braithwaite, Responsive Regulation: Transcending the D
Debate (O.U.P. Oxford, 1992) pp. 7-18; Shearing, "A Constitutive Conception of Re
Grabosky and Braithwaite (eds.), Business Regulation and Australia's Future (Australi
of Criminology, Canberra, 1993) p. 67; Cheffins, op. cit. n.152, Chapter 5;
"Reconceptualising Company Law: Reflections on the Law Commission's Consult
on Sharehoider Remedies: Part I" (1997) 18 Co. Lawyer 226, 237; Corbett, "A Pr
More Responsive Approach to the Regulation of Corporate Governance" (1995) 2
L.R. 277, 279.
The prohibition on financial assistance in the purchase of the company's shares
Act 1985, s. 151) and the prohibition of insider trading (Criminal Justice Act 1993)
examples.
1 Cheffins, op. cit. n.152, p. 227; Corbett, above, pp. 301-305.
1 Shearing, above
Ayres and Braithwaite, op. Cit. n.193.
The name commonly given to New Zealand's approach to the regulation of the
telecommunications industry: Ahdar, "The Privy Council and 'Light-Handed' Regulation"
(1995) 111 L.Q.R. 217; Vautier and Bollard, "Competition Policy in New Zealand" in Green
and Rosenthal (eds.), Competition Regulation in the Pacific Rim (Oceana Publications, New
York, 1996) p. 382.
One notable example may be found in the New Zealand provisions prohibiting insider trading.
Unlike most other jurisdiction which provide for enforcement by the State, the Securities
Amendment Act 1988 leaves enforcement almost entirely up to the shareholders. For an
overview see, Rickett and Grantham (eds.), Essays on Insider Trading and Securities Regulation
(Brooker's, Wellington, 1997).
* Thus, for example, in Australia the Corporations Law vests rights in creditors to seek an
injunction to restrain corporate conduct: Corporations Law, ss. 1323, 1324.
Ayres and Braithwaite, op. cit. n.193, p. 103: "a form of subcontracti
private actors. In particular, [responsive regulation] envisions that in
be more efficacious for the regulated firms to take on some or all of
and judicial regulatory functions." See also, Hill, "Changes in the R
Grantham and Rickett (eds.), Corporate Personality in the 20th Cen
Chapter 10.
VI. Conclusion
202 A shareholder's sense of aggrievement may compel him or her to pursue the claim
the costs to the company in terms of disruption, publicity and staff involvement
warrant prosecution of the claim.
203 See, for example, the Law Commission's proposals for a derivative action: Law Co
Shareholder Remedies, Consultation Paper No. 142 (1996) and Final Report No. LC2
The proposals are outlined and critiqued by Sugarman, "Reconceptualising Com
Reflections on the Law Commission's Consultation Paper on Shareholder Remedies"
Co. Lawyer 226 and 274.
204 Smith v. Croft (No. 2) [1988] Ch. 114.
205 See Hill, "Changes in the Role of the Shareholder" in Grantham and Rickett (eds.)
Personality in the 20th Century (Hart, Oxford, 1998) Chapter 10.
206 Butt v. Kelson [1952] Ch. 197 (CA.). The Companies Act 1985 now creates
information; see, for example, sections 251 and 253.
207 Thus, in the New Zealand statutory provisions which prohibit insider trading, enfor
left up to shareholders, but shareholders' right of access to information is enhanced.
196 above.
Dan-Cohen, Rights, Persons, and Organizations: A Legal Theory for Bureaucratic Society
(University of California Press, 1986) p. 21.