SSRN Id4592419

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 58

Hedge Fund Option Usage and Skewness Risk

Premium*
Shuaiyu Chen„ Shuaiqi Li

Abstract
We study how hedge fund option usage can aect the skewness risk
premium in the cross-section of individual stock options. We nd that stocks
with more of their hedge fund holders employing the long naked put strategy
(long put option without the underlying stock) have more positive returns of
their skewness assets comprised of options, whose payo (price) resembles
the realized (risk-neutral) skewness of the underlying stock return. We
document evidence consistent with a price-pressure channel: Those stocks
face larger demand on their out-of-the-money put options, which makes
their risk-neutral skewness more negative and lowers the price of skewness
asset; In the meanwhile, the long naked put positions of hedge funds cannot
predict the realized skewness. The channel works through the idiosyncratic
rather than systematic component of skewness. Other hedge fund option
strategies cannot robustly predict skewness asset returns.

Keywords: skewness risk premium, option, hedge fund.

* We are grateful for the comments from George Aragon, Steven Heston, Christopher Jones, Gang
Li (discussant), and conference participants at the 9th Hong Kong Joint Finance Research Conference.
All errors are our own.
„ Mitchell E. Daniels, Jr. School of Business, Purdue University, chen4144@purdue.edu
Department of Economics and Finance, City University of Hong Kong, shuaiqli@cityu.edu.hk.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


1 Introduction

Classic portfolio theory assumes that investors only care about the mean and variance

of stock returns, but the question of whether higher moments are priced has been of

long-standing interest to nancial economists. Early studies such as Rubinstein (1973),

Kraus and Litzenberger (1976), and Harvey and Siddique (2000) develop theoretical

frameworks in which only systematic skewness carries a negative risk premium as it

cannot be hedged away, while recent theories (see Brunnermeier, Gollier, and Parker

(2007), Barberis and Huang (2008), and Mitton and Vorkink (2007)) show that total

skewness, including the idiosyncratic skewness, plays a critical role because investors

with skewness preference may choose to hold under-diversied portfolios.

The empirical pursuit of measuring skewness premium is divided into two ap-

proaches. One strand of the literature uses stocks as the testing asset: They sort

stocks into portfolios based on future skewness estimated from some statistical models,

1
and then compare the stock portfolio returns. . The other approach is to construct a

skewness asset that typically involves a long position on out-of-the-money (OTM) call

options and a short position on OTM put options. The asset has a payo resembling

2
or replicating the realized skewness of the underlying stock return. Therefore, the

average return of this asset is a direct measure of the skewness risk premium.

In this paper, we study how hedge fund (HF hereafter) usage of individual stock

options can aect the skewness risk premium, measured with options, in the cross-

section. There are ve reasons why this design can be important: First, the leverage

1 See Harvey and Siddique (2000), Boyer, Mitton, and Vorkink (2010), Conrad, Dittmar, and Ghysels
(2013), Chang, Christoersen, and Jacobs (2013), Amaya, Christoersen, Jacobs, and Vasquez (2015),
and Langlois (2020)
2 See Bali and Murray (2013), Kozhan, Neuberger, and Schneider (2013), Schneider and Trojani
(2019), Pederzoli (2017), and Orªowski, Schneider, and Trojani (2023).

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


embedded in option contracts makes them particularly attractive to those investors

with lottery preference and leverage constraint, and oers an ideal arena to measure

skewness risk premium (Boyer and Vorkink (2014), and Frazzini and Pedersen (2022));

Second, HF is commonly viewed as an important user of options. Since option demand

pressure can signicantly aect option prices (Garleanu, Pedersen, and Poteshman

(2008), and Muravyev (2016)), the option usage of HF can potentially aect the price

level of skewness asset and hence the magnitude of skewness risk premium; Third, HF

is supposed to be important marginal investor in pricing the skewness risk, given the

ample evidence in the extant literature documenting that HF uses options to exploit

tail risk, which is closely related to skewness risk. For example, Agarwal, Ruenzi, and

Weigert (2017) nd that HFs change their option positions to time the systematic tail

risk prior to the 2008 nancial crisis. Gao, Gao, and Song (2018) document evidence

consistent with some HFs exploiting market-level ex-ante disaster concerns by selling

insurance; Forth, the individual stock option positions of HFs are supposed to represent

their preference for idiosyncratic, rather than systematic, skewness. Otherwise, they

should use the relatively more liquid index options. This can oer new evidence on

whether idiosyncratic skewness is priced; Fifth, the nature of dierent option strategies

could reveal the speculative demand of HF for dierent sides of the distribution. For

example, long put (call) strategy should signal the desire for exposure to the left (right)

side of the distribution. This helps us understand that HF option demand aects

skewness premium through which side of the distribution.

HF option demand may aect the return of skewness asset via two opposing chan-

nels: price-pressure channel versus informed-trading channel. Take the long naked put

position as an example: In a price-pressure channel, HF demand for put option will

make put more expensive relative to call and thus lower the price of skewness asset

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


due to its short position on put option. This positively predicts the return of skewness

asset. In an informed-trading channel, HFs take the long naked put position because

they anticipate large downward movements. If they have skills in timing crashes at the

individual-stock-level, their naked put position will negatively predict future skewness,

which is analogous to the payo of skewness asset, and thus negatively predict the

return of skewness asset.

We utilize the individual stock option positions of HF disclosed in the quarterly

SEC 13F llings. Since HFs are only required to disclose their long positions, we focus

on strategies involving long option positions and ignore those involving short positions

due to the data constraint. We classify option positions into four dierent types of

strategies: long naked put, protective put, straddle/strangle, and long call. Due to the

fact that HFs are not required to report the details of their option contracts such as

market value, strikes, and maturities, we follow Aragon and Martin (2012) in using the

proportion of a stock's HF holders disclosing a certain option strategy on the underlying

stock to proxy for hedge fund option demand. This measure is at the stock-quarter level.

In each month, we match the monthly skewness asset return with the option demand

proxy in the previous quarter, and run Fama-MacBeth regressions to predict returns.

We construct the skewness asset following Bali and Murray (2013).

Our main nding is that stocks with a larger proportion of HF holders employing

the long naked put tend to have higher returns on their skewness assets. This nding

supports the price-pressure but not informed-trading channel. The positive relation

remains robust after controlling for a wide range of rm characteristics and persists for

only one quarter. This lines up with our nding that the majority of HF option positions

last up to one quarter. The relatively short holding period suggests that HFs use the

naked put to bet on short-term information and that the price pressure should be fairly

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


short-lived. A long-short strategy formed on the naked put usage generates a monthly

return of 1.53% and an annual Sharpe ratio of 0.68. The strategy remains protable

after considering reasonable option bid-ask spreads. The return spread is insignicant

(largest) among the subset of stocks with the lowest (highest) option-hedging costs,

consistent with the price-pressure channel in which option demand pressure aects

option price through the frictions from market makers.

To further disentangle the price-pressure channel from the informed-trading chan-

nel, we separately investigate how the long naked put position predicts the risk-neutral

and realized skewness, which closely resemble the price and payo of the skewness asset,

respectively. The skewness asset in Bali and Murray (2013) is delta- and vega-neutral

just at the inception of portfolio formation. Even though this static hedge minimizes

transaction cost and enhances tradeability, large stock price and volatility movements

after the formation date may reduce the hedging performance and the resemblance

between asset payo and realized skewness. As a robustness check, we construct risk-

neutral skewness following Orªowski, Schneider, and Trojani (2023) (OST hereafter).

Unlike the conventional method in Bakshi, Kapadia, and Madan (2003) (BKM here-

after), OST dene skewness in a way such that we can form a linear portfolio of options,

whose price equals the risk-neutral skewness, to generate a payo equal to the realized

skewness. We use naked put positions to predict the synthetic return of the skewness

asset in OST and nd the same positive predictive power with a similar t-statistic as

using the asset in Bali and Murray (2013).

To investigate how HF naked put usage aects the risk-neutral skewness, we rst

verify that the proxy constructed from long naked put positions is indeed positively

related to option demand pressure. Specically, we nd that market makers face larger

buying pressure on the put options written on the stocks with more HFs using the

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


naked put. Therefore, the proxy captures not only the extensive margin of HF option

usage, but also the intensive margin. After we split option contracts into OTM and

other moneynesses, we nd that the proxy can only positively predict the demand on

OTM put options that take up a short position in the risk-neutral skewness. This

specic pattern of demand pressure is supposed to make these stocks' put options more

expensive and lower their risk-neutral skewness. Consistent with this conjecture, we

nd that the naked put positions negatively predict cross-sectional risk-neutral skewness

3
constructed in OST. The evidence supports the price-pressure channel in which HF

naked put usage lowers the price of skewness asset and positively predicts skewness

asset return.

Next, we investigate whether HF naked put usage can predict realized skewness.

HFs supposedly use naked put to exploit the large downward movements in future stock

prices, i.e., crash risks. If they have the skill to time the stock-level crashes, their naked

put positions should negatively predict future skewness. If their timing skill were strong

enough, it could outweigh the decrease of risk-neutral skewness in the price-pressure

channel and negatively predict the return of skewness asset. We nd limited evidence

for this hypothesis: Used alone, the coecient of naked put is negative but signicant

only at the 10% level; After controlling for other predictors in the literature, it becomes

insignicant. The evidence contradicts the informed-trading channel and suggests that

HFs using naked put do not possess skills at timing crashes at the individual-stock-level.

In summary, the ndings that HF naked put positions lower risk-neutral skewness, have

little predictive power on realized skewness, and positively predict the return of skewness

asset combined lend supports to the price-pressure channel.

Intuitively, HFs use individual stock options to exploit the idiosyncratic component

3 The negative relation is robust to alternative construction in BKM.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


of stock price movements. Consistent with this intuition, after decomposing the total

risk-neutral skewness into idiosyncratic and systematic components, we nd that naked

put usage only lowers the idiosyncratic but not the systematic component. It suggests

that the desire for exposures to idiosyncratic downward stock movements motivates HFs

to long naked put, which makes put options overpriced and then aects the skewness

premium embedded in options. This is consistent with the empirical ndings in Boyer,

Mitton, and Vorkink (2010) and Boyer and Vorkink (2014) that idiosyncratic skewness

is priced and carries a negative expected return. Our nding also complements the HF

literature that typically focuses on the exposure to the market-level tail risk.

Other option strategies, including protective put, straddle/strangle, and long call,

cannot robustly predict skewness asset return. We nd that those option positions fail

to predict the option demand pressure faced by market makers. Therefore, there are no

evidence that their usage imposes enough price pressure to aect option return. Even

though the market value of option position is not reported, HFs report the market value

of the stocks underlying the option contract. In terms of stock value, naked put has

an average more than twice of protective put and straddle/strangle. Thus, it is not

surprising that those two strategies do not create demand pressure as large as naked

put. However, for long call position, it has an average more than twice of naked put. To

explore why it do not translate into large buying pressure for call options, we use rm

characteristics to explain option usage. What we nd is that turnover, which proxies

for dierence of opinions according to Hong and Stein (1999), is the most important

determinant of call usage other than rm size. Its coecient magnitude is twice of short

interest, which is the most important determinant of naked put usage. In comparison,

when we explain naked put usage, the coecient of short interest is more than twice of

turnover. Therefore, it is likely that other investors trade against HFs and absorb the

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


buying orders on call options from HFs. Another possibility is that covered call (writing

call option and long the underlying stock) is a popular strategy employed by mutual

fund for the purpose of income generation (Cici and Palacios (2015) and Kaniel and

Wang (2022)). This would neutralize the buying pressure from HF to some extent. To

test this possibility, we match the long option positions of HF with the corresponding

4
short option positions of mutual fund at the stock-quarter level. We nd that 24.56% of

the long call positions from HF have at least one mutual fund taking the corresponding

short call positions on the same underlying rm in the same quarter. In contrast, only

9.6% of long naked put positions from HF correspond to the short put positions from

mutual fund. Therefore, the liquidity provided by mutual funds that use covered call

may dampen the price pressure from the HFs that long call. Overall, we nd that HF

speculative demand for the right-side of distribution, proxied by long call positions, is

not strong enough to aect the skewness premium. This is in contrast with long naked

put positions, which proxy for the demand on the left-side of distribution.

We also provide empirical evidence against alternative interpretations. First, the

SEC only requires HFs to report long positions but not short positions. This asymmetric

regulatory requirement raises the concern that the long naked put positions we observe

may be used to hedge the unobservable short positions on put options of HFs. In

this case, long naked put positions of HF are used for risk management, instead of

speculation, purpose, and it would be unsurprising that they cannot predict future

skewness. However, if risk management were the main purpose, the size of those long

naked put positions should be smaller or at most equal to the short positions. In

this case, the net demand of HFs on put options should be negative, and our proxy is

4 In addition to long positions, mutual funds report their short positions to data vendors such as
Morningstar and Lipper.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


expected to negatively predict the open interest of put options. This predicted sign is

in sharp contrast with our earlier ndings. If we multiply put open interest by delta

(vega), we nd that the long naked put usage negatively (positively) predicts the delta-

(vega-) adjusted put open interest, suggesting that market makers have to sell put to

clear the market. This further corroborates our earlier ndings and contradicts the risk

management interpretation.

Second, we do several things to tease out the eect of volatility from skewness. The

skewness asset in Bali and Murray (2013) is vega-neutral at the formation day, and we

control for volatility in regressions. In addition, the skewness asset in OST we use as a

robustness check can separate the jump component of skewness from the leverage eect

component. The naked put usage can negatively predict the return of jump component

with highly signicant t-statistic. We also control for variance risk premium and nd

that it barely aects the predictive power of naked put usage on skewness asset return.

Our paper contributes to the literature on the skewness risk premium by connecting

it with the literature studying how HF exploits tail risk. The HF literature focuses on

5
how higher-moment risks can explain HF performance. However, no one examines the

other direction, i.e., how HF activities such as option usage can aect the pricing of

higher-moment risks. To the best of our knowledge, we are the rst to study the role

of HF as a marginal investor in pricing skewness risk.

Aragon and Martin (2012) nd that HF positions of individual stock options predict

the direction and volatility of the underlying stock return, indicating that HFs are

informed about the rst- and second-order moments. We extend the framework to study

the pricing of third-order moment, after noticing the fact that HFs are sophisticated

5 See Agarwal, Bakshi, and Huij (2009), Bali, Brown, and Caglayan (2012), Kelly and Jiang (2012),
and Agarwal, Ruenzi, and Weigert (2017) for example.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


enough to utilize options to exploit higher-order moment risks as suggested by the HF

literature and that the activity itself can create option demand pressure and thus aect

the pricing of those risks.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data used in

our empirical work. Section 3 investigates how HF option positions predict skewness

asset returns. Section 4 presents evidence supporting that the return predictability is

caused by price pressure. Section 5 performs robustness checks. Section 6 concludes.

2 Data

This section describes how we measure HF option demand and skewness asset return.

2.1 Hedge Fund Option Holdings

Our main database of portfolio holdings contains historical Form 13F lings. Since

1978, all institutional investors (including hedge fund investment advisors) who exercise

investment discretion over accounts holding at least $100 million are required by Section

13(f ) of the Exchange Act of 1934 to make quarterly disclosures of portfolio holdings

to the SEC in Form 13F within 45 days of the quarter end. The types of securities that

are required to be disclosed include exchange-traded stocks, ETFs, equity options and

warrants, convertible bonds, and shares of closed-end investment companies. All long

positions in these securities with more than ten thousand shares or with market values

greater than $200,000 must be reported on Form 13F. Short positions, open-end funds,

and private securities do not need to be disclosed. The items in Form 13F include

the issuers of the securities, the type of security, CUSIP, the number of shares, and

the market value of each security held by institutional investors. In the case of option

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


positions, institutional investors must provide the CUSIP and the dollar amount owned

in terms of the securities underlying the options, not the options themselves. They

are required to report whether options are calls or puts, but are not required to report

the strike price or expiration date of an option. In addition, institutional investors

report aggregated holdings in all individual funds managed by the same management

company.

The Form 13F lings are available for download from the SEC's EDGAR system,

but need considerable further processing due to manual formatting. While the widely

used institutional holdings databases in academic studies (e.g., Thomson Reuters and

Factset) only provide stock holdings, the commercial database WhaleWisdom oers

a complete set of reported 13F positions, including stock, option, and other types

of securities. Therefore, our empirical analysis is based on the 13F holdings data of

WhaleWisdom.

The Form 13F lings of HF investment advisors are identied as Agarwal, Jiang,

Tang, and Yang (2013) and Agarwal, Ruenzi, and Weigert (2017), based on the names

of HF companies that appear in four commercial HF databases: Eurekahedge, Hedge

6
Fund Research (HFR), Morningstar, and Lipper TASS. We match these HF company

names with the names of institutions reported in WhaleWisdom. Our sample consists

of portfolio holdings disclosed by 770 HF advisers from December 2004 to September

7
2020.
6 We thank Vikas Agarwal for providing the list of hedge fund rms. Joenväärä, Kaupila,
Kosowski, and Tolonen (2021) show that the use of multiple hedge fund databases rather than one
helps mitigate data biases. Some hedge fund rms are doing market-making in the option mar-
kets. According to the list of market makers in the derivative markets reported by the Financial
Conduct Authority (see, https://www.fca.org.uk/publication/documents/market-makers-authorised-
primary-dealers.pdf.), we remove six names from the hedge fund list: CREDIT SUISSE, EVNINE &
ASSOCIATES INC, GEMSSTOCK LTD., MITSUBISHI UFJ ASSET MANAGEMENT LTD., MOR-
GAN STANLEY, and TD ASSET MANAGEMENT INC.
7 Hedge fund holdings data in WhaleWisdom start from March 2001. However, due to the consid-
eration detailed in the next section, we pick this specic sample period.

10

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Since HFs are only required to disclose their long positions, we focus on strategies

involving long option positions. We classify option positions into six strategies: (1).`Op-

tion' means either long put or call. All option positions fall into this category, and it

is the most general category. (2).`Call' means that the fund only long call without put

on the stock. It is a directional bet on the upside information. (3).`Put' means long

put. In this case, the fund can either long only the put to make a directional bet on the

downside information, or long both put and call on the stock to make a non-directional

bet. The union of (2) and (3) equals (1). (4).`Straddle' means long both put and call on

8
the same underlying stock. It is a non-directional bet on the volatility. (5).`Protective

Put' means long both the put and the underlying stock without the call. HF uses it for

hedging purpose. (6).`Naked Put' means long put without the underlying stock or the

call. It is used for speculative purpose. The union of (4), (5), and (6) equals (3).

Table 1 presents the summary statistics of HF option holdings. In Panel A, there

are 22, 556 quarterly fund portfolios, 5, 110 of which contain at least one option holding.

In those 5, 110 portfolios, there are on average 119 rms on which the fund holds stocks

or options. On average, a fund holds options on 16.61% of the rms in its portfolio.

After we classify option positions into sub-categories, a fund long call (naked put) on

8.72% (5.25%) of the rms in its portfolio. A caveat is that the distributions are right

skewed, with medians much smaller than means.

In Panel B, we rst aggregate the market value (in millions of dollars) of the stocks

underlying the option contracts at the fund-quarter level, and then report the market

value conditioning on that a fund reported at least one option holding in that quarter.

On average, the market value of the stocks underlying all types of option contracts

8 Since funds do not report the strikes, we cannot dierentiate straddle from strangle. So we use
`Straddle' hereafter just for simplicity.

11

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


equals 98.31 million dollars in a HF portfolio, with long naked put positions contributing

23.42 million dollars.

Panel C reports the number of quarters each option position lasts. It is at the

granular fund-quarter-option level. For example, assume that a fund used options on

Tesla in March and June of 2019. It didn't report naked put in September, but started

to use it on Tesla in December 2019 again. Then we have two observations: One is the

naked put in March and June, and it equals 2 because it lasts for two quarters; The

other observation is the naked put in December, and it equals 1 because it only lasts

for one quarter. In the panel, the medians equal 1 for all categories, suggesting that

HFs use options to bet on relatively short-lived information.

To measure the option demand of HF industry for a given stock-quarter, we use the

proportion of HFs disclosing a certain type of option strategy on the stock, computed

as the number of funds using the strategy divided by the total number of funds holding

the stock or its options. For example, assume that there are 100 HFs holding the stock

or option of Tesla in a given quarter, and that 50 of them use naked put on Tesla.

Then:

50
N aked P ut = = 0.5.
100

Since naked put requires a long position on put options, we expect the measure to

be positively related to the demand pressure created by HF industry on Tesla's put

9
options. We construct the measure for each option strategy and for each stock-quarter.

Then we match this quarterly measure with the monthly skewness asset returns in the

next quarter. Therefore, the option holdings from December 2004 to September 2020

correspond to the returns from January 2005 to December 2020. By construction, the

9 If a stock or its option is not held by any HF in some quarter, the measure is not well-dened. We
follow Aragon and Martin (2012) and exclude those stock-quarters.

12

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


measure lines in [0, 1]. We pick it because funds do not report the details of their

option contracts. In addition, it is a well-established measure in the literature: Aragon

and Martin (2012) and Aragon, Chen, and Shi (2022) use it to show that HF option

positions predict volatilities and returns on the underlying stock.

2.2 Skewness Asset Return

To construct skewness asset, we use data from the OptionMetrics Ivy DB database,

which provides daily closing bid and ask quotes for the U.S. equity options. We use the

interest rate of appropriate maturity (interpolated when necessary) from OptionMetrics

as the risk-free rate. We obtain information about stock prices, returns, dividends,

trading volume, and market capitalization from CRSP. Accounting data and short

interest are from Compustat.

Following Bali and Murray (2013), the skewness asset comprises of a long position

on OTM call and a short position on OTM put. The OTM put (call) is the contract

with a delta closest to −0.1 (0.1). To isolate the third order movement from the rst

and second order moments, the skewness asset is constructed to be delta- and vega-

10
neutral. Let ∆P (∆C ) be the delta of put (call), and νP (νC ) be the vega of put (call).

The asset consists of 1 contract in the OTM call, −νC /νP contracts in the OTM put,

and −(∆C − νC /νP · ∆P ) shares in the underlying stock. We form the asset on the third

Friday of each month and hold it to the third Friday of the subsequent month, which

is the typical expiration day of monthly options. Therefore, skewness asset return is

10 To further tease out the relation between skewness and volatility, we control for the implied
volatility when predicting skewness asset returns later.

13

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


measured at monthly frequency as following:

P ayof f − P rice
rSkew = − rf .
|P rice|

Bali and Murray (2013) use the absolute value of the skewness asset price because the

price is not guaranteed to be positive. We construct the price using bid-ask midpoints

of options. rf is the risk-free interest rate.

The skewness asset is designed to increase in value if the skewness increases, and

it represents long skewness positions. If we hold the asset to expiration, it realizes a

high (low) payo when high (low) stock return is realized, but it is largely insensitive

to small stock moves.

We apply a series of lters: (1).Our sample includes only common shares (CRSP

share codes of 10 and 11). (2).We exclude stock-month observations if the underlying

stock price is less than $5 on the formation date or if the stock has a split or pays a

dividend during the remaining life of the option. Thus, the early exercise premium is

small. (3).We further remove option contracts with zero open interest or bid prices.

(4).We also discard options with missing delta or vega. (5).We then delete options

whose ask price is lower than the bid price, and eliminate those whose prices violate

arbitrage bounds. (6).Even though we pick the OTM options with deltas closest to

−0.1 (0.1) with an intention to capture the tail movements, the nal options picked

may not be as OTM as we desire after applying all the lters above. Thus, we include

only the observations with ∆P ≥ −0.25 and ∆C ≤ 0.25.11

Since HFs do not report the details of their option positions, there is no way for us

to compare the strikes of their option holdings with those options in the skewness asset,

11 Removing this lter does not qualitatively aect the return predictability of naked put.

14

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


and it is very likely that those options do not have the same strike and maturity. This

heterogeneity does not pose a concern on the price-pressure channel in the setting of

option markets, because Garleanu, Pedersen, and Poteshman (2008) show that the price

pressure created by demand imbalance on one option contract could spillover to other

options written on the same stock via correlated unhedgeable risks such as stochastic

volatility. Therefore, HFs can still aect the return of skewness asset even though they

are not holding the exact option contracts in the skewness asset.

We match each stock's skewness asset return with HF usage of the same stock's

options in the previous quarter. Figure 1 plots the number of stocks with positive HF

option demand for the 4 types of option strategies, respectively. To ensure adequate

statistical power and a fair comparison among those strategies, we require a month to

have at least 30 stocks with positive option demand and thus start the sample from

January 2005. The sample ends in December 2020.

Table 2 presents the summary statistics. Our nal sample contains 145, 067 stock-

month observations. rSkew has a mean of −0.77% per month with a standard deviation

of 16.33%. On average, a stock has 28 HF holders. HF option usage is heavily skewed:

Most of the stocks have no HF holders demanding their options, but the 90th percentiles

of most option strategies are positive. This leaves us enough stocks to form a reasonably

diversied decile portfolio.

15

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


3 Hedge Fund Option Demand and Skewness Asset

Return

This section investigates how dierent HF option strategies predict cross-sectional skew-

ness asset returns. Section 3.1 examines the return predictability using the Fama and

MacBeth (1973) regression. Section 3.2 explores the protability by forming long-short

portfolios. Section 3.3 checks the persistence of return predictability.

3.1 Cross-sectional Regressions

We run the following monthly Fama-MacBeth regression,

Skew
ri,t+1 = αt + γt · Hedge F und Option U sei,t + θt · Controlsi,t + ϵi,t+1 ,

Skew
where: ri,t+1 is stock i's skewness asset return in month t+1. Hedge F und Option U sei,t

is the latest available proportion of HFs disclosing a certain type of option position on

stock i. To ensure the robustness of our regression results, we include a variety of con-

trol variables that are common in the literature, including option return predictors and

stock characteristics. The construction details for all controls used in this paper can

be found in Appendix A. First, we control for the average implied volatility of the op-

tions in the skewness asset, as an eort to tease out the relation between the third and

second- order moments. Second, we control for option liquidity by using the average

percentile bid-ask spread of those options. Third, we include the short interest to make

sure that HF option demand is not a mere proxy for it. The rest variables are those

that have been shown by the literature to be related to the future or risk-neutral skew-

ness, including lagged skewness, turnover, maximum stock return in the past month,

16

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


beta, log market capitalization, log book-to-market ratio, idiosyncratic volatility, past

stock returns, Amihud illiquidity measure, and rm leverage ratio. We do not include

some important straddle return predictors such as volatility deviation in Goyal and

Saretto (2009), because we nd that they do not predict skewness asset return. This

suggests that skewness asset is constructed to capture higher-moment risk and diers

from volatility asset.

Table 3 reports the time-series averages of the coecients in Fama-MacBeth regres-

sions, together with their t-statistics in parentheses corrected for heteroskedasticity and

autocorrelation, following Newey and West (1986) with three lags. In column (1), the

variable Option positively predict rSkew with a t-statistic of 3.87. When it increases

from 0 to 1, rSkew increases by 5.2% per month. It remains signicant after controls. If

we split Option into Call and Put in column (3), they both signicantly predict rSkew .

However, they are no longer signicant at the conventional level after controls in column

(4). If we further split Put into Naked Put, Protective Put, and Straddle in column

(5), only Naked Put is signicant, indicating that the entire predictive power of put

option positions comes from naked put motivated by the speculative purpose. When it

increases from 0 to 1, rSkew increases by 15% per month. In column (6), we examine

the predictive power of all subcategories together with controls. The only subcategory

signicant at the conventional level is naked put, with a t-statistic of 2.86.

3.2 Portfolio Sort

The previous section documents that Naked Put displays a robust and positive predic-

tive power on skewness asset return. Next, we employ portfolio sort to examine the

performance of the option strategies formed by Naked Put and evaluate the impact of

17

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


transaction costs. The sample period is from January 2005 to December 2020.

We form long-short portfolio of skewness assets. We long the stocks in the top

decile with highest Naked Put. If the number of stocks with positive Naked Put is less

than 10% of the total number of stocks in a month, we only long those with positive

Naked Put. When we pick the sample period, we require a month to have at least 30

stocks with positive Naked Put. This lter enables us to have a reasonably diversied

portfolio. If the number is larger than 10% in that month, we long those stocks in the

top 10%. As to the short-side, we short all those stocks with zero Naked Put.

We value-weight stocks in the long and short portfolios on the third Friday of each

month based on their option dollar open interest. Since there is no well-established

factor model for skewness assets, we calculate risk-adjusted returns using the Fama

and French (2015) ve factors, stock momentum, the S&P 500 Index skewness return,

and the cross-sectional average of skewness returns, weighted by their option open

12
interests.

Panel A in Table 4 presents the average monthly returns of portfolios formed by

Naked Put. The (%) symbol after a variable means that it is reported as a percentage.

The long-short strategy generates a monthly return of 1.53% and an annualized Sharpe

ratio of 0.68. Its alpha equals 1.42% with a t-statistic of 2.81. A nice feature is that

the strategy has limited crash risk: It has a positive skewness of 5.60 and a minimum

monthly return of −8.83%.

We then analyze the protability over dierent subsamples. Figure 2 plots the ve-

year moving averages of monthly returns (Panel A) and annualized Sharpe ratio (Panel

B). The strategy performance is positive in each ve-year subsample, and performs

especially well during the nancial crisis and COVID period.

12 The risk factors are taken from Kenneth French's website.

18

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


So far, our results assume that options can be bought and sold at the midpoint of

bid and ask quotes. To evaluate how bid-ask spreads can aect the prots, we consider

eective spreads equal to 25%, 50%, 75%, and 100% of the quoted spreads in Panel

B. The eective spread is twice the dierence between the traded price and midpoint.

An eective-to-quoted spread ratio of 50% is equivalent to paying half of the quoted

spread. The column MidP corresponds to zero eective spread, i.e., options are traded

at midpoints. The column 100% refers to the case in which traders buy options at

ask and sell at bid. Muravyev and Pearson (2020) show that algorithmic traders who

time executions pay 20% of the spread. As an attempt to reduce the impact of bid-ask

spreads, we also look at a sub-sample with only stocks in the short-leg whose percentage

bid-ask spreads are lower than the median of that month..

Panel B in Table 4 presents the average monthly returns of long-short strategies

under dierent spread ratios. When we use all stocks, the strategy performance is

no longer signicant at the conventional level as early as the 25% spread ratio kicks

in. But when we exclude those stocks with higher-than-median option spreads, the

strategy remains protable with a monthly return of 1.25 and a t-statistic of 2.21 under

the spread ratio of 25%. All strategies incur losses if the entire quoted spread must be

paid. Therefore, reducing transaction cost is essential to maintain the protability of

the strategy.

3.3 Persistence of the Return Predictability

This section checks how long the return predictability persists. We use Naked Put with

lags up to 4 quarters to predict rSkew in Fama-MacBeth regressions including controls.

Table 5 shows that only the one-quarter-lagged Naked Put signicantly predicts

19

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


rSkew with a t-statistic of 2.88. Thus, the predictability only persists for one quarter.

This is consistent with the position-level evidence in Panel C of Table 1 that most of HF

option holdings last for one quarter. The coecients of Naked Put become insignicant

beyond the past quarter but stay positive. This pattern is dierent from the price

pressure eect in the stock market, which is typically followed by a reversal of signs.

The reason is that after the monthly options in skewness asset expire, there cannot be

any price reversal on those contracts. Thus, the price pressure eect in option markets

does not lead to a switch of signs in predicting option returns over dierent horizons.

4 A Price-Pressure Channel

This section proposes a price-pressure channel to explain the predictive power of Naked

Put: When more HFs use naked put on a stock, they create larger demand on the

stock's put options, make them more expensive, and lower the price of the skewness

asset that takes a short position on put option. If naked put positions do not contain

information on future skewness, which closely resembles the payo of skewness asset,

Naked Put will positively predict rSkew .

Section 4.1 conrms that Naked Put is positively related to the buying pressure on

put options and especially the OTM ones. Section 4.2 explores an alternative explana-

tion that HFs use naked put to do risk management rather than speculation. Section

4.3 investigates the determinants of HF option usage at the stock-quarter level. Section

4.4 proposes a potential reason why long call positions do not translate into buying

pressure on call options by looking at how mutual funds trade against HFs in option

markets. Section 4.5 shows that option hedging costs are necessary for HF option usage

to aect option return.

20

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


4.1 Option Demand Pressure

The proxies constructed for dierent option strategies capture the extensive margin of

HF option usage, but not necessarily the intensive margin. In addition, option demand

from HFs may be absorbed by other investors and thus not translate into the net

demand pressure faced by market makers. This section aims to establish the positive

relation between Naked Put and the net buying pressure on put option.

We use the net signed open interest to measure net buying pressure on option.

We use the data from The International Securities Exchange (ISE) Open/Close Trade

Prole, which records the information on signed option volumes of the open/close and

13
buy/sell orders from public customers, broker/dealer, and proprietary traders. Fol-

lowing the literature, we group together the three types of investors, and their aggregate

option demand is the demand pressure faced by market makers. We adopt the method

in Ni, Pearson, Poteshman, and White (2021) to construct the net signed open interest

for option contract j on trading day t, as follows:

OpenInterestBuy Buy OpenBuy


j,t = OpenInterestj,t−1 + V olumej,t − V olumeCloseSell
j,t ,
OpenSell
OpenInterestSell Sell
j,t = OpenInterestj,t−1 + V olumej,t − V olumeCloseBuy
j,t ,

N etOpenInterestj,t = OpenInterestBuy Sell


j,t − OpenInterestj,t .

Then we aggregate put and call options, respectively, into stock-month-level by sum-

ming up all available puts/calls written on the same stock on the third Friday of each

month, in order to align with the time point when we construct skewness asset.

To account for heterogeneous rm sizes, we scale the net signed open interest by

the shares outstanding of the underlying stock. We then use all option positions to

13 Ge, Lin, and Pearson (2016) provide a detailed description of the dataset.

21

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


predict the scaled net open interests of put and call, respectively, in Fama-MacBeth

regressions. The control variables largely follow those in previous exercises, except that

we use the average implied volatility of at-the-money (ATM) options instead of those in

the skewness asset as before, because: (1). The dependent variables aggregate the open

interests of all option contracts; (2). ATM options are most sensitive to volatility. Also

due to reason (1), we use the average percentage bid-ask spread of all options written on

the same stock. To facilitate interpretation, we standardize all independent variables to

have a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of 1. Constrained by the availability of ISE

data, the sample period in this section is from January 2006 to May 2016. To enlarge

sample and be general, we do not restrict to the stocks with enough valid options to

construct rSkew in this section.

Table 6 reports the regression results. To ease visualization, we multiply all de-

pendent variables by 103 and omit the coecients of controls. In Panel A, Naked Put

positively predicts the net buying pressure on put options faced by market makers: In

column (1) without controls, it has a t-statistic of 3.44, and a one-standard-deviation

increase will increase the scaled open interest by 0.00058. After including controls in

column (2), the magnitude drops to 0.000328 while remaining highly signicant with

a t-statistic of 3.37. Therefore, when more HFs use naked put, market makers face a

higher buying pressure on put, which is expected to make put more expensive. An-

other interesting observation is that Naked Put negatively predicts the demand for call

options. This is not surprising given that a higher value of Naked Put reects a more

bearish view of HFs. Some HFs would probably sell calls instead of buying puts. Since

HFs do not report their short positions, we cannot provide direct empirical evidence.

Nevertheless, the negative relation between Naked Put and call option demand will also

lower the price of skewness asset that takes a long position on call.

22

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Protective Put cannot signicantly predict open interests. The signicance of Strad-

dle varies inconsistently depending on whether we include controls. In terms of under-

lying stock value in Panel B of Table 1, Protective Put and Straddle have an average

less than half of Naked Put. Hence, it is not surprising that these two do not create

demand pressure as large as naked put and cannot predict skewness asset return. For

long call positions, it has an average more than twice of naked put. However, when we

predict the open interest of call option in columns (3) and (4), the coecients of Call

are positive but insignicant at the conventional level, suggesting that HF demand for

call options also do not translate into large buying pressure. We will revisit the poten-

tial reason for this nding in depth in later sections. Call negatively predicts the open

interest of put options in columns (1) and (2), suggesting that some HFs may express

their bullish views by selling put. However, the magnitude is much smaller than the

coecient of Naked Put. This may explain why Call cannot robustly predict skewness

asset return.

We further explore the moneyness of options potentially used by HF. The leverage

of OTM options makes them attractive to speculators, and HFs are likely to use OTM

put options to bet on the large downside movement in stock prices. To check this,

we classify option contracts into OTM and other moneyness (at- and in-the-money)

following Bollen and Whaley (2004): The category OTM Put includes put options with

deltas larger than −0.375; The category ATM+ITM Put includes those with deltas

smaller than −0.375; OTM Call includes call options with deltas smaller than 0.375;

ATM+ITM Call includes those with deltas larger than 0.375. Then we compute open

interests by summing up options in each category.

In Panel B of Table 6, we use HF optoin usage to predict the open interests of

dierent moneynesses. In columns (1) and (2), Naked Put positively predict the open

23

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


interest of OTM put with highly signicant t-statistics. However, it loses signicance

when we predict the open interest of ATM and ITM put with controls in column

(4). This evidence suggests that HFs using naked put are particularly interested in

purchasing OTM put options. This demand pattern can aect option return especially

given that OTM put is part of the skewness asset.

In summary, we nd that the measure Naked Put is indeed positively related to the

net buying pressure on put options, especially the OTM ones, faced by market makers,

which is a necessary condition for the price-pressure channel. Other option strategies do

not translate into order imbalances, either because HFs do not use them heavily enough

(such as protective put and straddle) or because option demand of HFs is absorbed by

other investors as in the case for long call positions we will show in later sections.

4.2 Risk Management vs. Speculation

Since the SEC only requires HFs to report long positions but not short positions, this

makes it possible that the long put positions we observe may be used to hedge the

unobservable short positions on put options taken by HFs. In this case, long naked put

positions are used for risk management, instead of speculation, purpose.

If risk management were the main purpose, the size of those long naked put positions

is supposed to be smaller or at most equal to the corresponding short positions. In this

case, the net demand from HFs on put options should be negative, and Naked Put is

expected to negatively predict the open interest of put options. This predicted sign is

in sharp contrast with our ndings in the previous section, which contradicts the risk

management story.

Another possibility is that HFs hedge their option positions by delta or vega and

24

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


the way we compute open interest does not take this into account. To check this, we

compute the delta- (vega-) adjusted open interest: We multiply the open interest of

each option contract by its delta (vega) and then aggregate the adjusted open interest

14
at the stock-month level.

In Panel C of Table 6, we use HF optoin usage to predict the delta- or vega-adjusted

open interests. In columns (1) and (2), Naked Put negatively predict the delta-adjusted

open interest of put option with signicant t-statistics. In columns (5) and (6), Naked

Put signicantly predict the vega-adjusted open interest of put option with a positive

coecient. Since put options have negative delta and positive vega, both evidence

suggest that market makers face a larger buying pressure on put when Naked Put

increases. This contradicts the risk management story that the observed long naked

put positions are used by HFs to hedge some unobservable short positions, and further

corroborates our earlier ndings .

4.3 The Determinants of Hedge Fund Option Usage

This section explores the determinants of HF option usage at the stock-quarter level.

We explain the HF option positions in the next quarter by running quarterly Tobit

regressions, because the dependent variables are censored at 0 and 1. To account for

auto-correlation, we control for the one-quarter-lagged dependent variables. We include

the time-xed eects and cluster standard errors at the quarter level.

Table 7 presents the results. We standardize all independent variables to help com-

parison. The strongest determinant for all option strategies is the rm's log market

capitalization, followed by lag dependent. Other than the two, short interest is the

strongest determinant for Naked Put, suggesting that HFs use naked put as a substi-

14 Delta and vega are taken from OptionMetrics.

25

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


tute for short-selling. In column (1), a one-standard-deviation increase would increase

naked put usage by 0.021. The strongest determinant for Call is turnover, which proxies

for dierence of opinions according to Hong and Stein (1999). In column (2), a one-

standard-deviation increase in turnover would increase long call usage by 0.012, twice of

the coecient of short interest. In comparison, the magnitude of short interest is more

than twice of turnover in column (1). Hence, compared with long naked put position,

it is much more likely that other investors trade against HFs and absorb the buying

pressure from HFs on call options. Dierence of opinions could be a reason why HF

demand for call options do not translate into the net buying pressure faced by market

makers.

4.4 Mutual Fund Option Holdings

Covered call is a popular strategy employed by mutual funds for the purpose of income

generation (Cici and Palacios (2015)). Their short position on call option could neu-

tralize part of the buying pressure from HFs for the call options written on the same

stock. This could also oer an explanation for why the HF demand for call does not

translate into net buying pressure.

To test this possibility, we match the long option positions of HF with the corre-

sponding short option positions of mutual fund at the stock-quarter level. We extract

15
option holdings of mutual funds from a Morningstar dataset. Since the dataset ends

in June 2015, the sample period in this section is from December 2004 to June 2015. An

advantage of the dataset is that mutual funds report the market value of their option

positions: A positive (negative) value means a long (short) position. However, a chal-

lenge is that mutual funds report option holdings in a nonstandard way: First, unlike

15 We thank David Hunter for sharing this dataset. It is used in Hunter (2015).

26

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


stock holdings, most of the option holdings reported do not have common identiers

like CUSIP, making it impossible to directly link option positions with their underlying

stocks. Second, the names of underlying stocks are included in the security name item

for option holdings. However, mutual funds abbreviate the underlying stocks' names in

an arbitrary way, and sometimes they use tickers instead of names, making the match-

ing with underlying stocks dicult. Finally, mutual funds do not report the important

characteristics of option contracts other than whether it is a call or put. It is impossible

to tell the strikes and maturities for most of the option positions.

To extract option holdings, we follow the procedures in Cici and Palacios (2015).

We begin by using the security names of holdings as the main input and identify the

16
observations that contain the Call or Put text strings in the names. Next, we use

visual inspection to remove misclassications because some observations contain the

above text strings but are not option holdings, such as Output and Computer. We

link individual stock option positions with the names of underlying stocks. We use a

name-matching algorithm based on spelling distance to match security names with rm

names. Then we use visual inspections to pick the observations in which mutual funds

report tickers instead of rm names and match those security names with rm tickers.

In the last step, we use visual inspections again to lter out mismatches.

After extracting the option holdings of mutual funds, we match the long option

positions of HFs with the corresponding short option positions of mutual funds at the

stock-quarter level. In Table 8, there are 20, 969 long call positions from HFs at the

fund-quarter-stock level. 5, 151 of them can be matched with at least one mutual fund

taking a short call position on the same underlying stock in the same reporting quarter.

16 Mutual funds can be arbitrary in capitalizations and spelling: In addition to Call, they might
write CALL, call, Calloption, etc. The same is true for put options. We also consider these
variants in the search.

27

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Therefore, 24.56% of long call positions from HFs have mutual funds trading against

them. In comparison, 12.04% of general long put positions from HF correspond to the

short put positions from mutual funds, a proportion only half of that for long call. If

we further zoom into the long naked put positions from HF, only 9.6% of them have

corresponding short put positions from mutual funds.

The above evidence suggests that the liquidity provided by mutual funds that use

covered call may dampen the price pressure from the HFs that long call. In addition

to dierence of opinions, this could be another explanation why HF demand for call

options do not translate into net buying pressure and predict option return.

4.5 Option Hedging Costs

Garleanu, Pedersen, and Poteshman (2008) show that for option demand imbalance to

aect option return, a necessary condition is the frictions for market makers to hedge

their option positions. If the price-pressure channel were true, the long-short portfolio

sorted by Naked Put should be more protable among the subset of stocks whose

options are more dicult to hedge. We use double-sort to test this: Each month we

rst sort stocks into terciles by a proxy for option hedging cost. Then we further form

long-short portfolios based on Naked Put within each tercile. Specically, we long/short

the skewness assets of all stocks with positive/zero Naked Put and value-weight them

by option dollar open interests.

We consider three forms of hedging costs in Garleanu et al. (2008): stochastic

volatility, jump risk, and delta-hedging cost. Following Cao, Vasquez, Xiao, and Zhan

(2023), we measure stochastic volatility by estimating an EGARCH(1,1) model on the

28

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


third Friday each month using rolling-one-year daily stock returns as follows:

2 1
rt = σt zt ; lnσt2 = ω + αrt−1
2 2
+ βlnσt−1 + γ[|zt−1 | − ( ) 2 ],
π

where: rt is the stock return; σt is the conditional volatility; zt is the innovation term.

We set the maximum number of iterations at 500, and 97.3% of cases successfully

converge. After we generate a series of time-varying volatilities for each day in the

estimation window, we calculate the standard deviation of the model-implied volatilities

for each rm every month with successful convergence and use it as the proxy for

stochastic volatility. To measure jump risk, we follow Gao, Gao, and Song (2018) and

use a disaster concern index constructed with OTM puts as follows:

Z
ln(St /K)
Jump Risk = 2 P (K, t, T )dK.
K<St K2

The portfolio assigns larger weights to more deeply OTM puts and thus protects in-

vestors against negative price jumps. The larger the index, the greater the downward

jump risk, which means more risks for market makers who write put options. To ap-

proximate the continuous integral, we follow the procedure in Carr and Wu (2009) by

extrapolating the strike range to −5 standard deviations from the current stock price

and generating a ne grid of 500 implied volatility points. Then we transform implied

volatilities into option prices via Black-Scholes formula. To nd a proxy for delta-

hedging cost, we follow Boulatov, Eisdorfer, Goyal, and Zhdanov (2022) and use the

average daily stock bid-ask spread in the previous month.

Table 9 presents the returns (in percentage) of the double-sorted portfolios. For all

three hedging costs, the returns are low and insignicant among the subset of stocks

29

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


with the lowest costs. In contrast, when the costs become the highest, the prots

are the largest in magnitude and highly signicant. The pattern is consistent with the

price-pressure channel in which Naked Put aects option return because market makers

charge a higher price as a compensation for bearing inventory risk when they write put

options to HFs.

5 Other Empirical Tests

The previous section presents evidence that HF usage of long naked put could lead to

net buying pressure on put options. We hypothesize that this demand pressure will

make put more expensive and lower the risk-neutral skewness, which resembles the

price of skewness asset. Section 4.1 tests this hypothesis using an alternative skewness

asset in OST and also investigates the informed-trading channel. Section 4.2 constructs

the risk-neutral skewness following BKM as a robustness check and decomposes it into

systematic and idiosyncratic components. Section 4.3 examines whether our result is

related to variance risk premium.

5.1 Price Pressure vs. Informed Trading

In a price-pressure channel, HF naked put usage negatively predicts risk-neutral skew-

ness and positively predicts skewness asset return. While in an informed-trading chan-

nel, it negatively predicts both the future realized skewness and the skewness asset re-

turn, if the crash-timing skill of HFs were strong enough to outweigh the price-pressure.

To test the two channels, we construct an alternative skewness asset following OST

because it has the following advantages: First, OST dene realized skewness in such a

way that it is tradeable as the payo of a model-free portfolio of options and stocks.

30

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Therefore, the risk-neutral and realized skewness are internally consistent, which oers

a clean economic interpretation; Second, we pick as the payo the jump component of

skewness in OST dened as:

T
Realized, OST
X rt2
Skew = (ert − rt − 1 − ), (1)
t=1
2

3
17
PT
which equals t=1 ( r3! + o(rt4 )) based on Taylor expansion. This conceptual frame-

work enables us to separate jump eect from leverage eect and better tease out volatil-

ity from higher moment; Third, this asset involves a daily rebalancing position of stock

and option to replicate the dened jump skewness as payo. This strengthens the close

resemblance between the price (payo ) of skewness asset and the risk-neutral (realized)

skewness.

The price of the portfolio that can generate the payo in Equation 1 equals:

Z ∞
Implied, OST ln(K/F0 )
Skew = O(K, t, T )dK, (2)
0 K2

where F0 is the forward price at formation day; O(K, t, T ) is the price of an OTM

option. We apply to individual stocks the option lters (1)-(5) in Section 2.2, and then

follow Carr and Wu (2009) in computing the price in Equation (2): We extrapolate

the strike range to ±5 standard deviations from the current stock price, generate a ne

grid of 1000 implied volatility points, and then transform implied volatilities into option
18
prices via Black-Scholes formula.

17 r is the daily log stock return and T is the option expiration date.
t
18 The standard deviation is approximated by the average implied volatility of OTM options. Before
we do the extrapolation, we require a stock-month to have at least three valid options after applying
the option lters, with at least one OTM put and one OTM call.

31

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


The return of this asset is dened as:

SkewRealized, OST − SkewImplied, OST


rSkew, OST = . (3)
|SkewImplied, OST |

19
There exists extreme outlier due to very small denominator. The estimation of higher

moments using individual stock options could be sensitive to microstructure noise. To

make the empirical test more reliable, we trim observations with |SkewImplied, OST | at

the bottom 5% of each month. Since the option-implied skewness is known at the

formation day, we do not use forward-looking information here.

We use Naked Put to predict cross-sectional rSkew, OST , the price and payo of

skewness asset, respectively. Control variables largely follow those in Table 3. The

asset is dierent from that in Bali and Murray (2013) in that it includes all OTM

options. Therefore, we use as controls the average implied volatility of ATM put and

call as it is the most sensitive to volatility, and the average percentage bid-ask spread

of all OTM options as this better reect the liquidity of this asset.

Table 10 presents the result. In columns (1) and (2), Naked Put positively pre-

dicts the return with highly signicant t-statistics, consistent with the sign in Table 3.

Thus, the positive predictive power of Naked Put is robust to dierent constructions of

skewness asset and supports the price-pressure channel. Next, to dissect the return pre-

dictability, we decompose the return into price and payo, and use them as dependent

variables. In columns (3) and (4), Naked Put negatively predicts risk-neutral skewness,

which is the price of asset. Again, this is consistent with the prediction of price-pressure

channel. When we predict future skewness, the payo of asset, in columns (5) and (6),

Naked Put has negative signs. However, the coecients are insignicant at the conven-

19 The smallest absolute risk-neutral skewness is at the order of 10−8 . When we scale realized
skewness by this number, option return blows up.

32

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


tional level, and there is very limited evidence supporting the informed-trading channel.

In summary, we nd that HF naked put usage lowers risk-neutral skewness, fails

to predict future skewness, and positively predicts the return of skewness asset. These

evidence combined lends support to the price-pressure channel and contradicts the

informed-trading channel.

5.2 Systematic vs. Idiosyncratic Skewness

As a robustness check for the negative predictability of risk-neutral skewness, we con-

20
struct the risk-neutral skewness following BKM. In addition, we follow BKM and

decompose the skewness into systematic and idiosyncratic components. Intuitively,

HFs use individual stock options to exploit the idiosyncratic component of stock price

movements. If so, naked put usage is expected to lower the idiosyncratic but not the

systematic component.

On the third Friday of each month, we construct the risk-neutral skewness, SkewImplied, T otal ,

using Equation (5) in BKM. BKM assume that risk-neutral stock return process follows

a one-factor market-model:

ri,t = ai + βRN,i rm,t + ϵi,t ,

where ri,t and rm,t are the excess returns of the stock and the market portfolio, respec-

3
20 BKM dene risk-neutral skewness based on the scaled skewness measure: E[(rt −Ert ) ]
. The
E[(rt −Ert )2 ]3/2
option portfolio is nonlinear and nontradeable, and hence does not allow a return decomposition into
risk-neutral and realized skewness as in the previous section. In addition, this measure of realized
skewness can be heavily inuenced by the leverage eect as shown in Neuberger (2012).

33

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


tively; βRN,i is the risk-neutral beta. The systematic skewness of stock i is as follows:

3 3
βRN,i σm
SkewiImplied, Sys. = Implied
Skewm ,
σi3

Implied
where Skewm is the risk-neutral skewness of the S&P 500 Index. The square of σi

(σm ) is the risk-neutral variance of stock i (the S&P 500 Index) constructed following

Equation (7) in BKM. To estimate βRN,i , we use the methodology in French, Groth, and

Kolari (1983). It incorporates the information in options and is more appropriate than

a rolling-based historical measure for this exercise. We dene idiosyncratic skewness as

the dierence between the total and systematic skewness:

SkewiImplied, Idio. = SkewiImplied, T otal − SkewiImplied, Sys. .

We use Naked Put to predict the three types of skewness in monthly Fama-MacBeth

regressions and standardize all independent variables. Table 11 reports the result.

In column (1) and (2), Naked Put negatively predicts SkewImplied, T otal with highly

signicant t-statistics. The negative sign is consistent with that in columns (3) and (4)

of Table 10, and is robust to alternative constructions of risk-neutral skewness. After

decomposition, we nd that Naked Put negatively predicts SkewImplied, Idio. in columns

(3) and (4) but positively predicts SkewImplied, Sys. in columns (5) and (6), suggesting

that the negative predictability of risk-neutral skewness comes from the desire of HF

for exposure to the idiosyncratic rather than systematic component of stock return.

This is consistent with the empirical ndings in Boyer, Mitton, and Vorkink (2010) and

Boyer and Vorkink (2014) that idiosyncratic skewness is priced.

34

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


5.3 Variance Risk Premium

Kozhan, Neuberger, and Schneider (2013) nd that skewness risk is closely related to

variance risk at the aggregate market level. This section investigates the possibility

that HF naked put usage aects skewness premium via its inuence on variance risk

premium (VRP). We follow Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009) and dene VRP

as the dierence between implied and realized variance. On the third Friday of each

month, we estimate realized variance using the high-frequency 15-minutes-interval stock

returns in the previous month, and construct a model-free implied variance using the

Volatility Surface database.

We use Naked Put and VRP to predict the cross-sectional return of skewness asset

in Bali and Murray (2013). Table 12 presents the result. Without controls in column

(2), VRP signicantly predicts return. When we include both of them in column (3)

without controls, Naked Put still positively predicts return and its coecient is very

similar to that in column (1). When we include controls in column (4), VRP becomes

insignicant while Naked Put remains highly signicant. The above evidence suggests

that VRP cannot explain the predictive power of naked put usage on skewness premium.

6 Conclusion

While nance literature attempts to estimate skewness risk premium in various ways,

no one explores the role of HFs in pricing skewness risk. According to the rich literature

studying how HFs exploit tail risk, they are supposed to be pivotal. This paper lls the

gap by examining how HF option usage can aect skewness premium. Specically, we

nd that naked put usage positively predicts cross-sectional return of skewness asset.

This predictability is robust to the inclusion of a battery of control variables and to

35

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


alternative constructions of skewness asset. A long-short strategy generates a monthly

return of 1.53% and an annual Sharpe ratio of 0.68. The protability of this strategy

survives reasonable option bid-ask spreads.

To understand the underlying economic mechanism, we document evidence consis-

tent with a price-pressure channel: (1).Stocks with more HFs employing naked put

on them face larger buying pressure on their put options, especially the OTM ones;

(2).Those stocks tend to have more negative risk-neutral skewness, which corresponds

to a lower price of skewness asset. (3).Naked put usage cannot predict future skewness,

which resembles the payo of skewness asset; (4).Option hedging costs are necessary

for HF naked put usage to aect option return.

After we decompose risk-neutral skewness into the systematic and idiosyncratic

components, we nd that the price pressure from naked put positions mainly exerts

on the idiosyncratic but not systematic component. The nding suggests that the

desire for exposures to idiosyncratic downward stock movements motivates HFs to long

naked put, which makes put options overpriced and then aects the skewness premium

embedded in options. This is consistent with the empirical ndings in the literature that

idiosyncratic skewness is priced and carries a negative expected return. Our nding also

complements the HF literature that typically focuses on the exposure to the market-

level tail risk.

We nd that the usage of other option strategies fails to predict skewness asset

return and do not translate into net buying pressure faced by option market makers.

To explore the reason, we show that HFs do not use protective put and straddle as

heavily as they do for naked put and long call in terms of underlying stock value. For

long call strategy, HFs tend to use it on stocks with large dierence of opinions, which

raises the possibility that other investors trade against them and absorb their buying

36

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


pressure. In addition, we nd that the popularity of covered call strategy among mutual

funds partially counteracts the demand of HFs on call options.

37

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


References

Agarwal, V., G. Bakshi, and J. Huij, 2009, Do higher-moment equity risks explain hedge fund re-

turns?, Robert H. Smith school research paper no. RHS, pp. 06153.

Agarwal, V., W. Jiang, Y. Tang, and B. Yang, 2013, Uncovering hedge fund skill from the portfolio

holdings they hide, The Journal of Finance, 68(2), 739783.

Agarwal, V., S. Ruenzi, and F. Weigert, 2017, Tail risk in hedge funds: A unique view from portfolio

holdings, Journal of Financial Economics, 125(3), 610636.

Amaya, D., P. Christoersen, K. Jacobs, and A. Vasquez, 2015, Does realized skewness predict the

cross-section of equity returns?, Journal of Financial Economics, 118(1), 135167.

Amihud, Y., 2002, Illiquidity and stock returns: cross-section and time-series eects, Journal of
nancial markets, 5(1), 3156.

Ang, A., R. J. Hodrick, Y. Xing, and X. Zhang, 2006, The cross-section of volatility and expected

returns, The journal of nance, 61(1), 259299.

Aragon, G. O., S. Chen, and Z. Shi, 2022, Volatility Timing Using ETF Options: Evidence from

Hedge Funds, Available at SSRN 4246146.

Aragon, G. O., and J. S. Martin, 2012, A unique view of hedge fund derivatives usage: Safeguard or

speculation?, Journal of Financial Economics, 105(2), 436456.

Bakshi, G., N. Kapadia, and D. Madan, 2003, Stock return characteristics, skew laws, and the dier-

ential pricing of individual equity options, The Review of Financial Studies, 16(1), 101143.

Bali, T. G., S. J. Brown, and M. O. Caglayan, 2012, Systematic risk and the cross section of hedge

fund returns, Journal of Financial Economics, 106(1), 114131.

Bali, T. G., N. Cakici, and R. F. Whitelaw, 2011, Maxing out: Stocks as lotteries and the cross-section

of expected returns, Journal of nancial economics, 99(2), 427446.

Bali, T. G., and S. Murray, 2013, Does risk-neutral skewness predict the cross-section of equity option

portfolio returns?, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 48(4), 11451171.

38

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Barberis, N., and M. Huang, 2008, Stocks as lotteries: The implications of probability weighting for

security prices, American Economic Review, 98(5), 20662100.

Bollen, N. P., and R. E. Whaley, 2004, Does net buying pressure aect the shape of implied volatility

functions?, The Journal of Finance, 59(2), 711753.

Bollerslev, T., G. Tauchen, and H. Zhou, 2009, Expected stock returns and variance risk premia,

The Review of Financial Studies, 22(11), 44634492.

Boulatov, A., A. Eisdorfer, A. Goyal, and A. Zhdanov, 2022, Limited attention and option prices,

Swiss Finance Institute Research Paper, (20-64).

Boyer, B., T. Mitton, and K. Vorkink, 2010, Expected idiosyncratic skewness, The Review of Finan-
cial Studies, 23(1), 169202.

Boyer, B. H., and K. Vorkink, 2014, Stock options as lotteries, The Journal of Finance, 69(4),

14851527.

Brunnermeier, M. K., C. Gollier, and J. A. Parker, 2007, Optimal beliefs, asset prices, and the

preference for skewed returns, American Economic Review, 97(2), 159165.

Cao, J. J., A. Vasquez, X. Xiao, and X. E. Zhan, 2023, Why Does Volatility Uncertainty Predict

Equity Option Returns?, The Quarterly Journal of Finance, 13(01), 2350005.

Carr, P., and L. Wu, 2009, Variance risk premiums, The Review of Financial Studies, 22(3), 1311

1341.

Chang, B. Y., P. Christoersen, and K. Jacobs, 2013, Market skewness risk and the cross section of

stock returns, Journal of Financial Economics, 107(1), 4668.

Cici, G., and L.-F. Palacios, 2015, On the use of options by mutual funds: Do they know what they

are doing?, Journal of Banking & Finance, 50, 157168.

Conrad, J., R. F. Dittmar, and E. Ghysels, 2013, Ex ante skewness and expected stock returns, The
Journal of Finance, 68(1), 85124.

39

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Fama, E. F., and K. R. French, 1992, The cross-section of expected stock returns, the Journal of
Finance, 47(2), 427465.

, 2015, A ve-factor asset pricing model, Journal of nancial economics, 116(1), 122.

Fama, E. F., and J. D. MacBeth, 1973, Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests, Journal of
political economy, 81(3), 607636.

Frazzini, A., and L. H. Pedersen, 2022, Embedded leverage, The Review of Asset Pricing Studies,
12(1), 152.

French, D. W., J. C. Groth, and J. W. Kolari, 1983, Current investor expectations and better betas,

The Journal of Portfolio Management, 10(1), 1217.

Gao, G. P., P. Gao, and Z. Song, 2018, Do hedge funds exploit rare disaster concerns?, The Review
of Financial Studies, 31(7), 26502692.

Garleanu, N., L. H. Pedersen, and A. M. Poteshman, 2008, Demand-based option pricing, The Review
of Financial Studies, 22(10), 42594299.

Ge, L., T.-C. Lin, and N. D. Pearson, 2016, Why does the option to stock volume ratio predict stock

returns?, Journal of Financial Economics, 120(3), 601622.

Goyal, A., and A. Saretto, 2009, Cross-section of option returns and volatility, Journal of Financial
Economics, 94(2), 310326.

Harvey, C. R., and A. Siddique, 2000, Conditional skewness in asset pricing tests, The Journal of
nance, 55(3), 12631295.

Hong, H., and J. C. Stein, 1999, Dierences of opinion, rational arbitrage and market crashes, .

Hunter, D. L., 2015, Mind the Gap: The Portfolio Eects of 'Other' Holdings, Asian Finance Asso-
ciation (AsianFA) 2015 Conference Paper, Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2565274
or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2565274.

Jegadeesh, N., and S. Titman, 1993, Returns to buying winners and selling losers: Implications for

stock market eciency, The Journal of nance, 48(1), 6591.

40

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Joenväärä, J., M. Kaupila, R. Kosowski, and P. Tolonen, 2021, Hedge fund performance: Are stylized

facts sensitive to which database one uses?, Critical Finance Review, 10, 170.

Kaniel, R., and P. Wang, 2022, Unmasking mutual fund derivative use, Available at SSRN 3692838.

Kelly, B. T., and H. Jiang, 2012, Tail risk and hedge fund returns, Chicago Booth Research Paper,
(12-44).

Kozhan, R., A. Neuberger, and P. Schneider, 2013, The skew risk premium in the equity index market,

The Review of Financial Studies, 26(9), 21742203.

Kraus, A., and R. H. Litzenberger, 1976, Skewness preference and the valuation of risk assets, The
Journal of nance, 31(4), 10851100.

Langlois, H., 2020, Measuring skewness premia, Journal of Financial Economics, 135(2), 399424.

Mitton, T., and K. Vorkink, 2007, Equilibrium underdiversication and the preference for skewness,

The Review of Financial Studies, 20(4), 12551288.

Muravyev, D., 2016, Order ow and expected option returns, The Journal of Finance, 71(2), 673708.

Muravyev, D., and N. D. Pearson, 2020, Options trading costs are lower than you think, The Review
of Financial Studies, 33(11), 49735014.

Neuberger, A., 2012, Realized skewness, The Review of Financial Studies, 25(11), 34233455.

Newey, W. K., and K. D. West, 1986, A simple, positive semi-denite, heteroskedasticity and auto-

correlationconsistent covariance matrix, .

Ni, S. X., N. D. Pearson, A. M. Poteshman, and J. White, 2021, Does option trading have a pervasive

impact on underlying stock prices?, The Review of Financial Studies, 34(4), 19521986.

Orªowski, P., P. Schneider, and F. Trojani, 2023, On the nature of (jump) skewness risk premia,

Management Science.

Pederzoli, P., 2017, Crash risk in individual stocks, Available at SSRN 2862372.

41

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Rubinstein, M. E., 1973, The fundamental theorem of parameter-preference security valuation, Jour-
nal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 8(1), 6169.

Schneider, P., and F. Trojani, 2019, Divergence and the Price of Uncertainty, Journal of Financial
Econometrics, 17(3), 341396.

42

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Figure 1: Number of Stocks with Positive Hedge Fund Option Demand

This gure plots the number of stocks in each month with positive HF option usage for four types
of option strategies (Naked Put, Protective Put, Straddle, and Call), respectively, after we match
monthly skewness asset return of each stock with its HF option usage in the previous quarter. The
sample is from April 2001 to December 2020.

Number of US Common Stocks with Hedge Fund Option Demand


Naked Put
Protective Put
Straddle
400
Call

300

200

100

0
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021

43

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Figure 2: Performance of the Long-Short Portfolio Sorted by Naked Put

The gure plots the rolling-ve-year performance of the long-short (L/S) portfolio sorted by Naked
Put. The upper panel plots the rolling-average monthly return (in percentage). The lower panel plots
the rolling annualized Sharpe ratio.

Plot 1. 60-Month Moving Average Returns of the L/S Portfolio of Skewness Assets Sorted by Hedge Fund Naked Put Demand
2.5

2.0

1.5
%

1.0

0.5
Plot 2. 60-Month Moving Sharpe Ratios of the L/S Portfolio of Skewness Assets Sorted by Hedge Fund Naked Put Demand
0.9
0.8
0.7
Annual

0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020

44

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Table 1: Summary Statistics: Option Positions

This table reports the summary statistics of hedge fund holdings from December 2004 to September
2020: Panel A presents the fraction of option holdings per hedge fund portfolio and reporting quarter,
conditioning on that a fund reported at least one option holding. There are 22, 556 portfolios at the
fund-quarter level, and 5, 110 of them contain at least one option holding. Number of Positions is the
total number of rms on which a fund holds stocks or options. Option Fraction is the fraction of rms
on which a fund holds options. For example, if a fund discloses 10 dierent rms in its portfolio and
holds options on 2 of them, Option Fraction equals 0.2. (%) means that a variable is in percentage.
Panel B reports the market value (in millions of dollars) of the stocks underlying the option contracts
per fund portfolio and quarter, conditioning on that a fund reported at least one option holding.
Panel C reports the number of quarters an option position lasts. For example, a fund used options on
Tesla in March and June of 2020. It didn't use naked put on Tesla in September, but started to use it
in December 2020 again. Then we have 2 observations: One is the naked put in March and June, and
it equals 2 because it lasts for 2 quarters; The other observation is the naked put in December, and it
equals 1 because it only lasts for 1 quarter.

Panel A: Fraction of options per fund portfolio and report date (N = 5110).
Mean StdDev P1 P10 Median P90 P99
Number of Positions 119.43 239.09 3 12 46 271 1418
Option Fraction (%) 16.61 18.65 0.16 1.41 9.52 42.86 83.33
Call Fraction (%) 8.72 12.22 0 0 4.50 22.22 58.82
Put Fraction (%) 7.89 13.79 0 0 2.50 24.07 66.67
Naked Put Fraction (%) 5.25 11.43 0 0 0.64 14.89 57.14
Protective Put Fraction (%) 1.39 4.19 0 0 0 4.12 20.00
Straddle Fraction (%) 1.25 5.48 0 0 0 2.33 26.20

Panel B: `Market value' of options per fund portfolio and report date.

Mean StdDev P1 P10 Median P90 P99


Option 98.31 249.18 0.003 0.21 19.42 251.47 1153.34
Call 57.12 185.96 0 0 5.81 140.27 682.66
Put 41.18 151.14 0 0 1.62 96.39 591.12
Naked Put 23.42 75.02 0 0 0.04 57.81 364.29
Protective Put 9.50 95.85 0 0 0 12.80 127.54
Straddle 8.27 81.62 0 0 0 2.16 160.55

Panel C: The number of quarters option positions last.

Mean StdDev P1 P10 Median P90 P99


Option 2.07 2.24 1 1 1 4 12
Call 1.52 1.23 1 1 1 3 6
Put 2.14 2.32 1 1 1 4 12
Naked Put 1.46 1.15 1 1 1 3 6
Protective Put 1.41 1.07 1 1 1 2 6
Straddle 2.37 2.60 1 1 1 5 13

45

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Table 2: Summary Statistics

This table reports the summary statistics: rSkew is the monthly return of the skewness asset in Bali
and Murray (2013); Number of Holders is the total number of hedge funds that hold the stock or its
options. Other variables are the proportions of hedge funds disclosing a certain type of option strategy
on the rm, dened as the number of funds using the strategy divided by the total number of funds
holding the stock or its option. We match rSkew with its option variables in the past quarter. We
classify 6 option strategies: (1).`Option' means either long put or call; (2).`Call' means only long call
but without put; (3).`Put' means long put. Fund may also long call in this case; (4).`Naked Put'
means long put without the underlying stock and call; (5).`Protective Put' means long put and the
underlying stock, without call; (6).`Straddle' means long both put and call. Sample is from January
2005 to December 2020.

Observation Mean StdDev P1 P10 Median P90 P99


rSkew 145067 -0.0077 0.1633 -0.4618 -0.1163 -0.0053 0.1099 0.3127
Number of Holders 145067 28 20 4 10 23 52 101
Option 145067 0.0296 0.0461 0 0 0 0.0833 0.2000
Call 145067 0.0113 0.0272 0 0 0 0.0417 0.1250
Put 145067 0.0184 0.0351 0 0 0 0.0571 0.1538
Naked Put 145067 0.0059 0.0219 0 0 0 0.0204 0.1000
Protective Put 145067 0.0036 0.0143 0 0 0 0 0.0667
Straddle 145067 0.0089 0.0212 0 0 0 0.0333 0.0909

46

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Table 3: Predict cross-sectional skewness asset returns
We run the monthly Fama-MacBeth regression:
Skew
ri,t+1 = αt + γt · Hedge F und Option U sei,t + θt · Controlsi,t + ϵi,t+1 ,
Skew
where: ri,t+1 is rm i's skewness asset return in month t + 1. Hedge F und Option U sei,t is the latest
available proportion of hedge funds disclosing a certain type of option position on rm i. Control
variables include: average implied volatilities and percentage bid-ask spreads of options in the skewness
asset; short interest of the stock; realized skewness of daily log stock returns in the past month;
daily average turnover in the past month; the maximum stock return in the past month; market beta
estimated using rolling-1-year daily stock return; logarithm of market cap; logarithm of book-to-market
ratio; idiosyncratic volatility of Fama-French 3 factors in past month (IVOL); past month stock return
(RETt−1,t ); stock momentum (RETt−12,t−1 ); Amihud illiquidity measure; rm leverage. T statistics
are Newey-West adjusted with 3 lags. Sample is from January 2005 to December 2020.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)


Option 0.052 0.029
(3.87) (2.42)
Call 0.050 0.046 0.044 0.041
(2.34) (1.94) (2.04) (1.72)
Put 0.059 0.025
(3.04) (1.64)
Naked Put 0.150 0.097
(4.38) (2.86)
Protective Put 0.008 -0.012
(0.26) (-0.37)
Straddle 0.078 -0.015
(0.72) (-0.48)
Implied Volatility 0.029 0.029 0.030
(4.12) (4.11) (4.20)
Option BA Spread -0.000 -0.000 -0.001
(-0.16) (-0.17) (-0.34)
Short Interest 0.047 0.047 0.047
(4.51) (4.37) (4.37)
Lag Skew -0.001 -0.001 -0.001
(-2.09) (-2.10) (-2.04)
Turnover -0.169 -0.170 -0.163
(-2.32) (-2.31) (-2.19)
Max. Stock Return 0.007 0.009 0.006
(0.23) (0.32) (0.22)
β -0.006 -0.006 -0.006
(-3.04) (-3.06) (-3.05)
log(ME) 0.001 0.001 0.001
(2.47) (2.36) (2.46)
log(B/M) 0.000 0.000 0.000
(0.44) (0.24) (0.35)
IVOL -0.047 -0.049 -0.042
(-0.38) (-0.41) (-0.35)
RETt−1,t 0.029 0.029 0.030
(3.91) (3.92) (4.03)
RETt−12,t−1 0.002 0.002 0.001
(0.64) (0.65) (0.59)
Amihud 0.721 0.708 0.684
(3.11) (2.99) (2.89)
Leverage -0.005 -0.005 -0.006
(-0.94) (-0.92) (-1.02)
Intercept -0.009 -0.043 -0.009 -0.042 -0.008 -0.042
(-1.92) (-2.64) (-1.92) (-2.56) (-1.84) (-2.63)
Observation 145067 130191 145067 130191 145067 130191
Adjusted R2 0.002 0.039 47 0.004 0.041 0.008 0.043

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Table 4: Strategy performance and transaction costs

This table reports the monthly average returns of long-short strategies. In Panel A, the Long portfolio
includes rms in the top decile sorted by the variable `Naked Put'. We also require those rms to have
positive Naked Put. The Short portfolio includes all rms with Naked Put equal to 0. We weight rms
by the dollar open interests of their options. We adjust alpha for the Fama and French ve factors,
stock momentum, the S&P 500 Index skewness return in excess of the risk-free rate, and the average
skewness return across all rms weighted by their open interests.
In Panel B, we compare the long-short strategy returns computed from the midpoint price (MidP)
with those computed from the eective bid-ask spread, estimated to be 25%, 50%, 75%, and 100%
of the quoted spread. To lower the impact of option bid-ask spread, we also compute returns using
only rms in the short-leg whose percentage bid-ask spreads are lower than the median of that month.
T -statistics are in parentheses. The sample period is from January 2005 to December 2020.

Panel A: Long-short portfolios.

Long Short Long - Short


Return (%) 0.79 -0.74 1.53
(1.26) (-1.55) (2.73)
Alpha (%) 1.08 -0.34 1.42
(2.72) (-2.76) (2.81)
Standard Deviation (%) 8.71 6.61 7.75
Annual Sharpe Ratio 0.31 -0.39 0.68
Skewness 2.24 -9.58 5.60
Kurtosis 43.68 114.46 46.80
Minimum (%) -59.18 -80.80 -8.83

Panel B: Option bid-ask (BA) spread.

MidP 25% 50% 75% 100%


All Firms:

Return (%) 1.53 0.94 0.35 -0.24 -0.83


(2.73) (1.68) (0.62) (-0.43) (-1.47)
Alpha (%) 1.42 0.85 0.27 -0.30 -0.88
(2.81) (1.68) (0.54) (-0.60) (-1.74)

Firms with low BA spread:

Return (%) 1.68 1.25 0.82 0.38 -0.06


(2.98) (2.21) (1.44) (0.67) (-0.10)
Alpha (%) 1.59 1.17 0.75 0.32 -0.11
(3.18) (2.34) (1.49) (0.64) (-0.23)

48

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Table 5: Persistence of skewness asset return predictability

We use the naked put positions of hedge funds, lagged from 1 to 4 quarters, to predict skewness asset
returns in Fama-MacBeth regressions. T statistics are Newey-West adjusted with 3 lags. Sample is
from January 2005 to December 2020.

(1) (2) (3) (4)


N aked P ut−1 0.095
(2.88)

N aked P ut−2 0.034


(1.41)

N aked P ut−3 0.052


(1.63)

N aked P ut−4 0.040


(1.33)

Implied Volatility 0.030 0.030 0.029 0.030


(4.23) (4.27) (4.21) (4.27)
Option BA Spread -0.000 -0.001 -0.001 -0.001
(-0.23) (-0.41) (-0.56) (-0.41)
Short Interest 0.045 0.050 0.051 0.052
(4.48) (4.85) (4.94) (4.83)
Lag Skew -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 -0.001
(-2.05) (-1.98) (-1.97) (-1.88)
Turnover -0.160 -0.164 -0.173 -0.175
(-2.12) (-2.16) (-2.28) (-2.36)
Max. Stock Return 0.006 0.008 0.006 0.003
(0.20) (0.28) (0.20) (0.10)
β -0.006 -0.006 -0.006 -0.006
(-3.06) (-3.03) (-2.89) (-2.90)
log(ME) 0.001 0.002 0.002 0.002
(2.62) (2.87) (2.79) (2.76)
log(B/M) 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
(0.42) (0.48) (0.53) (0.68)
IVOL -0.047 -0.052 -0.039 -0.029
(-0.37) (-0.42) (-0.30) (-0.23)
RETt−1,t 0.029 0.028 0.029 0.028
(3.95) (3.65) (3.67) (3.54)
RETt−12,t−1 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001
(0.58) (0.56) (0.50) (0.48)
Amihud 0.750 0.746 0.728 0.730
(3.17) (3.18) (3.10) (3.01)
Leverage -0.005 -0.005 -0.005 -0.005
(-0.95) (-0.84) (-0.91) (-0.92)
Intercept -0.044 -0.047 -0.047 -0.047
(-2.73) (-2.93) (-2.87) (-2.81)

Observation 130191 130072 129803 129304


Adjusted R2 0.039 0.038 0.039 0.039

49

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Table 6: Net signed option open interest
This table reports the results of monthly Fama-MacBeth regressions. The dependent variable is a
rm's net signed open interest of put (call), scaled by its shares outstanding and then multiplied by
103 , on the third Friday of each month. In Panel B, we classify option contracts into OTM (out-of-
the-money) and ATM+ITM (at- and in-the-money). In Panel C, we multiply open interest by the
delta and vega, respectively. All independent variables are standardized. T-statistics, in parentheses,
are computed using the Newey-West standard errors with three lags. Constrained by the availability
of the ISE data, the sample begins in January 2006 and ends in May 2016.

Panel A: Open interest.

Put Call

(1) (2) (3) (4)


Naked Put 0.580 0.328 -0.609 -0.439
(3.44) (3.37) (-5.21) (-3.60)
Call -0.106 -0.155 0.137 0.136
(-2.00) (-2.55) (1.72) (1.72)
Protective Put 0.201 0.161 -0.165 -0.125
(1.56) (1.60) (-1.64) (-1.43)
Straddle -0.091 -0.188 -0.264 -0.107
(-1.23) (-2.13) (-3.20) (-1.21)
Controls No Yes No Yes
Observation 135516 119727 135516 119727
Adjusted R2 0.020 0.058 0.017 0.056

Panel B: Open interest by moneynesses.

Put Call

OTM ATM+ITM OTM ATM+ITM

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)


Naked Put 0.301 0.227 0.279 0.101 -0.249 -0.186 -0.360 -0.253
(2.79) (2.91) (3.39) (1.47) (-2.93) (-1.95) (-4.59) (-3.80)
Call -0.027 -0.049 -0.078 -0.106 -0.000 0.058 0.137 0.078
(-0.65) (-1.02) (-2.62) (-3.07) (-0.00) (0.77) (1.87) (1.07)
Protective Put 0.125 0.126 0.076 0.035 -0.115 -0.077 -0.050 -0.048
(1.43) (1.81) (1.21) (0.64) (-1.74) (-1.33) (-0.90) (-0.92)
Straddle -0.048 -0.042 -0.044 -0.147 -0.193 -0.051 -0.071 -0.056
(-0.72) (-0.54) (-0.86) (-3.00) (-3.34) (-0.75) (-1.25) (-1.04)
Controls No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes
Observation 135516 119727 135516 119727 135516 119727 135516 119727
Adjusted R2 0.017 0.048 0.018 0.058 0.017 0.049 0.014 0.048

Panel C: Weighted by delta and vega.

Delta-adjusted Vega-adjuested

Put Call Put Call

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)


Naked Put -0.203 -0.095 -0.264 -0.186 2.835 2.248 -3.951 -2.688
(-3.05) (-2.17) (-5.18) (-4.11) (2.44) (2.61) (-4.46) (-3.54)
Call 0.046 0.069 0.058 0.036 -0.432 -0.600 -0.790 -0.219
(1.99) (3.09) (1.27) (0.79) (-1.21) (-1.67) (-1.33) (-0.33)
Protective Put -0.094 -0.059 -0.066 -0.059 0.397 0.441 -1.689 -0.695
(-1.85) (-1.42) (-1.63) (-1.57) (0.84) (1.11) (-2.63) (-1.52)
Straddle 0.054 0.096 -0.087 -0.056 -0.404 -0.000 -3.517 -0.780
(1.96) (3.45) (-2.18)
50(-1.46) (-0.68) (-0.00) (-3.26) (-0.81)
Controls No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes
Observation 135516 119727 135516 119727 135516 119727 135516 119727
Adjusted R2 0.021 0.059 0.015 0.054 0.008 0.024 0.008 0.025
Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419
Table 7: Explain hedge fund option usage

We run the quarterly Tobit regression:

Hedge F und Option U sei,t+1 = α + θ · V ariablesi,t + ϵi,t+1 .

Dependent variables are left censored at 0 and right censored at 1. We include quarter-xed eects and
cluster standard errors at the quarter level. We control for the lagged-one-quarter dependent variable.
Independent variables are standardized and winsorized at 1% level. Sample is from December 2004 to
September 2020.

(1) (2) (3) (4)


Naked Put Call Protective Put Straddle
Short Interest 0.021 0.006 0.010 0.008
(26.79) (11.30) (9.97) (12.54)
Turnover 0.008 0.012 0.007 0.011
(9.59) (16.20) (8.16) (15.31)
log(ME) 0.054 0.048 0.053 0.044
(41.93) (33.63) (39.45) (36.55)
Implied Volatility 0.012 0.011 0.009 0.004
(8.51) (8.87) (5.11) (3.03)
RETt−1,t 0.002 0.003 -0.003 0.003
(1.95) (4.25) (-2.08) (5.84)
RETt−12,t−1 0.006 -0.004 -0.002 -0.001
(6.02) (-5.23) (-1.70) (-2.00)
IVOL -0.000 0.005 0.004 0.004
(-0.09) (4.40) (3.13) (5.20)
Max. Stock Return 0.000 -0.002 -0.001 -0.002
(0.09) (-1.72) (-0.87) (-1.92)
β -0.000 -0.000 -0.000 0.001
(-0.68) (-0.73) (-0.35) (0.67)
log(B/M) -0.000 -0.000 -0.000 0.000
(-0.41) (-0.87) (-0.62) (0.78)
Leverage 0.002 0.000 -0.002 -0.000
(1.70) (0.60) (-2.38) (-0.74)
Amihud 0.002 0.004 0.007 0.004
(0.66) (2.22) (2.82) (3.62)
Lag Skew -0.000 0.001 0.001 -0.000
(-0.48) (1.24) (1.19) (-0.96)
Lag Dependent 0.024 0.026 0.017 0.018
(40.35) (30.50) (28.06) (29.00)
Intercept -0.119 -0.137 -0.178 -0.114
(-55.62) (-73.83) (-30.92) (-32.74)

Observation 133607 133607 133607 133607


Pseudo R2 0.576 0.734 0.530 1.616

51

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Table 8: Hedge fund versus mutual fund

This table matches the long option positions of hedge funds with the short option positions of mutual
fund based on the underlying stock and reporting quarter. The column `Hedge Fund' is the number
of option positions for a certain type of strategy in the row variable, and is at the fund-quarter-stock
level. The column `Mutual Fund' is the number of hedge fund option positions with at least one mutual
fund taking the corresponding short option positions on the same underlying rm in the same quarter.
The column `Percentage' is dened as the ratio of Mutual Fund to Hedge Fund. Constrained by the
availability of mutual fund option holdings data, the sample is from December 2004 to June 2015.

Hedge Fund Mutual Fund Percentage


Call 20969 5151 24.56%
Put 25591 3081 12.04%
Naked Put 8166 784 9.60%

Table 9: Option hedging costs

This table reports return means and t-statistics from sequential double sorts on skewness assets. Every
third Friday, we sort skewness assets into 3 portfolios (Low, Middle, High) based on a proxy for the
option hedging cost as shown in the row variable and then, within each tercile, form long-short portfolio
based on the variable `Naked Put'. We take long (short) positions on all rms with positive (zero)
Naked Put and value-weight them by option dollar open interests. Numbers reported are the long-short
return spreads within each tercile. T-statistics are in parentheses. Following Cao et al. (2019), we
measure stochastic volatility by estimating an EGARCH(1,1) model on the third Friday using rolling-
1-year daily stock returns and then computing the standard deviation of the model-implied volatilities.
To measure jump risk, we use the disaster concern index in Gao, Gao, and Song (2018). The larger
the index, the greater the downward jump risk faced by market makers who write put options. We
measure stock bid-ask spread as the average daily bid-ask spread in the previous month. Sample is
from January 2005 to December 2020.

Low Middle High


Stochastic volatility 0.39 1.06 2.18
(1.01) (1.50) (2.74)
Jump risk 0.17 0.16 2.16
(0.73) (0.42) (2.40)
Stock bid-ask spread -0.06 1.19 1.79
(-0.17) (2.47) (2.19)

52

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Table 10: Skewness asset in Orªowski, Schneider, and Trojani (2023)
We run monthly Fama-MacBeth regression to predict the return, price, and payo of the skewness
asset in Orªowski, Schneider, and Trojani (2023). T statistics are Newey-West adjusted with 3 lags.
Sample is from January 2005 to December 2020.

rSkew, OST SkewImplied, OST SkewRealized, OST


(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Naked Put 0.349 0.464 -0.433 -0.167 -0.009 -0.006
(4.74) (4.41) (-5.53) (-3.40) (-1.83) (-1.25)

Implied Volatility -0.281 -0.283 -0.007


(-7.75) (-13.86) (-4.14)
Option BA Spread -0.209 -0.017 -0.000
(-9.81) (-5.08) (-0.08)
Short Interest 0.219 0.020 0.001
(6.00) (2.98) (0.55)
Lag Skew -0.008 0.002 0.000
(-2.80) (3.22) (1.17)
Turnover -1.519 -0.045 -0.002
(-2.81) (-0.69) (-0.14)
Max. Stock Return 0.160 -0.109 -0.005
(1.07) (-3.54) (-1.49)
β 0.042 0.023 0.000
(4.35) (7.58) (2.37)
log(ME) 0.007 -0.010 -0.000
(2.74) (-11.44) (-3.76)
log(B/M) 0.001 -0.002 -0.000
(0.49) (-3.76) (-0.28)
IVOL -0.708 0.631 0.046
(-1.01) (5.23) (3.20)
RETt−1,t 0.466 -0.030 0.001
(9.25) (-5.42) (0.40)
RETt−12,t−1 0.072 0.009 0.000
(6.09) (4.45) (0.35)
Amihud -0.732 -0.754 -0.030
(-0.64) (-3.32) (-0.64)
Leverage 0.026 -0.026 -0.000
(1.41) (-7.17) (-0.29)
Intercept 0.891 0.893 -0.018 0.314 -0.000 0.007
(88.67) (12.78) (-6.82) (10.62) (-5.71) (3.99)

Observation 154999 138839 154999 138839 154999 138839


2
Adjusted R 0.000 0.045 0.018 0.380 0.003 0.090

53

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Table 11: Predict option-implied skewness

We run monthly Fama-MacBeth regression to predict the option-implied skewness in Bakshi, Kapadia,
Implied, T otal
and Madan (2003). We consider three types of skewnesses: the total skewness (Skew ),
Implied, Idio. Implied, Sys.
the idiosyncratic skewness (Skew ), and the systematic skewness (Skew ). All
independent variables are standardized. T statistics are Newey-West adjusted with 3 lags. Sample is
from January 2005 to December 2020.

Implied, T otal Implied, Idio. Implied, Sys.


Skewi,t+1 Skewi,t+1 Skewi,t+1
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Naked Put -0.039 -0.035 -0.062 -0.042 0.023 0.007
(-13.35) (-12.32) (-16.46) (-12.44) (10.70) (5.45)

Implied Volatility 0.189 -0.106 0.294


(14.45) (-7.43) (19.34)
Option BA Spread -0.083 -0.086 0.002
(-12.20) (-12.51) (2.29)
Short Interest -0.097 -0.106 0.009
(-17.80) (-18.28) (4.80)
Lag Skew 0.003 -0.024 0.027
(0.93) (-6.38) (10.65)
Turnover 0.000 -0.007 0.007
(0.11) (-1.31) (3.59)
Max. Stock Return -0.019 0.068 -0.088
(-2.04) (5.35) (-11.85)
β -0.151 0.127 -0.278
(-11.69) (10.32) (-19.01)
log(ME) -0.279 -0.181 -0.098
(-13.35) (-8.92) (-12.74)
log(B/M) 0.000 0.014 -0.013
(0.10) (3.96) (-9.07)
IVOL 0.002 -0.092 0.094
(0.23) (-7.19) (12.86)
RETt−1,t -0.076 -0.092 0.017
(-17.19) (-18.60) (9.40)
RETt−12,t−1 -0.021 -0.034 0.013
(-4.47) (-6.71) (7.08)
Amihud -0.078 -0.021 -0.057
(-10.54) (-2.93) (-12.99)
Leverage -0.029 -0.027 -0.002
(-8.50) (-7.57) (-0.82)
Intercept -0.642 -0.656 -0.195 -0.222 -0.447 -0.434
(-29.31) (-21.56) (-10.16) (-10.96) (-16.24) (-12.77)

Observation 163066 146039 163066 146039 163066 146039


Adjusted R2 0.005 0.252 0.010 0.158 0.004 0.640

54

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


Table 12: Variance risk premium

This table checks whether the predictive power of long naked put positions is robust to the inclusion of
variance risk premium, dened as the dierence between implied variance and rolling-one-month his-
torical variance following Bollerslev, Tauchen, and Zhou (2009). T statistics are Newey-West adjusted
with 3 lags. Sample is from January 2005 to December 2020.

(1) (2) (3) (4)


Naked Put 0.153 0.147 0.094
(4.69) (4.46) (2.82)
Variance Risk Premium 0.013 0.013 0.006
(3.95) (3.74) (1.26)

Implied Volatility 0.021


(2.71)
Option BA Spread -0.000
(-0.12)
Short Interest 0.045
(4.41)
Lag Skew -0.001
(-2.22)
Turnover -0.145
(-1.89)
Max. Stock Return 0.013
(0.41)
β -0.006
(-2.88)
log(ME) 0.001
(2.60)
log(B/M) 0.000
(0.42)
IVOL 0.020
(0.14)
RETt−1,t 0.028
(3.69)
RETt−12,t−1 0.001
(0.59)
Amihud 0.766
(3.17)
Leverage -0.006
(-0.99)
Intercept -0.008 -0.008 -0.009 -0.044
(-1.70) (-1.67) (-1.84) (-2.63)

Observation 145067 144898 144707 129933


Adjusted R2 0.002 0.004 0.006 0.042

55

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


A Variable Construction

This section presents the construction details for the control variables used in this paper:

ˆ Implied Volatility: In Table 3, 5, and 12, we use the average implied volatility of

the options in the skewness asset of Bali and Murray (2013). In Table 6, 7, 10,

and 11, we use the average implied volatility of ATM put and call with 30 days

maturity in Volatility Surface database of OptionMetrics.

ˆ Option Bid-Ask Spread: The average percentage option bid-ask spread.

ˆ Short Interest: The number of shares shorted in the Compustat database, scaled

by the shares outstanding.

ˆ Lag Skew: The lagged realized skewness calculated from daily log stock returns

in the previous months.

ˆ Turnover: The average daily turnover (volume/shares outstanding) in the previ-

ous month.

ˆ Max. Stock Return: the maximum daily stock return in the previous month (Bali,

Cakici, and Whitelaw (2011)).

ˆ β: The CAPM beta calculated from rolling-one-year daily stock returns.

ˆ Log(ME): The natural logarithm of a rm's market capitalization on the third

Friday of each month.

ˆ Log(B/M): The natural logarithm of the book equity for the scal year-end of a

calendar year divided by the market equity at the end of December of that year,

as in Fama and French (1992).

56

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419


ˆ IVOL: The idiosyncratic volatility of stock returns estimated from the Fama-

French three factors using rolling one-month daily returns, following Ang, Ho-

drick, Xing, and Zhang (2006).

ˆ RETt−1,t : Short-term stock return reversal, calculated as the cumulative stock

return from the start of a month to the third Friday of that month.

ˆ RETt−12,t−1 : Stock return momentum, calculated as the cumulative stock return

over the past 11 months ending at the end of the previous month (Jegadeesh and

Titman (1993)).

ˆ Amihud: Amihud illiquidity measure (Amihud (2002)), calculated using the past

year daily data and multiplied by 106 to adjust for the scale.

ˆ Leverage: The leverage ratio of a rm computed from the quarterly Compustat

database, dened as Book Debt / (Book Debt + Market Cap.). Book Debt equals

the sum of DLTTQ and DLCQ in Compustat.

57

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4592419

You might also like