3 Mundlak Cavallo y Domenech 1990
3 Mundlak Cavallo y Domenech 1990
3 Mundlak Cavallo y Domenech 1990
FILE CO!PY
""/J
Effects of Macroeconomic Policies
on Sectoral Prices
Yair Mundlak, Domingo Cavallo, and Roberto Domenech
reflects inputs, such as location, which are not tradable. Thus, if we are to
Yair Mundlak is a professor at the Universityof Chicago and a researchfellow at the International
Food Policy Research Institute. Domingo Cavallo and Roberto Domenech are economists at Instituto
de Estudios Economicos sobre la Realidad Argentina y Latinoamericana, Fundacion Mediteranea. In
revisingthe paper, the authors benefited from commentsby Maurice Schiffand the referees.
© 1990 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/ THE WORLD BANK.
55
56 THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW, VOL. 4, NO. I
(2) I (t P.) =
where Ajis the elasticity of excess supply of the home good with respect to the
price of thejth tradable good. We integrateequation 3, write c = Am / ( Am +
Mundlak, Cavallo, and Domenech 57
A.), decompose the price of the tradables into world price (P*) and taxes, T,
and label T = Tx / Tm to obtain:
Thus, both PIP h and PmIPh constitute measures of the real exchange rate,
but they behave differently in response to foreign terms of trade or taxes. A
more conventional measure of the real exchange rate, e, is obtained by aggre-
gating these two measures using the geometric averages of the foreign prices,
P-, and the taxes, T':
(5) e = P*T*E/Ph
The behavior of e in response to changes in the foreign terms of trade and taxes
depends on the weights used in the aggregation. To demonstrate, let PTF' -
(P:Tj)b(P.T.)I-b, insert this term in equation 5, combine with equation 4, and
rearrange to get:
In e = a - (1 - b - c) In (x)+ (1 - b - c) In Tm - (1 - b - c) In T.
When b = 1 (that is, the foreign price is measured by the export price), e varies
positively with the foreign terms of trade. The opposite is true for the case
where b = 0, (the foreign price is measured by the import price).
important effect on the real rate of exchange (see Cavallo and Mundlak 1982,
Cavallo and Garcia 1985, Cavallo 1986, and Mundlak, Cavallo, and Dome-
nech 1987). The main conclusion derived from these studies is that overvalua-
tion of the Argentine currency arose not just from commercial policy but also
from macro and incomes policies. Moreover, these effects were shown to
depend on the structural features of the economy. That has led us to a more
detailed specification of exchange rate determinants, including government con-
sumption (g) and borrowing (f), money growth (,a), and income (Y):
exchange they require. It is not hard to think of more ideal measures, but the
problem is the lack of appropriate available data.
We assume that o, and the elasticities of real income (Y) and government
consumption (g), depend only on the share of trade in total income. The
elasticities of the fiscal deficit financed by borrowing (f) and of the money
supply (,) are assumed to depend on both of these openness variables. A
summary of the results appears in table 1.
The elasticity of the real exchange rate with respect to the terms of trade as
reflected in the values of X computed from the regression are plotted in figure
1. The value ranged between 0.6 and 0.7 before 1925, when the economy was
very open to the rest of the world. In that period, the price of the home good
was more closely related to the price of imported goods than to the price of
exports. This reflected a high degree of substitution in production and demand
between the domestic and the imported good. As the restrictions imposed on
imports increased over the following two decades, co declined. The lowest
values are observed in the early 1950s, when the economy was very closed.
Recall that lower values of c mean that the prices of home goods are more
closely related to the domestic price of exports than to prices of imports.
Since the late 1950s, X has oscillated around 0.25. This low value of X
explains why changes in export taxes produce only a small change in the
0.80
0.70
0.60
0.50
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
0.00
1915 1925 1935 1945 1955 1965 1975
Note: Verticalaxis shows elasticity of the price of exportables with respect to the terms of trade (0)).
Px = price of exports; Pm = price of imports.
Source: Mundlak, Cavallo, and Domenech (1989a).
effective real exchange rate for exports. When t. goes down, the domestic
producer price of exportables, equation 1, increases accordingly. With other
variables held constant, equation 4 indicates that 1 - X of the increase in P. is
transmitted to P,. Thus, with w = 0.25, the price of the home good increases
by 75 percent of the increase in P,. This in turn implies that the real rate of
exchange for exportables, measured as the difference between the rates of
change of the two prices, increases only by 25 percent of the initial increase in
P.. In other words, a 20 percent reduction in the export tax produces only a 5
percent increase in the price of the exported good relative to the price of the
home good.
The intuitive explanation is as follows. When the tax on exports is reduced,
the increased incentive to produce exportable goods induces an increase in
exports and thereby an increase in income. As all goods are assumed to have
positive income elasticities, their demand increases accordingly. That generates
excess demand for the home good and forces its price to increase. Restrictions
on imports cause some of the augmented demand for imports to be diverted to
Mundlak, Cavallo, and Domenech 63
the home good and thereby generate a further increase in the price of the home
good. The increased price of exportables also reduces the demand for them and
further increases the demand for the home good. As a consequence, domestic
prices increase and the real exchange rate decreases to absorb much of the
initial increase in export prices. It is in this sense that domestic prices move in
line with export prices. Of course, the outcome would be different if imports
were allowed to increase without restriction, that is, if the economy were open.
This suggests that reducing import restrictions would allow more of the income
increase to be absorbed by imports, reducing the pressure on home goods
prices. Therefore a given change in t. would have a stronger effect on the
relative price of exportables vis-a-vis the home good.
Government consumption has a negative effect on the real exchange rate.
This is so because government expenditures have a larger share of nontraded
goods than do private expenditures taxed away and because home goods prices
rise when the substitution between imports and domestic goods is low due to
import restrictions.
The effect of the fiscal deficit financed by borrowing is more pronounced
when the economy is financially open, that is, when there is no black market
premium on foreign exchange. The increase in the deficit requires increased
foreign financing and produces either a decline in the nominal rate of exchange
or an increase in domestic prices, or a combination of both. When domestic
financial markets are completely closed, that is, when the black market pre-
mium is very large, financing the deficit by domestic borrowing produces a
very strong crowding-out effect on private expenditures.
The effect of money supply and nominal exchange rate management also
depends on the openness of the economy. When the economy is financially
open, monetary expansion over and above the value of income valued at
foreign prices affects the real exchange rate with an elasticity of -0.44. This
means that a 10 percent increase in ja produces a 4.4 percent reduction in the
real rate of exchange. The elasticity becomes larger in absolute value when the
economy is more closed to financial transactions with the rest of the world.
This is because financial openness will dampen the real effect of nominal shocks
in the money supply or in the exchange rate since capital inflows or outflows
will respond quickly to such shocks. This dampening effect does not operate
when the flows are obstructed, and a large black market premium is created.
The analysis outlined above provides the basis here for evaluating the effect
of macro and trade policies, through the real exchange rate, on sectoral prices.
The various shocks considered above affect the sectoral prices largely because
they affect the relative prices of the tradables, and it is therefore important to
examine this effect first. Having done this, we can now move to the analysis of
the sectoral prices.
64 THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW, VOL. 4, NO. 1
(11) In (p) (X
a In (p'T) + (1 - ii)hiIn (MPI)
Mundlak, Cavallo, and Domenech 65
0.80
0.70
0.60
0.50
o.4o~~
0.40 . . . . . . . . ' :
1915 1925 1935 1945 1955 1965 1975
1.00
0.75
0.50
0.25 . . : 4. X
0.00
1915 1925 1935 1945 1955 1965 1975
The lagged value of DO, is included to represent the more permanent struc-
tural changes that affect trade. To estimate equation 12, it is necessary to
distinguish between trade taxes and quantitative restrictions. Because no annual
data are available for the quantitative restrictions, however, macropolicy indi-
cators are introduced in the empirical equation to capture their effects. Foreign
terms of trade were not significant and were eliminated from the equation.
IV. SIMULTANEOUSESTIMATION
1.50
1.25
1.00
0.75
0.50
0.251
1915 1925 1935 1945 1955 1965 1975
failed mostly because of the inconsistent and inappropriate policies that were
followed (Cavallo and Cottani 1986).
The trade liberalization exercise is carried out for a limited set of commercial
and macroeconomic policies. Modifications in commercial policy are intro-
duced into the system in the year 1930. They consist of complete elimination
of export taxes (T. = 1) and imposition of a 10 percent import tariff (Tm
1.1); the actual values are plotted in figure 7. For fiscal policy, it is assumed
that public expenditures followed their historical levels except for two actual
nonsustainable jumps: a smooth increase in the growth of expenditures between
1946 and 19S3, and a jump to a constant level from 1973 on (figure 8).
Eliminating these two sharp rises in public expenditures reduces the simu-
lated deficit; we assume by the amount of the expenditure cuts. We then allow
borrowing to decline by an equal amount so that the level financed by moneti-
zation remains unchanged (figure 9).
Mundlak, Cavallo, and Domenech 69
1.05
0.85
0.65
0.45
0.25
1915 1925 1935 1945 1955 1965 1975
Ky ............
fitted; actual.
Source: Mundlak,Cavallo,and Domenech (1989a).
We hold the rate of change of It at its average level for the 1930-84 period:
-0.008. We assume that the system is financially open so that there is no black
market premium on the exchange rate.
We compare the simulated values of our measures of commercial openness,
the real exchange rate, and sectoral prices with the base run values (figures 10-
13). As can be seen, all the relative prices respond strongly to trade liberaliza-
tion. This response is quantified in table 2, where the increases in the "free-
trade" values relative to the actual values are reported.
These results imply that if the Argentine economy had been more integrated
with the world economy after 1929, the relative volume of trade would have
been almost 70 percent higher than its actual level. Moreover, domestic relative
70 THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW, VOL. 4, NO. I
1.20
1.10
1.00
0.90 *
0.80
0.70
0.60
0.50
0.40
1915 1925 1935 1945 1955 1965 1975
prices would have been more in line with international prices, implying much
greater price incentives for both agriculture and nonagriculture. For the period
1930-84, the price of agriculture would have been, on average, 40 percent
higher, and the price of private nonagriculture would have been almost 20
percent higher relative to our measure of home goods prices, P3 A greater
supply of agricultural and nonagricultural goods might have dampened some-
what the changes in relative prices, but this would not change the general
pattern. Finally, as it is shown elsewhere, these changes in sectoral prices have
a very substantive positive effect on sectoral and overall growth (Mundlak,
Cavallo, and Domenech 1989a).
Mundlak, Cavallo, and Domenech 71
1.30 *,
1.20
1.10
1.00
0.90
0.80 . . . . ,, . . . _ . . . . . . .
1915 1925 1935 1945 1955 1965 1975
VI. CONCLUSIONS
Share
0.30
0.25
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
1915 1925 1935 1945 1955 1965 1975
Share
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
-0.05
1915 1925 1935 1945 1955 1965 1975
disaggregated product groups. Most product groups have both traded and
nontraded components and therefore are affected by changes in the real ex-
change rate. This allows us to measure the degree of tradability from the
relation of sectoral prices and the real exchange rate. This relation depends on
the openness of the sector to trade, indicated here by the share of trade in
sectoral income.
We applied this approach to an evaluation of the consequences of macroeco-
nomic policy in Argentina from 1913 to 1984. To assess the extent to which a
more open trade regime and restrained macropolicies would affect sectoral
prices, we simulated a policy of low uniform tariffs on imports and elimination
74 THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW, VOL. 4, NO. 1
0.80
0.60
o.40
.. . .~~~~~............
0.20
0.00
1915 1925 1935 1945 1955 1965 1975
of export taxes from 1930 on, combined with changes in the macro variables.
The counterfactual analysis suggests that such policies would have increased
incentives to agricultural and nonagricultural production by nearly 40 and 20
percent, respectively. As a result, the volume of trade would have been almost
70 percent higher.
Such changes in incentives are of importance because of their powerful effect
on production and growth. Increased sectoral incentives encourage capital ac-
cumulation, intersectoral resource transfers, and the implementation of new
techniques and adoption of new technology. These relations have been exten-
sively studied, and we have evaluated them in detail using the Argentinian
example (see Mundlak, Cavallo, and Domenech 1989a).
The main message is clear. There is, however, a danger that these results will
Mundlak, Cavallo, and Domenech 7S
1.00 V
0.75 .
0.50
0.25
1915 1925 1935 1945 1955 1965 1975
be attributed to some specific conditions which are not widely applicable. The
purpose of the analysis is to derive the results within a framework which is
universally applicable. If there is something which is specific to Argentina it is
that it has had very favorable initial conditions and that its relatively poor
performance can be attributed to its policies. This shows the cost of wrong
policies but at the same time also indicates what are the potential gains from
alternatives which take the long-run consequences into account.
The four equations were estimated by nonlinear three-stage least squares.
The exogenous variables are g, g, DOf, PIlPm, Y', and f. Note that the system
has a recursive structure. DO, is determined only by predetermined variables;
P,/1P3is determined by DO, and the predetermined variables. Finally, sectoral
prices are determined by DOE, P, P3, and predetermined variables. The two
symbols, x and d log x, are used interchangeably.
76 THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW, VOL. 4, NO. 1
1.20
1.10
1.00
0.90
0.80
0.70
o.60
0.50
0.40
1915 1925 1935 1945 1955 1965 1975
0.80
0.50
0.40
1915 1925 1935 1945 1955 1965 1975
(A-2) log (P.IP3 ) = 0.026 + 0.744 log (PJP,) + 0.349 [log (PIP_) log DOJ]
(1.9) (5.0) (2.7)
+ 0.194k + 0.428 [(logg)(logDO,)] - 1.12f - 1.31f(logDOf) - 0.130A
(1.6) (6.7) (2.5) (1.4) (1.2)
- 0.022D[(logA)(logDOf)]+ 1.88 tOc
(2.1) (.95)
R2 = 0.89; D.W. = 1.59
REFERENCES