Policy Adaptation
Policy Adaptation
Policy Adaptation
May 2014
Copyright (c) IRENA 2014
Unless otherwise indicated, material in this publication may be used freely, shared or reprinted, but
acknowledgement is requested. This publication should be cited as: IRENA (2014),“Adapting renew-
able energy policies to dynamic market conditions”. Abu Dhabi.
About IRENA
The International Renewable Energy Agency (IRENA) is an intergovernmental organisation that sup-
ports countries in their transition to a sustainable energy future, and serves as the principal platform for
international co-operation, a centre of excellence, and a repository of policy, technology, resource and
financial knowledge on renewable energy. IRENA promotes the widespread adoption and sustainable
use of all forms of renewable energy, including bioenergy, geothermal, hydropower, ocean, solar and
wind energy, in the pursuit of sustainable development, energy access, energy security and low-carbon
economic growth and prosperity. www.irena.org
Acknowledgements
Authors: Salvatore Vinci, Divyam Nagpal and Rabia Ferroukhi (IRENA); Ethan Zindler and Anna
Czajkowska (BNEF)
Reviewers: Martin Schöpe (BMWi), David Jacobs (IASS Potsdam), Gireesh Shrimali (Indian School of Busi-
ness), Toby D. Couture (E3 Analytics), Luca Benedetti (GSE), Ghislaine Kieffer, Arslan Khalid, Diala Hawila,
Michael Taylor and Troy Hodges (IRENA), and Nico Tyabji, Vandana Gombar and Stephen Munro (BNEF).
Supporting entity: Bloomberg New Energy Finance (BNEF) provides analysis, tools and data for decision
makers driving change in the energy system.
For further information or for provision of feedback, please contact Rabia Ferroukhi, IRENA, Knowledge,
Policy and Finance Centre (KPFC), CI Tower, 32nd Street Khalidiyah, P.O. Box 236, Abu Dhabi, United Arab
Emirates; Email: RFerroukhi@irena.org.
The designations employed and the presentation of materials herein do not imply the expression of any
opinion whatsoever on the part of the International Renewable Energy Agency (IRENA) concerning the
legal status of any country, territory, city or area or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of
its frontiers or boundaries. While this publication promotes the adoption and use of renewable energy,
IRENA does not endorse any particular project, product or service provider.
Foreword
A combination of effective support policies, high learning rates and rapidly decreasing technology costs has
enabled the accelerated deployment of renewables globally. Renewables now make up a distinct share of the
energy mix in several countries with further substantial growth anticipated in the coming decades. This ongoing
transition of the energy sector opens up new opportunities for governments to reap the long-standing benefits
of a sustainable energy system. Ensuring an effective and rapid transition, however, is a challenge faced by
policy makers today. This requires the timely adaptation of policies to the dynamic market conditions caused by
changing costs, growing deployment and increasing variable generation.
IRENA’s report - Adapting renewable energy policies to dynamic market conditions - identifies key challenges
faced by policy makers due to renewable energy market dynamics and analyses policy adaptation responses to
address them. The study builds upon diverse country experiences and provides a framework for understanding
the conditions under which policy measures to support growing shares of renewables in the energy mix can be
optimised.
The report shows that with decreasing cost of renewable energy technologies, governments are adapting policy
measures to ensure that incentives are appropriately set while increasing transparency and stability within the
sector. The country case studies presented here demonstrate how such measures contribute to ensuring that the
growth of the sector remains sustainable and cost-efficient in the long-term.
The report highlights the importance of adopting a systemic approach to policy-making in order to reach high
shares of renewables. Integration of variable renewables are known to have system-wide impacts which intensify
as deployment grows. Technical measures, such as development of grid infrastructure, smart technologies and
storage as well as adequate regulatory interventions facilitate integration efforts. The report also highlights that
the growth in decentralised generation, driven by approaching grid parity and adoption of enabling policies,
is transforming the traditional ownership structures within the energy sector. This presents new challenges for
incumbent stakeholders, which need to be accounted for in the policy-making process to allow a smooth market
integration of renewables and ensure the long-term reliability of the energy system.
I am confident that the findings from this study will contribute to the ongoing discussions on pathways to further
increase the share of renewable energy in the global energy system. The lessons laid out in the report can serve
as an important reference point for countries at different stages of renewable energy market development.
Adnan Z. Amin
Director - General of International Renewable Energy Agency
3
Contents
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY10
INTRODUCTION15
METHODOLOGY16
REFERENCES 76
FIGURES
FIGURE 1.1 SPOT PRICE OF CRYSTALLINE SILICON MODULES, JANUARY 2012 – JANUARY 2014 (USD/W) 18
FIGURE 1.2 WIND TURBINE PRICE INDEX, MEAN PRICE BY DATE OF DELIVERY, H1 2008 – H1 2014 (EUR MILLION/MW) 19
FIGURE 1.3 LEVELISED COST OF ELECTRICITY FOR SELECT TECHNOLOGIES, Q3 2009 – Q4 2013 (USD/MWh) 19
FIGURE 1.4 COMPARISON OF ANNUAL INSTALLED CAPACITY OF SOLAR PV WITH MODULE PRODUCTION CAPACITY (MW) AND
LEVELISED COST OF ELECTRICITY FOR C -SI SOLAR PV (USD/MWh) 20
FIGURE 1.5 LEVELISED COST OF ELECTRICITY RANGES IN OECD AND NON -OECD COUNTRIES, 2012-2013 (USD/kWh) 20
FIGURE 1.6 PV FIT DEGRESSION MECHANISM IN GERMANY, THE U.K. AND FRANCE, 2009-13 (EUR/MWh) 21
FIGURE 1.7 SMALL- SCALE PV CAPITAL EXPENDITURES, FEED - IN TARIFF RATE AND POWER PRICES IN GERMANY, 2006-2013 23
FIGURE 1.8 EVOLUTION OF RENEWABLE ENERGY ELECTRICITY TARIFF - BASED SUPPORT MECHANISMS IN BRAZIL 26
FIGURE 1.9 WIND CAPACITY CONTRACTED IN BRAZIL (MW) AND AVERAGE PRICE (USD/MWh) 26
FIGURE 1.10 VERIFIED CAPACITY FACTORS FOR BRAZILIAN WIND PROJECTS COMMISSIONED UNDER AUCTION SCHEME AND UNDER
PROINFA FEED - IN TARIFF, 2012 (%) 27
FIGURE 1.11 US WIND CAPACITY ADDITIONS AND PTC (MW) 28
FIGURE 2.1 COST OF PV SUPPORT AS A SHARE OF 2011 ELECTRICITY PRICES IN SELECT EUROPEAN COUNTRIES (EUR/MWh) 32
FIGURE 2.2 GERMAN EEG SURCHARGE ON HOUSEHOLD ELECTRICITY BILLS (EUR CENTS/kWh) AND INSTALLED RENEWABLE
GENERATION CAPACITY (GW), 2010-14E 33
FIGURE 2.3 INDIA’S INSTALLED RENEWABLE ENERGY CAPACITY, 2010-13 (GW) 34
FIGURE 2.5 INDIA’S ESTIMATED ANNUAL NATIONAL SPENDING ON SUBSIDIES, 2010-13 (USD BILLION) 34
FIGURE 2.4 CHINA’S INSTALLED RENEWABLE ENERGY CAPACITY, 2010-13 (GW) 34
FIGURE 2.6 CHINA’S ESTIMATED ANNUAL NATIONAL SPENDING ON SUBSIDIES, 2010-13 (USD BILLION) 34
FIGURE 2.7 U.K. LEVY CONTROL FRAMEWORK, 2011/12 – 2020/21 (GBP BILLION, 2011/12 PRICES) 36
FIGURE 2.8 SDE+ BUDGET CEILING PER SUBSIDY YEAR, 2008-2013 (EUR BILLION) 37
FIGURE 3.1 SMALL SOLAR PV SYSTEM COSTS IN SELECT COUNTRIES (USD/kW) 39
FIGURE 3.2 ESTIMATED COST REDUCTIONS IN RESIDENTIAL SOLAR PV BY COMPONENT, GLOBAL BENCHMARK, 2010-20 (USD/W) 41
FIGURE 3.3 RESIDENTIAL ELECTRICITY PRICE IN 2012, INSOLATION, AND LCOE OF RESIDENTIAL PV, Q2 2013 42
FIGURE 3.4 STATE NET METERING LIMITS IN THE UNITED STATES 44
FIGURE 3.5 COMMERCIAL AND RESIDENTIAL SMALL- SCALE PV CAPACITY IN GERMANY, ITALY AND THE UNITED STATES, 2012 (GW) 44
FIGURE 3.6 NET METERED CAPACITY VERSUS ESTIMATED LIMIT IN SELECTED U.S. STATES, H2 2013 (MW) 45
FIGURE 3.7 PV SYSTEM VALUE BY COMPONENT AND CONFIGURATION IN AUSTIN, TEXAS 46
FIGURE 4.1 AVERAGE UNSCHEDULED CROSS - BORDER POWER FLOWS FROM GERMANY, 2011-12 (MW) 52
FIGURE 4.2 GERMANY’S OFFSHORE GRID DEVELOPMENT PLAN TO CONNECT 6.5 GW OF OFFSHORE WIND PROJECTS BY 2020 AND
ESTIMATED COSTS 52
FIGURE 4.3 GERMANY’S ONSHORE GRID DEVELOPMENT PLAN AND ESTIMATED COST, 2013-23 52
FIGURE 4.4 MERIT ORDER ON A SUMMER DAY (1 JUNE 2010) IN GERMANY 53
FIGURE 4.5 MERIT ORDER ON A SUMMER DAY (1 JUNE 2012) IN GERMANY 53
FIGURE 4.6 AVERAGE DAILY SUMMER SPOT PRICE PROFILE IN GERMANY, 2010 AND 2013 (EUR/MWh) 54
FIGURE 4.7 INDIA’S GREEN ENERGY CORRIDOR PLAN, JULY 2012-2017 55
FIGURE 4.8 KEY STEPS IN GERMANY’S NETWORK DEVELOPMENT PROCESS 57
FIGURE 4.9 ANNUAL SMART METER INSTALLATIONS IN THE EU, 2011-2020 E (MILLION METERS) 60
FIGURE 5.1 POLICIES BEST SUITED FOR DIFFERING LEVELS OF RENEWABLE ENERGY PENETRATION 69
FIGURE 5.2 POLICIES BEST SUITED FOR DIFFERING LEVELS OF ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 70
FIGURE 5.3 POLICIES BEST SUITED FOR CERTAIN TECHNOLOGIES 71
FIGURE 5.4 POLICIES AFFECTING CERTAIN ASSET OWNERS 72
BOXES
BOX 1.1 DEGRESSION MECHANISM FOR SOLAR PV FIT SUPPORT IN THE UK 22
BOX 1.2 CALCULATING THE ISRAEL SOLAR FEED - IN TARIFF 24
BOX 1.3 ACCELERATED DEPRICIATION FOR WIND SECTOR DEVELOPMENT: THE CASE OF INDIA 29
BOX 4.1 EMERGING CHALLENGES AND OPPORTUNITIES FOR TRADITIONAL UTILITIES 55
BOX 4.2 THE RISK OF CAPPING UTILITY RETURNS ON SMART METER INVESTMENTS 60
BOX 4.3 LOOKING FORWARD: RD&D FOR STORAGE DEVELOPMENT – THE CASE OF SOUTH KOREA 62
7
Acronyms
AC Alternating Current
AEEG Italy’s Regulatory Authority for Electricity and Gas
APS Arizona Public Service
BNEF Bloomberg New Energy Finance
BNetzA German Federal Network Agency
BRL Brazilian real
Capex Capital Expenditure
c-Si Crystalline silicon
CRS U.S. Congressional Research Service
CSP Concentrating solar thermal power
DKK Danish krone
DSO Distribution system operator
DR Demand response
EEG Germany’s Renewable Energy Sources Act
EUR Euro
EV Electric vehicle
FiP Feed-in Premium
FiT Feed-in Tariff
GBI Generation Based Incentive
GBP British Pound
GSE Gestore Servizi Energetici
GW Gigawatt
H1, H2 First half, second half (of a given year)
HVDC High-voltage direct current
IPP Independent power producer
IRENA International Renewable Energy Agency
ITC U.S. Investment Tax Credit
KRW South Korean won
kW kilowatt
kWh kilowatt-hour
LCF U.K.’s Levy Control Framework
LCOE Levelised cost of energy
MW Megawatt
MWh Megawatt-hour
NIS Israeli sheqel
O&M operations and maintenance
OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
PJM PJM Interconnection LLC
PPA Power purchase agreement
PROINFA Brazil’s Programme of Incentives for Alternative Electricity Sources
PTC U.S. Production Tax Credit
PUA Israel’s Public Utilities Authority
PV Photovoltaic
Q1, Q2 First quarter, second quarter (of a given year)
9
Executive Summary
T
he conditions affecting renewable energy policy-making have shifted dramatically within a very short
time span. In some countries and jurisdictions, rapidly declining renewable generation costs have made
it challenging to set “appropriate” levels of public support. In others, the proliferation of renewables is
having unanticipated consequences for power grids and markets. Meanwhile, almost everywhere, tighter
post-recession fiscal conditions have meant that fewer funds are available to support the industry.
These conditions have prompted policy makers to reconsider how they support renewable energy develop-
ment and deployment. This has resulted in the adoption of innovative policy design features as well as in
the introduction of a new generation of support policies that are crafted to be compatible with the ongoing
transformation. Such policies are intended to be transparent and impactful, with emphasis on flexibility,
efficiency and cost effectiveness.
This report sets out to provide an overview of selected challenges emerging from dynamic markets and policy
responses being adopted to address them. In particular, it identifies four key challenges faced by policy
makers today: 1) accounting for rapidly falling renewable generation costs, 2) addressing tax/rate-payer
burdens, 3) accounting for renewable energy’s cost competitiveness, and 4) integrating variable renewable
power. For each of the challenges, innovative policies being implemented or proposed around the world are
analysed with the aim to assess their recent or potential impact and to highlight their potential risks. Through
the analysis, the report gathers “lessons learned”. A framework is then presented that allows policy makers to
assess the suitability of specific policies to different contexts.
The sharp fall in renewable energy equipment costs, while a positive trend, presents challenges for policy mak-
ers to ensure that support measures are kept effective and efficient. A fine balance needs to be maintained
between implementing mechanisms that allow for cost tracking and maintaining a stable environment for
investments into the sector. In attaining that balance, countries have either implemented design features into
existing policies, such as degression rate in feed-in tariffs, or introduced new policies altogether, such as auc-
tion schemes. Some lessons that can be learned from country experiences include the following:
»»Adaptation policies that integrate technology cost-tracking features (e.g. degression schemes, auc-
tions, etc.) provide transparency and predictability to market participants.
»»The design stage of policies benefit from active engagement with stakeholders within the sector to clearly
communicate the intended policy objectives and to better calibrate specific policy elements, such as
tariff revision frequency, degression rates, etc.
»»Market-based policy support mechanisms, such as auctions, are gaining increasing prominence as a
way of reducing information asymmetry between governments and developers on generation costs.
When well designed, these can be critical to identify the appropriate level of public support and also
contribute to more predictability in the sector.
The substantial growth that has been experienced by the renewable energy sector during the past decade has
mostly been a result of financial support offered by “early-adopters”. These countries recognized the long-term
benefits of renewables from an environmental, economic and social standpoint. The support for renewables
is a means of internalising external costs not accounted for in traditional energy markets. Resilient support for
the sector translated into the scale-up in deployment, thereby leading to a substantial decrease in technology
costs and the development of the renewable energy industry. This results in relatively less support required for
further deployment. It is, however, important to ensure that the cost of support is kept under control and that it
is distributed fairly across the different stakeholders. As a result, several countries have adopted spending caps
on support for renewables directly or indirectly (through deployment caps) which are often complementary
to other deployment policies. The analysis of country responses to address this challenge yields the following
lessons learned:
»»Limiting the cost of renewables support gains importance as the market expands and deployment grows.
While providing higher support levels may be important to kick-off new technology deployment, it is es-
sential that the costs are closely monitored as the share of renewables rises.
»»Somewhat counterintuitively, capping support may improve rather than diminish investor confidence in a
market, as it provides long-term predictability to the market.
»»When designing spending control measures, a critical element is the distribution of costs across different
stakeholders. Controlling costs is as important for high-income countries concerned about their economic
competitiveness as for middle- or low-income countries focussed on basic economic development.
As renewable energy costs continue to decline and grid parity is attained in different countries, a new era of
policies will be necessary to ensure the further expansion of renewables in the energy mix. Support measures in
a ‘post-parity’ era will need to transition from being purely financial-based to those that are compatible with the
overall system of renewables promotion and the general structure of the electricity system. The report analyses
the role of policies, such as net metering, that can play an instrumental role in promoting the deployment of de-
centralised renewable energy. Net metering schemes are being widely adopted globally and while their design
features might vary, innovation is afoot on ways to address specific challenges associated with distributing costs
between consumers with or without renewable systems. Some of the lessons learned from country experiences
include:
»»Net metering policies can drive residential solar PV adoption, particularly in markets characterised by rela-
tively high electricity prices. However, policy design needs to carefully consider the “reconciliation period”
(i.e., for how long the project owners can claim back thee credit generated by the electricity fed into the
grid) to avoid unintended consequences for grid stability.
11
»»Policy makers need to estimate in a timely manner technical and economic impacts of massive deployment
of decentralised systems on transmission and distribution systems in order to ensure reliability of supply and
efficient management of the electricity system.
»»Residential-size storage systems present important opportunities to promote self-consumption and better
integrate electricity from distributed projects into the grid. Their widespread adoption will mostly depend on
the decrease in the cost of storage technology.
Effective and efficient integration – in terms of physical connection, network management and market integration – is
necessary to allow an increase in the share of renewables in the energy mix. Integration of variable generation can
become a pressing challenge for the sector, particularly in markets or regions with higher rates of renewable penetra-
tion. Grid integration needs to be supported by technical and economic measures. Those include planning for and
investing in physical grid development and enhancement, promoting grid-scale storage and smart infrastructures,
and defining new market designs that consider the broad market-wide impacts of integrating variable renewables. The
analysis of country case studies on these issues yield the following lessons:
»»Inadequate grid infrastructure development can lead to geographically uneven renewable energy capacity
deployment, mismatch between transmission and generation capacity, and significant cost for system balancing.
The lead time associated with developing the infrastructure to facilitate grid evacuation and transfer can be rela-
tively long and, hence, needs to be accounted for in the planning process. “Passive” development of infrastructure
can increase costs, lead to stranded generation assets and hurt investor confidence in the long term.
»»Emerging technologies, such as smart grids, smart meters, storage applications, will play pivotal roles in manag-
ing the system to enable further integration of renewable power while maintaining supply reliability.
»»Integrating high shares of zero- or low- marginal-cost renewable power into power markets can affect the com-
petitiveness of conventional “mid-merit” or “peak” plants. Providing dispatchable capacity remuneration in some
cases may prove necessary, but it is important to ensure that such schemes incentivise only the needed capacity
and, if possible, the different forms of capacity – generation as well as demand response, potentially storage, etc.
Analytical framework
The report presents analytical frameworks or “prisms” which policy makers can use to assess which renewable energy
policy adaptation mechanisms analysed in this report might be best suited for the circumstances in their countries.
The prisms are based on country experience and on how policies have been implemented in different contexts.
it is acknowledged that policies or policy types generally do not fit neatly into clearly defined boxes. The “prisms”
adopted, however, are intended to serve as rudimentary tools for policy-making. An example of such a framework is
illustrated below. It compares the type of policy adaptation mechanisms which could be best suited for jurisdictions
where renewables have achieved “low”, “medium” or “high” penetration rates.
Other “prisms” seek to identify relevant policy types for contexts that are: 1) at varying levels of economic development
(low, middle, or high); 2) interested in supporting specific technologies (wind, solar, smart grid, storage and others);
or 3) seeking to craft policies that affect various asset owners (utilities, independent power producers, community/
residential consumers or commercial customers).
Integrating ‘real time capacity corridors” into the feed-in tariff reduction structure (1.2.1.)
Grid development plan - India (4.2.1.) Grid development plan - Germany (4.2.2.)
POL ICIES
Building third-party metrics into feed-in tariffs (1.2.2.) Implementing spending caps on support for
renewables (2.2.1.)
MINIMISE COST
GOALS
Note: The degree of blue shading indicates how appropriate the goal is for each level of renewables penetration (for example, improved
market integration of renewable power applies more to the most mature markets). A reference to the individual sub-sections from the
report has been included for each policy.
Like with any policy-making, there is no one-size-fits-all solution for renewable energy. Each country is unique
with its own set of characteristics that influence how public policies are crafted and implemented. Still, today
a common set of dynamics is having global impact. And, just as importantly, a variety of innovative policy
responses are being set in motion in various corners of the world. While some of these renewable energy
policies are relatively recent, they hold great potential to support the industry as it advances to its next, all-
important phase of development, in which it attempts to compete with more traditional forms of generation
in a post-parity era.
13
14 Ad a p ting Renewab l e Ene rgy Pol i c i e s to D yn a mic M a rke t C o n d it io n s
Introduction
P
olicy support has played a critical role in spur- efficiency and cost effectiveness. These interesting
ring both a scale-up in renewable energy – and potentially transformative – new efforts are the
capacity deployment and a major industry ex- subject of this report.
pansion. At one time, designing these schemes ap-
peared to be relatively straightforward to legislators This report pursues three objectives. First, it aims to profile
and regulators. Some renewable energy technology renewable energy market dynamics which policy mak-
costs were high and their deployment levels were low. ers should take into account when designing new poli-
In countries with governments that were committed cy frameworks. These include: rapidly falling renewable
to promoting renewables, market-creating measures, energy equipment costs (Section 1), impact of support
such as feed-in tariffs (FiTs) and tax credits, were schemes on national budgets and/or consumer
widely adopted. electricity bills (Section 2), approaching grid parity for
renewable energy technologies (Section 3), integration
In just a few years, the situation has changed dra- of variable renewable generation and broader power
matically in many countries. Rapidly falling costs for market design considerations (Section 4).
renewable technologies, particularly for solar photo-
voltaics (PV) and onshore wind, have caused spikes Second, this report highlights interesting and po-
in installation levels. Unexpected side effects have tentially innovative policies that seek to address the
included inflated government financial liabilities and/ challenges emanating from the market dynamics
or higher consumer electricity bills. In countries with discussed earlier. These include flexible tariff or tax
the largest share of variable renewable generation in schemes which take into account “real-world” costs,
their energy mix, rapid renewables deployment has auctions to enhance price discovery and other solu-
highlighted an urgent need for upgrades and exten- tions. The result can be better controls over the amount
sions to grid infrastructure. of renewable energy which is deployed in certain time
frames and at certain costs. The report provides back-
In some cases, these unintended results have left ground and assessments of each of the highlighted
policy makers with little choice but to react post- measures as well as the potential risks associated with
factum and change the support schemes in place. implementation.
In Europe, governments are addressing the issue
through comprehensive reviews, in some cases Finally, the report draws preliminary conclusions about
resulting in retroactive FiT cuts. In the United States, which of these types of policies might be best suited
costs associated with the Production Tax Credit for different types of markets, situations or countries,
partly led to the its expiration at the end of 2013. given differing economic, political and power mar-
In Australia, states have cut support for solar in the ket structures. The conclusions are preliminary also
wake of higher-than-anticipated installation rates. because some of the policy ideas discussed in this
All of this has raised market uncertainty and lowered report are relatively new. Some solutions may be best
investor confidence. for countries with state-run utilities and lower levels of
electrification. Others may be a better fit for countries
Now, however, a new wave of policy innovation is with liberalised power markets and high connectivity
under way around the world as policy makers seek rates. The report concludes with basic “prisms” which
to craft supports that are not just transparent and policy makers can use to assess the types of renew-
impactful, but also tailored to the new realities of the able energy policy solutions that might be best suited
market. More than ever, the emphasis is on flexibility, for the circumstances in their countries.
15
Methodology
T
he analysis focusses on broad challenges which »»Impact Assessment – an assessment of the
policy makers may face when contemplating policy’s impacts as it can be measured, including
renewable energy policy frameworks, with a par- measures implemented in response to the chal-
ticular focus on electricity. These apply to a wide range lenges outlined above.
of countries, depending on the level of economic
development, degree of renewable energy penetra- »» Risk Assessment – an examination of potential factors
tion, power market structure and other factors. Four key that might undermine a new policy scheme’s success.
challenges have been identified, which are addressed
in the next four sections: In the case of the latter two, the report provides the best
information available on impacts to date and specu-
1. Rapidly falling renewable generation costs have lates to some degree about potential risks. In a number
made it difficult to calibrate public sector supports of cases, the policies highlighted have been adopted
to appropriate levels in recent years. recently, and it remains to be seen how beneficial they
will prove to be.
2. Support schemes that have been successful in
spurring renewables deployment have in some Each policy outlined in the report is assessed based on
cases proven to be relatively expensive contribut- seven selected indicators (see Table on the next page).
ing to consumer/tax-payer burdens. These are presented as a box alongside the respective
policy section and aim to highlight the characteristics of
3. Approaching (and in some locations, the arrival markets where such a policy might fit best.
of) “socket parity” for solar PV and growth in decen-
tralised generation has resulted in unanticipated Of these indicators, the “policy goal” is potentially the most
competition between distributed generators and ambiguous, and thus the potential options merit further
incumbent generators. explanation. Given that policies often have multiple, overlap-
ping aims, the following goals are not mutually exclusive:
4. Growing levels of variable renewable generation
are placing strains on certain national grids and »»Providing adequate support for renewables –
power markets which are generally unequipped Ensuring that financial support aligns with real costs
to accommodate variable sources of power. of power generation from particular technologies.
Supports should provide sufficient help to incentivise
For each of these challenges, the report analyses investment when necessary but not to “overpay”.
examples of countries or other jurisdictions that have
pursued novel policy approaches to address them. »»Minimising cost of support – Ensuring that costs
Such policies have been selected either because they associated with supporting renewables are mi-
have a proven track record of addressing the particular nimised and distributed equitably. Often, such
challenge, or because they sought to bring relatively costs result in surcharges on electricity bills or taxes.
new ideas to address it. These policy approaches are Determining who pays is an important part of de-
categorised by the challenges they seek to address. termining cost.
Each scheme profiled includes:
»»Incentivising self-consumption – Where grid par-
»»Policy Overview – an explanation of what the ity is already a reality, policy makers can empower
measure is, who it affects and what objectives it consumers to become producers by providing
aims to achieve. appropriate regulatory frameworks.
Policy type What mechanism does the Feed-in tariff, market premium, tax-based incentive, net metering, auctions,
policy use to accomplish its Renewable Portfolio Standards (quota schemes), ring-fence budget, grant,
goals? soft-loan, grid regulation, market regulation, smart meter rollout, regulated
investment return, strategic reserve, capacity mechanism, demand-
response incentive.
Eligible Which technologies can benefit All renewable energy technologies, grid, smart meters, storage
technologies from – or are affected by – the
policy discussed?
Complementary What associated policies (if any) A list of policies that can be implemented in concert with the case study.
policies help this policy succeed?
»»Ensuring security and reliability of power sup- Section 5 of the report uses these indicators to pres-
ply – Providing adequate transmission and ent analytical frameworks under which these novel
distribution infrastructure and adequate load policy approaches can be assessed. This is done
management mechanisms, to ensure that the through the presentation of “prisms” which policy
grid system is able to cope with higher levels makers can use when designing – or reforming – their
of variable power without risking power supply policy frameworks for renewables, and broader power
disruptions. markets. These prisms map the indicators highlighted
throughout the report against the policies presented
» »Improving market integration of renewables to illustrate which schemes potentially make the most
– Adjusting power market structures to ensure sense under specific conditions.
that renewable power is integrated and that
sufficient back-up exists as necessary. This It is important to note that this report does not contain pre-
goal captures more-effective system balanc- scriptive conclusions or recommendations. In that sense,
ing, demand management and storage its dual aims are: 1) to highlight novel policy responses to
incentives. the challenges that have arisen as the renewable energy
industry has matured and 2) to shed some light on how
»»Accelerating innovation - Creating an en- these new policy tools might best be applied elsewhere.
abling environment for fostering innovation
in technology design, production processes, This report builds on the analytical policy work con-
deployment and operation. This contrib- ducted by IRENA and several other institutions and
utes to increasing efficiency, cost reduction non-governmental organisations to date and repre-
and enhancement of competitiveness. sents original analysis and synthesis1.
1 Several figures presented in the report are derived from proprietary datasets created by Bloomberg New Energy Finance (BNEF).
17
1 Accounting for Rapidly Falling
Renewable Generation Costs
1.1 CHALLENGE: KEEPING PACE WITH are expected to level in 2014, the long-term downward
COST DECLINES trend is expected to resume due to learning-curve ef-
fects. As turbine sizes grow, more wind is harvested from
Complex technological improvements and simple a given site, meaning that even though price reduc-
economies of scale have combined to drive down tions per kilowatt (kW) may be more modest than in the
renewable energy equipment costs in recent years. past, the trend in delivered electricity costs will continue
Between December 2009 and December 2012, solar downwards at near-historical rates.
PV module prices declined by 65-70%. In 2012 alone, so-
lar module prices dropped more than 20% (see Figure Another reason for the decline in prices is a dramatic
1.1). This was also due to an expanding manufacturing improvement in the technologies used to manufacture
overcapacity that peaked in 2010 when almost twice equipment. Assembly lines have become more sophisti-
as much module production capacity existed glob- cated, automated and efficient. But sheer economies of
ally compared to demand. Module prices stabilised scale combined with major supply gluts are also impor-
in 2013 as manufacturers tried to return margins to tant reasons. Until recently, roughly twice as much final
sustainable levels. Despite an anticipated reduction capacity for wind turbine manufacturing was available
in the global surplus of solar production capacity, the around the world as demand for such equipment. The
overall trend for solar is expected to continue to be same was true for PV cells. As a result, manufacturers are
characterised by falling technology costs due to the faced with marginal profits on equipment sales. In some
high learning rates for solar PV. cases, manufacturers have actually sold equipment at a
loss, a situation that is unsustainable over the long term.
Wind turbine prices dropped by around one-quarter The capacity-demand gap has narrowed recently, al-
between 2009 and 2013 (see Figure 1.2). While prices lowing prices to stabilise and, in some cases, rise slightly.
FIGURE 1.1 SPOT PRICE OF CRYSTALLINE SILICON MODULES, JANUARY 2012 – JANUARY 2014 (USD/W)
1.2 Monocrystalline
silicon module
USD/W
Multicrystalline
1.0 silicon module
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
02 Jan
30 Jan
05 Mar
02 Apr
07 May
04 Jun
02 Jul
06 Aug
03 Sept
01 Oct
05 Nov
03 Dec
07 Jan
14 Jan
04 Mar
01 Apr
06 May
03 Jun
01 Jul
05 Aug
02 Sept
07 Oct
04 Nov
02 Dec
06 Jan
13 Jan
20 Jan
1,5
Wind Turbine Price
Index (WTPI)
EUR million/MW
Old models
(<95m rotor diameter)
New models
1,2 (>95m rotor diameter)
1.21
1.20
0,6
H1 H2 H1 H2 H1 H2 H1 H2 H1 H2 H1 H2 H1
2008 2008 2009 2009 2010 2010 2011 2011 2012 2012 2013 2013 2014
Decreasing technology costs have translated into existed in the industry over the past few years (see
lower installed costs and cheaper electricity from Figure 1.4).
renewables. As shown in Figure 1.3, the levelised cost
of electricity for solar PV technologies and onshore The virtuous cycle of high learning rates and
wind has followed a downward trajectory. For solar PV, increased deployment is driving down the costs
in particular, the decrease in the cost of generation of solar and wind technologies; meanwhile, hy-
is also linked to the production overcapacity that has dropower, geothermal, and biomass for power
FIGURE 1.3 LEVELISED COST OF ELECTRICITY FOR SELECT TECHNOLOGIES, Q3 2009 – Q4 2013 (USD/MWh)
350
200
150
100
50
0
Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4
2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
Source: BNEF.
19
FIGURE 1.4 COMPARISON OF ANNUAL INSTALLED CAPACITY OF SOLAR PV WITH MODULE PRODUCTION CAPACITY (MW) AND LEVELISED COST OF ELECTRICITY FOR C-SI
SOLAR PV (USD/MWh)
Levelised cost of
electricity (USD/MWh)
50 000 250
40 000 200
30 000 150
20 000 100
10 000 50
0 0
2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
generation are mature technologies. Renewables are The situation was further complicated by lag times
now increasingly the most economic choice for new between when policies were proposed, approved
grid supply, and they are cheaper than alternatives in and implemented. In order to guard against wind-
virtually any power system reliant on liquid fuels (e.g., fall profits by developers and to protect consumers
on islands) (see Figure 1.5). from unnecessary cost burden, policy makers are
moving quickly to re-evaluate support programmes
The speed at which prices fell, although indis- which were instituted at a time when equipment
putably positive for developers and end-users, prices were much higher and were expected to
clearly caught some policy makers by surprise. decline more slowly.
FIGURE 1.5 LEVELISED COST OF ELECTRICITY RANGES IN OECD AND NON-OECD COUNTRIES, 2012-2013 (USD/kWh)
0.60
2011 USD/kWh
0.50 Diesel-fired electricity cost range
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.00
Onshore wind
Offshore wind
CSP
Biomass
Hydro: small
Hydro: large
Geothermal
Onshore wind
CSP
Biomass
Hydro: small
Hydro: large
Geothermal
OECD Non-OECD
FIGURE 1.6 PV FIT DEGRESSION MECHANISM IN GERMANY, THE U.K. AND FRANCE, 2009-13 (EUR/MWh)
600 Germany
EUR/MWh UK
France
500
400
300
200
100
0
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4
2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
Source: BNEF based on data from Ofgem (UK), CRE (France) and BNETZA (Germany)
Note: The data gap between Q4 2010 and Q1 2011 in the case of France represents a three-month moratorium implemented to reassess FiT support.
21
Box 1.1
DEGRESSION MECHANISM FOR SOLAR PV FIT SUPPORT IN THE UK
As in most countries, the feed-in tariff policy in the UK is designed in a manner that once the system is installed
and registered, the tariff levels remain fixed and are subject only to the inflation index. As deployment costs
decrease, a mechanism for estimating the future FiT rate was established through a consultation process con-
ducted in 2012. The mechanism adopts a three-pronged approach to estimate the level of support:
1. Pre-planned degression: The frequency was revised from an annual review of tariffs to a quarterly one. The degression
takes place on a fixed date but the amount depends on the capacity deployed relative to pre-set capacity thresholds.
The relevant deployment period considered is the quarter ending three months before the degression applies. The
table below provides an overview of the deployment corridors and the degression factor which they trigger for different
capacity bands.
2. Contingent degression: As evident from the table above, deployment under the ‘low corridor’ attracts zero degression.
However, the mechanism put in place allows for the degression to be skipped only up to two consecutive periods, after
which an automatic default rate (3.5%) applies.
3. Annual reviews: Tariff review is also conducted annually to ensure that the mechanism is operating efficiently and
effectively in adequately supporting PV deployment.
A similar degression mechanism is applied to other technologies, including wind, anaerobic digestors and biogas,
with different design characteristics depending on the technology maturity, volatility in deployment costs and policy
objectives.
new capacity is actually being added to the system (MWh) of electricity generated from PV plants. As tariff
over a period of time. Second, they provide investors reductions are implemented more frequently, new
with clarity about the timing and the extent of tariff projects receive lower support, minimising the impact
changes. The design also lowers longer-term political on consumers’ electricity bills. In Germany, this reduc-
risk by reducing the likelihood of an uncontrollable tion was around 20% in 2013 (see Table 1.1).
boom which could lead a government to cut tariffs
suddenly or even retroactively. Risks: The success of degression mechanisms depends
on effective design and administration. The specific
The German experience shows that the degression design features of the mechanism, such as the setting
mechanism has been successful in accurately and of degression rates, capacity corridors, capacity caps,
timely tracking the decreasing cost of the technology, and the time period between successive revisions, are
as depicted in Figure 1.7. critical for the success of this adaptation measure.
Furthermore, by aligning the tariffs more accurately One of the primary design risks, as observed from the
and rapidly with falling technology costs, such a case of the U.K., is the possibility of situations where
mechanism can accelerate the reduction of the despite lower-than-expected (below capacity cor-
amount that consumers pay per megawatt-hour ridor) deployment, a degression is applied (even if in
Source: Adapted from annual forecasts published by transmission system operators (TSOs) in Network-Transparenz, 2014. Figures are rounded up.
successive review rounds), further reducing the incen- deliveries begin may create a windfall for the genera-
tive for deployment (see Box 1.1). From an administration tor in a time of falling project costs.
point of view, regulators in particular must operate
timely project-by-project registries that are accurate POLICY
and maintained in real time. Delays in the registries may INDICATOR
decisions. Moreover, any tariff degression mechanism Economic development: Middle-high income
needs to start from an appropriate “starting price”. If the
Policy goal: Provide adequate support for renewables;
initial level is set too high, even an aggressive degression minimise cost
schedule would not prevent windfall profits, at least for
a while. Policy type: Feed-in tariff
FIGURE 1.7 SMALL-SCALE PV CAPITAL EXPENDITURES, FEED-IN TARIFF RATE AND POWER PRICES IN GERMANY, 2006-2013
Capex <10kW
Capex (EUR/W) Electricity (EUR/MWh) (EUR/W)
6
Residential
power price
(EUR/MWh)
5 Feed-in tariff
<10kW (EUR/MWh)
Commercial
power price
4 (EUR/MWh)
0
Q2 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3
2006 2007 2007 2008 2008 2009 2009 2010 2010 2011 2011 2012 2012 2013 2013
23
1.2.2 Building third-party metrics into per kWh (USD 0.16/kWh). The tariff was calculated
feed-in tariffs separately for each project based on a specific for-
mula (see Box 1.2). As such, the mechanism was ap-
Policy overview: The most effective FiT rates over the plied mainly to utility-scale plants, since the quota for
long term are those that are set high enough to in- other capacity brackets had been fulfilled at the time
centivise the desired level of generation but not too of the scheme’s introduction. This unique approach
high to constitute windfall profits for generators or to may offer a comparative advantage over capacity-
incur outsized liabilities on the government or utilities. based degressions wherein the elasticity between
Building FiTs that successfully achieve this goal can be decreasing price and increasing deployment might
challenging, however. not necessarily be as definitive as required.
In Israel, the country’s grid regulator, the Public Utilities For 2014, Israel has shifted its scheme to focus instead
Authority (PUA), took an unique approach to degres- on net metering for residential systems, having con-
sion in 2012. It decided to peg the FiT that it offered cluded that solar PV technologies are now cost com-
directly to a set of factors that closely reflect the state of petitive in the sunny nation. In addition, the country’s
solar markets. Specifically, these factors include interest Ministerial Committee on Promotion of Renewable
rates, inflation, exchange rates, the cost of capital, and Energy approved the raising of the target quota for PV
the BNEF module and inverter price indices (which are by nearly 290 MW, which were originally allocated for
based on a confidential survey of buyers and sellers of solar-thermal and wind technology (Udasin, 2014). In
such equipment). both cases, these decisions were informed in part by
the experience with the index, which allowed regula-
The objective of adopting such an approach was to tors to track “real-world” prices closely.
avoid a “solar bubble” in which the support schemes
become disconnected from actual market costs. In Impact assessment: Israel’s novel scheme was in
March 2013, the PUA significantly reduced FiTs in light effect for just a short time, so gauging its success is
of lower PV equipment prices. The rate available to difficult. Integrating the market index into the rate
medium-sized PV projects was cut by 41% to NIS 0.57 did result in the tariff declining sharply. There is little to
Box 1.2
CALCULATING THE ISRAEL SOLAR FEED-IN TARIFF
MIt Cpt
RPt = P * [ DD * ( 35% * MI
t
o o
)
+ 20% + 45% * Cp * Z
o
[
rt
Z = 0.15 * + 0.85
ro
Where:
MIo Base BNEF module and inverter index (e.g 0.87+0.11 USD/Wp)
MIt Updated BNEF module and inverter index known on the day of update
In a renewable energy auction, a grid operator, energy Experience with the FiT scheme led the govern-
regulator or energy ministry issues a call for tenders to ment to explore a legal framework to use energy
install a certain capacity or level of generation. Project auctions as a mechanism to deploy renewables.
developers typically submit bids with a price per unit Accordingly, an auction scheme to contract
of electricity to be delivered. The government or other generation capacity was launched in 2007 (see
entity evaluates the offers on the basis of the price Figure 1.8). The original motivation for auctions was
25
FIGURE 1.8 EVOLUTION OF RENEWABLE ENERGY ELECTRICITY TARIFF-BASED SUPPORT MECHANISMS IN BRAZIL
2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
FIT
AUCTION
price disclosure and efficiency in the procurement The challenge that many countries face in implement-
process by reducing the asymmetry of informa- ing auction schemes is ensuring that winning bids
tion between the industry and the government. translate into the timely development of projects and
These auctions have been technology-specific, to sustainable generation over their envisaged lifetime.
alternative energy auctions or technology-neutral. As such, projects supported through FiTs or auctions
Renewable energy technologies, in particular all have an incentive to maximise output.
wind, have seen much success during the different
rounds of auction. Nearly 13 GW of wind has been Figure 1.10 provides a comparison of capacity factors
contracted until the end of 2013 with the price of for projects deployed under the PROINFA FiT scheme
wind energy consistently reducing with a general and the auction scheme in Brazil. It is clear that projects
trend of decreasing prices (see Figure 1.9). that obtained PPAs via an auction operated at higher
FIGURE 1.9 WIND CAPACITY CONTRACTED IN BRAZIL (MW) AND AVERAGE PRICE (USD/MWh)
120
10 000
100
8 000
80
6 000
60
4 000
40
2 000
20
0 0
PROINFA 2009 Auction 2010 Auction 2011 Auction 2012 Auction 2013 Auction
Source: Adapted from IRENA, 2013b (data for PROINFA, 2009, 2010, 2011, 2012 auction) and GWEC, 2014a (data for 2013 auction using exchange
rate: 1USD = 2.2 BRL)
80% Auctions
Average
70% PROINFA
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
Jun 12
Jul 12
Jun 13
Jul 13
Jan 12
Feb 12
Mar 12
Apr 12
May 12
Aug 12
Sept 12
Oct 12
Nov 12
Dec 12
Jan 13
Feb 13
Mar 13
Apr 13
May 13
Aug 13
Sep 13
Oct 13
Nov 13
Dec 13
Source: BNEF; ANEEL; ABEEólica (2013).
capacity factors than those contracted under the FiT Impact assessment: In the August 2013 auction, 66
scheme. This is primarily due to technological improve- contracts were signed with a total capacity of 1 505
ments, but also to siting and operational choices. MW and an average price of BRL 110.51 (USD 50.9)
per MWh. The November 2013 auction resulted in
The experience from Brazil demonstrates that several the award of 39 projects with a combined installed
factors should be considered while designing and capacity of 867.8MW at an average price of BRL 124.43
implementing auction schemes. For instance, in a (USD 57.3) per MWh. In December 2013, the auction
departure from previous auctions, the government resulted in the award of 97 new projects totalling 2.3
instituted a “P90” standard for qualifying projects. This GW at an average price of BRL 109.93 (USD 50.6) per
meant that a project’s annual generation had to equal MWh (GWEC, 2014a).
90% or more of the probability of generation forecast
by wind measurement and annual generation data. These results were higher than the minimum price
The P90 standard differs from the P50 capacity factor reached in the 2012 auction that resulted in the award
required in previous auctions, which allowed for a of just 10 projects of 281.9 MW total capacity at BRL 87.94
larger margin of error in qualifying for a PPA. (USD 42.16) per MWh. The surprisingly low prices of 2012
were attributed to the low ceiling price established for
To address previous nonfulfillment of commitments as- the auction (USD 54 per MWh), among other factors
sociated with grid connection limitations, the August (Brazilian Wind Energy Conference, 2013). Factors that
2013 auction included inter-connection qualifiers. could have influenced the marginal increase in price
Developers had to connect their projects to the grid in 2013 include: 1) the developers were responsible
at their own expense if necessary, and a project may for connecting their projects to the grid at their own
only be bid in the auction if it is feasible to connect expense, if necessary; 2) the developers were respon-
it. When the project developer submits a proposal, sible for delivering the projects in a short period of two
it must identify which substation it plans to connect years; and 3) BNDES had more stringent local content
to. All substations are mapped onto the transmission requirements for financing projects.
system. In the case where multiple projects compete
to connect to the same substation, the project which In November 2013, Brazil held its first auction in
bids lowest is offered the contract. which solar projects were encouraged to compete.
27
Developers registered 3 gigawatts (GW) of potential to encourage investment in new generating capac-
capacity to bid for contracts. However, a ceiling price ity. These supports have typically come in one of two
for contracts of just BRL 126 (USD 58) per MWh was set forms:
by regulators, and no registered solar projects won »»Tax credits, which allow renewable energy asset
contracts. Later that year, a solar-exclusive auction was owners to directly reduce the taxes they pay at
held on December 27. It registered 122.82 MW of total the end of the year, pegged either to the volume
capacity at an average price of BRL 228.63 (USD 105.25) of electricity that their project has generated or
per MWh. their total investment in building the project.
Risks: The most significant risk in auctions is that de- »»Allowable accelerated depreciation, which allows
velopers will offer bids low enough to win contracts developers to amortise the costs of a renewable
but too low to ensure that they earn an adequate energy project in an expedited manner. The result is
return on investment. Such “low-ball” bids, whether higher booked costs in the earlier operating years of
intentional or not, can result in financing delays and, a project to reduce reported earnings and associ-
in the worst case, in failure of the project to be built ated taxes. Later, when the costs are fully amortised,
at all. While different countries have adopted various the asset can generate larger profits that do get
design features to avoid such a situation (e.g., intro- taxed; but in the meantime, the actual economic
ducing floor tariffs, establishing tariff benchmarks, cost to the project owner has been reduced.
etc.), the risk remains as domestic markets become
increasingly competitive. Tax policies have been used most notably in the
United States and India (see Box 1.3) to spur renew-
Successful auctions also are contingent on the power able energy deployment. The United States has relied
purchaser following through on commitments to buy on a combination of accelerated depreciation and
electricity at an agreed-upon price. Even for transactions tax credits. Wind projects commissioned before 1
in which the offtaker is government-owned or -backed, January 2014 benefitted from the Production Tax
it is important to assess its history in fulfilling contract ob- Credit (PTC) which allowed them to directly reduce
ligations and its track record on payments and dispute their annual tax bills by USD 23 for each MWh that a
resolution. Finally, the process relies on transparent and project generates over the first ten years in operation.
efficient administration of bids in order to preclude ac- Solar project owners can apply for the Investment Tax
cusations of “fixing the contracts”. Credit (ITC), set at 30% of a new project’s capital ex-
penditure. Combined with accelerated depreciation
POLICY rules, these tax credits have proven critical to the ex-
INDICATOR
pansion of U.S. renewable energy capacity. However,
Renewables penetration: Low-medium-high
the tax policies put in place in the United States
Economic development: Middle-high income require periodic extensions that are often approved
Policy goal: Provide adequate support for renewables, either close to the expiry date or retroactively. While
trigger technology innovation the ITC is available in its current form through 2016,
Policy type: Auctions the PTC has been allowed to expire four times since
1999 and officially expired at the end of 2013. At the
Eligible technologies: All
height of the financial crisis in January 2009, Congress
Asset ownership: Utility, IPP enacted a key change to make the PTC more flex-
ible through the establishment of “cash grants” that
Complementary policies: Power market liberalisation
project developers could receive in lieu of the PTC.
The grants would cover 30% of a typical wind project’s
capital expenditure. Developers quickly put the cash
1.2.4 Designing flexible tax policies grant to use, building nearly 21.3 GW of new capacity
from 2009 to 2011.
Policy overview: Policy makers have long used tax
codes as an instrument to incentivise private sector The cash grant programme expired at the end of
participation. In the context of renewable energy 2011. The PTC lived on for two more years until its expiry
development, tax policies have been used extensively at the end of 2013, but not before a key change was
In India, accelerated depreciation rules for both wind and solar PV have played a key role in supporting deployment
of those technologies. During the initial stages of market development, the entire value of an Indian wind project could
be depreciated in the first year of its existence. First-year depreciation was then lowered to 80% around 2003 and, in
March 2012, reduced further to 15%. The incentive was withdrawn in April 2012 (PIB, 2012), along with another key incen-
tive- Generation Based Incentive (GBI). With no economic incentives in place, the installations dipped to 1 700 MW in
2012-13, compared to 3 164 MW in 2011-12 (CSE, 2014). This led the government to re-introduce the GBI scheme with the
objective of incentivising generation rather than capacity deployment as well as to allow a broader set of developers
to enter the market. However, there is growing demand for reinstating the accelerated depreciation benefit (CSE, 2014).
Accelerated depreciation benefits those projects that rely on balance-sheet financing rather than a project financ-
ing. The argument against such an approach is that it hinders the scalability of the sector (as the purpose of
lending is not directly power generation) and that it does not encourage the participation of a broader set of IPPs
that face difficulties in accessing corporate credit for wind projects. While a GBI scheme addresses this to a certain
extent, in this case investors need to take on performance risks given that the revenues become entirely dependent
on the generation of wind projects.
made to increase the flexibility of the policy. Whereas in the policy design is that if the gap between the
projects previously needed to be commissioned by LCOEs for wind and natural gas does not close, the
the time of the PTC expiry, at the end of 2013 they PTC remains on the books.
merely needed to be “under construction”. Partly as
a result of this change, developers were able to keep Impact assessment: The impact of the PTC on U.S.
considerably more projects in motion and their “pipe- wind installations is clear: they peaked in 2009 and
lines” full. The U.S. Energy Information Administration is 2012, as developers rushed to build projects ahead
projecting that 16.1 GW of new wind capacity will be of the anticipated expiry of the credit (see Figure
built in 2014-15 (U.S. Energy Information Agency, 2014). 1.11). As evident from the figure, each time the credit
has been allowed to expire, the following year has
Against this backdrop, the non-partisan experienced a significant drop in deployment. The
Congressional Research Service (CRS) published a PTC was last extended in January 2013 for one year,
paper that examined some policy options to address but the effect of its “false” expiry is permanent. Only
the shortcoming of the PTC. One option considered an estimated 600 MW of new wind capacity was
that the level of the PTC that is presently fixed at USD added in the United States in 2013, in part because
23 (and rises at the rate of inflation) could be set an- projects which would have been completed that
nually at a rate just high enough to bridge the gap year were brought on line in 2012 by developers
between the average levelised cost of electricity fearful of missing out on the PTC. Although the
(LCOE) for wind power generation and a similarly set PTC expired in January 2014, the extension in 2013
LCOE for natural gas combined-cycle power genera- included an adjustment of the eligibility criteria to
tion (CRS, 2013). include projects that began construction in 2013
and not necessarily coming online in the same
The annual adjustment was proposed with a PTC year (NREL, 2014). This has led to a positive outlook
“phase out” in mind, under the assumption that the being adopted for the industry in 2014 with over 12
LCOE for wind will continue to decline, natural gas GW of new generation capacity being under con-
prices will rise, or some combination of both will occur. struction at the end of 2013 (GWEC, 2014b).
The result would be that the PTC could be reduced
accordingly. Once that gap closes altogether, the Risks: The potential drawbacks of the proposed revi-
PTC would fall to zero and effectively sunset itself. Thus, sions of the PTC include: 1) complex implementation,
the PTC would exist on an as-needed basis. Implicit 2) issues with using LCOE as a way to compare the
29
FIGURE 1.11 US WIND CAPACITY ADDITIONS AND PTC (1999- 2014E) (MW)
16 000
MW Deployed
14 000
12 000
10 000
PTC expiration
8 000
6 000
4 000
2 000
0
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014e
Source: Adapted from IRENA, 2014. Note: The capacity addition for 2014 is estimated from GlobalData, 2014.
economics of wind and natural gas combined-cycle year might provide greater incentive for the industry
power generation, 3) regional resource and market to make improvements over a certain period of time.
variations and 4) industry’s ability to realise cost reduc-
tions (CRS, 2013). POLICY
INDICATOR
Each of these has the potential to undermine the Renewables penetration: Low-medium-high
flexible PTC proposal. The first – “complex implementa- Economic development: Middle-high income
tion” – simply refers to the difficulty overall of adding any
Policy goal: Provide adequate support for renewables ,
level of nuance to what to date has been a fixed-rate trigger technology innovation
subsidy. The second raises questions about whether
Policy type: Tax-based mechanism
LCOE is the proper metric for comparing wind with its
nearest-priced competitor in U.S. power generation. Eligible technologies: Multiple
The third refers to the fact that there are substantial re- Asset ownership: Utility, IPP
gional differences in the United States in terms of natural
Complementary policies: U.S. Production Tax Credit
resources (and hence LCOEs), raising the possibility that
a “one-size-fits-all” approach to setting a support level
may not be appropriate. Finally, the entire proposal rests 1.3 LESSONS LEARNED
on the assumption that the wind industry will continue
to innovate and reduce its costs in order for the PTC to The sharp fall in renewable energy equipment
decline and eventually disappear. Should costs not costs has both a positive and a negative impact
drop, the gap between the LCOE for wind and natural for policy-making. It is positive in that cheaper solar
gas will not necessarily narrow, and the PTC will have to PV modules or wind turbines have led to an expan-
remain at current or higher levels. sion in renewable energy deployment. It is negative
in that it can be challenging to set support levels
There is one additional and associated concern: if appropriately enough to spur market activity and
the wind industry knows that the PTC will be set annu- low enough to avoid unintended windfall profits for
ally at a level substantial enough to bridge the gap developers. Sudden efforts to rein in supports have
between wind and natural gas costs, will it still be created market uncertainty. In a number of cases,
sufficiently motivated to continue to reduce its costs? this has resulted directly in decreased private in-
A system that automatically reduces the PTC year by vestment and deployment.
31
2 Addressing Tax/Rate-payer
Burdens
R
enewable energy deployment has experienced fossil fuels, it is important that it is kept under control
substantial growth during the past decade- and that its cost is distributed fairly across the different
global solar PV installed capacity has risen from stakeholders.
over 7 GW in 2006 to 137 GW in 2013, while wind capac-
ity has grown from 74 GW to 318 GW in the same period 2.1 CHALLENGE: REDUCING IMPACTS ON
(REN21, 2013; GWEC, 2014b). Much of this growth has TAX-PAYERS OR CONSUMERS
been a result of financial support offered by countries
that have been early-adopters of these technologies. The misalignment of the level of support and the cost
These countries recognized the long-term benefits of technology is one of the factors that has led to an
brought on by renewables from an environmental, unprecedented spike in renewable energy capac-
economic and social standpoint. As such, support for ity installations in some countries. This boom, driven
renewables has been seen as a means of internalising largely by attractive support rates, has in some cases
external costs presently not accounted for in traditional resulted inadvertently in an increased burden on
energy markets. Resilient support for the sector trans- consumers and tax-payers – or, as in Spain, in a “tariff
lated into a scale-up in deployment, thereby leading deficit” caused by policies that have at times forced
to a substantial decrease in technology costs and the utilities to sell electricity to consumers at rates below
development of the renewable energy industry. As a the cost of supply.
result, further deployment will not require the level of
support witnessed in the past. While the support for Figure 2.1 illustrates that in 2012, the Italian residen-
renewables has generally been much lower than for tial power price rose by 10% purely as a result of FiTs
FIGURE 2.1 COST OF PV SUPPORT AS A SHARE OF 2011 ELECTRICITY PRICES IN SELECT EUROPEAN COUNTRIES (EUR/MWh)
300
PV support
EUR/MWh
7.6%
Electricity price
250
10.1%
4.4%
200
7.5%
1.0% 1.9%
150
4.5%
100
50
0
Germany Italy Spain Czech Republic UK France Greece
Germany is a clear example of a country whose ambi- Still, these policies have had a cost. There have been
tious – and successful – renewable energy policies led clear instances where they have inflated rate-payers’
to the development of a local industry, albeit at a cost electricity bills or tax-payers’ tax bills. Europe is chosen
(see Figure 2.2). Several gigawatts of installed renewable as a suitable example to illustrate this impact for three
energy capacity resulted in significant cost added to reasons: 1) the continent has been a front-runner in
final consumers’ electricity bills. As a result, speculations several renewable energy technology deployment,
were abound that the 2014 level of the EEG surcharge and hence the effects of support are most obvious;
was likely to exceed EUR 7 cents per kWh. To the surprise 2) for many years high FiTs were the dominant support
of many, it increased to only EUR 6.24 cents/kWh in 2014, policy in the continent, raising the overall costs of sup-
which may suggest that these costs are beginning to port, and 3) timely data are either readily available or
be contained and that some cost-efficiency measures relatively easy to calculate, because European opera-
that have been implemented are bearing fruit. tors are obliged to report periodically.
In virtually all of these cases, policy makers were will- However, the impact of support measures on consum-
ing to support the renewable energy sector seeking to ers is different depending on the form in which this
make inroads into a power sector dominated by large support is granted. FiTs, feed-in premiums and green
incumbent players such as utilities or independent certificates usually affect consumers in a similar way – by
power producers. To a large degree, the policies of adding a “renewables surcharge” to their electricity bills.
Germany, Spain, Italy, Denmark and other nations Countries using auctions as the main support measure
succeeded in allowing the renewable energy sector for renewables are likely to include their costs in the “cost
to scale up and drive down the generation costs. of electricity” component of the final consumer bill, as
FIGURE 2.2 GERMAN EEG SURCHARGE ON HOUSEHOLD ELECTRICITY BILLS (EUR CENTS/kWh) AND INSTALLED RENEWABLE GENERATION CAPACITY
(GW), 2010-14E
9 90
EEG surcharge on household electricity (EUR cents/kWh)
82.6
8 77.1 80
Installed renewable energy capacity (GW)
71.0
7 70
6.24
6 60.5
60
5.28
51.0
5 50
4 3.59 40
3.53
3 30
2.05
2 20
1 10
0 0
2010 2011 2012 2013 2014e
Source: Adapted from Network-Transparenz, 2014. Note: ‘e’ denotes that the figure is an estimation for the given year.
Note: Figures provided by the German Ministry of Environment and BNetzA. Installed capacity numbers are from BNEF and the Capacity for 2014 is
estimated.
33
arguably this is not subsidised since projects win con- electricity at subsidised rates, as is also the case in Spain.
tracts via competitive bidding (unless the auctions are This may affect credit ratings of both the underwriting
technology-specific, in which case a subsidy is some- authorities and the companies themselves.
times included). This is the case in many Latin American
markets, such as Brazil, Uruguay and South Africa. An analysis of average annual spending on renewable
energy support – calculated as the difference between
Assessing the impact of net metering is more difficult (see the wholesale power price and the price paid to renew-
sub-section 3.2.1), for example, given the often avoided able generators – of some of the most prominent players
fixed payments for transmission and distribution. In cases among the emerging markets highlights that as India
where the cost of support does not permeate through to and China have added more renewables to their power
the consumers, as with many developing countries like generation mix (see Figures 2.3 and 2.4), the burden on
India, the state simply underwrites the debt (partly or en- consumers (or tax-payers, where subsidies are funded
tirely) that distribution companies accumulate by selling from the budget) has risen as well (see Figures 2.5 and 2.6).
FIGURE 2.3 INDIA’S INSTALLED RENEWABLE ENERGY CAPACITY, 2010-13 (GW) FIGURE 2.4 CHINA’S INSTALLED RENEWABLE ENERGY CAPACITY, 2010-13 (GW)
Biomass & waste Solar Small-hydro Wind Marine Geothermal Biomass & waste Solar Hydro Wind
35 200
32.4 185.4
GW GW
180
30 28.0 155.5
160
24.0
25 133.7
140
19.8
120 108.8
20
100
15
80
10 60
40
5
20
0 0
2010 2011 2012 2013 2010 2011 2012 2013
Source: BNEF. Note: Large hydro not included. Source: BNEF. Note: Large hydro not included.
FIGURE 2.5 INDIA’S ESTIMATED ANNUAL NATIONAL SPENDING ON SUBSIDIES, 2010- FIGURE 2.6 CHINA’S ESTIMATED ANNUAL NATIONAL SPENDING ON SUBSIDIES,
13 (USD BILLION) 2010-13 (USD BILLION)
4 8
Large-scale solar Waste-to-energy
USD billion
USD billion Biomass Large-scale solar
7
Onshore wind Biomass
3 6
Onshore wind
2 4
1 2
0 0
Sum of 2010 Sum of 2011 Sum of 2012 Sum of 2013 Sum of 2010 Sum of 2011 Sum of 2012 Sum of 2013
Source: BNEF. Note: Chart represents net cost of subsidies (i.e., exclud- Source: BNEF. Note: Chart represents net cost of subsidies (i.e., exclud-
ing wholesale electricity prices). Direct subsidies only, local incentives ing wholesale electricity prices). Direct subsidies only. China Develop-
not included. ment Bank funding and local tax breaks not included
their bill levies – the amount that can be passed on Following the solar boom of 2011, when 9.3 GW of solar PV
to consumers – to cover the support. Once the cap was added to the Italian grid (see Table 2.1), the country
is reached, the policies need to either be altered in decided to limit the amount of economic support avail-
line with the budgetary prescriptions, or the support able to the technology. Under the 5th Conto Energia law,
is suspended or terminated. Some countries imple- enacted in August 2012, FiTs were allocated to projects
ment “capacity” caps, rather than budgetary limits, included in a registry administered by the Gestore Servizi
to achieve the same purposes. This way, the govern- Energetici (GSE), created specially for this purpose.
ments try to ensure that the cost borne by society is Through this registry, the regulator could track the num-
both controlled and predictable. ber of projects applying for support and ensure that the
half-yearly budget cap was not exceeded. These caps
As many developing nations embark on the renew- were set at EUR 140 million for the first registry, EUR 120 mil-
able energy route, they too need to take into account lion for the second and EUR 80 million for the third. The
the impact that any support provided to the sector caps resulted in significant slowdown of additional PV
may have on consumers. Malaysia has taken these capacity built in Italy, particularly of large-scale projects.
aspects into account by introducing a spending cap
on FiTs provided to renewables. TABLE 2.1 PV GROWTH IN ITALY (2008-2013)
35
was reached on 6 June 2013 and the FiTs stopped be- surcharge (EEG Umlage) added to consumers’ bills.
ing allocated a month later. However, the residential While energy-intensive industries benefit from dis-
segment still benefits from a tax incentive (income tax counts on that surcharge, the cost is paid primarily
deduction), which has been driving steady growth in by household consumers. The levy is set each year
this market following the FiT termination. by the regulator, following the renewable generation
forecast and consultations with transmission system
U.K.: LEVY CONTROL FRAMEWORK operators (TSOs).
The U.K.’s Levy Control Framework (LCF) provides an
upper budget limit on the annual surcharges added For calendar year 2013, the EEG surcharge was raised
to consumer bills to fund renewable energy projects. 47%, from EUR 3.59 cents/kWh to EUR 5.28 cents/kWh
It was introduced by the government in 2010 to keep on domestic electricity bills (seen earlier in Figure
a lid on expenditures that are off the government 2.2). Soon after the announcement of that increase,
balance sheet but still considered public spending. a proposal was initiated to control electricity prices
Since then, the LCF has come to be viewed by inves- via a limit on the EEG surcharge increase. Under the
tors as a source of confidence that the U.K. is less likely proposal, in 2014 the surcharge would stay level at
to overspend on renewable energy and put a high EUR 5.28 cents/kWh. From 2015 onwards, it can rise
burden on consumers. That in turn reduces the risk of by no more than 2.5% annually. A set of measures
retroactive cuts for existing assets. lowering the support for renewables and limiting the
exemptions available to energy-intensive industries
The framework also offers visibility about the government’s was proposed to achieve this goal.
ambitions and scale of support over time. Notably, the U.K.
Department of Energy and Climate Change (DECC) has Although the proposal was not implemented due
published LCF amounts out to 2020/21, with a levy cap of to objections from the Bundesrat (Upper House of
GBP 7.6 billion in 2020 (2011/12 prices), providing a long- Parliament), it was a clear attempt to set binding bud-
term framework for prospective investors (see Figure 2.7). get limitations for renewables support. In 2014, the
EEG surcharge increased to EUR 6.24 cents/kWh, and,
GERMANY: PROPOSED EEG SURCHARGE LIMIT following the September parliamentary elections, the
In Germany, support for renewables – both feed-in new government’s priority was to stop further cost
tariffs and feed-in premiums – is funded via an EEG escalation.
FIGURE 2.7 U.K. LEVY CONTROL FRAMEWORK, 2011/12 – 2020/21 (GBP BILLION, 2011/12 PRICES)
8 7.6
GBP billion
7.0
7
6.5
6 5.6
4.9
5
4.3
4
3.3
3.0
3 2.5
2.1
2
0
2011/12 2012/13 2 013/14 2014/15 2015/16 2016/17 2017/18 2018/19 2019/20 2020/21
FIGURE 2.8 SDE+ BUDGET CEILING PER SUBSIDY YEAR, 2008-2013 (EUR BILLION)
Heat
10
EUR billion 9.2
Biogas
9
Hydro
8 PV
Biomass
7
Offshore wind
6
Onshore wind
4 3.5
3.0
3
2.1
2 1.5 1.7
1.5
0
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014
37
POLICY
INDICATOR
Three key lessons can be learned from the experience
of the countries analysed above:
Renewables penetration: Medium-high
Economic development: Middle-high income 1. Limiting the costs of renewables support gains
importance with increasing market maturity.
Policy goal: Minimise cost of support
While providing higher support levels may be im-
Policy type: Budget caps portant to kick-off new technology deployment, it
Eligible technology: All is essential that the costs are closely monitored as
renewable energy share expands.
Asset ownership: N/A
Complementary policies: Feed-in tariffs, market premiums, 2. The Malaysian example illustrates that keeping
green certificates, market premiums, grants, other support
schemes
costs under control is as important for middle-
income countries, concerned about maintaining
household income, as it is for high-income coun-
2.3 LESSONS LEARNED tries, concerned about industrial competitiveness.
This in part explains why in Malaysia, the support
Policy makers need to strike a balance between being is funded largely by non-domestic consumers,
supportive of renewable energy deployment and ensur- while in Europe the schemes are funded primarily
ing that the costs associated with that support do not fall by households.
disproportionately on one segment of the population.
Offering uncapped support for renewable power genera- 3. In a somewhat counterintuitive way, a cap on sup-
tion can add a high burden on consumers or tax-payers, port may improve rather than diminish investors’
who ultimately cover the costs through an electricity bill confidence in the market, as it provides long-term
surcharge or via additional taxes. visibility and predictability to the market. It also
minimises the risk of sudden or even retroactive
Putting a budget cap on spending for renewable energy changes.
support can limit this impact greatly, and several countries
have successfully demonstrated the impact of such mea- It is important to note that these budget caps can
sures. Italy stopped providing FiT support to solar PV when – and should – be complementary to all of the poli-
the total expenditure reached EUR 6.7 billion, avoiding fur- cies analysed in the previous section. In other words,
ther escalation of the costs. The U.K. restricts its spending governments need to think about ensuring that the
via a special levy control framework, limiting the spending support they provide accurately reflects the costs of
to GBP 3.3 billion in 2014 and GBP 7.6 billion in 2020. The generation and provides sufficient incentive to devel-
Netherlands managed to reduce its annual expenditure opers; at the same time, they need to state their inten-
on renewables support from EUR 9.2 billion in 2009 to EUR 3 tions clearly and to indicate early on how big a market
billion in 2013 through strict budget allocations. they are willing to support financially.
8000
US residential
USD/kW
US non-residential
US utility
6000 Germany
Residential annual
Japanese
4000 Australian
Italian
Chinese
2000
0
06
06
07
08
09
09
10
10
11
11
12
12
13
13
14
0
0
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
4
2
2
Q
6 Module
Inverter
4.90
5 Balance of Plant
0.55
Engineering, Procurement
0.68 3.98 and Construction
4
0.78 Other
0.70
2.96
0.56
3 2.75
0.43 0.53 2.62
0.61 0.43 2.40
0.36 2.23
2.54 0.60 0.30 2.14
0.60 2.06 1.99 1.92
0.58 0.25 0.24
2 0.28 0.56 0.24 0.23
0.54 0.53 0.23
0.65 0.51 0.50
1.75 0.65 0.49
0.63
0.60 0.54
0.26 0.59 0.57 0.54 0.53
1 0.21 0.19
0.18 0.18
0.93 0.86 0.86 0.16 0.15 0.14
0.76 0.68 0.14
0.64 0.60 0.56 0.53
0
2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
Source: BNEF.
exact moment when competitiveness arrives will be As costs continue to decline towards parity in different
difficult in countries where consumer power prices are countries, the need to adapt support policies arises.
subsidised. Competition from solar PV versus incumbent Achievement of PV competitiveness does not mean
sources comes most strongly at the small-scale com- that the sector requires no further support. Instead, a
mercial and residential level, where retail (not wholesale) policy transition is necessary from measures that are
electricity prices from the grid are being offset. Thus, the purely financial-based to measures that are compat-
term “socket parity” is used to distinguish from the com- ible with the overall system of renewables promotion
petitiveness of large, utility-scale PV projects. For large and the general structure of the electricity system.
projects, “grid parity” tends to refer to the LCOE of PV Alternative support incentives, such as self-consump-
compared to alternative means of wholesale electric- tion or net-metering, which may become increasingly
ity provision. Residential installations are, therefore, not relevant as decentralised PV deployment increases
competing against wholesale generation but, instead, and as grid parity is attained (PV Parity, 2013). This
with the delivered price of electricity through the grid. brings new challenges to policy makers, grid opera-
tors and utilities, as the ongoing transformation of the
While solar PV system costs clearly play a crucial role traditional energy system involves consumers now
in determining socket parity, insolation levels and lo- not only purchasing electricity from the grid but also
cal residential electricity prices are also crucial. For feeding their own excess production back into it. While
this reason, several developing countries in particular this has the potential to be a benefit for consumers, it
offer a huge potential market for PV deployment. represents possible system balancing challenges (see
While historically the primary market for PV systems in Section 4). Spain has reacted to these challenges by
developing countries has been off-grid applications, proposing to impose additional charges on residential
grid-connected solar systems play a growing role in projects, and similar proposals are under discussion
countries where transmission and distribution networks in Germany. In the United States, some utilities have
are relatively well developed, and adequate policies sought to impose monthly fees on residential PV sys-
are in place. Estimates suggest that countries such as tem owners. In the state of Oklahoma, for example, a
Turkey, Brazil and Israel have already achieved “socket new bill intends to impose an additional fixed charge
parity”, while India and Argentina are likely to do so in on consumers with distributed generation systems
the near future (see Figure 3.3). installed compared to those who do not, in order
41
FIGURE 3.3 RESIDENTIAL ELECTRICITY PRICE IN 2012, INSOLATION, AND LCOE OF RESIDENTIAL PV, Q2 2013
Potential
0.40 More sun 25GW residential
USD/kWh
PV market
0.35
EMEA
0.30 Denmark
Source: BNEF.
Note: The blue line illustrates the LCOE levels (Q2 2013) for different insolation rates. Countries above the LCOE line have already reached “socket
parity”. EMEA = Europe, the Middle East and Africa; ASOC = Asia/Oceania; AMER = the Americas.
to avoid cross-subsidisation (Oklahoma Legislature, In its most basic form, net metering requires a
2014). bi-directional electricity meter, i.e., one that runs
backwards when power is fed to the grid rather than
These challenges will have the biggest impacts on consumed from it. In a basic net metering scheme,
markets with high PV adoption rates. Markets where the generator receives a flat rate for grid-delivered
solar power is just taking off will be less affected but electricity (a retail price). More-complex versions,
should not disregard these impacts, as PV grid parity such as the one in use in Italy, takes into consider-
(or even costs falling below that level) will lead to even ation the varying market price of power delivered
more rapid adoption of this technology. Rapid adop- or consumed during different periods. The design
tion of grid-connected small distributed PV projects features vary across different net metering schemes,
will require system integration efforts, as discussed in thus also affecting the financial return for investors
Section 4. and the attractiveness of the scheme. Table 3.1
provides an overview of schemes in four selected
3.2 RESPONSES regions across identified comparators, including
total programme capacity, maximum system size,
3.2.1 Permitting net metering to allow grid charges, etc.
consumers to become generators
There has been a marked rise in the adoption of net
Policy overview: Net metering supports small- to me- metering policies, with the number of such schemes
dium-scale renewable energy development by allow- (at the national or state/provincial level) increasing
ing generators to “bank” (on the electricity grid) any from 37 in 2012 to 42 as of early 2014 (REN21, 2014). Net
production which they do not consume at the time of metering, as a support instrument, has been widely
generation. They are credited for their net electricity adopted in the United States, where it originated
generation on their electricity bills. As such, the policy in the 1980s to encourage distributed generation.
can be introduced relatively simply. As of early 2014, 45 U.S. states and the District of
Rate awarded Retail (kWh Retail (kWh credit against Retail (kWh credit Retail price reduced
credit against retail price) against retail price) of tax and levies for
retail price) plants smaller than 20
kW; Wholesale price for
plants incentivized also
by FiT with a capacity
larger than 20 kW
Treatment of net Reconciled at Indefinite carry over; Reconciled at DKK Indefinite carry over;
excess generation avoided cost customer option to 1.3/kWh (~USD 0.24) customer option to
rate / adjusted reconcile net excess at redeem at value at end
average annual annual average rate of year
market price
(varies by utility)
Grid charges USD 0.70/kW None currently. The None Included in calculation
monthly charge California Public Utilities to reflect net usage
Commission is mandated
to determine an
appropriate fixed fee not
to exceed USD 10/month.
Other/ notes Grid charge Virtual net metering Annual reconciliation Italy’s ‘scambio sul
passed in and meter aggregation replaced by hourly posto’ is differentiated
November 2013 possible. New law calls for in late 2012, after a from simple net
new rules by 2017 boom. This is leading metering due to its
to a fixed tariff basis in market pricing
Columbia had voluntary or mandatory net metering within the energy sector. Some U.S. states use the
programmes in place. utilities’ “avoided cost” to calculate the rate owed,
which is generally the cost of generation (see sub-
The practice is also expanding to South Asia and Latin section 3.2.2).
America and the Caribbean, where several countries
have introduced net metering policies in recent years, In the United States, 29 of the net metering states
often in support of rooftop PV deployment. Several have in place some kind of limit on total net me-
countries in Europe, such as Belgium, Denmark, the tered capacity – either through a defined cap
Netherlands and Italy, have adopted forms of net (usually based on a percentage of each utility’s
metering, often in addition to other support measures. peak demand) or through a trigger point at which
utilities can request a binding limit (see Figure 3.4).
The classic form of net metering employed in the These vary from 0.1% (Idaho) to 20% (Utah) of peak
majority of U.S. states credits generators with the re- demand, while Maryland and New Hampshire have
tail price that they would otherwise pay to consume in place capacity limits (1 500 MW and 50 MW, re-
from the grid – thus reimbursing them for non-power spectively). Caps on individual system size run from
network charges as well. This has sparked off a 20 kW in Wisconsin to 8 MW in New Mexico. States
continuing debate on the sharing of costs between are generally divided in their treatment of annual
different sets of consumers and other stakeholders net excess generation between allowing indefinite
43
FIGURE 3.4 STATE NET METERING LIMITS IN THE UNITED STATES
Unlimited
Capped
Trigger
No state-wide
net metering
Source: BNEF.
Note: Map does not include Alaska, which is capped.
carry-over, granting the benefit to the utility or set- through net metering) is modest compared to capaci-
tling at an avoided cost rate. ties driven by FiTs in Germany and Italy (see Figure 3.5).
Impact Assessment: Net metering has proven to be There is disagreement over the balance of costs and
an effective stimulant of distributed renewable genera- benefits associated with higher levels of net metered
tion. In fact, over 1.5 GW of solar PV capacity deployed distributed capacity. Increasingly in the United States,
in the United States in 2012 was net metered, represent- utilities argue that net metering still requires grid us-
ing 99% of the total solar installations that year (Solar age while exempting payment for it, which puts a
Electric Power Association, 2013). However, the total disproportionate cost burden on other consumers.
capacity installed in that market segment (including Meanwhile, solar advocates argue that net metering
actually saves the utility transmission and distribu-
FIGURE 3.5 COMMERCIAL AND RESIDENTIAL SMALL-SCALE PV
tion costs, because energy is generated close to
CAPACITY IN GERMANY, ITALY AND THE UNITED STATES, 2012 (GW)
consumption, and it reduces the need for expensive
25 “peaking” generating capacity. Measures such as
Commercial
GW
“value of solar” take into consideration these concerns
Residential
(see sub-section 3.2.2).
20
10
supposed to address the fact that by consuming
self-generated electricity and receiving a full retail
price for the power share fed into the grid, the net
5
metering customers avoid paying transmission
and distribution charges, which have to be spread
0 among other consumers via their electricity bills.
Germany Italy US
APS’s net metering customers now pay a monthly
Source: BNEF. charge of USD 0.70/kW of installed generating ca-
Note: Residential installation is defined as <20kW; pacity while continuing to be paid for their power at
commercial is defined as 20kW-1MW.
FIGURE 3.6 NET METERED CAPACITY VERSUS ESTIMATED LIMIT IN SELECTED U.S. STATES, H2 2013 (MW)
6,000
5,500 5,258 Estimated room
MW in limit
5,000
4,500 Current net
metered capacity
4,000
Trigger
3,500
3,000 Cap
2,500
2,000
1,500
1,500
1,000
880
487 662
500 240 182 230
0
ii s
rnia ers
ey wa ett ork nd da re
lifo Ha us wY yla va wa
Ca wJ ch Ne ar Ne a
Ne ssa M Del
Ma
Source: BNEF.
45
use storage systems as a means to export electricity by net metering customers is shifted to the utility’s cus-
when it is more profitable. tomers who do not net meter. This disparity is currently
POLICY not significant due to the limited penetration of net
INDICATOR metering-driven renewable energy deployment, but it
Renewables penetration: Low-medium-high will grow and represents a potential challenge.
As discussed in the previous section, net metering has In October 2012, Austin migrated its residential solar
come into wider use as a means of promoting renew- net metering customers to the VOS-based credit
able energy. However, concerns about rate-payer programme, for which a customer-owned system is
equity are being raised. In a typical net metering pro- eligible for 25 years. The VOS is calculated using the
gramme, the bill credit received by self-generators is following five cost inputs (see Figure 3.7):
equal to the full retail rate of the utility-delivered power
that is displaced. The retail rate of practically all regu- 1. Energy, defined as the wholesale cost of electric-
lated distribution utilities includes a “system”, “delivery” ity displaced by the customer’s generation;
or “capacity” component, which pays for the utility’s
investment in power plants, wires, transformers and 2. Capacity, defined as the cost of a new natural
other non-power assets necessary to provide service. gas-fuelled generating turbine that is avoided by
Therefore, the portion of those charges that is avoided the customer’s generation;
Energy
0.075
0.050
0.025
0.000
al º º º º is
30
º
nt 30 30 30 45 Ax
o h t t t 1- xis
riz ut es es es A
Ho So h-w W W 1-
ut
So
2020 goal. In the first year of VOS, rooftop solar capac- Policy goal: Provide adequate support for renewables,
ity installation rose 60%, leading utility officials to be triggering technology innovation
optimistic that the 25 MW goal is achievable. Policy type: Feed-in tariff
47
3.2.3 Integrating residential storage in the generated by the PV system and dispatching it to the
system grid later in the day, hence receiving the feed-in tariff;
or increasing the share of self-consumption, by storing
Net metering policies are designed to allow the export PV energy during times of low usage and consuming
of excess generation to the grid. As the penetration it later, thereby providing further independence from
of renewables increases, however, integrating high steadily increasing electricity prices (Bundesverband
shares of variable generation becomes increasingly Solarwirtschaft (BSW), 2013).
challenging. A broad range of measures are being
adopted to address this, including those incentivising Impact assessment: The economic case for PV-
self-consumption; however, storage options, such as connected energy storage depends on a specific
batteries, have been identified as the silver bullet in household’s consumption, usage patterns, the size of
addressing this challenge. Household-size storage both the PV system and the battery, how the battery is
can also support self-consumption by saving PV- cycled throughout the day, and seasonal variations.
generated energy for when it is needed. This applies Rough calculations indicate that the payback period
in particular to markets that have relatively high retail for PV-connected energy storage systems in Germany
prices, such as Germany, where residential storage ranges from 11 to 18 years, which is far too long for
can help offset electricity bills and allow the owners most customers (see Table 3.2). Despite this long pay-
to use the stored electricity when generation from back time, the programme was fully subscribed within
rooftop panels is low. months of its launch, indicating that reasons other
than payback time were motivating the uptake.
Policy overview: In May 2013, Germany launched a
EUR 25 million subsidy programme for PV-connected Another requirement of this particular programme is
energy storage. The programme provides low-interest that no more than 60% of the output from the PV sys-
loans and a grant, or “repayment bonus”, of up to 30% tem can be exported to the grid at any single moment.
of the cost of the battery system. A new PV-connected This is beneficial from a grid management standpoint
energy storage system is eligible for a grant of up to since it reduces the early-afternoon supply peak, but
EUR 600/kW of storage, while an existing PV system it makes little sense for a consumer. By accepting the
that is retrofitted with a battery could receive up to EUR subsidy and restricting the amount of electricity that
660/kW. Thus, in principle, the funding set aside for the can be exported to the grid, the recipient is limiting the
programme could pay for up to 42 MW of storage (or revenue that he or she can receive from the FiT.
38 MW of storage retrofitted to existing PV systems).
Table 3.2 illustrates the payback periods – calculated in
There are two ways for a grant recipient to operate a terms of savings on electricity bills – for various storage
storage-connected PV system: storing the electricity system costs. For instance, a 4 kW system from RWE in
SYSTEM SIZE PV SYSTEM COST PRE-SUBSIDY BATTERY NEW-BUILD SUBSIDY EXPECTED PAYBACK
(EUR/kW) SYSTEM COST (EUR/kW) WITH SUBSIDY
(EUR/kW) (YEARS)
3 750 18
3 250 16
2 750 14
4.5 kW PV and
1 460 2 250 600 12
4 kW battery
2 100 11
1 250 8
1 000 7
Source: BNEF.
Note: This assumes O&M costs for PV of 1.5% of capital expenditures,operations and maintenance costs for batteries of 2% and PV degradation of
0.7%. The two highlighted rows represent the products of RWE AG and BYD Auto Co., Ltd. Products costing <EUR 2 100/kW are not currently available
in the market.
49
4 Integration of Variable
Renewable Power
4.1 CHALLENGE: INTEGRATING to avoid a situation of plant idling due to the lack of
INCREASING GENERATION FROM evacuation or transmission infrastructure.
VARIABLE SOURCES
At a sub-national, national and regional level, as
Effective and efficient integration – in terms of physi- renewable generation increases, challenges associ-
cal connection, network management and market ated with grid availability, transmission capacity and
integration – has become a pressing challenge for the balancing costs become more prevalent. Such chal-
renewable energy sector, particularly in markets with lenges are further compounded for grids which do
higher rates of renewable penetration. A recent study not benefit from adequate interconnection capacity
concluded that technical integration is not a relevant to balance out excess or deficit generation. This sub-
constraint for integrating variable generation when section examines two case studies to illustrate these
the share of such renewables is between 5 and 10% of challenges from a developing-country (India) and
electricity generation, so long as specific best practic- developed-country (Germany) perspective.
es, such as improved forecasting, are implemented in
system operation (International Energy Agency (IEA), INDIA
2014). However, as penetration rates further increase, Renewables accounted for over 12% of India’s total in-
system integration and adaptation issues become stalled capacity of 243 GW as of March 2014 (excluding
more prominent. large hydropower) (Central Electricity Authority (CEA),
2014). Wind is the largest contributor with over 21 GW in-
This section reviews some of the different dimensions stalled, up 2 GW from the same period in 2013. Large-scale
of grid and system integration of variable renew- solar deployment has picked up pace, with more than
able energy generation, including expansion and 2.6 GW deployed, following the launch of the National
reinforcement of physical grid infrastructure, the role Solar Mission and the introduction of dedicated solar
of technological advancements in making networks policies in several states (MNRE, 2014). However, much
smarter and better able to cope with variability of of this renewable generation is concentrated in certain
supply, and the broader impacts of integrating higher pockets of the country that have the best resources as
levels of renewables on power markets. well as effective support policies (see Table 4.1).
4.1.1 Grid infrastructure In the Southern grid, for example, renewables ac-
count for almost a quarter of total generating capac-
Adequate grid infrastructure to evacuate renewable ity. The southern state of Tamil Nadu had the highest
generation and transmit it from generation sites to installed capacity of renewable energy at 7.8 GW, 7
load centres is critical for increasing the share of re- GW of which was wind. Other states with high renew-
newables in the national energy mix. At the generation able penetration rates include Maharashtra, Gujarat,
level, large-scale renewable energy plants are often Rajasthan and Karnataka.
located in remote areas, and hence the develop-
ment phase is often accompanied by an assessment The challenges associated with grid integration are
of the infrastructure needed to facilitate connection already apparent. Lack of adequate power evacu-
of the plant to nearest connection point. Experience ation capacity in the state grids has been a major
with grid integration has shown the need for extend- concern in transmission planning (GWEC, 2012). In the
ing such an assessment until the end-user in order to state of Tamil Nadu, for example, about 40% of the en-
identify early on any grid enhancement needed and ergy during peak wind season was lost due to power
Islands 0 10 80 12.5%
evacuation issues. Capacity deployment increased network. North-south grid connections are currently un-
rapidly, however the evacuation infrastructure could able to cope with the heavy flow of renewable power
not keep pace. This is evident from the fact that over- from the north to the south. Limited national grid ca-
all capacity utilisation factor for the state dipped by pacity to allow power flows from the northern wind gen-
more than 50% for the same month in 2012 and 2013 eration hub to the centre of consumption in the south
(Nampoothiri, 2014). This reduction has also been in often leads to electricity “detouring” to other countries
part due to grid congestion and limited flexibility of via the cross-border interconnections. It is not uncom-
base-load capacity operational in the region. Similar mon for renewable power generated in Germany’s
grid evacuation challenges have been faced by solar north to move through the Netherlands and France
developers who are often left with stranded generat- in the west, or Poland and the Czech Republic in the
ing assets awaiting enhancement of evacuation and east via cross-border interconnections (see Figure 4.1)
distribution infrastructure. before arriving at its final destination back in southern
Germany. The magnitude of recent cross-border flows
GERMANY has highlighted an urgent need for grid network devel-
With roughly a quarter of its power demand sourced opment, both nationally and internationally.
from renewable generation, the need for upgrading
and expanding Germany’s transmission and distri- Under its proposed 2014 EEG reform, Germany aims
bution network is emerging. The main grid-related to construct 6.5 GW of offshore wind by 2020, up from
challenges faced are distances between genera- 720 MW on line today (see Figure 4.2). The new projects
tion and consumption hubs, demand for offshore will need to be connected to the onshore grid and the
wind connections, and intensification of “power power then transported through to demand centres
loop-flows”. (see Figure 4.3).
Traditionally, fossil fuel and nuclear generation proj- 4.1.2 Maintaining system stability
ects have been constructed relatively close to de-
mand centres. By contrast, renewables projects – wind Wind and solar-generated power can displace mid-
farms, in particular – have been developed mostly merit power in liberalised markets (see sub-section
in the northern parts of the country. A large share of 4.1.3), but it cannot fully substitute other generation
Germany’s 32 GW of onshore wind capacity oper- technologies in most markets due to variable gen-
ates in the north. The hubs of German industry with eration patterns. A certain margin of dispatchable
the highest power demand, on the other hand, are generation (i.e., plants that can be switched on
centred in the southern parts of the country. and off as required, with fast ramp up/ramp down
capability) must stay on the system to supply power
This expanded average distance between power gen- in the event of lower provision from renewables. With
eration and consumption has created an urgent need increasing penetration of variable renewables, the
for a radical overhaul and expansion of Germany’s integration costs related to balancing, maintaining
51
FIGURE 4.1 AVERAGE UNSCHEDULED CROSS-BORDER POWER FLOWS FROM GERMANY, 2011-12 (MW)
Phase shifting
transformer
NL Unplanned flows
428
899
PL
435
DE Possible loop
BE 536
667 flow route
436
268 CZ
775
SK
2213
1248
AT
764
CH
FR
New HVDC
New AC
Source: German Offshore Grid Development Plan, 2014. Governments, grid operators and regulators often find
themselves in a challenging position of balancing
FIGURE 4.3 GERMANY’S ONSHORE GRID DEVELOPMENT PLAN AND
the dual objectives of supporting the deployment of
ESTIMATED COST, 2013-23
reneawble energy while maintaining grid stability and
reliability of supply. Although wholly new market de-
New HVDC
signs have yet to emerge, some countries are already
New AC
2,100 rolling out various ways to reward those on both the
Upgrades
supply and demand side of the electricity equation
for being willing to provide flexibility. Smart grid tech-
1,700
nologies can also help address this issue and energy
EUR 21bn storage technologies are poised to play a significant
role once their costs are reduced.
4,400
4.1.3 Merit-order
800
effect and price
HVAC
1,390
Demand: 71.93 GW
200
USD/MWh 180
160
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
0 20000 40000 60000 80000 100000
-20
-40
-60
-80
-100
-120
-140
-160
-180
MW
Source: BNEF.
Note: The adopted colour scheme is as follows- blue (solar and onshore wind), green (biomass), red (nuclear), brown (lignite), grey (natural gas),
black (coal) and dark grey (oil). Light blue (extreme right) signifies demand response.
Demand : 70.12 GW
USD/MWh 200
180
160
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
-20 0 40000 60000 80000 100000
-40
-60
-80
-100
-120
-140
-160
-180
MW
Source: BNEF.
53
FIGURE 4.6 AVERAGE DAILY SUMMER SPOT PRICE PROFILE IN GERMANY, 2010 AND 2013 (EUR/MWh)
60
EUR/MWh
55
Summer 2010
50
45
40
Summer 2013
35
30
25
20
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24
Hours
The dynamics of a transitioning electricity market are implementing alternative business strategies. Some
presenting particular challenges for traditional utilities. utilities have started expanding their geographical
Rising deployment of renewable energy and its impact focus and continuing their existing business models
on wholesale power prices is affecting the profitabil- (providing power generation from fossil and renewable
ity of generation assets across the utility portfolios. sources) abroad. They are targeting primarily markets
Additionally, rapidly growing deployment of decentral- with high (or growing) electricity demand to invest in
ised solutions, such as rooftop PV, is altering the tradi- thermal or large-scale renewable generation. In their
tional ownership structures that have prevailed within domestic markets, utilities are increasingly considering
the energy sector for decades. Many utilities are now various downstream activities. These may include, but
compelled to adapt their business models to be better are not limited to: demand-side management (on both
placed to tap into the opportunities that the transition the industrial and residential levels), smart-home man-
presents. Emerging technological fields, such as distrib- agement, offering distributed generation packages
uted storage, smart grids, transport sector electrification (including generation equipment and installation,
and demand response, while adding to the complexity operations and maintenance services), sale or loan of
of conventional operations, also provide opportunities energy efficiency products. New utility strategies also
for diversification of activities. require thorough organisational changes within the
utilities, which have been operating under their tradi-
As a result, utilities – particularly in Europe and tional business models for decades without the need
the United States – are considering or already for significant business innovation.
the end of 2012, inter-regional transmission capacity transmission network. In January 2014, the southern
in India was just 32 GW. The five-year plan envisages grid was synchronously connected to the rest of the
capacity to double to 65 GW by 2017, thanks to a sub- national grid as part of the country’s “One Nation – One
stantial share of the overall investment directed to this Grid – One Frequency” initiative. While this benefits the
expansion (see Figure 4.7). The plan also envisages overall management of an electricity sector faced with
improved grid management practices, centred on acute power deficits, it also has positive implications
managing variable renewable electricity generation for integrating variable renewable generation such as
through storage capacity deployment and real-time solar and wind (PIB, 2014). The plan also proposes to
monitoring of power flows, to allow early detection of establish renewable energy management centres to
stress situations. be collocated with respective load dispatch centers
at the state and regional-level. Such an arrangement
In addition to renewables-specific grid development aims at facilitating real-time data monitoring, coor-
plans, other important milestones have been reached dinated forecasting efforts and more cost-effective
recently to improve the management of India’s stressed management of the grid (POWERGRID, 2012). As such,
Energy storage
USD bn 7.23 Renewable energy management centre
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
55
to allow proper scheduling and dispatching of genera- effectively in a timely and co-ordinated manner. A
tion from wind power plants, the grid code mandated complex system of checks and balances can en-
wind energy forecasting on a day-ahead basis with sure that bottlenecks are identified early on and ad-
70% accuracy. Forecasting can be done either on an dressed through established alternative procedures.
individual developer basis or on a joint basis for an This however, requires transparent co-operation be-
aggregated generation capacity of 10 MW or above. tween the grid actors responsible for plan implementa-
Variations in actual generation beyond ± 30% of the tion, regulators and the government. A critical success
schedule leads to the generator bearing pre-set pen- factor in designing regulatory regimes that improve grid
alties (CEA, 2013). discipline and minimise costs from integrating renew-
able energy is ensuring compliance. India’s experience
Impact Assessment: A clearly defined grid investment with mandating forecasting on project developers
timeline established by policy makers can create demonstrates the need for more closely analysing the
important visibility for private sector players seeking distribution of specific responsibilities and costs across a
to make investment decisions, particularly regarding range of stakeholders that can collectively contribute to
the development of new renewable energy projects. smoother integration of renewables.
Understanding grid constraints can reduce project de-
velopment costs, prevent connection delays and lower 4.2.2 Grid development plan: Germany
risks of future curtailments. For these advantages to be
realised, however, strong implementation is needed. Policy overview: In Germany, the government has ac-
knowledged that grid upgrades must be prioritised for its
There have been several important developments in Energiewende2 to succeed. By obliging its TSOs to submit
regard to smart grid technologies in India The Ministry of binding grid development plans, Germany is ensuring
Power approved 14 smart grid pilot projects across the national network development visibility. In return, the
country with the aim of using these as test beds for sub- government has established a funding mechanism that
sequent large-scale roll out. The functionalities covered allows TSOs to pass some of the associated costs on to
in the pilot projects include advanced metering infra- the final consumers and that guarantees fixed returns
structure, demand side management and response, on investments. To ensure the successful rollout of the
outage management system, power quality manage- network development plans, in July 2013 the German
ment, renewables integration, street light automation government passed a policy package that intends to:
and smart home, electric vehicles and energy storage.
The Puducherry Smart Grid Pilot, one among the 14 »»Streamline planning procedures, making BNetzA
selected projects, has been operational with over 1400 a “one-stop shop” for obtaining all necessary
smart meters deployed, renewables integrated through planning permissions, thereby, minimising the
net metering, demand response measures in place and state-level approval requirements;
smart street lighting system introduced (POWERGRID,
2014). »»End the full network charge exemption for energy
intensive industries, with an aim to gradually move
Developers met the introduction of wind forecasting towards a system rewarding energy efficiency
regulations with scepticism, stating that compliance and creating a positive relationship between pay-
was challenging for individual projects and rallying for ments and consumption; and
more accurate, region-wide predictions which can be
conducted by a centralised dispatcher. With projects »»Extend the investment framework from sole trans-
unable to produce forecasts within the set margins, the mission upgrades and developments, to cover
regulation has been suspended temporarily (Pearson, investments in high-voltage distribution networks
2014). Regulators are now tasked with identifying the and related research and development (R&D).
most suitable mechanisms through which grid stability
can be ensured, especially while integrating growing Impact Assessment: Through this set of measures, the
shares of variable renewable generation. German government expects to secure the EUR 21
billion that the TSOs estimate will be needed to build
Risks: Major grid upgrade plans are useful to renew- 3 600 kilometres of new lines and to upgrade 4 900
able energy markets only if they are implemented kilometres of existing lines by 2023. A separate offshore
2 Energy transiton or turnaround, a term which refers to the decision to phase out nuclear power and replace it largely with renewable generation.
Source: BNEF.
future policy-making towards a more-planned grid information and communication technology into every
infrastructure development strategy. aspect of electricity generation, delivery and consump-
tion to improve reliability of the system and enable it to
POLICY react more effectively to variability in generation (IRENA,
INDICATOR
2013c). This is increasingly emerging as a significant
Renewables penetration: Medium-high
opportunity for transmission system operators as well as
Economic development: Medium-high income distribution system operators (DSOs) that are seeking to
adapt their operations towards integrating higher shares
Policy goal: Improve renewables integration, ensure
security of power supply of variable power into the grid.
grid investments, such as digital grid management. introducing regulatory frameworks for smart meter
Another related area is mandated smart meter in- rollout. The experience of Netherlands in particular
stallations, which has perhaps seen the most rapid illustrates how these concerns can be addressed.
regulatory progress in Europe.
Netherlands rollout: The Netherlands undertook a na-
SMART METER ROLLOUTS tional smart meter deployment beginning in 2012. The
Policy overview: Smart meters can act as grid sensors objective of the scheme is to install 7.5 million electric
and provide valuable information to improve distribu- and 6.5 million natural gas devices by 2020. Under the
tion grid management. Data from smart meters can initiative, smart meters are being installed in newly con-
be used to optimise voltage levels, extend the life of structed buildings as well as those under renovation.
grid assets and help pinpoint network outages, all of The initiative offers consumers an opt-out clause under
which become increasingly important as shares of which they may refuse to have a smart meter installed
variable renewable power rise. They are also comple- or may block it from being read remotely.
mentary to other measures, such as net metering,
time-of-use rates and demand response, all of which Impact assessment: By providing detailed consumption
help manage the system with high level of renewables data, smart meters have a potential to facilitate demand-
penetration. While there is variation among the spe- response activities, particularly through aggregation
cific functionalities, in general they require the substitu- of data from several smaller consumers and hence
tion of existing analogue and mechanical meters with enhancing grid management. Such data availability,
digital devices capable of transmitting and receiving however, raises privacy concerns, and the Dutch smart
data from a customer’s premises to a utility communi- meter rollout signifies an important shift in terms of data
cations network. protection. The act transferred authority for installing and
maintaining the meters from private suppliers to the coun-
The EU has mandated that member states roll out smart try’s power network operators. As a result, smart metering
meters to 80% of customers by 2020, with member nations became a regulated activity in the Netherlands, with its
having implemented the mandates to varying degrees. installation and operating costs reimbursed via retail elec-
Annual installations in the region are expected to reach tricity rates paid by the consumer.
27 million meters by 2020 (see Figure 4.9).
To address privacy concerns, the act limits how of-
The digital nature of smart meters and their ability to ten network operators may read smart meters and
actively monitor consumption patterns have raised pri- prohibits continuous data flows. Customers won op-
vacy concerns among different stakeholders, primar- tions at both ends of the continuum: adopters may
ily communities. These concerns are affecting policy- approve higher frequency data flows, while sceptics
making in terms of standardising design features and may opt out of smart grid-enabled services.
59
FIGURE 4.9 ANNUAL SMART METER INSTALLATIONS IN THE EU, 2011-2020E (MILLION METERS)
30
25 24.6
23.3
Others
21.0
Poland
20
Austria
16.5 Portugal
15 Belgium
Netherlands
10.6
Germany
10
UK
6.2
5.1 Spain
4.3
5
3.4
France
0
2011 2012 2013e 2014e 2015e 2016e 2017e 2018e 2019e 2020e
from regulators to pass associated costs on to rate- Economic development: High income
payers, caps on utility rates of return (see Box 4.2) and
Policy goal: Improve market integration of renewables;
higher capital spending priorities among utilities. ensure security and reliability of power supply; triggering
technology innovation
Data protection concerns have been a major chal-
Policy type: Utility regulation
lenge for policy makers designing smart meter
rollout schemes. Creating a central data provider to Eligible technology: Smart meters
be in charge of managing this data flow (as in the Asset ownership: N/A
Netherlands) is one way of ensuring a certain level of
Complementary policies: Net metering, time-of-use rates,
protection. However, it may be hard for such a body demand response
to provide this data to DSOs in a timely manner which
allows them to apply other mechanisms of their smart
networks to react to unexpected developments such 4.2.5 Grid-scale energy storage
as rapid demand swings. The data and privacy con-
cerns can also be addressed by allowing consumers Affordable and reliable grid-scale power storage tech-
to opt out of participating – an option which dilutes nologies can play an important role in overcoming
smart meters’ value proposition. the variability of renewable generation. Section 3.2.3
Box 4.2
THE RISK OF CAPPING UTILITY RETURNS ON SMART METER INVESTMENTS
Spain provides an example of the challenges posed by This puts the regulated rate of return at around 6.5% for
capping the rate of return that a utility can generate by 2014. Such a return is below the current weighted average
investing in smart meter infrastructure. The country’s Royal cost of capital for Spanish utilities of 7.3-8.9%. With returns for
Decree Law (RDL), passed on 1 February 2013, set rates for distributors lower than the cost of capital, grid investment
2013 and 2014. The rate of return under the RDL is based on could be stymied in the coming years, and smart metering
ten-year government bonds plus 200 basis points for 2014. and smart grid projects could be impacted.
Power quality
Reserve power Prevention of power outages
management
61
instantly. The Regulatory Authority for Electricity and Gas Risks: The rationale behind Italy’s policy is to enhance
(AEEG) is responsible for defining the return guarantee for flexibility on a grid where renewables play a vastly ex-
each project, which can be proposed by distribution and panded role compared to just five years ago. The policy
transmission system operators (DSOs and TSOs). could have a long-term effect of helping to reduce the
cost of power storage technologies by assisting the
Impact assessment: Terna has committed the largest industry in scaling up. In the short run, however, the
investments to date to meet the government’s plans. Italian policy is being implemented while such costs are
Its entity, Terna Plus, has begun work on the following still high. Although the necessity for grid-scale storage is
projects: clear, the rapidity with which costs will decline depends
on several factors, including R&D to improve efficiencies
»»Six projects accounting for 35 MW of energy in- (see Box 4.3) and achieving economies of scale.
tensive storage corresponding to 240 MWh under
the Grid Development Plan for which a 10.4% POLICY
return on assets is guaranteed by AEEG; INDICATOR
Renewable penetration: High
fined, securing a 9.9% return on assets guarantee Complementary policies: Demand response, strategic
by AEEG. Such projects will mainly contribute in reserve, smart meter rollout
ultra-fast frequency regulation and primary and
secondary regulation for renewables integration.
4.2.6 Capacity mechanisms
Terna has signed a first contract with NGK Insulators
for upto 70 MW of storage units, under which Historically, capacity mechanisms – or payments –
NGK will deliver the first 35 MW for an estimated have been introduced to ensure system stability and
EUR 100 million (NGK Insulators, 2013). The com- to secure electricity supply at times of demand spikes.
pany also plans to build 130 MW of storage in the In Europe, the policy option has been revived, as high
short-to-medium term, which represents 55 MW shares of variable renewable electricity in certain
above what was set in the Grid Development markets have increased the need for dispatchable
and Defence Plans. These storage units should back-up capacity. This is in addition to the impact
contribute greatly to grid stabilisation and load of integrating increasing renewables into the market
management, making integration of renewables (see Section 4.1.3) on wholesale electricity prices.
easier and limiting curtailment. The reduction in spot prices harms the profitability
Box 4.3
LOOKING FORWARD: RD&D FOR STORAGE DEVELOPMENT – THE CASE OF SOUTH KOREA
Given the potential of large-scale storage as a stra- by securing KRW 6.4 trillion (USD 38 billion) from the
tegic technology for grid stability, South Korea has public and private sector by 2020. By December
launched extensive research, development, and 2012, the government had committed KRW 304 billion
deployment (RD&D) programmes. With its national (USD 1.8 billion) for the 2013-2017 period. The govern-
investment plan to develop the energy storage indus- ment also hopes that the sector will be a key source
try, the country aims to become a market leader of employment.
Price »»
Established by regulator/ system »»
Variable, determined by the market
operator (usually through capacity auctions)
»»
Often linked to fixed costs of a peaking »»
Often determined by auctions (either
plant or value of lost load pay-as-bid or auctions with a uniform
clearing price)
Capacity requirement »»
Fixed by regulator/system operator/ »»
Fixed by regulator/system operator/
government government
Who earns? »»
Generators »»
Generators
»»
Occasionally tiered based on baseload »»
Incentives for different forms of capacity
and peaking plants (e.g., South Korea)` (generation, demand response,
interconnectors)
Who pays? »»
Typically suppliers (and hence »»
Typically suppliers based on peak
consumers via bill surcharges) based on consumption (plus a target margin)
consumption
63
TABLE 4.6 SELECT CAPACITY MARKET APPROACHES
An advantage of a well-functioning, technology- Risks: The attributes described above can be realised
neutral capacity market is that it establishes an with careful capacity market design. Yet there is also
equivalent value between the cost of generation a potential for failure, which could mean either that
and demand-side management: both options adequate capacity is not provided in time or that its
can equally bid into an auction, or receive cer- costs escalate and are reflected in increasing retail
tificates. This could potentially reduce the need electricity prices. Table 4.7 discusses the key elements
for additional dispatchable generation capacity. that must be considered in order to mitigate that risk.
All three capacity markets discussed here – the In its recent draft state-aid guidelines, the European
U.K., France and PJM – establish that. However, as Commission (2014) stated that any such scheme
a relatively unexplored policy option in the context must be a last resort to solving capacity adequacy
of integrating renewables, capacity markets carry problems and should be open to generators from the
several uncertainties. neighbouring countries.
Incorrect What is adequate The "reliability standard" is a measure which the U.K. grid operator develops
assessment for margin for secure each year to establish the amount of capacity it wishes to procure through
capacity needs supply? auctions. This is approved by the regulator and reviewed each year, to allow for
correction.
Inadequate How many auctions Under the PJM’s Reliability Pricing Model, a centrally cleared auction is held
number and and when? three years ahead of delivery. Incremental auctions are also organised in
timing of auctions advance of the delivery year to balance changes in load forecast and allow
suppliers to adjust their positions.
Adequate What is the In the U.K. design, a proposed auction price cap helps to prevent cost
remuneration acceptable price? escalation while ensuring that the price offered covers the so-called “cost of
new entry” with a sufficient margin.
Contracted What penalties Financial penalties are put on generators in both the PJM and the future U.K.
generation is not should be in place? capacity markets, if they fail to meet their contractual obligations.
delivered
Policy Overview: Demand response is a mechanism that The PJM market (see Section 4.2.6) is already cutting 7%
requires or encourages consumers to reduce their load off its seasonal peaks through various demand response
during periods of peak demand or in response to an actions. Although further analysis is required, a rough esti-
emergency. Due to technological, financial and regulatory mate from the Smart Energy Demand Coalition (2011) sug-
issues, demand-response mechanisms have tended to fo- gests that reductions of 6-11% in seasonal peaks are pos-
cus on large-scale industrial consumers. The arrival of smart sible in Europe through demand-response programmes,
grid technologies, however, has the potential to expand depending on the profiles of commercial, industrial and
demand-response participants to smaller consumers. residential resources available in each market.
In the context of increasing renewable genera- Most countries experiencing serious stress on their pow-
tion, demand-response incentives can contribute er systems as a result of rapid renewables growth adopt
to system stability and lower consumption peaks. several different types of demand-response schemes,
Furthermore, widespread adoption of smart grid as they consider it a cost-efficient option for smoothing
technologies – smart meters, in particular – allow for demand peaks and preparing for emergency events
demand response to play an even more active role in (which can be caused by a power station trip, renew-
contributing to system balancing. ables output drop or other system malfunctions).
65
TABLE 4.8 SELECT EUROPEAN DEMAND-RESPONSE PROGRAMMES
Design feature Demand response (DR) Short-notice and short- "Consumption blocks" DR eligible to
effectively treated as duration curtailment in can be traded on the participate in various
generation capacity system stress situations; energy market. ancillary markets.
and eligible for often TSO can cut off
"capacity payments" supply to participating
usually awarded consumers without
via auctions (more prior notice.
on capacity market
designs in sub-section
4.2.6).
Source: BNEF.
Note: Cells with blue background indicates operating programmes, while white indicates proposed or partly operating programmes and orange
indicates no DR programme in place at the moment.
supply the contracted capacity. A strong regulatory of smart infrastructure revolving around smart meters
and enforcement structure is thus needed to verify the and interactive grids.
availability of loads and to ensure the correct function-
ing of the scheme. In order to reduce this risk, several Allowing for “aggregated demand response units” is also
demand-response programmes provide the TSO with gaining currency, as purposefully created companies provid-
automatic control of the loads for short response ing aggregation platforms execute fast, targeted curtailment
times, rather than leaving it at the discretion of end- on short notice. Such operations, however, again require
customers, particularly those dealing with emergency load-control devices and digital communication technol-
situations. However, this may not always be possible or ogy to be installed at customers’ premises and linked to an
the most economically-efficient approach. aggregation platform. While this is not inherently a barrier, it
can be cost prohibitive for smaller loads. Smart metering and
In the wider context of integrating renewables and the related communications infrastructure can be leveraged
smoothing load curves, the potential from large con- to help further the penetration of demand response.
sumer demand-response schemes is fairly limited, with
many of the very biggest players, such as aluminium Finally, market design needs to enable demand-
smelters, already participating. As a result, policy mak- response participation and requires appropriate
ers are looking increasingly at small commercial and adaptation. Demand-response uptake has been
even household-level demand response as a key most successful in countries with some form of capac-
source of capacity, as is the case in France. Such ity markets, which allow for it to be effectively treated
an approach can leverage upon the emergence on par with generation. Capacity markets can allow
POLICY
INDICATOR Three key lessons can be learned from the experience
Renewable penetration: Medium-high of the countries analysed above:
67
5 The Prisms: Using Analytical
Frameworks to Hone
In on Smart Policy
W
hen it comes to renewable energy 5.1 RENEWABLE ENERGY PENETRATION
policy-making, there is no one-size-fits-all
solution. Each jurisdiction is unique with The stage of development of a renewable energy
its own set of characteristics that influences how market to some degree influences what policy goals
policies are crafted and implemented. With that in are more relevant and what types of measures are
mind, this section sets out to provide an indication most suitable. Markets with low renewable capacity
of the suitability of the policy adaptation measures on line require policy makers to focus on providing
analysed in this report to different contexts. To cap- sufficient “market-creating” support to stimulate
ture the varying conditions, this report highlights investments in the sector, while at the same time en-
four frameworks or “prisms” policy makers can look suring that developers are not overcompensated.
through as they consider which policy adaptation As the deployment of renewables increases, the fo-
approach fits best. cus tends to shift towards ensuring that the support
cost is minimised and is fairly distributed across dif-
The prisms have been constructed using the indicators ferent stakeholders. Moreover, markets with medium
discussed in the Methodology section of this report. or high penetration rates for renewables inevitably
Countries or jurisdictions are categorised based on: prompt policy-making to address the challenge
of smooth market integration, to ensure the long-
»»varying levels of renewable penetration (low, me- run security and reliability of supply. In this context,
dium or high); Figure 5.1 presents the different policy adaptation
measures discussed in this report and illustrates their
»»varying levels of economic development (low, potential relevance to markets with varying penetra-
middle or high); tion of renewables.
»»support directed at specific technologies (wind, Certain types of policies analysed in this report are
solar, smart grid, storage and others); and applicable in multiple market conditions. For instance,
holding auctions for power contracts can be a useful
»»seeking to craft policies that affect various asset means of price discovery in many markets, regard-
owners (utilities, IPPs, community/residential con- less of the level of renewable energy penetration.
sumers or commercial customers). The same could be said for establishing effective net
metering programmes. Other policy types have more
Sections 5.1 through 5.4 examine each of these limited applicability or relevance. For instance, the
categories in greater detail. Section 5.5 offers an need for capacity markets tends to become acute
example of how policy makers may apply these after renewables begin to account for enough power
prisms in conjunction with one another to construct generation to affect the grid and power markets.
a policy structure that is most appropriate for their
jurisdiction. As such, it is acknowledged that policies 5.2 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT
or policy types generally do not fit neatly into clearly
defined boxes. The “prisms” adopted in this section, A related but somewhat different question arises
however, are intended to serve as rudimentary tools around the level of market development. In most
for policy-making. cases, developing countries have seen lower levels
Integrating ‘real time capacity corridors” into the feed-in tariff reduction structure (1.2.1.)
Grid development plan - India (4.2.1.) Grid development plan - Germany (4.2.2.)
P OLI C I E S
Building third-party metrics into feed-in tariffs (1.2.2.) Implementing spending caps on support for
renewables (2.2.1.)
MINIMISE COST
GOALS
Note: The degree of blue shading indicates how appropriate the goal is for each level of renewables penetration (for example, improved
market integration of renewable power applies more to the most mature markets).
of renewable energy penetration. However, that is not the challenge of integrating substantial portions of
always the case and, in particular, some of the larger variable renewables into an established power grid or
so-called middle-income nations have seen very market.
substantial volumes of renewable capacity deployed.
The linkages between the stage of economic de-
The policy types examined for this report have varying velopment and renewables integration enablers,
levels of applicability for countries at different levels such as grids and R&D infrastructure, are strong. For
of economic development, but they are somewhat instance, grid infrastructure in low-income countries
slanted towards middle- and higher-income countries. is often marked by high losses in transmission and
This is in part because these countries have had the distribution, whereas grids in high-income countries
capacity to provide the financial support necessary are more advanced in terms of control, monitoring
to create markets for renewables domestically. As a and operation. This may affects the introduction of
consequence, they often are also the ones faced by policies, such as net metering, which have direct
69
relevance for distributed generation, since their suc- applicability in countries with low, middle and high
cess depends on the physical availability of a distribu- economic development, although until now these
tion network that can handle reverse flows as well as types of measures have been implemented particu-
regulatory structures that can manage them at a larly in middle- or higher-income countries.
system-level. Figure 5.2 maps out those interlinkages by
presenting an overview of the relevance of the policy In addition to taking into account the level of renew-
adaptation measures studied in this report for countries able energy penetration and their country’s overall
at different stages of economic development. level of economic development, a question for policy
makers revolves around the availability of resource en-
Some of the other policies illustrated here, for example dowment -- and which renewable energy technolo-
spending caps on renewables support, might have gies should be deployed to exploit these.
FIGURE 5.2 POLICIES BEST SUITED FOR DIFFERING LEVELS OF ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT
ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT
Integrating “real time capacity corridors” into the feed-in tariff reducion structure (1.2.1.)
MINIMISE COST
GOAL S
Renewable energy technologies require a specific The development or reform of renewables policies af-
mix of policies along the stages of development. fects all players involved in a country’s power genera-
Supporting their development requires a constant tion, delivery and consumption segments. Still, some
adaptation of policies that are best suited to the policies have a more direct impact on stakeholders
stage of development. While some policies can in a certain segment of the energy value chain.
be designed to be technology-specific, others can It is important to understand these impacts and to
be technology-neutral. A typical example is renew- deploy measures that can mitigate any unintended
able energy auctions, which can either be held for consequences which put at risk the broader long-
contracting capacity of a specific technology to term sustainability of the energy system.
promote its deployment, or be competitive across
technologies in identifying least-cost options. It is With increasing deployment of decentralised renew-
equally important for policies to focus in a timely able energy systems, in particular PV, the ownership
manner on other complementary non-generating structures of the energy sector are undergoing a
technologies, for example R&D of storage infrastruc- transition in many countries. Many of these systems
ture, smart grids, etc., that support the growth and are owned by individuals or community-based
smooth integration of renewables into the system. organisations. This redistribution of asset ownership
within the energy sector, as well as the increasing role
Technology-specific policies need to consider the local of renewables in meeting the electricity demand, is
resources available as well as the development of strong affecting traditional utilities in some countries (e.g., in
distribution chains. Further reduction in the levelised Europe and some U.S. states). Nearly all of the policies
cost of generating renewable energy will also come analysed in this study are directly relevant to utilities
from reducing “soft” costs (associated with installation, since a focus of this study has been markets where
connection, etc.). These are among the key reasons for renewables have achieved sufficiently enough market
the difference in deployment costs in different countries penetration to pose a challenge for energy industry
and regions. Figure 5.3 provides an overview of the incumbents. These utility-relevant policy types include:
relevance of the different policies covered in this report fostering grid scale storage projects, establishing ca-
to some generating and non-generating technologies. pacity markets, and others.
ELIGIBLE TECHNOLOGIES
Integrating “real time capacity corridors” into the feed-in tariff Grid development plans - India (4.2.1.) and
reducion structure (1.2.1.) Germany (4.2.2.)
Holding auctions for power contracts (1.2.3.) Demand response programmes (4.2.7.)
Implementing spending caps on support for renewables (2.2.1.) Smart grid implementation and smart meter
rollouts (4.2.4)
POL ICIE S
71
The analysis reveals that, irrespective of the level of eco-
nomic development and market maturity, we are likely 5.5 PUTTING THE PRISMS TO WORK
to observe (and in some markets already are observ-
ing) a shift away from the traditional central supply of This report sets out to provide an overview of the
power to a much more diverse and distributed portfolio different renewable energy policy adaptation tools
of generating assets. With the advent of small-scale available to policy makers. The prisms outlined
generation, community-wide systems, as well as in- above have been designed to allow a basic “fil-
creasingly relevant IPPs, the role of the utility is changing. tering out” of policies that may be inappropriate
under certain circumstances. Taken together,
In markets with high levels of renewables penetration, however, these prisms have the potential to allow
the most forward-looking utilities are re-thinking their busi- policy makers to hone in on the best regime for
ness models. Meanwhile, markets with less advanced their jurisdiction.
energy infrastructure now have the very real potential to
leapfrog the traditional “utility-transmission-consumer” The four prisms can be combined to produce a
model directly to more diversified systems. All of these wide variety of results. This sub-section offers just
need to be considered up-front when a new regulation one example of how the prisms can be overlaid
is being designed, and utmost consideration should against one another to yield potentially useful
be given to the impact that this shift in generating asset information. While it is not intended to capture the
ownership may have on generators, transmission sys- complexities of policy-making, the below example
tem operators, governments and consumers. Figure 5.4 merely illustrates how context-specific factors
attempts at illustrating who owns the generating assets can influence the selection of appropriate policy
that is affected by the different policies. mechanims.
Integrating “real time capacity corridors” into the feed-in tariff reducion structure (1.2.1.)
Now consider that the country policy maker also wants As discussed, there is no one-size-fits-all approach
to shield local taxpayers from bearing the costs associ- to renewable energy policy-making. Legislators
ated with the new policy. That eliminates the potential and regulators must be guided by their unique
for using most flexible tax policies to support the local local economic and political circumstances while
wind industry, and leaves just two policy options: inte- taking into account the availability of natural re-
grating “real-time capacity corridors” into the feed-in sources to fuel renewable energy projects. However,
tariff reduction structure (1.2.1) and holding auctions important insights can be gained by looking across
for power contracts (1.2.3). borders for best-practice examples. There exists
73
a short but rapidly expanding track record of how serve as rudimentary tools for those at the initial stages
certain schemes have performed, and these “lessons of designing policy schemes.
learned” can be integrated into further policy-making.
As such, the transition towards a renewable energy- There are inherent limitations on any conceptual
dominant power sector is a systemic one, involving a mechanism intended to guide policy-making. In real-
broad range of stakeholders; hence, policy-making ity, policies or policy types generally do not fit neatly
will benefit from an all-inclusive approach that consid- into clearly defined boxes. Ultimately, the most im-
ers costs and benefits across the sector. portant decisions which policy makers must take are
fundamentally qualitative.
This report took a structural approach to surveying the
landscape of innovative thinking about renewable Still, there is value in imposing a structural framework
energy policy which is now very much under way. The on such discussions. Our modest hope is that this
frameworks constructed were intended to highlight to report and the tools it offers shed useful light on the
policy makers approaches which have been adopted critical questions confronting policy makers globally.
in certain contexts and that therefore may be consid- In the best of circumstances, we hope that it guides
ered under similar circumstances. These “prisms” can better-informed policy-making.
BDEW (Bundesverband der Energie- und Wasserwirtschaft CSE (Centre for Science and Environment) (2014), “State
e.V.) (Federal Association of Energy and Water Industries) of Renewable Energy in India: A Citizen’s Report”, CSE, New
(2013), “Strengthening Markets, Securing Supply Conceptual Delhi, pp. 198.
Framework for Implementing a Strategic Reserve in Germany”,
www.bdew.de/internet.nsf/id/25273740766E25F1C1257BB90052 DECC (Department of Energy and Climate Change)
22B5/$file/130628_ExpertDialogue_StrategicReserve.pdf. (2012), “Feed-in Tariffs Scheme: Government response to
Consultation on Comprehensive Review Phase 2A: Solar
BNEF (Bloomberg New Energy Finance) (n.d.), Propreitary PV cost control”, www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/
datasets. uploads/attachment_data/file/43079/4309-feedin-tariffs-
scheme-phase-2a-consultation-paper.pdf.
BNEF (2012a), “Israel links tariffs to equipment cost for new
PV quota”, 17 August 2012, www.pua.gov.il/Sip_storage/ DECC (2013), “Levy Control Framework and Draft CfD Strike
FILES/8/2588.pdf Prices”, www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/
attachment_data/file/209361/Levy_Control_Framework_and_
BNEF (2012b), Q4 2013 Energy Smart Technologies Market Draft_CfD_Strike_Prices.pdf.
Outlook.
Dutch Ministry of Economic Affairs (n.d.), www.rvo.nl/
BNEF (2013), “European renewables: distribution automation subsidies-regelingen/sde/nieuws, accessed March 2014.
wins?”, 20 March 2013.
Eirgrid (2012), “Demand side unit workshop”, Eirgrid, 26 July,
BNetzA (n.d.), “Expansion of the electricity transmission www.eirgrid.com/media/DSU%20Workshop%20Slides%20-%20
net works”, http://www.bundesnetzagentur.de/cln_1432/ 26%20July%202012.pdf.
EN/Areas/Energy/Companies/ElectricityGridExpansion/
ElectricityGridExpansion-node.html. European Commission (2013), “Paper of the Services of DG
Competition containing draft Guidelines on environmental
Brazilian Wind Energy Conference (2013), “Brazilian wind: and energy aid for 2014-2020”, www.ec.europa.eu/
back on track”, www.cleantechinvestor.com/events/en/ competition/consultations/2013_state_aid_environment/
blogbwec2014/803-brazilian-wind-back-on-track.html. draft_guidelines_en.pdf.
BSW (Bundesverband Solarwirtschaft) (2013), “Information Eurostat (n.d.), “Eurostat”, European Commission, http://epp.
on Support Measures for Solar Power Storage Systems”, BSW- eurostat.ec.europa.eu/, accessed November 2013.
Solar Information paper, 30 August 2013, www.solarwirtschaft.
de/fileadmin/media/pdf/infopaper_energy_storage.pdf German onshore grid development plan (2013),
http://www.netzentwicklungsplan.de/en/content/
CEA (Central Electricity Authority) (2013), “Large scale grid grid-development-plan-2013-second-draft
integration of renewable energy sources- way forward”, www.
cea.nic.in/reports/powersystems/large_scale_grid_integ.pdf. German offshore grid development plan (2014), http://
www.netzentwicklungsplan.de/_NEP_file_transfer/Neue_
CEA (2014), Executive Summary Power Sector Mar-14, Netze_fuer_neue_Energien_2_Entwurf.pdf
Government Of India, Ministry of Power, Central Electricity
Authority, New Delhi, www.cea.nic.in/reports/monthly/ GlobalData (2014), “GlobalData Power database [Internet]”,
executive_rep/mar14.pdf. accessed 2014 May 25, http://power.globaldata.com/
(registration required).
CEM (Clean Energy Ministerial) (n.d.), “Solar PV: Reducing
Soft Costs”, www.cleanenergyministerial.org/Events/CEM4/ GSE (Gestore Servizi Energetici) (2014), Personal
Roundtables/Solar-PV-Reducing-Soft-Costs. communication with Luca Benedetti, GSE, May 25 2014.
GWEC (2014a), “ABEEólica celebrates record Oklahoma Legislature (2014), “An Act: Electrical power distribution
levels of wind power in Brazil”, http://www.gwec.net/ requirements”, Enrolled Senate Bill No. 1456, http://webserver1.lsb.
abeeolica-celebrates-record-levels-wind-power-brazil/. state.ok.us/cf_pdf/2013-14%20ENR/SB/SB1456%20ENR.PDF.
GWEC (2014b), “Global Wind Report: Annual Market Update Overseas Development Institute (2013), “Time to
2013”, http://www.gwec.net/wp-content/uploads/2014/04/ Change the Game: Fossil Fuel Subsidies and Climate”,
GWEC-Global-Wind-Report_9-April-2014.pdf. www.odi.org.uk/sites/odi.org.uk/files/odi-assets/
publications-opinion-files/8668.pdf.
IEA (International Energy Agency) (2014), “The Power of
Transformation: Wind, Sun and the Economics of Flexible Pearson, N. (2014), “India Reconsiders Wind Forecasting
Power Systems”, IEA,Paris, pp.239. on Inaccurate Results”, http://www.bloomberg.com/
news/2014- 03- 07/india-puts-wind-forecasting-on-hold-
International Council on Clean Transportation (2014), on-inaccurate-results.html.
“Driving Electrification: A Global Comparison of Fiscal Incentive
Policy for Electric Vehicles”, www.theicct.org/sites/default/files/ PIB (Press Information Bureau) (2012), “Accelerated
publications/ICCT_EV-fiscal-incentives_20140506.pdf. IRENA Depreciation for Wind Power Producers”, 21 May, Ministry
Costing Alliance (n.d.), http://costing.irena.org/, accessed of New and Renewable Energy, http://pib.nic.in/newsite/
May 2014. erelease.aspx?relid=84317.
IRENA (International Renewable Energy Agency) (2012), PIB (2014), “In a major achievement for the power sector,
“Electricity storage: technology brief”, www.irena.org/ Southern Grid synchronously connected with the National
DocumentDownloads/Publications/IRENA-ETSAP%20Tech%20 Power Grid”, 1 January, Ministry of New and Renewable
Brief%20E18%20Electricity-Storage.pdf. Energy, http://pib.nic.in/newsite/erelease.aspx?relid=102244.
IRENA (2013a), “Renewable Energy Auctions in Developing POWERGRID (2012), “Report on Green Energy Corridors:
Countries”, www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/ Transmission Plan for Envisaged Renewable Capacity”,
Publications/IRENA_Renewable_energy_auctions_in_ http://www.indiaenvironmentportal.org.in/files/file/Report-
developing_countries.pdf. Green%20Energy%20corridor.pdf.
IRENA (2013b), “Renewable Energy and Jobs”, www.irena. POWERGRID (2014), “Smart Grids Pilot Projects in India”,
org/rejobs.pdf. www.assocham.org/events/recent/event_960/Smart-Grid-
Pilot-project-in-India.pdf.
IRENA (2013c), “Smart Grids and Renewables: A
guide for effective deployment”. http://www.irena.org/ PUA (Israel Public Utilities Authority) (2013), “The Israeli
DocumentDownloads/Publications/smart_grids.pdf Renewable Energy Market and Regulation: Current Status
Report”, www.pua.gov.il/Sip_storage/FILES/6/3026.pdf .
IRENA (2014), Renewable Energy and Jobs – Annual Review
2014, IRENA, Abu Dhabi. Pudjianto, D., et al. (2013) Grid integration cost of
photovoltaic power generation, Imperial College,
IRENA and CEM (2014), The Socio-economic Benefits of London.
Large-scale Solar and Wind: an econValue Report, IRENA,
Abu Dhabi. PV Parity (2013), “How to support different photovoltaic
applications in the achievement of competitiveness
MNRE (Ministry of New and Renewable Energy) (2014), and beyond”, http://www.pvparity.eu/index.php?eID=tx_
“Physical Progress (Achievements)”, www.mnre.gov.in/ nawsecuredl&u=0&file=fileadmin/PVPARITY_docs/public/
mission-and-vision-2/achievements/. PVParity_Final_Report.pdf&t=1400850072&hash=8626cd597cf
e9e9226f184e8bd47f48fb9fc41ad
Nampoothiri, M. (2014), “Tamil Nadu Wind – A Victim Of Its
Own Success?”, www.re-solve.in/perspectives-and-insights/ Rabago, R.R., et al., (2012), “Designing Austin Energy’s
tamil-nadu-wind-a-victim-of-its-own-success/ Solar Tariff using a Distributed PV Value Calculator”, http://
rabagoenergy.com/files/value-of-solar-rate.pdf
Network-Transparenz (2014), TSOs’ annual “EEG
(Erneuerbare Energien Gesetz)-Umlage” announcements, REN21 (2013) “Renewables 2013 – Global Status Report”,
www.netztransparenz.de/de/EEG-Umlage.htm www.ren21.net/REN21Activities/GlobalStatusReport.aspx.
NGK Insulators (2013), “NAS Battery Energy Storage System”, REN21 (2014) “Renewables 2014 – Global Status Report”,
http://www.eei.org/meetings/Meeting_Documents/Abe.pdf. www.ren21.net/REN21Activities/GlobalStatusReport.aspx.
77
SEDA (2013), “Briefing on RE Funding Mechanism for Feed-in Tariffs”, U.S. Energy Information Agency (2014), “Market Trends:
www.st.gov.my/index.php/en/download-page/category/107- Electricity demand”, Annual Energy Outlook 2014, www.eia.
briefing-session-on-electricity-tariff-in-peninsular-malaysia-19- gov/forecasts/aeo/MT_electric.cfm#cap_natgas.
december-2013.html?download=428:briefing-on-re-funding-
mechanism-for-the-feed-in-tariff. USAID India and MNRE (2014), “Assessment of the Role
of Energy Storage Technologies for Renewable Energy
SEDC (Smart Energy Demand Coalition) (2011), Demand Deployment in India”, http://www.pace-d.com/wp-content/
response in Europe: Snapshot, SEDC, Brussels. uploads/2013/11/PACE-D-Energy-Storage-Report-Executive-
Summary-Sec.pdf.
Solar Electric Power Association (2013), “Read the News”.
www.solarelectricpower.org/read-the-news.aspx. World Bank (2013), “GNI per capita ranking, Atlas method
and PPP based”, http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/
Udasin, S. (2014), “Ministers approve renewable energy quota GNI-per-capita-Atlas-and-PPP-table.
shifts to photovoltaic sector”, The Jerusalem Post, 3 March,
www.jpost.com/Enviro-Tech/Ministers-approve-renewable- World Bank (n.d.), “How we Classify Countries”, http://data.worldbank.
energy-quota-shifts-to-photovoltaic-sector-340231. org/about/country-classifications, accessed March 2014.
Co pyright 2014