0% found this document useful (0 votes)
45 views18 pages

Towards An Institution-Based View of Business Strategy: 2002 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Manufactured in The Netherlands

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1/ 18

Asia Pacic Journal of Management, 19, 251267, 2002 c 2002 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Manufactured in The Netherlands.

Towards an Institution-Based View of Business Strategy


MIKE W. PENG peng.51@osu.edu (http://sher.osu.edu/mhr/faculty/peng) Fisher College of Business, The Ohio State University, 2100 Neil Avenue, Columbus, OH 43210, USA

Abstract. This article focuses on a key question: Why do strategies of rms from different countries differ? Drawing from recent research on business strategies in Asian organizations, this article outlines the emergence of an institution-based view of business strategy which sheds light on why rms differ, reviews four streams of research in a broad range of countries, and critiques and extends some of the current work by suggesting a number of future research directions. Keywords: institution, business strategy, Asia

This article focuses on a key question: Why do strategies of rms from different countries and regions differ? This is the very rst question among the ve most fundamental questions in strategic management raised by Rumelt, Schendel and Teece (1994:564).1 Since the diversity of rm strategies around the world can arise as the result of many possible forces internal or external to the organization, this question engenders a wide variety of disparate answers from economists (Nelson, 1991) and sociologists (Carroll, 1993). Thus far, strategy researchers have primarily focused on industry conditions (Porter, 1980) and rm resources (Barney, 1991) as drivers of rm differences, leading to competition- and resource-based perspectives, respectively. Drawing from recent research on Asian organizations, I argue that in addition to these existing theories, a new, institution-based view has emerged to account for differences in business strategy. A number of scholars suggested that in addition to industry and rm level conditions, a rm also needs to take into account wider inuences from sources such as the state and society when crafting and implementing its strategies (DiMaggio and Powell, 1991; Oliver, 1997). These inuences are broadly considered as institutional frameworks (North, 1990; Scott, 1995). When applied to strategy research, this new perspective, consequently, can be called an institution-based view of business strategy (Peng, 2000a, 2002; Peng and Heath, 1996). Since no rm can be immune from institutional frameworks in which it is embedded, there is hardly any dispute that institutions matter. In order to make further theoretical progress, researchers must tackle the harder and more interesting issues of how they matter, under what circumstances, to what extent, and in what ways (Powell, 1996:297). This article, consequently, has three objectives. First, extending earlier theoretical work (Peng, 2000a, 2002; Peng and Heath, 1996), this article outlines the broad contour of the new, institutionbased view of business strategy. Second, I review the recent Asian management literature to assess the progress made in the direction Powell (1996) calls for. Given that most existing

252

PENG

research takes place in the West, a focus on Asia allows us to vary institutional contexts; otherwise, it is difcult if not impossible to discern the effects of institutions on social structures and behaviors if all our cases are embedded in the same or very similar ones (Scott, 1995:146). Informed by research on a number of Asian countries, the four substantive areas reviewed are (1) supplier strategies, (2) entrepreneurial strategies, (3) diversication strategies, and (4) growth strategies. While this is not an exhaustive list of research areas, I believe that they represent a broad spectrum of research interests through which the institution-based view of business strategy can be illustrated. Finally, current research is critiqued and future research directions are suggested.

Understanding institutions According to North (1990:3), institutions are the rules of the game in a society or, more formally, are the humanly devised constraints that shape human interaction. Similarly, Scott (1995:33) denes institutions as cognitive, normative, and regulative structures and activities that provide stability and meaning to social behavior. Consequently, an institutional framework is dened by Davis and North (1971:6) as the set of fundamental political, social, and legal ground rules that establishes the basis for production, exchange, and distribution. Under the label of new institutionalism, there are differences between the economic version (North, 1990; Williamson, 1985), which focuses more on efciency, and the sociological version (DiMaggio and Powell, 1991; Scott, 1995), which concentrates more on legitimacy. Delineating the theoretical boundaries of these perspectives is beyond the scope of the present article. In the spirit of previous institutional work in strategy (e.g., Oliver, 1997; Peng and Heath, 1996), this article takes an integrative approach, drawing from the broad institutional literature to examine how institutions bear on the strategy problem. Institutional frameworks interact with organizations by signaling which choices are acceptable and supportable. As a result, institutions help reduce uncertainty for organizations. Institutional frameworks are made up of both formal and informal constraints (North, 1990). Formal constraints include political rules, judicial decisions, and economic contracts. Informal constraints, on the other hand, include socially sanctioned norms of behavior, which are embedded in culture and ideology (Scott, 1995). North (1990) suggests that in situations where formal constraints fail, informal constraints will come into play to reduce uncertainty and provide constancy to organizations. These insights have important implications for the development of an institution-based view of business strategy (Peng, 2000a).

An institution-based view of business strategy Strategies are about choices. Therefore, an analysis of business strategy needs to recognize the exercise of choice by organizational decision makers (Child, 1972:10). Given the inuence of institutional frameworks on rm behavior, any strategic choice that rms make is inherently affected by the formal and informal constraints of a given institutional framework (North, 1990; Oliver, 1997). Viewed from such a perspective, much of the strategy literature,

TOWARDS AN INSTITUTION-BASED VIEW OF BUSINESS STRATEGY

253

which largely focuses on Western rms, does not discuss the specic relationship between strategic choices and institutional frameworks. To be sure, the inuence of the environment has long been featured in the literature (Lawrence and Lorsch, 1969). However, what has dominated this research is a task environment view, which focuses on economic variables such as market demand and technological change. Until recently, scholars had rarely looked beyond the task environment to explore the interaction among institutions, organizations, and strategic choices. Instead, a market-based institutional framework has been taken for granted. Such an omission is unfortunate, because it is precisely the institutional frameworks in developed economies that prompt Western rms to choose certain strategies and constrain them from choosing others (Peng and Heath, 1996). Today, we are much more conscious of the importance of the relationships between organizations and institutions. Treating institutions as independent variables, an institution-based view on business strategy, therefore, focuses on the dynamic interaction between institutions and organizations, and considers strategic choices as the outcome of such an interaction (gure 1). Specically, strategic choices are not only driven by industry conditions and rm-specic resources that traditional strategy research emphasizes (Barney, 1991; Porter, 1980), but are also a reection of the formal and informal constraints of a particular institutional framework that decision makers confront (Oliver, 1997; Scott, 1995). Since the 1990s, more and more scholars have come to realize that institutions matter (Powell and DiMaggio, 1991; Scott, 1995), and that strategy research cannot just focus on industry conditions and rm resources (Khanna and Palepu, 1997; Peng, 2000a). As argued by Hoskisson et al. (2000), institutional theory appears to be a highly insightful approach when probing into organizational strategies in Asia. While taking institutions seriously is only a rst step, working out the analytic logic of their inuence is the second, and explicating the underlying mechanisms comes next. This article can be considered as a part

Figure 1. Institutions, organizations, and strategic choices. Source: Peng, M.W. (2000). Business Strategies in Transition Economies: p. 45. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.

254

PENG

of this broad intellectual movement in search of a better understanding of the relationship among institutions, organizations, and strategic choices (Peng, 2002). Next, I turn to four substantive areas of recent research in a variety of Asian economies to illustrate how the institution-based view has evolved. Supplier strategies While most strategy research focuses on Western rms, recently, it has become virtually impossible to discuss the matter of business strategy long without the issue of Japanese economic organization surfacing (Williamson, 1991:87). Of particular concern to strategy researchers is the keiretsu networks, the webs of interrm relations that envelop many Japanese rms (Gerlach, 1992) and now increasingly involve other Asian rms (Peng, Lee and Tan, 2001). Specically, within such a network, independent suppliers seem to be willing to site their factories close to major manufacturers such as Toyota and Honda, in the absence of a long-term contract. Such a high degree of asset specicity creates economic value by reducing delivery time and costs and increasing the efciency of more juts-in-time deliveries (Dyer, 1997). However, according to research in the West (Williamson, 1985), such a high degree of asset specicity is likely to result in high transaction costs, because the value of suppliers location-specic assets will depreciate considerably when they no longer have a contract with manufacturers and/or when suppliers want to deliver to other manufacturers located elsewhere. Consequently, suppliers are predicted to be unwilling to site their factories in a vulnerable location, and manufacturers often need to engage in costly vertical integration. In contrast to such thinking, some Japanese rms seem to have an unlikely combination, namely, high asset specicity and low transaction costs, thus presenting a puzzle to researchers (Dyer and Nobeoka, 2000). More recently, as keiretsu networks are extended throughout Asia, how indigenous Asian rms buy in becomes an interesting new issue (Peng, Lee and Tan, 2001). One answer to solve the puzzle is to invoke the difference in national cultures between Japan and Western countries such as the United States (Dore, 1987). A high propensity to cooperate is believed to be rooted in the Japanese culture, and, consequently, a high degree of interrm cooperation is more likely. Beyond this simplistic culturalist perspective, more recent work has increasingly focused on the institutional frameworks in which Japanese rms are embedded (Hill, 1995). Specically, while Japan has developed a set of formal legal frameworks based on the American model in the postwar decades, they are not used extensively. Instead, Japanese rms tend to place a greater emphasis on informal constraints, such as consensus- and trust-building, instead of formal contracts. In other words, the informal constraints of Japanese society do a relatively better job of holding opportunism in check than those of many Western societies, resulting in both a high degree of specialization and low transaction costs (Hill, 1995:129, original emphasis). The upshot is that major manufacturers such as Toyota and Honda can avoid costly vertical integration typically found in Western automobile companies, while still beneting from close cooperation with suppliers (Dyer and Nobeoka, 2000). Although research on Japanese supplier strategies has demonstrated that interrm strategies can be organized differently and still generate competitive advantage (Peng, Lee and

TOWARDS AN INSTITUTION-BASED VIEW OF BUSINESS STRATEGY

255

Tan, 2001), this work is a weak test of the institutional perspective. This is because the national cultures between Japan and Western countries are so different that it is difcult to partition out the impact of institutional inuences independent of national cultural inuences. The next section reviews some recent work that takes on such a challenge. Entrepreneurial strategies A strong test of the institutional perspective needs to demonstrate that institutions matter independent of national cultures (Lau and Ngo, 2001). Such work has only begun recently. Most research in this area starts with a cross-cultural perspective, that is, comparing and contrasting the impact of different national cultures on rm behavior. For example, the dramatic contrasts between Chinese and American cultures have attracted a number of cross-cultural studies which report signicant differences. However, critics argue that many cross-cultural studies do not accomplish their objective; rather, they end up being crossnational studies that reect the impact of environmental factors such as different formal and informal institutional frameworks in various countries (Farh, Earley and Lin, 1997:441; Kelley and Worthley, 1981:164). Therefore, it is difcult to conclude whether the observed differences between subjects in two different countries are due to cross-cultural or crossnational differences (Lau and Ngo, 2001). One solution is to introduce a third sample from Hong Kong or Taiwan (McGrath et al., 1992). Subjects in Taiwan and Hong Kong are assumed to share the cultural roots with their counterparts in mainland China, and operate in a different, market economy. However, since Taiwan and Hong Kong represent a third national environment, employing these samples, although representing substantial progress, is still unable to allow researchers to isolate the role of national institutions that is independent of the cultural effect, or vice versa (Mitchell et al., 2000). Attempting to ll such a gap, Tan and Peng (2002) recently employ a rigorous, quasiexperimental design to better isolate the role of cultural and national differences. It is widely known that the Chinese are an entrepreneurial people, as evidenced by the wealth they generate throughout Southeast Asia and now increasingly in North America and Western Europe (Fukuyama, 1996). However, entrepreneurial activities in mainland China were kept at a minimum during the Maoist period until the 1970s. Since then, the emergence of entrepreneurship in mainland China seems to indicate that it is the development of market-supporting institutions, both formal and informal, that gives birth to a new wave of entrepreneurship (Peng, 2001a). Similar to Lau and Buenitz (2001), Tan and Peng (2002) test this proposition by focusing on entrepreneurs who have founded new businesses. Specifically, we draw on three samples, namely, mainland Chinese, Chinese Americans, and Caucasian Americans. These samples represent two distinctive national environments (the Peoples Republic of China versus the United States) and two different cultures (Chinese versus American). We measure the differences in entrepreneurs perception of the environment and their strategic orientations. Two competing hypotheses are generated. First, if the national institutional effect predominates, then Chinese American and Caucasian American entrepreneurs would show relatively similar patterns of response compared with those of mainland Chinese entrepreneurs. Conversely, if the cultural effect predominates,

256

PENG

then mainland Chinese and Chinese American entrepreneurs would show relatively similar patterns of response when compared with those of their Caucasian American counterparts (Tan and Peng, 2002). The introduction of the Chinese American sample thus bridges the two national samples. On one hand, these entrepreneurs compete with their Caucasian American counterparts in the same national environment. On the other hand, Chinese American entrepreneurs, despite their immigration experience, have been found to maintain signicant cultural similarities with counterparts in their former homeland. For example, while other immigrant groups may try to blend in, Chinese Americans often emphasize their cultural uniqueness, as evidenced, for example, by the distinctive decorations for Chinatowns in major American cities (Fukuyama, 1996). Under the joint impact of cultural and environmental inuence, the response of Chinese American entrepreneurs, therefore, cannot be predicted a priori in a single direction, and has to be entertained in two competing hypotheses. Our empirical results lend strong support for the institutional perspective (Tan and Peng, 2002). Specically, Chinese American and Caucasian American entrepreneurs tend to share more similarities in terms of their environmental perceptions and strategic orientations when compared with their counterparts in mainland China. Despite a presumed cultural link between mainland Chinese and Chinese American samples, these two groups differ signicantly on many dimensions. These results, therefore, provide some preliminary evidence suggesting that it is institutional frameworks, rather than national cultures, that drive entrepreneurship. Given that the institutional environments between mainland China and the United States are radically different, our ndings are hardly surprising. More work may need to concentrate on partially similar cases (Lau and Ngo, 2001; Shenkar and von Glinow, 1994), such as by comparing and contrasting rm strategies in different Asian economies, which we turn to next. Diversication strategies Since the 1970s, research in the West suggests that, on average, rms with a higher level of diversication are less protable than rms with a lower level of diversication (Hoskisson and Hitt, 1994). What seems to hurt performance the most is a strategy of conglomerate (or unrelated) diversication. Consequently, unrelated conglomerates have largely become a thing of the past in major developed economies since the 1980s and 1990s. In contrast, highly diversied conglomerates, often called business groups, have often been found extensively in Asian countries, such as China (Keister, 2000; Peng, 1997), Hong Kong (Au, Peng and Wang, 2000; Wan, 1998), India (Khanna and Palepu, 2000), South Korea (Chang and Hong, 2000), and Taiwan (Chung, 2001; Hamilton and Feenstra, 1995). Seen through a Western lens, the persistence and emergence of these diversied conglomerates throughout Asia seems puzzling (Granovetter, 1994). A culturalist perspective would suggest that the national cultures of these emerging economies may foster these culturally important practices. The validity of this view, however, is questionable in light of signicant cultural differences among this diverse group of countries. Another perspective suggests that as a highly institutionalized organizational form due to historical reasons, these conglomerates persist in these backward countries with little performance benets.

TOWARDS AN INSTITUTION-BASED VIEW OF BUSINESS STRATEGY

257

A stronger proposition, often embraced by Western media, consultants, and advisors to Asian governments, is that these conglomerates actually destroy value and therefore should be dismantled. Rigorous evidence supporting this proposition, however, is rare. Preliminary ndings actually suggest that in contrast to the conventional wisdom in the West, there seems to be discernible performance benets associated with conglomerates in emerging economies, as Khanna and Palepu (2000) and Khanna and Rivkin (2001) nd in India and Indonesia. Other scholars report similar ndings in Hong Kong (Wan, 1998), Singapore (Lim and Teck, 1995), and Taiwan (Chung, 2001). These ndings thus confront researchers: How to reconcile the striking differences in diversication strategies from developed and emerging economies? The answer seems to lie in the institutional perspective with a focus on the underlying formal and informal institutional frameworks permeating these countries. While emerging economies in Asia are hardly uniform, their formal institutions tend to fall short to varying degrees in providing support for low transaction-cost business operations in three critical areas: (1) a credible legal framework, (2) a stable political structure, and (3) functioning strategic factor markets (Khanna and Palepu, 1997; Peng and Heath, 1996). Throughout Asia, because of the weaknesses of formal institutions, informal constraints rise to play a larger role in regulating economic exchanges in these countries during the transition (Peng and Heath, 1996:504, added emphasis). The main informal constraints come from three sources. First, the interpersonal relations among executives serve as a focal point for valuable managerial networking. Although managers all over the world devote a considerable amount of time and energy to cultivate interpersonal ties, managers in Asia, due to a lack of publicly available, reliable information about market opportunities, perhaps rely more heavily on the cultivation of personal relationships to cope with the exigencies of their situation (Child, 1994:150). By engaging in reciprocal, preferential, and mutually supportive networking, managers in diversied conglomerates, who often share the same family, clan, and/or educational background, are able to reduce uncertainty in their decision making. Second, external connections linking these executives and key stakeholders, especially government ofcials, are also a crucial part of the informal institutional constraints (Boddewyn and Brewer, 1994; Oliver, 1997). Given the need to combat environmental uncertainty, it is not surprising that managers maintain a disproportionately greater contact with government ofcials (Child, 1994:154). For example, in China, Peng and Luo (2000) nd that connections with ofcials appear to be more important than ties with other managers in terms of their impact on rm performance. In Thailand, Peng, Au and Wang (2001:171) document that 42 of the top 200 listed rms have active-duty military ofcers serving as directors on the board, who may provide important political resources (Boddewyn and Brewer, 1994) and institutional capital (Oliver, 1997) for rms in such an unstable environment. Bribes, gifts, cronyism, and other corrupt practices may be part of working with the bureaucracy. But that is not the whole story. In many cases, educating ofcials is more important than exchanging favors (Khanna and Palepu, 1997). Conglomerates can leverage their government contacts, and present to ofcials a united front of the interests of diverse industries and businesses represented by a single group, thus minimizing the risk of overloading the bureaucracy.

258

PENG

Finally, the reputation of conglomerates serves as an informal but strong signaling device to reduce uncertainty for customers and investors. In consumer markets throughout Asia, independent consumer protection organizations are rare, and government watchdog agencies are often ineffective (Khanna and Palepu, 1997). As a result, consumers are reluctant to trust new brands. Conversely, since established brands wield tremendous power, conglomerates with a quality reputation can leverage their names to enter new industries, including unrelated ones. When attracting nancial investors, the reputation of conglomerates also becomes a valuable, unique, and hard-to-imitate competitive advantage (Barney, 1991). It is interesting to note that in contrast to the United States, where Internet business is dominated by start-ups which have raised signicant capital, Internet services in Asia are predominately provided by established conglomerates, which can more easily raise external nancing and provide internal funding. Such an ability to raise capital, as well as to internally allocate capital, compensates for a crucial void in the underdeveloped nancial markets. In addition to nancial investors, foreign direct investors are also more likely to be attracted to established conglomerates than to unknown independent rms in emerging economies. Again, the reputation and prestige of established business groups saves on search costs for foreign investors, which can be tremendous given the lack of information and the steep learning curve in these countries (Luo and Peng, 1999). Overall, informal constraints offer some constancy and predictability in the absence of well-developed formal market-supporting institutions. Specically, diversied conglomerates are able to compensate for the lack of formal institutional constraints by performing basic functions by themselves, such as allocating capital, obtaining market information, and enforcing contracts. In contrast, in developed economies, specialized organizations (e.g., stock exchanges, market research rms, law rms, and the courts) as part of the formal institutions will handle these responsibilities, thus nullifying the needs to support these costly activities within the rm. Taken together, research on diversication strategies in Asia not only highlights the explanatory power of the institutional perspective, but also reminds us of the institutional embeddedness of the recent ndings of diversication research in developed economies. It is important to note that the negative relationship between conglomerate diversication and performance was actually not found during an earlier era in the West (Matsusaka, 1993). Instead, nancial markets response to unrelated acquisitions was positive in the 1960s. These ndings thus document a dramatic reversal in [U.S.] investor sentiment toward diversicationpositive in the 1960s, neutral in the 1970s, and negative in the 1980s (Matsusaka, 1993:358). In the 1960s, external capital markets in the United States were less developed in terms of rm-specic information disclosure than in later decades. For example, relative to the current period, there was less access by the public to databases, analyst reports, and other sources of information that could reduce transaction costs between external investors and rms. As a result, conglomerates in the United States at that time were perceived ex ante by external capital markets to have an advantage in their abilities to allocate capital internally, a logic very similar to the favorable reaction of external markets to conglomerates in some Asian economies now. In short, the institutional perspective highlights the historical specicity of a particular relationship

TOWARDS AN INSTITUTION-BASED VIEW OF BUSINESS STRATEGY

259

between diversication and performance, which may not necessarily hold longitudinally and spatially. Growth strategies Before the current economic transition, rms in China were not interested in growth (Tan and Litschert, 1994). A fascinating aspect of the transition process is that rms there are now compelled to grow to be more competitive in the emerging ocean of market competition, thus presenting strategy researchers with a previously unencountered question rst raised by Peng and Heath (1996): How do rms in transition economies such as China achieve growth? Existing research on the growth of the rm suggests that there are typically three strategies for growth, namely, generic expansion, mergers and acquisitions, and/or networks and alliances (Penrose, 1959; Williamson, 1985). Work on rm growth in transition economies highlights the institutional prerequisites that support each of these three growth strategies. Specically, generic expansion calls for a staff of capable managers. Mergers and acquisitions require functioning strategic factor markets. Developing networks and alliances needs to build trust and mutual understanding. While the institutional frameworks supporting the rst two growth strategies are primarily formal ones, those for the last strategy are of an informal nature based on interpersonal relationships (Peng, 2000a). Empirical work has been initiated in China, rst through a qualitative phase building on three longitudinal case studies conducted over a seven-year period (Peng, 1997). This work has recently moved to a quantitative phase (Peng and Luo, 2000). Several interesting ndings emerge. First, generic expansion, based on rms own resources, is typically infeasible initially, because of the lack of certain critical resources at most rms (e.g., technology). In fact, some of these rms may need to shrink by turning around from persistent performance problems (Bruton, Ahlstrom and Wan, 2001). Second, handicapped by both a lack of capital and a lack of formal strategic factor markets, nor can most rms hope, at least initially, to acquire necessary resources through mergers and acquisitions. Many so-called mergers have been mandated by the government in an effort to bail out ailing state-owned rms (Peng, Luo and Sun, 1999). Third, an informal, network-based growth strategy is typically favored by a variety of rms (Peng and Heath, 1996). They usually rely on developing inter-organizational networks by tapping into the complementary resources at partner rms in order to jointly pursue growth opportunities (Peng, 1997; White, 2000). Specically, state-owned rms like to team up with foreign rms and private rms in order to access nancial capital, advanced technology, and entrepreneurial energy (Peng, 2000b; Shenkar and Li, 1999). Non-state rms are interested in obtaining some political support from the government by collaborating with state-owned rms (Lau and Busenitz, 2001; Peng, 2001a). Foreign rms tap into the capabilities of domestic partners in order to navigate the uncertain waters of economic transition (Beamish, 1993; Luo and Peng, 1999; Peng, 2000b; Yan and Gray, 1994). Finally, micro, interpersonal ties among managers at multiple rms are translated into macro, interorganizational relations leading to better rm performancein short, a micro-macro link (Peng and Luo, 2000). Further, another extension of such micro-macro link can be found in Lau and Busenitz (2001), in which they link the

260

PENG

micro, entrepreneurial cognition with the macro, entrepreneurial strategies and performance in China. Given that strategic choices are inherently affected by managers national cultures (Hofstede, 1991), it is not surprising that Chinese managers, who have a widely noted cultural propensity to rely on informal ties, resort to personal connections to achieve organizational goals (Chen, 2001). However, Boisot and Child (1996), Peng (1997, 2000a), Peng and Heath (1996), and Xin and Pearce (1996) argue that, in addition to cultural inuences, institutional imperatives during the transition may further necessitate the extensive reliance on personalized exchange relationships. Such an institutional interpretation is borne out by similar ndings from transition economies throughout Central and Eastern Europe (Grabher and Stark, 1997). These countries include the Czech Republic (Spicer, McDermott and Kogut, 2000), Hungary (Stark, 1996), and Russia (Linz and Krueger, 1998; Puffer, 1994). Note that in these countries there is little inuence of the Chinese (or Asian) culture which puts a premium on interpersonal ties. Nevertheless, the emergence of a network-based strategy, which blurs existing organizational boundaries and creates recombinent property (Stark, 1996), has been widely reported. It is evident that despite the cultural differences, similar institutional imperatives during the transition must have played an important role in leading to similar growth strategies throughout transition economies (Peng, 2000a). While initial research nds that growth strategies in transition economies such as China converge on networks and alliances, it is important to caution that this is a dominant strategy, which should not be confused as the only strategy (Peng and Heath, 1996:517). A networkbased strategy is not without its problems. The rst is the lack of codication of information, routines, and capabilities. The second is the lack of a formal governance basis; often, members do not operate as unied groups. Decision making in these networks tends to be case by case, with extensive negotiations and bargaining among members. These loosely structured, largely informal networks are based on trust, reputation, and mutual understanding, which, unfortunately, can be exploited if there are divergent economic interests and/or when the enforcement mechanism is weak (Peng, 2000a:64). As a result, there is a recent move throughout China to establish large, fully incorporated enterprises and business groups with a unied command-and-control structure and subsidiaries, as opposed to loosely connected network members (Keister, 2000). Some of these groups, such as the red chips listed in Hong Kong and New York, have ventured abroad with some success (Au, Peng and Wang, 2000). Consequently, these activities increasingly call for a strategy of mergers and acquisitions to achieve growth (Peng, Luo and Sun, 1999). Such a need, in turn, has fueled the urgency to strengthen the formal institutional constraints, namely, to establish an adequate legal framework to allow for such market-based transactions (Zhang and Peng, 2000). In other words, the failure of formal institutional frameworks has led to the reliance on informal constraints, which results in a network-based strategy. Further more, the problems of such a strategy call for strengthening formal institutions, and therefore, the dynamic interaction between institutions and organizations comes full circle (gure 1). Specically, it evolves precisely in a manner described by North (1990:5) in that strategic choices made by organizations are inuenced by the institutional framework, and in turn, they inuence how the institutional framework evolves.

TOWARDS AN INSTITUTION-BASED VIEW OF BUSINESS STRATEGY

261

Contributions, critiques, and extensions Contributions While a short article such as the present one is certainly unable to do justice to such a vast and expanding literature,2 it is evident that signicant progress has been made in the past decade or so. At least two major contributions emerge. First, research on Asian organizations has addressed head-on the very rst fundamental question in strategic management on why rm strategies differ identied by Rumelt and colleagues (1994), through developing and extending an institution-based view of business strategy. Note that this new perspective does not imply a rejection of existing work based on competition- and resource-based views. Elsewhere (Peng, 2001b:821), I have argued that there is substantial room to integrate the more established resource-based view with the emerging institution-based view of business strategy. It is important to note that these perspectives are not mutually exclusive. The institution-based view supplements and enriches mainstream strategy research by drawing attention to the often overlooked importance of institutions, both formal and informal, which are broader than the traditional notion of national cultural differences (Hoskisson et al., 2000). The recent rise of interest in institutional research is probably a reaction to its backburner status in the strategy research agenda for a long time. Moreover, not only existing strategy research focuses largely on the West, so does most institutional work. As a result, the importance of institutions fades into the background, which is generally ignored by most strategy researchers. A focus on Asian economies is, therefore, theoretically important because it allows us to highlight the importance of institutional forces (Scott, 1995:146). In other words, Asian economies have become viable research laboratories (Shenkar and von Glinow, 1994:56). Such work, I believe, has provided the strongest support to the institution-based view, because research in developed economies, where the rules of the game are taken for granted, has had a difcult time separating the institutional effect on rm strategy and performance that is independent of economic and cultural effects. Research on non-Western economies, on the other hand, has not only clearly demonstrated that institutions matter, but has also made signicant progress to take on the challenge suggested by Powell (1996:297) to specify the nature of such a link in terms of how they matter, under what circumstances, to what extent, and in what ways. Second, in addition to advancing strategy research, institution-based research on business strategies in Asian economies also contributes to institutional theory by demonstrating the benets of integrating with efciency-oriented research. Some institutional theorists suggest that the new institutionalism . . . comprises a rejection of rational-actor models often found in efciency-based research (DiMaggio and Powell, 1991:8, added emphasis). While such a perspective may be insightful when studying educational institutions and public bureaucracies, where institutional research initially rose, recent work argues against pitting strategic and institutional, substantive and symbolic, and economic and social factors against each other (Powell, 1996:295). When institutional theory moves away from schools and bureaucracies to assert its inuence in the arena of efciency-driven business organizations, a focus on efciency outcomes becomes necessary (Oliver, 1997; Scott,

262

PENG

1995). Otherwise, the usefulness of institutional theory in explaining performance-driven organizational phenomena such as business strategy is limited. In our particular case, traditional institutional analysis would suggest that certain strategies (e.g., supplier relations in Japan, conglomerate diversication in India and Korea) persist simply because such a practice is widely adopted (or institutionalized), independent of evidence that it works. Such a perspective, however, is difcult to accommodate the emerging evidence documenting concrete performance benets associated with these strategies (Khanna and Palepu, 2000; Khanna and Rivkin, 2001). At this conjuncture, an integrative approach incorporating both the institutional and efciency perspectives would be sensible. The challenge for researchers is to uncover the underlying mechanisms that relate institutions to organizational strategies, and then to link them with rm performance (Peng and Luo, 2000). Critiques and extensions Originating in the 1970s, the new institutionalism in the social sciences was still in its adolescence by the 1980s (Scott, 1995), and its application to strategic management is a more recent development (Oliver, 1997)note that virtually all key references reviewed in the four substantive sections are published in the 1990s and beyond. As a result, there are a number of important problems that existing research has yet to address. Perhaps foremost is the need for more theoretical development in order to answer the question rst raised by Coase (1937): What is the nature of the rm? A lot of existing work on rm strategies does not agree on what exactly a rm is. A rm in the West has relatively clear legal boundaries characterized by hierarchical control by top management (Williamson, 1985). A rm, especially the large conglomerate, in many Asian economies tends to have blurring boundaries permeated by personal connections, partial ownerships, and board interlocks. Such a loosely dened organization is often called a business group (Granovetter, 1994). The difculty in dening rm (or group) boundaries has not only led to empirical problems when measuring their size, strategy, and performance (Khanna and Rivkin, 2001), but also resulted in a conceptual debate on whether these organizations qualify as rms. Specically, Hamilton and Feenstra (1995:58) argue that the narrowly dened Coasian rm with clear boundaries does not have the same empirical and conceptual signicance throughout the world but, rather, is a prominent feature . . . only in modern Western societies. While research on keirestsu networks in Japan has forced strategy researchers to examine the validity of our conceptualization of the rm based on the Western model, more recent work nds that similar networks dominate the organizational landscape in many Asian countries. A traditional answer is to suggest that these organizations are outliers operating under a different set of logic, and that the eld can afford to ignore them and develop grand theories (mostly focusing on Western economies). However, in light of the growing importance of Asian economies and their increased integration with the rest of the world, such an answer becomes indefensible, if we as a eld ever endeavor to approach a global science of organizations (Peng, Lee and Tan, 2001). While delineating the essence of this debate is beyond the scope of this article, future conceptual progress on what constitutes a rm

TOWARDS AN INSTITUTION-BASED VIEW OF BUSINESS STRATEGY

263

is clearly needed when carrying out strategy research in both Western and non-Western economies. Second, most existing research is of a static nature, that is, scholars propose and test linear directions, such as close supplier relations and conglomerate diversication lead to better performance. The dynamic aspects of the complex relationships have been rarely explored. For example, supplier relations that are too close may introduce rigidities in product designs, resulting in a loss of much-needed exibility. It is not known, however, how close the relationship with suppliers is too close. In terms of conglomerates in Asian economies, after all, they confront the same problems that plague those in the West: The more activities a rm engages in, the harder it is for the head ofce to coordinate, control, and invest properly in different member units. Therefore, how much scope is too much remains to be explored, because it is evident that beyond a point of inection, further diversication will only backre (Chang and Hong, 2000; Lee, Peng and Lee, 2002). In future research, how to identify such a point of inection in highly dynamic and uncertain institutional environments remains a major challenge. Finaly, how national cultures, interacting with institutional frameworks, affect strategic choices needs to be explored in more depth. Will strategies in Asian economies converge on Western models? Given that individual managers making strategic decisions are inuenced by their own national cultures (Hofstede, 1991), convergence is not likely to be the case, at least in the short run (Chen, 2001). On the other hand, complete divergence is also not feasible in todays increasingly integrated global economy. By implication, what seems more likely is crossvergence, in that strategies in non-Western economies will continue to be different from those observed in the West, while, beyond some point of inection discussed above, gradually moving toward more similar (but not the same) strategies, as more market-supporting institutions are developed (Young et al., 2002). Currently, we know very little about how these cultural processes manifest themselves in strategic choices, and therefore, need to pay attention to these processes in future research. Conclusions This article has focused on why rm strategies differ, by exploring the underlying institutional frameworks that drive strategic choices. Since frame-breaking experiences only come from examining and comprehending organizations operating in other places and other times (Scott, 1995:151), business strategies in Asian organizations have attracted signicant attention recently. Overall, research in this area has increasingly appeared in leading journals, thus starting to disseminate this knowledge and assert its inuence in the mainstream literature (Peng, 2001b; Peng et al., 2001). To be sure, the studies reviewed in this article, mostly published in the 1990s, are just the entering wedges into the complex and dynamic relationships among institutions, organizations, and strategic choices, and certainly not the nal words on them. Companies strategic moves and our learning about them are not likely to stop soon. One thing for sure is that the importance of institutional inuences on business strategies will be increasingly appreciated in the new millennium, thus necessitating more attention from researchers, practitioners, as well as policy makers not only in Asia but also around the world.

264 Acknowledgment

PENG

This article was rst drafted when I was a visiting scholar at The Chinese University of Hong Kong during December 2001. It was supported in part by the Center for International Business Education and Research, Fisher College of Business Research Committee, Center for East Asian Studies, and Ofce of International Affairs, The Ohio State University. I thank Kevin Au, Janet Ng, and Denis Wang for making my visit possible, and the editor (C.M. Lau) and the two anonymous reviewers for their encouragement and guidance on this article. Notes
1. The other four most fundamental questions are (1) How do rms behave? (2) How are strategy outcomes affected by strategy processes? (3) What determines the scope of the rm? and (4) What determines the international success and failure of rms? While other questions can be raised, according to Rumelt and colleagues (1994:570), they all relate in one way or another to these ve questions. 2. For a detailed review of management and organizational research on Greater China, see Peng et al. (2001).

References
Au, K., M.W. Peng, and D. Wang. (2000). Interlocking Directorates, Firm Strategies, and Performance in Hong Kong: Towards a Research Agenda. Asia Pacic Journal of Management 17(1), 2947. Barney, J. (1991). Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage. Journal of Management 17, 99120. Beamish, P. (1993). The Characteristics of Joint Ventures in the Peoples Republic of China. Journal of International Marketing 1(2), 2948. Boddewyn, J. and T. Brewer. (1994). International-Business Political Behavior: New Theoretical Directions. Academy of Management Review 19, 119143. Boisot, M. and J. Child. (1996). From Fiefs to Clans and Network Capitalism: Expanding Chinas Emerging Economic Order. Administrative Science Quarterly 41, 600628. Bruton, G., D. Ahlstrom, and J. Wan. (2001). Turnaround Success of Large and Midsize Chinese Owned Firms: Evidence from Hong Kong and Thailand. Journal of World Business 36, 146165. Carroll, G. (1993). A Sociological View on Why Firms Differ. Strategic Management Journal 14, 237 249. Chang, S.J. and J. Hong. (2000). Economic Performance of Group-Afliated Companies in Korea: Intragroup Resource Sharing and Internal Business Transactions. Academy of Management Journal 43, 429449. Chen, M.-J. (2001). Inside Chinese Business. Boston: Harvard Business School Press. Child, J. (1972). Organizational Structure, Environment, and Performance: The Role of Strategic Choice. Sociology 6, 122. Child, J. (1994). Management in China During the Age of Reform. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Chung, C. (2001). Markets, Culture, and Institutions: The Emergence of Large Business Groups in Taiwan, 1950s1970s. Journal of Management Studies 38, 719745. Coase, R. (1937). The Nature of the Firm. Economica 4, 386405. Davis, L. and D. North. (1970). Institutional Change and American Economic Growth. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. DiMaggio, P. and W. Powell. (1991). Introduction. In W. Powell and P. DiMaggio (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Dore, R. (1987). Taking Japan Seriously. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Dyer, J. (1997). Effective Interrm Collaboration: How Firms Minimize Transaction Costs and Maximize Transaction Value. Strategic Management Journal 18, 535556.

TOWARDS AN INSTITUTION-BASED VIEW OF BUSINESS STRATEGY

265

Dyer, J. and K. Nobeoka. (2000). Creating and Managing a High-Performance Knowledge-Sharing Network: The Toyota Case. Strategic Management Journal 21, 345367. Farh, J., C. Earley, and B. Cheng. (1997). Impetus for Action: A Cultural Analysis of Justice and Organizational Citizenship Behavior in Chinese Society. Administrative Science Quarterly 42, 421444. Fukuyama, F. (1996). Trust: The Social Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity. New York: Free Press. Gerlach, M. (1992). Alliance Capitalism: The Social Organization of Japanese Business. Berkeley: University of California Press. Grabher, G. and D. Stark (eds.). (1997). Restructuring Networks in Post-Socialism. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Granovetter, M. (1994). Business Groups. In N. Smesler and R. Swedberg (eds.), Handbook of Economic Sociology. pp. 453475. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Hamilton, G. and R. Feenstra. (1995). Varieties of Hierarchies and Markets: An Introduction. Industrial and Corporate Change 4, 5191. Hill, C. (1995). National Institutional Structures, Transaction Cost Economizing, and Competitive Advantage: The Case of Japan. Organization Science 6, 119131. Hofstede, G. (1991). Cultures and Organizations. New York: McGraw-Hill. Hoskisson, R., L. Eden, C.M. Lau, and M. Wright. (2000). Strategy in Emerging Economies. Academy of Management Journal 43, 249267. Hoskisson, R. and M. Hitt. (1994). Downscoping. New York: Oxford University Press. Keister, L. (2000). Chinese Business Groups. New York: Oxford University Press. Kelley, L. and R. Worthley. (1981). The Role of Culture in Comparative Management: A Cross-Cultural Perspective. Academy of Management Journal 24, 164173. Khanna, T. and K. Palepu. (1997). Why Focused Strategies May be Wrong for Emerging Markets. Harvard Business Review July/August, 4151. Khanna, T. and K. Palepu. (2000). Is Group Afliation Protable in Emerging Markets? An Analysis of Diversied Indian Business Groups. Journal of Finance 55, 867891. Khanna, T. and J. Rivkin. (2001). Estimating the Performance Effects of Business Groups in Emerging Markets. Strategic Management Journal 22, 4574. Lau, C.M. and L. Busenitz. (2001). Growth Intentions of Entrepreneurs in a Transition Economy: The Peoples Republic of China. Entrepreneurship Theory and Research Fall, 520. Lau, C.M. and H. Ngo. (2001). Organization Development and Firm Performance: A Comparison of Multinational and Local Firms. Journal of International Business Studies 32, 95114. Lawrence, P. and J. Lorsch. (1969). Organization and Environment. Homewood, IL: Irwin. Lee, K., M.W. Peng, and K. Lee. (2002). Institutional Transitions and Diversication Discount. Working Paper. Columbus: Fisher College of Business, The Ohio State University. Lim, G. and T. Teck. (1995). Diversication Strategies, Firm Characteristics, and Performance Among Singapore Firms. International Journal of Management 12, 223233. Linz, S. and G. Krueger. (1998). Enterprise Restructuring in Russias Transition Economy: Formal and Informal Mechanisms. Comparative Economic Studies 40, 552. Luo, Y. and M.W. Peng. (1999). Learning to Compete in a Transition Economy: Experience, Environment, and Performance. Journal of International Business Studies 30(2), 269296. Matsusaka, J. (1993). Takeover Motives during the Conglomerate Merger Wave. RAND Journal of Economics 24, 357379. McGrath, R., I. MacMillan, I. Yang, and W. Tsai. (1992). Does Culture Endure, or is it Malleable? Issues for Entrepreneurial Economic Development. Journal of Business Venturing 7, 441458. Mitchell, R., B. Smith, K. Seawright, and E. Morse. (2000). Cross-Cultural Cognitions and the Venture Creation Decision. Academy of Management Journal 43, 974993. Nelson, R. (1991). Why do Firms Differ and How Does it Matter? Strategic Management Journal 12(winter), 6174. North, D. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Oliver, C. (1997). Sustainable Competitive Advantage: Combining Institutional and Resource-Based Views. Strategic Management Journal 18, 679713.

266

PENG

Peng, M.W. (1997). Firm Growth in Transition Economies: Three Longitudinal Cases from China, 198996. Organization Studies 18(3), 385413. Peng, M.W. (2000a). Business Strategies in Transition Economies. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Peng, M.W. (2000b). Controlling the Foreign Agent: How Governments Deal with Multinationals in a Transition Economy. Management International Review 40(2), 141165. Peng, M.W. (2001a). How Entrepreneurs Create Wealth in Transition Economies. Academy of Management Executive 15(1), 95108. Peng, M.W. (2001b). The Resource-Based View and International Business. Journal of Management 27(6), 803829. Peng, M.W. (2002). Cultures, Institutions, and Strategic Choices: Towards an Institutional Perspective on Business Strategy. In M. Gannon and K. Newman (eds.), The Blackwell Handbook of Cross-Cultural Management. (pp. 5266). Cambridge, UK: Blackwell. Peng, M.W., K. Au, and D. Wang. (2001). Interlocking Directorates as Corporate Governance in Third World Multinationals: Theory and Evidence from Thailand. Asia Pacic Journal of Management 18(2), 161181. Peng, M.W. and P. Heath. (1996). The Growth of the Firm in Planned Economies in Transition: Institutions, Organizations, and Strategic Choice. Academy of Management Review 21(2), 492528. Peng, M.W., S. Lee, and J. Tan, J. (2001). The keiretsu in Asia: Implications for Multilevel Theories of Competitive Advantage. Journal of International Management 7(4), 253276. Peng, M.W., Y. Lu, O. Shenkar, and D. Wang. (2001). Treasures in the China House: A Review of Management and Organizational Research on Greater China. Journal of Business Research 52(2), 95110. Peng, M.W. and Y. Luo. (2000). Managerial Ties and Firm Performance in a Transition Economy: The Nature of a Micro-Macro Link. Academy of Management Journal 43(3), 486501. Peng, M.W., Y. Luo, and L. Sun. (1999). Firm Growth via Mergers and Acquisitions in China. In L. Kelley and Y. Luo (eds.), China 2000: Emerging Business Issues. pp. 73100. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Penrose, E. (1959). The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. New York: Wiley. Porter, M. (1980). Competitive Strategy. New York: Free Press. Powell, W. (1996). Commentary on the Nature of Institutional Embeddedness. Advances in Strategic Management 13, 293300. Puffer, S. (1994). Understanding the Bear: A Portrait of Russian Business Leaders. Academy of Management Executive 8(1), 4154. Rumelt, R., D. Schendel, and D. Teece (eds.). (1994). Fundamental Issues in Strategy: A Research Agenda. Boston: Harvard Business School Press. Scott, W.R. (1995). Institutions and Organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Shenkar, O. and J. Li. (1999). Knowledge Search in International Cooperative Ventures. Organization Science 10, 134143. Shenkar, O. and M. von Glinow. (1994). Paradoxes of Organizational Theory and Research: Using the Case of China to Illustrate National Contingency. Management Science 40, 5671. Spicer, A., G. McDermott, and B. Kogut. (2000). Entrepreneurship and Privatization in Central Europe: The Tenuous Balance Between Destruction and Creation. Academy of Management Review 25, 630649. Stark, D. (1996). Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism. American Journal of Sociology 101, 9931027. Tan, J., and R. Litschert. (1994). Environment-Strategy Relationship and its Performance Implications: An Empirical Study of the Chinese Electronics Industry. Strategic Management Journal 15, 120. Tan, J. and M.W. Peng. (2002). Culture, Nation, and Entrepreneurship: Implications for an Emerging Economy. Working Paper. Columbus: Fisher College of Business, The Ohio State University. Wan, C. (1998). International Diversication, Product Diversication, and Firm Performance of Hong Kong MNCs. Asia Pacic Journal of Management 15, 205217. White, S. (2000). Competition, Capabilities, and the Make, Buy, or Ally Decisions of Chinese State-Owned Firms. Academy of Management Journal 43, 324341. Williamson, O. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free Press. Williamson, O. (1991). Strategizing, Economizing, and Economic Organization. Strategic Management Journal 12, 7594.

TOWARDS AN INSTITUTION-BASED VIEW OF BUSINESS STRATEGY

267

Xin, K. and J. Pearce. (1996). Guanxi: Good Connections as Substitutes for Institutional Support. Academy of Management Journal 39, 16411658. Yan, A. and B. Gray. (1994). Bargaining Power, Management Control, and Performance in U.S.-China Joint Ventures: A Comparative Case Study. Academy of Management Journal 37, 14781517. Young, M., M.W. Peng, D. Ahlstrom, and G. Bruton. (2002). Governing the Corporation in Emerging Economies: A Principal-Principal Agency Perspective. Working paper. Hong Kong: The Chinese University of Hong Kong. Zhang, B. and M.W. Peng. (2000). Telecom Competition, Post-WTO Style. China Business Review May-June, 1221. Mike W. Peng is an assistant professor of management at the Fisher College of Business, The Ohio State University. He holds a Ph.D. from the University of Washington. He has widely published in leading journals such as the Academy of Management Journal, Academy of Management Review, Journal of International Business Studies, and Journal of Management, served on the editorial boards of AMR, APJM, and JIBS, and authored Business Strategies in Transition Economies (Sage, 2000).

You might also like