Housing Dynamics
Housing Dynamics
Housing Dynamics
HOUSING DYNAMICS
Edward L. Glaeser
Joseph Gyourko
Glaeser thanks the Taubman Center for State and Local Government at Harvard University, and Gyourko
thanks the Research Sponsors Program of the Zell/Lurie Real Estate Center at The Wharton School,
University of Pennsylvania for financial support. We appreciate the comments of seminar participants
at the University of Chicago, the NBER Summer Institute, and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation
on previous versions of the paper. Graham Elliot and James Stock provided helpful guidance. Andy
Moore, Charles Nathanson, and Jon Steinnsen provided superb research assistance. The views expressed
herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of
Economic Research.
© 2006 by Edward L. Glaeser and Joseph Gyourko. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not
to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including
© notice, is given to the source.
Housing Dynamics
Edward L. Glaeser and Joseph Gyourko
NBER Working Paper No. 12787
December 2006
JEL No. A1
ABSTRACT
The key stylized facts of the housing market are positive serial correlation of price changes at one
year frequencies and mean reversion over longer periods, strong persistence in construction, and highly
volatile prices and construction levels within markets. We calibrate a dynamic model of housing in
the spatial equilibrium tradition of Rosen and Roback to see whether such a model can generate these
facts. With reasonable parameter values, this model readily explains the mean reversion of prices
over five year periods, but cannot explain the observed positive serial correlation at higher frequencies.
The model predicts the positive serial correlation of new construction that we see in the data and the
volatility of both prices and quantities in the typical market, but not the volatility of the nation's more
extreme markets. The strong serial correlation in annual house price changes and the high volatility
of prices in coastal markets are the two biggest housing market puzzles. More research is needed to
determine whether measurement error-related data smoothing or market inefficiency can best account
for the persistence of high frequency price changes. The best rational explanations of the volatility
in high cost markets are shocks to interest rates and unobserved income shocks.
Edward L. Glaeser
Department of Economics
315A Littauer Center
Harvard University
Cambridge, MA 02138
and NBER
eglaeser@harvard.edu
Joseph Gyourko
University of Pennsylvania
Wharton School of Business
3620 Locust Walk
1480 Steinberg-Dietrich Hall
Philadelphia, PA 19104-6302
and NBER
gyourko@wharton.upenn.edu
I. Introduction
more than $18 trillion worth of real estate is owned within the household sector.1
Despite the enormous size of this sector, economists’ understanding of many features of
the housing market remains incomplete.2 For example, in the sample of 115
metropolitan areas from 1980 to 2005 for which we have Office of Federal Housing
Enterprise Oversight (OFHEO) constant quality house price series, a $1 increase in real
house prices in one year is associated with a 71 cent increase the next year. A $1
increase in local market prices over the past five years is associated with a 32 cent
decrease over the next five year period. This predictability of price changes seems to
pose a challenge for an efficient markets view (Case and Shiller, 1989; Cutler, Poterba,
metropolitan area average house prices is $26,354 (in 2000 dollars throughout the paper),
which is about one-fifth of the median price level. Over one, three, and five year periods,
the standard deviation of house price changes is at least three times the mean price
change. Can this volatility be the result of real shocks to housing market or must it
1
The portfolio share is from Tracy, Schneider, and Chan (1999). The dollar value figure is for the fourth
quarter of 2005 and is from Table B.100 Balance Sheet of Households and Nonprofit Organizations which
may be downloaded at http://www.federalreserve.gov/RELEASES/z1/Current/data.htm. The Federal
Reserve’s data includes market value estimates for second homes, vacant homes for sale, and vacant land
owned by the household sector.
2
The debate over whether the recent boom was a bubble is only the latest example. See McCarthy and
Peach (2004), Himmelberg, Mayer and Sinai (2005), and Smith and Smith (2006) for recent analyses that
conclude there is no large-scale bubble in housing prices. Shiller (2005, 2006) and Baker (2006) argue to
the contrary that the bubble is both real and very large.
1
Another more subtle puzzle is that house price appreciation in the 1990s was
negatively correlated with that in the 1980s (as shown in Figure 1), while housing unit
growth was positively serially correlated over the same time periods (see Figure 2).
Basic demand-driven housing models predict that prices and quantities should move
symmetrically. The mismatch of quantity and price movements seems to suggest that
models of housing prices need to more firmly embed supply as well as demand.
Many housing models also put great stock in macroeconomic variables such as
interest rates and national income, but most variation in housing price changes is local,
not national. Less than eight percent of the variation in price levels and barely more than
one-quarter of the variation in price changes across cities can be accounted for by
national year-specific fixed effects. The large amount of local variation and its
formation to see whether such a framework can explain the salient moments of housing
price and quantity changes. The model follows the urban tradition of Alonso (1962),
Rosen (1979) and Roback (1982) in which housing prices reflect the willingness to pay
for one location versus another. In this approach, housing prices are determined
endogenously by local wages and amenities, so that local heterogeneity is natural. Our
In Section II of this paper, we present the model and four propositions regarding
its implications. The model shows that the predictability of housing price changes is
2
compatible with a no-arbitrage rational expectations equilibrium. Slow construction
responses and mean reverting wage shocks imply that prices will mean revert. And,
positive serial correlation of labor demand shocks at high frequencies can generate
The model can also explain the apparent puzzle of mean reverting prices and
persistent quantity changes shown in Figures 1 and 2. Proposition 4 shows that long-term
trends to city productivity or local amenities will create persistence in population and
housing supply changes, but will have a much smaller impact on prices, since those
trends are anticipated and incorporated into initial prices. Price changes are driven by
unexpected high frequency shocks, which mean revert, while quantity changes are driven
The model also serves as the basis for the calibrations discussed in Sections III
and IV of the paper. Section III presents our estimates of the model’s key parameters: the
real rate of interest, the degree to which construction responds to higher prices, and the
variance and serial correlation of local demand shocks. We assume constant interest
rates for most of the paper, but do turn to time-varying interest rates in Section V. We
estimate construction cost parameters using data on construction and price variance. The
for particular locales. And, we use Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) income data to
In Section IV, we compare the moments of the real data with the moments
predicted by the model based on the parameter estimates from Section III. We first
investigate the serial correlation properties of prices and quantities. The parameter values
3
described in Section III predict that housing prices will mean revert over five year periods
at almost exactly the same rate that we see in the data. This mean reversion is the result
of new construction satisfying demand and the observed mean reversion of economic
shocks to local productivity. We fit the modest mean reversion of construction quantities
less perfectly, but the patterns in the real data are quite compatible with reasonable
parameter values.
Over one year periods, we predict strong serial correlation of new construction,
but in the data serial correlation of new permits is even greater than the level that our
model predicts. The model does not predict the strong serial correlation of price changes
at one and three year intervals. This serial correlation could be due to the artificial
smoothing of the underlying data or less rational factors. Persistence itself is not enough
to reject a rational expectations model, but the mismatch between data and model at
annual frequencies indicates that Case and Shiller’s (1989) conclusion regarding
inefficiency could be right. Future work needs to deal with the data smoothing problem
to see whether the actual serial correlation still is far too high relative to the model.
changes that are quite close to the variances seen in the median metropolitan area in our
sample. We do overestimate the volatility of price changes at annual frequencies, but that
could be the result of data smoothing. The model does not predict ‘too much’ variation
for three and five year changes, where smoothing should be less of an issue.
While the model can fit the median market, it cannot explain the volatility of
either prices or construction in the nation’s more extreme markets. The model does not
fit the price volatility in California which has huge price changes and it does not fit the
4
construction volatility in sunbelt cities such as Atlanta and Houston. The high
construction volatility in the sunbelt areas is most plausibly the result of lumpiness in the
construction process and the possibility that the sunbelt areas have much lower
construction cost parameters than we estimate. However, these explanations cannot help
us explain the high price volatility areas, and we try to understand them in the
income volatility, and volatile interest rates. The one high frequency amenity variable
that we have—crime rates—shows little ability to increase predicted demand and price
variability. Using data from New York City, we examine whether the volatility of
incomes for recent home buyers is higher than the volatility for average income, and find
that it is. The variance of income in areas with big price change areas is higher than the
variance of incomes for the average market. These factors may explain the high variation
of prices in the most volatile markets on the east coast, but do little to help us understand
California outside of the bay region, which has less income volatility.
Volatile interest rates will not increase the volatility of prices or construction in
markets with prices close to construction costs (or to the national median price in our
model), but they can increase the predicted variance for places with permanently high
amenities or productivity. For interest rates to generate high levels of volatility, shocks to
interest rates must be extremely high and areas must be innately extremely attractive, but
these conditions may be true for California over the last two decades.
5
II. A Dynamic Model of Housing Prices
across space at all points in time, which requires utility U(W, A, R) to be equal across
space, where W refers to wages, A to amenities, and R to the flow cost of housing. Our
simplifying assumption that this spatial equilibrium must hold in all periods is the
require the expected returns from making a house (its expected price) to be equal to the
cost of construction. If the city is not growing, this equilibrium condition need not hold
(as in Glaeser and Gyourko, 2005), but we make the simplifying assumption that the city
is always adding new units. Our final equilibrium condition concerns wages which must
“reservation locale” that delivers utility of U (t ) in each period “t” and that the cost of
building a home there always equals “C,” which reflects the physical costs of
construction. Since housing can be built in the reservation locale freely at cost C, we
assume that the price of a house there always equals C.3 The reservation locale
represents the many metropolitan areas in the American hinterland with steady growth
and where prices stay close to the physical costs of construction (Glaeser, Gyourko and
Saks, 2005).4 The annual cost of living in the reservation locale equals the difference
3
While it is possible that prices will deviate around this value because of temporary over- or under-
building, we simplify and assume that the price of a house always equals C.
4
Van Neiuwerburgh and Weill (2006) present a similar model in their exploration of long run changes in
the distribution of income (also studied by Gyourko, Mayer and Sinai, 2006). Our paper was produced
6
between the price of the house at time t and the discounted value of the house at time t+1,
or C-C/(1+r) = rC/(1+r), where r is the assumed fixed rate of interest.5 We abstract from
taxes, maintenance costs and allow time-varying interest rates only in Section 5.6
The spatial equilibrium requires all cities at all times to deliver to the marginal
resident the same utility that always is available in the reservation locale. We focus on
the dynamics in a single representative city (which is different from the reservation city).
The utility flow for person i living in that city during period t is W (i, t ) + A(i, t ) , or wages
plus amenities. We assume that there are a fixed number of firms each of which has
output that is quadratic in labor. This assumption ensures that the marginal product at
each firm is linearly decreasing with the number of workers and that wages in the city are
linearly decreasing with the number of workers. These labor demand schedules
generated by firm optimization underpin our assumption that wages at the city level
We assume that the time-specific and individual-specific effects that make up the
net utility flow from the city are separable so W (i, t ) + A(i, t ) − U (t ) can be written as
D(t ) + θ (i ) . The composite variable D(t) reflects wages and amenities, which in turn
reflect exogenous shocks and city size. We let N(t) denote the housing stock in the city
and assume that the city’s population and labor force equal a constant times the amount
independently of theirs, and our focus on high frequency variation in prices and quantities is quite different
from their focus on changes in the long run distribution of housing prices. More generally, the approach
taken here differs from most research into housing prices, which employs the user cost approach introduced
by Hendershott and Slemrod (1983) and Poterba (1984). That branch of the literature is too voluminous to
describe in detail. The first three papers referenced in footnote 2 employ a user cost framework to examine
the recent housing boom.
5
This difference would also be the rent that a landlord earning zero profits would charge a tenant.
6
If maintenance costs are independent of housing values and constant over space, they will not change the
analysis. If maintenance costs scale with housing and if there are property taxes, then the cost of owning a
house would be higher than the after-tax interest rate. For this reason, we will assume a relatively high real
rate in our simulations. See below for more on that.
7
of housing.7 We further assume that D(t) moves linearly with city population to allow for
the fact that wages and amenities may fall due to congestion or rise because of
distributed taste for living in this particular locale, so that the value of θ (i ) for the
component (denoted D ), a city-specific time trend (denoted qt) and a mean zero
stochastic component (denoted x(t)). Thus, the flow of utility for the city’s marginal
resident at time t with index i*(t) relative to the reservation locale, D(t ) + θ (i * (t )) , can
and the taste of the marginal resident for living in the locale can fall linearly with city
size. We further assume that x(t) follows an auto regressive moving average (ARMA) (1,
1) process so that x(t ) = δx(t − 1) + ε (t ) + θε (t − 1) , where 0 < δ < 1 , and the ε (t ) shocks
Et ( H (t + 1)) /(1 + r ) , where Et (.) denotes the time t expectation operator. The difference
between the cost of housing in the representative city and housing costs in the reservation
locale, rC/(1+r), should be understood as the cost of receiving the extra utility flow
associated with locating in the city. If extra housing costs in the city equals extra utility
E t ( H (t + 1)) rC
(1) H (t ) − − = D + qt + x(t ) − αN (t ) .
1+ r 1+ r
7
Glaeser, Gyourko and Saks (2006) provide evidence showing that population is essentially proportional to
the size of the housing stock.
8
Equation (1) represents a dynamic version of the Rosen-Roback spatial indifference
equation where differences in housing costs equal differences in wages plus differences
H (t + j )
lim j →∞ = 0 .8 If housing supply was fixed, so N(t)=N (as might be the case in
(1 + r ) j
(1 + r )( D − αN + qt ) (1 + r )q (1 + r ) x(t ) + θε (t )
(2) H (t ) = C + + + .
r r2 1+ r −δ
Housing prices are a function of exogenous population and exogenous shocks to wages
and amenities, and the derivative of housing prices with respect to a one dollar permanent
increase in wages will be (1+r)/r. Note that house price changes are predictable in this
framework as long as there are predictable components to changes in urban wages and
amenities. The ARMA(1,1) structure of the shocks makes it possible to have the positive
correlation of changes at high frequencies and the negative correlation at low frequencies
The city can grow with new construction so that N (t ) equals N (t − 1) + I (t ) , where
I(t) is the amount of construction in time t. 9 The physical, administrative and land costs
housing production should have a bigger impact on current construction costs than
housing production many years ago.10 Investment decisions for time t are made based on
time t-1 information, and there is free entry of risk neutral builders. Thus, if there is any
8
This assumption limits the possible role of housing bubbles. While our focus here is on a purely rational
model, we expect that future work will consider dropping this assumption.
9
For simplicity, we do not allow depreciation which may be reasonable for shorter term housing dynamics,
but would not be appropriate for a very long term analysis of city population changes.
10
We deviate from the investment cost assumptions of Topel and Rosen (1988) by assuming that costs are
increasing with the total level of development and not with changes in the level of investment.
9
building, construction costs will equal the time t expected housing price as described in
equation (3):
(3) Et −1 ( H (t )) = C + c0 t + c1 I (t ) + c 2 N (t − 1) .
As mentioned above, we assume that demand for the city is sufficiently robust so that
there is always a positive quantity of new construction and this equation always holds.11
Equations (1) and (3) then together describe housing supply and demand.
These equations give us the steady state values of housing prices, investment and
+ Iˆt .
rc 2 + α (1 + r ) (rc 2 + α (1 + r )) 2
If x(t)=0 for all t, and Nˆ (t ) = N (t ) for some initial period, then these quantities would
fully describe this representative city.12 Secular trends in housing prices can come from
trend in housing demand as long as c 2 > 0 , or the trend in construction costs as long as
α > 0 . If c 2 = 0 so that construction costs don’t increase with total city size, then trends
in wages or amenities will impact city size but not housing prices. If α = 0 and city size
doesn’t decrease wages or amenities, then trends in construction costs will impact city
11
The model can be extended to allow for the possibility that, in some states of the world, new construction
will be zero. This adds much complication and only a modest amount of insight into our questions.
12
In this case, the assumption that there is always some construction requires that q (1 + r ) > rc 0 .
10
Proposition 1 describes housing prices and investment when there are shocks to
This proposition describes the movement of housing prices and construction around their
φ +θ
steady state levels. A temporary shock, ε , will increase housing prices by and
φ −δ
(1 + r )(δ + θ )
increase construction by . Higher values of δ ( i.e., more permanent
c1 (φ − δ )
shocks) will make both of these effects stronger. Higher values of c1 mute the
construction response to shocks and increase the price response to a temporary shock (by
reducing the quantity response). These comparative statics provide the intuition that
places which are quantity constrained should have less construction volatility and more
price volatility.
The next proposition provides implications about expected housing price changes.
Proposition 2: At time t, the expected home price change between time t and t + j is
Hˆ (t + j ) − Hˆ (t ) +
α (1 + r )
1+ r −φ
(
− φ j −1 ((1 − φ )c1 − c 2 ) N (t ) − Nˆ (t ) )
1 1 + r δ j −1 ((1 − δ )c1 − c2 ) − φ j −1 ((1 − φ )c1 − c2 )
− x(t ) + − 1 Et ( x(t + 1)) ,
φ − δ c1 φ −δ
the expected change in the city housing stock between time t and t + j is
11
1+ r φ j −δ j
jIˆ +
c1 (φ − δ ) φ − δ
Et ( x(t + 1)) − (1 − φ j ) N (t ) − Nˆ (t ) ,( )
and expected time t + j construction is
δ (1 − δ ) − φ j −1 (1 − φ )
( )
j −1
1+ r
Iˆ + Et ( x(t + 1)) − φ j −1 (1 − φ ) N (t ) − Nˆ (t ) .
c1 (φ − δ ) φ −δ
housing prices is fully compatible with predictability in housing prices. If utility flows in
a city are high today and expected to be low in the future, then housing prices will also be
expected to decline over time. Any predictability of wages and construction means that
The predictability of construction and prices comes in part from the convergence
to steady state values. If x(t ) = ε (t ) = 0 and initial population is above its steady state
levels, then prices and investment are expected converge on their steady state levels from
above. If initial population is below its steady state level and x(t ) = ε (t ) = 0 , then price
and population is expected to converge on their steady state levels from below. The rate
c1 c2
of convergence is determined by r and the ratios and . Higher levels of these
α α
ratios will cause the rate of convergence to slow by reducing the extent that new
12
Proposition 3 highlights that this model not only delivers mean reversion, but
overshooting. Figure 3 shows the response of population, construction and prices relative
to their steady state levels in response to a one time shock. Construction and prices
immediately shoot up, but both start to decline from that point. At first, population rises
slowly over time, but as the shock wears off, the heightened construction means that the
city is too large relative to its steady state level. Eventually, both construction and prices
end up below their steady state levels because there is too much housing in the city
relative to its wages and amenities. Places with positive shocks will experience mean
Finally, we turn to the puzzling empirical fact that, across the 1980s and 1990s,
there was strong mean reversion of prices and strong positive serial correlation in
population levels. We address this by looking at the one period covariance of price and
population changes. We focus on one-period for simplicity, but think of this proposition
as relating to longer time periods. Since mean reversion dominates over long time
Proposition 4: If N (0) = Nˆ (0) , θ = 0 , x(0) = ε (0) , cities differ only in their demand
trends q and their shock terms ε (0) , ε (1) and ε (2) , and the demand trends are
uncorrelated with the demand shocks, then the coefficient estimated when regressing
second period population growth on first period population growth will be positive if and
δ (rc 2 + α (1 + r ) )
2
Var (q )
only if > (1 − δ − φ ) while the coefficient estimated when
Var (ε ) c1 (φ − δ )
regressing second period price growth on first period price growth will be negative if and
2
rc 2 + α (1 + r ) Var (q )
only if Ω > , where
(1 + r )c1c 2 (φ − δ ) Var (ε )
α (1 + r ) 2 δ αδ (1 + r ) 2
Ω= + c1 (1 − δ )φ (1 − δ − φ ) + c1 (1 − δ + δ 2 )φ .
1+ r −φ 1+ r −φ
13
Proposition 4 tells us that positive correlation of quantities and negative
correlation of prices are quite compatible in the model. The positive correlation of
quantities is driven by the heterogeneous trends in demand across urban areas. As long as
the variance of these trends is high enough relative to the variance of temporary shocks,
sufficiently low, prices will mean revert. As discussed above, when c2 is low, trends will
have little impact on steady state price growth. The positive trends show up mainly in the
level of prices. However, regardless of the value of c2 , unexpected shocks impact prices
This suggests two requirements for the observed positive correlation of quantities
and negative correlation of prices: city-specific trends must differ significantly and the
impact of city size on construction costs must be small. The extensive heterogeneity in
city-specific trends is much commented on, with the recent papers by Gyourko, Mayer,
and Sinai (2006) and Van Nieuwerburgh and Weill (2006) attempting to explain the
phenomenon. The literature on housing investment suggests that the impact of city size
on construction costs is small (Topel and Rosen, 1988; Gyourko and Saiz, 2006). Thus,
We now use the model as a calibration tool to see what moments of the data,
including its serial correlation properties and variances, can and cannot be explained by
14
our framework. We focus on the movements in prices and construction intensity around
steady state levels. The appendix contains the formulae for the predicted values of these
moments.13 The model’s predictions about variances and serial correlations depend on
seven parameters: the real interest rate (r), the degree to which demand declines with city
population ( α ), the degree to which construction responds to higher costs (c1 and c2),
the time series pattern of local economic shocks ( δ and ), and the variation of those
2
shocks ( ). Table 1 reports the value of these parameters which are used in the
calibration exercise, with the remainder of this section discussing how we estimate or
impute them.
The first row of Table 1 shows that we use a real interest rate (r) of 4 percent in all
calibrations. This value is higher than standard estimates of the real rate because it is also
meant to reflect other facets of the cost of owning, such as taxes or maintenance
expenses, that might scale with housing. Experimentation shows that the simulation
results are robust to a wide range of alternative values of r (e.g., from 2.5-5 percent).
The housing cost parameters are both particularly important for our model and
relatively understudied by the literature. The parameter c1 reflects the extent that
construction costs, including land assembly, permitting and physical construction costs,
13
We do not use the high frequency correlations of prices with other variables to pin down parameter
values. Changes in house prices and changes in income accompany each other at longer horizons (e.g.,
over the past twenty years, the correlation of the two changes is over 50 percent), but the correlation is
much weaker at higher frequencies. Higher frequency correlations are difficult to interpret because the real
world information structure may not match that presumed in our model. For example, if income shocks are
known a period earlier, this will not matter much for predicted variances and serial correlations, but it will
dramatically alter the predicted relationship between income and price changes.
15
rise with the level of current construction activity. The c2 parameter measures the
Topel and Rosen (1988) use national data and estimate a supply elasticity ranging
from 1.4 and 2.2. This supply elasticity is the relationship between the logarithm of
investment and the logarithm of price, which in our model would equal H (t ) / c1 I (t ) .
Using the mean values of investment and housing prices across our cities and an elasticity
of 1.8, this generates a range of c1 from 1 to 151. The median value is 18 which seems
too high to us. The range between 25th and 75th percentiles of the distribution is 5 to 28,
within the data. While this violates the typical calibration rule of using parameter
estimates from outside the data to be explained, we think that this exercise is useful in
generating a range of possible construction cost values. We estimate them for each of our
115 metropolitan areas and use this broad range in our simulations.14 Our hope is that by
showing results for a wide range of estimates, we can diffuse worries that naturally arise
from the fact that our estimates were made using the data that we are trying to explain.
14
Physical construction costs vary the least across U.S. markets, but Gyourko and Saiz (2006) report a 20
percent gap across the interquartile range of major metropolitan areas. The differences are driven largely
by the degree of union penetration in the local construction trades and select other local factors. The nature
of local land use regulation varies much more dramatically by market, with little binding constraint on new
development in markets such as Atlanta and Las Vegas, while the Boston and Bay Area markets have very
stringent and expensive regulation that makes it very hard to build even though market prices of homes are
well above physical construction costs in those places. [See Glaeser and Gyourko (2003), Glaeser,
Gyourko, and Saks (2006), and Saks (2006)) for studies on the impacts of differing land use regulation.]
16
κVar ( H (t ) − C − c0 t − c1 Iˆ − c 2 ( N (0) + tIˆ) , where the parameter κ is one minus the R2
from the best possible prediction of next period’s housing price. To determine this
unexplained share of the deviation from actual house prices, we begin by regressing
house prices on year and metropolitan area dummies. The R2 from that fixed effects
specification is 0.935. When we add two lags of house prices and housing permits to the
specification, the R2 increases to 0.993. Thus, κ = 10% or (0.1 ~ 0.07/0.7) based on these
The numerator of this ratio is the variance of the house price prediction error, weighted
by the share of unexplained variation. The denominator contains two components. The
first reflects the variation associated with yearly new construction deviating from its
average level. The second term in the denominator, which is weighted by , captures the
variation associated with the market’s housing stock being off its trend amount.
To empirically use equation (5), we must impute the housing stock (the N(t-1)
term) because the census provides actual counts of the stock only once each decade. For
each metropolitan area, we know the housing stock at the beginning and end of each
decade and the permits issued each year in between. Our estimate of the housing stock at
j −1
Permitst +i
time t+j, is N (t ) + i =0
9
( N (t + 10) − N (t )) , where N(t) and N(t+10) are the
i =0
Permitst +i
17
housing stocks measured during the two closest censuses. The change in housing stock is
portioned across years based on the observed permitting activity. To measure how many
units the market should have had each year (the “ N (0) + (t − 1) Iˆ ” term), we use the actual
count of the housing stock from the decennial census in our initial year of 1980 and
assume that I-hat is the average change in the actual housing stock between 1980 and
Since costs do not appear to vary much based on city development, we conclude
that c1 > c2, but beyond that, the literature yields little to help us pin down the
relationship between c1 and c2. We consider a range of values for , including 0, 0.25,
and 0.50.15
The bottom two panels of Table 1 report the distribution of estimated values of c1
and c2 for the three different values of omega. If =0.25, there is a wide range of values
for c1 from 1.5 for the 10th percentile metropolitan area to 28.1 for the 90th percentile
area. The mean value of c1 is 13.6 which is twice the median market’s c1 value of 6.4,
15
An alternative method of estimating these parameters suggests a value of 0.25 for . That approach to
estimating the construction cost parameters follows Rosen and Topel (1988) in inverting the construction
cost equation to obtain I(t) = (1/c1)(Et-1[H(t) – C) – (c2/c1)(Nt-1). In empirically implementing this equation,
we used total housing permits in period t to proxy for new construction in period t+1, and actual house
prices to measure expected values. Obviously, the use of actual prices in lieu of expected prices introduces
some bias, but it should be small since the annual time period over which price is measured is relatively
short. We also imputed the housing stock (N(t)) each year as described above. A simple regression of each
market’s resulting c2 value on its c1 value (with no intercept, as suggested by our assumed functional form)
yielded a coefficient of 0.25. The estimated coefficient is 0.21 if we allow for an intercept. The simple
correlation between c1 and c2 values estimated this way is quite high at 0.92. Finally, it is noteworthy that
the absolute level of these c1 values is higher than those reported in Table 1 based on the approach
described in equations (4) and (5). This was to be expected given that this alternative strategy effectively
assumes that price only reflects demand, not supply, shocks. To the extent that prices incorporate
productivity-enhancing changes, the relationship between new construction and values is magnified. More
problematic for this alternative approach is the issue of the potential endogeneity of housing prices with
respect to new construction. We also estimated a singe nationwide regression using the interaction of
initial industrial characteristics and national economic success of the industries as instruments (as in Bartik,
1989). When a linear specification is estimated, the coefficients are quite imprecise. When we follow
Rosen and Topel (1988) and use a log-log specification, we precisely estimate an elasticity of 2, which
implies a range of estimates of c1 and c2 similar to those presented in Table 1.
18
which reflects the skewness of the distribution of costs. A handful of large and
expanding markets such as Atlanta, Charlotte, Houston, and Dallas have c1 values below
one.16 The top ten percent of markets in terms of c1 values are all in Hawaii, along the
coast of California, or in the suburbs of New York City. These high values of c1 appear
to reflect both high labor costs and regulations that constrain construction.17 The
interquartile range of c2 runs from 0.7 to 3.3. The median value is 1.6
The value of reflects the impact that an increase in the housing stock will have
on the willingness to pay to live in a locale. If population was fixed, equation (2) tells us
that the derivative of housing prices with respect to the housing stock equals - (1 + r )α / r ,
which can be seen as the slope of the housing demand curve. Typically, housing demand
While many housing demand elasticity estimates are around one (or slightly
below-in absolute value), there is a wide range in the literature, so we experiment with a
multiplying by the ratio of price to population, which produces a range of estimates for
We will use a parameter estimate of 0.1 in our simulations which implies that for every
10,000 extra homes sold, the marginal purchaser likes living in the area $1,000 less per
16
The Atlanta area has the lowest value at 0.39.
17
The values for the metropolitan areas of Honolulu, Salinas, Santa Cruz, and Napa each are above 70.
While we cannot tell for sure, these magnitudes probably are associated with regulatory costs, as they seem
too high to solely reflect labor.
19
year (see row 5 of Table 1). This estimate seems high to us, but lower estimated values
The model does not separately address wages and amenities. There is little
evidence on high frequency changes in amenities, except for crime rates which we will
discuss in Section V. Consequently, we assume here that the high frequency movement
and trend will eliminate the term w0 − γN (0) + w1t , and the residual component of wages
The most difficult part of estimating the x(t) process is our attempt to control the
impact of population changes, but while our procedure is debatable, it has little impact on
the estimated properties of x(t). The parameter represents the impact that an increase in
city size will have on wages, which is proportional to the impact of labor supply on wage
(or the slope of the labor demand function). Customarily, labor demand is estimated as
statistically indistinguishable from zero (e.g., Card and Butcher, 1991). Borjas (2003)
finds a higher estimate of -0.3, although this is at the national level. We use this upper-
18
The distinguished literature on regional shocks (e.g. Blanchard and Katz, 1992) does not yield the
parameter estimates that we need to calibrate the model.
20
bound estimate, but note that it has little differential effect on our results compared to
Just as with housing demand, we must convert this elasticity into an estimate of
γ . We use BEA data on personal income per capita as our measure of wages, and for our
sample of metropolitan areas, the mean of this variable in 1990 (the middle of our sample
period) was $26,965 (in $2,000). Mean employment in 1990 across these metropolitan
areas was 539,215, so our ratio of wage to the labor force is about 0.05
worker is associated with 1.5 cents less annual income in the city. In our sample, there
are on average 1.26 workers per home, so each extra home is associated with 1.9 cents
The per capita income series is converted into household income by multiplying
by 2.63 (the average ratio of people per household in our sample in 1990). We adjust this
income variable for N(t) using our estimate of 0.019 for γ and by using
j −1
Permitst +i
N (t ) + i =0
9
( N (t + j ) − N (t )) (as above) as our estimate of total housing stock
i =0
Permitst +i
With this corrected income series, we can estimate the time series properties of
income shocks at the local level, by fitting an ARMA(1,1) to the wage series that is first
demeaned with city and year fixed effects and then corrected for city size changes as
21
discussed above. As shown in Table 1, this estimation procedure yields estimates of
2
=0.87, =0.17, and = $3,603,463.19
In this section, we calibrate the model using the parameters values discussed
above. We then compare this calibration to the moments of the real data. We first
discuss the time series coefficients of prices and construction, and then discuss the
volatility of these series. Our “real data” sample is a set of 115 metropolitan areas for
which we have continuously defined price data from 1980-2005. As discussed above,
our simulations assume that the real interest rate (r) equals 0.04, the variance of the local
2
economic shock ( ) equals $3,603,463, the parameters of the ARMA process describing
that shock are 0.87 ( ) and 0.17 ( ), and the valuation of the metropolitan area by the
marginal entrant ( ) is 0.1. We let c1 and c2 equal the fifteen different pairwise
combinations associated with the three different values of omega and report simulation
Short-Term Momentum and Longer-Term Mean Reversion in Prices, Rents and Permits
The top row of Table 2 provides evidence on momentum and mean reversion in
OFHEO house prices within market over time. We use absolute price changes rather
than changes in the logarithm of prices in order to be compatible with the model, but our
empirical results are not sensitive to such changes in functional form. Since the OFHEO
index only provides price increases relative to a base year, we convert this into an implied
19
Largely because is so small throughout its relevant range, this adjustment to wages does not have a
material impact on our results. If we use a value of 0 for γ , we estimate a value of δ = 0.86, an estimate of
θ = 0.18, and an estimate of 2=$3,408,250 In addition, we attempted joint maximum likelihood
estimation of , , and 2 for given trend effects and metropolitan area fixed effects, but the program would
not converge because the panel was too short relative to the number of markets.
22
price series by using the median housing value in the metropolitan area in 1980 as a base
price in the metropolitan area and then scaling that value by the appreciation in the
The results are estimates from a regression of the current change in prices on the
for j equal to one, three and five years. Because fixed effects estimates such as these
which remove market-specific averages can be biased (with spurious mean reversion
produced especially when the number of time periods is relatively low), in the first row of
Table 2, we report Arellano-Bond estimates which use lagged values of the dependent
Our one year estimate of price change serial correlation is 0.71, so a $1 increase
in housing prices between time t and t+1 is associated with a 71 cent increase between
time t+1 and t+2. Our estimate is larger than that reported by the pioneering work of
Case and Shiller (1989). It is now well understood that smoothing of the underlying data
series can bias one towards finding short-run momentum. Case and Shiller (1989) were
able to address this problem by splitting their sample, which consisted of extensive micro
data on sales transactions in four markets (Atlanta, Chicago, Dallas, and San Francisco).
They report coefficients ranging from 0.2-0.5, although they use the logarithm, not the
20
This procedure essentially provides the real price for a constant quality house with the quality being that
associated with the median house in 1980. We have experimented with using values from the 1990 and
2000 censuses as the base. All the results reported below are robust to such changes.
21
See Arellano and Bond (1991) for more detail on this estimation procedure. More specifically, we use
the “xtabond” Stata command with year and area fixed effects.
23
level, of prices so the results are not exactly comparable. Because we cannot perform
any comparable procedure with the OFHEO data, our estimate is surely biased upwards.22
Over three years, there is still momentum. The estimate of 0.27 means that a $1
increase in housing prices between time t and t+3 is associated with a 27 cent increase
between time t+3 and t+6. Over five year periods, we estimate a mean reversion
coefficient of -0.32, so a $1 increase between times t and t+5 is associated with a 32 cent
decline between time t+5 and t+10.23 These estimates are not an artifact of the Arellano-
Bond procedure. The analogous ordinary least squares estimates over 1, 3, and 5 year
The mean reversion in prices that we estimate over five-year horizons is quite
similar in magnitude to that observed for financial assets by Fama and French (1988).
Unfortunately, the short time period for which we have constant quality data at less than
permanent feature of urban life or whether it represents the impact of shocks that are
specific to the post-1980 time period. Cutler, Poterba and Summers (1991) also find this
22
The OFHEO index includes data on repeat sales or refinancings of the same house. The latter typically
rely on an appraisal, not a market sale price. Undoubtedly, this results in smoothing of the series and biases
upward our estimate of short-run momentum. Even the Case and Shiller (1989) estimates, which rely only
on actual sales, could be upward biased. Working with a split sample, bias can result if, randomly, some
fraction of homes on which a buyer and seller agree on a price have delayed closings that move their
reported sales dates into the next reported period (quarter, year, etc.). Whatever shock there was in period t
that influenced the agreed upon price, some of its measured impact will spill over into period t+1.
Obviously this is potentially more of a problem the shorter the measurement period.
23
As noted in the Introduction, decadal changes also find significant mean reversion across the 1980s and
1990s.
24
We also addressed concerns about spurious mean reversion by estimating specifications without
metropolitan area fixed effects. If we estimate the following equation,
Pr icet +5 − Pr icet = α + γ Year + β (Pr icet − Pr icet −5 ) , the mean reversion coefficient drops to -0.11 and
becomes only marginally significant. However, as soon as we include percent of adults with college
degrees as a control, the coefficient becomes -0.18 with a t-statistic of three. If we estimate the same
change regression using the logarithm of prices instead of the levels, the coefficient is -0.20 (-0.22 with the
college graduate control) and has a t-statistic of four.
24
pattern of short run momentum and longer- run mean reversion for housing and a number
Table 3 reports the comparable results for our simulations using the different c1
and c2 values discussed above. All other parameter values are fixed at the values listed in
Table 1. The first three columns show results for annual serial correlation in prices, the
next three columns present the analogous findings over three year periods, with the final
three columns being for five year periods. Within each time horizon, the fifteen cells
The first three columns document the model’s failure to match the positive serial
correlation observed in the annual data. In fact, our parameter estimates suggest a mild
amount of mean reversion even at such a high frequency. Similarly, the results for three
year horizons reported in the middle columns of Table 3 find a mismatch with the data.
Assuming the middle case for omega ( =0.25, column 4), we predict mean reversion
coefficients from -0.18 to -0.28, not the positive persistence we see in the data.
Our model does a much better job of fitting the -0.32 mean reversion seen at five
year intervals (columns 6-9). At five year horizons, if c1 and c2 are at their medians for
the case of =0.25, we come within ten percent of matching the data (see row 3, column
8). And, if c1=2.7 and c2=0.7, the prediction literally is -0.32 (row 2, column 8). Thus,
the predictable mean reversion of prices at five year intervals cannot be seen as a
In the model, this mean reversion reflects both the tendency of shocks to mean
revert and of new construction to cause future declines in prices. To decompose the
impact of the two forces, we also looked at the cases where there is no new construction
25
impact (i.e., =0) and where there is no mean reversion in the x(t) parameter. When
mean reversion in wages is turned off (i.e., =1), our simulations predict very low levels
of overall mean reversion in house prices. However, we predict higher levels of mean
reversion close to those found in the data when there is no effect allowed from
construction increasing market size. Thus, our analysis suggests that the majority of
mean reversion is coming from the mean reversion of local demand shocks.
One way to check whether short run momentum reflects the dynamics of euphoria
in an asset market is to see if the same phenomenon appears in rents. In the second row
Rental data on apartments is collected by an industry consultant and data provider, REIS
Inc. Their data covers only a limited number of metropolitan areas (46 in our sample),
Over one- and three-year horizons, there is strong evidence of persistence, with
the Arellano-Bond estimates being 0.27 in both cases. Over five year time horizons, we
estimate a mean reversion parameter of -0.64. The presence of momentum and mean
reversion in rents suggests that these features do not reflect something unique to housing
asset markets, but rather something about the changing demand for cities.26
Table 4 then reports the predicted values of serial correlation from the simulations
of the model. At annual frequencies, we tend to predict very modest persistence, with the
25
Rental units are overwhelmingly in multi-unit buildings, while owner-occupied housing is
overwhelmingly single-family detached housing. These differences in housing types and the problem of
accurately measuring maintenance costs are two reasons why it is extremely difficult to tell whether
housing prices are high or low relative to rents.
26
The ordinary least squares estimates of these coefficients are 0.28, 0.08 and -0.51 for one, three and five
year horizons, respectively.
26
results ranging from -0.05 to 0.08 when =0.25 (column 2). These estimates are well
below the 0.27 seen in the data over one year horizons. Over three year horizons, we
consistently predict mean reversion, while there is still a positive correlation of rents in
the data. For five year intervals, we predict that rent changes should have a mean
reversion coefficient of about -0.30 if we use the median value of 6.4 and 1.6,
respectively, for c1 and c2 when =0.25 (row 3, column 8). Slightly higher mean
reversion is predicted if c1 is lower, but our estimates still are only about one-half of the
We are again unable to explain the strong positive serial correlations at shorter
time horizons. Since there are many reasons to be suspicious about the properties of the
rental data, especially because of artificial smoothing, we do not attach much importance
to the quantitative mismatch with the data here.27 However, the short run momentum and
long run mean reversion of rents, which are predicted by the model, suggest that these
from the Census of Construction. The final set of results reported in Table 2 use housing
permits estimated in the following regression: Permits tt + j = α MSA + γ Year + βPermits tt− j ,
where Permits tt− j refers to the number of permits issued between time t-j and time t. The
one-three and five year Arellano-Bond coefficient estimates are 0.84, 0.43, and -0.07,
27
For example, smoothing is a greater problem in the rental data. The industry consultant that provides the
rent data does not survey actual renters, but the landlord owners of apartment buildings. Undoubtedly,
averages are being reported.
27
respectively. Thus, construction also displays high frequency momentum, but little or no
The calibration results for this variable are provided in Table 5. For the case
where c1 and c2 are the median values when =0.25, the predicted coefficients are 0.60,
0.29 and 0.06, for one, three, and five year horizons, respectively. These are reasonably
close to the actual parameters, and minor changes in the values of one or both of the
supply side parameters enable us to fit the data more exactly. While the predictions about
the serial correlation of construction are not as accurate as the predictions about the mean
reversion in prices, the moments of the real data cannot be said to reject the model.
Thus, the model does a reasonable job at fitting the time series properties of new
building and an excellent job at fitting the long term mean reversion of rents. It does a
poor job of fitting the high frequency positive serial correlation of price changes. This
momentum, or as Case and Shiller (1989) suggest, some sort of irrationality in the
housing market.
Table 6 reports the variance of price changes and of new construction in our
sample.29 The volatility of both prices and construction varies enormously across cities
and is quite skewed, with the mean variance much higher than the median variance.
Consequently, our approach to documenting both housing price change and construction
variance is to first run a pooled market regression (separately for each variable, of course)
28
As is the case with the other data, this pattern is not an artifact of our estimation procedure. The
analogous ordinary least squares coefficients are 0.82, 0.37, and 0.07, respectively.
29
Since the rent data are smoothed, we don’t put much weight on the variance of rents and exclude them
from this part of the analysis.
28
controlling for year effects, and then to compute the variance of the residuals from this
regression by metropolitan area. This variance gives us the volatility of prices and
The top panel of Table 6 shows that that the variance of one year price changes
equals $14 million in the tenth percentile metropolitan area and $209 million in the 90th
percentile market. The median market has a one year price change variance of $34
million, which is much smaller that the sample mean of $83 million. This skewness is
driven primarily by California markets and Honolulu. The variance of one-year price
changes in Honolulu is $763 million, which is the largest in our sample. Five other
markets—San Jose, San Francisco, Santa Barbara, Santa Ana and Salinas--had variances
The second and third columns of this table report the distribution of variances of
three and five year price changes. The distribution of longer horizon price changes is
again quite skewed, with the mean price change substantially exceeding the change for
the median area. The volatility of price changes is very high at longer horizons. The
variance in five-year price changes is $625 million for the median market, with one
Table 7 reports predicted price change variances from our simulations with the
results arrayed in the same manner as in the serial correlation tables above. At annual
frequencies (columns 1-3), we predict a range of price change variances from a low of
$50 million to a high of $181 million. Not surprisingly, price change volatility is lower
the smaller are c1 and c2—markets in which quantity changes a lot with changes in costs.
However, our variance prediction for the lowest (c1, c2) combination still is well above
29
the $34 million variance found in the median market. Data smoothing would bias price
volatility downward over short time periods, and if so, we would expect this problem to
Our ability to match the volatility of price changes does increase with the horizon
over which those changes are measured. For example, the range of predicted variances of
3-year price changes across all 15 (c1, c2) combination runs from $123-$488 million
(columns 3-6, Table 7). This spans the interquartile range of $124-$445 million found in
the data (column 2, top panel of Table 6), but we still need to have a relatively low value
for c1 (2.7) and a c2=0 to closely match the median. This is not the case for the 5-year
price change variance predictions listed in the final three columns of Table 7. Our range
of predictions runs from $163-$718 million, allowing us to capture much of the lower
half of the distribution of actual price change variation reported in the third column of
The median (c1, c2) pair of 6.4 and 1.6 when =0.25 is associated with a predicted
variance of $469 million, which still underpredicts the sample median ($625 million), but
higher c1 values allow us to come much closer. However, we are still unable to approach
matching the very high price change volatility found in the top quarter of markets, and
the top ten percent, especially. That is an issue to which we will turn in the next section.
In sum, the general pattern of results in Table 7 shows an overestimate of price volatility
at high frequencies which then disappears at lower frequencies. This trend is consistent
with data smoothing, but it could also reflect a flaw in our model.
The bottom panel of Table 6 reports the variance in units permitted across our
115 metropolitan area sample. As with price changes, there is substantial heterogeneity
30
in the volatility of construction intensity across markets, and this distribution is skewed
by a few outliers. For example, the bottom quartile of markets has a new construction
variance of about 2 million units per annum, while the top quartile is at least five times
more volatile. Moreover, this distribution is skewed by relatively few markets in the
right tail that have variances of at least 38 million units (column 1, bottom panel of Table
6). Six markets—Phoenix, Dallas, Riverside-San Bernardino, Atlanta, Los Angeles, and
Houston---stand out in this regard, having construction intensity variances that are at least
double the next six highest variance markets. There also is great heterogeneity in
construction intensity variance over longer horizons, as the second and third columns of
Table 8 reports the construction intensity variance estimates from our standard set
of simulations. Over annual periods, our model does a decent job of matching this data.
Our range of predicted construction variances runs from 300 thousand to 42 million units.
This captures the bulk of the range across markets in the actual data, which is 2 million
units in the 10th percentile market and 38 million units in the 90th percentile market
(Table 6). The median market in our sample has a one year standard deviation of 3
million units, which precisely equals the 3 million unit variance we predict if c1=6.4, the
Over three year horizons, we can match the median market in the nation as well,
but the fit is not as perfect. For example, the three-year construction variance in the
median market is 26 million units (middle column, bottom panel of Table 6), while we
predict a 21 million unit variance for our ‘median’ (c1, c2) combination of 6.4 and 1.6
(see the middle cell in columns 4-6 of Table 8). Our range of estimates using our ‘lower’
31
(but not ‘lowest’ (c1, c2) values as in row 2 of these columns) spans the 84 million unit
variance associated with the 75th percentile metropolitan area (Table 6). Our ability to
match outcomes weakens for the most volatile markets. Our top variance estimate of 189
million units for three year horizons is only 58 percent of the 328 million unit variance
horizons. Our full range of estimates runs from 3-328 million units, versus a 10th-90th
percentile range of 29-760 million in the data. Our ‘median’ estimate of 44 million units
is only three-quarters of the national market median of 59 million. Just as in the case of
prices, we are able to fit the volatility of the median markets with plausible parameter
values, but we completely fail to predict the volatility of the more extreme cases.
The model implies that markets with elastic supplies of housing (i.e., those with
low c1 and c2 values) should have relatively low price change variation and relatively
high construction volatility. Concomitantly, those areas with high c1 and c2 values that
have inelastic supplies will have little variation in quantities and more volatility in prices.
Hence, if our estimation procedure for determining these two supply side parameters
One natural explanation for these extreme markets is that we have significantly
overestimated the value of c1 and c2 in sunbelt region markets with elastic supplies of
housing. To address the role that mismeasurement of these parameters can play, we ran
four additional simulations using values for c1 and c2 from the Atlanta, Phoenix, San
Francisco, and Salinas (CA) metropolitan areas. The Atlanta market has the lowest c1
32
value in our sample, and assuming =0.25, its (c1, c2) combination is (0.4, 0.1). Phoenix
also experiences new supply if prices rise even slightly, and its (c1, c2) combination is
(1.0, 0.25). San Francisco and Salinas are at the opposite end of the spectrum, with
Salinas being a particularly extreme outlier. Their (c1, c2) combinations are estimated to
volatility. Our parameter estimates for Phoenix predict 1, 3, and 5 year construction
variances of 34 million, 186 million, and 357 million units, respectively. The analogous
figures for our Atlanta parameter estimates are 74 million units, 361 million units, and
651 million units, respectively. These numbers still are well below what we observe in
the most highly volatile construction markets (e.g., Atlanta’s five year variance is 4.52
billion units), but they do match the values for the market in the 90th percentile of the
distribution (see Table 6). The most volatile construction markets still remain a puzzle
for our model, but we interpret these results to imply that underestimating how elastic the
supply side is could help account for a meaningful part of our underestimation of the
highly volatile coastal markets, that cannot explain the dramatic price change variation
we see in those place. More specifically, the 1, 3, and 5 year predictions assuming supply
side conditions are those found in San Francisco are $181 million, $487 million, and
$714 million, respectively. The Salinas estimates yield similar predictions: $190 million,
$515 million, and $759 million, respectively. These estimates are barely above the
33
maximum values reported in Table 7. Although supply elasticity can explain a
significant amount of the high construction volatility in the sunbelt, supply inelasticity
cannot explain much of the high price volatility in coastal markets. We now turn to other
potential explanations.
To see if we can match the high volatility of housing prices observed in certain
markets in the data, we first turn to omitted demand factors such as local tax rates and
income shocks. Finally, we look at the role of time-varying real interest rates.
While we assume that income volatility is the only source of high frequency
changes in demand in our simulations, changes in local tax rates and amenity flows also
could affect volatility. To address volatility related to tax rates, we used data from the
NBER TAXSIM website on the average tax rate on wage income earned in a given state
each year to create an after-tax income measure for each market. Our analysis of after-
tax income showed that controlling for this factor cannot be responsible for more than a
10 percent increase in local demand variability which would translate into a ten percent
increase in price and construction volatility. Appendix II provides the details, but we
conclude that changes in state level tax rates cannot be driving the high price volatility.
place, (e.g., the weather, local architecture). The demand for these amenities may change
slowly over time as a society becomes richer or more unequal or as new technologies
34
become available, but it is hard to imagine that their value will fluctuate a lot at annual
frequencies. Crime represents one of the few amenities that does change relatively
rapidly and for which there is available data. Since crime represents a possible omitted
amenity, we collected violent crime rates for the largest cities in each of our metropolitan
areas using continuous crime data from 1985-2005.30 We then created an adjusted
income variable that subtracted the negative effect of crime from our BEA real income
measure. As detailed in Appendix III, the results showed almost no impact on the
variability of local demand from controlling for crime. We infer from this that we are
unlikely to be find an amenity with high frequency variation that can explain much of the
There are two reasons why our estimates of income volatility might be
understating the true magnitude of income shocks in high volatility markets. First, our
2
estimate of is based on all 115 markets in the sample, and if income variability were
systematically higher in the high price change variance markets, then our estimates of
price volatility would be biased downward in those markets. Second, our use of BEA per
capita income makes no allowance for the possibility that the volatility of the marginal
focus on coastal markets that have particularly volatile housing prices. We re-estimated
2
using the same ARMA procedure described above for a subsample of 31 markets
whose centroids are within 50 miles of the Atlantic or Pacific Oceans. While the AR ( )
30
We emphasize that this measure is for the local political jurisdiction, which we then impute to the
metropolitan area.
35
and MA ( ) components were little changed from those reported for the 115 market
2
national sample, the estimate of is almost 50 percent higher in the 31 coastal markets:
$5.3 million versus $3.6 million. This difference in volatility of local wage shocks is
large, and to our knowledge, has not been well-documented and is not well-understood.
The puzzle of excess price change variance also could be at least partially
explained if our measure of income variance understates the true year-to-year variation in
the returns from living in the city for the marginal homebuyer. For example, if marginal
buyers are young, then this might mean that their incomes are more volatile. In cities
with vibrant economies, buyers on the margin might be people in the cities’ fastest
growing and most volatile industries. In New York City, the marginal homebuyer might
be more likely to be in finance, for example, and have a more volatile income. In San
Francisco, the marginal homebuyer might be more likely to work in the volatile
technology sector.
To investigate this hypothesis, we turned to the New York City Housing and
York City residents. This survey was available for the years 1978, 1981, 1984, 1987,
1991, 1993, 1996 and 2002. In each year, we calculated the mean income for the sample
of people who bought a house within the last two years. This two year window is meant
to capture the population of recent buyers, while also providing a decent sample size
(e.g., there are between 100 and 400 observations in each year).
36
The incomes for this sample could be more volatile than the BEA per capita
figures simply because of smaller numbers, so our approach is not to look at its variance,
but at its correlation with BEA real income in New York. Specifically, we estimated the
following regression:
(8) Recent Buyer Real Income=-32,451+ 1.29*BEA Per Capita Real Income,
(15,102) (0.19)
There are nine observations (one for each survey year), the R2=0.87, and standard errors
are in parentheses. This regression suggests that recent buyer income increases by $1.29
assume that the value of x(t), the income shock, for recent owners is 1.29 times the shock
for the entire population, then the variance of shocks is 1.66 times the variance for the
entire population.32
Including both effects implies predicted variances in high (c1, c2) markets are 2.4
times greater than those reported in Tables 7 and 8 (1.66*1.44~2.4). Because our
evidence certainly is not strong enough to warrant confidence in such a precise result, we
2
report ranges of values for new simulation results assuming the local demand shock ( )
is 50 percent, 100 percent, and 150 percent greater than the $3.6 million figure used in
31
While the small samples and nine observations make it hard to draw too much from this, it is noteworthy
that this procedure does not generate estimates above $1 automatically. When we performed the same
analysis using the sample of renters in the survey, the following resulted:
The number of observations again is nine, the R2 still is 0.87, and standard errors are in parentheses.
32
In addition, if recent buyer incomes were more cyclical than average incomes, then the variance of prices
might be substantially higher than the variance predicted by the model. A related point is that if the New
York City regressions are to be believed, then the income of renters is far less volatile than the income of
owners. The regression predicts that the variance of their income shocks is one quarter of the variance of
income shocks for the general population. This difference may be one reason why rents are so stable
relative to housing prices, and it also suggests that comparing rents and prices is a very tricky process,
indeed.
37
the baseline simulations reported above. Because the key outstanding price-related
puzzle for our model is the high volatility of lower frequency price changes in the top
quartile of metropolitan areas, the top panel of Table 9 provides new estimated variances
of five-year price changes for markets with the 75th and 90th percentile values of our
supply-side parameters (c1 and c2), assuming more variable local demand shocks.
The first column reproduces our baseline estimates for these parameter values
from Table 7. Recall that those simulation results are well below the $1.17 billion
variance in five-year price changes found in the metropolitan area that is in the 75th
percentile for all such changes, and not even close to the $3.58 billion variance observed
for the 90th percentile market (see column 3, top panel of Table 6 for those values). The
next three columns report predicted variances assuming the three higher estimates of
2
local demand variability. The first row of the third column indicates that needs to be
doubled in order to account for all of the mismatch between predicted and actual variance
While this represents a large increase in local volatility, based on the discussion
above, it is not implausible. However, the results in the second row of the top panel of
Table 9 indicate that our model still cannot account for the most volatile ten percent of
2
markets. If our baseline estimate is off by 150 percent, the predicted variance of
$1.71 billion is only 48 percent of the $3.58 billion variance seen in the 90th percentile
metropolitan area.
Even the best of models have trouble accounting for the outliers in any
distribution. Still, examining the 12 most volatile markets (the top 10 percent of our 115
metropolitan areas), in terms of price changes over five-year periods, shows that what our
38
model just cannot explain is the volatility of coastal California (plus Honolulu). 33
Literally, there are no east coast markets in this group, with the Nassau-Suffolk and
intensity assuming supply-side parameters (c1 and c2) consistent with values associated
with the 10th and 25th percentiles of that distribution and assuming a 66 percent increase
2
in . We focus on the impact in markets with more elastic supply sides because the
remaining puzzle about quantities is the very high variation observed in many of the high
growth sunbelt markets. We only allow demand side volatility to increase by 66 percent
because there is no evidence to suggest their intrinsic income variability is higher than the
average we use in the baseline simulations34, but we would expect the volatility of the
marginal buyer’s income to be greater than the average we are using in the baseline
simulations. Even assuming the NYCHVS results are applicable to these markets, the
results show that underestimating local demand variability cannot account for our
underestimate of quantity variation for the most volatile markets in this respect.
We have so far assumed that interest rates are fixed for reasons of tractability, but
understand that many authors have claimed that the dramatic rise in house prices,
33
The top ten percent of the most volatile metropolitan areas in terms of five-year price changes (in
ascending order from #104-#115) are as follows: Oakland-Fremont-Hayward, Santa Cruz-Watsonville,
San Luis Obispo-Paso Robles, San Diego-Carlsbad-San Marcos, Oxnard-Thousand Oaks-Ventura, Los
Angeles-Long Beach-Glendale, San Jose-Sunnyvale-Santa Clara, Salinas, Santa Ana-Anaheim-Irvine, San
Francisco-San Mateo-Redwood City, Santa Barbara-Santa Maria, and Honolulu.
34
Mathematically, it is somewhat smaller given that coastal market income volatility is higher. We ignore
this effect for simplicity. It does not change any of our conclusions.
39
especially in high cost markets, over the past decade is best understood as a response to
declining interest rates that make housing in those areas more affordable (e.g.,
Himmelberg, Mayer and Sinai, 2005). A full treatment of interest rates would require an
analysis of long period mortgages and prepayment that lies well beyond the scope of this
paper. We can, however, adjust the model modestly to acquire some understanding of
1 1
≈ and r (t )( H (t ) − C ) = r ( H (t ) − C ) + ρ (t )( H − C ) , where H is meant to
1 + r (t ) 1 + r
reflect the average housing price in the city.35 If we adjust equation (2) for time-varying
rC E ( H (t + 1))
(2’) H (t ) − − t = D + qt + x(t ) − ρ (t )( H − C ) − αN (t )
1+ r 1+ r
straightforward fashion.
H (t ) = Hˆ (t ) +
(c1φ + Ψ ) x(t )
+
c1θε (t )
−
α (1 + r )
c1 (φ − δ ) + Ψ c1 (φ − δ ) + Ψ 1 + r − φ
(
N (t ) − Nˆ (t ) )
(9)
(c1φ + Ψ )( H − C ) ρ (t )
−
c1 (φ − λ ) + Ψ
35
The first approximation is minor and would have been unnecessary if we assumed that the utility flow
was received at the end of the period rather than the beginning of each period. The second approximation
eliminates interactions between transitory changes in value and transitory changes in the interest rate and it
may be more consequential.
40
This differs from the price equation in Proposition 1 because of its last term which
c1φ + Ψ
multiplies times the interest rate shock times H − C (the gap between
c1 (φ − δ ) + Ψ
average housing prices in the area and construction costs). This term reflects the fact that
a decline in interest rates essentially is a positive demand shock for high amenity and
productivity places. The shock makes it cheaper to live in such places, pushing up
Since our regressions correct for year effects, this interest rate effect can have no
impact on our empirical estimates for the average market which will have prices close to
construction costs. The interest rate effect does, however, have the capacity to generate
increased variance in both price changes and construction levels for places that are
$25,000, $50,000, $100,000 and $200,000, which over the past 25 years captures most of
We set c1, and c2 equal to 6.4 and 1.6, respectively, in order to focus on interest
rates effects. We assume that =0.90, but experimentation with values as high as 0.95
yield similar results. The variance of interest rates is far more important, and we use a
range of standard deviations for (t) from 0.005 to 0.02 which appears to encompass
36
For example, in 1980 the highest price metropolitan area had a median house value that was about
$170,000 greater than in the median market. The real value of median market’s median house price is
barely changed between 1980 and 2000. Except for a handful of markets in the upper tail of the
metropolitan area price distributions, gaps in excess of $200,000 with the median market do not exist.
Finally, we omit runs with a value of zero because they correspond to the simulations from the previous
section.
37
Campbell’s (2000) review of the asset pricing literature notes that the standard deviation on a one period
riskless asset is 1.76 percent, but concludes that “… perhaps half … is due to ex post inflation shocks (p.
41
Simulations suggest that these changes to our baseline model make little
difference to the amount of predicted mean reversion. Thus, the results in Tables 10 and
11 focus on the impact of interest rate volatility on the variance of price changes and
construction, respectively. Table 10 shows that including interest rates shocks can
generate significant increases in the variance of price changes if the interest rate shock is
quite high and if the market has house prices much greater than the average (and, thus,
much more than construction costs). For example, comparing the predicted variances in
Table 10 for markets $25,000 or $50,000 above the average market with those reported in
Table 7 (for the same (c1, c2) parameters) shows that interest rate volatility does not
increase the predicted volatility of price changes much at all. To generate a predicted
variance above the $209 million observed over annual periods for the 90th percentile
metropolitan area (see Table 6) requires that H-C be $200,000 if the standard deviation of
At three year intervals, the predicted variance without interest rate shocks is $330
million (see the middle cell of Table 7), which is higher than the median market (Table
6), but less than the mean and far less than the 90th percentile metropolitan area.
Including interest rate shocks with a standard deviation of 0.01 and a $100,000 gap
between prices and construction costs increases the predicted variance to $418,000,
which is near the volatility observed in the 75th percentile city according to the figures in
Table 6. To fit the 90th percentile city’s price change variation of $1.38 billion, the gap
between average prices and construction costs needs to be $200,000 dollars and the
1519).” Thus, the lower half of this range may be more plausible. Recent asset pricing papers such as
Bansal, Kiku, and Yaron (2006) assume a standard deviation of 1 percent.
42
standard deviation of interest rates needs to be much greater than 0.01. We think that
At five year intervals, including interest rate shocks again increases the predicted
variation significantly in the most attractive or productive markets, but the predicted
variation is still far less than is actually observed in the most volatile markets according
to the data in Table 6. A 0.01 standard deviation interest rate shock and a $100,000 gap
between housing prices in the city and construction costs increase the predicted variance
by about one quarter. To get the much higher variances that we seen in the data, the gulf
between prices and construction costs must be over $100,000 and the shock to interest
The ability of interest rate shocks to explain the high level of variation in
construction is far more limited. For example, Table 11 documents that even if the
standard deviation of shocks is 0.02 and H − C equals $200,000, the model still does not
predict the sample mean variance of construction. At more reasonable parameter values,
such as a standard deviation of interest rate shocks of 0.01 and H − C equal to $100,000,
interest rate shocks predict almost no increase in the variance of construction at one year
increase in construction variance of 25 percent at five year intervals. Thus, interest rate
One clear implication of the model is that if interest rate shocks are important,
then the variance of price changes and construction should be higher in high price areas.
Figure 4 graphs the variance of one year price changes for each metropolitan area against
its average price in 1980. The graph shows a strong positive relationship, just as
43
predicted by the role of interest rates. The most volatile places in the country are places
that were most expensive in 1980. Interest rate shocks are one explanation of this
phenomenon. However, another possible explanation is that these places had high costs
because they restricted construction, so that Figure 4 is showing the impact of restricted
that interest rates can generate this high level of price volatility more readily than
restricted construction without interest rate shocks. We suspect both phenomena are at
In Figure 5, we graph the variance of one year construction rates on the average
price in the metropolitan area in 1980. In this case, there is no visible relationship,
perhaps because restrictions on construction in high cost areas ensure low levels of
construction volatility. Nonetheless, we think that both Tables 10 and 11 and Figures 4
and 5 suggest that interest rates shocks can plausibly play a role in explaining some of the
observed price volatility in high cost areas. Those results also suggest that interest rates
are unlikely to explain high construction volatility in lower cost, sunbelt areas.
VI. Conclusion
based on a cross-city spatial equilibrium. The model predicts that housing markets will
be largely local, which they are, and that construction persistence is fully compatible with
price mean reversion. The model is also consistent with price changes being predictable.
The model has successes and failures at fitting the real data. The model can
explain the serial correlation of construction quantities reasonably well and can explain
44
the five year mean reversion of prices almost perfectly. However, the model cannot
explain the high frequency positive serial correlation of price changes. The model can
explain the price and construction volatility of the nation’s typical housing markets, but it
Time-varying interest rates can in principle explain some of the price variation in
high cost markets, but interest rates are unlikely to explain much of the extreme cases of
construction variation. Our simulations showed that interest rate shocks do a better job of
fitting the markets with high levels of price variance than the markets with high levels of
construction variance. Across cities, price volatility is concentrated in high costs areas,
which is a prediction of the model when it includes interest rates. Construction volatility
is concentrated in lower cost markets, which the model suggests should have little
There are two problems with concluding too much from our interest rate findings.
contracts such as a the prepayment option which seem crucial to us in understanding the
impact the interest rates will have on price dynamics. Second, empirically, interest rates
explain only a small portion of price volatility even in high price areas. We hope that
Finally, the value of this model is as much in what it cannot explain as in what it
can explain. It suggests that housing economists should focus their attention on high
price volatility in coastal markets and on the positive serial correlation of price changes.
The average volatility and longer-term mean reversion of prices should no longer be
viewed as puzzles.
45
References
Alonso, William (1964). Location and Land Use. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press.
Arellano, Manuel and Stephen Bond (1991). “Some Tests of Specification for Panel
Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations”, Review
of Economic Studies, Vol. 58, no. 2 (April): 277-97.
Baker, Dean (2006). “The Menace of an Unchecked Housing Bubble”, The Economists’
Voice, Vol. 3, no. 4, Article 1.
Bansal, Ravi, Dana Kiku, and Amir Yaron (2006). “Risks for the Long Run: Estimation
and Inference”, working paper, October 2006.
Blanchard, Olivier and Lawrence Katz (1992) “Regional Evolutions” Brookings Papers
on Economic Activity 1: 1-75.
Borjas, George (2003). “The Labor Demand Curve Is Downward Sloping: Reexamining
the Impact of Immigration on the Labor Market”, Quarterly Journal of Economics,
Vol. 188, no. 4 (November): 1335-1374.
Campbell, John (2000). “Asset Pricing at the Millennium”, Journal of Finance, Vol. LX,
no. 4 (August): 1515-1567.
Card, David and Kristin Butcher (1991). “Immigration and Wages: Evidence from the
1980s”, American Economic Review, Vol. 81, no. 2 (May): 292-296.
Case, Karl E. and Robert Shiller (1989). “The Efficiency of the Market for Single Family
Homes”, American Economic Review, Vol. 79, no. 1: 125-37.
Cutler, David, James Poterba, and Lawrence Summers (1991). “Speculative Dynamics”,
Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 58, no. 3 (May 1991): 529-46.
Fama, Eugene and Kenneth French (1988). “Permanent and Temporary Components of
Stock Prices”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 96, no.2 (April 1988): 246-73.
Glaeser, Edward and Joseph Gyourko (2005). “Urban Decline and Durable Housing”,
Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 113, no. 2 (April): 345-375.
Glaeser, Edward, Joseph Gyourko and Raven Saks (2005). “Why Have House Prices
Gone Up?”, American Economic Review, Vol. 95, no. 2 (May): 329-333.
Glaeser, Edward, Joseph Gyourko and Raven Saks (2006). “Urban Growth and Housing
Supply”, Journal of Economic Geography, Vol. 6, no. 1 (January): 71-89.
46
Glaeser, Edward and Jesse Shapiro (2003). “Urban Growth in the 1990s” Is City Living
Back?’, Journal of Regional Science, Vol. 43 (February): 139-165.
Gyourko, Joseph, Christopher Mayer, and Todd Sinai (2006). “Superstar Cities”, NBER
Working Paper 12355, July 2006.
Gyourko, Joseph and Albert Saiz (2006). “Construction Costs and the Supply of Housing
Structure”, Journal of Regional Science, Vol. 46, no. 4 (November 2006):
forthcoming.
Hansen, Lars and Ravi Jagannathan (1991). “Implications of Security Market Data for
Models of Dynamic Economies”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 99, no. 2
(April): 225-262.
Hendershott, Patric and Joel Slemrod (1983). “Taxes and the User Cost of Capital for
Owner-Occupied Housing”, Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban
Economics Association, Vol. 10, no. 4 (Winter): 375-93.
Himmelberg, Charles, Christopher Mayer and Todd Sinai (2005). “Assessing High
House Prices: Bubbles, Fundamentals, and Misperceptions”, Journal of Economic
Perspectives, Vol. 19, no. 4 (Fall 2005): 67-92.
McCarthy, Jonathan and Richard Peach (2004). “Are Home Prices the Next Bubble?”,
Economic Policy Review, Vol. 10, no. 3: 1-17.
Roback, Jennifer (1982). “Wages, Rents, and the Quality of Life”, Journal of Political
Economy, Vol. 90, no. 4 (December 1982): 1257-78.
Schwartz, Amy Ellen, Scott Susin and Ioan Voicu (2003). “Has Falling Crime Driven
New York’s Real Estate Boom?”, Journal of Housing Research, Vol. 14, no. 1: 101-
135.
Shiller, Robert (2005). Irrational Exuberance (2nd edition). Princeton University Press.
Smith, Margaret Hwang and Gary Smith (2006). “Bubble, Bubble, Where’s the Housing
Bubble”, Pomona College mimeo, March 2006.
47
Thaler, Richard (1978). “A Note on Crime Control: Evidence from the Property
Market”, Journal of Urban Economics, Vol 5, no. 1 (January): 137-145.
Topel, Robert and Sherwin Rosen (1988). “Housing Investment in the United States”,
Journal of Political Economy, Vol 96, no. 4: 718-740.
Tracy, Joseph, Henry Schneider and Sewin Chan (1999). “Are Stocks Overtaking Real
Estate in Household Portfolios?”, Current Issues in Economics and Finance, Vol. 5,
no. 5 (April): 1-6
Van Nieuwerburgh, Stijn and Pierre-Olivier Weill (2006). “Why Has House Price
Dispersion Gone Up?”, NBER Working Paper #12538, September.
48
Table 1: Model Parameters
R 0.04
0.87
0.17
2
$3,603,463
0.1
=0.0 =0.25 =0.50
th
10 percentile value: 1.7 1.5 1.0
25th percentile value: 3.5 2.7 2.0
C1
50th percentile value: 7.0 6.4 4.8
75th percentile value: 14.4 13.3 10.3
90th percentile value: 28.8 28.1 22.9
C2 =0.0 =0.25 =0.50
10th percentile value: 0.0 0.4 0.5
25th percentile value: 0.0 0.7 1.0
50th percentile value: 0.0 1.6 2.4
75th percentile value: 0.0 3.3 5.2
90th percentile value: 0.0 7.0 11.5
49
Table 2: Variation in Prices and Quantities Within-Market Over Time
Arellano-Bond Estimates of Coefficients on Lagged Dependent Variable
1, 3, & 5 year horizons
Dependent Variable 1-year 3-year changes 5-year changes
changes
House Price Change 0.71 0.27 -0.32
(0.01) (0.04) (0.07)
N=2,819 N=690 N=345
Rent Change 0.27 0.27 -0.64
(0.03) (0.08) (0.17)
N=1,007 N=274 N=91
New Permits 0.84 0.43 -0.07
(0.01) (0.04) (0.06)
N=2,645 N=690 N=460
Notes:
1. Sample for house price, employment, and permit specifications is 115 metropolitan
area sample described in text.
2. Sample for rent specification is 46 metropolitan areas tracked by REIS.
50
Table 3: Predicted Serial Correlation in House Prices
One-Year Three-Year Five-Year
c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if
=0 = 0.25 = 0.5 =0 = 0.25 = 0.5 =0 = 0.25 = 0.5
lowest
-0.09 -0.11 -0.13 -0.29 -0.28 -0.25 -0.41 -0.35 -0.31
c1
lower
-0.07 -0.09 -0.09 -0.25 -0.25 -0.22 -0.36 -0.32 -0.28
c1
medium
-0.05 -0.07 -0.07 -0.21 -0.21 -0.19 -0.32 -0.29 -0.26
c1
higher
-0.05 -0.05 -0.05 -0.19 -0.19 -0.17 -0.29 -0.27 -0.25
c1
highest
-0.04 -0.05 -0.05 -0.18 -0.18 -0.17 -0.27 -0.26 -0.25
c1
Notes: Within each time horizon over which serial correlation is estimated, 15 simulations were run, corresponding to the 15 (c1, c2)
pairs reported in Table 1. Thus, the (c1, c2) combinations used in the first, fourth, and seventh columns for which =0 are (1.7, 0.0),
(3.5, 0.0), (7.0, 0.0), (14.4, 0.0), and (28.8, 0.0), going from the top to the bottom of the table. The (c1, c2) combinations used in the
second, fifth, and eighth columns for which =0.25 are (1.5, 0.4), (2.7, 0.7), (6.4, 1.6), (13.3, 3.3), and (28.1, 7.0). The (c1, c2)
combinations used in the third, sixth, and ninth columns for which =0.50 are (1.0, 0.5), (2.0, 1.0), (4.8, 2.4), (10.3, 5.2), and (22.9,
11.5).
51
Table 4: Predicted Serial Correlation in Apartment Rents
One-Year Three-Year Five-Year
c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if
=0 = 0.25 = 0.5 =0 = 0.25 = 0.5 =0 = 0.25 = 0.5
lowest
0.02 -0.05 -0.14 -0.25 -0.31 -0.34 -0.37 -0.39 -0.38
c1
lower
0.05 -0.00 -0.07 -0.21 -0.26 -0.27 -0.32 -0.35 -0.33
c1
medium
0.07 0.04 0.01 -0.17 -0.21 -0.20 -0.29 -0.30 -0.28
c1
higher
0.08 0.07 0.05 -0.15 -0.17 -0.17 -0.26 -0.27 -0.25
c1
highest
0.09 0.08 0.07 -0.14 -0.15 -0.15 -0.24 -0.25 -0.24
c1
Notes: Within each time horizon over which serial correlation is estimated, 15 simulations were run, corresponding to the 15 (c1, c2)
pairs reported in Table 1. Thus, the (c1, c2) combinations used in the first, fourth, and seventh columns for which =0 are (1.7, 0.0),
(3.5, 0.0), (7.0, 0.0), (14.4, 0.0), and (28.8, 0.0), going from the top to the bottom of the table. The (c1, c2) combinations used in the
second, fifth, and eighth columns for which =0.25 are (1.5, 0.4), (2.7, 0.7), (6.4, 1.6), (13.3, 3.3), and (28.1, 7.0). The (c1, c2)
combinations used in the third, sixth, and ninth columns for which =0.50 are (1.0, 0.5), (2.0, 1.0), (4.8, 2.4), (10.3, 5.2), and (22.9,
11.5).
52
Table 5: Predicted Serial Correlation in Construction
One-Year Three-Year Five-Year
c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if
=0 = 0.25 = 0.5 =0 = 0.25 = 0.5 =0 = 0.25 = 0.5
lowest
0.68 0.52 0.34 0.40 0.19 0.02 0.17 -0.03 -0.15
c1
lower
0.74 0.56 0.36 0.50 0.24 0.04 0.28 0.01 -0.14
c1
medium
0.78 0.60 0.39 0.57 0.29 0.06 0.37 0.06 -0.13
c1
higher
0.81 0.62 0.37 0.63 0.32 0.05 0.45 0.08 -0.13
c1
highest
0.83 0.63 0.40 0.67 0.33 0.07 0.51 0.09 -0.12
c1
Notes: Within each time horizon over which serial correlation is estimated, 15 simulations were run, corresponding to the 15 (c1, c2)
pairs reported in Table 1. Thus, the (c1, c2) combinations used in the first, fourth, and seventh columns for which =0 are (1.7, 0.0),
(3.5, 0.0), (7.0, 0.0), (14.4, 0.0), and (28.8, 0.0), going from the top to the bottom of the table. The (c1, c2) combinations used in the
second, fifth, and eighth columns for which =0.25 are (1.5, 0.4), (2.7, 0.7), (6.4, 1.6), (13.3, 3.3), and (28.1, 7.0). The (c1, c2)
combinations used in the third, sixth, and ninth columns for which =0.50 are (1.0, 0.5), (2.0, 1.0), (4.8, 2.4), (10.3, 5.2), and (22.9,
11.5).
53
Table 6: Variance in House Price Changes and Construction Intensity
1, 3, and 5 Year Horizons
House Price Change Variance (millions of $2000)
1 year 3 years 5 years
10th percentile market $14 $69 $183
th
25 percentile market $26 $124 $452
th
50 percentile market $34 $185 $625
75th percentile market $70 $445 $1,170
90th percentile market $209 $1,380 $3,580
Sample mean $83 $484 $1,310
Construction Intensity Variance (millions of units)
1 year 3 years 5 years
th
10 percentile market 2 13 29
th
25 percentile market 2 19 41
50th percentile market 3 26 59
th
75 percentile market 11 84 212
90th percentile market 38 328 760
Sample mean 21 160 417
54
Table 7: Predicted Variance of Price Changes ($millions)
1, 3, and 5 Year Horizons
One-Year Three-Year Five-Year
c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if
=0 = 0.25 = 0.5 =0 = 0.25 = 0.5 =0 = 0.25 = 0.5
lowest
50 66 64 123 154 148 163 203 200
c1
lower
70 90 97 178 221 239 246 303 337
c1
medium
91 128 138 239 330 360 340 469 520
c1
higher
114 155 166 306 411 442 443 595 647
c1
highest
136 175 181 367 468 488 538 685 718
c1
Notes: Within each time horizon over which serial correlation is estimated, 15 simulations were run, corresponding to the 15 (c1, c2)
pairs reported in Table 1. Thus, the (c1, c2) combinations used in the first, fourth, and seventh columns for which =0 are (1.7, 0.0),
(3.5, 0.0), (7.0, 0.0), (14.4, 0.0), and (28.8, 0.0), going from the top to the bottom of the table. The (c1, c2) combinations used in the
second, fifth, and eighth columns for which =0.25 are (1.5, 0.4), (2.7, 0.7), (6.4, 1.6), (13.3, 3.3), and (28.1, 7.0). The (c1, c2)
combinations used in the third, sixth, and ninth columns for which =0.50 are (1.0, 0.5), (2.0, 1.0), (4.8, 2.4), (10.3, 5.2), and (22.9,
11.5).
55
Table 8: Predicted Variance of Construction Intensity (millions of units)
1, 3, and 5 Year Horizons
One-Year Three-Year Five-Year
c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if c2 if
=0 = 0.25 = 0.5 =0 = 0.25 = 0.5 =0 = 0.25 = 0.5
lowest
15 23 42 101 128 189 221 250 328
c1
lower
7 12 19 48 68 87 110 135 153
c1
medium
3 3 5 21 21 25 49 44 44
c1
higher
1 1 1 8 7 7 19 14 12
c1
highest
0.4 0.3 0.3 3 2 2 7 4 3
c1
Notes: Within each time horizon over which serial correlation is estimated, 15 simulations were run, corresponding to the 15 (c1, c2)
pairs reported in Table 1. Thus, the (c1, c2) combinations used in the first, fourth, and seventh columns for which =0 are (1.7, 0.0),
(3.5, 0.0), (7.0, 0.0), (14.4, 0.0), and (28.8, 0.0), going from the top to the bottom of the table. The (c1, c2) combinations used in the
second, fifth, and eighth columns for which =0.25 are (1.5, 0.4), (2.7, 0.7), (6.4, 1.6), (13.3, 3.3), and (28.1, 7.0). The (c1, c2)
combinations used in the third, sixth, and ninth columns for which =0.50 are (1.0, 0.5), (2.0, 1.0), (4.8, 2.4), (10.3, 5.2), and (22.9,
11.5).
56
Table 9: The Impact of Greater Local Demand Variability
Five-year Price Change Variance ($millions)
Baseline 2 (=$3.6) Baseline 2 * 1.5 Baseline 2 * 2.0 Baseline 2
* 2.5
th
Market with 75 percentile (c1, c2)
595 893 1,190 1,488
values (c1=13.3, c2=3.3)
Market with 90th percentile (c1, c2)
685 1,028 1,370 1,713
values (c1=28.8, c2=7.0)
Five-Year Quantity Change Variance (millions of units)
2
Baseline (=$3.6) Baseline 2 * 1.66
Market with 25th percentile (c1, c2)
135 224
values (c1=2.7, c2=0.7)
Market with 10th percentile (c1, c2)
250 415
values (c1=1.5, c2=0.4)
Notes: Unless noted explicitly in the table, each simulation reported above using common parameter values for the national sample as
reported in Table 1. In each case, =0.25.
57
Table 10: Predicted Variance of Price Changes ($millions): Interest Rate Volatility
1, 3, and 5 Year Horizons
One-Year Three-Year Five-Year
H −C Stand. Stand. Stand. Stand. Stand. Stand. Stand. Stand. Stand.
Dev. ( ) Dev. ( ) Dev. ( ) = Dev. ( ) Dev. ( ) = Dev. ( ) = Dev. ( ) Dev. ( ) = Dev. ( ) =
= 0.005 = 0.01 0.02 = 0.005 0.01 0.02 = 0.005 0.01 0.02
$25,000 128 130 136 331 335 352 471 477 501
$50,000 130 136 162 335 352 418 477 501 597
$100,000 136 162 266 352 418 683 501 597 980
$200,000 162 266 681 418 683 1743 597 980 2513
Table 11: Predicted Variance of Construction (millions of units): Interest Rate Volatility
1, 3, and 5 Year Horizons
One-Year Three-Year Five-Year
H −C Stand. Stand. Stand. Stand. Stand. Stand. Stand. Stand. Stand.
Dev. ( ) Dev. ( ) Dev. ( ) = Dev. ( ) Dev. ( ) = Dev. ( ) = Dev. ( ) Dev. ( ) = Dev. ( ) =
= 0.005 = 0.01 0.02 = 0.005 0.01 0.02 = 0.005 0.01 0.02
$25,000 4 4 4 21 22 23 44 45 47
$50,000 4 4 4 22 23 28 45 47 57
$100,000 4 4 7 23 28 46 47 57 97
$200,000 5 7 19 28 46 121 57 97 255
58
.6
Boulder
Real Appreciation in the 1990s, .1=10%
Salt Lak
Fort Col
Portland
.4
Ogden-Cl
Austin-R
Detroit-
Colorado
Warren-F
Flint
Minneapo San Jose
Peoria Canton-M
BoiseMilwauke
Ci Charlest
Louisvil Tacoma
.2
Allentow
Bakersfi Modesto
Riversid Los Ange
Honolulu
-.4
-.5 0 .5 1
Real Appreciation in the 1980s, .1=10%
Figure 1: Real House Price Appreciation in the 1980s and 1990s
59
.6
Las Vega
Growth in 1990s, .1=10%
.4
Boise Ci Raleigh-
Fort Col
Austin-R
Bellingh Charlott Phoenix-
Atlanta- Orlando-
Ogden-Cl Reno-Spa
Portland Boulder
Columbia
Lak Nashvill
SaltAlbuquer TucsonColorado
.2
Lake Cou
Greensbo
Tacoma Jacksonv
Lexingto
Indianap Dallas-P West Pal
Columbus San Anto
Winston-
Little R Richmond Fort
Seattle- Lau
Sacramen Sarasota Fort
Deltona-
Wor
Spokane Warren-F
Des Moin Grand Ra Fresno
Memphis Houston-
WashingtBakersfiCharlestBethesda Riversid
Birmingh Wilmingt
Baton Ro MinneapoModesto
Louisvil
Cincinna
Omaha-Co
Fort Way Stockton Santa RoSan Luis
HonoluluWichita
Kansas
Baltimor Edison
C Santa An Tampa-St Vallejo-
Gary Akron
Milwauke Allentow
Harrisbu
Lansing- Oxnard-T San Dieg
Chicago- Napa Camden Tulsa Oklahoma
Oakland-
Salinas Corpus C
Flint
Canton-M Rocheste San
Santa Jose
Cr
Peoria New YorkDayton
Clevelan St. LouiCoWorceste
Providen
Cambridg
Nassau-S
Toledo
Newark-U
SanPhiladel
Beaumont Essex
Boston-Q
Fran
Bridgepo
Buffalo-
Pittsbur NewLos Ange
Orle Santa Ba
0
Detroit-
0 .2 .4 .6
Growth in 1980s, .1=10%
Figure 2: Housing Unit Growth in the 1980s and 1990s
60
Figure 3: One-Time Shock
2 4 6 8 10
Population: ------------
Construction: –––––––––
Price: –––––––––
( = 0.1, c1 = 3, c2 = 0.1)
61
800
Honolulu
Variance in 1 year Price Residual(millions $)
600
San Jose
San Fran
400
Santa Ba An
Santa
Salinas
Bridgepo
Oxnard-T
Santa Cr
Los Ange
200
62
400
Variance in 1 year Unit Residual(millions of Units)
Houston-
300
Los Ange
200
Atlanta-
Dallas-P Riversid
Phoenix-
100
San Dieg
Las Vega
63
Appendix 1: Proofs of Propositions
α c2
Define u ≡ and v ≡ ; 0 ≤ u and 0 ≤ v < 1 by the conventions in force. Then
c1 c1
φ=
1
2
(
2 + r + (1 + r )u − v − r 2 + v 2 + 2(1 + r )(2 + r )u + (1 + r ) 2 u 2 + 2v(r − (1 + r )u ) )
and
1
φ=
2
(
2 + r + (1 + r )u − v + r 2 + v 2 + 2(1 + r )(2 + r )u + (1 + r ) 2 u 2 + 2v(r − (1 + r )u ) . )
Because 0 ≤ v < 1 , the expression under the radical is positive. Note that
φ + φ = 2 + r + (1 + r )u − v > (1 + r )(1 + u ) > 0 and φφ = (1 + r )(1 − v) > 0 , so φ , φ > 0 .
Also, r 2 + v 2 + 2(1 + r )(2 + r )u + (1 + r ) 2 u 2 + 2v(r − (1 + r )u ) >
2(1 + r )(2 + r )u + (1 + r ) 2 u 2 − 2(1 + r )u > 2(1 + r )(1 + r )u + (1 + r ) 2 u 2 > 1 + r ,
so
1
φ> (1 + r + (1 + r )u + 1 + r ) ≥ 1 + r > 1 ,
2
which in turn gives
(1 + r )(1 − v)
0≤φ = < 1 − v ≤ 1.
φ
64
1+ r ∞
n(t ) = φ i Li Et −1 ( x(t )) (2),
c1 (φ − δ ) i =0
where L denotes the lag operator. Now that we have defined n, we set
1 α (1 + r )
z (t ) ≡ x(t ) + Et ( x(t + 1)) − n(t ) (3)
φ −δ 1+ r −φ
and
1+ r
m(t + 1) ≡ Et ( x(t + 1)) − (1 − φ )n(t ) . (4)
c1 (φ − δ )
With these choices for z and m, (*) reduces to
α
(n(t + 1) − φn(t ) ) = φ − 1 − r Et ( x(t + 1)) , (5)
1+ r −φ (φ − δ )(1 + r )
which by (1) is equivalent to
u (1 + r ) φ −1− r
Et ( x(t + 1)) = Et ( x(t + 1)) ,
(1 + r − φ )(φ − δ ) (φ − δ )(1 + r )
which is true, as one sees from cross-multiplying the coefficients and using the
previously established formulas for the product and sum of φ and φ . (**) reduces to
α (1 + r ) 1+ r −φ
n(t + 1) − (c1 (1 − φ ) − c2 ))n(t ) = φ − 1 − r Et ( x(t + 1)) ,
1+ r −φ α (1 + r ) φ −δ
which is equivalent to (5), and thus true, because
1+ r −φ
φ= (c1 (1 − φ ) − c2 ) ) = (1 + r − φ )(1 − φ − v) ,
α (1 + r ) u (1 + r )
itself evident from cross-multiplying and using the fact that φ satisfies the quadratic
equation y 2 − (2 + r + (1 + r )u − v) y + (1 + r )(1 − v) = 0 . Finally, (***) reduces to (1).
This shows that our choices for n, z, and m solve the starred equations. To recover
Proposition 1, we use I (t ) = m(t ) + Iˆ(t ) , N (t ) = n(t ) + Nˆ (t ) , and H (t ) = z (t ) + Hˆ (t ) .
[The result then follows from Et ( x(t + 1)) = δx(t ) + θε (t ) .]
1+ r φ j −δ j
= φ j n(t ) + E t ( x(t + 1)) . (6)
c1 (φ − δ ) φ − δ
65
Using (4) and (6), we next find that
1+ r
Et (m(t + j )) = Et ( x(t + j )) − (1 − φ ) Et (n(t + j − 1))
c1 (φ − δ )
1+ r φ j −1 − δ j −1
= δ j −1
− (1 − φ ) Et ( x(t + 1)) − φ j −1 (1 − φ )n(t )
c1 (φ − δ ) φ −δ
1+ r δ j −1 (1 − δ ) − φ j −1 (1 − φ )
= Et ( x(t + 1)) − φ j −1 (1 − φ )n(t ) . (7)
c1 (φ − δ ) φ −δ
Finally, using (**), (6), and (7), we get
Et ( z (t + j )) = c1 Et (m(t + j )) + c 2 Et (n(t + j − 1))
1+ r δ j −1
(1 − δ ) − φ j −1 (1 − φ ) φ j −1 − δ j −1
= c1 + c2 Et ( x(t + 1))
c1 (φ − δ ) φ −δ φ −δ
− φ j −1 (c1 (1 − φ ) − c2 )n(t )
1+ r δ (1 − v − δ ) − φ j −1 (1 − v − φ )
j −1
= Et ( x(t + 1)) − c1φ j −1 (1 − v − φ )n(t ) . (8)
φ −δ φ −δ
To recover Proposition 2, we use I (t ) = m(t ) + Iˆ(t ) , N (t ) = n(t ) + Nˆ (t ) ,
and H (t ) = z (t ) + Hˆ (t ) with equations (3), (8) , (4), (7), and (6).
φ − δ − (φ − δ
j j j −1 j −1
) i =0 i =0
0< = = φ j −2 ( jφ − j + 1) ,
φ −δ φ −δ
66
which holds for sufficiently large j because 0 ≤ φ < 1 . This shows that there exists j *
such that for all j > j * , time t expected values of time t + j construction and housing
prices will lie below steady state levels. When ε (t ) < 0 , we swap > and < to recover the
symmetric case.
67
which is negative if and only if
2
rc 2 + α (1 + r ) Var (q )
Ω > .
(1 + r )c1c 2 (φ − δ ) Var (ε )
68
Appendix II: The Contribution of Taxes Local Demand Variance
Data on the average tax rate paid each year in each state was matched to our
metropolitan areas using files from the NBER’s TaxSim web page. We then multiplied
our income numbers by one minus the average tax rate, and calculated new values of δ ,
θ and 2 for this adjusted after-tax income measure. The new “after-tax” values of the
three parameters are very similar to those used in our simulations: =0.87, =0.18, and
2
=$3.3 million. The latter is 92 percent of the $3.6 million figure obtained without any
adjustment for taxes. Hence, correcting for taxes creates an eight percent reduction in the
variance and almost no change in the other parameters. Consequently, we conclude that
including state level tax rates does not offer any hope of explaining the particularly high
volatilities.
We began by drawing on the hedonic literature on the costs of crime. The range
of estimates of the elasticity of property value with respect to the violent crime rate ran
from 0.05 to 0.15.38 To turn these housing price elasticities into estimates of the impact
of crime on the flow of utility measured in dollar units, we multiply the elasticity by the
average housing price per crime to obtain a relationship between the price of housing and
the level of crime. We then followed our model and multiplied this figure by r/(1+r) to
generate an estimate of the impact of crime on the flow of utility measured in dollars.
Using this method, our elasticity range from 0.05 to 0.15 implies that the impact
of violent crime on the flow of well-being ranges from $35 to $105. The upper bound
estimate of $105 dollars implies that, if the violent crime rate in a city increases from 12
violent crimes per 1,000 inhabitants (the national mean) to 24 violent crimes per 1,000
inhabitants, then this is equivalent to an income loss of about $1,260 dollars, which we
believe is a reasonable result.
We then used this upper bound impact to adjust the underlying BEA real income
variable and δ , θ and 2. As with taxes, crime had little impact on the volatility of the
local income shock. Specifically, there is only a 1.4 percent greater shock variance when
controlling for crime.39 While the crime data is far from perfect for our purposes, this
exercise leads us to conclude that variation in local amenities will explain little of the
high variance price change or construction markets.
38
See Thaler (1978) for the lower bound estimate and Schwartz, Susin, and Voicu (2003) for the upper
bound number.
39
We were able to obtain crime data for the major cities of 105 of our 115 metropolitan areas. The ARMA
estimates of and are virtually unchanged depending upon whether income is adjusted for crime in these
105 markets. As noted, the variability of the ‘after-crime’ income shock is marginally higher.
69