Dymski 1988
Dymski 1988
Dymski 1988
Gary A. Dymski
To cite this article: Gary A. Dymski (1988) A Keynesian Theory of Bank Behavior, Journal of Post
Keynesian Economics, 10:4, 499-526, DOI: 10.1080/01603477.1988.11489704
Download by: [University of California Santa Barbara] Date: 04 April 2016, At: 08:13
GARY A. DYMSKI
Dr. Herbert Bab has suggested to me that one could regard the rate of
interest as being determined by the interplay of the terms on which the
public desires to become more or less liquid and those on which the
banking system is ready to become more or less un liquid. This is, I
think, an illuminating way of expressing the liquidity theory of the rate
of interest . .. (John Maynard Keynes, The Collected Works of John
Maynard Keynes, Vol. 14, p. 219)
I. Introduction
This paper develops a micro level model of the banking firm rooted in
Keynes's insights as a microfoundation for post Keynesian theory. This
model substantiates Keynes's claims that banks' functions of liquidity
supply and credit creation are interdependent and that the banking
system is a crucial determinant of the level of economic activity. The
essential feature of this model is the explicit incorporation of "real
time. " By contrast, in a standard bank model which ignores real time,
the bank's functions are independent, and bank behavior is not a deter-
minant of the level of economic activity.
A number of post Keynesian theorists have given considerable atten-
tion to the macroeconomic aspects of banking; however, analysis of
micro level bank behavior has been relegated to intuitive comments. A
case in point is Minsky's work on the financial fragility hypothesis
... the modern banker performs two distinct sets of services. He sup-
plies a substitute for State money by acting as a clearing house . . .
But he is also acting as a middleman in respect of a particular type of
lending, receiving deposits from the public which he employs in purchas-
ing securities, or in making loans to industry and trade .... (1930, Vol. 2,
p. 191)
3This passage refers specifically to the impact on banks of the "loss of money
value"-that is, of deflation. However, this passage can be generalized readily to
encompass a situation in which bank assets lose their value. Note that Keynes's
writing on banks is treated herein as an integrated whole.
KEYNESIAN THEORY OF BANK BEHAVIOR 503
4The role of money is necessarily incorporated into this analysis of the role of bank-
ing in economic analysis. This follows naturally from the fact that banks are funda-
mentally monetary institutions.
504 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS
cient to generate a role for money and banking. With stochastic out-
comes, mismatches may arise between available resources and planned
expenditures at any point in time. This creates a precautionary demand
for liquid reserves-an analytical role for money. A role for banks
arises if it is assumed (as in Gurley and Shaw, 1960; Parkin, 1970; and
others) that banks arise because economies of scale are to be had in
liquidity supply. The law of large numbers suggests that these econo-
mies result when the bank attracts a sufficiently large number of de-
SIt is important to note that a nonredundant role for money and banking can also be
generated by substituting for the A-D assumption of costless transactions the idea
that the economy's transactions mechanism is either costly or flawed.
Benston and Smith (1976) introduced tlle costly-transactions approach to banking
in a partial eqUilibrium context. More recently, in an approach characterized as the
"New Monetary Economics" (Cowen and Kroszner, 1987), costly transactions-
alternatively, decentralized trading (Sargent, 1987)-have been introduced into an
A-D or EM (efficient-markets) construct (see note 6). This leads to a "unitary"
banking model: banks' role is to provide payments services (Fama, 1980).
Townsend explains the existence of banks (1983) by postulating that barter equilib-
ria are suboptimal when transaction costs increase monotonically with geographical
distance between agents. We ignore this approach here because its view of banking
is completely at odds with Keynes's. For example, Fama has written that "banks re-
main passive intermediaries, with no control over· any of the details of a general
equilibrium .... the real activity that takes place, the way it is financed, and the
prices of securities and goods are not controlled either by individual banks or by the
banking sector" (p. 48).
The idea of a flawed transaction mechanism underlies much recent work on
"overlapping generations" (OG). OG models generate a role for money and bank-
ing by assuming that multi-period-lived agents cannot achieve Pareto efficient equi-
libria autarchically because of incomplete markets. This is equivalent to assuming
that the economy's transactions mechanism is flawed. Given market incompleteness,
a trusted "social contrivance" is needed to effect optimal transfers of wealth. A fiat
money in the form of accounts at an eternal "bank" both provides this contrivance
and guarantees agents' trust; so the bank's existence assures a socially optimal
equilibrium.
We ignore the explicitly dynamic OG conception of banking because including it
here would force us to consider the relationship between explicitly dynamic and
"real-time" analysis. This goes well beyond the goals of this paper. Further, the is-
sues raised are not simple. For example, Michael Woodford has pointed out in con-
versation that a temporary equilibrium approach which is explicitly dynamic while
rejecting the possibility of steady-state equilibrium could simulate "real time." The
problem of explicitly dynamic monetary frameworks deserves separate treatment.
KEYNESIAN THEORY OF BANK BEHAVIOR 505
6The bank models cited here, while representative, are drawn from a vast literature.
Baltensperger (1980) and Santomero (1984) provide extensive reviews of contempo-
rary models of the banking firm.
506 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS
(2)
7Thls simplified treatment of the bank's short-term borrowing markets is severe, but
not without justification. Bank borrowing at the discount window is quantitatively
unimportant-in a typical week, discount window borrowings average less than 3
percent of interbank borrowings. Examination of interest rate data on two other
short-term borrowing markets frequently accessed by banks-the market for nego-
tiable certificates of deposit and for Eurodeposits-reveals that the rates in these
markets have tracked the interbank rate very closely since June 1970 (when the reg-
ulatory rate maximum on the former instrument was removed). See Dymski (1988).
KEYNESIAN THEORY OF BANK BEHAVIOR 507
claim the bank's residual income after obligations have been met.
The bank's expected profit flow in any period is then given by:
(4)
(5)
(6)
and
(7)
where €I = (oJ/oz)(i/l).
8Derivatives of functions with single arguments are indicated by primes ('). Deriva-
tives of functions with multiple arguments are indicated by using subscripts for
functional operators.
508 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS
given that (5)-(7) are satisfied for all banks. Also, we assume through-
out this analysis that net planned borrowing demand in the B market
does not exceed net planned S holdings. So the following consistency
condition holds:
N N
(9) E (Bi + Si) =E (Di(1 + h) + Ki - L i) ~ O.
i=l i=l
Equilibrium is achieved when there exists a vector (d*, IC*, B*, be *)
which satisfies condition (8) and which for all N banks satisfies equa-
tions (5)-(7) and generates expected residuals high enough that equa-
tion (4) does not bind. 9
An important feature of this equilibrium is the relationship of the B
and S markets. 10 By equation (7), be and se are equal in equilibrium.
This relation holds because B and S are structurally indistinguishable:
both are costless assets sold in competitive markets. Tnen (7) and
condition (8) jointly imply th.at the bank can effectively borrow and
lend at S8. This interbank market functions like the domestic capital
market in the open-economy Mundell-Fleming model. That is, sup-
pose that initially there is excess demand for interbank borrowings;
then b rises infinitesimally, causing ban.1(s with S positions to sell those
91n the case of the market for bank credit, equation (5), equilibrium does not imply
market clearing. Several authors (for example, Stiglitz and Weiss, 1981) have ob-
served that credit rationing, apparently a disequilibrium event, can be understood in
equilibrium terms. Note that second-order conditions are guaranteed by assumptions
made about the slopes of the L, D, and C functions.
IORelaxing condition (9) would open up a richer set of possibilities. For example, if
banks' aggregated initial plans resulted in the violation of (9), perhaps due to un-
usually strong credit demand, then the interbank rate would rise to accommodate the
borrowing pressure in the B market. This would drive a wedge between the securi-
ties and interbank rates, forcing all banks to cancel their S positions and dropping
equation (7) from the system. A model which explicitly incorporates this possibility
is examined in Dymski (1988). Condition (9) is not relaxed in this analysis to focus
attention on the role of factors related to "real-time" considerations. All N banks
are still, however, able to achieve ex ante equilibrium; only introduction of the as-
sumptions special to section 4 creates the possibility of ex ante bank diseqUilibrium.
KEYNESIAN THEORY OF BANK BEHAVIOR 509
off and shift into the B market. Given condition (9), the interbank
market always generates whatever volume of funds will satisfy (7) in
this way. So the thinness of the B market, due to restricted participa-
tion, is irrelevant; the B market functions as an extension of a deep,
broad S market.
A well-known result for this model is that the bank's asset-composi-
tion and portfolio-size decisions are independent. 11 This is readily
Downloaded by [University of California Santa Barbara] at 08:13 04 April 2016
seen. The bank makes a decision on its (D) portfolio size using equation
(6): it sets d just equal to its expected return on S, net of the marginal
cost of D. The bank's L-market decision is based on equation (7): the
loan-contract rate is set where the net marginal return on L just equals
SB. SO independence here means that the size of the bank's loan portfo-
lio is not limited by its D volume: the bank can borrow in the B market,
at the expected S-market rate, whatever funds beyond its D base are
required for loan-market eqUilibrium.
This result leads to three further results contrary to Keynes's depic-
tion of banks and the banking sector. First, no tension arises between
banking functions in these timeless models. The bank discharges its
liquidity-supply function through its d decision, and its credit-creation
function through its Ie decision. Independence rules out tension, be-
cause the bank's functions are independently satisfied. Second, the
bank can achieve an equilibrium for each function based solely on
presently prevailing conditions. This is true no matter what previous ex
post experience has been; the essential aspect of timelessness is the
absence of lingering effects or commitments from one period to the
next. 12
Third, this banking sector is not a determinant of economic activ-
ity-it simply adjusts passively to structural conditions originating else-
where. Equations (5)-(7) clearly show this. Conditions in the financial
markets-that is, sB-determine the size of the banking sector; and
llSee Klein (1971) and Baltensperger (1980). Langohr (1982) shows that the inde-
pendence result is due to the assumption of imperfectly competitive L markets.
l20ne period's experience may, of course, affect bank behavior in the next. For ex-
ample, the bank may respond to bad draws in one period by increasing its expected
default rate, or even by changing its degree of risk aversion.
Also note that the bank's ability to achieve equilibrium in each planning period
is no guarantee of its ability to survive or discharge its obligations. Its ability to
meet condition (4)-with kB replaced by .t-and satisfy its equity owners, to pay its
deposit holders, and even to satisfy liquidity demand fully depends on the realiza-
tions of borrowers on funded projects. With sufficiently bad draws, the bank may
even fail to survive.
510 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS
In the loan period, the bank decides on the volume of new loans it
will add to its stock of vintage loans. Deposit volume remains
stochastic until the adjustment period: so realized D, B, and S volumes
may diverge from those expected. Security and borrowing volumes can
be varied without penalty in both periods; for this reason, the differ-
ence (S - B) is termed (after Tobin, 1982) the bank's "net defensive
Downloaded by [University of California Santa Barbara] at 08:13 04 April 2016
(11) LV + L + S + B = D(1 - h) + K,
where
t-J
LV = 1: Lj.
j=t-l
(13)
{2 = 7re + Al(L + se + K - D(l - h) - K) + A2(k - (7re /K»
514 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS
where the form of 7I"e depends on the bank's choice of i and on which x
is realized.
To see this, we define two distinct profit equations, 71"1 and 71"2, as
follows:
t-J
(l4a) 71"1 = 1: W - oi)D
j=t-1 J J 'J
+ CZC - oe)LCZC) + beB + seS
Downloaded by [University of California Santa Barbara] at 08:13 04 April 2016
- dD(d) - C(D, L)
if x > i
t-J
(l4b) 71"2 = 1: (/'j - oj)Lj + CZC - oe)LCZC) + beB
j=t-1
- dD(d) - C(D, L)
if x < i.
Note that B > 0 in (14a) and B < 0 in (14b). We then take expecta-
tions of (14a) and (l4b); it follows immediately that 7I"e = 7I"f + 7I"i.
The Appendix shows that the bank's loan-period maximand can be
written more succinctly as follows:
where F(i) is the probability that the bank has to borrow in the adjust-
ment period to fund its fixed position. The bank maximizes equation
(15) over the decision variables ZC and d. The first-order conditions for
Ie and d are, respectively:
(9')
E (B~ + S~) = E (Di(1 - h) + Ki - Li - L i) ~ o.
i i
Discussion
This model has very different properties from the timeless model of
Downloaded by [University of California Santa Barbara] at 08:13 04 April 2016
librium will deepen if, as noted, the banking system has to make
adjustments spurred by liquidity shortages, triggered by the fact that
relation (18) is less than zero.
A third feature of this bank model is that its behavior is an indepen-
dent determinant of the level of economic activity. This follows, first,
because bank loan rate and volume decisions in the loan period are
based partly on assessments of the availability of banking-system li-
quidity in the adjustment period; in effect, expected liquidity consider-
ations influence current credit-creation activities. Second, as noted,
banks may be unable to meet all loan-contract obligations if the bank-
ing system is faced with a shortage of liquidity in the adjustment
period. Of central importance in banks' decisions about whether to
maintain asset positions or to maximize liquidity in adverse borrowing
environments is the amount of equity owner pressure on bank manag-
ers.
Minsky, then, suggests that all economic units are bank-like. Bank-
ing is a "pervasive phenomenon" (1982, p. 77); banks are "generical-
ly defined as institutions specializing in finance" (1975, p. 57). In
effect, Minsky uses as his model for both banks and nonbanks the
timeless model of section 3: all units take liability positions to support
assets with uncertain return, but no units (for example, banks) are
burdened with the role of liquidity supplier of last resort. 20
must the bank take an asset position with a stochastic return; it must
finance that position with a liability base of uncertain composition.
The behavior of the real-time bank model is, however, consistent
with the broad outlines of the theory of fmancial fragility: (1) its asset
composition depends on its willingness to absorb risks associated with
uncertain future events; (2) its position thus depends critically on the
Downloaded by [University of California Santa Barbara] at 08:13 04 April 2016
sharp rise (a "spike' ') in the interbank rate. 21 The effect of an increased
B-market rate on the real-time bank, in turn, is shown by this
comparative-static result for equation (15): a7r e /ab e = (ff+ S')F(x).
This expression is negative for a bank with negative NDP-that is, a
bank which depends on B-market borrowings to fund its asset position.
So it is precisely banks that do not match maturities and thus have taken
the risk that "required cash may be available only at penalty rates or
terms when refinancing is necessary" (Minsky, 1975, p. 88) that will,
then, be forced to contract credit. This credit contraction will then
bring about distress through the entire financial/real system. Note that
for the timeless model, by contrast with this result, an autonomous
upward shift in be is precluded by conditions (7) and (9).
Minsky neglects this event; his emphasis on the "subjective" risks
universally entailed in all maturity transformation leads him to ignore
the uniquely fragile structure of banks' liquidity supply.
The real-time bank model can also extend Minsky's conception of how
shocks spread from their point of impact to the financial system as a
whole, in a cyclical downturn. Two contributions of banks to the
dissemination process are developed here.
Minsky has argued that any shock is spread through revaluations of
21The evidence from the credit crunches of 1966-67, 1969-70, 1973-74, and 1980-
82 reveals that "spikes" in the interbank rate are a recurring feature of periods of
monetary contraction. Dymski (1987) shows that the interbank rate "spikes" above
other interest rates in crunch periods because of segmented participation in the
interbank market. Note that one effect of financial innovations since 1966 has been
an increase in the number of short-term liquidity markets to which banks have ac-
cess. Interestingly, however, the interest rates in these additional markets have
closely tracked the interbank rate (and, thus, have also exhibited "spiking" behav-
ior) since their inception, suggesting that participants in these markets key their be-
havior to developments in the interbank market proper (in effect demanding a pre-
mium when banks are vulnerable). Wolfson (1986) discusses the empirical aspects
of episodes of "credit crunch" in the postwar period.
KEYNESIAN THEORY OF BANK BEHAVIOR 521
22These contradictory tendencies are heightened to the extent that nonbanks tap into
lines of credit in downturns; indeed loan-commitment drawdowns may be increas-
ing just as the bank's low-cost deposits are being fled away in a high-interest-rate
environment.
KEYNESIAN THEORY OF BANK BEHAVIOR 523
the unit acquiring a liability may have liabilities of its own, and its
ability to fulfill its obligations depends upon the cash flow it receives
from its assets, that is, other units' liabilities" (1975, p. 87). We have
suggested, however, that dual-function banks in real-time environ-
ments have a second source of fragility, discounted by Minsky: their
liquidity supply function. Contractionary monetary policy affects the
Downloaded by [University of California Santa Barbara] at 08:13 04 April 2016
VI. Conclusion
This paper has attempted to achieve goals at the analytical and method-
ological levels. Analytically, a Keynesian model of the banking firm
has been developed as a microfoundation for the macroeconomic
framework of Keynes and post Keynesian theorists. We have contrasted
a "real-time" model of a dual-function banking firm with the
"timeless" Klein/Monti model. This model is then used to reevaluate
the role of banking in the FFH. While Minsky implicitly uses the
timeless model in exposition of the FFH, the real-time model is consis-
tent with the broad outlines of the FFH. Further, the real-time model
suggests two refmements in the theory of financial fragility. First, with
real-time banks one can explain why monetary contractions (and not
just real-sector events) trigger downtowns. Second, it is precisely the
asymmetric impact of forces unleashed in downturns on real-time
banks' differentia specijica, the liquidity supply function, that explains
why a financially fragile set of fmancial relations can come unraveled.
Methodologically, this paper develops a microeconomic analysis on
the basis of some macrofoundational principles. This raises the ques-
tion of whether one or the other level is more fundamental. This paper
posits the primacy of the macroeconomic dimension. The limits on and
possibilities open to microeconomic units cannot otherwise be well
defined. Even the Walrasian general equilibrium model defines its
macrofoundational context by default.
This does not mean that macrofoundational analysis alone is suffi-
cient. For consistent modeling, correspondence between macroeco-
524 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS
APPENDIX
Derivation of section 4 equations
To derive equation (15), the bank's maximand, we first take the expectation of
the budget constraint, equation (11), and substitute the resulting equation into
equation (14). This requires a simplifying assumption on equation (14a): the
bank's managers are assumed to expect the interest rates on Sand B to be equal
if x > x. So let se = be in equation (14a). Then we substitute for se
in (14a)
the budget constraint C + L + se
= De(l - h) + K; and we substitute for
Bin (14b) the constraint C + L = D e(1 - h) - Be + K, where we recall
that Be < O. Substitute jj for De (take the expectation of equation (9)). These
manipulations yield:
t-J
(AI) 1I"i = E (lJ - 5j - se)Lj + CZC - 5e - se)L(lc)
j=t-l
for x > x
t-J
(A2) 11"2 = E (lJ - 5j - bjLj + (lc - 5e - be)L(lC)
j=t-l
KEYNESIAN THEORY OF BANK BEHAVIOR 525
for x < x.
Recall that, for any constant C, I~ f(u)du = F(A) - F(B), where F(u) is
the c.d.f. for u; and note that, in this case, F(l) = 1 and F( -1) = O. Then
integrate equations (AI) and (A2) over the range of x, and add; this yields
equation (15) in the text. Note that we have made sufficient assumptions about
the curvature of the C, D, and L functions to satisfy second-order conditions.
r
Downloaded by [University of California Santa Barbara] at 08:13 04 April 2016
In using (15) to derive first-order conditions for and d, one must recall
that F(x) is a function of both L(f) and D(d) through equation (12). Dividing
r
the first-order condition for through by L and rearranging gives:
I
REFERENCES
Akerlof, G. "The Market for 'Lemons': Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism."
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1970, 84, 488-500.
Baltensperger, E. "Alternative Approaches to the Theory of the Banking Firm." Journal of
Monetary Economics, 1980, 6, 1-37.
Benston, G., and Smith, C. "A Transactions Cost Approach to the Theory of Financial
Intermediation." Journal of Finance, 1976,31,215-232.
Cowen, T., and Kroszner, R. "The Development of the New Monetary Economics." Journal
of Political Economy, 1987,95, 567-590.
Davidson, P. Money and the Real World. 2nd ed. London: Macmillan, 1978a.
- - - . "Why Money Matters: Lessons from a Half-Century of Monetary Theory." Jour-
nal of Post Keynesian Economics, Fall 1978b, 1 (1), 46-70.
Deshmukh, S.; Greenbaum, S.; and Kanatas, G. "Interest Rate Uncertainty and the Financial
Intermediary's Choice of Exposure." Journal of Finance, 1983,38,141-147.
Diamond, D. "Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring." Review of Economic
Studies, 1984, 51, 393-414.
Dymski, G. On the Role of Banks and the Interbank Market in Short-Run Financial Instability.
Mimeo, University of Southern California, 1987.
- - - . Banking, Bank Innovation, and Monetary Repression. Mimeo, University of South-
ern California, 1988.
Fama, E. Foundations of Finance. New York: Basic Books, 1976.
- - - . "Banking in the Theory of Finance." Journal of Monetary Economics, 1980, 6, 39-
57.
526 JOURNAL OF POST KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS
Gurley, J., and Shaw, E. Money in a Theory of Finance. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings In-
stitution, 1960.
Katzner, D. "Potential Surprise, Potential Confirmation, and Probability." Journal of Post
Keynesian Economics, Fall 1986, 9 (1), 58-78.
Keynes, J. M. A Treatise on Money. Vol. 1-2. London: Macmillan, 1930.
- - - . The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan, 1936.
- - - . "The Consequences to the Banks of the Collapse of Money Values." In Essays in
Persuasion. New York: Norton, 1963.
Downloaded by [University of California Santa Barbara] at 08:13 04 April 2016
- - - . The Collected Works of John Maynard Keynes. Vol. 14. London: Macmillan, 1973.
Klein, M. "Imperfect Asset Elasticity and Portfolio Theory." American Economic Review,
May 1970.
- - - . "A Theory of the Banking Firm." Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 1971,3,
205-218.
Langohr, H. "Alternative Approaches to the Theory of the Banking Firm: A Note." Journal
of Banking and Finance, 1982, 6, 297-304.
Leland, H., and Pyle, D. "Information Asymmetries, Financial Structure, and Financial
Intermediation." Journal of Finance, 1977,32, 371-387.
Minsky, H. John Maynard Keynes. New York: Columbia University Press, 1975.
- - - . Can "It" Happen Again? Armonk, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe, Inc., 1982.
Monti, M. "Deposit, Credit and Interest Rate Determination under Alternative Bank Objec-
tive Functions." In Mathematical Methods in Investment and Finance. Ed. by. G. Szego and
K. Shell. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1972, pp. 430-454.
Moore, B. "Unpacking the Post Keynesian Black Box: Bank Lending and the Money Supply."
Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 1983,5 (4), 537-556.
Pal ley, T. "Bank Lending, Discount Window Borrowing, and the Endogenous Money Supply:
A Theoretical Framework." Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, Winter 1987-88, 10 (2),
282-303.
Parkin, M. "Discount House Portfolio and Debt Selection." Review of Economic Studies,
1970,37,469-497.
Radner, R. "Competitive Equilibrium Under Uncertainty." Econometrica, 1968,36,31-58.
Rousseas, Stephen. "A Markup Theory of Bank Loan Rates." Journal of Post Keynesian Eco-
nomics, Fal11985, 8 (1), 135-144.
Santomero, A. "Modeling the Banking Firm: A Survey." Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking, 1984, 16, Part 2, 576-602.
Sargent, T. Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1987.
Shackle, G. L. S. The Years of High Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1967.
Sprenkle, C. "Liability and Asset Uncertainty for Banks." Journal of Banking and Finance,
1987, 11, 147-159.
Stiglitz, J., and Weiss, A. "Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information." Ameri-
can Economic Review, 1981, 71,393-410.
Tobin, J. "The Commercial Banking Firm-A Simple Model." Scandanavian Journal of Eco-
nomics, 1982,495-530.
Townsend, R. M. "Theories of Intermediated Structures." Carnegie-Rochester Conference
Series on Public Policy: Money, Monetary Policies and Financial Institutions, Spring 1983,
18, 221-272.
Wells, P. "A Post Keynesian View of Liquidity Preference and the Demand for Money."
Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, Summer 1983, 5 (4), 523-536.
Wolfson, M. Financial Crises. Armonk, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe, Inc., 1986.