Kaufman Origins Evolution Field IR USA ILR Press 1993
Kaufman Origins Evolution Field IR USA ILR Press 1993
INDUSTRIAL
RELATIONS
in the United States
The Origins &
Evolution of the Field of
INDUSTRIAL
RELATIONS
in the United States
CORNELL STUDIES
IN INDUSTRIAL AND
LABOR RELATIONS
NUMBER 25
BRUCE E. KAuFMAN
ILR PRESS
AN IMPRINT OF
All rights reserved. Except for brief quotations in a review, this book, or parts
thereof, must not be reproduced in any form without permission in writing from
the publisher. For information address Cornell University Press, Sage House,
512 East State Street, Ithaca, New York 14850.
Kaufman, Bruce E.
The origins & evolution of the field of industrial relations in the United States.
p. cm.-(Cornell studies in industrial and labor relations; no.25)
Includes bibliographical references and index.
ISBN 0-87546-191-3 (alk. paper).-ISBN 0-87546-192-1 (pbk.: alk. paper)
1. Industrial relations-United States-History. I. Title.
II. Title: Origins and evolution of the field of industrial
relations in the United States. III. Series.
HD8066.K38 1993
331'.0973--dc20 92-19055
@The paper in this book meets the minimum requirements of the American
National Standard for Information Sciences-Permanence of Paper for Printed
Library Materials, ANSI Z39.48-1984.
T o L a u r e n a n d An d r e 'W
CoNTENTS
PREFACE u
INTRODUCTION xiii
NoTES 199
REFERENCES 253
INDEX 281
PREFACE
ix
Preface
X
Preface
I see them, I have also labored to be fair and accurate to all parties and
points of view. My intent is to stimulate constructive dialogue, not to
cause heartburn.
A central theme of this book is that research in industrial relations
has been animated by two very different impulses: science-building (the
advancement of knowledge for its own sake) and problem-solving (the
application of knowledge to solve practical problems). These impulses
have given the field a split personality-researchers interested in
science-building seek to tum the field into a distinct discipline with its
own overarching theoretical framework, while the problem-solvers find
its multidisciplinary nature a rich source from which to mix and match
specific theories and concepts to issues of practice and policy.
This book exhibits much the same split personality. In part, it is a
science-building exercise in historical analysis (albeit of an interpretive
nature) in which I attempt to trace the origins and evolution of insti-
tutions and ideas in industrial relations. But the book also has a problem-
solving dimension to it, for I am interested not only in chronicling the
development of the field but also in offering a vision for change that
will reverse the decline in the field's intellectual vital signs. The danger
in mixing these two motives, as in the broader world of IR research, is
that it blurs the purpose of the book and the nature of the intended
audience. Readers who want a straightforward history of thought text,
for example, will find the amount of space given to curricular and
programmatic developments and the development and organizational
details of the Industrial Relations Research Association to be excessive.
From my point of view, however, a consideration of these institutional
details is crucial if we are to chart a new path for the field. Such are
the tensions between science-building and problem-solving!
This book has benefited from the contributions of many people, fore-
most among them Clark Kerr, Richard Lester, and George Strauss. Each
of these men spent considerable time with me during the research phase
of the project discussing the key events, people, and ideas in the field
from the time of their first involvement with it in the 1940s to the
present time. After I had completed a first draft of the manuscript, they
also gave me detailed comments and suggestions. The manuscript has
benefited greatly from their efforts.
During the research phase of the project I also benefited from written
and telephone communications with numerous other scholars in the
xi
Preface
field. A partial list includes Chris Argyris, Jack Barbash, Don Cullen,
Milton Derber, William Form, John Fossum, Dallas Jones, Robert Lamp-
man, David Lewin, H. Gregg Lewis, Charles Myers, Maurice Neufeld,
Lloyd Reynolds, Richard Rowan, Tony Sinicropi, Philip Way, Hoyt
Wheeler and William Foote Whyte. I also received valued assistance
from the staff of the Industrial Relations Research Association. After
completing a first draft, I sent the manuscript to numerous people for
review. I received written or telephone comments from Jack Barbash,
Don Cullen, John Delaney, John Dunlop, John Fossum, Sanford Jacoby,
Thomas Kochan, Morris Kleiner, Michael Lee, Robert McKersie, Peter
Sherer, James Stem, Hoyt Wheeler, William Foote Whyte, and Daniel
Wren. I wish to express my sincere appreciation to each of these people
for their help and assistance. All contributors and reviewers are, of
course, absolved from responsibility for errors of fact or interpretation.
Finally, I wish to acknowledge a number of other people who also
made valuable contributions to this book: Fran Benson, Erica Fox, An-
drea Fleck Clardy, and Patricia Peltekos, all of ILR Press, and Donna
Smith, who assisted me in preparing the manuscript for submission to
the publisher. Completion of this project was also aided by financial
assistance from the College of Business Administration of Georgia State
University. Last, but not least, I owe a debt of thanks to my wife,
Deborah, who somehow managed her own full-time career and two
young children while her husband worked nights and weekends to com-
plete this manuscript.
xii
INTRODUCTION
xiii
Introduction
where the first IR academic programs were established and the structure
and historical evolution of IR curricula.
The second consideration is that substantial controversy exists in the
field concerning its intellectual boundaries and core subject area (Begin
1987; Boivin 1989; Strauss 1989, 1990). Several IR scholars, for ex-
ample, define the field broadly to include the study of all aspects of the
employment relationship (Heneman 1969; Fossum 1987). From this
point of view, IR subsumes all subfields relevant to the employment
relationship, such as human resources management, collective bargain-
ing, industrial psychology, and labor law, and covers in its coursework
and research all dimensions of work, including the practice of employ-
ment relations in both union and nonunion situations.
Other people adopt a narrower interpretation that defines industrial
relations as the study of organized employment relationships, with a
particular focus on unions and collective bargaining (see Behrend 1963;
Strauss 1990). Juxtaposed to the field of IR, in this view, is the separate
field of human resources (HR), which has become associated with a
largely behavioral science approach to the study of nonunion work sit-
uations, with particular emphasis on the practice and organization of
management. This bifurcation in the study of the employment rela-
tionship is attested to, for example, in the title of the University Council
of Industrial Relations and Human Resource Programs and the title of
a textbook by Thomas Kochan and Thomas Barocci (1985), Human
Resources Management and Industrial Relations.
These starkly different visions of industrial relations have created a
significant identity problem for the field, a situation exacerbated by the
attempt of IR scholars to have it both ways-to stake out a broad, all-
inclusive jurisdiction for industrial relations when discussing the nature
of the field but to focus primarily on collective bargaining when con-
ducting research. I hope this book helps to resolve this intellectual
paradox or, if not to resolve it, at least to identify its origins and un-
derlying causes.
The third consideration motivating this book concerns the recent
decline in the vitality and academic stature of industrial relations as a
field of study and its prospects for survival and growth in the future. A
variety of signs indicate that the field of industrial relations experienced
a significant decline in the 1980s as a focal point for teaching and
research in employment relations (W. Franke 1987; Begin 1987;
xiv
Introduction
XV
The Origins &
Evolution of the Field of
INDUSTRIAL
RELATIONS
in the United States
1
THE ORIGINS OF
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS
3
The Origins of Industrial Relations
LABOR PROBLEMS
The intellectual precursor of industrial relations was the concept of
"the labor problem." The term labor problem came into vogue in the
latter part of the nineteenth century and was used to connote the general
struggle between labor and capital over the control of production and
the distribution of income and the conflict engendered by this struggle
(see Barnes 1886; Olson 1894). The concept then evolved in two steps.
The first step, which occurred shortly after the tum of the century,
was a movement away from the unitary conception of the labor problem
to a pluralistic conception of labor problems (Adams and Sumner 1905;
Watkins 1922). 3 The pluralistic version represented an intellectual ad-
vance in that it recognized that labor problems take many different forms
besides labor-management conflict, that labor problems afflict both em-
ployers and workers, and that labor problems exist in both socialist and
capitalist economies. Commonly cited examples of labor problems facing
employers were high employee turnover, worker "soldiering" (loafing),
and excessive waste and inefficiency in production, while labor problems
affecting workers included insecurity of employment, low pay, child
labor, and unsafe working conditions.
The second step, which occurred gradually after World War I, was
the replacement of labor problems with a terminology that was more field-
specific. Thus, the term labor problems continued to be used in labor
economics but was gradually replaced by personnel problems in personnel
management, social problems in sociology, and so on. 4 It was not until
the late 1940s-early 1950s that the "problems" perspective began to fall
out of favor in the social sciences, for reasons discussed in chapter 6.
The concept of labor problems was crucial to the development of
industrial relations because it provided both an intellectual justification
for the field and a focal point for research and teaching (Derber 1967).
When the labor problems perspective first emerged it was as a reaction
against the policy conclusions derived from the intellectual doctrines of
classical economics and social Darwinism. As discussed in more detail
in chapter 2, classical economics purported to show that competition
in free, unregulated labor markets promotes efficiency in production and
4
The Origins of Industrial Relations
5
The Origins of Industrial Relations
6
The Origins of Industrial Relations
number of jobless workers during this period was caused by both demand
and supply factors. On the demand side, the economy was in recession
or depression roughly half the years between 1870 and 1900. The scarcity
of jobs because of the insufficient demand was exacerbated on the supply
side by the influx of millions of immigrants into the country. The result
in many urban areas was a persistent pool of unemployed workers and
cut-throat competition for jobs. Faced with numerous job seekers, many
of whom were foreign-hom and unskilled, and continual downward
pressure on prices in the product market (prices fell by one-third between
1870 and 1900), the competitive struggle to stay in business forced
employers to reduce labor costs wherever possible, be it by lowering
wages, speeding up the pace of work, or skimping on even elementary
safety precautions. The working life of most manual workers during the
period, therefore, was marked by considerable insecurity and hardship
(Lescohier 1935). The resulting social tensions were further exacerbated
by the growing affluence of the upper classes and the notable trend
toward a greater inequality in income and wealth (Williamson and
Lindert 1980).
The third reason for the increase in labor-management conflict was
the arbitrary, unsystematic, and authoritarian methods of personnel
management used in industry (Jacoby 1985). Employers generally re-
garded workers as a commodity from which maximum production should
be extracted for the least cost and then discarded when no longer needed.
Personnel departments and written policies were nonexistent before
World War I. In most plants, top management delegated all personnel
matters such as hiring, firing, pay, promotion, and work load to the
foreman in charge of each department or shop. Typically, the foreman's
decisions on these matters were final. His task was to maximize pro-
duction at minimum unit cost. To accomplish this, the accepted method
was the "drive system." The drive system entailed constant supervision
by the foreman and the use of profane language and verbal abuse to
induce the employees to work harder. The factors that made the drive
system an effective device to elicit work effort was the threat of dismissal
from the job-a threat made credible by the existence of numerous job
seekers outside the plant gate. Although employers generally found the
"foreman-in-charge" method of personnel administration and the drive
system of employee motivation to be cost-effective, these practices
nevertheless created considerable tension and dissatisfaction among em-
7
The Origins of Industrial Relations
8
The Origins of Industrial Relations
9
The Origins of Industrial Relations
and policy makers debated the causes and cures of the breakdown in
employer-employee relations. 8 Given the severity of the labor problems
at this time, the widespread interest in employment reform, and the
absence of organized research and teaching on the subject of the em-
ployment relationship, the term soon came to describe a new subject
area or field of study. The focal point of this new field was the em-
ployment relationship and, in particular, the causes of labor problems
and their resolution through improved methods of administration and
organization.
The birth of industrial relations as an independent field of academic
study was marked by the establishment in 1920 of the Bureau of Com-
mercial and Industrial Relations in the extension division of the Uni-
versity of Wisconsin and of a "course" (area of specialization) in
industrial relations in the Department of Economics, under the direction
of John R. Commons (U.S. Department of Labor 1921). This special-
ization was, as far as I can determine, the first academic program of
study in industrial relations at an American university. Students taking
the specialization enrolled in four subjects: labor legislation, labor history
and industrial government, labor management, and causes and remedies
of unemployment.
The new field of industrial relations was soon introduced at other
major universities. In 1921, the Industrial Research Unit was established
at the Wharton School of Business and Commerce of the University of
Pennsylvania to promote research on the problems of industry (Wharton
School 1989). For the first decade research conducted by the unit was
focused almost exclusively on industrial relations topics. In later years,
several studies on the economics of the mining, metals, and textile
industries were also published.
The first academic unit devoted specifically to industrial relations was
created in 1922 by Princeton University with the establishment of its
Industrial Relations Section in the Department of Economics (Industrial
Relations Section 1986). The purpose of the section was to foster re-
search on industrial relations, principally through published reports and
monographs by the faculty associated with the section and the devel-
opment of a comprehensive library of industrial relations materials. At
Harvard University industrial relations appeared in 1923 when the Jacob
Wertheim Research Fellowship for the Betterment of Industrial Rela-
tions was established. Finally, in 1925, the University of Chicago pro-
10
The Origins of Industrial Relations
Q
ployment levels, while sociology examines social groups and behaviors
ch as status differentiation and mobility across social classes. lndustriaD
elations was thought to focus on the employment relationship and, in
articular, on the relationship between employers and workers and the
bor problems that grow out of this relationship. 11
This conceptualization of the field was most clearly enunciated in an
II
The Origins of Industrial Relations
12
The Origins of Industrial Relations
13
FIGURE 1.1 Map Suggesting the Field of Research in Industrial Relations
III.
Illustrative Problems Arising in Industry
Affecting
THE WORKER IN RELATION TO HIS WORK
I. II. (Objective conditions of the job, personal
Sciences Nearest Related to Studies FACTORS IN HUMAN BEHAVIOR condition of the worker, attitude
of Factors in Human Behavior With special reference to industry towards task)
14
VI.
IV. v. Illustrative Problems Arising in Industry
Illustrative Problems Arising in Industry Illustrative Problems Arising in Industry Affecting
Affecting Affecting THE WORKER IN RELATION TO
THE WORKER IN RELATION TO HIS THE WORKER IN RELATION TO THE PUBUC
FELLOW•WORKER HIS EMPLOYER (Consumer, semi-public agencies, police,
(At his side, in his plant, in his union, in (Foreman, manager, owner, employing class, government, legislatures, couns,
his community or in the world at large) investor, capitalist, banker) commissions)
(~)
(10) (12)
Grievances, wage difficulties, A. Qvil Service problems (selection,
and conflicts caused by unsuitability of training, promotion, etc.)
the worker for the job, or
A. Lack of sympathy or cohesion between B
personality traits of the worker,
highly efficient or highly skilled worker involving:
and the mediocre or unskilled I. Selection procedure
2. Rating, follow.. up, promotion,
ere.
B. Exploitation of workers by other more
a~}
dynamic workers, existence of 11agitarors," Discipline problems caused by B. Accidents and damage caused by
"firebrands," etc. I. Poor leadership by foremen, improperly selected motormen, taxi..
managers, etc. drivers, having personality traits of
2. Neuroses of executives ( 11 Mental recklessness, etc.
C. Personal traits of leaders of workers hygiene of executives")
(paralleled with qualities of outstanding 3. Abuse of wage incentive plans,
executives?) rime study, etc.
4. General 11 Unpsychologic"
handling of situations in plant
15
FIGURE 1.1 (continued)
III.
Illusmtive Problems Arising in lndusny
Affecting
THE WORKER IN RElATION TO HIS WORK
I. II. (Objective conditions of the job, penonal
Sciences Nearest Related to Studies FACfORS IN HUMAN BEHAVIOR condition of the worker, attirude towards
of Factots in Human Behavior With special reference to indusny task)
Ethics
A. Beliefs, customs, traditions, structural or
institutional attirudes, national rraits, etc. B. The effect of different economic systems
(Religious, ethical, social) and industrial organization upon the wage
earner, including such elements as:
I. The industrial population and the labor
market
2. Mechanization, pace, routine work
3. Insecurity, unemployment, "pre..
senescence"
4. Competition and monopoly
B. Economic organization 5. The wage system and wage scales
I. Ownership and control of indusny 6. Insecurity, attitude towards older men
Economics 2. Technology of indusny 7. Personnel practices and labor turnover
3. Distribution of wealth 8. Employee ownetship of stock or control
4. General economic setting of plant
Education
16
VI.
IV. v. Illustrative Problems Arising in Industry
Illustrative Problems Arising in Industry Illustrative Problems Arising in Industry Affecting
Affecting Affecting THE WORKER IN RELATION TO
THE WORKER IN RELATION TO HIS THE WORKER IN RELATION TO
THE PUBLIC
FELLOW•WORKER HIS EMPLOYER (Consumer, semi..public agencies, police,
(At his side, in his plant, in his union, in (Foreman, manager, owner, employing class, government, legislatures, courts,
his community or in the world at large) investor, capitalist, banker) commissions)
17
The Origins of Industrial Relations
I8
2
THE ScHISM IN
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS
19
Schism in Industrial Relations
20
Schism in Industrial Relations
21
Schism in Industrial Relations
Scientific management was born shortly before the tum of the twen-
tieth century. Its most important proponent was Frederick Taylor, al-
though disciples such as Henry Gantt and Harrington Emerson also
made contributions (Hoxie 1915; Haber 1964). Taylor's focus of atten-
tion was on plant management. He argued that labor problems and the
adversarial relation between labor and capital arose from defective or-
ganization and improper methods of production and distribution in the
workplace. Production and distribution, he contended, are governed by
immutable natural laws that operate independently of human judgment.
The object of scientific management is to discover these laws and to
apply the "one best way" to selection, promotion, compensation, train-
ing, and production.
Taylor advocated using time and motion studies to determine the
most efficient method for performing each work task, piece-rate systems
of compensation to maximize employee work effort, and the selection
and training of employees based on a thorough investigation of their
talents and skills. Taylor also advocated changes in the organizational
structure of the business firm, such as replacing the single foreman in
charge of all aspects of production and personnel management in a given
department with several foremen, each of whom would be trained in
the knowledge and skills of a specific functional activity (e.g., produc-
tion, machine repair, and so on.) The end result of these reforms in
organization and methods would be the elimination of labor problems
and the adversarial relation between labor and capital. This would be
accomplished because all matters concerning production and distribution
would be made on the basis of natural law and the one best way, thus
eliminating disputes arising from errors and biases in human judgment.
Increased efficiency would result in higher profits and higher wages,
causing workers and employers to recognize that the employment re-
lationship involves a mutuality of interests, not a conflict of interests.
Industrial welfare work was introduced before the tum of the century,
grew in popularity up to the beginning of World War I, and then fell
into disfavor thereafter as an independent employment practice (Ling
1965:80). Welfare work consisted of a variety of activities, sponsored
and financed unilaterally by individual companies, the aim of which
was to improve the home and working life of the companies' employees.
Companies installed employee washrooms and lunchrooms, provided
the services of a company doctor or nurse, built various recreational
22
Schism in Industrial Relations
facilities, offered financial assistance for home purchases, and sent com~
pany welfare representatives to employees' homes to check on the sick
or advise on nutritional and hygiene matters. In some cases companies
undertook welfare work out of philanthropic motives; others did it as a
way to forestall unionism or as a substitute for direct cash compensation.
Most often, however, the motive was the belief that welfare work was
"good business" because it helped foster loyalty and improved employees'
morale.
By the start of World War I a small minority of companies had
implemented at least some of the activities or principles associated with
scientific management and welfare work (Jacoby 1985). But in most of
these firms, to say nothing of the great majority of industry, the main
personnel functions of recruitment, hiring, compensation, training, and
discharge of employees still remained in the hands of the shop foremen
or other line management, and the foremen continued to use the drive
system as the principal mechanism for motivating employees. According
to the advocates of PM, the labor problems of the war era occurred
because the traditional system of personnel management was unscientific
and inhumane. The solution, in tum, was to take the personnel function
away from line management and vest it in a new staff function called
personnel management, where trained experts could devise and imple~
menta set of uniform, progressive policies and practices.
Some of these new personnel policies and practices were direct de~
scendants of scientific management. Thus, firms stripped the individual
foreman of the ability to hire at the plant gate and centralized this
activity in the personnel department, which developed formalized se~
lection procedures using written employment histories and aptitude tests.
Other practices were direct descendants of welfare work, such as pro~
viding services or benefits that fulfilled various personal and work~related
needs of employees. Thus, the duties of the company welfare worker,
such as management of the lunchroom or home visits, were also cen~
tralized in the personnel department and transformed from a sideline
activity smacking of heavy~handed paternalism to a modem business
practice that was an integral part of the management of labor.
Several other personnel principles and practices emerged in the 1920s
as reactions against some of the perceived shortcomings of scientific
management and welfare work (Milton 1960). The two most important
came under the headings "human relations" and "industrial democracy."
23
Schism in Industrial Relations
24
Schism in Industrial Relations
25
Schism in Industrial Relations
what the worker was thought to want was economic security, respect
and fair dealing from supervisors, opportunity for advancement, and
effective leadership from the firm's managers. Although much of this
work was based on relatively unscientific methods, it nevertheless de,
veloped several themes that later proved quite important in PM.
One such theme concerned economic versus noneconomic determi,
nants of employee work behavior. Classical economics and scientific
management both used a model of "economic man" in that they pre,
sumed employees were motivated primarily by economic considera,
tions. 14 Management writers in the 1920s took the first step in replacing
economic man with "social man." Numerous writers {e.g., Thorndike
1922; Lewisohn 1926) argued that workers value such nonpecuniary
rewards as status, justice, security, and advancement. Ordway Tead
(1929:132) went one step further and, in anticipation of later theories
of motivation by Abraham H. Maslow and Frederick Herzberg, argued
that economic needs have to be met first but that worker loyalty and
satisfaction ultimately depend on the fulfillment of such noneconomic
needs as security, justice, and self,worth. The displacement of economic
man by social man in the PM literature was important because it provided
an intellectual justification for the abandonment of drive methods of
motivation that relied on fear and intimidation and the adoption of
positive employment methods (e.g., supervisor training, employment
security, profit sharing) that not only encouraged hard work by linking
personal gain with corporate gain but also fostered an atmosphere of
fair treatment and personal growth.
The role of managerial leadership also became an important theme.
Writers on PM noted that corporate managers were prone to devoting
most of their attention to the "business" side of the firm and to neglecting
the "people" side (e.g., firms had created staff departments for the
finance, production, and accounting functions long before personnel
departments). The proponents of PM claimed that the most important
determinant of profitability was the way firms treated their employees
(Lewisohn 1926; Spates 1937; Hicks 1941). It was crucial, therefore,
for both improved industrial relations and firm performance that· man,
agers take a progressive, forward,looking approach to labor. Toward that
end, PM treatises of the 1920s expounded the benefits to managers and
their organizations of progressive, humane personnel policies and iden,
tified the traits of successful leadership so that managers might more
26
Schism in Industrial Relations
effectively deal with employees and earn their loyalty and support (Craig
and Charters 1925). The job of the ·manager had changed from com,
manding employees to perform certain tasks to enlisting their cooper,
ation, something that could only be done successfully with good
interpersonal skills and a sound knowledge of what motivates work effort.
The emphasis on leadership thus reinforced the shift of attention in PM
away from earlier views of labor as a commodity or a machine to a
conception of workers as human beings who, with the right management
practices and work environment, could become satisfied, productive
members of the company team. This emphasis on the role of managerial
leadership also imparted a unilateral, paternalistic tone to PM since it
tended to locate all responsibility for improved industrial relations in
the hands of management.
The organizational goals of the firm were yet another area of impor,
tance. Proponents of PM argued that a congruence of interests between
the organization and its employees could be obtained only if the firm
pursued goals that were salient to workers (Tead 1931:33-36; Hicks
1941:167-69). Strict adherence to a goal of profit maximization was
likely to perpetuate an environment of conflict and mistrust because it
emphasized the role of labor as a cost of production and subordinated
employees' interests to those of absentee shareholders. Successful in,
dustrial relations required, therefore, that managers pursue multiple goals
that would satisfy the needs of various stakeholders, including workers.
Although this strategy might reduce profits in the short run, the pro,
ponents of PM argued that it increased profits in the long run by leading
to reduced absenteeism, greater work effort, and less conflict.
The human relations perspective provided one of the fundamental
pillars of thought in PM in the 1920s; the concept of industrial de,
mocracy provided another. The term industrial democracy had been pop,
ularized by Sidney and Beatrice Webb of Great Britain in their landmark
book Industrial Democracy (1897). The Webbs were Fabian socialists and
ardent supporters of trade unions. They argued at length that the tra,
ditional master,servant relationship in industry was incompatible with
democratic principles because workers had neither a formal voice in the
determination of wages and other terms and conditions of employment
nor protection from arbitrary and/or discriminatory decisions of man,
agement with regard to discipline, discharge, and other such matters.
From the Webbs' point of view, trade unions were the major instrument
27
Schism in Industrial Relations
28
Schism in Industrial Relations
29
Schism in Industrial Relations
30
Schism in Industrial Relations
31
Schism in Industrial Relations
32
Schism in Industrial Relations
33
Schism in Industrial Relations
34
Schism in Industrial Relations
have occurred had the labor market been competitive and at full em~
ployment, thus leading to an increase in both efficiency and equity.
The solution to management authoritarianism, the institutionalists
claimed, was industrial democracy, or joint determination of the terms
and conditions of employment and the provision of due process in the
settlement of disputes over rights. The institutionalists regarded non~
union employee representation plans as a step forward, particularly if
they provided employees with independent decision~making power and
protection from arbitrary discipline and discharge. The fundamental
weakness of such plans, however, was that they were created by a
unilateral act of management and just as easily could be abolished or
ignored (Douglas 1921). For this reason the institutionalists advocated
trade unions as a complement to employee representation plans and
viewed unions as the long~term solution to industrial democracy. Union
bargaining power, they said, provided workers with both voice and
protection that was independent of the goodwill of the employer (Com~
mons 1920; Leiserson 1923, 1929).
Eliminating the insecurity of the worker involved both micro~ and
macro~level changes (Commons 1921, 1926:263-72). At the plant
level, it required a philosophical commitment by management to provide
employment security; improved production and marketing methods to
reduce seasonal and cyclical fluctuations in employment; and a system
of employee representation to provide protection against arbitrary dis~
missal and discipline. At the economywide level, it required stabilization
of the currency by the Federal Reserve Bank, a negotiated or legislated
floor under wages and working conditions so that recessions and depres~
sion would not lead to a general liquidation of labor standards, and the
creation of social insurance programs (e.g., workmens' compensation,
unemployment compensation, social security) that would provide both
tax incentives to firms to regularize employment and income support to
workers who for reasons outside their control were unable to work. 19
POINTS OF AGREEMENT
The overarching issue that united both the PM and the ILE schools
was the need for employment reform. The traditional way of managing
35
Schism in Industrial Relations
POINTS OF DISAGREEMENT
In general, the proponents of the ILE school were academically trained
economists, while the early writers in the PM school tended to come
from the ranks of management in industry (as did many of the teachers
of personnel courses in business schools of the 1920s). The two groups
inevitably looked at the causes and solutions of labor problems from
different perspectives. 20 It was evident to both that the business orga-
nization was the place to begin the investigation of labor problems, for
that was where the inefficiency in production, the low work effort, and
the conflict occurred. When it came to identifying the underlying causes
of the problems, however, the two sides diverged. The economists
tended to give far greater weight to the external economic, legal, and
technological environment, such as business cycles, labor market im-
perfections, and the lt!gal rights and protections given to employers and
employees. In contrast, the management practitioners tended to focus
36
Schism in Industrial Relations
37
Schism in Industrial Relations
38
Schism in Industrial Relations
nents of PM did not dispute. The issue for employment reform, then,
was how to get the other 75 to 90 percent (the laggards) up to the same
level of accomplishment.
The basic approach favored by the proponents of the PM school was
to use education, persuasion, and patience. As noted earlier, they be-
lieved that a mutuality of interests could be attained by adopting pro-
gressive personnel policies, particularly human relations and industrial
democracy. The challenge was to induce firms to adopt these practices.
The PM school believed a two-prong strategy would work best (Milton
1960:129-40). The first prong involved an appeal to the employer's
sense of ethics and Christian duty; that is, convincing the laggards that
they had a moral responsibility to improve their treatment of employees.
The second prong involved business education; that is, convincing em-
ployers that improved management practices were also good for their
bottom line.
The early proponents of PM believed that employers would adopt
progressive personnel practices if they perceived the benefits to be greater
than the costs. Thus, a fundamental axiom of PM is that progressive
personnel practices are not only right from a moral and ethical point
of view but also more than pay for themselves in the form of increased
profit (Tead and Metcalf 1920:9). The problem is that many employers
have a difficult time seeing the validity of this proposition because, on
the one hand, the costs of improved personnel practices tend to be
readily quantifiable and incurred in the short run (e.g., salaries of per-
sonnel staff, additional payroll costs associated with employment se-
curity), whereas the benefits are often difficult to measure and often do
not become evident until well into the future (e.g., increased produc-
tivity through higher morale, lower chances of unionization). The result
is that many employers mistakenly believe that good labor relations
policies are a "luxury" that only profitable firms can afford and thus do
not undertake them. The proponents of PM believed that the only way
to counteract this view was through education, both on the new tech-
niques of personnel administration (e.g., employment tests, employee
representation plans) and on their benefits to the firm (Kennedy 1920;
Tead and Metcalf 1920:15-16; Houser 1927:202-18).
From the ILE point of view, these positions were not so much wrong
as seriously incomplete. Commons, for example, agreed with the con-
tention that progressive personnel policies could reduce labor problems
39
Schism in Industrial Relations
40
Schism in Industrial Relations
41
Schism in Industrial Relations
adopt. Many of these practices (e. g., twelve~ hour workdays, excessive
line speed, lack of elementary safety equipment) are clearly injurious
to both workers and society and their elimination through collective
bargaining is thus to be desired. While individual firms may be put
at a competitive disadvantage to the extent that restrictive union prac~
tices raise labor costs only at those firms, the solution to this problem
is best met by taking labor costs out of competition by organizing all
firms in the relevant product market and imposing common labor stan~
dards on them.
The institutionalists also favored labor unions as the primary vehicle
to achieve industrial democracy. Company unions, works councils, and
other employer-sponsored forms of employee representation do not pro~
vide industrial democracy in the true sense of the term, since they are
created by management and give workers little or no independent power
to negotiate improved terms of employment or protection from arbitrary
management decisions on discipline and discharge. True democracy
means that decisions are reached only with the consent of the governed,
implying that workers must be able to elect representatives of their own
choosing, engage in collective bargaining over wages and other con~
ditions of employment, and go on strike if an agreement cannot be
reached. Industrial democracy also implies that unions have a legitimate
right to demand the union shop or closed shop, for, just as all citizens
in the nation are bound to abide by laws adopted by the majority, so
too should all employees belong to and support the union if it has been
freely chosen by a majority in the plant.
Finally, institutionalists were strong advocates of economic and po~
litical "pluralism" and saw unions as essential parts of such a system.
Business firms, they thought, had a power advantage over workers and
consumers because the latter were unorganized and could not effectively
represent their interests. The solution was a pluralistic network of or~
ganized interest groups, such as labor unions, political parties, church
groups, civic associations, and so on, each of which would represent
their respective constituencies. This conception of society led the in~
stitutionalists to stress a "tripartite" approach to the resolution of labor
disputes, in which tripartite meant collaboration, consultation, and
compromise between representatives of labor, management, and the
public. 26
For all of these reasons, the proponents of the ILE school saw unions
42
Schism in Industrial Relations
43
3
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS IN THE
INTERWAR YEARS
45
Industrial Relations in the Interwar Years
46
Industrial Relations in the Interwar Years
financial gift from Rockefeller. The purpose of the section was to collect
and disseminate information on industrial relations topics, sponsor IR
research, and organize conferences and training classes for industrial
relations practitioners (primarily upper,level managers). The section was
organized as a subunit of the Department of Economics, although the
approach to industrial relations was intended to be multidisciplinary
(Brown 1976). Given Hicks's philosophical position on the practice of
industrial relations and the apparent triumph of welfare capitalism and
defeat of unionism in the 1920s, it is not surprising that the early research
output of the section had a heavy PM flavor. The first five publications,
for example, dealt with employee stock ownership plans, corporate train,
ing programs, labor turnover, absenteeism and tardiness, and group
insurance.
The four other U.S. IR sections Hicks organized were similar to the
one at Princeton. Of these units, the one at MIT has made the most
impact on the field. 5 Established in 193 7, it was started as a subunit of
the Department of Economics and Social Science (McKersie 1990) but
was later transferred to the Sloan School of Management. The section
initially had three faculty members, Rupert Maclaurin (economics),
Douglas McGregor (psychology), and Charles Myers (economics/per,
sonnel), each of whom served at some point as section director. The
research output of the section during its first decade was eclectic but
was weighted toward local labor market studies, human relations topics,
and personnel management.
47
Industrial Relations in the Interwar Years
48
Industrial Relations in the Interwar Years
lems texts represented, therefore, the 1930s' version of what today would
be called an IR theory text.
Several features distinguish the labor problems courses of the 1930s
from a post-1970 labor economics course. First, the emphasis on labor
problems gave the course of the 1930s a critical and reformist tone-
critical because it suggested that the capitalist system was prone to serious
maladjustments and defects that accounted for the "evils," and reformist
because it focused on changes in the organizational, economic, and
political status quo to solve these evils (Estey 1928; Yoder 1931). In
contrast, modem labor economics generally gives the market system
high marks for its allocative efficiency and for that reason tends to
emphasize the virtues of competition in free markets and the harmful
effects of institutional interventions (e. g., unions, minimum wage laws).
Second, labor problems texts were generally descriptive and written
largely from a historical and sociological point of view; they gave scant
attention to the operation of labor markets and the manner in which
demand and supply determine outcomes such as wages, hours· of work,
and so on. 7 Present-day labor economics texts are in many ways the
opposite. Finally, the labor problems texts spent several chapters ana-
lyzing personnel management, including topics such as the philosophies
and goals of management; personnel practices, such as hiring tests,
compensation systems, and techniques of performance appraisal; and
methods for dispute resolution. Modem labor economics texts generally
exclude these subjects altogether.
49
Industrial Relations in the Interwar Years
50
Industrial Relations in the Interwar Years
One may quarrel with specific aspects of the figure, but it nevertheless
provides an accurate portrayal of the development of IR research in the
years before 1940. 8 As the figure indicates, IR research spanned a wide
range of academic fields and included a very heterogeneous mix of topics.
Economics, sociology, anthropology, engineering, personnel manage,
ment, and psychology all contributed to the field. Topics investigated
included union history, wage determination, the practice of collective
bargaining, government regulation of the employment relationship,
working,class social structures and values, restriction of output by em,
ployees, preemployment hiring tests, attributes of effective leadership,
determinants of employee motivation and morale, and methods of in,
dustrial governance and conflict resolution.
As the figure also illustrates, from its earliest days, IR research was
composed of both behavioral and nonbehavioral science wings. The
nonbehavioral wing was represented by economics and industrial man,
agement (i.e., scientific management). The behavioral wing was initially
(1920s) represented by the discipline of psychology, both directly
through industrial psychology and indirectly through the psychological
component of personnel management. In the 1930s, the behavioral side
of IR research expanded greatly with the addition of several new branches
of thought, including industrial sociology, applied anthropology, and
what Miller and Form called the "Harvard Graduate School of Business
Administration" (the writings of Elton Mayo, T. N. Whitehead, and
Fritz J. Roethlisberger and William J. Dickson). The involvement of
all three fields was the result of a common catalyst, the research findings
of the Hawthorne experiments at the Western Electric Company, con,
ducted between 1924 and 1933. For this reason, all three branches are
commonly combined under the label of "human relations." Since the
human relations movement (the academic version, that is) did not
emerge with full force until the publication of Roethlisberger and Dick,
son's monumental study, Management and the Worker, in 1939, a full
discussion of this aspect of IR research is postponed until the next
chapter.
Figure 3.1 also clearly reveals the presence of what has been called
here the ILE and PM schools of thought in industrial relations. The
ILE school was composed of the institutional economics and industrial
and labor economics branches on the lefthand side of the figure. Initially,
the PM school was composed of the fields in the three most righthand
51
FIGURE 3.1. Outlines of the Streams of Industrial Relations Knowledge
INSTITUTIONAL
ECONOMICS
1867 K.Marx
INDUSTRIAL.t
1867
IABOil ECONOMICS 1899
1899 T. Veblen
R. Ely
INDUSTRIAL 1903
1903
MANAiiEMENT INDUSTRIAL
1910 J. R. Commons 1910
PSYCHOLO~Y
1911 Taylor 1911
W.Williams
F. R. Donovan
.MANAEiEMENT Porfenbc:rgcr
\.Jl
N
1922
1923
1925
M. Weber
T. Veblen
R. Tawney
S. Perlman
I .
SCott &: Ooth1er Farnsworth
1922
1923
1925
I I
W.Williams
1926 J.M.Ciark H. Bum 1926
1927
19.28
G. D. H. Cole
S. Perlman E.T. Hiller
I
A. Pnffenbcrger
1927
1928
I
F. R. Donovan
R. &: H. Lynd Tnd
I
V. Anderson 1929
1929
19.~0
JQ.H
M.Webet
E. Durkhtim
HARVAilD
61\ADLIATE SCHOOL
OF BUSINESS
I
H. Hepner
1930
1931
19,\.:!
1933
I
A. ~le & G. Means
E. E. Witte
A. Todd
E. W. Bakke SOCIOMETRY
ADMINISTMTION
I
1932
1933
1~34
I
T. Veblen M=no C. Griffith 1934
L Mumford M. Vi11~-lcs
H. Hcpntr
1935
I
J.Davis S. ~rlman & P. Taft
PUBLIC
ADMINISTAATION 1935
L Co"!' LHuberman
1936
I I T. N. Whilt"head J. Gaus, L
D. Whice
& M. Dimock
I 1936
I
S. Chase
I
1938
I I F. R. Donovan
I
T. N.
I
Wh~hnd llonwd
I
c. c. Balderston
Wad.:W& Dodd
E. K. Strong
I
1938
I I I
1939
\
P. Pigon. L C. McKettnc"Y
& T. 0. Armstrong
I Ronhlubc-rf:C't &
[)i(kson
I
Lansburg &:
Hanmann
Mj &del)'i
& Ne.,.con>b, EJ. \939
1940
I
5. Hardwood
I
1940 K. Mannheim P. Landis
fl. W. Bakke Sprieg"l Bin,l!ham & Moore:
1941 J.
I Burnham S. H. Slichtcr
I
W. F. Cottrell
APPLIED
ANTHRO• Roethlisberger Foller & Metcalf
A. Walton
1941
1942
I
T. Arnold
C R. Daugherty
Rj A. Lester
C. Golden &
H. Rum-nberg
A. Jont'S
I
L Wilson
PfLO<jY
Arensburg
Richardson
I
Riegel Yoder J.liffin
C ROgers
1942
I
F. Graham
194.\
J. A. Schumpeter
I
R. Brady
I
S. H. Patterson E. Hughe-s JennmJ,>s Fa~ & Scott
I
Urwid;
H. Hl."pncr
H. Moore
I 1943
1944 K. Polanyi N. Chamberlain Mayo &. Lombard M. Smith 1944
194S
W. Ber~
s. Chut>
C. Whittelest:y
J. Dunlop
P. Drucker
M1lh~ .X MontE:Omcry
I
B. B. Gardner
I
lundberg
Jacobs
SOCIATRY
8< <;ROUP ~1ghton
I
Mayo M. Dimock Tead
I
C. Nonhcon
Wahers
R. McMurray
I
N. Cantor 1945
1946 I
I
F. Peterson
I
W.Moore
I
Rogers
.----
DYNAMICS
Moreno
I E. Chapple&:
S. Lewis(lhn
I
N. R. F. Maier 1946
W.Whyre French Donald
1947
I
E. W. Bakke
B. Sc:lekman
I
W. L. Warner & Low
I
ZC'ltn)'
Bradford&:
Lippitt
Bavclas Mayo J-Gaus
H. A. Simon
Breaded
I
Pigors & Myers
Jucius
I
T. Ryan
C. Tbomason
1947
VI
\.N
1948
I
G. Swcking
Harbison & Dubin
Bakke & Kerr
W. H. Hopkins
). Barbash
I
W. Whyte
Mills & Schneider
I
Lewin
I
Roethl1sht-rw:r
I
Barnard
I
Ghisdli
I
H.-Bum 1948
& M. Watkins R. Thornd1kc
l.es«-r &: Shisrer
I I
G. Srockins
I I I
I
&:M. Warkms A. Ross
N. Chamberlain
1949 E. Ginzberg Richardson & Walker Lippitt Lc:ighron P. Appleby Niles Thompson M. L. Blum 1949
I J. Shisrer
L Reynolds
L. G. Reynolds
& ). Shisrer
Pigors
j j
Bdlows
Hemphill
I
19SO V. Mund P. Mt:adows 1950
J
KNOWLEDGE OF INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS
54
Industrial Relations in the Interwar Years
virtually one and the same is, nevertheless, far from the truth. Several
reasons most likely account for this confusion.
It is not always recognized that in the 1920s-30s the discipline of
economics, and labor economics in particular, contained an extremely
heterodox group of scholars. Some of these scholars were truly econo-
mists in that they were conversant with economic theory and interested
in economic subjects per se. Others, however, had much greater ex-
pertise in related fields, such as personnel management, labor history,
sociology, and law. Before World War II, for example, most of the
influential academic writers on personnel management, including Paul
Douglas, Sumner Stichter, Gordon Watkins, and Dale Yoder, had de-
grees in economics. Similarly, labor history was dominated by econo-
mists, including Commons, Selig Perlman, and Phillip Taft.
In both cases, at least some of these people (e.g., Watkins, Perlman)
were not economists as defined above, although their doctoral degrees
were in economics. Most schools of business in the pre-World War II
period considered personnel management and other business-related sub-
jects to be "applied economics" and included them under the curricular
umbrella for the doctoral degree program in economics (Gordon and
Howell1959:400-402). 1° Furthermore, labor economics during this pe-
riod was construed broadly to encompass nearly all subjects pertinent
to the employment and utilization of labor, including personnel man-
agement and trade union history, which today would be considered the
province of other fields of study (McNulty 1980: 156-59). Thus, even
though a significant number of the early writers in industrial relations
were "economists," this does not mean that economics, at least as the
discipline is conceived today, was the principal intellectual wellspring
of the field.
Another potential source of confusion concerning the roots of in-
dustrial relations involves the labor problems courses offered during the
period. The labor problems course was the closest equivalent to an IR
theory course in that it focused squarely on the causes and resolutions
of labor problems. It was also in the labor problems texts where the
most frequent mention of the term industrial relations was found. Because
these courses were nearly always taught by economists, particularly in-
stitutional economists, it is not surprising that scholars concluded that
institutional economics was the major intellectual wellspring of indus-
trial relations. Such an inference, however, founders on the fact that
55
Industrial Relations in the Interwar Years
nearly every labor problems text featured both the PM and the ILE
perspectives on labor problems (the employers', workers', and com-
munity's solutions to labor problems) and provided extensive coverage
of personnel management and employee representation plans. These
subjects, it will 'be recalled, were the mainstays of the PM approach to
improved industrial relations; were based heavily on knowledge derived
from the fields of engineering, administrative science, and psychology;
and had been written about principally by persons with a management
background. Thus, on the one hand, the labor problems texts undeniably
had a heavy institutional flavor, as one would expect given the dis-
ciplinary background of the authors, but, on the other, these texts al-
so made a concerted attempt to present both the ILE and the PM
perspective.
Yet another source of the confusion pertains to the undeveloped
nature of institutional economics. As envisioned by Commons, insti-
tutional economics was to be a new approach to the study of the fun-
damental questions of economics-the allocation of resources and
determination of output, prices, and the distribution of income. T award
that end, he attempted to construct a theoretical model based on con-
cepts such as a volitional theory of value, transactions, reasonable value,
and property rights, with heavy emphasis on the role of law and judicial
opinion {Commons 1924, 1934b, 1950). Unfortunately, his foray into
theory was largely unsuccessful; neither his fellow economists nor his
students could understand what he was driving at, .and his conception
of economics was so expansive that his writings had more in common
with law and sociology than with economics per se. Given the failure
of Commons and his students to develop institutional theory, institu-
tional labor economists fell back on a largely historical, descriptive,
multidisciplinary analysis of labor problems and institutional solutions
to those problems. 11 This approach was largely coterminous with the
subject of industrial relations, however, a fact that made the two subjects
seem as if they were one and the same. In practice, they were largely
one and the same, but only because the institutionalists failed to develop
theory.
Another probable reason for the confusion is that contemporary
chroniclers of industrial relations tend to ignore the extensive literature
of the 1920s-30s authored by nonacademics, most of whom were busi-
56
Industrial Relations in the Interwar Years
57
Industrial Relations in the Interwar Years
58
4
THE INSTITUTIONALIZATION OF
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS
59
Institutionalization of Industrial Relations
60
Institutionalization of Industrial Relations
61
Institutionalization of Industrial Relations
62
Institutionalization of Industrial Relations
particularly with regard to wages, which had badly lagged behind both
prices and corporate profits. The prospect, therefore, was for renewed
labor-management conflict at the end of the war on a scale as large or
larger than when the war began five years earlier. (This prospect became
a reality in 1946 when the economy experienced a strike wave of un-
precedented proportions.)
From the perspective of 1945, then, employer-employee relations,
and labor violence and unrest in particular, was suddenly the number-
one domestic issue confronting the nation. just as the labor conflict _-
engendered by World War I precipitated the birth of the field, the labor
conflict of the Depression and World War II years led to the emergence
of industrial relations as a widely recognized, fully institutionalized ac-
ademic field of study. 3 Industrial relations had come of age.
63
Institutionalization of Industrial Relations
a doctoral degree} and numerous extension courses off campus for both
union and management groups, and conducted extensive research on
all aspects of industrial relations. Graduate students could choose a major
or minor field of concentration in collective bargaining, mediation, and
arbitration; human relations in industry; industrial and labor legislation
and social security; labor market economics and analysis; labor history,
organization, and management; personnel management; or industrial
education.
Most other universities followed the Cornell model in that they
housed their industrial relations programs in a free-standing adminis-
trative unit, as opposed to a subunit of an existing department (e.g.,
economics) such as had been done at Princeton and MIT. The most
common designations given to these units were school, institute, and
center.
Some of the units were in business schools, but this was not the
preferred approach. Rather, the more common arrangement (Rezler
1968a) was to house the program in a nonbusiness division of the uni-
versity, such as a graduate school or a college of arts and sciences
or social sciences; to make the unit an autonomous division of the
university; or to divide administrative control of the unit among several
departments or schools, emphasizing interdisciplinary control and
coordination.
Placing the IR unit outside the business school facilitated the re-
cruitment of a multidisciplinary faculty from all the major divisions of
the university, ensured that the unit's intellectual and ideological neu-
trality on labor-management issues was not compromised, and allayed
fears among organized labor that the units would become tools of the
business community. An additional consideration at some universities
was that the business school was hostile to the concept of a joint labor-
management program. 6
Placing the units outside the business school also created "turf' prob-
lems, however, since both the IR units and the business schools claimed
jurisdiction over personnel and human relations subjects. Some uni-
versities (e.g., Illinois) resolved the conflict by permitting both theIR
unit and the business school to hire faculty and teach courses in these
areas. 7 This arrangement was satisfactory for the IR units because it
allowed them to offer management-related subjects. In addition, the
64
Institutionalization of Industrial Relations
65
Institutionalization of Industrial Relations
the costs and maintained their labor education activities, while others
phased out their extension work or transferred extension activities to a
separate administrative unit (e.g., a labor studies department).
A significant degree of standardization existed among IR units with
respect to their curricula. Martin Estey (1960), who conducted a survey
of IR curricula, found, for example, that four courses comprised the
"core" of most IR programs: personnel management, labor economics,
labor law, and collective bargaining. Among the other courses that were
frequently taught were human relations in industry, trade unionism and
union government, industrial sociology, industrial psychology, social
security, and comparative labor movements (also see Schnelle and Fox
1951). These courses corresponded closely to the major areas of con-
centration in Cornell's program. Other IR programs could not match
the breadth and depth of the courses offered by Cornell, but they never-
theless offered concentrations in a number of the same areas. The Illinois
program, for example, had four areas of concentration: labor economics
(including collective bargaining, labor legislation, mediation and arbi-
tration, and social security), human relations in industry, labor union
organization and administration, and personnel management.
Finally, the names attached to the units varied in some interesting
ways. Most included the term industrial relations, either alone or in
combination with some other term. Examples of the former include the
Institute of Industrial Relations at Berkeley and the Industrial Relations
Center at Minnesota; examples of the latter include the School of In-
dustrial and Labor Relations at Cornell and its near equivalent, the
Institute of Labor and Industrial Relations at Illinois; and the Industrial
Relations Research Institute at Wisconsin. Several programs did not use
industrial relations in their titles: the Labor and Management Center
(Yale), the Institute of Management and Labor Relations (Rutgers),
and the Institute of Labor Relations and Social Security (New York).
Several aspects of these new IR programs are important. First, the
goal of the new units was to promote both problem-solving and science-
building, but problem-solving was the first priority. The legislation that
established the School of Industrial and Labor Relations at Cornell, for
example, stated that the unit's mission was "to improve industrial and
labor conditions in the State through the conduct of research and dis-
semination of information in all aspects of industrial, labor, and pub-
66
Institutionalization of Industrial Relations
67
Institutionalization of Industrial Relations
68
Institutionalization of Industrial Relations
IR units took the existence of unions and the necessity (if not the virtue}
of collective bargaining as "givens" and thus saw their mission as pro~
mating dialogue and accommodation between labor and management.
Many employers remained steadfastly anti~union, however, and thus
saw the attempt at dialogue as a thinly disguised attempt to promote
collective bargaining.
Other considerations also came into play. The creation of the IR
units increased substantially the amount of teaching, research, and uni~
versity resources devoted to the organized labor movement, a movement
many employers saw as threatening their economic position and power.
Many employers also believed that the faculty of the IR units were
ideologically pro~union and thus were inculcating students with biased,
antibusiness viewpoints. They also charged that the units were agents
of socialism and communism, given their alleged bias in favor of col~
lectivist solutions to labor problems. As a result of all of these pressures,
many unit directors had to beat back attempts by employers and their
allies in the university system to eliminate the programs. 16 The IR units
also found that many employers were very reluctant to participate in
classes or conferences or to be on advisory boards if representatives of
organized labor were also participating.
While the primary threat to the new IR units came from the employer
side, they did not escape attack and criticism from labor. Many officials
of organized labor were suspicious of the programs since universities in
the past had been largely antagonistic to the aims and methods of the
labor movement. Labor leaders were also skeptical about becoming in~
valved with intellectuals, who often promoted goals or methods that
were not grounded in the pragmatic experience of trade unionism (Ware
1946). For these reasons, some center directors had to fend off attempts
by trade union leaders to purge the programs of management courses
and management representatives, which, if successful, would have
turned the units into labor education programs. The universities resisted
these lobbying efforts, as well as those of management, thus preserving
at least a modicum of balance in both IR research and teaching.
69
Institutionalization of Industrial Relations
70
Institutionalization of Industrial Relations
71
Institutionalization of Industrial Relations
The Review had a significant influence on the field in that its editorial
policy (choice of paper topics, authors, and books to be reviewed) helped
define both the intellectual boundaries and center of gravity of industrial
relations. Like the IRRA, the Review clearly recognized that industrial
relations was multidisciplinary and addressed subject areas in both the
PM school (personnel management, human relations} and the ILE
school (labor-management relations, protective labor legislation}. This
fact was most clearly illustrated by the broad and relatively well-balanced
selection of books chosen for inclusion in the book review section.
The same balance was not achieved in the articles, however. Like
the papers in the proceedings of the IRRA, the great majority of the
papers published in the Review were written by economists and dealt
with trade unions, the process and outcome of collective bargaining,
labor legislation, and labor market issues. Of the twenty-six articles
published in the first four issues of the journal, for example, twenty dealt
directly with unions, collective bargaining, and labor legislation, while
only two pertained to personnel management or human relations topics
in nonunion workplaces.
To a significant degree the preponderance of ILE-related research was
a reflection of both the nature of the research being done at the time
and the choices authors made regarding the journals to which they
submitted articles, rather than any explicit editorial policy of the journal
itself. Labor unions and collective bargaining were, after all, the research
topics in the late 1940s, labor economists had historically represented
the largest disciplinary contingent in IR, and relatively little academic
research of intellectual substance was being done in personnel manage-
ment at that time. Likewise, most IR scholars in those PM-related fields
where significant research was taking place (e. g., human relations, in-
dustrial sociology, management, industrial psychology) submitted arti-
cles to journals in those fields rather than to the Review.
But the ILE tilt of the journal also reflected to some degree the
underlying value system of the School of Industrial and Labor Relations
and the editorial board of the journal. In the foreword to the first issue
of the Review, for example, Edmund Day (president of Cornell Uni-
versity} wrote, "The establishment of the Industrial and Labor Relations
Review is a logical extension of the function which higher education is
assuming in the area of labor-management relations." The use of the
term labor-management relations was important in that it immediately
72
Institutionalization of Industrial Relations
73
5
THE GoLDEN AGE OF
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS
75
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
76
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
em Electric Company from 1924 through 1932 (Miller and Form 1964;
Whyte 1965, 1987).
The Hawthorne experiments started as a straightforward exercise in
scientific management (Greenwood and Wrege 1986; Wren 1987). The
issue investigated was the impact of different levels of illumination on
worker productivity. The results, however, were quite surprising: the
rate of output of the workers in both the control group and the test
group increased regardless of the level of lighting.
In 192 7, the illumination tests at Hawthorne were replaced by a set
of experiments involving five relay assemblers. Initially, to establish a
baseline for comparison, the work performance of the assemblers was
monitored for two weeks in their regular department. They were then
isolated in a separate room with their own supervisors and observers.
Various changes in the work environment were introduced, such as
differences in the incentive pay system, the number of lunch breaks,
and the work hours. After a year of experimentation, all the work
conditions were returned to their original level. The results that emerged
baffled the company officials: the assemblers' productivity had increased
steadily over the year, and at the end of the experiments it was con-
siderably higher than at the beginning.
The assistant plant manager, George Pennock, presented these anom-
alous results to several faculty members at MIT and Harvard for their
analysis. Three of these people were Elton Mayo, T. North Whitehead,
and Fritz Roethlisberger, all of whom were in the industrial research
department at Harvard. (Two other faculty members of this department
also published significant work in human relations, George Homans and
Benjamin Selekman.) The professors found the results intriguing and
decided to conduct further investigations. One line of activity they
pursued was a large-scale interviewing program in which employees were
encouraged to tell a counselor what was on their minds. A second line
of investigation was the observance of the interpersonal and social dy-
namics of workers in a small-group setting. In this experiment, a small
group of bank wiring workers was isolated in a separate room and their
behaviors and interrelationships recorded. Unlike in the relay assembly
experiment, the supervisors and observers did not interact and become
friendly with the workers. Although the output of the relay assemblers
had increased significantly over the course of the experiment, the same
did not occur with the bank wiring workers. In fact, these workers
77
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
78
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
79
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
80
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
81
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
82
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
is held by Elton Mayo .... Indeed, many believe that Mayo holds the
key to industrial peace"-and a claim in Time (1952:96) that Mayo was
"the father of industrial human relations." Finally, the first sentence in
a biography of Mayo (Trahair 1984:1) states, "George Elton Mayo pi-
oneered in the field of industrial human relations and for that work
deserves a place in business history."
Considerable evidence also indicates that human relations was com-
monly perceived to be a subfield of industrial relations by people in both
the PM and the ILE wings of the field. In a review article on individual
and group behavior in organizations, for example, Conrad D. Arensberg
(1951), a leading behavioral science researcher, discussed three com-
monly used names to describe this area of research-human relations,
industrial sociology, and industrial psychology-and rejected all three
as unduly narrow in perspective. He went on to state (p. 330), "The
best common description of the field, then, is the historical one: sci-
entific study of the sources of unrest in labor and management relations,
that is, the study of the problems of industrial relations" (emphasis added).
Looking at the subject from an ILE perspective, labor economist
Lloyd Reynolds (1948:285) stated: "The problems [of human relations
in industry] range over the whole field of labor and industrial relations .
. . . The phrase "human relations in industry" connotes not a separate
subject matter speciality, but a different point of view and method of
approach. In a later article, Reynolds (1955:2) amplified on this theme:
"The study of industrial relations needs to be conceived in very broad
terms. People concerned with curriculum construction are perhaps forced
to draw fine lines between 'industrial relations,' 'labor relations,' 'labor
economics,' 'human relations,' 'personnel management' and so on. This
fragmentation should not veil the fact that we are integrally involved
in all the phenomena surrounding the use of human effort in
production."
The IRRA's 1957 research volume, Research in Industrial Human Re-
lations (Arensberg et al.), provides additional evidence. The editors state
in the preface (p. vii) that "human relations in industry has become
both the label of a group of studies of people at work and the slogan of
a movement of thought and action in American industrial relations."
Finally, one of the branches of IR's intellectual family tree, shown
in figure 3-1, is the human relations movement (what Form and Miller
labeled the "Harvard Graduate School of Business"). 11
83
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
84
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
85
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
Three major events shaped this blend of perspectives. The first was
that these economists had received a heavier dose of economic theory
in their doctoral studies than had the earlier generation of institution,
alists. Much of this theory was imported from England, which up to
that time had produced far more able economic theorists than had the
United States. Doctoral students in economics, for example, were re,
quired to master Alfred Marshall's Principles of Economics (1920), a
pioneering text that developed the competitive model of demand and
supply in product and factor markets, albeit with numerous qualifications
to take into account institutional realities. (Calculus was used in foot,
notes and appendixes). Another required text for labor students of the
1930s was John R. Hicks's The Theory of Wages (1932). This book was
an exact antithesis to institutional works such as Blum's Labor Economics
(1925) in that Hicks applied neoclassical competitive theory thoroughly
and unflinchingly to the labor market. Hicks (particularly in chapter 1)
largely omitted the qualifications Marshall thought were important on
the grounds that they had little impact in the long run on the pattern
of wages and employment. Other important English contributions to
economic theory in the 1930s were Joan Robinson's The Economics of
Imperfect Competition ( 1933), which developed models of imperfect com,
petition, such as monopsony (one buyer of labor) and oligopsony (several
buyers of labor), and J. M. Keynes's The General Theory of Employment,
Interest, and Money (1936), which purported to show that the macro,
economy could become mired in an underemployment equilibrium.
The second event that significantly influenced these labor economists
was the Great Depression (Kerr 1988; Reynolds 1988). The Depression
seemed to provide overwhelming evidence that the market mechanism
did not work as effectively or as automatically as predicted by competitive
theory. According to competitive theory, wages and prices are supposed
to rise and fall to maintain an equilibrium between demand and supply.
The assumption is that if people remain unemployed for long, it is
through choice or laziness. For the new generation of labor economists,
the persistence of mass unemployment during the 1930s, and the large,
scale human suffering that accompanied it, were convincing evidence
that the cause of the unemployment problem was defects of the market,
not defects of the unemployed.
Another development of the Depression years that influenced their
perspective was the surge in union membership and the spread of in,
86
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
87
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
88
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
89
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
90
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
in unions and labor,management relations after the war, this placed the
labor economists in the position to become preeminent in the field during
its golden age, in the late 1940s and 1950s.
VOLUME
Industrial relations was without doubt one of the boom areas of re,
search in the social and behavioral sciences in the 1950s. Whereas a
computer search for the period 1930-39 turned up only fifteen published
works with industrial relations in the title, a similar search for the years
1950-59 produced more than sixty. And if one defines industrial rela,
tions to include any subject related to the employer,employee relation,
ship, the number of entries is huge. Adding articles published in
academic journals and proceedings only reinforces this conclusion, in
part because in the 1950s periodicals such as the ILR Review and the
IRRA proceedings were devoted exclusively to IR research, whereas in
the 1930s no such publications existed.
BREADTH
Equally impressive is the disciplinary breadth of the IR research of
the 1950s. Economics was heavily represented, of course. The doyens
were Sumner Slichter and Edwin Witte. Among the younger generation
of economists, several economic theorists (e.g., Paul Samuelson, Milton
Friedman, Fritz Machlup, Edward Chamberlain) made contact with the
field, as well as a host of labor economists. The labor economists were
themselves a heterodox group, represented on one end by people who
were more management or union specialists than economists per se (e.g.,
George Strauss, Frederick Harbison, Milton Derber, George Taylor,
James Healy, Dale Yoder), on the other end by people who were applied
price theorists and statisticians (H. Gregg Lewis, Martin Bronfenbren,
ner, Melvin Reder, Gary Becker). In the middle was a large group (John
Dunlop, Clark Kerr, Richard Lester, Lloyd Reynolds, Arthur Ross,
91
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
92
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
INTERDISCIPLINARY CHARACTER
The primary intellectual justification for the creation of the IR schools
and institutes, as noted previously, was the belief that the study and
resolution of labor problems would be materially enhanced by a collab-
orative, integrative research design that would draw upon methods and
ideas from the various disciplines related to the employment relation-
ship. Using three different approaches, IR scholars in the 1950s made
considerable attempts to practice this precept.
The first approach was to conduct cross-disciplinary research; that is,
research performed by a person trained in one discipline on a subject
traditionally examined by scholars in a different discipline. Several econ-
omists, for example, examined aspects of management, such as the
impact of collective bargaining on the practice of management (Cham-
berlain 1948; Slichter, Healy, and Livemash 1960) and specific per-
sonnel problems such as job evaluation (Kerr and Fisher 1950) and
recruitment and hiring methods (Lester 1954). Among the most notable
efforts in this regard were Herbert Simon's book Administrative Behavior
(1947) and E. Wight Bakke's Bonds of Organization (1950) and The
Fusion Process (1953). Several noneconomists also crossed disciplinary
lines. Examples include William Foote Whyte's study of incentive wage
systems and employee productivity (1955), Lloyd Fisher's study of the
harvest labor market (1953), and articles by Robert Dubin (1949) and
Benjamin Selekman and Sylvia Selekman (1950) on the impact of col-
lective bargaining on productivity.
The second approach was to select a particular IR topic and then
commission a series of research articles on it by scholars from a wide
range of disciplines, with the intent of encouraging a melding of ideas
and perspectives. One example is the book Industrial Conflict (1954),
edited by Arthur Kornhauser (psychology), Robert Dubin (sociology),
and Arthur Ross (economics). It contained contributions from more
than thirty other scholars, including many of the most prominent par-
ticipants in industrial relations from economics, sociology, psychology,
history, and law. Another noteworthy example is the volume Causes of
Industrial Peace (Golden and Parker 1955), a series of case studies of
collective bargaining relationships sponsored by the National Planning
93
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
94
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
95
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
1949; Dunlop 1950; Barkin 1950; Kerr and Fisher 1957; Roethlisberger
1977). Among the more important reasons were that human relations
research neglected the influence on IR outcomes of external economic,
social, political, and technological conditions and overemphasized the
influence of internal social and psychological factors; not only were the
independent variables used in human relations research (e.g., senti-
ments, patterns of interaction, leadership styles) likely to have a small
quantitative effect on the dependent variable, but many were not in-
dependent in a causal sense and represented dependent or intervening
variables; the model of man assumed in human relations research was
fundamentally flawed because it overemphasized the role of nonlogical
sentiments, feelings of anomie, and needs for stability and group be-
longingness; the development of a competitive, individualistic society
did not threaten social and economic disorganization but rather pro-
moted political freedom and economic growth; human relations under-
played conflicts of interest between workers and managers and promoted
the manipulation of workers to achieve management's profit objectives;
and human relations was anti-union in spirit and practice.
Several proponents of human relations rebutted the critics and pointed
out the weaknesses of the economists' approach to the study of industrial
relations (see Arensberg 1951; Whyte 1950, 1959; Arensberg and Too-
tell 1957). Among their major points were that human relations did
not ignore variations in external environmental conditions but, rather,
took this variation as a "given" and then proceeded to analyze how the
internal social system of the plant adjusted; the internal psychological
and social factors stressed in human relations research had a far larger
impact on IR outcomes than the critics admitted, in part because the
technological and economic system allowed managers significant dis-
cretion in how they organized work and managed the work force; econ-
omists' theories of industrial relations treated unions and firms as
organizational "black boxes" and hence were unable to specify the link
by which variations in external conditions give rise to specific IR out-
comes; the economists' model of rational, individualistic behavior was
seriously in error because it neglected the social dimension of work and
the role played by custom, ritual, symbols, group norms, and sanctions;
much of the criticism of human relations was fundamentally misdirected
because it was aimed at specific hypotheses or positions staked out by
Mayo and his close followers and that many human relationists later
96
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
abandoned or never subscribed to in the first place; and while the aim
of human relations was to promote increased employee job satisfaction
and cooperation between workers and managers, this did not mean that
human relations was inherently anti-union, for its proponents recognized·
that unions protected employees' vital interests and helped promote a
stable social order in the plant.
The debate over human relations had both positive and negative
repercussions for the field of industrial relations. On the positive side,
the debate encouraged an interchange of ideas between researchers in
the various disciplines related to industrial relations, thus helping to
break down the walls that separated the economists from the sociologists,
the sociologists from the psychologists, the psychologists from the his-
torians, and so on. It also suggested the outlines for a theoretical com-
promise or modus vivendi between the "externalists" of the ILE school
and the "internalists" of the PM school.
The nature of this compromise was most clearly spelled out by Charles
Myers (1955:46) in a chapter of the book Causes of Industrial Peace in
which he attempted to summarize and synthesize the conclusions of
several authors such as Clark Kerr, John Dunlop, and Douglas McGregor:
97
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
98
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
99
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
100
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
101
Golden Age of Industrial Relations
102
6
THE HoLLOWING OuT OF
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS
103
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
of the first half of this century were mathematics and physics; beyond
reasonable doubt industrial relations is the most important discipline of
the second half."
Heneman based his claim on the fact that the field of industrial
relations covered all aspects of the world of work and that developments
and trends in the world of work had become central, in his view, to
the nation's social and economic progress. But, ironically, even as Hene-
man was writing these words, the core of the field was being seriously
eroded, including its hitherto undisputed claim of intellectual sover-
eignty over the subject of work. In particular, what occurred between
1960 and 1979 was a hollowing out of the field as it metamorphosed
from a broad coalition of behavioral and nonbehavioral disciplines de-
voted to the study of all aspects of the world of work to a much narrower
field devoted to the study of unions, collective bargaining, and the
employment problems of special groups (e. g., minorities, the aged, the
poor) with a core group of committed participants made up mainly of
a small and dwindling number of institutional labor economists.
If unionism and collective bargaining had continued to grow in the
1960s and 1970s as they had in the previous two decades, this narrowing
of focus might have been both intellectually justified and organizationally
viable. As it was, the nonunion sector of the economy became not only
the major source of new gains in employment but also the major source
of new innovations in employment relations practices (Foulkes 1980;
Kochan, Katz, and McKersie 1986). The result was that the preoccu-
pation of industrial relations with unionism and collective bargaining
led to its gradual decline as a field of study, a condition partially hidden
from view through the 1970s but one that became all too obvious in
the 1980s.
This chapter explores both the symptoms and the causes of the hol-
lowing out of industrial relations. Specifically, it examines the debate
over the theoretical and disciplinary status of the field in the 1960s; the
narrowing of industrial relations from a broad "all aspects of employment
relations" definition to a narrow "labor-management" definition; the
decision of the PM school to end its association with industrial relations
and establish itself as a separate, rival field of study; and the growing
estrangement between the fields of labor economics and industrial re-
lations. I then discuss four reasons for the hollowing out: the increased
emphasis among academics on science-building and the concomitant
104
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
I approach my task this morning with some reluctance for I feel that
our discussion is simply a part of a long playing record that has been
playing the same old melody and the same old lyrics for many years.
If you examine the annual proceedings of almost any industrial relations
or personnel association you will find periodic public confessionals de,
crying the second class status of industrial relations. The theme is always
the same-the lack of rigorous theoretical underpinnings, the cleavage
between theory and practice, the lack of intellectual cohesion and
respectability, whether industrial relations should be a separate disci,
pline in its own right, and whether the subject should be oriented to
traditional disciplines or be interdisciplinary in nature.
As Woods suggested, the debate over theory and methods during this
period revolved around several related and interconnected themes:
whether IR was best conceptualized as an art or a science; whether IR
had a theoretical framework and, if it did not, whether such was possible;
whether IR was a bona fide academic discipline and, if it was not,
whether it was practical and desirable for it to become one; and, finally,
among those scholars who believed IR was not a self,contained disci,
pline, whether teaching and research in the field should be organized
on a loosely structured multidisciplinary or closely integrated interdis,
ciplinary basis. As shall become clear, IR scholars were in effect arguing
over the merits of two very different conceptualizations of the field.
105
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
ART OR SCIENCE?
The debate over whether IR was best conceptualized as an art or a
science originated in the multiple objectives of the field's founders: the
reform of workplace organization and practice, the promulgation of new
public policies, and the advancement of knowledge. Before the 1950s,
IR was heavily oriented toward the first two goals, which had given the
field a distinct applied, problem-solving character. This character was
accentuated by the heavy intellectual influence of institutionalism,
which favored an inductive, case study, historical approach to research
over more formalized, deductively derived theories and frameworks.
The proponents of IR as an art or exercise in problem-solving largely
came from the reform, public policy, institutional perspective. Thus, J.
Douglas Brown, an early advocate of this position, stated in his IRRA
presidential address (1952:6}:
106
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
107
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
108
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
109
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
II 0
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
IMPLICATIONS
It is noteworthy that this debate over the appropriate conceptuali,
zation of industrial relations did not occur until the 1960s, a full forty
years after its founding as an academic field of study. Given that a broad
111
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
I I2
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
11 3
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
I I4
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
I I5
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
116
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
11 7
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
in the late 1970s provides further evidence of the gap between the field's
stated ideals and actual practice. As noted earlier, the IRRA was founded
with the express purpose of fostering research on all aspects of the
employment relationship, including union and nonunion work situa~
tions. It is understandable that in the first decade of the organization's
existence a large number of sessions would have been devoted to topics
pertaining to the union sector, given the meteoric rise of organized labor
in the previous two decades and the host of important problems and
issues in labor~management relations that demanded attention. By the
late 1970s, however, the share of the organized work force had dropped
sharply and many of the innovations in employment practices were
originating in the nonunion sector. Did the IRRA's selection of session
topics reflect this shift? An examination of the proceedings of the winter
IRRA meetings for the years 1975-79 reveals the answer is clearly no.
They contained twenty~five sessions related to some aspect of union~
management relations and only five pertaining to some aspect of non~
union work situations.
118
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
member of the field. In part, this trend reflected natural causes, such
as death and retirement; however, it also reflected a dwindling of par-
ticipation per se, particularly in the form of articles published in the
major IR journals and involvement in IRRA activities. The falloff in
involvement in industrial relations was most marked among sociologists,
which was doubly surprising given the large number of sociologists who
were active in the field in the early 1950s and the emphasis in both
sociology and industrial relations on collective action. 10
Concomitantly, only a small number of the newer generation of be-
havioral science and management scholars became active in industrial
relations. Of those who did, most wrote on collective bargaining-related
topics. The most prominent example of research of this genre was Rich-
ard Walton and Robert McKersie's A Behavioral Theory of Labor Nego-
tiations (1965). Other examples include the papers (some by British
authors, some by American) in Industrial Relations: A Social Psychological
Approach (Stephenson and Brotherton 1979); several articles on strike
trends by sociologists (Britt and Galle 1974; Snyder 1977); and a smat-
tering of articles on the determinants of union joining (e.g., Schriesheim
1978). 11
The number of younger PM-oriented scholars who were active in
industrial relations in the 1960s and 1970s and who did non-collective
bargaining research was relatively small. Included in this group were
Edward Lawler III, Thomas Mahoney, Donald Schwab, jeffrey Pfeffer,
Lyman Porter, and George Milkovitch, all of whom occasionally pub-
lished in the two major IR journals and participated in IRRA meetings
(generally on an invited basis). None, however, was considered a big
name in IR research per se, although several had national name rec-
ognition in their home fields. Perhaps more revealing is the list of PM-
oriented people who were widely recognized for their research on aspects
of the employment relationship and yet were not associated with in-
dustrial relations. Examples include Richard Steers, David McClelland,
Warren Bennis, Stanley Seashore, Jay Lorsch, Paul Lawrence, Victor
Vroom, Daniel Katz, and Fred Fiedler.
Of the many reasons that younger scholars of the PM school decided
not to become involved in industrial relations, one of the most significant
was the birth of the field of organizational behavior and its applied
offshoot, human resource management. Before the mid-1950s, the
management-oriented academics of the PM school may have been dis-
119
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
120
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
12 1
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
122
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
123
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
124
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
SCIENCE~ BUILDING
125
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
12 6
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
127
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
LACK OF IR THEORY
Industrial relations is recognized as a field of study precisely because
it focuses on an activity-the employment relationship-that is not the
128
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
129
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
130
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
CURRENT EVENTS
The hollowing out of industrial relations that occurred after 1960 was
further abetted by the tum of current events.
Part of the perceptible malaise that seemed to descend on the field
in the early 1960s was no doubt due to the realization among IR scholars
that current events had shoved industrial relations off the center stage
of public concern. When the nation's attention was riveted on issues
of strikes and union power, as it was in the late 1940s and early 1950s,
students and researchers flocked to industrial relations, imparting to it
a sense of both importance and excitement. By the early 1960s, however,
labor-management relations had gone from being front-page news to
being back-page news as collective bargaining became institutionalized
and routinized and strikes and other attention-getting forms of conflict
dropped to the lowest levels since the early years of the Depression. As
the spotlight of public attention shifted to other economic and social
problems, IR academics inevitably felt some angst as they contemplated
declining student enrollments in graduate programs and a body of re-
search topics that was looking increasingly picked over and pedestrian.
As labor-management relations receded in newsworthiness and policy
concern, other labor-oriented issues took their place, including auto-
mation and structural unemployment, discrimination and civil rights,
job dissatisfaction and alienation among blue-collar workers, poverty,
and manpower training programs. All of these issues were labor problems
and thus fully in the intellectual domain of industrial relations. They
were also well suited to the field's multidisciplinary focus, involving as
they did a diverse range of economic, organizational, political, and social
influences.
Were industrial relations truly a problem-solving field, it would have
131
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
gone with the headlines {per the critics' charges) and made these topics
the new focal point of research. Efforts were made in this direction, but
in the final analysis they did not quite gel. It is certainly clear, on the
one hand, that IR academics gave these new labor problems considerable
attention in the 1960s and 1970s. For example, the IRRA devoted
several sessions at its annual winter meetings to these subjects and
published research volumes on adjustments to technological change
(Somers, Cushman, and Weinberg 1963), poverty {Levitan, Cohen,
and Lampman 1968), manpower training programs {Weber, Cassell,
and Ginsburg 1969), and civil rights (Hausman et al. 1977). On the
other hand, as the IR literature makes clear, collective bargaining re-
mained the heart and soul of industrial relations. The new issues were
the "swing" topics in IR in that they waxed and waned in research
importance based on their newsworthiness. Thus, automation was a
prominent subject in the early 1960s, while poverty had its day in the
late 1960s and early 1970s and then faded from sight. The one subject
that was always given attention at every IRRA meeting and in nearly
every issue of the IR journals, however, was collective bargaining.
The emergence of collective bargaining in the 1970s as the core
subject area of the field was unfortunately timed from the perspective
of current events. Just as industrial relations became increasingly asso-
ciated with the study of collective bargaining, the extent and influence
of collective bargaining noticeably began to decline. Union density, for
example, dropped from 32 percent of the work force in 1960 to 25
percent in 1980. Further, the bulk of the pioneering innovations in
employment relations practices no longer came from the union sector
but from a small but growing number of nonunion companies that were
successfully applying behavioral science-based human resource and or-
ganizational development methods {see Foulkes 1980; Beer and Spector
1984; Kochan, Katz, and McKersie 1986).
Thus, quite apart from the pressures of science-building and the lack
of IR theory, industrial relations would have lost some of its organiza-
tional vitality as a result of the gradual decline in size and influence of
the union sector of the economy. In the late 1970s, these developments
did not seem unduly worrisome, however, and there were even reasons
for modest optimism. Union representation and power, for example,
remained strong in such core areas of the economy as mining, construc-
tion, manufacturing, and transportation. Similarly, although union
132
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
VALUES
Industrial relations has always been animated by a distinct value
system and ideology that have given purpose and direction to the field
(Weber 1987a). The community of interests that draws people to a field
and that provides the focal point for research and teaching has been
weaker in industrial relations than in many other fields because of the
vastness and diversity of the subject matter and the lack of an integrating
theoretical framework. Industrial relations, therefore, has had to rely to
a greater degree than other fields on ideology and values to provide the
bonds of association and the sense of shared purpose. 19
The ideology of industrial relations in its early, pre-World War II
years was reformist and progressive. Both the institutional labor econ,
omists and the personnel practitioners who founded the field were drawn
to it by the conviction that the prevalent methods of organizing work
and managing the work force resulted in a deplorable amount of waste,
inefficiency, human suffering, and enmity between workers and em,
ployers. They also agreed that these evils could be, and should be,
eradicated through a combination of improved management methods,
the introduction of industrial democracy into the workplace, and the
enactment of protective labor legislation and social insurance programs.
This reform agenda was broad enough to accommodate a diversity of
viewpoints. Thus, the members of both the PM and the ILE schools
were committed to the idea that some system of shared governance was
an essential part of the reform of the employment relationship but they
133
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
134
Hollowing Out of Industrial Relations
states, "It is probably fair to say that the distinctive character of many
[IR] programs has been the study of trade unionism and collective bar,
gaining and the value system that supported these institutions."
These statements elicited neither debate nor controversy. They had
become, in effect, the reigning orthodoxy of industrial relations. The /
ideological character of industrial relations had gradually but perceptibly
changed from broad,based, middle,of,the road progressivism to a more
narrow, liberal, leaning, pro,union perspective. 23 This change in ideo,
logical orientation, in turn, contributed to the hollowing out of the field
in several ways. First, the ILE ideology effectively narrowed the com,
munity of interests that defined the field and thus made involvement
in industrial relations unattractive to many potential participants. Sec,
ond, it led to the falloff in student enrollments and scholarly interest
in industrial relations due to the decline in the union sector of the
economy and the concomitant growth of the nonunion sector and hu,
man resources as a field of study. Third, the ILE commitment to unions
and the New Deal system of industrial relations caused a growing number
of people to see the field as increasingly stale, reactive, and out,of,date.
Fourth and finally, the field became less interesting when members of
the PM school left and the debates over theory and policy, such as
occurred in the 1950s over human relations, largely ceased.
135
7
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS IN
DECLINE
I 37
Industrial Relations in Decline
138
Industrial Relations in Decline
139
Industrial Relations in Decline
140
Industrial Relations in Decline
Spector 1984; Walton and Lawrence 1985; Lawler 1986). These fields,
often lumped together under the label human resources, were the 1980s
version of the PM school that had originated in the 1920s. 3 Like their
forebears of the 1920s, HR scholars were unenthusiastic about labor
unions and most forms of government regulation of the workplace. As
they saw it, unions and government regulation were antithetical to
economic efficiency and job satisfaction because they institutionalized
adversarialism, stifled work effort and creativity, and promoted a rigid,
bureaucratized, and litigious system of workplace organization. Harking
back to the basic ideas developed by the personnel practitioners of the
1920s and the human relations academics of the 1930-50s, these scholars
sought to eliminate adversarialism and promote a "win-win" outcome.
The result, they thought, would be higher economic performance for
the organization and greater economic and psychological rewards for the
individual, achieved through the development and implementation of
a "commitment model" of workplace organization in which a congruence
of interests would be established between workers and the organization
through the use of a consensual leadership style, participative methods
of management, group production methods, pay-for-performance com-
pensation systems, and a formalized method of dispute resolution.
The political environment in the 1980s also turned hostile to the
New Deal IR system. The election of Ronald Reagan to the presidency
in 1980 precipitated a significant tum toward political conservatism with
respect to government labor policy. Reagan was an outspoken champion
of free markets and of minimalist role for government, a philosophical
belief that was at direct odds with the ILE policy program erected over
the previous half-century. Over the next decade the Reagan adminis-
tration, and to a lesser degree that of George Bush, implemented several
policy initiatives that struck at the heart of the New Deal system. The
organizing ability and bargaining power of labor unions, for example,
were heavily circumscribed by adverse changes in the interpretation of
law and precedent by the National Labor Relations Board (Weiler 1990).
Similarly, Reagan's decision to fire the air traffic controllers when they
went on strike in 1981 was widely interpreted as sending a signal to
private sector employers that it was alright to play hardball with unions.
Reagan and Bush also sought to eliminate or soften numerous workplace
regulations or protections, such as the minimum wage and occupational
safety and health laws. As a final insult, the Reagan administration
141
Industrial Relations in Decline
142
Industrial Relations in Decline
the New Deal IR system into crisis, the brunt of which was home by
the union movement. Between 1979 and 1989, unions lost almost 5
million members and saw the proportion of the organized work force
shrink from 23 to 17 percent. More ominously, by the late 1980s, unions
were able to win fewer than 100,000 new members through the NLRB
representation election process, while many times that number were
lost through decertifications, plant closing, layoffs, and striker replace,
ment (Freeman 1988). In effect, the organized labor movement was
slowly being bled to death and its dwindling band of intellectual and
political supporters were powerless to reverse the process. Not since the
1920s had the prospects for organized labor looked so bleak (Dubofsky
1985). Meanwhile, the American economy generated more than 19
million new jobs over the decade, almost all in nonunion firms. The
message was clear: the New Deal IR system, and the collective bargaining
process at its core, was rapidly shrinking in size and importance, while
the nonunion sector of the economy was increasingly becoming the
dynamic source of both new jobs and new ideas. Not unexpectedly,
these trends reverberated strongly through academia, with doleful con,
sequences for the field of industrial relations.
143
Industrial Relations in Decline
144
Industrial Relations in Decline
The impact of this shift in demand toward HRM and OB courses and
majors varied across programs and universities. The top-tier IR programs
experienced the least disruption of their basic structures and identities.
Several circumstances worked in their favor. First, these programs al-
ready offered concentrations and extensive coursework in HR, so it was
relatively simple (internal politics aside) to augment the HRend of the
curriculum and faculty. Second, they already had excellent reputations
and thus employers continued to seek out their graduates despite the
negative stigma of the IR label, and students continued to apply to these
programs given their good record of job placement. Third, nearly all of
the top-tier IR programs were in states with a relatively high level of
union density, providing both greater job opportunities for students with
an IR degree and greater political clout from organized labor to protect
funding for the programs.
Programs that were smaller, less well known, or located in states with
low union densities often had to make bigger adjustments. One common
practice was to drop the IR label from the name of the program, in
favor of some HR-related alternative, such as Personnel and Employment
Relations (Georgia State) or Human Resources Institute (Alabama). 7
Other programs kept the IR label but added an HR-related term. Loyola
University (Chicago), for example, changed the name of its institute
from Industrial Relations to Human Resources and Industrial Relations.
In either case, the basic multidisciplinary structure of the program was
preserved, but at the cost of abandoning the original "all aspects of
employment relations" meaning of the IR label.
Still other programs were forced to make more wrenching adjustments.
The shift in student demand toward HR subjects, the decline of inter-
disciplinary (or even multidisciplinary) research in employment rela-
tions, and the loss of the membership and political power of labor unions
all eroded the original justification for free-standing IR units. As cur-
ricula and student enrollments shifted toward HR subjects, these units
increasingly came to resemble the personnel and OB wing of a traditional
department of management (Begin 1987). Likewise, as faculty research
became ever more specialized in focus because of the continued pressures
of science-building, faculty interest and participation in cross-
disciplinary activities waned and universities began to examine whether
the research payoff of an interdisciplinary unit was worth the admin-
istrative complexities and costs.
145
Industrial Relations in Decline
Finally, the sharp drop in the size of the union sector and in the
number of job opportunities in labor~management relations called into
question both the need for and the viability of IR programs, while the
erosion of organized labor's political power made it far easier for uni~
versity administrators to consider the once unthinkable-shuttering or
significantly restructuring the programs.
The result was that free~standing IR units were merged or absorbed
into business programs or departments. The experience of theIR unit
at Purdue University is typical.
In 1957, an interdisciplinary body offaculty from across the Purdue
campus was organized to administer M.S. and Ph.D. programs in in~
dustrial relations. According to James Dworkin ( 1988:462-63), the pro~
gram originally had a heavy labor relations orientation, although some
coursework in personnel management was offered. Over the years several
changes were made to the program. In 1962, it was transferred to the
business school. Then, in 1967, the interdisciplinary Ph.D. program
was eliminated because of a lack of participation by faculty. Next, the
program was restructured so that more general business courses were
required (partly in response to accreditation pressures). Concurrently,
the number of traditional IR courses offered was reduced. Finally, in
1986, the title of the M.S. program was changed from industrial relations
to human resources management. Currently, this program, as well as
the Ph.D. program in organizational behavior and human resources
management, is taught by faculty from the business school's Department
of Organizational Behavior and Human Resources Management. Stu~
dents in the M.S. program are required to take sixteen courses, of which
five are OB and HRM courses, four are general management courses,
four are research methods courses, one is a labor economics course, one
is a labor law course, and one is a collective bargaining course.
The end result is that industrial relations has disappeared from the
name of the program at Purdue and the program has been relocated to
the business school and has a substantial management orientation. The
proportion of coursework devoted to the ILE perspective on industrial
relations, and to union~related topics in particular, has also been reduced
significantly. The program continues to include coursework from both
economics and the behavioral sciences, but the proportion of work in
the behavioral sciences has been expanded significantly while the rel~
ative contribution of economics has been reduced (labor economics is
146
Industrial Relations in Decline
now only one course out of sixteen). Finally, the multidisciplinary char-
acter of the curriculum and faculty has also been significantly reduced.
During the 1980s the structure and curriculum of a number of other
IR programs were changed in much the same direction as at Purdue. 8
Whether these changes are to be welcomed or lamented is, in large part,
a matter of personal opinion. Advocates of the ILE school generally
regard these developments as a quasi disaster in that they threaten the
survival of the IR label, the interdisciplinary approach to teaching and
research, and the intellectual and ideological emphasis on the adversarial
relationship, collective bargaining, and accommodated conflict. Most
advocates of the PM (HR) school, however, welcome these changes as
a long overdue shift from an outdated 1930s-era approach to the subject
of employer-employee relations to a modem, progressive approach that
is consistent with both the revolution in behavioral science research
and the economic realities of the marketplace. Whatever one's position,
clearly academic IR programs in the United States are undergoing a
fundamental transformation that represents a renaissance for the PM
school and an eclipse of the ILE school.
The forces discussed above that so significantly affected IR programs
in the 1980s also affected the birth of new IR units. For all intents and
purposes, the creation of free-standing, degree-granting IR units with
multidisciplinary faculties came to a halt. To the best of my knowledge,
no such unit with industrial relations in its title was created in the 1980s. 9
The creation of IR degree programs and majors also slowed to a trickle.
Herman's surveys of IR and HR programs (1984) reveal that of the net
increase of forty-three master's degree programs between 1974 and 1984,
only eight included one or more of the terms industrial relations, labor
relations, labor studies, or employee relations in their titles, while the
remainder included one or more of the terms personnel, human resource
(or human relations), organization, or management. In some cases these
new programs were multidisciplinary in character, but more often they
were housed in a department of management or a graduate school of
business and provided a largely behavioral science, nonunion perspective
on employment relations.
Finally, even as the birth of new IR units was coming to a standstill,
a simultaneous increase in the "death" or downsizing of existing units
was occurring. Some universities, such as Columbia, Chicago, and Pace,
chose to eliminate their programs altogether. Other schools, such as
147
Industrial Relations in Decline
IR RESEARCH
The bright spot for industrial relations in the 1980s was research. By
most accounts (e. g., Strauss and Feuille 1981), IR research suffered
through a period of the doldrums in the 1960s and early 1970s and
reached an intellectual and creative nadir sometime in the middle of
the decade. As I perceive it, IR research then staged a modest rebound
that persisted through the 1980s.
The clearest case of a rebound is in IR-related research monographs.
The "big book" of the 1960s was Richard Walton and Robert McKersie's
A Behavioral Theory of Labor Negotiations (1965). It is not clear what
book would be selected for the 1970s, for although several are certainly
high-quality works of scholarship (e.g., Getman, Goldberg, and Herman
1976), none is recognized as an IR "classic."
In the 1980s, however, several monographs significantly influenced
industrial relations teaching and research and are likely to be cited by
IR scholars for many years to come. They are (in chronological order)
The Elements of Industrial Relations (1984), by Jack Barbash; What Do
Unions Do? (1984), by Richard Freeman and James Medoff; and The
Transformation of American Industrial Relations (1986), by Thomas Ko-
chan, Harry Katz, and Robert McKersie.
A common characteristic of these three books, and of IR research in
general during the 1980s, was the renewed interest in theory-building. 10
This must rank as one of the most heartening developments of the
decade. Before the 1980s, there was much decrying the lack of IR theory
but few attempts to remedy the deficiency. The most notable attempt
at theorizing was Dunlop's Industrial Relations Systems (1958). A second
effort worth mention was by Gerald Somers (1969). Somers argued that
the process of exchange is the common denominator that underlies all
behavior in the employment relationship and that the analysis of ex-
change can provide the integrating framework needed by the field. His
ideas never caught on, however.
After the appearance of Somers's work, the subject of theory was
148
Industrial Relations in Decline
rarely addressed in the United States for the next decade (but see Hills
1975). 11 As the field headed into the 1980s, however, theory-building
again moved to the fore, partly as a response, no doubt, to the field's
sagging intellectual fortunes. The first contribution in this regard was
Thomas Kochan's book Collective Bargaining and Industrial Relations
(1980). Although ostensibly written as a textbook, Kochan used it as
a vehicle to address larger issues, particularly the integration of view-
points and research findings from labor economics, industrial relations
(institutionalism), and the behavioral sciences. 12
Kochan's next effort, co-authored with Harry Katz and Robert
McKersie, was The Transformation of American Industrial Relations. The
book's major intellectual contribution is its development of a three-tier
strategic choice framework to analyze the evolution and interaction of
the union and nonunion sectors of the economy. This framework over-
laps with Dunlop's in that it emphasizes the importance of the external
economic and political structure in which the industrial relations system
is imbedded, but it also elaborates on the different levels of decision-
making in the system, the role of business strategy, and the interde-
pendency of the union and nonunion sectors. 13 As a result of these two
books, plus numerous other research contributions, Kochan came to be
widely regarded as the leading research figure of the younger generation
in industrial relations.
Another person who made significant contributions to IR research in
the 1980s is labor economist Richard Freeman. Freeman is an indefa-
tigable writer whose articles and books on various aspects of unions and
collective bargaining are often cited. Of these, the most important is
What Do Unions Do, co-authored with James Medoff. The book's major
conceptual contribution is the exit/voice model of trade unionism. The
basic idea is that unions, by providing workers with a formalized channel
for making grievances, complaints, and suggestions, can contribute to
increased economic efficiency through lower quit rates, higher produc-
tivity, and improved management practices. All of these factors are
often ignored or underestimated in the standard neoclassical "union as
a monopoly" analysis. 14 The book is also notable for its use of an im-
pressive array of data sets and advanced econometric methods to analyze
the impact of unions on a wide range of economic outcomes, such as
wages, fringe benefits, quit rates, productivity, and income inequality. 15
Jack Barbash, an institutional labor economist and emeritus professor
149
Industrial Relations in Decline
150
Industrial Relations in Decline
I5I
Industrial Relations in Decline
IRRA
The events of the 1980s significantly eroded the organizational vitality
of the Industrial Relations Research Association. Many of the underlying
causes originated in earlier years, as discussed in the previous chapter,
but their effect was intensified in the adverse climate of the 1980s.
On the surface, the health of the IRRA appeared relatively good.
The most explicit statement of this viewpoint is in the final report of
the IRRA's Comprehensive Review Committee (IRRA 1988a). The
committee was appointed in 1986 by the association's executive board
to take stock of and make recommendations concerning the organiza-
tion's structure, membership, finances, programs, and publishing activ-
ities. 18 The committee was codirected by Clark Kerr and John Dunlop,
two of the early presidents of the organization. The final report states
(pp. 2-3):
In at least four fundamental respects, the IRRA has proved to be a
viable and effective association: First, its membership has grown steadily
throughout the years .... Second, its finances are in sound and satis-
factory condition.... Third, IRRA has benefited greatly from a lean
and professionally sophisticated administration .... Fourth, IRRA has
indeed attracted into its membership (a) academics from a variety of
disciplines, and also (b) practitioners from the ranks of the unions,
management, government at all levels, and neutrals .... These findings
and developments lend support to the view that the IRRA's founding
objectives remain valid and that an Association designed to implement
these objectives retains relevance and vitality.
A critical review of the four areas mentioned above, as well as of
other indicators of organizational health, suggest a far less sanguine
assessment. Consider IRRA membership, for example.
As the report claimed, IRRA membership has grown steadily since
the organization's founding. Membership in the national IRRA increased
152
Industrial Relations in Decline
153
Industrial Relations in Decline
154
Industrial Relations in Decline
155
8
INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS IN THE
1990s AND BEYOND
157
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
IR AS A FIELD OF STUDY
The future of industrial relations as a field of study depends crucially
on how the intellectual boundaries of the field are defined and on what
the field is called. Two definitions of the field co,exist today. The first
is a broad, all,inclusive definition that equates the field with the study
of all aspects of the employment relationship. According to this defi,
nition, the intellectual domain of industrial relations includes both the
ILE and the PM schools and their principal subfields of study, labor
economics, labor history, labor law, organizational behavior and human
resource management, industrial and organizational psychology, and
industrial sociology. This is the original pre, 1960s definition of industrial
relations.
The second definition is more recent in origin and more narrow in
scope. According to this definition, the field is divided into two wings,
HR and IR, where HR is the modern,day equivalent of the PM school
and IR is the modern,day equivalent of the ILE school. Industrial re,
lations is thus defined as one particular approach to the study of labor
problems and employer,employee relations. This approach is based on
certain assumptions and values (e.g., the irreducible level of adversar,
ialism in the employment relationship; labor's inequality of bargaining
power; the necessity of independent employee representation; the im,
portance of accommodating rather than eliminating conflict; and the
efficacy of economic, social, and political pluralism) and on the value
of certain methods or policies for resolving or ameliorating labor prob,
lems, such as collective bargaining, protective labor legislation, social
insurance programs, macroeconomic full,employment policies, and
tripartite (management, union, government) policy formulation and
problem,solving at the national level. In practice, this definition tends
to equate the field with the study of trade unionism and collective
bargaining, although the intellectual boundaries are actually wider.
The label attached to the field will also influence its future. One
approach is to define the field generically in terms of its subject matter,
while the other is to define it in terms of a particular label. Thus, from
the perspective of the second approach, the field is "industrial relations"
only as long as the IR label is attached to it and loss of the label is
158
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
159
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
decline of the union sector and job opportunities therein, and the neg,
ative stigma carried by the IR label because of its association with
unionism, students will increasingly shun IR,labeled programs and
union,related courses, forcing first the weaker programs and then the
stronger ones to transform themselves into HR units. As the number
of IR courses and IR units shrink, so too will the number of graduates
of doctoral programs who are trained in industrial relations, leading to
a gradual withering of academic talent in the field and a concomitant
decline in IR research, journals, and professional associations. As long
as there are labor unions, there will be a field of industrial relations,
but it will become a niche field with a presence at only a few universities.
Somewhere between these two extremes lies the actual future of in,
dustrial relations. My guess is that, absent significant changes, the latter
scenario more closely represents the future than does the former. The
reasons are several.
First, industrial relations sacrificed its claim to intellectual sovereignty
over the employment relationship some thirty years ago and too much
has happened for the field to reassert its rights of ownership. The field
does not have the intellectual manpower, integrative theory, or flexi,
bility in its values to accomplish the task. For better or worse, therefore,
industrial relations will continue to be seen as one approach to the study
of employment problems-an approach currently identified with the ILE
policy program of support for collective bargaining and various forms of
government regulation of labor markets.
Second, given the ILE orientation of industrial relations, its future
depends critically on the course of employer,employee relations and, in
particular, on the fortunes of the organized labor movement. If union
membership and political power continue to decline and no major eco,
nomic or political upheavals disrupt the employment relationship, ac,
ademic and popular interest in industrial relations will slide further.
Alternatively, if the trade union movement becomes revitalized or the
nation's labor law is changed in a way that makes it substantially easier
for unions to win new members, or a new form of employee represen,
tation (e.g., works councils) becomes widely established, or some na,
tional crisis precipitates significant conflict and unrest in the workplace,
industrial relations will be well positioned to experience a renaissance.
Although either outcome is possible, the odds favor the former.
Third, the future of industrial relations also depends on its ability to
160
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
161
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
162
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
RESEARCH
The pattern of research in industrial relations in the 1990s, and the
associated strengths and weaknesses, will closely match those of the
1980s. Since the record for IR research in the 1980s was relatively good
by my reckoning, the outlook for the 1990s is also optimistic, albeit
modestly so.
I expect to see the publication of several influential, highly regarded
IR books and articles. The current crisis affecting the New Deal industrial
relations system, and the concomitant intellectual crisis afflicting in-
dustrial relations, open up a host of important research issues that schol-
ars are just beginning to investigate. In this respect the research
performance of the 1990s is likely to resemble that of the 1950s, in that
both periods followed a dramatic sea change in the level of union density.
Among the most important topics demanding attention are national
labor policy, particularly the continued appropriateness of the Wagner
Act; new forms of employee representation, such as works councils and
associational unionism; international dimensions of unionism, such as
divergent growth rates, organizational and legal structures, and economic
effects; innovations in union practices and contracts as unions attempt
to broaden their appeal to the unorganized and deal with the competitive
problems of unionized employers; and the impact of IR practices in the
workplace on economic competitiveness.
In addition to collective bargaining-related topics, fertile areas for
research exist on the causes of and solutions to the many serious eco·
nomic problems facing the American work force, including the height-
ened insecurity of employment, the stagnation in real income, the
163
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
164
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
165
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
166
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
IR AS A FIELD OF STUDY
The first requirement for a resuscitation of industrial relations is a
name change. Although the term industrial relations has a long and
honored history, in recent years it has acquired an overly narrow and
out-of-date meaning that is an increasing handicap for the field. The
most attractive replacement is employment relations. The virtues of this
term are that it continues to emphasize the field's emphasis on relations
between employers and employees but at the same time broadens the
focus of the field from the industrial sector of the economy to the totality
of employment relationships. 8
The second requirement is to broaden and reposition the boundaries
of the field and redefine its core subject matter. The intellectual domain
of present-day IR is largely the product of the historical development
of science-building and problem-solving in the ILE wing of the field. A
broadening and repositioning of the field requires, therefore, a funda-
mental reexamination of the subject matter included within both sci-
ence-building and problem-solving. It is the combination of topics and
167
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
168
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
169
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
170
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
industrial relations position itself? I believe the field is again best served
by an intermediate position.
My reading of the evidence is that economic and social conditions
both inside and outside the workplace have evolved in the post-World
War II period in ways that have seriously undercut the net contribution
of the New Deal industrial relations system to the achievement of the
three aforementioned goals. Unlike some of the critics, I do not believe
that this evolution has made the current IR system obsolete or that it
should be dismantled in favor of a deregulated, union-free environment.
The system does need a substantial overhaul, however. The case becomes
obvious when one examines the reasons advanced for the establishment
of the current system.
As described in chapter 2, the ILE view of the employment relation-
ship provided a number of rationales for the enactment of the Wagner
Act and other pieces of protective labor legislation in the 1930s. One
major pillar was the assumption that restrictions on labor mobility,
collusive practices by employers, and the frequent existence of substan-
tial involuntary unemployment tilt the plane of competition against
individual workers in a nonunion situation, leading to substandard
wages, working conditions, and treatment by management. Another
fundamental pillar of ILE support for trade unions and collective bar-
gaining was that they replace the autocratic master-servant relationship
in the workplace with a system of industrial democracy, thereby ensuring
due process and opportunities for employee involvement in both the
management of the enterprise and the determination of wages and work-
ing conditions.
Do these rationales make sense in the economic and social context
of the 1990s? The answer, I think, is a qualified yes; yes because at the
most elemental level the major ILE premises retain validity but with a
strong note of qualification because they require significant modification
and adaptation if they are to be relevant in today's economy and
workplace.
A prime example concerns one of the principal justifications for the
Wagner Act-labor's inequality of bargaining power. A good case can
be made that the labor market was not a level playing field for many
workers in the 1930s and that the development of industrial unions and
companywide and industrywide collective bargaining helped restore bal-
ance into the wage determination process (see Kaufman 1989a, 1991a).
171
Industrial Relations in the I 990s & Beyond
Over the last half-century, however, most of the causes of labor's dis-
advantageous position have been significantly reduced through full-
employment macroeconomic policies, labor's increased geographical mo-
bility, antidiscrimination legislation, and so on. Thus, in the 1930s,
union bargaining power could justifiably be regarded as a countervailing
force that tended to offset the market power of employers. In the 1990s,
however, fewer workers suffer from a disadvantage in bargaining power
and the extent of this disadvantage is likewise smaller. As a result, the
playing field is more level, thereby reducing the demand for collective
bargaining by unorganized workers and making it far more likely that
once a union is recognized its exercise of bargaining power will lead
over time to monopolistic wage premiums and attendant forms of re-
source misallocation. The implication, then, is that a set of public
policies that made sense in the 1930s may no longer be appropriate.
Similar considerations apply to the voice function of unions. One of
the strongest arguments for unions is that, by providing workers with
an independent form of representation (or voice), they not only ensure
greater workplace equity through the bargaining and grievance processes
but also lead to increased efficiency by leading to lower turnover rates,
higher productivity, and so on. Even granting the correctness of these
assertions (a strongly debated issue, particularly with regard to the latter
point), one must still wonder whether traditional collective bargaining
as practiced under the Wagner Act is as successful in achieving these
ends as it was several decades earlier. Evidence indicates, for example,
that unionized workers continue to value formalized grievance systems
but that the effectiveness of these systems is coming under increasing
scrutiny because of their high cost, significant time delays in resolving
disputes, and the residue of adversarialism left after a settlement is
reached (Dalton and T odor 1981).
Likewise, while research studies from forty years ago found that the
process of union voice had a positive impact on productivity and cor-
porate personnel practices (e.g., Stichter, Healy, and Livemash 1960),
the evidence from today is more mixed (Freeman and Medoff 1984;
Hirsch 1991). A particularly salient issue in judging the continued ef-
ficacy of collective bargaining is whether the adversarial principle on
which the system is built is still compatible with the attainment of
world-class standards in product quality and productivity. 15 The newest
generation of best-practice plants, for example, rely heavily on trust-
172
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
173
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
174
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
175
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
176
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
177
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
RESEARCH
IR research must also be repositioned if industrial relations is to survive
and prosper in the future. The first step is to widen the scope of the
research. The approach to be taken follows directly from the discussion
in the previous sections. Suggestions similar in spirit if not in detail
have also been made by Strauss (1990), Cappelli (1990), Cutcher-
Gershenfeld (1991), and Sherer (1991). As I conceive it, the aim of
IR research is to explain how conditions in the economic, legal, tech-
nological, social, and political environment external to unions and firms
affect the structure, practices, and policies of these organizations, and
the behavioral outcomes that emerge out of the employment relation-
ship. So conceived, industrial relations research encompasses a wide
variety of topics. Certainly among these is the traditional forte of in-
dustrial relations, trade unions and labor-management relations. Other
topics also qualify, however, even though by the conventional definition
of the field their relationship to the study of industrial relations is unclear.
Two examples illustrate the point.
A subject popularized by Kochan, Katz, and McKersie (1986), for ex-
ample, is the relationship between business strategy and corporate capital
investment decisions and human resource practices. This subject is
squarely within the domain of IR research because it focuses on a macro-
level explanation for an organization-level employment outcome-the
effect of heightened international competition on corporate business
strategy and the consequent decision to close unionized plants, open new
plants in the South, introduce self-managed work teams, and so on.
Employment systems are another example (see Osterman 1987; Begin
1990). Employment systems are alternative technical and social systems
for organizing production and the performance of work. Each employ-
ment system carries with it a particular set of human resource policies
concerning recruitment, selection, compensation, and retention. A
wide diversity of such systems and associated human resource policies
exist across firms (e.g., compare a fast-food restaurant, a bank, and an
auto-assembly plant). Why do firms choose a particular employment
system? Why are firms abandoning the traditional "control" model of
work organization for a "high-involvement" model? Industrial relations
is well positioned to answer these questions, for much of the variation
in employment systems and individual human resource practices (the
I 78
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
179
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
investigation. The blame lies not with the individual researchers but
with the reward system and culture in academe that overemphasizes
science-building.
The solution is to devise mechanisms that facilitate and encourage
cross-disciplinary research, the collection of primary data, interviews
with company and union officials, and immersion in the nitty-gritty of
institutional details and daily practice. (Some researchers are already
doing it, but more are needed.) This unglamorous process must take
place if scholars are to discover the true nature of the labor problems
confronting employers and workers and develop the theories and prac-
tices needed to resolve them. Accomplishment of this goal is difficult,
however, in the current environment of science-building in American
universities. Nonetheless, several actions could make a difference.
To help broaden and strengthen the field, the mainstream IR journals
need to reposition the mix of articles accepted for publication. For
example, the number of "pure" labor economics articles accepted for
publication should be reduced, since these often have only a tangential
link to the employment relationship and offer little, if any, cross-
disciplinary perspective. Articles on economic aspects of human re-
sources management should be encouraged, however, for they are di-
rectly relevant to the field and are more likely to span disciplinary
boundaries with respect to content. Another step is to increase the
number of papers published by authors from other "external" disciplines,
such as sociology and political science. At the same time, research that
is clearly of an "internal" nature (e.g., organizational commitment stud-
ies) should be published elsewhere if IR is to develop a coherent image
vis-a-vis HR. Mainstream IR journals should also give preference to
articles that involve primary data, interviews with company and union
officials, and participant-observer techniques so as to encourage the
development of more relevant, problem-solving research. Each of these
steps will probably require an "affirmative action"-type editorial policy.
Simply requesting more such articles, the journal editors tell me, will
yield little change.
Another useful action would be to create additional outlets for case
study and applied policy-oriented research. Such research promotes the
goal of developing informed, relevant theory and empirical work that
tends to be excluded from mainline IR journals. The field could benefit,
180
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
IRRA
The future of industrial relations as a field of study also depends
significantly on the strategic choices made by the Industrial Relations
Research Association. The declining fortunes of the association in many
respects mirror those of the field in general, with the cause,and,effect
relationship going both ways.
The IRRA is caught up in the same intellectual contradiction as are
theIR academic programs and journals; namely, it professes allegiance
to the broad definition of industrial relations but practices the narrow
version. The IRRA needs to resolve this contradiction one way or the
other. Two approaches are possible: to maintain the current ILE ori,
entation of the organization and abandon the stated claim to represent
all segments of the IR and HR community or to retain the stated com,
mitment to represent all segments of the IR and HR community and
implement a series of wide,reaching changes to broaden the organiza,
tion's programs and membership.
The latter option would require that the association take at least five
actions: change its title to signify that it includes both the IR and HR
wings; establish an annual meeting date and place independent of the
Allied Social Science Association (an umbrella group of associations
that includes the American Economic Association) or rotate the annual
meeting so that one year it is with the economics group, another year
with the sociologists, and so on; expand significantly the number of
program sessions and annual research volumes devoted to HR topics;
give balanced weight and perspective at all association meetings and in
all publications to the practice of nonunion employment relations; and
provide equal political representation and access to high office to aca,
demics from the HR wing and executives and practitioners from non,
union companies.
I suspect that this package of revisions could not command sufficient
support in the IRRA to gain ratification. Nor could it be implemented
without significantly damaging and quite possibly destroying the viability
of the organization. I therefore advocate an alternative, second,best
strategy. It has three parts.
181
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
The first part requires people to accept that the IRRA will serve as
the professional association for only half the field-IR, not HR. At
the same time, the association should work to reposition its programs
and activities to make them consistent with the broader definition of
industrial relations advanced earlier in this chapter. In practical terms,
this means structuring the program of the winter meeting so that less
emphasis is given to collective bargaining topics and more to topics
related to the external environment and employment governance. This
also means making concerted efforts to encourage more active partici-
pation by scholars from externally oriented disciplines that are now
underrepresented (e. g., sociology, political science). A greater interface
between IR and HR scholars should also be encouraged, although the
focus needs to be on the themes that define the field (as opposed to an
open-ended session on organizational behavior research). Finally, the
association's name should be changed so that the term industrial relations
is dropped in favor of employment relations or some other more inclusive
label. 18
The second part of the strategy is for the IRRA to promote a wide-
ranging review of the underlying assumptions and policy program of
current-day industrial relations (i.e., to reexamine the problem-solving
face of the field). If the field is to enjoy a renaissance, the IRRA must
play a central role through its meetings and publications in developing
a new way of looking at the employment relationship that is consistent
with modem realities and that yields new practices and policies that
promote efficiency and equity. In particular, it must sponsor a variety
of paper sessions at meetings and dedicate annual research volumes to
a balanced, critical examination of the current system of collective
bargaining and labor law, proposals for change in the IR system, and
innovative employment practices and institutions in both the union and
nonunion sectors.
The third part of the strategy entails both reversing the decline in
membership of the national organization and increasing participation
by academics from outside the ILE school. This can be done by addressing
some serious structural issues. The first such issue concerns the academic-
practitioner interface. While the goal of encouraging a cross-fertilization
of ideas between academics and practitioners is excellent in intent, it
largely fails to accomplish its purpose and, worse, creates significant
disincentives for participation in the national association by academic
182
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
183
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
184
Industrial Relations in the 1990s & Beyond
185
SuMMARY AND CoNCLUSION
s EVERAL KEY POINTS have emerged from the analysis in this book.
The following section summarizes them.
SuMMARY
187
Summary and Conclusion
188
Summary and Conclusion
189
Summary and Conclusion
190
Summary and Conclusion
191
Summary and Conclusion
192
Summary and Conclusion
193
Summary and Conclusion
194
Summary and Conclusion
195
Summary and Conclusion
CoNCLUSION
The events of the last decade have been hard on U.S. industrial
relations and have raised the question of whether the field will survive
into the twenty-first century as anything more than a marginal area of
teaching and research. The prognosis for the field as it is currently
structured is relatively gloomy. I do not foresee IR going the way of
home economics, but, absent significant change, the future surely entails
a further shrinkage in the number of IR academic programs and faculty
with IR training and interests and in the organizational vitality and
membership of the IRRA.
These events are not foreordained, however. It is possible that my
assessment is overly pessimistic and academic IR will ride out the current
period of turbulence relatively intact. It is also possible that economic
and political events in the remainder of the 1990s will become favorable
for the field. Although I do not wish a crisis to befall the nation, the
history of the field clearly reveals that major disruptions to the em-
ployment relationship, be they in the form of war or depression, bene-
fit industrial relations by drawing public attention to the subject of
employer-employee relations and bringing academic researchers into
greater contact with the real world of employment practice and policy.
The odds do not favor either event, however. The evidence is over-
196
Summary and Conclusion
whelming, I think, that the status quo position for the field is not viable
in the long run. Nor do I think industrial relations can count on an
economic or political crisis to save the day. A crisis of some sort may
well be brewing, judged by the growing perception among the populace
that the nation is embarked on a road of economic and social decline,
but the New Deal-era policy program associated with the field of in,
dustrial relations is more likely to be seen as part of the problem, not
the solution. The only path with real promise for industrial relations,
therefore, is change, both intellectual and institutional in nature.
Two aspects of this change process are crucial to the long,term fortunes
of the field. The first is a reconceptualization of the intellectual bound,
aries and core subject matter of industrial relations. Industrial relations
will secure its future only if it carves out a distinct intellectual area of
inquiry that is independent of specific institutions and practices (e.g.,
trade unions and collective bargaining). The approach I advocate defines
industrial relations as the study of the employment relationship from
the perspective of the environment external to the organization. This
definition would not only provide the field with a distinct place in the
social sciences but is consistent with the intellectual approach to the
subject taken by the ILE school from the early 1920s to the present.
The second equally important aspect of the change process is the
development of a problem,solving program for change in employment
practices and policy that promotes the objectives of increased efficiency,
equity, and individual well,being. Industrial relations scholars have for
too long accepted the verities of the past, with the consequence that
industrial relations is now seen as a reactive, out,of date field that has
little relevance for resolving the employment problems of the 1990s.
The challenge facing IR scholars is to reexamine the assumptions and
values that underlie the field, keep what remains valid and graft on new
material where necessary, and then develop and advocate a set of prac,
tices and policies that are both congruent with the intellectual foun,
dations of the field and responsive to the needs of employers, workers,
and the larger society.
Like all challenges to the status quo, this process carries the risk of
failure and the potential for conflict. If IR scholars can successfully meet
the challenge, however, the future of industrial relations will be bright
indeed.
197
NoTES
INTRODUCTION
1. Industrial relations as both a concept and a field of study is largely Anglo-
American in origin, although interest in the field spread across the world
in the post-World War II period. In the chapters that follow, attention is
focused primarily on developments in the United States, although reference
is occasionally made to events and research in Canada and Great Britain.
Limiting the discussion to the United States, besides being a matter of
practicality, is justified to the extent that industrial relations first emerged
as a formal concept and field of study in the United States and many of
the field's most influential institutional and scholarly developments oc-
curred here. The downside is that the development of the field in the
United States, and consequently the conceptual and ideological perspec-
tives of U.S. researchers, are unique in certain respects to this country,
thus limiting the generalizability of the findings of this study.
For a survey of industrial relations thought and practice in Canada, see
Hebert, Jain, and Meltz (1988); asurveyofiR academic programs in Canada
is provided by Boivin (1991). For Great Britain, see Roberts (1972), Ber-
ridge and Goodman (1988), and P. Beaumont (1990). A summary of
developments in international IR is provided by R. Adams (1992).
199
Notes to pages 3-5
200
Notes to pages 5-12
of the weak by the strong ... are the decrees of a large far-seeing benev-
olence.' This conclusion was seized upon by the staunchest advocates of
dominant extreme laissez-faire economics as reinforcing their position."
6. The distaste of early American socialists and Marxists for industrial
relations is reflected in modem times by the paucity of academics of a
radical or Marxist bent who are active in the field. By contrast, a relatively
strong contingent of British academics approach the subject from a radical
or Marxist perspective (e.g., Hyman 1975). To some degree this reflects
the fact that economists have dominated academic IR research in the
United States, while sociologists and historians have played a larger role
in Britain.
7. Taylor's (1895) first paper on the subject of scientific management was
entitled "A Piece Rate System, Being a Step Toward a Partial Solution of
the Labor Problem."
8. Symptomatic of the growing use of the term was the publication in 1919
of Industrial Relations: A Selected Bibliography by the Russell Sage Foundation
Library. The bibliography was divided into two subtopics, employment
management and participation in management.
9. As far as I can determine, the first academic article containing the term
industrial relations in the title was chapter 1, "Industrial Relations," by John
R. Commons in the 1921 edition of Trade Unionism and Labor Problems (a
book of collected readings on labor). The first doctoral dissertation to have
the term in the title, "Industrial Relations in the West Coast Lumber
Industry," was written in 1923 by Cloice Howd (University of California,
Berkeley).
10. A fairly complete list of the local chapters still in existence as of 1940 is
in "Among the Local Industrial Relations Associations," Personnel17 (Au-
gust 1940): 79-83. The article states (p. 79), "Nearly every major city of
the United States and all important industrial regions have their local
industrial relations associations, whose membership is comprised of per-
sonnel executives from neighboring plants." Several of these local asso-
ciations, including the ones in Chicago and Philadelphia, remain active.
(The Chicago chapter changed its name several years ago to the Human
Resource Management Association, while the Philadelphia chapter con-
tinues to call itself an industrial relations association.)
11. Dale Yoder (1931: 123) states in this regard, "The most widely accepted
approach to the study of industrial relations is one which involves an
examination of phenomena that are usually described as labor problems."
12. J. Douglas Brown, director of the IR section at Princeton from 1926 to
1954, states (1976:5): "It was the intention of the founders [of the section]
to broaden the scope of the field studied to include aU factors, conditions,
problems and policies involved in the employment of human resources in
organized production or service. It was not to be limited to any single
academic discipline. Nor was the term 'industrial relations' limited to ac-
tivities within private enterprise but was assumed to cover the relations of
201
Notes to pages 12-13
governments and all other institutions with those people who constituted
the working forces of the country" (emphasis in original). For a similar
view see Watkins (1922:5).
13. The map was reproduced in 1929 in Personnel journal 7 (5):391. A brief
discussion of the work of the committee that prepared the map is given
on pp. 390-93.
14. Stichter (1928:287-88) states in this regard: "There are two ways oflooking
at labor problems. One is from a scientific point of view .... It is aspired
to by the scientist who studies trade unions, child labor, unemployment,
in order to find out what is or what might be, without speculating about
what should be .... To the vast majority of people, however, even to the
economists and sociologists, the labor problem is more than this. It is also
a problem of ethics, a matter not simply of what is or what might be, but
of what should be .... From the ethical point of view, therefore, the labor
problem is concerned with two principal things: with the effect of the
prevailing economic institutions ... upon the conflict between life and
work, and with the institutional changes needed to harmonize men's ac-
tivities as laborers with their interests as men." The terms science-building
and problem-solving are from Barbash (1991a).
15. As detailed in the next chapter, the early literature on industrial relations
was written largely by two groups, academic economists and management
practitioners (with a modest contribution by industrial psychologists). Al-
though references to the goals of efficiency, equity, and enhanced individual
well-being can be found in the writings of both groups, the economists
tended to emphasize efficiency and equity while the management practi-
tioners and psychologists tended to emphasize efficiency and enhanced
individual well-being or happiness. This difference probably reflects a dif-
ference in disciplinary perspectives: the economists were trained to think
in terms of markets and the processes of production and distribution, while
the management practitioners and psychologists generally focused on the
interaction of managers and workers inside the firm, most often from an
individualistic, psychological frame of reference. The difference in emphasis
also reflected the greater weight the economists gave to the adversarial
nature of the employment relationship, a point of view that focused at-
tention on distributional or equity issues, while the emphasis among the
management practitioners and psychologists was on the congruence of
interests that exists in the employment relationship, a perspective that
tended to downgrade the saliency of equity issues. This difference in per-
spectives persists to the present day in the IR and human resources liter-
atures. Noah Meltz ( 1989: 109), for example, states that "industrial relations
is concerned with balancing efficiency and equity," while Richard Walton
(1985:36) states that "the theory [the new human resource management
model] is that the policies of mutuality will elicit commitment which in
tum will yield both better economic performance and greater human
development."
202
Notes to page 20
203
Notes to pages 20-2 I
the ILE schools distinguished here correspond to the latter two. At least
in America, the former two are not, in my opinion, bona fide parts of
industrial relations since the systems of employment relations envisioned
(laissez-faire capitalism and socialism/syndicalism) were exactly what the
founders of the field were trying to avoid. If one thinks of alternative
systems of employment relations as ordered along a political and economic
continuum, the righthand end point would be the labor market school and
the lefthand end point would be the political school, with the management
and institutional schools in the middle (the institutional school would be
to the left of the management school). As discussed in chapter 1, the
founders of industrial relations desired to steer a middle course between
these two extremes, thereby promoting reform rather than reaction or
revolution. It is also apparent that early participants in industrial relations
regarded the field as divided into two competing schools of thought, not
four. Paul Brissenden (1926:444), for example, mentions two "lines of
thought" in industrial relations: the "academic line" of the economists and
the "labor-management line" of the personnel practitioners. A similar
division of thought is suggested by William M. Leiserson (1929:126), by
James Bossard and J. Frederic Dewhurst (1931:430), and by Martin Estey
(1960:93).
4. It is worth reiterating that the PM and ILE labels represent alternative
schools of thought or approaches to problem-solving in industrial relations,
not specific intellectual fields of study associated with science-building.
Thus, the label "PM" does not designate the field of personnel management
per se but rather represents the basic point of view held by personnel
professionals concerning the cause and resolution of labor problems. As
described in later chapters, the PM school grew to include academics from
a variety of fields, including human relations, organizational behavior, and
human resource management. While these academics differ significantly
with respect to the theoretical constructs and research methodologies used
in science-building, they nevertheless share a core set of beliefs about how
best to promote improved industrial relations in the workplace. This is
what the PM label is meant to connote. The same consideration applies
equally well to the ILE label, which is meant to be an umbrella term for
people who share a common set of beliefs about the source and solution
of labor problems, even though they may differ substantially in their ap-
proach to the study of labor markets. From a problem-solving perspective,
it is thus appropriate to combine the institutionalists of the Wisconsin
school and the "neoclassical revisionists" (Kerr 1983) of the 1950s, even
though from a science-building perspective the two groups had much less
in common.
5. The employment management movement started in Boston in early 1913
with the founding of the Boston Employment Managers' Association, a
group in which Meyer Bloomfield and Daniel Bloomfield played important
roles (Lange 1928). Other local associations were soon founded, followed
204
Notes to pages 21-24
205
Notes to pages 24-25
action, they can multiply these gestures of protest many times over....
But on the other hand, there are vast and comparatively untapped reservoirs
of energy and interest which they can put at the service of industry .... "
On the next several pages Houser discusses two other themes later advanced
by Mayo and his colleagues, namely, the concept of equilibrium in the
social system of the plant and the overemphasis given to the role of financial
incentives in motivating work effort.
10. Although most of the influential writers in the PM school of the 1920s
were businessmen or consultants, many nevertheless had close ties to uni-
versities and actively participated in scholarly research. Sam Lewisohn, for
example, was vice-president of the Miami Copper Company, co-author
with John R. Commons and others of Can Business Prevent Unemployment?
(1925) and author of The New Leadership in Industry (1926), president of
the American Management Association, and chairman of the Industrial
Relations Research Committee of the Academy of Political Science. Other
members of the PM school who had close ties to universities or who
published research of a scholarly nature were Ordway Tead, Henry Metcalf,
Mary Parker Follett, Henry Dennison, Clarence Hicks, Chester Barnard,
and Arthur Young. Biographical sketches of these people, and of other
prominent PM writers of the 1920s, is provided in Spates 1960.
11. On this subject Lewisohn states (pp. 48-49): "To approach labor unrest
as if it were mainly due to peculiar defects of capitalism is thus a profound
error.... We should, therefore, focus our attention for a while on the
individual plant where the daily contact between employer and employee
takes place. Here is the starting point of any endeavor to improve indus-
trial relations." He goes on to say (p. 202), "There is no escaping the con-
clusion that the most important factor in sound industrial relations is
management."
12. Pyschology affected the development of personnel management in two
ways, first, through the development of theories of motivation, group dy-
namics, leadership, and other such factors associated with human relations
and, second, through its impact on particular personnel practices and tech-
niques, such as applicant interviewing, hiring tests, job analysis, and train-
ing. A major catalyst in this regard was the set of psychological experiments
conducted by the army during World War I involving aptitude tests and
rating systems. The practical applications of these experiments were soon
transferred to personnel practice in private industry after the war (Ling
1965). The psychological work associated with human relations had a major
influence on the field of industrial relations and is thus discussed at length;
the psychological work on specific personnel practices, while of major
significance to the development of personnel management per se, had only
a secondary impact on the broader issues associated with industrial relations
and thus is not discussed further. Much of the discussion of the PM school
in this chapter is derived from the writings of business practitioners and
consultants, not academic industrial psychologists. The reason is that the
206
Notes to pages 25-32
207
Notes to pages 33-36
208
Notes to pages 38-40
209
Notes to pages 40-41
210
Notes to pages 42-47
but also in safe and humane working conditions at the work site and that
some balancing of these interests is appropriate. A recent statement of this
position is provided by Lester Thurow (1988).
26. A belief in the social efficacy of pluralism is one of the strongest philo-
sophical threads running through the ILE school from Commons's time to
the present. See, for example, Kerr (1954b) and the winter 1983 issue of
Industrial Relations. The latter contains a report (pp. 125-31) on a two-
day conference attended by twenty-nine leading IR scholars on "The Future
of Industrial Relations." The last paragraph of the report states: "The
conference closed with what came close to a consensus: our economic and
social problems can best be resolved through tripartite union-management-
government discussion and collaboration. No better model was presented."
Also see Dunlop (1984b) and Schatz (1993).
. 2I I
Notes to pages 47-53
212
Notes to pages 54-56
213
Notes to page 57
214
Notes to pages 57-63
13. The opinion of Richard Lester and Maurice Neufeld as stated in telephone
conversations.
14. Mention should also be made of the Personnel Research Federation, a
nonprofit group founded in 1921 to promote "the cooperation of research
activities pertaining to personnel in industry, commerce, education, and
government" (U.S. Department of Labor 1921:111). Interestingly, one of
the charter members of the group was the American Federation of Labor.
The Personnel Research Federation sponsored numerous conferences and
publications on industrial relations-related topics, including Stanley Ma-
thewson's (1931) well-known monograph on restriction of output among
unorganized workers and the monthly periodical Personnel Journal. Al-
though Personnel Journal became largely practitioner-oriented after 1935
(because of a change in editors), before then many of its articles had a
significant research element. It is noteworthy, for example, that seven of
the ten members of the editorial board in the early 1930s were academics
(including Wesley Mitchell from economics and Morris Viteles from in-
dustrial psychology), but not one was a business person.
215
Notes to pages 63-64
consin State Journal said of the newly created institute that it provided "a
giant microscope into which to peer into America's number one domestic
problem, Big Business versus Big Labor" (quoted in Fried 1987:2-3).
4. A brief description of these programs (with the exception of the one at
the University of Hawaii) is given in Industrial Relations Counselors 1949.
Detailed histories of the IR programs at Illinois and Wisconsin are provided
in Derber 1987 and Fried 1987. The establishment of IR units and devel-
opments at existing units are also chronicled in the "News and Notes"
section of each issue of the Industrial and Labor Relations Review.
5. While the immediate post-World War II period saw a tremendous expan-
sion in industrial relations programs in America, the same was not nearly
so true in Canada and Great Britain. Canada saw the establishment of an
IR institute at Laval University in the mid-1940s and the subsequent pub-
lication of an IR journal, Industrial Relations-Quarterly Review (R. Adams
1992). The major expansion of IR programs, and the establishment of the
Canadian Industrial Relations Association, did not occur until two decades
later, however. Speaking of the situation in Britain in the postwar period,
John Berridge and John Goodman (1988:156) state, "Prior to the 1960s,
the process of acceptance of industrial relations in the academic world was
slow and problematic." Although the British Universities Industrial Re-
lations Association was founded in 1950, the major period of growth took
place from the mid-1960s to the late 1970s. The most important British
IR programs in the 1960s were at Oxford University, Cambridge University,
and the London School of Economics. In the 1970s, the IR program at
Warwick University became the leading center for industrial relations re-
search in Great Britain. This disparate pattern of growth in the three
countries in IR largely reflects different cycles of union growth and accom-
panying public concern over issues such as strikes and inflation.
6. According to Derber (1987) and Fried (1987), the creation of the IR
institutes at Illinois and Wisconsin was actively opposed by the schools of
commerce at each university. The frosty relations between theIR institute
and the school of commerce at Illinois is illustrated by the fact that as
many as six faculty members from economics and one to three from so-
ciology and psychology but only one from the business school held joint
appointments with the institute in the 1950s (Derber 1987:28). While the
situations at Illinois and Wisconsin were the norm in this regard, there
were exceptions. At Berkeley, for example, a majority of the IR faculty
held joint appointments with the business school, and the two units main-
tained a relatively amicable relationship (George Strauss, personal cor-
respondence).
7. The compromise worked out at Illinois was that the IR institute was to
specialize in labor relations and the school of commerce was to specialize
in management. Both units shared responsibility for subjects dealing with
the interaction of labor and management (Derber 1987:16).
216
Notes to page 65
217
Notes to pages 65-67
218
Notes to page 68
219
Notes to pages 69-70
220
Notes to pages 75-79
221
Notes to pages 79-80
impressed Mayo with his ideas about business leadership, particularly the
idea of leadership through consent rather than command.
Mayo was particularly critical of economists and their promotion of
individualism and competition, for, in his view, these forces destroyed the
sense of community and social order necessary for effective collaboration
and thereby reduced society to a "rabble." Mayo (1945:59) states: "Eco-
nomic theory in its human aspect is woefully insufficient; indeed it is absurd.
Humanity is not adequately described as a horde of individuals, each ac-
tuated by self-interest, each fighting his neighbor for the scarce material
of survival. Realization that such theories completely falsify the normal
human scene drives us back to the study of particular human situations
[e.g., internal plant studies such as at Hawthorne]."
5. Of all the implications derived from the Hawthorne experiments with
regard to successful management, Mayo considered the most important to
be the use of human relations techniques to foster cooperation and team-
work among workers and supervisors (1945:73): "Here then are the two
topics which deserve the closest attention of all those engaged in admin-
istrative work-the organization of working teams and the free participation
of such teams in the task and purpose of the organization as it directly
affects them in their daily rounds." This theme was echoed twelve years
later by Conrad D. Arensberg and Geoffrey Tootell (1957:312): "They
[the Mayoites] retain the distinction of having demonstrated again and
again the crucial role of teamwork in the creation of work morale and in
the productivity of the workers. They show that morale and output depend,
not on individual incentives alone or directly, but upon the 'informal
organization' of interpersonal relationships and small-group sentiments
within the immediate workforce."
6. Mayo himself had largely neglected the social dimension of the workplace in
his early writings. In an article published in Harper's (1925), for example,
Mayo said (pp. 229-30), "When we talk of social problems we are apt to for-
get that every social problem is ultimately individual." In emphasizing the
individual, Mayo was following the dominant trend among industrial psy-
chologists of the period, which was to seek explanations for differences in hu-
man behavior by searching for variations in individual mental attitudes,
needs, motives, and so on. The emphasis in his later writings on the social di-
mension of work thus represented a significant intellectual conversion.
7. Warner's first academic research work was an anthropological field study
of a primitive tribe in the South Pacific. Acting as a participant-observer,
he recorded the tribe's various social relationships and the economic func-
tion of its various rites, customs, and so forth. Warner was then recruited
to assist in the development of the bank wiring room experiments at Haw-
thorne. Thus, the decision to study the workers as an autonomous social
group and to observe and record their daily routines and patterns of in-
teraction was solidly in the anthropological tradition.
222
Notes to pages 81-82
223
Notes to pages 83-84
"the most outstanding study of industrial relations that has ever been
published anywhere, anytime" (Miller and Form 1951:4).
11. My claim is that the majority of academics engaged in human relations
research regarded their investigations as falling under the intellectual
umbrella of industrial relations, just as was true of labor economists. The
identification with industrial relations weakened, however, the further
the person's research interests were from the subject of employer-employee
interactions. Thus, researchers such as Kurt Lewin and Rensis Likert in
the PM school, who were primarily interested in the psychological and
administrative aspects of management, saw little intellectual kinship with
industrial relations, while others such as Chris Argyris and George Ho-
mans saw a modest connection (Argyris, for example, was a member of
the executive board of the IRRA), while still others such as Benjamin
Selekman and William Foote Whyte saw a substantial connection. The
same was true of economists, although in this case the connection with
industrial relations weakened as one moved closer to the neoclassical
school. Clark Kerr and Richard Lester, for example, were closely affiliated
with industrial relations, while Melvin Reder and H. Gregg Lewis saw
only a modest connection (as told to me by Lewis in telephone con-
versation) and Milton Friedman most likely saw none at all (although
he did write articles in the 1950s on labor). Finally, to say that persons
such as Homans and Kerr both perceived themselves to be members of
the field of industrial relations suggests no more than that they possessed
a common interest in employer-employee relations. Their specific research
interests and disciplinary perspectives (sociology and economics) were
quite distinct.
12. Blum briefly discussed the concept of a labor market and stated that
(1925:128) "of all markets the labor market is the poorest [i.e., least
efficient in operation)." He later states (pp. 372-73): "Under competitive
conditions, the demand of the buying public for cheaper goods ... forces
a cut-throat competition and breaking down of wage rates that finally
reaches an extreme, but logical conclusion in the sweatshop" and "the
trade union is a group united to protect a common interest ... [and] has
been forced by the weakness of the individual bargainer. Large scale in-
dustry, concentration of capital and reduction of skill have reduced the
isolated workman to an insignificant unit in the full scheme of production,
but has increased enormously the power, influence and resources of the
large employer."
13. Indicative of this is Witte's comment (1954: 131) that "I shifted to eco-
nomics from history because my major professor, Frederick Jackson Turner,
... left Wisconsin and told me that the best historian among many good
historians on our campus was John R. Commons, although he was attached
to the economics department." Commons was also well versed in sociology
and anthropology, in part because those fields were housed in the economics
department at Wisconsin until 1929 and he was chairman of that depart-
224
Notes to page 85
225
Notes to page 85
16. Another young economist who took up the study of labor in the early
1940s was H. Gregg Lewis. Lewis did his doctoral work at Chicago in the
late 1930s under Paul Douglas and, upon graduation, was appointed to a
faculty position. Lewis's name is not included in the list of prominent labor
economists cited here because his research had relatively little impact on
the field until the publication of his book on unions and relative wages
(Lewis 1963). Lewis had a significant but more indirect impact on the field
in earlier years through his influence on graduate students at Chicago, such
as Albert Rees and Gary Becker.
Lewis has been called the father of "modem" or "analytical" labor eco-
nomics (see Rees 1976; American Economic Review, September 1982, fron-
tispiece). I believe a more correct title is father of the Chicago school of
labor economics or, what is essentially the same thing, the neoclassical
revival in American labor economics. As I have argued elsewhere (Kaufman
1988: 197), Lewis can be considered the father of analytical or modem labor
economics only if these terms are interpreted narrowly to mean the thor-
ough application of competitive price theory to labor markets and, more
particularly, the testing of hypotheses through rigorous statistical analyses.
If modem and analytical are interpreted more broadly to mean the analysis
of the operation of labor markets and the determinants of labor demand
and supply, then Paul Douglas deserves to be listed as the progenitor of
the field and economists such as Dunlop, Kerr, Lester, and Reynolds as
the "fathers."
17. The clearest dividing line between the labor problems and labor markets
approach to labor economics is provided by Richard Lester's text Economics
of Labor (1941 ). Three features of the book distinguish it from earlier labor
problems texts: its focus on labor markets rather than labor problems per
se, the important role it gives to the determination oflabor market outcomes
by demand and supply conditions, and the use of analytical techniques
such as graphical representation of demand and/or supply curves. The text
also represents an interesting middle ground between the institutionalism
of Commons and the neoclassical economics of Hicks. Lester clearly follows
Hicks and the neoclassical approach to labor economics in that he focuses
attention on the operation of labor markets and demand and supply, but
he clearly follows the institutional perspective in the amount of attention
given to the imperfect nature of labor markets and in the relatively favorable
treatment of unions and protective labor legislation.
18. A recurrent debate concerns the appropriate label to attach to these labor
economists and, in particular, whether they are an offshoot of the neo-
classical or the institutional school (see Kaufman 1988). Glen Cain (1976),
for example, has labeled them neoinstitutionalists on the grounds that,
like the earlier institutionalists, they largely rejected competitive neoclassi-
cal theory as a useful tool to understand the behavior of labor markets;
desired to incorporate into economic theory a more behavioral model of
man, models of imperfect competition, and the influence of organizational
226
Notes to page 85
227
Notes to pages 87-89
228
Notes to pages 89-90
22. Another event that is suggestive of the gap between the theorists and the
ILE-oriented labor economists was the publication of The Impact of the
Union (Wright 1951). The book contained a series of articles by eight
prominent economic theorists and a round-table discussion by these men
on the impact of labor unions on wages, employment, inflation, and other
such market outcomes. No labor economist was invited to contribute to
the volume, leading Lloyd Reynolds (1953:474) to observe, "This volume
seems to have developed from a feeling that-to paraphrase a famous
remark about generals-that labor economics is too important to be left
to the labor economists." Another piece of evidence in this regard comes
from a biography of the institutional economist Edwin Witte. Theron F.
Schlabach (1969:224) states that "Witte's feeling of alienation from his
profession approached its peak in the late 1940s" and that Witte complained
that identifying himself as an institutionalist was "equivalent to admitting
that I am not an economist at all."
23. The different perspectives of the two groups of economists regarding unions
is clearly revealed in the debate over the "labor monopoly" issue. See, for
example, Lester 1947b and Lewis 1951.
24. The most detailed discussion of the goals and objectives of the founders of
the IRRA is contained in an article by Clark Kerr ( 1983) commemorating
the thirty-sixth anniversary of the founding of the association. That the
IRRA was founded as an act of rebellion in economics and that its dominant
goal was to provide an organizational home for more institutionally oriented
labor economists and their soulmates from other disciplines are clearly
revealed in his article (p. 14): "We [the young labor economists] started
out as rebels. We first met almost like conspirators in the hallways during
the annual meetings of the American Economic Association to grumble
about what then seemed to us to be the neglect of labor economics at these
meetings .... It seemed to us then almost incredible ... that labor ... was
so ignored as compared, for example, with the role of capital; that the firm
was the source of so much attention and the union hardly mentioned; that
labor markets, when noticed at all, were viewed as though they were
commodity markets; that collective bargaining, then in the daily headlines,
had not penetrated into the domain of the interests of most traditional
economists; but, most of all, that theory seemed to move along at the
microeconomy level with so little contact with reality."
Kerr goes on to describe the goals of the founders of the association (p.
15): "We had several goals in mind when we founded the association. First
of all, we wanted to meet together, to get to know each other better, to
find out what others of us were doing, and this was not possible in the
crowded mass atmosphere of the American Economic Association. Second,
we wished to have an impact on the programming of the Association ...
[and to call the attention of] the theorists to our field of interest and to
our own research. Third, we wanted to create a forum which would be
participated in by practitioners in the unions, in industry, and in govern-
229
Notes to page 92
ment who would never feel at home and would consequently never come
to meetings of the American Economic Association .... We had a fourth
goal which was to bring in scholars from related social sciences, particularly
law, sociology, political science, and psychology, to discuss matters which
clearly transcended the traditional boundaries of economics."
It seems clear from these remarks that the IRRA was born out of dual
motives. The purported motive was to foster the study of the employment
relationship from all disciplinary and ideological perspectives (as stated in
the IRRA constitution). The second motive, and the one that clearly was
the more salient to Kerr and the other founders of the organization, was
to provide a forum for labor economists who wanted to pursue a more
institutionally oriented, interdisciplinary mode of research than was wel-
comed in the American Economic Association. In hindsight, it would have
been better for the founders of the IRRA to pursue one objective or the
other but not both. If the IRRA was to promote industrial relations, it
should have had a wider disciplinary and ideological representation and
most certainly would not have been centered in economics given that
economics was the disciplinary base of the ILE school. (Kerr [1983: 17]
suggests that sociology might have been a better disciplinary base for in-
dustrial relations, a suggestion with considerable merit, given that sociology
seemed to be centered on the disciplinary fault line that separated the PM
and the ILE schools.) If the IRRA was instead to be devoted to the prop-
agation of a more institutionally oriented brand of labor economics, it
would have been preferable to state this as its mission, to give the orga-
nization an appropriate name, and to pursue this objective explicitly in
the organization's programs and publications. (Yoder [1958:3] states that
the original name selected for the IRRA was the American Association
for Labor Research, which would have better conveyed the second objec-
tive). As it is, the IRRA has been too timid in its pursuit of rebellion in
labor economics, and, worse, it has corrupted the original meaning and
spirit of the term industrial relations by its refusal to give equal representation
to the members and viewpoints of the PM school.
25. The active participation of behavioral scientists in industrial relations is
illustrated by the titles of several books: The Sociology of Industrial Relations
(Knox 1955), Industrial Relations and the Social Order (Moore 1951), and
Psychology of Industrial Relations (Lawshe et al. 1953).
26. In the 1940s-50s, most industrial relations research was done by academics,
unlike earlier periods, when businessmen, union officials, and consultants
authored a significant share of the literature. Exceptions in the latter period
include works by Clinton Golden and Harold Ruttenberg (1942) and by
Solomon Barkin (1950, 1957), all of whom were union officials, and by
Robert Johnson (1949) and Carter Nyman (1949), who were business
executives.
27. Wilensky was apparently unaware of the earlier map of industrial relations
that had been prepared by the Social Science Research Council in 1928
230
Notes to pages 94-99
(see fig. 1-1), for he makes no mention of it. The major differences between
the maps are that Wilensky omitted some of the fringe fields of study (e. g. ,
physiology, chemistry, education) that were included in the earlier survey
and provided a much more in-depth treatment of the research literature.
The maps are similar in that both define industrial relations quite expan-
sively to include all manner of relations in the workplace (e.g., vertical
"man-boss" relations within a company, horizontal relations between work-
ers and work groups in a plant or workshop, relations between workers and
labor organizations, and relations between organizations such as unions and
firms) and a broad range of disciplines and fields of study across the be-
havioral and social sciences.
28. According to Strauss (1979:371), "The project was widely viewed as a
failure; it is rarely cited ... [and] appears to have had little influence on
other research."
29. Derber (1968) found that international studies comprised 17.3 percent of
the research projects conducted at fifteen IR centers during 1956-59. Of
the fourteen subject areas Derber surveyed, management organization and
communication was the most researched topic (18.6 percent), followed by
international IR.
30. A thorough review of the origins and development of the Inter-University
Study project, as well as an assessment of the strengths and weaknesses of
the book Industrialism and Industrial Man, is given in Cochrane 1979. A
retrospective look at the conclusions by the four authors is contained in
Dunlop et al. 1975.
31. Empirical evidence in support of Dunlop's position was provided in a study
by Kerr and Siegel (1954) on the propensity to strike across industries.
They demonstrated that certain industries such as coal and longshoring are
strike-prone in nearly every industrial country. They argued that this pat-
tern reflected common environmental characteristics of these industries
(e.g., the dangerous nature of the work) rather than plant-specific human
relations practices.
32. The extent and degree of the anti-union bias in human relations is a matter
of considerable debate (see Landsberger 1958). Mayo certainly seemed
ambivalent about unions and suggested that they often played an undesir-
able role by interfering with the development of "spontaneous collabora-
tion" in the plant. Later human relations writers took some pains, however,
to accord unions legitimacy in the conceptual model of human relations
and its normative prescriptions for practice and policy. Whyte (1951b),
for example, argued that the union was an integral part of the social system
in the steel plant he studied, while Homans (1954:57) allowed that "if
unions did not exist, we should have to invent them .... We must not
only accept the fact that unions are here to stay but accept the idea that
they need to stay."
These concessions did not allay the fears of the critics, however (see
Kerr and Fisher 1957). As they saw it, the emphasis on cooperation and
231
Notes to page 99
232
Notes to page 99
interest was human relations, and his doctoral training was primarily in
social psychology, clinical psychology, and sociology. He stated in a tele-
phone interview that in the early 1950s he felt a strong sense of affiliation
with industrial relations and perceived that human relations research was
an integral part of the field. Participation in industrial relations was at-
tractive, Argyris said, because it provided an opportunity to integrate the
social and psychological research of human relations with the economics
and institutional research of the ILE school. He discovered, however, that
the majority of economists were not interested in such an integration.
In the early 1950s, the IRRA and the Social Science Research Council
asked Argyris to conduct a survey of human relations research at major
American universities. In 1954, he presented his findings at a meeting of
the council (see Argyris 1954). He said that, while some ILE participants
expressed genuine interest in human relations research, his perception was
that the attitude of the majority ranged from indifference to hostility. Given
such an attitude, he largely ceased active involvement in industrial relations
by the late 1950s. Argyris cited several reasons the majority of economists
were unreceptive to human relations research: it was perceived as a threat
to unions and collective bargaining, was regarded as too "soft" (unscien-
tific), and was seen as a tool to manipulate workers.
34. An example is provided by Kerr and Fisher (1957:282): "This group of
sociologists has grown steadily in size and influence during the past few
years, bringing with it certain charges against the intellectual apparatus
with which the economists have worked. For those with a sense of history
of ideas, there is a haunting familiarity to the charges. For they are the
charges levelled by the church and aristocracy against the abstract, indi-
vidualistic conception of the philosophes; they are the charges levelled by
Burke against the French Revolution in the name of the prior rights of
society and the group as against those of the artificial conception of rea-
soning man, by the German romantics of the 19th century in the name
of the greater reality of the folk, by the Nazis against 'liberalism,' and by
the Communists against cosmopolitanism.... This is the most modem
episode in the attack on reason in the name of harmony, cohesion, and a
traditional culture."
35. The selection of William Foote Whyte as IRRA president in 1963 would
appear to contradict this claim, given Whyte's status as the leading ex-
ponent of the human relations school in industrial relations. By 1963,
however, the battle between the ILE and PM wings over human relations
was effectively over and the human relations group was well into the process
of divorcing itself from industrial relations. My perception, therefore, is
that by 1963 Whyte was a politically "safe" candidate because the human
relations movement no longer posed an effective challenge to the ILE
hegemony of the field, whereas a decade earlier Whyte's selection would
have potentially opened the door to a true sharing of political power and
intellectual perspectives. (This interpretation is supported by Whyte, who
233
Notes to pages 99-101
234
Notes to page 102
235
Notes to page 103
icized. His stance on this matter made it difficult for him to include within
his theoretical model in Industrial Relations Systems topics such as union-
joining since much of the literature on this subject tended to emphasize
the social and psychological motives discussed in the human relations
literature (see, for example, Hoxie 1917, Tannenbaum 1921, and Leiserson
1959:16-31).
Since Dunlop had unsurpassed familiarity with the internal workings of
both firms and unions, it is clear beyond a doubt that he was cognizant of
the internal organizational dimension as a practical matter. That he omitted
it from his theory has to be interpreted as reflecting his perception that
internal organizational, psychological, and sociological factors play a rel-
atively minor role in the operation of the industrial relations system (as
stated in his 1950 article). This is an entirely acceptable position, but it
would have been better if he had explicitly discussed this proposition in
the book and provided empirical support for it, rather than adopt it as an
unstated assumption. There is some evidence that Dunlop's position may
have softened over the years, for in an article published in 1988 he discusses
at length the important role played in wage determination by the informal
social organization in the plant and cites a book by Elton Mayo as evidence.
236
Notes to pages 113-17
the path taken by the book Industrialism and Industrial Man (Kerr et al.
1960). Thus, .the intent was to move away from the preoccupation with
unions and labor-management relations that had characterized IR research
in the 1950s toward a dynamic, comparative analysis of the evolution
of industrial society, its major institutions, and the manner in which
work is organized and performed. He thought that, although the journal
has been quite successful in its own right, it has largely failed in guiding
IR research along this new path. As will become clear, the principal
reason for this failure is that the trend toward pure science-building
research in academia was incompatible with the research agenda mapped
out by Kerr and his colleagues.
2. The narrowing of the subject domain of IR after 1960 complicates use of
the term industrial relations in this and subsequent chapters since it is no
longer clear whether the term applies to IR broadly conceived (all aspects
of the employment relationship) or to IR narrowly conceived (labor-
management relations). From 1960 onward, most academics and practi-
tioners used industrial relations in its narrow sense, a convention that I
follow from here on (unless the broad interpretation is clearly implied or
is specifically stated).
3. Representative of this point of view is the statement by Wilensky in his
Syllabus of Industrial Relations (1954:6) that "few students identified with
the field confine it to union-management or employee relations."
4. A small number of articles did not fit into any of these topical areas and
were thus excluded from the calculations.
5. I mentioned earlier (note 1) that the founders of Industrial Relations intended
it to include research on all aspects of the employment relationship. The
data cited here suggest that the journal had modest success in the 1960s
in this regard (and certainly more so than the ILR Review) but that during
the 1970s it lost a considerable degree of its disciplinary and topical
eclecticism.
6. It is my perception that behavioral research on even narrowly defined IR
topics (e.g., subjects pertaining to unions and labor-management relations)
declined during the 1960s and 1970s. The increasing percentage of papers
published in the IRjournals by economists (as documented earlier) certainly
supports this position. Since the late 1970s, however, a modest rebirth of
interest in behavioral research has occurred in industrial relations. That
IR is still conceived narrowly in this research is suggested by yet another
symposium on the subject, this one published in the winter 1988 issue of
Industrial Relations. Five of the seven papers focused on a collective bar-
gaining subject.
7. This statement was affirmed by William Form in a telephone interview.
When the first edition of the book was written, industrial sociology did
not exist as a distinct field of study. Hence, he and Delbert Miller sought
to take various strands of largely unconnected research on labor (e.g.,
social stratification, sociometry, organization theory, human relations) and
237
Notes to pages 117-20
238
Notes to pages 121-22
239
Notes to pages 124-34
16. Although the 1950s-era labor economists associated with the ILE school
largely ceased active research in labor economics per se, several continued
to publish in the field of industrial relations. The two most notable examples
were Dunlop and Kerr, who authored articles and books on IR subjects
throughout the 1970s and 1980s (Dunlop more so than Kerr). This pub-
lication record, augmented by their highly visible public service careers
and work as top-level arbitrators and mediators in labor disputes, made
them the two most influential "father figures" of the field in the 1980s.
17. Interdisciplinary research also waned in other fields of study. William Sewell
(1989) notes, for example, that a great wave of enthusiasm for interdis-
ciplinary research emerged in social psychology immediately after World
War II and led to the founding of several significant interdisciplinary re-
search centers but that by the 1970s interdisciplinary research had almost
vanished. He attributes the decline to the threat posed by interdisciplinary
research to the traditional departmental structure of American universities,
the lack of adequate funding for such research, the lack of a breakthrough
in integrative theory, and the concentration on research methods.
18. George Shultz (1964:25) said of this problem: "The field of industrial
relations is thus confronted by a dilemma. On the one hand, the potential
contribution of the several disciplines, as disciplines, is widely recognized;
yet, on the other hand, the tradition of tackling a problem on its own
terms tempts the industrial relations student to be a sort of jack-of-all
disciplines. As master of none, however, he may well lose the essential
analytical power of each and, in the process, lose the really professional
content so essential to careful and precise analysis. This interdisciplinary
trap is especially dangerous where degree programs in industrial relations
as such are offered .... The effort to cover all aspects of the field almost
inevitably leads to the professional content of each individual discipline
being seriously diluted" (emphasis in original).
19. Jack Barbash supports this supposition (1989a:3): "If we are not bound by
one theory it is just possible that common values inform our work."
20. Paul Webbink (1954:103) alludes to this in his reference to the "apparent
resistance on the part of some economists toward the participation in
industrial relations research of collaborators or competitors from other
disciplines."
21. Clark Kerr (1978:132) observed that "before World War II ... the field
[industrial relations) had no core; it was fractionated among: the neoclas-
sicists ... the institutionalists ... the Marxists ... the antimonopolists ...
and the 'Human Relations' school." He then discusses the events of the
1950s (p. 134): "The field now had a core to it. The core might be identified
as 'neo-institutionalism,' drawing on theory and practice, on the operation
of competitive markets and organized power, and the various mixtures of
them; concerned with the impact of institutions on markets and of markets
on institutions."
240
Notes to pages 134-41
22. My view is that the split between the PM and the ILE schools was caused
by three types of "forces" that could be labeled as "push," "pull," and
"dissolving." The push came from the antagonistic attitude of the ILE
school toward the human relations movement and the policy implications
it represented; the pull from the attractiveness of establishing a separate
field of study devoted to the study of organizations and management from
a behavioral science perspective; and the dissolving from the pressures of
science-building, which weakened the incentives for cross-disciplinary col-
laboration. Although the "push" force from the ILE school was a contrib-
uting factor and no doubt hastened the divorce between it and the PM
school, I suspect that the impact of the "pull" and "dissolving" forces were
equally if not more important and that the effective demise of the "mar-
riage" between the two groups was a matter of when not if.
23. That industrial relations became more "liberal" and "pro-union" after 1960
is supported by the research of Goddard (1992b). Based on statistical anal-
ysis of data from an attitudinal survey of Canadian faculty members teaching
employment-related courses, he concluded that faculty in IR centers were
more "left-wing" than faculty from either management or economics de-
partments. Since the latter two groups were the ones that tended to drop
out of the field of industrial relations after 1960, the net effect was that
the field swung toward the more liberal end of the ideological spectrum.
241
Notes to pages 143-45
242
Notes to pages 147-49
243
Notes to pages 149-55
244
Notes to page 155
245
Notes to pages 155-61
Wallace, Robert McKersie, and James Stem. All but two are economists
(Bernstein and McKersie), all the economists are in what I consider the
ILE school (certainly none is a neoclassical economist of the Chicago
school), and none has taken a stance in their published writings that could
be construed as being even mildly critical of the basic principles and pur-
poses of trade unionism and several (e.g., Marshall, Derber, Barbash, Kas-
salow) are clearly supportive of trade unionism. It is also instructive to
examine who has not been elected president of the organization: prominent
labor economists affiliated with the University of Chicago (e. g., Albert
Rees, Melvin Reder, H. Gregg Lewis), academics who have been critical
of unions and collective bargaining (e.g., Herbert Northrup}, and persons
whose primary interest is in the management side of employer-employee
relations (e.g., Edward Lawler, Peter Drucker, Paul Lawrence).
23. It is difficult to quantify feelings of disenfranchisement and estrangement,
but one circumstantial piece of evidence exists. The Kerr-Dunlop com-
mittee commissioned a survey of the IRRA membership in which a wide
range of questions were asked concerning the activities and programs of
the association. Only an 18 percent response rate was obtained. In a letter
to the committee, David Lewin (1988b:9} said: "One wonders (disheart-
eningly) whether the bulk of the IRRA membership has given up. The 18
percent response rate to the recent survey suggests a 'yes' answer to this
question, as do many of the comments reproduced in the report of the
survey. At the 1987 annual meeting in Chicago, numerous IRRA members
speculated about the lack of even one 'younger' scholar on the Review
Committee. My purpose in mentioning these sensitive matters is not to
apportion blame; instead it is to suggest that the Review Committee may
have before it substantial evidence of the disillusionment of a large portion
of the Association's membership-particularly its younger members" (em-
phasis in the original).
246
Notes to pages 161-65
247
Notes to pages 166-67
248
Notes to pages 168-69
249
Notes to pages 169-70
250
Notes to pages 170-77
251
Notes to pages 182-84
situations. Because this meaning is neither correct nor viable in the long
run from a marketing perspective, I predict that eventually the name of
the Cornell program will be changed (or some other strategem found to
accomplish the same purpose). Doing so will mark the end of an era.
18. The term research should also be dropped from the title since it has little
relevance to the practitioner members of the association, who outnumber
the academic members by a wide margin. My suggestion for a new title is
the American Employment Relations Association or the Association for
the Advancement of Employment Relations.
19. Planning and organizing an independent meeting would, however, entail
a significantly greater expense for the IRRA, an expense it may not be
able to bear given its extremely tight budget. One option is to eliminate
the spring meeting and use those funds to support an independently held
winter meeting.
252
REFERENCES
Adams, Leonard P. 1967. "Research Note: Cornell University, New York State
School of Industrial and Labor Relations." Industrial and Labor Relations Review
20 (July): 730-33.
Adams, Roy. 1983. "Competing Paradigms in Industrial Relations." Relations
Industrielles 38 (3): 508-29.
- - . 1988. "Desperately Seeking Industrial Relations Theory." International
Journal of Comparative Labour Law and Industrial Relations 4 (1): 1-10.
- - . 1992. "All Aspects of People at Work: Unity and Division in the Study
of Labour and Labour Management." In Industrial Relations Theory: Its Nature,
Scope and Pedagogy, ed. Roy Adams and Noah Meltz. Melbourne: Longman
Cheshire. Forthcoming.
Adams, Thomas S., and Helen L. Sumner. 1905. Labor Problems. New York:
Macmillan.
Appelbaum, Eileen. 1979. "Post-Keynesian Theory: The Labor Market." Chal-
lenge 21 (Jan.-Feb.): 39-48.
Arensberg, Conrad D. 1951. "Behavior and Organization: Industrial Studies."
In Social Psychology at the Crossroads, ed. John H. Rohrer and Muzafer Sherif,
324-52. New York: Harper.
Arensberg, Conrad D., et al. 1957. Research in Industrial Human Relations: A
Critical AppraisaL New York: Harper and Row.
Arensberg, Conrad D., and Geoffrey Tootell. 1957. "Plant Sociology: Real
Discoveries and New Problems." In Common Frontiers of the Soda! Sciences,
ed. Mirra Komarovsky, 310-37. Glencoe, Ill.: Free Press.
Argyris, Chris. 1954. "The Present State of Research in Human Relations in
Industry: A Working Paper." New Haven: Labor and Management Center,
Yale University.
- - . 1957. Personality and Organization: The Conflict between System and the
Individual. New York: Harper and Row.
253
References
254
References
255
References
256
References
257
References
258
References
259
References
260
References
261
References
Fried, Amy E. 1987. Industrial Relations Research Institute: A Brief History, 1947-
1987. Madison: Industrial Relations Research Institute, University of
Wisconsin.
Friedman, Milton. 1951. "Some Comments on the Significance of labor Unions
for Economic Policy." In The Impact of the Union, ed. David McCord Wright,
204-34. New York: Harcourt Brace.
- - . 1953. Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Friedman, Milton, and Anna Schwartz. 1963. A Monetary History of the United
States: 1867-1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Furniss, Edgar S. 1925. Labor Problems. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Gallagher, Daniel G., and Cynthia Gramm. 1991. "Integrating Behavioral and
Economic Perspectives of Strike Activity: Promise or Illusion?" James Mad-
ison University, Harrisonburg, Va. Unpublished.
Gallagher, Daniel G. , and George Strauss. 1991. "Union Membership Attitudes
and Participation." In The State of the Unions, ed. Daniel Gallagher et al. ,
139-74. Madison: IRRA.
Gardner, Burleigh B. 1946. "The Factory as a Social System." In Industry and
Society, ed. William Foote Whyte, 4-20. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Getman, Julius, Stephen Goldberg, and Jeanne Herman. 1976. Union Repre-
sentation Elections: Law and ReaUty. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Ginsburg, Woodrow, E. Robert Livernash, Herbert Parnes, and George Strauss.
1970. A Review of Industrial Relations Research, vol. 1. Madison: IRRA.
Goddard, John. 1992a. "Beyond Empiricism: Towards a Reconstruction of IR
Theory and Research." In Advances in Industrial and Labor Relations, ed. David
Lewin, David Lipsky, and Donna Sockell. Forthcoming.
- - . 1992b. "Contemporary Industrial Relations Ideologies: A Study of the
Values and Beliefs of Canadian Academics." Relations Industrielles. Forth-
coming.
Golden, Clinton S., and Virginia D. Parker. 1955. Causes of Industrial Peace.
New York: Harper and Bros.
Golden, Clinton S., and Harold J. Ruttenberg. 1942. The Dynamics of Industrial
Democracy. New York: Harper and Bros.
Goldthorpe, John. 1984. Order and Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism. Oxford:
Clarendon Press.
Gordon, Robert A., and James E. Howell. 1959. Higher Education for Business.
New York: Columbia University Press.
Gouldner, Alvin W. 1954. PatternsofindustrialBureaucracy. Glencoe, Ill.: Free
Press.
Graham, Rev. Robert C. 1948. "The Industrial Relations Curriculum in Col-
leges and University." Master's thesis, Catholic University.
Gray, Wayne B. 1987. "The Cost of Regulation: OSHA, EPA and the Pro-
ductivity Slowdown." American Economic Review 77 (Dec.): 998-1006.
Greenwood, Ronald G., and Charles D. Wrege. 1986. "The Hawthorne Stud-
262
References
263
References
264
References
Industrial Relations Section, Princeton University. 1930. Selected Book Ust for
the Office of an Industrial Relations Executive. Princeton: Princeton University.
- - . 1939. Problems and Policies in Industrial Relations in a War Economy: A
Selected, Annotated Bibliography. Princeton: Princeton University.
- - . 1986. The Industrial Relations Section of Princeton University, 1922-1985.
Princeton: Princeton University.
Jacoby, Sanford. 1985. Employing Bureaucracy: Managers, Unions, and the Trans-
formation of Work in American Industry, 1900-1945. New York: Columbia
University Press.
- - . 1990. "The New Institutionalism: What It Can Learn from the Old."
Industrial Relations 29 (Spring): 316-40.
Johnson, George. 1984. "Changes over Time in the Union-Nonunion Wage
Differential." In The Economics of Trade Unions, ed. Jean-Jacques Rosa, 3-
19. Boston: Kluwer Nijhoff.
Johnson, Harry, and Peter Mieszkowski. 1969. "The Effects of Unionization
on the Distribution of Income: A General Equilibrium Approach." Quarterly
Journal of Economics 84 (Nov.): 539-61.
Johnson, Robert W. 1949. "Human Relations in Modern Business." Harvard
Business Review 27 (Sept.): 29-55.
Jucius, Michael J. 1948. Personnel Management. Chicago: Irwin.
Justin, Brother F. S. C. 1949. "The Study of Industrial and Labor Relations
in Catholic Colleges." Industrial and Labor Relations Review 3 (Oct.): 70-75.
Kanter, Rosabeth Moss. 1989. When Giants Learn to Dance. New York: Simon
and Schuster.
Kassalow, Everett. 1985. "Trade Unionism: Once More into the Future." Pro-
ceedings of the Thirty-eighth Annual Meeting, Industrial Relations Research As-
sociation, 1-13. Madison: IRRA.
Katz, Harry C. 1991. The Future of Industrial Relations. Ithaca: ILR Press.
Kaufman, Bruce E. 1988. "The Postwar View of Labor Markets and Wage
Determination." In How Labor Markets Work, ed. Bruce E. Kaufman, 145-
203. Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books.
- - . 1989a. "Labor's Inequality of Bargaining Power: Changes over Time
and Implications for Public Policy." Journal of Labor Research 10 (Summer):
285-98.
- - . 1989b. "Models of Man in Industrial Relations Research." Industrial
and Labor Relations Review 43 (Oct.): 72-88.
- - - . 1991a. "Labor's Inequality of Bargaining Power: Myth or Reality?"
Journal of Labor Research 12 (Spring): 151-66.
- - . 1991b. "Research Expectations in IRIHR Units: The View from the
Beebe Institute." In Proceedings of the Forty-fourth Annual Winter Meeting,
Industrial Relations Research Association, 502-9. Madison: IRRA.
- - . 1993. "The Evolution of Thought on the Competitive Nature of Labor
Markets." In Labor Economics and Industrial Relations: Markets and Institutions,
ed. Clark Kerr and Paul Staudohar. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Forthcoming.
265
References
Kaufman, Bruce E., and Paula E. Stephan. 1987. "The Determinants of Inter-
industry Wage Growth in the 1970s." Industrial Relations 26 (Spring): 186-94.
Kelly, Laurence. 1987. "Industrial Relations at Queen's: The First Fifty Years."
Relations Industrielles 42 (3): 475-99.
Kennedy, Dudley R. 1920. "The Future of Industrial Relations." Industrial
Maru1gement, March, 227-31.
Kerr, Clark. 1950. "Labor Markets: Their Character and Consequences." Amer·
ican Economic Review 40 (May): 278-91.
- - . 1954a. "The Balkanization of Labor Markets." In Labor Mobility and
Economic Opportunity, ed. E. Wight Bakke, 92-110. New York: Wiley.
- - . 1954b. "Industrial Relations and the Liberal Pluralist." In Proceedings
of the Seventh Annual Meeting, Industrial Relations Research Association, 2-16.
Madison: IRRA.
- - . 1978. "Industrial Relations Research: A Personal Retrospective." In-
dustrial Relations 17 (May): 131-42.
- - . 1983. "A Perspective on Industrial Relations Research-Thirty-six
Years Later." In Proceedings of the Thirty-sixth Annual Winter Meeting, Industrial
Relations Research Association, 14-21. Madison: IRRA.
- - . 1988. "The Neoclassical Revisionists in Labor Economics (1940-
1960)-RIP." In How Labor Markets Work, ed. Bruce E. Kaufman, 1-46.
Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books.
Kerr, Clark, John Dunlop, Frederick Harbison, and Charles Myers. 1960. In-
dustrialism and Industrial Man. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Kerr, Clark, and Lloyd H. Fisher. 1950. "Effects of Environment and Admin-
istration on Job Evaluation." Harvard Business Review 28 (May): 77-96.
- - . 1957. "Plant Sociology: The Elite and the Aborigines." In Common
Frontiers of the Social Sciences, ed. Mirra Komarovski, 281-309. Glencoe, Ill.:
Free Press.
Kerr, Clark, and Abraham Siegel. 1954. "The Interindustry Propensity to
Strike: An International Comparison." In Industrial Conflict, ed. Arthur Korn-
hauser, Robert Dubin, and Arthur Ross, 189-212. New York: McGraw-Hill.
- - . 1955. "The Structuring of the Labor Force in Industrial Society: New
Dimensions and New Questions." Industrial and Labor Relations Review 8
(Jan.): 151-68.
Keynes, John Maynard. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and
Money. New York: Harcourt Brace.
Keyserling, Leon. 1945. "Why the Wagner Act?" In The Wagner Act: Ten Years
Later, ed. Louis Silverberg, 5-33. Washington, D.C.: Bureau of National ·
Affairs.
Kleiner, Morris M., et al. 1987. Human Resources and the Performance of the
Firm. Madison: IRRA.
Knox, John B. 1955. The Sociology of Industrial Relations. New York: Random
House.
Kochan, Thomas. 1980. Collective Bargaining and Industrial Relations. Home-
wood, Ill.: R. D. Irwin.
266
References
267
References
United States, 1896-1932, vol. 3. ed. John R. Commons et al., 51-396. New
York: Macmillan.
Lester, Richard A. 1941; 2d. ed., rev., 1964. Economics of Labor. New York:
Macmillan.
- - . 1946a. "Shortcomings of Marginal Analysis for Wage-Employment
Problems." American Economic Review 36 (March): 63-82.
- - . 1946b. "Wage Diversity and Its Theoretical Implications." Review of
Economics and Statistics 28 (Aug.): 152-59.
- - . 1947a. "Marginalism, Minimum Wages, and the Labor Market." Amer-
ican Economic Review 37 (March): 135-48.
- - . 1947b. "Reflections on the Labor Monopoly Issue." Journal of Political
Economy 55 (Dec.): 13-36.
- - . 1951. Labor and Industrial Relations: A General Analysis. New York:
Macmillan.
- - . 1952. "A Range Theory of Wage Differentials." Industrial and Labor
Relations Review 5 (July): 433-50.
- - . 1954. Hiring Practices and Labor Competition. Princeton: Industrial Re-
lations Section, Princeton University.
- - . 1973. "Manipulation of the Labor Market." In The Next Twenty-five
Years of Industrial Relations, ed. Gerald G. Somers, 47-55. Madison: IRRA.
Levitan, Sar, Wilbur Cohen, and Robert Lampman. 1968. Towards Freedom
from Want. Madison: IRRA.
Lewin, David. 1987. "Industrial Relations as a Strategic Variable." In Human
Resources and the Performance of the Firm, ed. Morris Kleiner et al., 1-41.
Madison: IRRA.
- - . 1988a. "The Industrial Relations (IR) Content of MBA Degree Pro-
grams in the U.S." In Proceedings of the Forty-first Annual Winter Meeting,
Industrial Relations Research Association, 474-78. Madison: IRRA.
- - . 1988b. Letter to IRRA Comprehensive Review Committee on the
survey of the membership of the Industrial Relations Research Association.
- - . 1991. "The Contemporary Human Resource Management Challenge
to Industrial Relations." In The Future of Industrial Relations, ed. Harry C.
Katz, 82-99. Ithaca: ILR Press.
Lewin, David, and Peter Feuille. 1983. "Behavioral Research in Industrial
Relations." Industrial and Labor Relations Review 36 (April): 341-60.
Lewin, Kurt, R. Lippitt, and R. White. 1939. "Patterns of Aggressive Behavior
in Experimentally Created Social Climates." Journal of Social Psychology 10
(May): 271-99.
Lewis, H. Gregg. 1951. "The Labor-Monopoly Problem: A Positive Program."
Journal of Political Economy 69 (Aug.): 277-87.
- - . 1956. "Hours of Work and Hours of Leisure." In Proceedings of the
Ninth Annual Meeting, Industrial Relations Research Association, 192-206. Mad-
ison: IRRA.
- - . 1963. Unions and Relative Wages in the United States. Chicago: University
of Chicago Press.
268
References
269
References
270
References
2 71
References
Reynolds, Morgan 0. 1984. Power and Privilege: Labor Unions in America. New
York: Universe Books.
Rezler, Julius. 1968a. "The Place of the Industrial Relations Program in the
Organizational Structure of the University." Industrial and Labor Relations
Review 21 (Jan.): 251-58.
- - . 1968b. "Administrative Arrangements in Industrial Relations Cen-
ters." In The Role of Industrial Relations Centers, Proceedings of a Regional
Meeting of the International Industrial Relations Association, 1-11. Madison:
Industrial Relations Research Institute, University of Wisconsin.
Roberts, Benjamin C. 1972. "Affluence and Disruption." In Man and the Social
Sciences, ed. William A. Robson, 245-72. London: London School of Eco-
nomics and Political Science.
Robinson, Joan. 1933. The Economics of Imperfect Competition. London:
Macmillan.
Rockefeller, John D., Jr. 1923. "Representation in Industry." In Problems in
Personnel Management, ed. Daniel Bloomfield and Meyer Bloomfield, 517-
28. New York: H. W. Wilson.
Roethlisberger, Fritz). 1977. The Elusive Phenomena. Cambridge: Harvard Uni-
versity Press.
Roethlisberger, Fritz J., and William J. Dickson. 1939. Management and the
Worker. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Ross, Arthur M. 1948. Trade Union Wage Policy. Berkeley: University of Cal-
ifornia Press.
- - . 1961. "Introduction to a New Journal." Industrial Relations 1 (1): 5-
7.
- - . 1964. "Labor Courses: The Need for Radical Reconstruction." Industrial
Relations 4 (Oct.): 1-17.
Ross, Dorothy. 1991. The Origins of American Social Science. Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press.
Rothbaum, Melvin. 1967. "Research Note: University of Illinois Institute of
Labor and Industrial Relations." Industrial and Labar Relations Review 20 (July):
733-35.
Russell Sage Foundation. 1919. "Industrial Relations: A Selected Bibliography."
Bulletin of the Russell Sage Foundation Library 35.
Ruttenberg, Stanley H. 1958. "Appraisal of Education in Industrial and Human
Relations." In Proceedings of the Eleventh Annual Meeting, Industrial Relations
Research Association, 243-47. Madison: IRRA.
Ryan, Frederick L. 1936. Industrial Relations in the San Francisco Building Trades.
Norman: University of Oklahoma Press.
Sayles, Leonard, and George Strauss. 1953. The Local Union: Its Place in the
Industrial Plant. New York: Harper.
Schatz, Ronald W. 1993. "From Commons to Dunlop: Rethinking the Field
and Theory of Industrial Relations." In Defining Industrial Democracy: Wark
Relations in Twentieth Century America, ed. Howell Harris and Nelson Lich-
tenstein. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Forthcoming.
272
References
273
References
274
References
275
References
Strauss, George, Daniel Gallagher, and Jack Fiorito. 1991. The State of the
Unions. Madison: IRRA.
Tannenbaum, Frank. 1921. The Labor Movement: Its Conservative Functions and
Social Consequences. New York: Putnam.
Tannenbaum, Robert, and Warren Schmidt. 1958. "How to Choose a Lead-
ership Pattern." Harvard Business Review 36 (March-April): 95-101.
Taylor, Frederick. 1895. "A Piece Rate System, Being a Step toward Partial
Solution of the Labor Problem." Transactions 16: 856-83.
Tead, Ordway. 1921. "The Problem of Graduate Training in Personnel Admin-
istration." Journal of Political Economy 29 (May): 353-67.
- - . 1929. Human Nature and Management. New York: McGraw-Hill.
- - . 1931. "Human Nature and Management." In Preventive Management:
Mental Hygiene in Industry, ed. Henry B. Elkind, 23-52. New York: B. C.
Forbes.
- - . 1938. "Industrial Relations 1939 Model." Personnel Journal 17 (5):
160-67.
Tead, Ordway, and Henry C. Metcalf. 1920. Personnel Administration: Its Prin-
ciples and Practice. New York: McGraw-Hill.
- - . 1933. Labor Relations under the Recovery Act. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Teplow, Leo. 1976. "Industrial Relations Counselors at Fifty Years." In People,
Progress, and Employee Relations, ed. Richard Beaumont, 3-8. Charlottesville:
University of Virginia Press.
Thorndike, Edward L. 1922. "The Psychology of Labor." Harper's, June, 790-
806.
Thurow, Lester. 1988. "Producer Economics." In Proceedings of the Forty-first
Annual Meeting, Industrial Relations Research Association, 9-20. Madison:
IRRA.
Time Magazine. 1952. "Human Relations: A New Art Brings Revolution to
Industry." April 14, 96-97.
Tolles, Arnold. 1958. "Discussion." In Proceedings of the Eleventh Annual Meet-
ing, Industrial Relations Research Association, 253-57. Madison: IRRA.
Trahair, R. C. S. 1984. The Humanist Temper: The Life and Work of Elton
Mayo. New Brunswick: Transaction Books.
Tripp, L. Reed. 1964. "The Industrial Relations Discipline in American Uni-
versities." Industrial and Labor Relations Review 17 (July): 612-18.
U.S. Congress. 1916. Industrial Relations: Final Report and Testimony. Vol. 1.
Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Labor. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 1921. Personnel Research
Agencies. Bulletin no. 299. Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office.
- - . 1930. Personnel Research Agencies. Bulletin no. 518. Washington, D.C.:
Government Printing Office.
Van Metre, Thurman W. 1954. A History of the Graduate School of Business,
Columbia University. New York: Columbia University Press.
Verma, Ani!. 1985. "Relative Flow of Capital to Union and Nonunion Plants
within a Firm." Industrial Relations 24 (Fall): 395-405.
276
References
Voos, Paula, and Lawrence Mishel. 1986. "The Union Impact on Profits:
Evidence from Industry Price-Cost Data." journal of Labor Economics 4 (Jan.):
105-33.
- - . 1991. Unions and Economic Competitiveness. Armonk, N.Y.: M. E.
Sharpe.
Walker, Kenneth, 1977. "Towards Useful Theorising about Industrial Rela-
tions." British]oumal oflndustrial Relations 15 (Nov.): 307-16.
Walter, Jack E. 1934. Effect of the Depression on Industrial Relations Programs.
New York: National Industrial Conference Board.
Walton, Richard. 1985. "Toward a Strategy of Eliciting Employee Commitment
through Policies of Mutuality." In HRM: Trends and Challenges, ed. Richard
Walton and Paul Lawrence, 35-65. Cambridge: Harvard Business School
Press.
Walton, Richard, and Paul Lawrence, eds. 1985. HRM: Trends.and Challenges.
Cambridge: Harvard Business School Press.
Walton, Richard, and Robert McKersie. 1965. A Behavioral Theory of Labor
Negotiations. New York: McGraw-Hill.
WardS., A Wagner, E. Armstrong, J. Goodman, and J. Davis. 1975. "Rules
in Industrial Relations Theory." Industrial Relations ]oumal6 (1): 14-30.
Ware, Caroline F. 1946. Labor Education in Universities. New York: American
Labor Education Service.
Warner, W. Lloyd, and Joseph Low. 1947. The Social System of the Modem
Factory. Vol. 4, The Strike: A Social Analysis. New Haven: Yale University
Press.
Watkins, Gordon S. 1922. An Introduction to the Study of Labor Problems. New
York: Thomas Crowell.
- - . 1928. Labor Management. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Watkins, Gordon S., and Paul A. Dodd. 1940. Labor Problems. 3d ed. New
York: Thomas Crowell.
Webb, Sidney, and Beatrice Webb. 1894. A History of Trade Unionism. London:
Longmans, Green.
- - . 1897. Industrial Democracy. London: Longmans, Green.
Webbink, Paul. 1954. "Methods and Objectives of Industrial Relations Re-
search." In Proceedings of the Seventh Annual Meeting, Industrial Relations Re-
search Association, 102-6. Madison: IRRA.
Weber, Arnold R. 1987a. "Understanding Change in Industrial Relations: A
Second Look." In Proceedings of the Fortieth Annual Meeting, Industrial Relations
Research Association, 10-23. Madison: IRRA.
- - . 1987b. "Industrial Relations and Higher Education." In The Future of
Industrial Relations, ed. Daniel J. B. Mitchell, 8-28. Los Angeles: Institute
of Industrial Relations, University of California.
Weber, Arnold R., Frank H. Cassell, and Woodrow L. Ginsburg. 1969. Public-
Private Manpower Policies. Madison: IRRA.
Weiler, Paul C. 1990. Governing the Workplace. Cambridge: Harvard University
Press.
277
References
278
References
279
INDEX
Academy of Management, 153, 167, 184, Blum, Solomon, 84, 224, 228
185 Boston Employment Managers' Association,
Academy of Political Science, 206 204
Adams, Henry Carter, 31 Brissenden, Paul, 47
Advances in Industrial and Labor Relations, British University Industrial Relations
150 Association, 216
Alabama, University of, 145 Brody, David, 113
Allied Social Science Association (ASSA), Brooks, Earl, 219
181, 185 Brophy, john, 219
American Association of Collegiate Schools Brown, J. Douglas, 71, 201
of Business (AACSB), 144, 212, 217 Burling, Temple, 219
American Association for Labor Research, Burton, Montague, 211
230 Bush, George, 141
American Economic Association (AEA),
70, 90, 155, 181, 221, 228, 229 California, University of (Berkeley), 63,
American Federation of Labor (AFL), 62, 66, 103, 143, 148, 216, 220
215 California Institute of Technology, 46, 57,
American Management Association, 11, 212
46, 49, 205, 206 Canada, 199, 216, 241
Argyris, Chris, 91, 223, 224, 232-33 Canadian Industrial Relations Association,
216
Bakke, E. Wight, 71, 81, 234 Chamberlain, Edward, 91
Balderston, C. Canby, 50 Chamberlain, Neil, 92, 129
Barbash, Jack, 134, 149-50 Chicago, University of, 10-11, 63, 80, 92,
Bargaining power, inequality of, 28, 32-33, 122, 147. 217, 225, 226
34, 38, 41, 61, 171-72, 215, 224 Civic Federation, 8
Barnard, Chester, 206, 207, 221 Clague, Ewan, 71
Barnett, George, 12, 207 Clark, John Bates, 31, 207
Beach, Charles, 219 Classical economics, 4-5, 26, 30, 200-201
Becker, Gary, 91, 122, 226 Cleveland State University, 103, 242
Behavioral sciences, 51, 76, 90, 101, 102, Collective bargaining, 8, 9, 19, 20, 25, 28,
115-16, 119-21, 124-25, 129-30, 153- 34, 40-43, 48-49, 61, 68-69, 81-82,
54, 166, 237 86-89, 98-99, 102, 104, 113-14, 124,
Bloomfield, Daniel, 11, 57, 204 130, 133, 138-43, 170-75
Bloomfield, Meyer, 11, 57, 204 Columbia University, 47, 147, 243
281
Index
Colorado Fuel and Iron Co., 46, 211 Fair Labor Standards Act, 61, 138
Commission on Industrial Relations, 3, 8, Fayol, Henri, 207
9, 199, 213 Federal Reserve Bank, 35, 40, 210
Commons, John R., 8, 10, 12, 30-32, 33, Feldman, Herman, 12
35, 38, 39, 54-56, 57, 60, 70, 82, 85, Follett, Mary Parker, 206
134, 200, 20!, 203, 206, 207, 206, 210, Form, William, 50, 83, 116, 213, 237-38
2!2, 213, 214, 224, 225, 227 Freeman, Richard, 149, 244
Company unions. See Employee Friedman, Milton, 91, !22, 224
representation plans Full employment, 31, 34, 40
Congress of Industrial Organizations (CIO),
62 Gantt, Henry, 22
Cornell University, 63-64, 66, 67, 71, 72, Gardner, Burleigh, 80, 92
80, 103, 143, 144, 217, 218-19, 232, Georgia State University, 103, 145, 243,
25!-52 248
German historical school, 30, 31, 228
Great Britain, 86, 151, 199, 200-201, 211,
Davis, Ralph, 207 213, 2!6, 241, 243
Day, Edmund, 72 Great Depression, 60, 63, 86, !22
Dennison, Henry, 206
Derber, Milton, 91, 94, 235 Haber, William, 71
Dickson, William, 51, 78, 101 Harbison, Frederick, 91, 94, 227
Douglas, Paul H., 11, 55, 207, 225, 226 Harvard University, 10, 24, 51, 77, 82,
Drive system, 7-8, 9, 26 220
Dunlop, John, 71, 85, 87, 88-91, 94, 95, Hawaii, University of, 63
97, 98, 99-102, 118, 124, 148, 149, Hawthorne experiment, 21, 24, 51, 76-80,
!52, 170, 184, 217, 226, 227, 228, 234- 82, 205-6, 222
36, 240, 250 Heneman, Herberr, Jr., 67
Durkheim, Emile, 221 Hicks, Clarence, 35, 46-47, 57, 134, 203,
206, 211, 2!2
Hicks, John, 86, 87, 89, 226, 227, 228
Economic insecurity, 32, 33-34, 35 Hollander, Jacob, 207
Economic man, 26, 207 Homans, George, 77, 92, 95, 101, 223,
Ely, Richard, 31, 207 224, 231
Emerson, Harrington, 22 Howd, Cloice, 201
Employee representation plans, 8, 28-29, Hoxie, Robert, 8, 54, 200, 225
35, 48, 60, 203 Human relations: battle over, 95-99, 100-
Employee Responsibilities and Rights journal, 101, 232; as a field of study, 68, 72, 82,
150 83, 90, 92, !20, 130, 204, 207, 2!7,
Employer-employee relations, 10, 11, 12, 222, 233, 238-39; Hawthorne version,
18, 21, 22, 33, 63, 79, 89, 167, 231 53, 76-83, 96, 22!; pre-Hawthorne, 21,
Employers. See Management 23-27, 37, 38, 40, 48, 76, 80, 206
Employment Act of 1946, 138 Human resource management, 119-21,
Employment management, 21, 201, 205 140, 151, 162, 202, 204, 239
Employment Managers' Association, 11 Human Resource Management Review, 154
Employment relations (term), 167, 176, Human resources (HR), field of, xiv, 20,
182, 248 118-21, 142, 143-48, 158, 162-63, 168-
Employment relationship, 5, 8-11, 18, 2!, 70, 174, 176-77, 180, 181
29, 33, 37, 50, 61, 93, 109, 128, 129, Herzberg, Frederick, 26, 92
158, 168, 176, 229; conflict of interests,
22, 25, 30, 37-38, 60, 96, 202, 232; Illinois, University of, 63, 66, 68, 143,
congruence (mutuality) of interests, 22, 144, 216, 217, 219, 220
25, 27, 29, 30, 31, 37-38, 60 Industrial and Labar Relations Review, 71-73,
Employment systems, 178, 25 1 91, 99, 113-14, 125, 134, 150, 214, 237
England. See Great Britain Industrial conflict, 6, 9, 11, 13, 27, 28, 32,
282
Index
33, 37, 38, 40, 62-63, 68, 75-76, 131, Institutional economics, 30-32, 56, 58, 61,
141, 215, 231, 232, 251 212, 213, 214, 225, 227, 228
Industrial democracy, 23, 27-29, 33, 34, Institutional labor economics, 19-20, 30-
35, 37, 40, 85, 88 35, 51, 54-56, 84-85, 88, 124-25, 207-
Industrial psychology, 8, 54, 72, 202, 207, 8, 210, 215, 218, 226, 227, 229
215 Institutional labor economics (ILE) school,
Industrial relations: art versus science, 106- 20, 29-43, 48-49, 51, 58, 67, 68, 71,
7; curriculum, 10, 47-48, 63-64, 66, 83, 95, 97-98, 102, 113, 123, 128, 129-
144-46, 176, 238; definition of, 18, 49- 30, 133-34, 140-41, 147, 151, 158,
50, 83, 158, 205, 219, 247; enrollment, 170-73, 203-4, 213, 230, 232, 233, 241
144-45, 162, 221; external versus Interdisciplinary research, 80, 81, 93-95,
internal viewpoint, 36, 96-97, 129-30, 110-12, 123-24, 145, 230, 240
168-70, 175; as a field of study, 9-18, International Industrial Relations
63, 82-83, 88, 92, 95, 100-101, 104, Association, 243
112-25, 128, 158-61, 167-75, 212, 223, International Labor Organization, 57
230, 231, 232, 235, 237, 240, 244. 249- Inter-University Study of Labor Problems in
50; goals of, 13, 21, 133, 202; Economic Development, 94, 227, 228,
intellectual family tree, 50-54, 116-17; 231
and labor education, 65-66, 68-69, 162; Iowa, University of, 103, 243
and labor problems, 4-5, 9, 11-12, 88,
102, 201; multidisciplinary nature of, 12, Janet, Pierre, 221
18, 47, 64, 67, 70, 72. 75, 92-95, 102, Journal of Applied Psychology, 50, 179
107-11, 125-28, 130, 143-44. 164, 177, Journal of Labor Economics, 179
201-202, 212-13, 218; narrow Journal of Labor Research, 150, 245
(collective bargaining) version, xiv, 101-
2, 104, 112-21, 132-35, 144, 158, 159- Kansas Court of Industrial Relations, 11
60, 164-65, 167-68, 170-75, 176, 197; Kerr, Clark, 71, 85, 87, 88-91, 94, 95, 97,
origins of term, 3-4, 199-200, 201; 98, 124, 152, 184, 220, 224, 226, 227,
Ph.D. programs in, 64, 65, 103, 128, 228, 236, 240
143, 217-18, 240; research, 49-54, 91- Keynes, John M., 86, 215
95, 96, 103, 113-14, 119, 125-28, 148- Kochan, Thomas, 117, 148
52,163-65,169-70,177-80,230,237, Konvitz, Milton, 71
240; strategy for change, 167-85; theory,
99-101, 105, 108-10, 125-31, 133, 148- Labor economics, 49, 54, 55, 84-91, 113-
49, 217-18, 243; units (academic 14, 121-25, 205, 208, 212, 226, 229
programs), 10, 45-49, 63-69, 93, 103, Labor legislation, 34, 48, 61, 84, 85, 89-
143-48, 159, 160, 162-63, 175-77, 211- 90, 208, 225, 238
12, 215-20, 242; values, 68, 133-35, Labor market, 6, 30-32, 33, 34, 40, 61,
241 84-91, 208, 212, 214, 224, 225
Industrial Relations, 103, 113-14, 127, 150, Labor mobility, 32, 33, 88
216, 237 Labor problems: causes of, 5-8, 22, 25, 29,
Industrial Relations Association of America 30, 32-35, 36-43, 123, 130-32, 208,
(IRAA), 11, 19, 46, 57, 69-70, 201, 210; concept of, 4-5, 48-49, 200, 201;
203, 205, 210 reform of, 8-9, 10, 20, 21-29, 30, 34-
Industrial Relations Counselors, 46, 57 43, 48-49, 56, 123, 208, 210; texts, 48-
Industrial Relations-Quarterly Review, 216 49, 55-56, 205, 211, 226, 250
Industrial Relations Research Association Labor turnover, 4, 9, 40
(IRRA), 69-71, 88, 90, 91, 99, 103, Laissez-faire, 5, 201, 204, 207
114, 117-18, 132, 152-55, 165-67, 180- Laval University, 216
85, 220, 233, 244, 245, 246, 247, 248, Leighton, Alexander, 219
252 Leiserson, William, 71, 200, 203
Industrial sociology, 51, 52, 68, 71, 95, Lescohier, Don, 207
237-38 Lester, Richard, 70, 71, 85, 87, 88-91,
Industrial Workers of the World, 5 184, 215, 224, 226, 228
283
Index
284
Index
Psychology, 25, 53, 79-80, 81, 92, 154, Strauss, George, 91, ll8, 232
202, 206-7, 236, 238 Strikes. See Industrial conflict
Purdue University, 146
Taft, Phillip, 55
Queen's University, 46 Taft, William Howard, 3, 199
Taylor, Frederick, 8, 22, 24, 25, 36, 201
Reagan, Ronald, 141 Taylor, George, 71, 91
Reder, Melvin, 91, 122, 224, 246 Tead, Ordway, 21, 48, 206
Rees, Albert, 91, 122, 226, 246
Research methodology, 85, 106-7, llO, Ulman, Lloyd, 91, 245
114, 122-23, 125-28, 164, 179-80, 214, Unemployment, 6-7, 9, 33, 40, 60, 86,
218, 238, 244 208; compensation, 35, 61, 208
Reynolds, Lloyd, 71, 85, 87, 88-91, 226 Unions, 8, 9, 13, 20, 31, 48, 65, 68, 81-
Ricardo, David, 30 82, 89-90, 101, 149, 172-73, 225, 229,
Robinson, Joan, 86 238-43; ILE view of, 34-35, 41-43, 85,
Rockhurst College, 63, 212 88, 89, 210; membership, 60, 61-62,
Rockefeller, John D., Jr., 46, 47, 57, 211 86-87, 132-33, 143, 159, 241; PM view
Roethlisberger, Fritz, 51, 77-80, 100, 232 of, 27-29, 40-41, 96-97, 231-32; role in
Roosevelt, Franklin, 61 improved industrial relations, 27-28, 31,
Rorty, Malcolm, 210 34, 48-49, 210
Ross, Arthur, 85, 87, 91, 235, 236 United States Industrial Commission, 8
Rutgers University, 63, 66, 143 University Council of Industrial Relations
and Human Resources Programs
Samuelson, Paul, 91, 213, 227 (UCIRHRP), xiv, 144, 166, 177
Saposs, David, 207
Science-building, 12-13, 20, 66, 100, 106, Veblen, Thorstein, 30, 31, 225
125-28, 161, 167-68, 170, 182-83, 202, Viteles, Morris, 215
204, 218, 220, 228, 237
Scientific management, 8, 21-24, 26, 36, Wages, 8, 22, 28, 31, 33, 35, 37, 60, 86,
48, 77 88, 139, 209-10, 226, 228
Scott, Walter Dill, 8 Wagner Act. See National Labor Relations
Selekman, Benjamin, 77, 101, 224 Act
Seligman, Edwin, 31, 207 Walton, Richard, 119, 148
Shultz, George, 88, 124 War Labor Board, 9, 62, 87, 218
Stichter, Sumner, 55, 71, 200, 207, 225 Warner, W. Lloyd, 80, 92, 222
Smith, Adam, 30 Warwick University, 216
Social Darwinism, 4-5, 200-201 Watkins, Gordon, 55
Social insurance programs, 19, 35, 48, 61, Wayne State University, 212
208, 238 Webb, Sidney and Beatrice, 27, 30, 34,
Social Science Research Council, 12, 220- 213
21, 233 Webbink, Paul, 220
Social security, 35, 61, 138, 238 Weber, Arnold, 124
Socialism, 4, 5, 8, 204, 220 Weber, Max, 207
Society for Human Resource Management, Welfare work, 8, 21, 22-23
153 Wertheim, Jacob, 10, 82
Sociology, 92, 95, 119, 154, 227, 230, Western Electric Co., 24, 51, 76, 77
233, 237-38 Wharton School (Industrial Research
Solow, Robert, 227 Unit), 10, 45-46, 50
Somers, Gerald, 130, 134, 148, 249 Whitehead, T. N., 51, 77
Spates, Thomas, 57, 203 Whyte, William Foote, 80, 92, 95, 101,
Stanford University, 46, 212 219, 220, 223, 224, 231, 233, 235
Stem, James, 183 Wilensky, Harold, 92, 230-31, 237
Stewart, Bryce, 57 Willets, Joseph, 12, 45-46
Stigler, George, 89, 90, 122 Williams, Whiting, 205
285
Index
286
ABOUT THE AUTHOR
Bruce E. Kaufman is director of the W. T. Beebe Institute of Personnel
and Employment Relations and is a professor of economics at Georgia
State University, where he has served on the faculty since 1977. He
received his Ph.D. in economics from the University of Wisconsin and
has published widely in the field of industrial relations.