69 Geo Wash LRev 693
69 Geo Wash LRev 693
69 Geo Wash LRev 693
Citations:
Please note: citations are provided as a general guideline. Users should consult their preferred
citation format's style manual for proper citation formatting.
-- Your use of this HeinOnline PDF indicates your acceptance of HeinOnline's Terms and
Conditions of the license agreement available at
https://heinonline.org/HOL/License
-- The search text of this PDF is generated from uncorrected OCR text.
-- To obtain permission to use this article beyond the scope of your license, please use:
Copyright Information
The Use of Criminal Law Remedies to
Deter and Punish Cartels and
Bid-Rigging
Donald I. Baker*
* Senior Partner, Baker & Miller PLLC; former Assistant Attorney General in charge of
the Antitrust Division, U.S. Department of Justice. Mr. Baker wishes to express his thanks to his
colleague Christine J. Sommer for all her hard and insightful work in helping to create this
paper.
1 See James M. Griffin, Criminal Cartel Status Reports, Remarks at the 49th Annual
Conference of the American Bar Association Meeting of the Committee on Criminal Procedure
and Enforcement (Mar. 28, 2001), http:llwww.usdoj.govlatr/publiclspeeches/8063.htm.
2 Id. For example, Hoffman-La Roche and BASF were recently fined $500 million and
$225 million for their parts in the vitamins cartel. Id. Additional examples are listed infra, at
Part IV.C.
3 See Stephen Labaton, The World Gets Tough on Price Fixers, N.Y. TirMES, June 3, 2001,
§ 3, at 1.
4 In re Vitamins Antitrust Litig., 2000-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) 72,914 (D.D.C. 2000) (Vita-
mins); United States v. Andreas, 216 F.3d 645 (7th Cir. 2000) (Lysine); In re Auction Houses
Antitrust Litig., 2001-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) 73,170 (S.D.N.Y. 2001) (Art Auctions); Ferromin
Int'l Trade v. UCAR Int'l., Inc., 153 F. Supp. 2d 700 (E.D. Pa 2001) (Graphite Electrodes); see
Labaton supra note 3.
5 This point is dramatically illustrated by a recent book documenting in detail the FBI and
DOJ investigation of Archer Daniels Midland Co. and its coconspirators in the lysine and citric
acid cartels. KURT EICHEiNivALD, THE INWoarm r (2000).
6 See generallyScott D. Hammond, When Calculating the Costs and Benefits of Applying
for Corporate Amnesty, How Do You Put a Price Tag on an Individual's Freedom?, Address
Before The Fifteenth Annual National Institute on White Collar Crime (Mar. 8, 2001), http://
www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/7647.htm.
7 See, e.g., Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act, Pub. L. No. 93-528, § 3, 88 Stat. 1706,
1708 (1974) (current version at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-3 (1994)). An individual defendant faces a greater
risk of jail time today than even a few years ago. As detailed by Mr. Hammond, approximately
fifty individual defendants were imprisoned for antitrust and related offenses during 1999 and
2000-this is greater than the total number of persons incarcerated in the five years previous.
Hammond, supra note 6, at 9. In addition, during 1999 and 2000, individuals served 12,246 days
in jail (as compared to 9,920 days as a total for the five years previous), which is roughly thirty-
four years of jail time and included fifteen sentences of one year or more in jail. Id.
8 Donald I. Baker, Antitrust and Politics at the Justice Department, 9 J.L. & POL. 291
(1993).
9 Sherman Act, ch. 647, 26 Stat. 209 (1890) (current version at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-3 (1994)).
10 Robert L. Rabin, FederalRegulation in HistoricalPerspective, 38 STAN. L. REv. 1189,
1218-1220, 1225-1228 (1986).
2001] The Use of Criminal Law Remedies
standards, the Sherman Act could well have been too vague to be accepted as
constitutional on due process grounds. Over time, however, the DOJ, and
more importantly the courts, gradually developed distinguishing lines be-
tween the kinds of anticompetitive conduct that should be punished crimi-
nally and the remaining conduct, which would only be subject to civil
injunctions by the government and private damage cases by injured victims."
Thus, price-fixing, bid-rigging, and customer and market allocations came to
be regarded as criminal, while most other conduct (for example, joint venture
rules, standard setting practices, and vertical restraints) came to be regarded
2
as only suitable for civil prosecution.'
The line between the "civil" and "criminal" categories echoes, but does
not precisely follow, the line that emerged during the years between "per se
liability" and "rule of reason analysis" under section 1 of the Sherman Act:
everything that is properly regarded as criminal under section 1 is subject to a
per se rule, but not everything that is subject to a per se rule is regarded as
criminal (for example, tie-ins and vertical restraints). 13 Single firm violations
under section 2 of the Sherman Act have not generally been regarded as
suitable for criminal prosecution, even though some4
very clearly predatory
conduct might be treated under that provision.'
Although the substantive law had become much clearer through years of
judicial interpretation, the penalties for violating section I of the Sherman
Act remained fairly weak, even in the 1960s.15 The maximum corporate fine
was only $50,000, and judges rarely sentenced individuals to jail, even when
6
the DOJ recommended a jail sentence.'
increasing the culprit's chance of being caught and punished). Under the
1991 Sentencing Guidelines, sentencing became more uniform, and now indi-
viduals are regularly sent to jail for antitrust violations. Meanwhile, the max-
imum corporate Sherman Act fine was increased in 1990 to $10 million' 8 and
a new "alternative fine" based on twice the culprit's gain or twice society's
loss had been introduced in 1987.19 A successful amnesty program has
helped the DOJ generate some landmark cases-with very high fines-in the
1990s. Thus, the New York Times recently reported, with only modest
overstatement:
The antitrust division, once a small and sleepy backwater of the Jus-
tice Department, has become a power center against white-collar
crime. It has filed some of the government's biggest criminal cases
and shaken up a diverse range of industries as it reveals a seamy
20
side of globalization-international cartels.
C. Looking Back
In the balance of this article, we still look at how the idea of punishing
individuals, as well as enterprises, has worked in fact and why it is so central
to modern U.S. antitrust enforcement.
Viewed comparatively, the original Sherman Act idea of making both
enterprises and individuals liable for antitrust violations has turned out to be
the most unique-and quite possibly the most important-contribution of
the United States to the world's consumers. Other countries have widely
followed subsequent U.S. antitrust inventions (for example, merger control
under section 7 of the Clayton Act, originally enacted in 1914), and now, well
over fifty countries have antitrust statutes of some sort.21 Yet, only seven
other countries (Austria, Canada, Ireland, Israel, Japan, Korea, and Norway)
have provided criminal liability for both individuals and enterprises, 22 and
only three individuals (a Canadian and two Israelis) have ever served jail
23
time in any of those countries for violating antitrust laws.
18 Antitrust Amendments Act of 1990, Pub. L. No. 101-588, § 4, 104 Stat. 2879, 2880
(1990) (codified at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-3 (1994)).
19 18 U.S.C. § 3571(d) (1994).
20 Labaton, supra note 3. I do not recall the Antitrust Division as being either "small" or
"sleepy" when I was there (1966-1977), but it certainly has been more successful in developing
big international cartel cases since introducing an effective amnesty program in the early 1990s.
21 See INTERNATIONAL MERGERS-THE ANTITRusT PROCESS, at I-1 to 1-9 (J. William
Rowley & Donald I. Baker eds., 3rd ed. 2001) (detailing the merger control systems in 59
counties).
22 ORGANIZATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT, REPORT ON
HARD CORE CARTELS 46 n.13 (2000) [hereinafter OECD REPORT]. This source also explains
that three other countries (France, Greece, and Switzerland) have criminal liability for antitrust
violations by individuals, but not enterprises. Id. In addition to those listed in the OECD RE-
PORT, it now appears that at least two other countries have some relevant criminal provisions
directed at individuals; these include Israel and Germany (for bid-rigging only).
23 In Israel, the sentences (of 100 and 150 days) were part of plea bargains in which the
individuals and companies agreed to plead guilty to charges of fixing prices, dividing markets
and setting output quotas in floor covering materials (tiles, etc.); the plea bargains were entered
in December 2000 and February 2001.
2001] The Use of Criminal Law Remedies
24 The same point may be less true for enterprises-particularly those used to operate in
international environments where cartelization may have been common. Both Hoffman-La
Roche and ADM have been indicted several times by the United States for engaging in different
cartels in different markets.
25 See Griffin, supra note 1.
The George Washington Law Review [Vol 69:693
(not yet realized) of imposing fines that run up to ten percent of the world-
wide turnover (gross revenue) of the defendant in its most recent accounting
year.30 The case for punishing enterprises is fairly clear: the enterprise prof-
its from antitrust wrongdoing and the management of the enterprise may set
a tone that encourages, rewards, condones, or at least tolerates antitrust
wrongdoing by its employees. If the fines are set high enough and recurring
prosecutions are undertaken, then fines should have a significant deterrent
31
effect.
Enterprises can only be punished in economic ways. This being the case,
many civil law countries (and the European Union) have subjected enter-
prises to substantial monetary penalties for violating anticartel laws without
treating the violations as "criminal" or subjecting the enterprise to normal
32
criminal processes.
In the United States, the DOJ's choice of criminal enforcement may
have important procedural consequences. It gives the government the ad-
vantage of the nonpublic grand jury process that highly favors the govern-
ment at the investigational stage because testimony is taken in secret and
witnesses or targets do not have lawyers present in the grand jury room.
Once an indictment is returned, however, the choice of criminal enforcement
means that the government has to prove guilt beyond a reasonable doubt (as
opposed to proof by a preponderance of the evidence in a civil trial). The
United States process relies heavily on oral testimony before the grand jury,
while the European Union's enforcement is more document based.
30 Council Regulation 17/62, art. 15(2), 1958-1962 O.J. SPEC. ED. 87, 91-92.
31 I do not share Professor Bruce Yamanaga's concern about over-deterrence where
straight cartel violations are involved with clandestine meetings and communications. These
violations are often too profitable to participants and too hard to detect for me to want to
change the risk-reward calculation in the "reward" direction.
32 Interestingly, in the European Union some of the largest penalties have been levied for
single-firm abuse of dominance violations under Article 86 (now Article 82). Koen Lenaerts &
Ignace Maselis, European Community Competition Law: ProceduralRights and Issues in the
Enforcement of Articles 81 and 82 of the EC Treaty, 24 FORDI-AxM INT'L LJ. 1615 (2001); see
TREATY EsTABaLISHNG Tm EUROPEAN CoMMuNIrry, Feb. 7,1992, OJ. 224/1, art. 82. The DOJ
meanwhile has focused on civil injunctive remedies (rather than criminal prosecution) in modem
Sherman Act section 2 cases against such defendants as AT&T, IBM, Microsoft, and American
Airlines. See United States v. AT&T Corp., 2000-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) 73,096 (D.D.C. 2000)
(consent decree); United States v. Int'l Bus. Machs. Corp., 1998-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) 72,105
(D.D.C. 1998) (consent decree); United States v. Microsoft Corp., 1995-2 Trade Cas. (CCH)
71,096 (D.D.C. 1995) (consent decree); United States v. Airline Tariff Publ'g Co., 1994-2 Trade
Cas. (CCH) 70,687 (D.D.C. 1994) (consent decree).
The George Washington Law Review [Vol 69:693
was a misdemeanor and the maximum fine was only $5,000; 33 in 1973, the
offense was still a misdemeanor and the maximum fine was $50,000. 34
Because of this disparity between benefits and risks to the wrongdoer,
meaningful deterrence was largely achieved by depending on the strength of
civil remedies available to the victims of a cartel. Under the Clayton Act, a
conviction in a government case or a guilty plea extracted by the government
was treated as prima facie evidence of antitrust violations in subsequent civil
cases. 35 Moreover, the successful private plaintiff is entitled to receive treble
damages; 36 in other words, the plaintiff could recover three times the proven
overcharge under a system that accords plaintiffs a fair degree of latitude in
reconstructing what the "but for" competitive market would have been if
there was no antitrust violation. This issue came to the forefront in the 1960s
when hundreds of large antitrust cases were filed against General Electric,
Westinghouse, and others in the wake of the government's successful prose-
cution of the defendants for price-fixing and bid-rigging on turbine genera-
tors, transformers, switch gear, and other electrical equipment.
33 Sherman Act, ch. 647, 26 Stat. 209 (1890) (current version at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-3 (1994))
(This number was clearly much more significant in 1890 than it was sixty years later, when the
maximum fine was still only $5,000.)
34 Act of July 7, 1955, Pub. L. No. 84-135, 69 Stat. 282 (current version at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-3
(1994)) (increasing maximum to $50,000).
35 Clayton Act, ch. 323, § 7, 38 Stat. 730 (1914) (current version at 15 U.S.C. § 16(a)
(1994)).
36 Id. § 4. Interestingly, this provision (first enacted in 1890 as § 7 of the original Sherman
Act) was borrowed from the English Statute of Monopolies of 1620.
37 Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act, Pub. L. No. 93-528, § 3, 88 Stat. 1706, 1708
(1974) (current version at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-3 (1994)).
38 Antitrust Amendments Act of 1990, Pub. L. No. 101-588, § 4, 104 Stat. 2879, 2880
(1990) (codified at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-3 (1994)).
39 18 U.S.C. § 3571(d) (1994).
40 See Griffin, supra note 1.
41 The application of these guidelines is discussed in Donald C. Klawiter's paper: After the
2001] The Use of Criminal Law Remedies
The year 1999 proved extraordinary because of the Vitamins fines, which at-
tracted so much publicity. 47
It must be emphasized how international U.S. enforcement has come to
be. Foreign corporations have generally led the major cartels that were
fined, and when the Sentencing Guidelines standards have been applied to
them, these corporations have paid the highest fines. Based on the national-
ity of the defendant (or its parent or both), the table of defendants incurring
the greatest fines looks as follows:
GEOGRAPHIC TOTALS OF FINES
Sherman Act Violations Yielding a Fine of $10 Million or
More by the Antitrust Division
Nationality of Violator Fine ($ Millions)
Switzerland $536
Germany $503
Japan $284
United States $251
Belgium $15
Norway $15
Great Britain $10
Netherlands $10
The above table certainly suggests that U.S. antitrust deterrence must be
looked at globally; U.S. fines and punishments should be set at a high enough
level to get the attention of those in Zurich, Frankfurt and Osaka, even if the
fines may be higher than necessary to send a message to those in New Jersey,
Texas, or Illinois.48
47 See In re Vitamins Antitrust Litig., 2000-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) 72,914 (D.D.C. 2000).
48 See supra note 31 (commenting on Professor Yamanaga's concern about over-deter-
rence). Even if one were so concerned, effective enforcement would require U.S. corporate
antitrust fines to be high enough to deter the foreigners who often seem to lead the major inter-
national cartels and to be less sensitive to U.S. antitrust law than they should be.
49 Stephen J. Squeri, Government Investigation and Enforcement. Antitrust Division and
the FederalTrade Commission, 42 P.L.I. ANTrrRuST LAw INSTrrUTE 689, 803 (2001).
2001] The Use of Criminal Law Remedies
50 Panama Canal Act of 1912, 15 U.S.C. § 31 (1994). On March 14, 2001, the House of
Representatives passed a bill that would repeal § 31 for cases filed after the date of enactment.
H.R. 809, 107th Cong. § 2(b) (2001).
51 There is one important qualification here: the so-called Illinois Brick doctrine limits
price-fixing recovery to the initial purchaser, even though the loss may have been passed onto
the subsequent purchasers in the chain who might be more inclined to sue. Ill. Brick Co. v.
Illinois, 431 U.S. 720, 734-35 (1977). However, some seventeen states have in turn passed stat-
utes that allow indirect purchasers to recover for federal price-fixing violations in state courts.
52 Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 15 (1994); see, e.g., Tex. Indus., Inc. v. Radcliffe Materials, Inc.,
451 U.S. 630, 646-47 (1981) (denying claims for contribution among conspiracy defendants). The
United States has declined to follow the approach widely used by other countries, which is to
prevent the antitrust culprit from recovering payments due it under contracts that contain a
provision that violates the antitrust laws. In other words, in the United States, the victimized
consumer may not resist paying for purchases on the ground that the purchase price was set by
agreements among members of a cartel. See, e.g., Kelly v. Kosuga, 358 U.S. 516, 518-21 (1959).
53 Council Regulation 17/62, art. 15(2), 1958-1962 O.J. SPEc. ED. 87, 91-92.
The George Washington Law Review [Vol 69:693
* $31.5 million fined against TACA and others for concerted practices
and abuse of dominant position in maritime services (container shipping)
(March 22, 1999).
* $27.3 million against six stainless steel producers for cartel activity
(January 1998).
e $248 million against forty-one cement companies for price-fixing
(November 1994).
* $132.1 million against nineteen companies for participation in a car-
ton board cartel (July 1994).
A Commission decision on both liability and fine level is subject to re-
view by the Court of First Instance in Luxembourg. If the case involves im-
portant legal principles, it may also be reviewed by the European Court of
Justice. The Court of First Instance has substantially reduced Commission-
set fines in a number of cases.
Canada uses a traditional common law criminal enforcement system
with prosecution by the Crown (for example, Attorney General of Canada)
in the regular courts. When a plea is entered, as is frequently the case, it is
accompanied by a detailed "agreed" statement of facts spelling out the viola-
tion. Larger antitrust fines in Canada include the following:
0 C$50.9 million fined against Hoffman-La Roche for conspiracy to fix
prices and allocate markets in vitamins (September 22, 1999).
o C$19 million fined against BASF for conspiracy to fix prices and allo-
cate markets in vitamins (September 22, 1999).
0 C$16 million fined against ADM for conspiring to fix prices and allo-
cate markets in lysine (May 27, 1998).
* C$14 million against Rh6ne-Poulenc S.A. for conspiring to fix prices
and allocate vitamins markets (September 22, 1999).
* C$12.5 million against SGL Carbon AG conspiring to fix prices in
graphite electrodes (July 18, 2000).
• C$11 million against UCAR, Inc. for conspiring to fix prices in
graphite electrodes (May 18, 1999).
These all flow from quite successful cooperation agreements between
Canada and the United States, and generally it seems that the violation was
first discovered in the United States. The largest Canadian fine collected in
connection with a cartel not also prosecuted by the United States was $2.5
million against Canada Pipe Company for conspiracy.
Interestingly, the Canadian antitrust statute, enacted the year before the
Sherman Act, was criminal from the very beginning. It was not until modern
times, however, that substantial criminal fines were secured against enter-
prises. For example, as noted above, the maximum fine levied against an
enterprise was C$51 million against Hoffman-La Roche in 1999 for price-
fixing in the vitamins market (for the same violation that the company paid
the record $500 million to the U.S. Treasury).5 4
54 Press Release, Competition Bureau (Canada), Federal Court Imposes Fines Totalling
$88.4 Million For International Vitamin Conspiracies (Sept. 22, 1999), http://strategis.ic.gc.ca/
SSG/ctO1581e.html.
2001] The Use of Criminal Law Remedies
55 For example, Charles James, Assistant Attorney General for the Antitrust Division, re-
cently cited international cooperation as a driving force behind the recent Vitamins cartel convic-
tions. See Charles A. James, International Antitrust in the Bush Administration, Address
Before the Canadian Bar Association Annual Fall Conference on Competition Law (Sept. 21,
2001), http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/9100.htm.
56 Sherman Act, ch. 647, 26 Stat. 209 (1890) (current version at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-3 (1994)).
57 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-2 (1994). In 1974, the violations were elevated to felonies and the maxi-
mum individual fine was increased to $100,000. Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act, Pub. L.
No. 93-528, § 3, 88 Stat. 1706, 1708 (1974) (current version at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-3 (1994)). In 1990,
the maximum individual fine was increased to $350,000. Antitrust Amendment Act of 1990,
Pub. L. No. 101-588, § 4, 104 Stat. 2879, 2880 (1990) (codified at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-3 (1994)).
58 Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act, Pub. L. No. 93-528, § 3, 88 Stat. 1706, 1708
(1974) (current version at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-3 (1994)).
The George Washington Law Review [Vol 69:693
The stakes went up even further with the passage of the Sentencing
Guidelines in 1987. One of the problems that the DOJ had (and I was very
aware of it while I was there) was that federal judges were reluctant to sen-
tence price fixers to jail and tended to attempt to come up with alternative
"public service" type sentences. 59 The reason for this reluctance was that
antitrust price fixers were often pillars of the community, supporters of char-
ity, and posed no physical danger to other members of society. Moreover,
once caught, they tended to be very contrite and were not perceived by
judges (or for that matter prosecutors) as likely to repeat the offense. Thus,
imposing a jail sentence rested entirely on a theory of deterrence, which
many judges were unwilling to accept. It was the unevenness of sentences in
this area, and many others, that ultimately resulted in the Sentencing
Guidelines.
The Sentencing Guidelines treated antitrust felonies as very serious of-
fenses. Based on the same "point system" used to punish corporate criminal
behavior, the Guidelines make imprisonment an immediate remedy for the
sentencing court. For example, as with the corporate defendant, the current
antitrust guidelines establish a base offense level of ten for individuals con-
victed of antitrust violations. This level allows for up to six months incarcera-
tion and a fine based on a minimum of one to five percent of the volume of
commerce-but not less than $20,000.60 As with the corporate defendant,
different factors may affect the fine or the number of months (or years) that
the defendant is sentenced. 61 Multiple adjustments (such as importance of
the defendant's role in the offense, multiple counts of conviction, criminal
history, and other adjustments) are used to augment or decrease the offense
level, which can ultimately result in a greatly heightened fine, imprisonment,
or both.62
The statistics on the level of prison sentences imposed and served for
antitrust violations are impressive. The number of people sentenced to jail
and the amount of time served has continued to increase. It has always
seemed to me, however, that it is more important that the potential defen-
dant know to some degree of certainty that.she was likely to be sentenced to
jail than that long sentences be imposed. In any event, the statistical story
63
looks about as follows:
59 See Donald I. Baker & Barbara A. Reeves, The Paper Label Sentences: Critiques, 86
YALE L.J. 619, 623 (1977).
60 U.S. SENTENcING GUIDELINES MANUAL ch. 5, pt. A, sentencing table (2000).
61 Id. § 2R1.1(b)-(d).
62 id.
63 Scott Hammond, the DOJ's Director of Criminal Enforcement, gave these statistics in a
recent speech, emphasizing that the use of jail is growing dramatically in the very recent period.
Hammond, supra note 6, at 9.
2001] The Use of Criminal Law Remedies 707
Meanwhile, in the rest of world, there have been very few prosecutions
of individuals. As far as I know, only one Canadian and two Israelis have
been sentenced to jail for price-fixing under a foreign law. In a recent case
on which I worked, an American employee of a Canadian company was sen-
tenced to one year in jail after a plea-bargain guilty plea with the United
States, while his Canadian counterpart was sentenced to one year of home
detention after a Canadian guilty plea.
The United States has tried hard to raise the stakes for foreign execu-
tives residing outside of the United States. Thus, as part of the plea bargains
in the Vitamins cartel cases, three Swiss executives of one company and three
German executives of another leading company agreed to serve short
sentences in U.S. penitentiaries. 65 More recently, a Japanese executive
agreed to face a possible jail sentence in the United States.66 There are ap-
parently a number of other foreign executives who have been sentenced to
jail for Sherman Act violations and are now fugitives hiding abroad.
The fines levied against individual violators have also been increasing.
The largest fine ever imposed on an individual was for $10 million against
Robert J. Koehler, a German chief executive, in the Graphite Electrodes
67
cases.
64 Some of these individuals have served prison terms and some are fugitives from the
United States, Mr. Hammond explained. Id. at 10.
65 Id. (describing the Vitamins sentences).
66 Press Release, U.S. Dep't of Justice, Executive and U.S. Subsidiary of Japanese Manu-
facturer Agree to Plead Guilty to International Price-Fixing Conspiracy Charges (Feb. 14, 2001),
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/pressjreleases/2001/7476.htm.
67 Ferromin Int'l Trade v. UCAR Int'l., Inc., 153 F. Supp. 2d 700 (E.D. Pa 2001); Labaton,
supra note 3.
The George Washington Law Review [Vol'69:693
reason for separate counsel is the fundamental conflict that exists under this
"dog eat dog" system: the employee may gain immunity by testifying against
the company or his colleagues, and counsel for the company is not an appro-
priate party to advise her on whether to take this course. Thus, lawyers for
different individuals are jockeying vis-a-vis each other and the government
making "hypothetical" offers of proof, perhaps seeking immunity (or at least
72
a reduced sentence) in return for cooperation with the government.
The situation appears very different in countries that only punish enter-
prises for cartel violations. The involved individuals have little incentive to
work hard to recall awkward facts about meetings and understandings; they,
like their employers, hope that the whole thing blows over. This basic reality
helps explain why the DOJ investigators are generally in a better position to
piece together the details of a conspiracy in situations involving very little
documentary evidence of what transpired and when. By contrast, the Euro-
pean Commission seems to require considerably more by way of incriminat-
ing documents (for example, meeting agendas or memoranda that describe
meetings) than the United States would need in order to open a full grand
jury investigation. Better incentives for informants and cooperating wit-
nesses may help explain why the big international cartel investigations (in-
volving citric acid, lysine, carbon rods, and vitamins) all commenced in the
United States and only later were taken up by other authorities. The United
States has also developed a quite successful corporate amnesty program
under which a company may obtain immunity for itself and its employees by
revealing a conspiracy and cooperating with the government in its prosecu-
tion.73 A variation on this (called "amnesty plus") allows a company, under
investigation for one cartel, to potentially gain substantial leniency as to that
cartel if it blows the whistle on a second cartel for which it will receive com-
plete amnesty. 74 Under these programs, it is not only the company but all the
individual officers and employees of the company who get immunity. The
extent to which the immunity for individuals is an important part of most
companies' decision to seek amnesty may be an open question, but the DOJ
strongly emphasizes it as a key part of the program. It seems fairly clear to
me that the corporate amnesty program would probably be somewhat less
successful if corporate executives themselves did not face the risk of prosecu-
tion and jail.
I have stressed immunity as a vital incentive for cooperation with the
government, but the story goes much farther. Once a grand jury investiga-
tion is under way and the DOJ has a reasonable version of the story, it may
still offer knowledgeable participants a recommendation for a reduced sen-
72 The DOJ investigators may even suggest, "we'll give you a pass if you can give us good
evidence against X."
73 U.S. DEP'T oF JusTicE, supra note 68. See generally Hammond, supra note 6; Scott D.
Hammond, Lessons Common to Detecting and Deterring Cartel Activity, Remarks at the 3rd
Nordic Competition Policy Conference (Sept. 12, 2000), http:/Iwww.usdoj.gov/atr/publicl
speeches/6487.htm.
74 Gary R. Spratling, Making Companies an Offer They Shouldn't Refuse, Presentation at
the Bar Association of the District of Columbia's 35th Annual Symposium on Associations and
Antitrust (Feb. 16, 1999), http'/www.usdoj.gov/atr/publiclspeeches/2247.htm.
The George Washington Law Review [Vol 69:693
tence in return for more evidence against others. Indeed, a good many in-
dictments and information against individuals are resolved by pleas in which
the individual is allowed to get a below-guidelines sentence because of gov-
ernment representations to the court attesting to cooperation in its
investigations.
The lack of these features and incentives may help explain why Euro-
pean cartel enforcement has continued to lag behind the United States. The
European Union has had no amnesty program comparable to the United
States to encourage whistleblowers, 75 and the Commission has had to depend
on documents rather than testimony in most cases. The European Commis-
sion seems to have recognized this deficiency in announcing a program of
complete amnesty for the first company to call the Commission's attention to
a cartel. 76
75 The European Union has a fine reduction program aimed at enterprises, not individuals;
it provides for significant fine reduction to the first enterprise that comes in with evidence. Com-
mission Notice on the Non-Imposition or Reduction of Fines in Cartel Cases, 1996 O.J. (C 207).
However, the complaining enterprise will not know until the case is decided how much the fine is
to be reduced.
76 Press Release, European Commission, Commission adopts new leniency policy for com-
panies which give information on cartels (Feb. 13, 2002). According to the release,
[t]he commission will grant complete immunity from fines: to the first member of
the cartel to inform the Commission of an undetected cartel by providing sufficient
information to allow the Commission to launch an inspection on the premises of
the suspected companies; or to the first member of the cartel to provide evidence
that enables the Commission to establish an infringement, when the Commission is
already in possession of enough information to launch an inspection, but not to
establish an infringement. This type of immunity is available only in cases where
no other cartel member has qualified for immunity under the first scenario.
Id.
77 See OECD REPORT, supra note 22, at 46 n.13.
78 See id.
2001] The Use of Criminal Law Remedies
VIII. Conclusion
The use of criminal law processes and penalties against individual
wrongdoers has been one of the most successful and important features of
U.S. antitrust enforcement of the past three decades 4 I am convinced that it
has raised the perceptions of risk to individuals within companies and given
teeth to corporate compliance programs. Fear of being prosecuted for
wrongdoing has made individuals more willing to cooperate with the govern-
ment and, where possible, to seek complete immunity for prosecution. The
United States' effectiveness in this area has been increased significantly by,
first, the willingness of the U.S. Congress to increase penalties substantially
and to fund anticartel enforcement on a reasonable basis; second, the ability
of prosecutors to use the secret grand jury process to play one target against
another; and third, a growing network of cooperation arrangements with
other antitrust enforcers abroad.
In a more open investigative system, the threat to individual liability
might be a less potent tool in favor of the prosecutors than it is in the United
States. On the other hand, there remains an enormous difference between
only punishing the enterprise and punishing both the enterprise and the indi-
vidual decision makers or actors who have caused the enterprise to violate
the law.
I also remain convinced that deterrence is the critical issue in prosecut-
ing those who participate in highly profitable covert activities that are clearly
illegal. Deterrence is created by a combination of the prospect of being sub-
ject to reasonable predictable (and unpleasant) penalties and the serious like-
lihood of being caught while engaged in the illegal activity. Imposing liability
on individuals bears on both of these functions. Imposing criminal liability
only on the enterprise may have some of the same effects, but they are likely
83 Plea Agreement, United States v. Sommer, No. 3:99-CR-201-R (N.D. Tex. May 20,
1999); Press Release, U.S. Dep't of Justice, Four Foreign Executives of Leading European Vita-
min Firms Agree to Plead Guilty to Participating in International Vitamin Cartel (Apr. 6,2000),
http:lhvww.usdoj.govlatrlpublicpress~releases200014494.htm; Press Release, U.S. Dep't of Jus-
tice, Former F. Hoffman-La Roche Executive Agrees to Plead Guilty for Participating in Inter-
national Vitamin Cartel (Aug. 19, 1999), http'J/www.justice.gov/atr/publiclpress-releases/1999/
2626.htm; Press Release, U.S. Dep't of Justice, F. Hoffmann-La Roche and BASF Agree to Pay
Record Criminal Fines for Participating in International Vitamin Cartel (May 20, 1999), http://
www.usdoj.gov/atrlpubliclpress-releases/19992450.htm. However, there are counter examples:
when the former chief executive of Christie's, an art auction house, was indicted, he made clear
that he would rely on the absence of a U.S.-U.K. extradition treaty covering antitrust crimes,
rather than plead or stand trial in the United States.
84 See Labaton, supra note 3.
714 The George Washington Law Review [Vol 69:693
to be diluted. In most cases, the threat of civil liability (for example, treble
damage claims in the United States) are more significant for the enterprise
than for the individual wrongdoer because the individual wrongdoer may not
be worth enough for the plaintiff to bother suing.
When all is said and done, criminal liability ought to reflect the culture
and values of the people of a country. The United States has a long tradition
of fairly broad and sometimes noisy support of antitrust law and enforce-
ment. After all, this is what created the Sherman Act in 1890 and the felony
statute in 1974. Robber barons and cartel conspirators are bad people in the
American popular lexicon. When caught, they have been punished by the
United States to a degree far greater than any other country. It is too early
to tell whether this public psychology or political culture will be replicated
elsewhere in the world over time. Regardless of what happens in other coun-
tries, I see little chance of the Umted States abandoning the enforcement of
antitrust felony prohibitions against cartels large and small.