An Economist Goes To The Game - Paul Oyer
An Economist Goes To The Game - Paul Oyer
An Economist Goes To The Game - Paul Oyer
com
An Economist Goes to the Game
OceanofPDF.com
AN ECONOMIST GOES TO THE
GAME
PAUL OYER
OceanofPDF.com
Published with assistance from the foundation established in memory of Amasa Stone Mather of the
Class of 1907, Yale College.
Copyright © 2022 by Paul Oyer. All rights reserved. This book may not be reproduced, in whole or
in part, including illustrations, in any form (beyond that copying permitted by Sections 107 and 108
of the U.S. Copyright Law and except by reviewers for the public press), without written permission
from the publishers.
Yale University Press books may be purchased in quantity for educational, business, or promotional
use. For information, please e-mail sales.press@yale.edu (U.S. office) or sales@yaleup.co.uk (U.K.
office).
OceanofPDF.com
For my father, Calvin Oyer,
who helped develop my loves of sports and learning
OceanofPDF.com
Contents
Prologue
1 Should You Help Your Kid Become a Pro Athlete?
2 What Do Silicon Valley and Czech Women’s Tennis Have in Common?
3 Why Do Athletes Cheat and Lie?
4 Are Athletes Worth All That Money?
5 Why Do Athletes Use Their Least Successful Moves So Often?
6 How Does Discrimination Lead to a Proliferation of French Canadian
Goalies?
7 How Do Ticket Scalpers Make the World a Better Place?
8 Why Should You Be Upset If Your Hometown Hosts the Olympics?
9 Who Wins When People Gamble?
Epilogue
Notes
Acknowledgments
Index
OceanofPDF.com
Prologue
On the evening of June 13, 1997, tens of millions of people around the
world were glued to their television sets. Twenty-eight seconds remained on
the clock in the sixth game of the NBA Finals between the dynastic
Chicago Bulls, who led the series three games to two, and the long-
suffering Utah Jazz. The game was tied, and the Bulls were huddling,
planning the play they would use to take the lead and the NBA
championship. Michael Jordan, the Bulls’ star, later recalled: “When Phil
[Jackson, coach of the Bulls] drew up the play at the end, everybody in the
gym, everybody on TV, knew it was coming to me.” Jordan was the best
player in the league, maybe the best in NBA history, and he had won game
1 for the Bulls with a last-second shot. According to a teammate, the plan
on that play was to “give the ball to Michael and get out of the way.”1
When the game restarted, Jordan had the ball and made a move to the
basket as though he were going to take a shot—but, covered by two Utah
players, he dished the ball to Steve Kerr instead. Kerr, now famous as the
coach of another dynasty (the Golden State Warriors of the 2010s), was
then a decent NBA guard best known as an accurate shooter. After taking
Jordan’s pass, Kerr sank a seventeen-foot jump shot to give the Bulls a lead
they would not lose.
The Moroccan-born middle-distance runner Rashid Ramzi became a
citizen of Bahrain and subsequently brought athletic glory to that island
country’s one million people. Shortly after becoming a citizen, Ramzi took
the world of track and field by storm with victories in the 800-meter and
1,500-meter runs at the Helsinki world championships in 2005. More
important, he brought Bahrain its first Olympic gold medal (in fact, its first
Olympic medal of any kind) by winning the 1,500-meter race in Beijing in
2008. But his glory didn’t last long. Ramzi had to give back his gold medal
after a retest in 2009 of his Olympic blood sample showed he had used
EPO-CERA, a banned substance meant to help people with kidney
problems but also used by cyclists, sprinters, and other athletes to create
extra red blood cells.2
A twenty-three-year-old South Korean named Jeongeun Lee6 burst onto
the golf scene in June 2019, winning the U.S. Women’s Open and a $1
million prize. That’s not a typo in her name; she goes by “Lee6” because
there are so many Lees in the Korean LPGA that it is difficult to keep track
of them all. Lee6’s victory marked yet another milestone in Korean
domination of women’s golf.3
These three events may seem like a random collection of sports-page
headlines and highlights. No doubt they brought joy and excitement to the
Bulls, Ramzi (at least initially), Lee6, and their respective fans. But a
common thread runs more subtly through these examples: we can look at all
of them through the lens of economics. You could even say each is driven
by economics. Economic forces drove the participants’ choices and
strategies in all three examples. Jordan was an amazing player to watch, but
his pass to Kerr showed that Jordan also had a grasp of game theory. Ramzi
spent his life becoming an elite athlete but at some point realized he could
get to the very top of his sport only if he gave in to the prisoner’s dilemma.
And Lee6’s million-dollar payday was the product of growing up in a
country with a high savings rate and limited opportunities for women in the
labor market.
ESPN doesn’t explain these events as natural outcomes of economics.
But having researched and taught economics since before Jeongeun Lee6
was born, I believe that all great athletes (well, most of them anyway) and
fans are also sound economists. They have to understand how to make
investments, how to choose strategies, and how to resolve trade-offs that
separate champions from also-rans.
I could not have been Michael Jordan no matter how hard I tried. But
Michael Jordan could not have become the (arguably) greatest player of all
time without understanding strategy, which in turn relies on economic
principles. He had to know the point at which the costs of driving to the
hoop one more time outweighed the benefits. All else being equal, Jordan
should have taken every shot; he was the best player on the court. But all
else is not equal. In equilibrium, opponents guarded Jordan more closely
than they guarded Kerr. If they had known that Jordan would take every
shot, all five Jazz players would have swarmed him. To truly maximize his
talents, the Bulls had to use them just the right amount. That trade-off
between taking the shot himself and passing to Kerr was an economic
decision that Jordan, through endless practice, coaching, and game
experience, knew how to optimize.
Ramzi also had amazing natural athletic talent, which he developed
through exhaustive training. It made him one of the best runners in the
world. But it probably wasn’t enough; he would not have won a gold medal
solely through his talent and effort. He faced strong incentives to use
banned substances to give himself the extra boost he needed. Although he
ended up being caught and disgraced, he took a rational risk to get a huge
economic payoff in both money and fame. And because all his top
opponents were also taking banned substances, he had no choice if he
wanted to make it to the top.
Lee6 was the product of strong economic forces, as well. She grew up in
a country with an intense education system, an emphasis on skill
development in childhood, and limited labor-market opportunities for
talented women. So she focused her investments on developing golf skills.
It was a risky bet, but it paid off.
Economics won’t make you a great tennis or soccer player, but it
answers some of the questions that sports fans ask every day. Should I
encourage my kid to try to get a college athletic scholarship (a real one, that
is, not the kind people buy)? Why do major sports figures make so much
money? Why do NBA teams give players multiyear contracts that guarantee
them millions of dollars per year even if they get injured or stop playing
well? Why would a pitcher throw the same pitch twice in a row when
mixing up pitches is the key to keeping batters off-balance?
In addition to tackling these questions internal to the game, I also hope
to shed light on some aspects of public policy. Why do cities build stadiums
with public funds, usually with large cost overruns, when the same cities
are unable to provide basic services? Are ticket scalpers good or bad? Why
can’t you get a ticket to a playoff game at a reasonable price?
Along the way, we’ll meet people whose lives are driven by both sports
and economics. Bobby Estalella was a marginal catcher who hung on in
Major League Baseball with the help of unnatural substances; Amy
Stephens was a schoolteacher in suburban Atlanta who built a ticket empire
after a random event forced her to change one evening’s entertainment
plans; Tina Weirather was a downhill skier who hails from the greatest per
capita sports country in the world (and also the dominant country in
producing false teeth). Each of these three people made choices based on
the economic forces they faced—the costs and benefits of the opportunities
in front of them. All of them had to adjust their plans when the competitive
markets in which they were successful evolved in new and more
challenging directions.
Though I hope this book will get readers interested in the academic side
of sports economics, that is not my main goal. As an economist who loves
to play and watch sports, I have written primarily about the economics in
doing those things. This book is for sports fans and players, from casual to
professional. I focus much less on owners and the many others who make
money from sports—such as broadcasters, agents, and advertisers—except
as their decisions affect fans and players.
Sports are meant to be fun and relaxing, mostly. I gather that not
everybody feels the same is true of economics. I hope you will begin to see,
however, as we visit bleachers, broadcast booths, playing fields, and other
arenas, that economics too has its entertaining side. Just as you don’t need
to spend countless hours in the gym to appreciate Michael Jordan’s jump
shot (or Steve Kerr’s), you don’t need to master complex equations to enjoy
contemplating the insights that economics can give you.
And, just maybe, you will never watch or play a game the same way
again.
OceanofPDF.com
1
Should You Help Your Kid Become a Pro Athlete?
OceanofPDF.com
2
What Do Silicon Valley and Czech Women’s Tennis
Have in Common?
OceanofPDF.com
3
Why Do Athletes Cheat and Lie?
In the summer of 1998, Mark McGwire and Sammy Sosa were living
legends. Hot in pursuit of Roger Maris’s single-season home run record, the
two sluggers traded long bomb after long bomb as the year wore on and
Maris’s sixty-one-homer mark grew closer. The story helped to rejuvenate
baseball in the wake of its crippling strike in 1994: two media-friendly
stars, each quick to heap praise on the other, were chasing one of the sport’s
most storied records. The pinnacle of the months-long spectacle came on
September 8, when McGwire, playing for the Saint Louis Cardinals, hit his
record-breaking sixty-second home run against Sosa’s Chicago Cubs. As
McGwire rounded the bases, Sosa famously jogged in from the outfield to
congratulate him at home plate, a lasting image of sportsmanship and
respect that was hailed as an encapsulation of everything good about
baseball. McGwire ended the year with seventy home runs, Sosa with sixty-
six, and both were immortalized for their roles in one of the most exciting
baseball seasons ever.
The next time McGwire and Sosa made headlines together was in March
2005. This time, the venue was not the friendly confines of Wrigley Field in
Chicago but the august halls of the U.S. Capitol, where they were testifying
at a congressional hearing. As two of the most prominent baseball stars of
recent years, they had been called before the House of Representatives
Committee on Government Reform to testify about growing concerns over
the use of performance-enhancing drugs in baseball. Neither man, it turned
out, had much to say. McGwire repeatedly told the congressional
committee, “I’m not here to talk about the past,” while Sosa claimed that he
did not speak English well enough to testify and issued a terse statement
through his interpreter that he had never used steroids.1
The congressional hearing only marked the beginning of baseball’s
internal war on drugs. On December 13, 2007, with some fanfare, former
senator George Mitchell issued his commissioned report on the steroid
problem. At the end of the report’s four-hundred-odd pages, he included
among his findings and recommendations the following lament: “The
players who follow the law and the rules . . . are faced with the painful
choice of either being placed at a competitive disadvantage or becoming
illegal users themselves. No one should have to make that choice.”
Here Mitchell hit the nail on the head. A number of factors presumably
go into deciding whether or not to take steroids—including health concerns,
religious beliefs, and willingness to lie—but one consideration clearly at or
near the top of the list is how these drugs will affect the athlete’s
performance relative to his peers. If McGwire was on steroids and Sosa
wanted to keep pace, he would probably have had to take them too—and
vice versa.
In economics terms, McGwire and Sosa faced a “prisoner’s dilemma,” a
situation that can turn otherwise reasonable people into drug users, cheaters,
and liars.
OceanofPDF.com
4
Are Athletes Worth All That Money?
The growth in athletes’ pay, and some of the details regarding how that
pay has come to grow over time, suggests at least three questions. Why do
professional athletes make so much and, in particular, so much more than
they used to make? Why do baseball and basketball stars get large
guaranteed contracts, while most football stars are one bad season away
from losing their million-dollar paychecks? Finally, why do players and
owners fight so much over money, occasionally getting into such bitter
disagreements that part or all of a season is canceled?
The answers to these questions lie in the stories behind three numbers:
$430 million, $53 million, and $580 million, in that order.
The garage door was open one summer afternoon at my home on the
sprawling Stanford University campus. A light breeze kept the garage cool
as the competitive fires heated up toward the end of the fourth game in a
best-of-five Ping-Pong battle between my son, David, and me. Though I
was once the household king of the Ping-Pong table, David had surpassed
me and was a point away from handing me another demoralizing defeat.
After a brief rally, I hit a weak shot to David’s forehand that I immediately
knew he would try to smash for a winner. David’s forehand smash is more
reliable when he aims crosscourt, and I leaned that way, guessing he would
hit to his stronger side. Instead the ball sped down the line behind me.
Game and match to David.
Ping-Pong is just a game in our house. David and I can be overly intense
about it, but ultimately we play just for fun. Nonetheless, the point at the
end of that match illustrates how a game can become game theory. The
choices that David made about whether to drive the forehand crosscourt or
down the line, and I made about whether to lean left or right, were based on
our subconscious application of principles from the economic field of game
theory. In economics terms, we each wanted to maximize our utility—in
this case, maximize our chances of winning the point—while recognizing
that the other player was making calculated, strategic, and selfish choices in
his attempt to do the same.
An economist would say that deciding where to hit and how to lean
constituted a “mixed-strategy equilibrium.” With time and practice, David
and I have learned what probability to assign to each choice the other will
make while trying to vary our own choices in a roughly random matter.
David does not always go crosscourt, even though that’s his better shot,
because if he did, I would always be waiting there. Sometimes he goes
down the line, but since he’s not as good that way, he does it just enough to
keep me guessing. In the equilibrium we have worked out, David is equally
successful, on average, whichever way he hits, and I am equally successful,
on average, whichever way I lean.
It’s not hard to find mixed strategies in places that sports fans actually
care about. Game theory may sound esoteric (and sometimes—okay, most
of the time—it is), but once you have some understanding of it, you will
never again look at a soccer game, tennis match, or baseball game in the
same way. In each of these sports, and most others, success hinges on
optimally implementing a “mixed strategy” that relies crucially on two
things: knowing how often to choose each strategy, and randomly mixing
the strategies so that you remain unpredictable.
OceanofPDF.com
6
How Does Discrimination Lead to a Proliferation of
French Canadian Goalies?
“Integrating the NFL was the low point of my life,” Woody Strode told
Sports Illustrated, years after becoming the league’s first Black player. “If I
have to integrate heaven, I don’t want to go.”1
Although the story of Jackie Robinson is the most familiar tale of
breaking barriers in sports, baseball was hardly the only American
professional sports league to be tainted by segregation. The NFL fired all of
its Black players in 1934; it was another twelve years before Strode and his
teammate Kenny Washington returned racial diversity to the league.
For Strode and Washington, it was a matter of right place, right time.
When the Rams moved from Cleveland to Los Angeles in 1946, the team
wanted to play in Memorial Coliseum because it seated 100,000 people.
Stadium administrators, supported by a crusading local sportswriter,
demanded that the franchise sign a Black player. The Rams complied,
turning to former UCLA teammates Washington and Strode.
The duo suffered the same sorts of taunting and cheap shots that
Robinson did in his famous first season with the Dodgers a year later; like
Robinson, they were also asked to stay in “racially appropriate” hotels
when the team traveled. Washington, who saw more game action than
Strode, was once held down by opponents at the bottom of a pile while they
rubbed chalk in his eyes. “He could smile when his lip was bleeding,” a
college teammate said of him; in the NFL of 1946, he needed to. Within a
couple of years, both he and Strode were out of the league, but other teams
slowly signed Black players, and the NFL slowly accepted desegregation.
There was not a smooth, fairytale-like ascent from two Black NFL
players in 1946 to today, when Black players make up nearly 70 percent of
the league. It is nice to imagine that Strode and Washington and Robinson
—and Chuck Cooper, Nat Clifton, and Earl Lloyd in the NBA in 1950; Lee
Elder at the Masters golf tournament in 1975; Althea Gibson at Wimbledon
in 1950; and Willie O’Ree in the NHL in 1958—made an immediate and
lasting impact on their sports. To some degree, of course, they did; since
World War II, no league has been resegregated after its color barrier was
broken. But do athletes of color still face discrimination in less obvious
ways? Economists have examined this question for decades, and they have
found that the path to racial equality in sports has been bumpy and remains
incomplete.
Overall, the story of discrimination in sports is uplifting. Social changes
and market forces have helped many female and minority athletes. In
economic terms, team owners learned that discrimination was a competitive
disadvantage. The historical discrimination that came from fans, team
owners, and the players themselves—which affected the racial makeup of
teams, athletes’ pay, and the positions and sports that were open to athletes
—has been substantially reduced, and the explosive growth in sports
revenue has been shared with an increasingly diverse athlete pool. Yet we
still find discrimination in sports around the world. Markets often help
correct injustice, but they can take a long time to do so.
OceanofPDF.com
7
How Do Ticket Scalpers Make the World a Better
Place?
OceanofPDF.com
8
Why Should You Be Upset If Your Hometown Hosts
the Olympics?
The common thread in each of these and countless other examples is that
individuals had the power to decide how a much larger group of people
spent their money. This misalignment of interests led to an elected or self-
declared leader making financial decisions that hurt constituents while
making himself or herself better off.
Still, hopeful news is on the horizon. Fans and citizens are pushing back
against the idea of taxpayers shelling out for sports events and facilities.
Will they save cities from frittering away money? Maybe, although those
who champion Olympic bids are trying to stay a step ahead of those who
insist on fiscal responsibility.
Corruption
When the stakes are high enough, the misalignment between decision
makers with big power and the constituents they represent can make the
leap from “agency problems” to outright corruption.20 Many in the United
States like to think that corruption is something that happens in developing
countries, Russia, and maybe in the negotiation of a few New Jersey
sanitation contracts. But even Salt Lake City, with its squeaky-clean
reputation, is not immune.
In 1991 the city finished just four votes behind Nagano, Japan, in its bid
for the 1998 Winter Olympics. Officials supporting the Salt Lake bid were
convinced that the loss was a consequence of their failure to court the
representatives of developing countries, an emerging voting bloc under the
International Olympic Committee’s globalization efforts. Determined to
land the 2002 Games, the Salt Lake City bid’s backers lavished African and
Latin American IOC officials with all-expenses-paid trips to Utah, tuition
help and internships in the United States for their children, and campaign
donations. When the committee convened in 1995 to select a host, Salt
Lake won a decisive fifty-four-vote majority over the other four candidates
on the first ballot.
The scandal that ensued as details emerged of Salt Lake’s voter courtship
efforts underscored a predictable problem with many bidding processes: the
ultimate decision was made by a group of people who didn’t have much
interest in the outcome. In the case of the Olympics, host cities are elected
by the general body of the IOC, which is composed of one hundred or more
members from a wide range of countries around the world.
In theory, the IOC’s members should all share an interest in maximizing
the quality of the Olympics as a whole, but in practice, many of them are
probably more concerned with their country’s or their own welfare. After
all, why would a representative from Samoa or Sudan care about whether
the Winter Olympics are held in Utah or Sweden? No one from his country
is going to participate, and it’s unlikely that either site will do a vastly better
job of hosting than the other.
The main thing people on the Salt Lake bid committee were guilty of—
besides maybe a federal crime or two—was participating in a system of
broken incentives. Only two ways exist to win an Olympic bid: either you
can put together a great, detailed proposal that makes it clear your city is the
best choice for a host, or you can scratch the backs of the people who make
the decision. The former approach is more noble, but it’s really just a
crapshoot if you don’t do some of the latter as well. If you think there was a
big difference between Salt Lake City’s winning bid and the bids of its top
rivals Östersund, Sweden, and Sion, Switzerland, think again. Both cities
put together strong bids, and then politics and luck sorted the rest out.
After the Salt Lake scandal, the International Olympic Committee
changed the rules to try to discourage corruption. For example, site
selectors may no longer fly to potential locations to be courted by an
aspiring city. One theory about why Beijing was given the 2022 Winter
Games instead of Almaty, Kazakhstan, is that IOC voters could not travel to
Kazakhstan and therefore had only uninformed and vague images of the
country. This theory suggests that the change in IOC rules may lessen the
opportunities for corruption, but at the cost of leading to overly
conservative host city selections.
On the other hand, it would not be unreasonable to worry, based on
Nursultan Nazarbayev’s reputation, about the persuasive techniques he
might have used had the committee visited. If the IOC had not changed its
rules, perhaps some Kazakh oil money would have found its way into the
bank accounts of IOC officials and selectors. In any case, Nazarbayev did
not get his Olympics, which means you will have to get used to artificial
snow if you go to the Beijing Games in 2022, and you will have to find
some other reason to visit Kazakhstan.
Getting cities to bid for the Olympics or to build a stadium continues to
get harder as voters have woken up to the costs. Voters continue to stifle
attempts to build large new stadiums. For the 2026 Winter Olympics,
despite much early interest, voters in Calgary (Canada), Graz (Austria), and
Sion (Switzerland) all squashed bids led by local politicians looking to
make a name for themselves, and other cities also withdrew under public
pressure. The Covid-19 pandemic will surely make overcoming citizens’
objections even more difficult, given the massive losses Tokyo faced when
forced to delay the 2020 Olympics by a year and to hold the Games with no
international spectators, and the huge losses of money to cities as stadiums
sat idle for more than a year during the pandemic (leading Sacramento to
dip into its rainy-day fund to pay off bonds on the Golden 1 Center).
Meanwhile, Nursultan Nazarbayev is enjoying the quiet life of retirement,
and his country’s citizens are lucky he didn’t leave behind a large Olympic
bill.
OceanofPDF.com
9
Who Wins When People Gamble?
OceanofPDF.com
Epilogue
OceanofPDF.com
Notes
Prologue
1. Aaron Dodson, “On This Day in NBA Finals History: Steve Kerr’s 17-Foot Jumper Clinches
Bulls’ 1997 Title,” The Undefeated, June 13, 2017.
2. “CERA: The New EPO Discovered at the Tour de France,” Cycling Weekly, July 17, 2008;
“Rashid Ramzi Stripped of Beijing Olympic 1500m Gold After Failing Dope Test,” The Telegraph,
November 18, 2009.
3. “Lee6 Wins U.S. Women’s Open, Pockets $1M,” Associated Press, June 2, 2019.
OceanofPDF.com
Acknowledgments
David Oyer (my son, the hero of the chapter 1 Little League game and
my Ping-Pong nemesis in chapter 5) was a major contributor to this book.
He assisted with much of the research and drafted and edited several
chapters. We had many discussions (and more than a few arguments) about
the sports and the economics aspects of the book. Since I took David to
Comiskey Park when he was four years old, it has been a great joy to
experience sports with him, as both a fan and a participant. We spent time
together at many Stanford sporting events, Oakland A’s games, and
countless Little League and other games as he was growing up. Now that he
is grown, we don’t get to do that as often, but he keeps me informed and
amused with regular text updates about the A’s and other sports topics.
Spending time with David made all the research for this book far more
enjoyable than it would otherwise have been.
I also spent a lot of delightful time playing and enjoying sports with my
daughter, Lucy Oyer. Though my years of coaching her baseball and soccer
teams did not lead to athletic stardom, she did go on to be an economics
major, which seems to have prepared her well for nonathletic career
success.
My wife, Kathryn Stoner, has been a wonderful companion and source
of joy throughout this project. She is always encouraging, and she makes
me feel lucky every day. She also knows enough economics to get by and,
despite more than her share of injuries, holds her own in the sports world.
Thanks to my stepchildren, Abby and Adam Weiss, for brightening up
our household at various times throughout this project. They take their
athletic pursuits seriously and, hopefully, are learning some economics
along the way.
Bill Frucht has been a terrific editor. I enjoyed the many conversations
we had about the book, even when they inevitably devolved into lamenting
the condition of the Mets. Bill was extremely patient (too patient!) and had
excellent insights on the big picture of the book, as well as the little details.
Speaking of patient, my agent Zoe Pagnamenta has taught me a great deal
about shaping a book. Thanks, also, to Julio Cesar Franco Ardila for help
with the figures.
I have had many economics colleagues, those at Stanford as well as
others in the profession, who have taught me a great deal about economics
over the years and have also engaged in many great discussions of sports.
They are too numerous to single out here, but two are worthy of special
mention. My friend and co-author Scott Schaefer has influenced my
economic thinking for over twenty-five years and, more specifically, made
a key point about the difference between football and baseball players that
was crucial to chapter 4. Ed Lazear also made me a much better economist
over the last few decades. That happened mostly through seminars, working
on papers, and traditional academic pursuits, but we also spent countless
hours discussing sports (with and without mentioning the underlying
economics), sometimes while skiing and watching football. Sadly, Ed
passed away toward the end of this project.
Josie, our faithful flat-coated retriever, was by my side throughout the
entire project, including watching the Ping-Pong game in chapter 5. She
was a great athlete and the most optimistic distraction from work a person
could ask for, though her economics were never very good. Sadly, Josie
passed away as I concluded the book. Her younger sister, Phoebe, also
brings great joy to our household.
Finally, I want to thank my late mother, Alice Oyer, for all the support
she gave me for over forty years. And I thank my father, Calvin Oyer, for
playing sports with me and taking me to games when I was little, but never
overdoing it. Neither of my parents knew much about economics, but they
laid the groundwork that made this book and all my other academic
endeavors possible.
OceanofPDF.com
Index
Aaron, Hank, 68
African Americans, 19
in baseball, 113–14
earnings of, 15–16, 18–19
equipment and training unavailable to, 115–16
agency problems, 140, 152, 154
Almaty, Kazakhstan, 138–39, 140, 156
Amy’s Tickets, 120, 125, 135
Anderson, Oliver, 168, 169
Apple Computers, 71
Archer, Chris, 113
archery, 38, 41
Arizona Diamondbacks, 131
arms control, 54
Armstrong, Lance, 45–46, 49, 51, 59–60, 62–63
athletic scholarships, 12
Atlanta Braves, 151
Australian Open (tennis), 117, 118
Austro-Hungarian Empire, 35
auto racing, 70, 100–101
badminton, 24
Bahrain, 1
BALCO (Bay Area Laboratory Co-operative), 57
Baltimore, Md., 148
Baron Cohen, Sacha, 138
baseball: Black players in, 113–14
Dominican players in, 20
Japanese players in, 114–15
league structure in, 175
performance-enhancing drugs in, 44–45, 51–53, 60
pitch selection in, 94–100
racial integration of, 102, 103
racism in, 113–15, 119
Reserve Clause in, 72–73, 74
revenue in, 67, 131
salaries in, 53, 65–75
technological change and, 70–71
ticket sales and, 130
base stealing, 94
basketball, 1, 23
Black players in, 15–20, 103, 106–7, 108
collective bargaining in, 81–83
discriminatory officiating in, 106, 113
fan interest in, 116, 117
free agency in, 73
international competition in, 42–43
league structure in, 175
performance-enhancing drugs in, 61, 62
salaries in, 64, 80, 108, 109, 110, 115
Beane, Billy, 97, 166, 167
A Beautiful Mind (film), 88
Becker, Gary, 109–10, 190n14
Bedinghaus, Bob, 154
beer industry, 32
Beijing, China, 139–40
Beijing Winter Olympics (2022), 139, 140, 156
Berlusconi, Silvio, 138
best alternative to a negotiated agreement (BATNA), 81–82
Betts, Mookie, 97
Blair, Tony, 138
Blinder, Alan, 140
bluffing, 100–101
Biogenesis scandal (2014), 54–55
Bird, Larry, 106, 109
Boldon, Ato, 57–58
Bolt, Usain, 58–59, 60
Bonds, Barry, 51–53, 61
bookies, 158–72
Boston Bruins, 125–26, 187n14
Boston Celtics, 106, 109
Boston Red Sox, 130
Bovada, 163
bowling, 61
Bradley, Bill, 164
Bradley Act (1992), 164
Brady, Tom, 159
Braun, Ryan, 54
Brazil, 87
breakfast cereals, 32
broadcast rights, 70
Brooklyn Dodgers, 149
Budinger, Chase, 106
Buffalo Bills, 78
bunting, 94
Burrow, Joe, 158
fastball, 96–98
Federal Baseball Club v. National League (1922), 71
Federer, Roger, 168
Final Four, 133–34, 135
Finland, 27
Finn, Adharanand, 34
5Dimes, 163
Flood, Curt, 72
Florida Panthers, 131
football, 20, 100
betting on, 158–59
Black players in, 17–18, 115
free agency in, 73
performance-enhancing drugs in, 57, 60
racial integration of, 102–3
racism in, 102–3, 119
salaries in, 65, 75, 81
forwards, in hockey, 112–13
Fox Sports, 67
France, 87
free agency, 73, 80, 81
French Canadians, 111–12
French Open (tennis), 117, 118
Indianapolis Colts, 79
industry concentration, 32
inequality, 73–74
International Olympic Committee (IOC), 155, 156
internet, 70, 163
interracial marriage, 109
investment goods, 7, 10
Italy, 86–87
It’s Not About the Bike (Armstrong), 46
Jackson, Phil, 1
Johnson, Ben, 57, 61
Johnson, Boris, 176
Jones, Marion, 59, 60, 62–63
Jordan, Michael, 1, 3, 60
Joyner, Florence Griffith, 59
judo, 39
lacrosse, 13
Lasry, Marc, 141
Las Vegas, Nev., 164
Lee6, Jeongeun, 2, 3–4
Levin, Josh, 107
Lewis, Carl, 57
Ley, Tom, 136–37
Lieberman, Daniel, 33–34
Liechtenstein, 22–23, 25–27, 32
Ligue 1 (French soccer league), 20
Little League, 6–7, 95–96
Lloyd, Earl, 103
lockouts, 83
Lombe, Harrison, 168, 169
London Summer Olympics (2012), 142–43, 146, 150, 151
Los Angeles Angels, 66–69, 73, 74, 81
Los Angeles Chargers, 159
Los Angeles Clippers, 104, 108, 110
Los Angeles Dodgers, 114, 149
Los Angeles Lakers, 109
Los Angeles Rams, 102
Louisiana, 164
Love, Kevin, 106
Luck, Andrew, 75, 79
Lviv, Ukraine, 139
Ma, Yo-Yo, 71
Mahomes, Patrick, 74–80
Major League Baseball (MLB). See baseball
Mandlikova, Hana, 35
Mann, Ralph, 60
Mantle, Mickey, 69, 72
marathon running, 23, 30–34, 39
March Madness, 171
Maris, Roger, 44
Maryland, 164
Matheny, Mike, 99–100
Mayfield, Baker, 158
Mayo, O. J., 62
McCoy, Gerald, 18
McCoy, LeSean, 18
McGwire, Mark, 44–45, 52
McHale, Kevin, 109
McIlroy, Rory, 161–62
Memphis Grizzlies, 109
merchandise, 67, 76, 82
Meucci, Daniele, 31
Middlebury College, 11, 14
middle linebacker, 115
Miller, Marvin, 72–73
Milwaukee Bucks, 109, 141
Minnesota Timberwolves, 106–7, 110–11
Minnesota Twins, 107
Minnesota Vikings, 164–65
Mitchell, George, 45
Mitchell Report, 45, 51, 52
mixed-strategy equilibrium: in pitching and batting, 94–95, 98, 100
in soccer, 88, 91, 94
in tennis, 88, 92–94
modern pentathlon, 38
Moneyball (book and film), 166
Montana, 164
Montreal Canadiens, 106, 187n14
Morgan, Alex, 117
Morial, Marc, 115
Moyer, Jamie, 98–99
muscle memory, 93
Qatar, 141–42
quarterback, 115
Quebec, 112
Uber, 129–30
UEFA Champions League, 87
Ukraine, 139
Union Cycliste Internationale, 50
unions, 80–81
Unitas, Johnny, 74
U.S. Anti-Doping Agency, 50
U.S. Open (tennis), 117, 118, 119
U.S. Women’s Open (golf), 2
Utah Jazz, 1, 109
utility, 85–86, 149–50, 160
Verlander, Justin, 97
volleyball, 101
von Neumann, John, 88
Wakefield, Tim, 96
Walker, Mark, 92–93
Walker, Scott, 141
Walkowiak, Robert, 49–50
Walton, Bill, 109
Washington, Kenny, 102–3
Washington Nationals, 98
Washington Senators, 107
weightlifting, 57, 60
Weirather, Tina, 4, 22, 27
Westbrook, Russell, 19
West Ham United F.C., 143
Williams, Ted, 69, 71, 72
Wilson, A’ja, 117
Wilson, Alex, 69
Wilson, Russell, 165
Wimbledon championship, 35, 37, 103, 117, 118–19, 169
winemaking, 25, 28–29
Winfrey, Oprah, 46
wins above replacement (WAR), 68
Wisconsin, 141
Wolfers, Justin, 106, 170
Women’s National Basketball Association (WNBA), 20, 115–16
Women’s Sports Foundation, 116
Wooders, John, 92–93
Woods, Tiger, 60
World Cup (soccer), 86–87, 141–42
World Economic Forum, 40
Xie Chengfeng, 21
Yang, Y. E., 41
OceanofPDF.com