Paavola - Explaining Multilevel Environmental Governance

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 20

Sustainability Research Institute

SCHOOL OF EARTH AND ENVIRONMENT

Explaining Multi-Level Environmental Governance

Jouni Paavola

April, 2008

No. 10

SRI PAPERS
SRI Papers (Online) ISSN 1753-1330
First published in 2008 by the Sustainability Research Institute (SRI)

Sustainability Research Institute (SRI), School of Earth and Environment,


The University of Leeds, Leeds, LS2 9JT, United Kingdom

Tel: +44 (0)113 3436461


Fax: +44 (0)113 3436716

Email: SRI-papers@see.leeds.ac.uk
Web-site: http://www.see.leeds.ac.uk/sri

About the Sustainability Research Institute

The SRI is a dedicated team of over 20 researchers working on different aspects of


sustainability. Adapting to environmental change and governance for sustainability
are the Institute’s overarching themes. SRI research explores these in
interdisciplinary ways, drawing on geography, ecology, sociology, politics, planning,
economics and management. Our specialist areas are: sustainable development and
environmental change; environmental policy, planning and governance; ecological
and environmental economics; business, environment and corporate responsibility;
sustainable production and consumption.

Disclaimer

The opinions presented are those of the author(s) and should not be regarded as the
views of SRI or The University of Leeds.

2
Explaining Multi-Level Environmental Governance

© Jouni Paavola 2008

Email: j.paavola@ leeds.ac.uk

Contents

Contents……………………………………………………………………….. 3
Abstract ………………………………………………………………….......... 4
About the author ……………………………………………………………... 4
Introduction ………………………………………………………………….... 5
Multi-level environmental governance ...................................................... 6
Economic rationale(s) of MLEG …………................................................. 10
Conclusions ………………..........………………………….......................... 15
Acknowledgements …………………………………………………………... 16
References ……………………………………………………………………. 17

3
Abstract

Multi-level environmental governance has become a commonplace, yet few attempts


have been made to explain in economic terms why it should have emerged. This
manuscript argues that there are several possible starting points for economic
explanations of multi-level environmental governance and it reviews the most central
of them. One new institutional explanation of multi-level governance solutions sees
them as instruments for overcoming the collective action challenge of large number
of involved actors. Another explanation is that governance functions may have
different optimal scales of implementation and that multiple levels may be needed to
minimise governance costs. Third, multi-level institutional solutions could be
creations of economies of scope, institutional constraints and / or path dependency.
Fourthly, multifunctional resource systems may have spatially varying catchments for
different benefit streams. Multiple levels may be needed to deal with them and the
redistribution of costs and benefits between beneficiaries and those who directly
carry the costs of provision. The manuscript suggests that multiple explanations are
relevant and that the strength of all explanations is likely to be context-dependent.
For example, collective action theories explain the bottom-up emergence of multi-
level voluntary or contractual governance solutions, but they shed less light on
mandatory solutions or solutions mixing voluntary and mandatory strategies.

Key words: environmental governance, institutions, transaction costs, collective


action, ecosystem services

Submission date 20-09-2007; Publication date 28-04-2008

About the Author

Dr Jouni Paavola is Reader in Sustainability at the School of Earth and Environment,


University of Leeds, UK. His research examines the role of institutions and social
justice in environmental governance. He has published his research in journals such
as Science, Ecological Economics, and Review of Social Economy and has co-edited
three volumes on environmental decisions and values. The latest, Fairness in
Adaptation to Climate Change, was nominated for the Harold and Margaret Sprout
Prize of the Environmental Studies Section of the International Studies Association,
and was given a Honorary Mention. He is Associate Editor of Environmental Values
and a member of the Board of European Society of Ecological Economics (ESEE).

4
1 Introduction

Multi-level environmental governance (MLEG) has become a reality as the result of


proliferation of multi-lateral environmental agreements (MEAs) (Mitchell, 2003) and
the consolidation of the European Union’s arsenal of directives on environmental
matters (e.g. Jordan, 1999). Multi-level environmental governance solutions have
also become a subject of much research, particularly in political science and in
international relations (e.g. Biermann and Dingwerth, 2004; Jordan, 1999; Najam et
al., 2004; Vogler, 2003). However, in environmental and ecological economics the
interest in multi-level environmental governance and in environmental governance in
general has been somewhat weaker, and it has been limited mainly to those scholars
interested in law and economics, economics and politics and public finance (e.g.
Birner and Wittmer, 2004; Costanza et al., 1999; Esty, 1999; Hanna, 1999; Paavola,
2007). This manuscript examines alternative economic explanations for the
emergence of multi-level governance solutions for environmental resources in order
to start addressing this gap in the literature on environmental and ecological
economics.

In this manuscript environmental governance will be understood as the resolution of


environmental conflicts through the establishment, reaffirmation and change of
institutional arrangements (see e.g. Paavola, 2007). This definition is somewhat
broader than the definitions of governance that are common in political science (e.g.
Rhodes, 1996; Stoker, 1998). The former encompasses both state-centred solutions
and solutions where the state does not play a central role, while the latter definitions
frequently understand governance as something apart from the government. In the
light of the definition of environmental governance that informs this manuscript, multi-
level environmental governance is characterised either by nested levels of
jurisdictions or the organisation of governance functions at several spatial scales
simultaneously. Governance institutions in multi-level environmental governance thus
incorporate multiple jurisdictions and functional levels. The following section of the
manuscript will elaborate this definition somewhat to clarify what are the hallmarks of
multi-level environmental governance and what types of it exist.

The manuscript argues that there are a number of possible economic explanations
for the emergence of multi-level environmental governance solutions. One new
institutional explanation sees MLEG solutions as ways to overcome the collective
action challenge of a large number of actors. Another explanation is that governance
functions may have different optimal scales of implementation. That is, a multi-level
structure may be needed for the efficiency of governance solutions in the light of
governance / transaction costs. Thirdly, MLEG solutions could arise from economies
of scope, institutional constraints and / or path dependency. Further economic
explanations would draw attention to the multi-functionality of some environmental
resources, their spatially different benefit “catchments”, and spatial attributes of user
groups. MLEG solutions can broker and institute redistribution between these groups
for the optimal provision of a resource.

The manuscript will discuss these alternative explanations in greater detail in the
following sections. The manuscript does not seek to discredit any of the explanations
but rather to show that any one explanation is partial and that the strength of any
explanation is likely to be context-dependent. For example, arguments based on

5
collective action theories are pertinent to the emergence of multi-level voluntary or
contractual governance solutions, but they may not shed much light on the
mandatory solutions or solutions mixing voluntary and mandatory strategies. The
latter kind of solutions are more likely to arise from multi-functionality and the
optimisation of governance costs. In the same vein, an explanation based on multi-
functionality or economies of scope does not shed light on the challenges of
collective action.

In what follows, the second section will discuss multi-level environmental governance
in somewhat more detail to clarify its definition and to characterise different kinds of
multi-level environmental governance. The third section will discuss various
economic explanations of multi-level environmental governance more closely, and
the final section presents conclusions based on the earlier discussion.

2 Multi-level environmental governance

I have argued elsewhere that environmental governance is best understood as the


resolution of environmental conflicts through the establishment, reaffirmation or
change of institutional arrangements (Paavola, 2007; Paavola and Adger, 2005; for
conflict theory of institutional change in general, see Knight, 1992). I favour this
conflict-based definition over the typological ones that emphasise the absence of
government or its limited role as the hallmark of environmental governance, because
the former definition is analytically more encompassing. Descriptive definitions imply
a priori that there is a difference between different kinds of environmental
governance solutions. The conflict resolution definition suggests comparative
institutional analysis of alternative forms of environmental governance which asks
why particular kind of solutions are adopted in certain situations, and whether and in
which way it matters what kind of environmental governance solutions are adopted.

I also favour a conflict-based definition of environmental governance over a


coordination-based one. Coordination is frequently offered as a reason for the
existence of institutions (e.g. Taylor, 1987). However, the essence of many
“coordination problems” is in fact a conflict. When two or more ways of conducting
matters exist, and one of them has to be chosen for all involved agents, this choice
typically entails differential costs and benefits to involved actors. Under the different
coordination solutions such as A, B, C … N the beneficiaries and losers can and are
likely to differ, too. Therefore, even if the choice of one or another coordination
solution could enhance the overall social welfare, there remains a conflict over which
coordination solution and attendant distribution of costs and benefits to choose. But
even more importantly, there are conflicts which do not involve coordination
problems: these conflicts are typically purely about distribution or power or, in other
words, distributive and procedural justice, respectively. These conflicts are the most
important driver of institutional change: they demand institutional responses that
settle distributive conflicts one way or another (see Knight, 1992).

I find it useful to use the term “environmental resources” for the object of
environmental conflicts. Environmental resources include conventional natural
resources such as fisheries and forests, but they also include “newly discovered
environmental resources” such biodiversity, the ozone layer, and the global
atmospheric sinks for greenhouse gases. The term is also flexible enough to

6
encompass environmental safety and the quality of environmental media such as
water and air (see Paavola, 2007). Many environmental resources are multi-
functional and generate streams of ecosystem services that are used by different
groups of users in different “ecosystem service catchments” (see Balmford et al.,
2002; Turner et al., 2003). In essence, environmental resources are complex
resource systems rather than monolithic single-use resources. This means that
environmental conflicts can emerge over an individual service stream. For example,
there can be a conflict over which of the competing irrigators can divert water from a
watercourse to his or her consumptive water use. But environmental conflicts can
also emerge as a result of claims to different service streams. For example, claims to
consumptive use of water for irrigation and claims to recreational in-stream uses of
water can be in conflict with each other.

The conflict-based definition of environmental governance considers all formal and


informal institutional solutions from customary common property arrangements to
national natural resource and environmental policies to multi-lateral environmental
agreements as instances of environmental governance, without omitting formal self-
governance and other solutions which do not involve the state as a central player.
These environmental governance solutions can have different vertical structures. I
have elsewhere (Paavola, 2007) called some environmental governance solutions
“uni-planar” – they have a single jurisdiction where the decisions about the use and
preservation of pertinent environmental resources are made. Examples of uniplanar
environmental governance institutions include customary common property
arrangements, local zoning and land use planning solutions, and many national
environmental and natural resource use policies. One way of defining multi-level
environmental governance would be to simply say that they encompass all other than
uniplanar institutional solutions.

Multi-level environmental governance solutions can emerge as a result of different


kind of processes. There are instances where federations and over-arching
institutions have been created by bottom-up processes, to coordinate the functioning
of smaller-scale governance solutions (see Ostrom, 1998). Some of these solutions
are informal. For example, Ostrom (1990) discusses federations of irrigator
associations as an example of a nested solution. Similar solutions have emerged to
coordinate more formally local governance efforts for fisheries and shell fisheries
(Berkes 1992; Hanna, 1998). Blomquist (1992) in turn discusses how formal multi-
level governance arrangements for groundwater aquifers have emerged in California
through bottom up negotiation processes.

Top-down processes create many formal multi-level governance solutions. For


example, many federal environmental and natural resource policies provide for or
mandate the establishment of state implementation programs in the United States.
European Union’s Birds and Habitats directives require both national legislation and
local solutions for the governance of biodiversity (Paavola, 2004). Similarly, the
United Nations Framework Convention for Climate Change (UNFCCC) requires
national actions, programs or solutions for the planning, coordination and
implementation of internationally agreed upon actions (Paavola, 2005). Indeed,
consistently with this logic, the world systems scholars have argued that international
environmental agreements have been a key driver of national environmental policy

7
making, rather than being the logical extension or continuation of the latter (Frank,
1997; Frank et al., 2000).

The top down processes usually generate institutional structures where smaller
jurisdictions are nested within larger jurisdiction(s). Hooghe and Marks (2003) call
these kinds of multi-level governance solutions as “Type 1”; ones based on
permanent, general-purpose jurisdictions with relatively few levels and non-
intersecting membership. Examples of Type 1 solution include the federal state and
many environmental policies established in federal political systems. Hooghe and
Marks (2003) also identify “Type II” multi-level governance solutions which are often
based on non-permanent and special-purpose jurisdictions and which can have
numerous levels and intersecting memberships. Special districts for the provision of
public services are examples of these kinds of multi-level governance solutions (see
Blomquist, 1992; Foster, 1997). These kinds of governance solutions are more likely
to emerge as the results of bottom up negotiation processes.

The distinction between Type 1 and Type 2 governance solutions proposed by


Hooghe and Marks (2003) is linked to the notion of polycentricity originally proposed
by Vincent Ostrom and his colleagues (see Ostrom, Tiebout and Warren, 1961; V.
Ostrom, 1972). Ostrom proposed the notion of polycentricity to characterise complex
metropolitan governance structures that had emerged in the post-war decades for
public service delivery in the United States. These new complex structures did not
have a single core which characterises conventional monocentric arrangements. The
scholarship on polycentric government and governance has sought to establish the
rationale of such arrangements.

In essence, Hooghe and Marks (2003) project the notions of monocentric and
polycentric government and governance to multi-level governance. Doing so does
provide new insights into multilevel environmental governance. However, the key
interest of Vincent Ostrom was on the horizontal dispersion of authority to govern and
this is also what became imported into the distinction of Hooghe and Marks (2003).
Vertical structuring of governance and authority to govern is also involved in the
examples Ostrom et al. (1961) and Ostrom (1972) discuss. It is clearly considered an
element of polycentricity in these seminal works, but it does not become a central
issue of interest in them. Horizontal dispersion of authority was at the time novel and
attractive enough phenomenon, one which the established notions of government
and governance were not well placed to account for.

While the types of governance suggested by Hooghe and Marks (2003) do indeed
capture important aspects of classes of multi-level environmental governance
solutions, the reality is probably more complex than their terminology can portray.
Casual observation suggests that hybrid forms of governance combining elements
from Type 1 and Type 2 governance also exist. For example, many international
environmental conventions are explicitly constituted as special purpose jurisdictions
vested with limited decision-making and other powers, and they frequently rely on
pertinent national and sub-national general jurisdictions at lower levels of
governance. Particularly in developing countries but elsewhere as well, public service
provision and some governmental functions are occasionally performed by non-
governmental organisations at the national or sub-national levels. This is the case
with Church of England Schools in the United Kingdom, for example.

8
In light of the model proposed by Hooghe and Marks (2003), and the arguments of
Vincent Ostrom and others about polycentricity, a continuum between monocentric
and polycentric multi-level environmental governance could be argued to exist.
Another way to approach the phenomenon would be to say that the degree of
horizontal dispersion of authority varies in multi-level governance solutions. Other
concepts are needed to characterise the vertical features of multi-level governance
solutions. I suggest that the concept pair “vertical symmetry” and “vertical
differentiation” is helpful for mapping multi-level environmental governance solution
across another continuum, one where in one extreme solutions are identical at each
level, and in the other extreme there is complete differentiation across levels. The
second important attribute of multi-level governance solutions is the way in which
they emerge: bottom up as a result of voluntary collective action and bargaining, or
as a result of top down mandated processes. Together these two concept pairs help
to map multi-level governance solutions as suggested below in Figure 1.

Figure 1. A Mapping of Different Kind of Multi-evel


Environmental Governance Solutions

Vertical symmetry Vertical differentiation


+Top down

Federal states EU environmental directives

Federations of irrigator associations International environmental regimes

Federations of fishermen’s
Bottom up

associations

The scheme portrayed by figure 1 suggests that vertically symmetric nested


structures can emerge both as a result of bottom up and top down processes.
Vertically differentiated structures can also emerge in both ways. In practice, few
solutions would be ideal types where vertical symmetry or differentiation would be
perfect. In nested symmetric solutions, there is likely to be some difference across
the levels. Similarly, it is highly unlikely that perfectly differentiated solutions would
emerge: decisions to allocate governance functions to different levels are “lumpy”
and there are limits to how many levels of governance can feasibly exist. But
importantly, in principle the concepts of monocentricity and polycentricity can
characterise solutions in each quadrant of the figure 1.

Whatever the type of a multi-level governance solution, it is likely to have an


economic and political rationale. Multilevel solutions are also likely to have economic
and political consequences, as do choices between the types of multi-level solutions.

9
However, my emphasis in the reminder of this manuscript will be on the potential
economic explanations for the adoption or emergence of multi-level solutions. Some
of these solutions will be discussed in greater detail in the next section.

3 Economic Rationale(s) of MLEG

There are several possible starting points for explaining the economic rationale of
multi-level environmental governance solutions. In what follows, I will briefly discuss
explanations for the existence of multi-level environmental governance solutions
based on collective action, governance costs, economies of scope and path
dependency, and multi-functionality. The list of possible starting points is not
intended to be exhaustive. Further starting points and explanations are likely to exist,
but the range of discussed potential explanations is sufficiently broad to make the
case for multiple causation and to discuss its implications.

3.1 Collective action

The collective action explanation for the existence of multi-level environmental


governance solutions draws its core insights from the seminal work of Mancur Olson
(1971) on collective action. Olson argued that collective action is more likely
unsuccessful in large groups where actors deem their impact on collective action
outcomes small, and as a consequence have a stronger incentive to free ride. When
a large proportion of actors assesses their situation in this way, collective action is
undermined in large groups. Olson also saw that there is a difference in the
prospects of collective action depending on what kind of goods it seeks to provide,
and that collective action can be fostered by modifying individuals’ incentives.

The key issue to the rationale of multi-level environmental governance solutions is


the plain number of involved agents. Namely, one solution for overcoming the
collective action problem characteristic of large groups is to mobilise collective action
at a smaller scale. Keeping the primary collective action groups small helps to
overcome the incentive to ride free because the impact (and stake) of each individual
on collective action outcomes increases. At the same time, the smaller size of groups
can potentially increase the homogeneity of actors, possibly along a number of
attributes. This is likely to contribute to successful collective action. Relatively
homogeneous customary communities that have established common property
arrangements are examples of these kinds of small collective action groups (see
Ostrom, 1990).

Coordination between several small primary collective action groups can be achieved
by establishing larger-scale solutions where primary collective action groups are
represented. The introduction of representation reduces the large numbers situation
to a situation of small numbers, where the primary collective action groups are
treated as individuals. That is, a multi-level environmental governance solution can
emerge or be adopted as an instrument which facilitates collective action and
overcomes the challenges of collective action in large groups. Federations of
irrigators’, fishermen’s and pasture owners’ associations are examples of these kinds
of solutions that have emerged through bottom up processes (Ostrom, 1998). But the
challenges of collective action can also be recognised through a top down
intervention. For example, in Finland the governance of freshwater fisheries and

10
game is partly based on three tiers of self-governing user organisations but the
formation of these organisations is mandated in law and the incorporation statutes
also vest the user organisations with their legal powers and responsibilities (Paavola,
2002a: 23).

3.2 Governance costs

Another explanation of multilevel governance starts from the observation that all
environmental governance solutions have several generic governance functions
which may have different optimal scales of implementation. This starting point
suggests that a multi-level governance solution may be needed to ensure the
efficiency of governance solutions in the light of transaction or governance costs. To
understand this explanation, it is necessary to make a brief detour to governance
functions.

There has been a notion of governance functions in the new institutional literature
from the outset. For example, when discussing common property arrangements,
Schlager and Ostrom (1992) distinguish between “ownership functions” and
“management functions” (see also McCay, 1996). A more detailed typology of
governance functions can be distilled from the lists of common features of successful
governance solutions presented by for example Ostrom (1990: 88-102) and Agrawal
(2002). On the basis of these lists, I have suggested (Paavola, 2007) that generic
environmental governance functions include:

1) exclusion of unauthorised users;


2) Distribution of benefits of resource use by regulating it;
3) provisioning of rival and non-rival goods and recovering its costs;
4) monitoring of resource users and their compliance with rules;
5) enforcement of the rules of resource use;
6) resolution of conflicts over resource use;
7) collective choice for the modification governance solutions.

In uniplanar governance solutions all of these functions are organised at the same
spatial level of action and jurisdiction, although the way in which they are organised
may vary. For example, monitoring and enforcement may be based on users
monitoring each other and evoking enforcement functions when they observe
violation of rules. This was the case with the governance of water quality under
common law in the nineteenth century United States (see Paavola, 2002b). Another
solution is to appoint “officials” to take the responsibility for monitoring and
enforcement functions. Both of these solutions can be and are used in uniplanar
environmental governance solutions. But when the involved resources are large, it
may be that different governance functions have different economies of scale or
different optimal scales of implementation (see Ostrom et al., 1961). This may involve
for example making the key collective environmental decisions at a higher level, and
organising the provision of the resource at a lower level.

Governance solutions that organise and implement governance functions at different


spatial levels are common. For example, co-management of natural resources in
developing countries is based on the acknowledgement of relative advantages of
undertaking some governance functions such raising funds and making collective

11
decisions centrally at the national level and others, such as monitoring and
provisioning, locally. Multi-level governance of biodiversity in the European Union is
also based on differentiation of functions across levels. The provision of biodiversity
takes place locally at the Natura 2000 sites (see Paavola, 2004), but within the
constraints set forth by the Habitats and Birds Directives, the European level of
decision-making in the European Commission, and national legislation implementing
the European directives. Multi-level governance of biodiversity is also common in
other settings (see Ostrom, 1998).

It is noteworthy that the governance cost based explanation of multi-level


environmental governance solutions points to different kind of multi-level solutions
than the collective action based explanation. In the light of the collective action
explanation, nested governance solutions are like the Russian babushka dolls: they
are nested and identical otherwise apart from their different scale. The governance
cost based explanation suggests that the levels of governance can be and indeed
are likely to be functionally complementary and differentiated. Thus, environmental
governance arrangements at different levels do not by any means have to be similar,
and there could be sound economic reasons for this.

3.3 Path dependency, increasing returns, and economies of scope

Path dependency, increasing returns and economies of scope offer the third route for
explaining the emergence of multi-level environmental governance solutions. Path
dependency reasoning suggests that starting points, contingencies and
developmental trajectories matter because they can shape the future menu of
alternatives and their relative merits. My key contention below is that MLEG solutions
can be understood to replicate some of the key features of governmental templates
established earlier. That is, once established, multi-level governmental templates
structure and shape later solutions such as MLEG solutions by influencing their
relative costs (see Pierson, 2000).

Path dependence is typically attributed to increasing returns processes, which may


increase the relative benefits of an initial choice or action over time because of large
set-up or fixed costs, learning effects, coordination effects or adaptive expectations
(see Arthur 1994: 112; Pierson, 2000: 254). Increasing returns processes are
unpredictable because random changes in initial conditions can have a large impact
on future outcomes – accidental events early in the process do not cancel out
(Pierson, 2000; 253). Increasing returns processes make it difficult or costly to
change from one developmental path to another one, and may result in “lock-in” to
ineffective solutions or outcomes (ibid). While path dependency arguments based on
increasing returns originate from the study of technological change, they have also
been applied to institutional change (North, 1990; Pierson, 2000).

While Pierson (2000) sees that large set-up costs of institutions are a reason for
increasing returns in politics, I would argue that economies of scope also play a role
– especially when it comes to explaining the dominant role of the state in political
matters. States and sub-national political sub-divisions could be argued to enjoy
economies of scope just like a firm producing multiple goods or services. This would
mean that the state adoption of new functions could lower the costs of carrying out its
already existing functions (Panzar and Willig, 1980; Teece, 1980). Teng (2000)

12
argues that this kind of complementarity exists between the two core governmental
functions of taxation and enforcement of private property rights. Further functions
such as defence, the provision of law and order, public service delivery, and the
provision of public goods could also involve economies of scope.

I am not making an empirical claim that states and local governments in fact do have
economies of scope and that the portfolio of functions that they perform is
economically efficient. Rather, I want to propose that the concept of economies of
scope offers one way to account for the emergence of multi-level governance
structures. If states and local governments do enjoy economies of scope, over time
they would become the lowest-cost undertakers of the functions that they perform:
stand-alone alternatives would have narrower bundles of functions and thus higher
costs.

A similar argument could be based on the work of Coase (1937). Coase argued that
firms exist because their internal hierarchies entail lower transaction costs in carrying
out certain functions than performing the same functions over the market. In other
words, the boundaries of organisations adjust in the light of the relative transaction
cost implications of internal organisation and markets. The volume of transactions is
likely to influence unit transaction costs because of economies of scale in
transacting. However, economies of scope can also prevail in transacting. This would
establish the cost-advantage of a portfolio of functions which helps to attain a larger
volume of transactions than a single function would entail. Williamson (1999) has
also identified other reasons for why governmental organisations could enjoy
transaction cost economies.

To summarise, for better or worse, we have established social entities such as states
and local governments. Their establishment may have pre-empted or at least
increased the relative cost of using other possible institutional solutions. As a
consequence, many collective efforts are based on the central role of these collective
action templates. In the light of this logic, states are obvious players in discussions
and actions on large-scale environmental issues. It is ultimately the states that have
to act if any goals are to be achieved, either by acting directly to achieve these goals
or by authorising private actors to take responsibility. Local governments occupy a
similar when scale is smaller, whilst remaining subsidiaries of the state. The same
logic is extended further in federal governmental structures.

In this account, a multi-level governance solution emerges to reproduce the way in


which sovereignty and the use of mandatory power have been customarily
organised. The customary way could also be cost-effective when economies of
scope are involved. This is not to say that other solutions cannot be devised – it is
simply to say that there is a default solution that structures the set of alternatives and
influences their relative costs and feasibility. For example, a study by Foster (1997)
indicates that special districts for public service delivery are costlier than public
service delivery by general purpose jurisdictions. Of course, special districts have to
offer some advantages to exist at all. Following Ostrom et al. (1961), one such
advantage may be to reach a larger scale that includes all affected parties. If the
higher level of costs is efficient, then the cost advantage of smaller general purpose
jurisdictions would be explained by the presence of negative externalities.

13
3.4 Multifunctionality

The fourth route to explaining multi-level environmental governance is offered by the


multi-functionality of some environmental resources. The idea of multi-funtionality is
old and refers to the possibility of multiple use of many natural resources such as
forests and watercourses. The term multifunctionality is more recent and was used
early on for example in the discussions on the reform of the Common Agricultural
Policy (CAP) of the European Union as an argument for the detachment of
agricultural subsidies from the output of agricultural production, and their attachment
to the provision of other outputs such as environmental benefits in “multifunctional”
agriculture (see e.g. Vatn, 2002).

Multifunctionality is also central to the more recent ecosystem service literature. It is


this literature that offers perhaps the best route to a multi-functionality based
explanation of multi-level environmental governance solutions. The ecosystem
service approach has to be seen in contrast to conventional economic treatment of
environmental goods and bads. Conventional consumer theory conceptualises the
environment as goods (or bads) which are fundamentally similar to the other goods
that we consume. It considers utility as the only relevant attribute of environmental
goods, and that environmental goods are fully substitutable by other goods. In other
words, environmental goods are unproblematic, uni-dimensional goods just like all
other goods.

The concept of ecosystem services resembles Kelvin Lancaster’s (1966) view of


goods as having a multitude of attributes which provide consumers with utility
separately from each other. Ecosystem services can be defined as “the benefits
humans receive, directly or indirectly, from ecosystems” (Costanza et al., 1997: 253;
see also Farber et al., 2006: 118) or as “the end products of nature that yield human
wellbeing” (Boyd and Banzhaf, 2005: 16). Examples of ecosystem services that
benefit humans include the recycling of nutrients, regulation of run-off and river
discharge, coastal protection and carbon sequestration (de Groot et al., 2002: 396).
Ecosystem services are generated by ecosystem functions, such as regulation,
habitat, production and information, which in turn are underpinned by ecosystem
structures and processes (ibid, 394; see also Paavola, 2008).

The ecosystem service approach understands ecosystems in a fundamentally


multifunctional view, which is illustrated by the large number of benefit streams that
are identified in many of the empirical studies (see e.g. Costanza et al., 1997). There
is no compelling reason why the “catchments” of different benefit streams would
coincide. For example, tropical forests provide timber, charcoal, fuel wood and
various non-timber forest products to local users, hydrological, recreational and
landscape amenity benefits for a wider user group, and carbon sequestration which
provides global benefits. Other resources such as wetlands, the coastal zone and
grasslands offer comparable range of benefit streams which have groups of
beneficiaries that have different spatial scales.

The ecosystem service approach and its recognition of multi-functionality of resource


systems again has some parallels with the discussions on polycentric government.
Ostrom et al. (1961) considered that one of the key drivers of polycentricity is the fact
that the provision of different public services and goods can have different optimal

14
scales. A multiplicity of governance arrangements will thus emerge to take advantage
of these varied optimal scales of provision. Ecosystem services are not produced in
the same sense as public services are, but they do generate benefits to spatially
specific groups of beneficiaries, which will differ from ecosystem service to another
one. Moreover, the continued existence of these services has to be provided for, and
the provisioning involves both direct costs and opportunity costs. These costs are
again accrued to spatially specific groups. Just like with the provisioning of public
services, the provisioning of a multitude of ecosystem services is best arranged by
using a multitude of spatially divergent governance solutions. This is the efficiency-
based explanation for the emergence of multi-level environmental governance
solutions for multifunctional resource systems.

But it is also possible to formulate am equity and conflict resolution based


explanation on the basis of similar reasoning. Multi-level environmental governance
solutions can emerge as a response to conflicts of interests between users whose
catchments are different in size. For example, in the case of tropical forests,
sustained provision of carbon sequestration and hydrological services in the future
requires restraint in the harvesting of timber, charcoal and fuel wood now. The
opportunity cost of conservation is local and the benefits of conservation are mostly
accruing to others than those who bear the costs. As decisions on conservation are
often in practice made locally, interests in more widely distributed benefits are not
acknowledged. Redistribution is needed to address the situation (Balmford et al,
2002, Turner et al, 2003). This requires decisions on and raising of funding over a
larger geographical area, and solutions for channelling funds to cover the opportunity
costs of conservation.

That is, the varying spatial scales of benefit catchments may require multiple
jurisdictions and solutions to link them together for decision-making and benefit and
burden sharing. This is again a different rationale in comparison to the earlier ones.
Here the underlying rationale of MLEG solutions is the maximization of total value of
ecosystem service benefits, and fair distribution of burdens and benefits of
ecosystem service provision as one of its possible preconditions. In contrast, the
governance cost model looked at the costs of governance rather than at the benefits
it generates, and the collective action explanation only focuses on the costs of
collective action.

4 Conclusions

Multilevel environmental governance has become a part of the political reality in the
past several decades but there has been relatively little interest in different research
strands of economics, including ecological economics, to try and account for the
phenomenon. In part this reflects a more general neglect of institutional
arrangements in the economic literature on the environment. But somewhat
surprisingly, even the more institutionally oriented scholarship in ecological and other
strands of economics has not really considered why multi-level environmental
governance solutions would emerge.

Explaining the existence of multi-level governance institutions cannot constitute a


central activity for the researchers engaged in research on multi-level environmental
governance: the arrangements do exist and research questions related to their

15
effectiveness and impacts can appear more pressing. Nevertheless, the
consideration of possible theoretical explanations for the emergence of multi-level
environmental governance solutions can make some contributions. This manuscript
has demonstrated that there is no shortage of starting points for explaining the
emergence of multi-level environmental governance solutions. The manuscript has
demonstrated that collective action, governance cost minimisation, path dependency
and economies of scope, and multi-functionality offer somewhat distinct starting
points for economic explanations of the emergence of multi-level environmental
governance solutions. The manuscript has also demonstrated that these theoretical
strategies of explanation are complementary rather than competing. Their
applicability varies and they also have somewhat different implications to how we
ought to understand multi-level environmental governance.

The manuscript has argued that top down and bottom up processes of establishment
and vertical symmetry and differentiation are the key factors that distinguish between
different kinds of multi-level environmental governance solutions. Collective action
and economies of scope explanations both account for symmetrical nested multi-
level governance solutions, the first providing the bottom up account and the second
one being more pertinent to top down solutions. Governance cost based
explanations can highlight why different governance functions can be organised at
different levels and it applies to both bottom up and top down solutions. Multi-
functionality appears to provide the broadest explanation, having a capacity to
encompass all four key types of multi-level environmental governance solutions.

The importance of these differences in explanations is that multi-level governance


solutions are likely to have different and multiple rationales, which may vary from
context to context. Multi-level solutions can exist to overcome collective action
challenges or to minimise governance costs. However, they can also exist merely
because they replicate the default tiers of existing governmental organisations.
Alternatively, complex resource systems are likely to need complex governance
solutions, and the existence of multiple levels of governance is part of that
complexity. But multi-levelity alone can hardly constitute the required extent of
complexity: it is but one dimension of it. Horizontal complexity such as the degree of
polycentricity is likely to be important as well. In this light, institutional analysis of
multi-level environmental governance solutions should be informed by the
acknowledgement of multiple causation and the acknowledgement of its context-
specificity, and a recognition that both vertical and horizontal differentiation are likely
to characterise complex governance solutions for complex environmental resources.

Acknowledgements

This article manuscript is based on research which was financially supported by the
European Union (European Commission, Marie Curie RTN GoverNat, Contract No.
0035536, www.governat.eu). I thank Tim Foxon, Felix Rauschmayer and Arild Vatn
for good discussions and comments and suggestions to an earlier version of this
manuscript. As usual, all shortcomings remain my responsibility.

16
References

Agrawal, A. (2002) ‘Common resources and institutional sustainability’ In E. Ostrom, T.


Dietz, N. Dolšak, P.C. Stern, S. Stonich, and E.U. Weber (eds.), The Drama of the
Commons. National Academy Press, Washington, D.C. pp. 41-86.

Arthur, W.B. (1994) Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy.
University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor.

Balmford, A., Bruner, A., Cooper, P., Costanza, R., Farber, S., Green, R. E., Jenkins,
M., Jefferiss, P., Jessamy, V., Madden, J., Munro, K., Myers, N., Naeem, S.,
Paavola, J., Rayment, M., Rosendo, S., Roughgarden, J., Trumper, K., and Turner,
R. K. (2002) ‘Economic reasons for conserving wild nature’, Science, Vol. 297, pp.
950-953.

Berkes, F. (1992) ‘Success and failure in marine coastal fisheries of Turkey’, in D.W.
Bromley (ed.), Making the Commons Work. Institute for Contemporary Studies, San
Francisco. pp. 161-182.

Biermann, F. and Dingwerth, K. (2004) ‘Global environmental change and the nation
state’, Global Environmental Politics, Vol. 4, pp. 1-22.

Birner R. and Wittmer, H. (2004) ‘On the “efficient boundaries of the state”: the
contribution of transaction-costs economics to the analysis of decentralization and
devolution in natural resource management’, Environment and Planning C:
Government and Policy, Vol 22, pp. 667–685.

Blomquist, W. (1992) Dividing the Waters: Governing Groundwater in Southern


California. Institute for Contemporary Studies Press, San Francisco, CA.

Boyd, J.W. and Banzhaf, H.S. (2005) ‘Ecosystem services and government
accountability: the need for a new way of judging nature’s value’, Resources,
Summer 2005, pp. 16-19.

Coase, R.H. (1937) ‘The theory of the firm’, Economica, Vol. 4, pp. 386-405.

Costanza, R., d'Arge, R., de Groot, R., Farber, S., Grasso, M., Hannon, B., Limburg,
K., Naeem, S., O'Neill, R.V., Paruelo, J., Raskin, R. G., Sutton, P. and van den Belt,
M. (1997) ‘The value of the world's ecosystem services and natural capital’, Nature,
Vol. 387, pp. 253-260.

Costanza, R., Andrade, F., Antunes, P., van den Belt, M., Boesch, D., Boersma, D.,
Catarino, F., Hanna, S., Limburg, K., Low, B., Molitor, M., Pereira, J.G., Rayner, S.,
Santos, R., Wilson J. and Young, M. (1999) ‘Ecological economics and sustainable
governance of the oceans’, Ecological Economics, Vol. 31, pp. 171-187.

De Groot, R.S., Wilson M.A., and Boumans, R.M.J. (2002) ‘A typology for the
classification, description and valuation of ecosystem functions, goods and services’,
Ecological Economics, Vol. 41, pp. 393-408.

17
Esty, D.C. (1999) ‘Toward optimal environmental governance’, New York University
Law Review, Vol. 74, pp. 1495-1574.

Farber, S.; Costanza, R., Childers, D. L., Erickson, Jon, Gross, K., Grove, M.,
Hopkinson, C. S., Kahn, J., Pincetl, S, Troy, A. Warren, P. and Wilson, M. (2006)
‘Linking ecology and economics for ecosystem management’, BioScience, Vol. 56,
pp. 121-133.

Foster, K.A. (1997) The Political Economy of Special-purpose Government.


Georgetown University Press, Washington DC.

Frank, D.J. (1997) ‘Science, nature and the globalization of the environment, 1870-
1990’, Social Forces, Vol. 76, pp. 409-425.

Frank, D.J., Hironaka, A. and Schofer, A. (2000) ‘The nation-state and the natural
environment over the twentieth century’, American Sociological Review, Vol. 65, pp.
96-116.

Hanna, S. (1998) ‘Managing for human and ecological context in the Maine soft shell
clam fishery’, in F. Berkes and C. Folke (eds.), Linking Social and Ecological
Systems: Management Practices and Social Mechanisms for Building Resilience.
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK. pp. 190-212.

Hanna, S.S. (1999) ‘Strengthening governance of ocean fishery resources’,


Ecological Economics, Vol. 31, pp. 275-286.

Hooghe, L. and Marks, G. (2003) ‘Unraveling the central state, but how? types of
multi-level governance’, American Political Science Review, Vol. 97, pp. 233-243.

Jordan, A. (1999) ‘The construction of a multilevel environmental governance


system’, Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, Vol. 17, pp. 1–17.

Knight, J. (1992) Institutions and Social Conflict. Cambridge University Press,


Cambridge.

Lancaster, K.J. (1966) ‘A new approach to consumer theory’, Journal of Political


Economy, Vol. 74, pp. 132-57.

McCay, B.J. (1996) ‘Common and private concerns’, in S.S. Hanna, C. Folke, and K.-
G. Mäler (eds.), Rights to Nature: Ecological, Economic, Cultural and Political
Principles of Institutions for the Environment. Island Press, Washington DC. pp. 111-
126.

Mitchell, R.B. (2003) ‘International environmental agreements: a survey of their


features, formation, and effects’, Annual Review of Environment and Resources, Vol.
28, pp. 429–461.

Najam, A., Christopoulou, I. and Moomaw, W.R. (2004) ‘The emergent "system" of
global environmental governance’, Global Environmental Politics, Vol. 4, pp. 23-35.

18
North, D.C. (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance.
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Olson, M. (1971) The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of
Groups. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.

Ostrom, E. (1990) Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective
Action. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Ostrom, E. (1998) ‘Scales, polycentricity, and incentives: designing complexity to


govern complexity’, in L.D. Guruswamy and J.A. McNeely (eds.), Protection of Global
Biodiversity: Converging Strategies. Duke University Press, Durham and London, pp.
149-167.

Ostrom, V. (1972) Polycentricity. A paper prepared for the Annual Meeting of the
American Political Science Association, Washington Hill Hotel, Washington DC,
September 5-9, 1972.

Ostrom, V., Tiebout, C.M. and Warren, R. (1961) ‘The organization of government in
metropolitan areas: a theoretical inquiry’, American Political Science Review, Vol. 55,
pp. 831-842.

Paavola, J. (2008) ‘Contributions of ecological and institutional economics to


environmental-economic analysis’, in A. Dehnhardt and U. Petshcow (eds.)
Governance of River Basins. Ökom Verlag, Munich, Germany. pp. 93-108.

Paavola, J. (2007) Institutions and environmental governance: a reconceptualization’,


Ecological Economics, Vol. 63, pp. 93-103.

Paavola, J. (2005) ‘Seeking justice: international environmental governance and


climate change’, Globalizations, Vol. 2, pp. 309-322.

Paavola, J. (2004) ‘Protected areas governance and justice: theory and the
European Union’s Habitats Directive’, Environmental Sciences, Vol. 1, pp. 59-77.

Paavola, J. (2002a) ‘Environment and development: dissecting the connections’, Forum


for Development Studies, Vol. 29, pp. 5-32.

Paavola, J. (2002b) ‘Water quality as property: industrial water pollution and common
law in the nineteenth century United States’, Environment and History, Vol. 8, pp. 295-
318.

Paavola, J. and Adger, W.N. (2005) ‘Institutional ecological economics’, Ecological


Economics, Vol. 53, pp. 353-368.

Panzar, J.C. and Willig, R.D. (1981) ‘Economies of scope’, American Economic
Review, Vol. 71, pp. 268-272.

Pierson, P. (2000) ‘Increasing returns, path dependence, and the study of politics’,
American Political Science Review, Vol. 94, pp. 251-267.

19
Rhodes, R.A.W. (1996) ‘The new governance: governing without government’,
Political Studies, Vol. 44, pp. 652-667.

Schlager, E. and Ostrom, E. (1992) ‘Property-rights regimes and natural resources: a


conceptual analysis’, Land Economics, Vol. 68, pp. 249-262.

Stoker, G. (1998) ‘Governance as theory: five propositions’, International Social


Science Journal, Vol. 50, pp 17–28.

Taylor, M. (1987) The Possibility of Cooperation. Cambridge University Press,


Cambridge.

Teece, D.J. (1980) ‘Economies of scope and the scope of the enterprise’, Journal of
Economic Behaviour and Organization, Vol. 1, pp. 223-247.

Teng, J. (2000) ‘Endogeneous authoritarian property rights’, Journal of Public


Economics, Vol. 77, pp. 81-95.

Turner, R.K., Paavola, J., Farber, S., Cooper, P., Jessamy, V., Rosendo, S. and
Georgiou, S. (2003) ‘Valuing nature: lessons learnt and future research directions’,
Ecological Economics, Vol. 46, pp. 493-510.

Vatn, A. (2002) ‘Multifunctional agriculture: some consequences for international


trade regimes’, European Review of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 29, pp. 309-327.

Vogler, J. (2003) ‘Taking institutions seriously: how regime analysis can be relevant
to multilevel environmental governance’, Global Environmental Politics, Vol. 3, pp.
25-39.

Williamson, O.E. (1999) ‘Public and private bureaucracies: a transaction cost


economics perspective’, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, Vol. 15. pp.
306 – 341.

20

You might also like