Essays in International Finance
Essays in International Finance
Essays in International Finance
Title
Essays in International Finance
Permalink
https://escholarship.org/uc/item/2648m23t
Author
Chertman, Fernando
Publication Date
2020
Peer reviewed|Thesis/dissertation
DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY
in
ECONOMICS
by
Fernando Chertman
March 2020
Professor Chenyue Hu
Fernando Chertman
2020
Table of Contents
List of Figures v
List of Tables vi
Dedication ix
Acknowledgments x
iii
2.2.1 Regional Trade Agreements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64
2.2.2 GDP, consumption, and risk sharing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67
2.2.3 Geographic Distance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70
2.3 Empirical Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71
2.3.1 Cross-country Risk Sharing and RTAs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71
2.3.2 A Gravity Model of Risk-sharing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 74
2.3.3 Gravity Model and RTA . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82
2.4 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86
2.5 References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 87
2.6 Appendices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89
iv
List of Figures
v
List of Tables
vi
Abstract
by
Fernando Chertman
This dissertation studies topics of international finance, such as the use of inter-
national reserves as a tool of monetary policies by Emerging Markets (EM), the impact
of trade costs in cross-country risk sharing, and the new observed deviations from covered
interest rate parity. Each chapter of the dissertation approach one of these three topics.
The first chapter investigates extended Taylor rules and foreign exchange inter-
vention functions in large Emerging Markets (EM), measuring the extent to which policies
are designed to stabilize output, inflation, exchange rates and accumulate international re-
serves. We focus on two large emerging markets - India and Brazil. We also consider the
impact of greater capital account openness and which rules dominate when policy conflicts
arise. We find that output stabilization is a dominant characteristic of interest rate policy
in India, as is inflation targeting in Brazil. Both countries actively use intervention policy
to achieve exchange rate stabilization and, at times, stabilizing reserves around a target
(sales) accommodate low (high) interest rates, suggesting that external operations are sub-
vii
ordinate to domestic policy objectives. We extend the work to Chile and China for purposes
of comparison. Chile’s policy functions are similar to Brazil, while China pursues policies
The second chapter empirically examines whether trade costs impede cross-country
consumption risk sharing. Using the data for a large panel of countries over the period
1970-2014, we document that bilateral risk sharing improves once a pair of countries be-
come partners under a regional trade agreement. Moreover, we establish a gravity model
of consumption risk sharing by finding that bilateral risk sharing decreases in geographi-
cal distance between countries. The effect is more pronounced in the absence of regional
trade agreements. These empirical findings support the argument that lifting trade barriers
The third and last chapter examines the deviation from covered interest rate parity.
Being a new phenomena observed especially after the 2008 Great Financial Crisis (GFC),
we measured the deviations in a cross-country setup, and explored possible causality chan-
nels for this behavior. The empirical findings in this chapter show a big heterogeneity of
causalities per country, limiting the possibilities of a unified theoretical model to explain it.
viii
To Thais, Rebeca, and Naomi,
my biggest accomplishment.
ix
Acknowledgments
It is hard to express in few pages how thankful I am to a lot of people that helped me
to conclude this dissertation. I thank my advisor Michael Hutchison for the continuous
support throughout the PhD study and research. His experience, knowledge and his careful
and practical approach have taught me invaluable lessons about how to do research. I
and Chenyue Hu for their generous support. Professor Kletzer and professor Hu have always
been so encouraging and thoughtful and it has been a great privilege to share their wisdom
and experience, and work side by side with them these years.
Besides my advisors, I also would like to thank professor Eric Aldrich and professor
Amilcar Menichini for their help and support through my Qualifying Exam. Their insights
and suggestions were very important for the development of this dissertation as well. I
am also grateful to many other professors from the UCSC Economics Department: Natalia
Lazzati, Carlos Dobkins, Nirvikar Singh, Carl Walsh, Alan Spearot, Justin Marion, Grace
Beyond research, the program also offered some great opportunities to develop
my teaching skills. I would like to thank professors Julie Gonzalez and Kai Pommerenke
for all the advising and help on supervising me as a Teaching Assistant. The Economics
Department Staff was always so helpful these years, and I can’t thank enough all the support
from Sandra Reebie, Susan Leach, Lisa Morgan, Inga Tromba, and Leigh Faulk.
There is quote that says “A man is nothing without friends”. This journey would
not be possible if done alone. Special thanks to my UCSC friends: Luka Kocic, Andrew
x
Barber, David Zink, Zijing Zhu, Jiayi Xu, Evan Miao, Yifei Sheng, Rachel Zhang, Kelsey
Pilch, Jae Hoon Choi, Akatsuki Sukeda, Alan Ledesma, Dongwan Choo.
Finally, my deep gratitude and love to my family. My parents, Moacyr and Beti,
and my brothers Marcio and Carla, Telma and Ranieri. My nephews and nieces, DanDan,
Lele, Dudu, and Hannah. I am nothing without you. I would also want to make a special
thank you to my best friend, girlfriend, and wife Thais Nagata. All that happened these
years would not happen without her help and support. And for my beatiful daughters,
xi
Chapter 1
Emerging Markets
1.1 Introduction
The traditional “trilemma” set of policy constraints, where a country needs to bal-
ance tradeoffs between degrees of monetary independence, exchange rate stability and con-
trolled capital account openness, has in the recent literature been extended to a “quadrilemma”
with a fourth policy goal of financial stability (Aizenman,2017). The later consideration for
1
the form of sharp movements in capital flows, exchange rate instability and U.S. interest
rate fluctuations. Emerging markets have always looked beyond the domestic objectives
of inflation and output gaps, emphasized in large advanced economies and embodied in
complement policy interest rates with foreign exchange market intervention and capital
controls as additional policy instruments. Given that four policy objectives are combined
with only three policy instruments (policy interest rate, intervention and capital controls),
the “Tinbergen Principle” doesn’t hold (i.e. equal instruments and objectives) and policy
makers may at times face tradeoffs in achieving all their goals. In this context, the IMF
(2012) finds that the number of countries actively managing their exchange rates has in-
creased substantially since the Global Financial Crisis and that Brazil, Chile, Colombia,
Turkey, and other emerging markets with announced inflation targeting regimes have in-
creased both the frequency and the size of their interventions. Changes in capital controls
are also a powerful macroeconomic management tool in some emerging markets (Fernandez
Theoretical work has investigated the tradeoffs associated with domestic and ex-
ternal policy objectives, and where intervention and capital controls may contribute to
macroeconomic and financial stability (e.g. Gonçalves (2008), Cavallino (2019), Farhi and
Werning (2012), Jeanne (2012)). For example, the theoretical framework of Gonçalves
(2008) argues that official accumulation of foreign reserves may be perceived as interven-
tions to influence the exchange rate, undermining the credibility of floating exchange rates
2
and inflation targets. He develops a theoretical framework to study the interaction between
reserve accumulation and monetary policy, and highlights the trade-off between the speed
In related work, Cavallino (2019) develops a New Keynesian small open economy
model that characterizes the optimal use of foreign exchange intervention in response to ex-
change rate fluctuations driven by capital flows. In his model, an increase in foreign demand
for domestic assets appreciates the domestic currency and generates a boom-bust cycle in
the economy. In response to such a shock, the optimal foreign exchange intervention in his
model is to lean against the wind and stabilize the path of the exchange rate. By lean-
ing against the wind, the central bank reduces the real appreciation (and the consumption
boom triggered by the inflow of capital) and reduces the output gap. It is not optimal for
the central bank to fully stabilize the exchange rate in this framework since it reduces some
economies, emphasize policy interest rates as reflected in Taylor rules. Taylor rules for
stabilization objective, e.g. Aizenman et al. (2011). We extend previous work investigating
modified Taylor rules by considering a second policy rule linking foreign exchange market
get level. Specifically, we explore how large emerging-market economies have in practice
managed to accumulate substantial reserve levels over time (for precautionary purposes,
reducing the likelihood of financial instability), despite substantial cyclical variation, while
3
at the same time following monetary policy rules designed to stabilize inflation, output and
We focus on two policy instruments, interest rates and foreign exchange market
intervention, and four policy objectives—inflation, output, exchange rates and foreign re-
serve target. Against this background, we also investigate (1) the impact of changes in the
intensity of capital controls, though this instrument is only infrequently cyclically applied in
most EMs, and the impact of the transmission of U.S. interest rates; and (2) cases of very
large discretionary (unpredicted) intervention operations and interest rate changes, eval-
uating whether the interest rate instrument (internal balance) or intervention operations
(external balance) dominate when policy conflicts arise. Although not able to capture all
aspects of the quadrilemma with our analysis, we are able to shed light on practical policy
considerations for internal and external balance in the use of the two major tools - monetary
Our primary interest is in two large emerging market economies, Brazil and India,
with a comparative analysis of the largest EM, China, and one small open economy, Chile.
Most theoretical and empirical work in this area focuses on small open economies (SOEs)
and attempts to measure where each country lies on a spectrum of policy tradeoffs. However,
large emerging markets should display somewhat different characteristics than SOEs in the
not in principle be completely determined by the “center country” (some inherent monetary
independence compared with the SOEs) and potential foreign capital inflows are not infinite
4
Brazil and India use capital controls extensively as a macroeconomic management
tool. Although India has been gradually reducing capital controls over the past two decades,
it continues to have quite strict international capital controls. Brazil is much more open
financially but continues with fairly extensive controls. According to the Fernandez et al.
(2016; updated online June 2019) data set on capital control restrictiveness using the IMF
underlying data source, India and Brazil placed 0.93 and 0.65, respectively in 2017. (The
India with “walls” to external financial flows and Brazil with a “gate.” Net liberalization
has occurred over the past two decades as corresponding values for India and Brazil in
2000 were 1.0 and 0.85, respectively1 . (The U.S. had a restrictiveness index of 0.16 in 2017
and 0.13 in 2000 using this methodology). This allows us to explore whether variations
management.
These emerging markets have also experienced very large reserve accumulations,
motivated at least in part by the desire to reduce the likelihood or severity of financial crises.
This fact, in combination with active foreign exchange policies, is an important element of
policies and monetary regimes are very different. In particular, the Central Bank of Brazil
has had an explicit inflation targeting regime since 2001 while the Reserve Bank of India is
1
China is also characterized by Fernandez et al. (2016) as having “walls” with a capital account re-
strictiveness measure of 0.85 in 2017 and 1.0 in 2000. Chile is more much more open, with a restrictiveness
5
characterized by substantial discretion in policy actions2 .
as well as intervention policy functions, and whether capital controls influence policy ac-
tions and the transmission of U.S. interest rate changes to policy rates. We also consider
policy (external balance) when policy conflicts arise. We use time-series methods for our
methodology and employ quarterly data. Additional features of our analysis are the incor-
poration of a measure of “adequate” reserves, calculated by the IMF, into our intervention
equation, and a measure of capital account openness, based on the work of Pasricha et al.
(2015) and Pasricha (2017), into the interest rate rule (Taylor rule) and intervention rule
equations.
counterpart to our analysis of large emerging markets, we also consider a small commodity-
based emerging market - Chile. Chile is a small open economy, largely commodity-based
and with very open capital markets. We investigate whether the revealed policy choices for
large emerging markets carry over to small emerging markets like Chile. The remainder of
management and external considerations in Brazil and India. Section 3 presents the basic
model. Section 4 presents data and methodology. Section 5 presents the empirical results
for Brazil and India. Section 6 extends the analysis to China and Chile. Section 7 concludes.
2
Chile also has an inflation targeting regime, while the People’s Bank of China monetary policy demon-
6
1.2 Macroeconomic Management in Large Emerging Market
Economies
Our focus emerging markets - India and Brazil- have experienced challenges to
macroeconomic and financial stability similar to other emerging markets and advanced
economies. Managing domestic output and inflation objectives in tandem with exchange
rate and balance of payments stability has frequently been a balancing act between multi-
ple targets and limited policy instruments. Neither of these countries explicitly state that
they follow a Taylor rule in setting interest rates, but in monetary policy statements note
that inflation is a priority and usually point to the state of the economy as a considera-
tion in setting policy. Our objective is to quantify the relative importance of these factors.
Similarly, authorities rarely provide an explicit intervention policy guide but ex post pol-
icy statements often refer to “disorderly” exchange market conditions, reserve and current
account developments, and so forth in explaining their actions. Again, our objective is to
quantity, if possible, the relative weight that these various considerations play in system-
atically influencing intervention operations. Previous research and policy statements help
In particular, the Reserve Bank of India formally states that its primary objec-
tive is to maintain price stability, while “. . . keeping in mind the objective of growth” and
announced recently a “flexible inflation targeting” regime3 . Empirical work has found that
3
The Reserve Bank of India (July 2019) states that the goals of monetary policy are:
“The primary objective of monetary policy is to maintain price stability while keeping in mind the objective
of growth. Price stability is a necessary precondition to sustainable growth.” Moreover, in May 2016, the
Reserve Bank of India (RBI) Act, 1934 was amended to provide a statutory basis for the implementation of
7
India alternates between an emphasis on output and inflation in pursuing domestic macroe-
conomic stability (Hutchison et al. 2013; Gupta and Sengupta, 2014; Kaur, 2016), and
the Reserve Bank of India (RBI) (Hutchison and Pasricha, 2016). RBI is the manager of
the foreign exchange regulation act (FEMA, 2004), which also gives it the power to im-
pose capital controls. In practice, this objective has meant very active management of
controls on international capital movements and frequent foreign exchange market inter-
vention operations, as well as at least one episode (in 2013) of interest rate defense of the
exchange rate. These considerations make understanding the linkages between monetary
policy, capital controls and foreign exchange market intervention operations central to a
Hutchison and Pasricha (2016) find that India has followed active foreign exchange
market intervention and capital control policies. They argue that intervention policy is
mainly directed toward limiting exchange rate appreciation, during which times dollar pur-
chases were generally large, and not directed toward limiting depreciation. This policy may
have allowed relative stability in the real exchange rate, hence maintaining India export
competitiveness, as the exchange rate depreciated over longer-periods to offset relative high
inflation in India. Intervention policy and exchange rate depreciation also allowed greater
monetary autonomy, especially during a period associated with increased financial liberal-
purchases on the foreign exchange market—is a desirable objective to the extent that it pro-
8
or sudden stop in private capital inflows that generally finance persistent current account
deficits in India. On the other hand, the exchange rate has not been a “nominal anchor”
for monetary policy in India, and as a consequence high inflation is a recurring problem.
that has been frequently employed to influence financial flows in and out of India and the
exchange rate (Hutchison et al. (2012); Patnaik and Shah, 2012; Hutchison and Pasricha,
2016). Although the overall trend was towards financial liberalization of the capital account,
capital control actions (i.e. tightening and easing of restrictions on capital flows) have been
actively used as an instrument to “lean against the wind” of exchange rate pressures in
both directions. Whether or not capital controls policies have been effective is evaluated by
Similar, tradeoffs between domestic and external objectives have also confronted
the Central Bank of Brazil. The country is the largest emerging market to adopt an inflation
targeting regime (IT), starting in July 1999 and formally continuing to date. Cortes and
Paiva (2017) argue that the Central Bank of Brazil (BCB) succeeded in anchoring inflation
expectations and gaining credibility until 2011, when a new discretionary-based policy was
adopted despite a formal IT rule. However, it is evident from numerous policy statements
that output stabilization is also an important element in setting interest rate policy in Brazil.
Minutes from a recent monetary policy report from the Central Bank of Brazil (2019), for
example, note that: ”The Copom members assessed that economic conditions with anchored
projected around or slightly below target, and high level of slack in the economy prescribe
9
stimulative monetary policy, i.e., interest rates below the structural interest rate level. The
structural interest rate is a reference for the conduct of monetary policy”4 . Hence, in this
case it is also of interest to measure the weights the central bank places on the inflation
target as opposed to output stabilization and other factors in setting interest rates. Other
factors may include the exchange rate. For example, Aizenman et al. (2011) find that
commodity-based emerging markets with an IT regime such as Brazil are still very likely
to smooth exchange rates as part of their Taylor Rule interest rate setting policy.
The Central Bank of Brazil also intervenes in the foreign exchange market to
smooth excessive exchange rate volatility and to manage the level of international reserves
(Gnabo et al., 2010). Although intervention activity varies over time, waning in recent years,
spot-market interventions and the sale of exchange swaps are predominantly against the
wind in terms of USD. In terms of the effectiveness of intervention, several studies find that
FX intervention, including through swaps, can affect the exchange rate, e.g. Kohlscheen and
Andrade (2014), Barroso (2014), Chamon et al. (2017), and Oliveira and Novaesk (2007).
Oliveira and Novaesk (2007), for example, find that in periods of relative tranquility the
level of the exchange rate is affected more strongly by interventions (in both the spot and
the derivatives markets) than the stance of monetary policy, while interventions appear
10
1.3 Model
The basic analytical framework consists of two policy rules: a modified Taylor rule
and a foreign exchange intervention policy function. Policy is directed toward achieving
two domestic objectives, output and inflation stabilization, and two international macroe-
conomic objectives, exchange rate stabilization and a target level of international reserves
to reduce the risk of capital stops and financial instability. Two instruments are associated
with policy functions, and one instrument, fluctuations in capital controls, is taken as a
pre-determined variable. In addition to the two policy reaction functions, foreign exchange
The Taylor rule is modified to capture the central bank’s objective of reducing
output variations around trend, inflation variations from target, and stabilize the nominal
exchange rate. Given hysteresis found in policy actions we include a lagged interest rate as
is standard in most studies. The modification of the Taylor rule to include an exchange rate
target is standard in the emerging markets literature (e.g. Aizenman et al., 2011). This
where it is the central bank interest rate operating instrument, (yt − y ∗ ) is (log) output
less (log) output trend (i.e. percentage deviation from trend output), (πt − π ∗ ) is inflation
deviation from target, (et − et−1 ) is the (log) nominal exchange rate change, and εt is the
error term. Stabilizing objectives (“leaning against the wind”) of output, inflation and the
11
exchange market (foreign exchange purchases are positive values) to stabilize the exchange
rate and to manage foreign reserves around the target level. Hence, there are potentially
two instruments focused on exchange rate management. In addition, the target level may
itself vary over time as suggested by the very rapid buildup of international reserves by
emerging market economies during the period prior to the Global Financial Crisis (GFC).
exchange are positive values and sales are negative values, as a percent of last quarter’s
the (log) of the target reserve level (i.e. percentage deviation from target reserves) and µt
is the error term. Foreign exchange sales intervention to slow exchange rate depreciation
(et − et−1 > 0) suggests β2 < 0. A rise in the stock of reserves above the target value also
the rise (fall) in international reserves equals foreign exchange intervention purchases (sales)
where i∗t−1 is the interest rate on foreign exchange reserves and VALt−1 is valuation changes
on international reserve holdings. Hence, intervention is directly linked to the target for
international reserves. Our assumption is that i∗t−1 and VALt−1 are exogenous variables.
12
As extensions of the basic models represented by equations (1) and (2), we also
include the terms-of-trade and the current account in both equations. A rise in either the
terms-of-trade or the current account have wealth and liquidity effects on the economy
and could elicit a monetary response. Similarly, a terms-of-trade change could impact
the foreign exchange market (increasing foreign exchange receipts), as could a rise in the
current account by increasing liquidity in the market. Both of these variables also have
proved important in other studies of macroeconomic policy in EMs (e.g. Aizenman et al.
2011).
We also investigate the extent to which U.S. interest rates (i∗t ) and capital ac-
count openness (opennesst ) constrain domestic interest rate policy (Taylor rule) and, for
(opennesst ), enters into decisions to intervene in the foreign exchange market. We would
expect U.S. interest rates to enter directly into interest rate policy decisions, in addition to
the indirect channel via the exchange rate, especially in the post-GFC period when greater
movement of international capital was generally allowed in both Brazil and India. The effect
of greater capital market openness (liberalization) on both interest rate and intervention
policies would depend on the directional response of net private capital flows, which in turn
outflows.
13
1.4 Data and Methodology
1.4.1 Data
We employ quarterly data over the period 1999q1-2018q4 in our analysis. The
exact sample period varies slightly between regression specifications due to data availability.
Descriptions of each variable and the date range over which they are available are explained
in the appendix5 .
statistics of Table 1 and Figures 1-7. Panel A of Table 1 shows the full sample period,
Panel B shows the pre-GFC crisis sample period and Panel C shows the post-GFC crisis
period. India generally has a much more stable macro-economy than Brazil, with lower
interest rates, lower inflation and more stable (lower standard deviation) exchange rates,
intervention and reserves (relative to “adequate” reserves)6 . Figure 1 shows the output gap;
Figure 2 inflation (and, for Brazil, evolution of the inflation target); Figure 3 money market
interest rates; Figure 4 exchange rates (left panel, level of the domestic currency per USD;
right panel, percent change); Figure 5, left column, is the level of international reserves and
the “adequate reserves” level (estimated by the IMF) and the right column is the net spot
5
Two appendices - sources of data and detailed variable definitions - are omitted from the text for brevity
prime candidates more restrictive capital controls in India and, hence, less volatile capital movements; more
volatile external shocks in Brazil associated with dependence on commodities and terms-of-trade fluctuations;
and so on. Our focus is not in addressing this issue but to compare monetary and intervention policies in the
two countries. Differences in policies, however, may play an important role in explaining relative volatility
of these economies.
14
foreign exchange market intervention; Figure 6 is the reserve gap (difference between actual
reserves and adequate reserves as a percent of adequate reserves; Figure 7 is the measure
We use a standard measure of the output gap given by the cyclical deviation of
industrial production from its trend. We seasonally adjusted both series using the U.S.
Census Bureau X-13 procedure. HP filter estimates of the logged series are employed
to obtain trend and cyclical output measures. The cyclical portion is multiplied by 100,
yielding an output gap measure that can be interpreted as the percent deviation of industrial
production from its trend level. The output gap measures are shown in Figure 1. This series
has been employed in other studies investigating monetary policy in both Brazil and India.
(Kaur, 2016; Gupta and Sengupta, 2014; De Almeida, 2003). It is evident from the figure
that output gap volatility has been much larger in Brazil than India.
As noted, Brazil has had an inflation target since 1999. This target has changed
several times over the sample period, shown in Figure 2, but for most of the sample the
midpoint target was 4.5%. India does not have an announced inflation target. For purposes
of econometric estimation, we assume the target is constant and therefore subsumed in the
constant term of the estimated Taylor rule for India. We follow other studies (e.g. Gupta
and Sengupta, 2014; Modenesi et al., 2013) and use the WPI index to construct the inflation
rate in India and the IPCA index for Brazil. Inflation averaged 4.7% in India and 5.2% in
Brazil over the sample period, with similar volatility, shown in Table 1. Brazil has been
slightly above its inflation target over the sample period (0.4% above).
Money market interest rates are employed in both studies, shown in Figure 3.
15
Despite similar inflation rates, Brazil has almost double the nominal (and real) interest rates
than India. This may reflect both real growth equilibrium factors (determining equilibrium
real interest rates), risk premium differences, institutional features of the two economies,
and that Brazil is more financially open. The stance of monetary policy is measured with
the money market interest rate. For India, this is the 3-month interbank lending rate. For
Brazil, we use the SELIC rate, which is the overnight interbank lending rate. The nominal
exchange rate employed in the study, shown in Figure 4, is the value of local currency against
the USD. Brazil has experienced higher average depreciation (1.0% quarterly average) over
the sample than India (0.7% quarterly average), shown in Table 1, and much higher exchange
rate volatility.
mestic currency sales) in the foreign exchange market, valued in millions USD, shown in the
right panels of Figure 5. This data is obtained from the Central Banks of Brazil and India,
respectively. Negative values represent foreign currency sales (domestic currency purchases)
in the foreign exchange market. The advantage of this measure is that it only reports active
intervention in the foreign exchange market and excludes interest earnings and valuation
effects on reserves. (Many studies proxy intervention by changes in reserves). Both coun-
tries actively intervened in the foreign exchange market during most of the sample period,
Reserves are defined as international reserves less gold but including SDRs, shown
in the left panels of Figure 5. Reserve data for Brazil and India are obtained from the central
bank of each country. No reserve targets are announced in either country. As a proxy, we use
16
the IMF series on reserve adequacy for both Brazil and India. The IMF defines international
reserve adequacy (RA) for emerging market economies with floating exchange rates as RA =
The IMF measure of reserve adequacy is only available at the annual level. An approximate
quarterly series is estimated using a cubic spline interpolation. The resulting quarterly series
are also plotted in the left panels of Figure 5. It is apparent that both countries grew reserves
very substantially since the early 2000s, pausing at the time of the GFC. After that period,
The reserve “gap,” measured by the difference between actual reserves and reserve
adequacy (as a percentage of reserve adequacy), is shown in Figure 6. This figure shows
that India exceeded its “reserve adequacy” metric from around 2002, peaking at almost
100% just before the GFC. Since that time, the reserve gap declined before stabilizing at
about 30%. Brazil’s reserve gap was negative until 2007 but has been consistently positive
account liberalization or restrictiveness changes based on the Pasricha et al. (2015) dataset,
updated in Pasricha (2017). This is a dataset of capital control actions for 16 emerging
market economies, where country-level measures of capital control changes are based on a
weighted sum of the capital account changes for a given year, where the weights are given by
the share of the country’s international investment position that are affected by the policy
change. We take the cumulative sum of these changes so that they can be interpreted as
the level of capital openness for a given country, albeit not comparable across countries in
17
level form. The resulting time series for Brazil and India is shown in Figure 7. This index
has been used in Pasricha et al. (2015), Pasricha (2017), and Aizenman and Binici (2016).
Some of the advantages of this series are that it results in a measure of capital openness
that varies more regularly than several measures such as the Chinn-Ito index (Chinn and
Ito, 2006) or Fernandez et al. (2016). This is because it presumably takes into account
all regulatory changes for a given country and weights them according to their estimated
1.4.2 Methodology
Turning to methodology, our baseline time series models for Brazil and India are
estimated over the 1999q1-2018q4 period. We allow for sample shifts before (1999q1-2008q4)
and after the Global Financial Crisis (2009q1-2018q4), as the external environment changed
markedly at this time, likely impacting policy behavior. We employ a methodology that
considers the endogeneity of the reserve gap. The contemporaneous reserve gap is influenced
by the scope of intervention operations. Consequently, we treat the reserve gap variable as
endogenous and instrument for it with its lagged value. Exchange rate fluctuations are likely
to suffer from a two-way causality issue as well. However, we do not employ instrumental
variables for the exchange rate. There are two reasons for this decision. First, exchange
rates are notoriously difficult to predict and thus finding a strong instrument is a daunting
task. Weak instruments lead to results that perform poorer than OLS estimates (Stock,
Wright, and Yogo 2002), and it isn’t clear that instrumenting for the exchange rate leads to
improved estimates. The second reason is that the bias of the exchange rate coefficient works
against our hypothesis. This is because lower interest rates and foreign currency purchases
18
lead to exchange rate depreciation, whereas we expect depreciation to cause higher interest
rates and purchases of domestic currency. Our results for the exchange rate can therefore
be interpreted as a lower bound on the true effect of exchange rates on interest rate and
intervention policy. Both inflation and the output gap are assumed to respond to interest
rate changes only with a lag and are treated as pre-determined variables. We estimate HAC
1.5 Results
Table 2 shows the full-sample baseline results for Brazil and India (column 1),
together with the extended model including the terms-of-trade and the current account
(column 2). Panel A reports the extended Taylor rule model estimations and Panel B
the intervention functions. Spot intervention operations are employed in the intervention
The results shown in Panel A indicate very different monetary policies pursued
by India and Brazil over the full sample period. India has systemically pursued output
one percentage point rise in the output gap. We find no evidence that the Reserve Bank of
India systematically responds to inflation or exchange rates in setting money market rates
7
We also considered a measure of intervention aggregating spot and forward transactions. The results
were unchanged, omitted for brevity, and are available from the authors upon request.
19
over the full sample period. Brazil, on the other hand, responds strongly to deviations from
its inflation target, confirming the central bank’s commitment to an IT regime, increasing
the interest rate by 60 basis points for every 1 percentage point above the inflation target.
The extended results also suggest that the Central Bank of Brazil responds to exchange rate
depreciation by raising interest rates. In sharp contrast with India, no output stabilization
model do not appear significant for India, but the terms-of-trade does enter significantly for
significant) decline in interest rates. Interest rate policy is highly persistent in both coun-
tries, especially in India (lagged dependent variable coefficient equals 0.81-0.82 in India and
0.65-0.66 in Brazil).
Although following quite different Taylor rules, India and Brazil are similar in
foreign exchange market intervention policy responses to exchange rate changes, shown
“leaning against the wind” intervention operations, selling (buying) about 0.17-0.22% in
Brazil and 0.30-0.48% in India, of the stock of international reserves in response to a one
with observable economic fundamentals. A rise (fall) in actual reserves above (below) the
target induces a significant sale (purchase) in foreign exchange (as a percent of last period’s
total reserves)8 . Differences also emerge between the two countries in terms of responses
8
This result is statistically significant in the baseline model at the 1% level, but not statistically significant
20
to terms-of-trade fluctuations and the current account. A terms-of-trade improvement in
Brazil reduces U.S. dollar intervention purchases - most likely attributable to higher foreign
highly significant for intervention policy in India, with a rise in the surplus (as a percent of
GDP) leading to a significant increase in U.S. Dollar purchases, perhaps absorbing excess
liquidity generated by the surplus in the foreign exchange market in the face of fairly
restrictive capital controls. Although the exchange rate response remains significant in
Indian intervention policy, albeit weaker than in the basic equation, targeting of reserves
It is noteworthy that both India and Brazil built very substantial foreign exchange
reserve positions during the sample period. This is reflected in the empirical model by the
We address whether policy shifts occurred at the time of the GFC in Table 3,
comparing the pre-GFC 1999Q1-2008Q4 period with the post-GFC 2009Q1-2018Q4 period.
We present both the baseline model and the extended model in Table 3, but focus our
The full sample results on output and inflation carry over to the sub-sample re-
in the extended model.
21
sults—during both sub-samples India focused on output stabilization and Brazil focused
on inflation targeting. Nonetheless, we find some evidence that India began responding to
inflation deviations in the post-crisis period9 and also to terms-of-trade changes in both
pre- and post-crisis samples. The current account is only statistically significant for India
As stated, inflation targeting dominated the Central Bank of Brazil’s interest rate
policy in both sub-periods, as it did in the full sample period, but the estimated response is
weaker in the post-GFC period10 . This finding sheds some light on the concern that Brazil
is adhering less to inflation targeting in recent years (Cortes and Paiva, 2017). However,
in the pre and post-GFC, with quite similar responses, as for the full sample period. All
the coefficient estimates are significant at the 5% level or better. By contrast, the estimates
for the two sub-samples in Brazil are not statistically significant (unlike the full sample).
in India from the pre to the post-GFC11 , and the response in the latter period - selling
foreign exchange when reserves are above target - is consistent with a stabilizing role. The
response for the reserve gap is significantly negative in Brazil both periods, with policy
9
The coefficient is 0.04 (not statistically significant) for the early period and 0.03 (statistically significant)
for the later period. The difference in coefficient values is not statistically significant.
10
However, this difference in coefficient estimates is not statistically significant at conventional levels
(z-statistic 0.96).
11
The z-statistic measuring differences in coefficient estimates is 2.53 (significant at the 5% level).
22
targeting a desired reserve level, and the coefficient estimates are similar. The terms-of-
trade played a role in intervention policy for both countries in the pre-GFC period, but not
in post-GFC period. A rise in the current account surplus induced USD purchases in both
periods for India, probably to absorb surplus liquidity in the foreign exchange market and
limit pressure on the Rupee to appreciate in the face of capital controls. Surprisingly, the
opposite result is obtained (negative and statistically significant) for Brazil in the post-GFC
period.
In this section we explore the extent to which policy interest rates in India and
Brazil are directly tied to U.S. interest rates in addition to the indirect link via the exchange
rate. We also consider the impact of external financial account openness on policy interest
The results are reported in Table 4. U.S. interest rates did not move enough
the sample so only the pre-GFC period is presented in our Taylor rule equation estimates.
Column (1) in Panel A for India and Brazil include the U.S. interest rate in the baseline
Taylor rule regression, while column (2) reports estimates with the U.S. interest rate and
openness. The estimates indicate that domestic money market rates move about 18-27
(Brazil) to 24-25 (India) basis points for a 1 percentage point move in U.S. interest rates,
The results in Table 4 suggest quite different policy responses to capital account
liberalization in India and Brazil. For India, in the pre-GFC period, an increase in openness
23
led to lower money market interest rates (8 basis points, Panel A) and sales of foreign
exchange (0.97 percent of reserves) by the central bank (Panel B). No significant impact on
intervention policy from greater openness is seen in the post-GFC. In Brazil, steps toward
greater openness (restrictiveness) also is associated with lower (higher) domestic interest
rates (61 basis points), but prompted the purchase of foreign currency by the central bank
in the pre-GFC (6.17 percent of reserves) and sales of foreign currency in the post-GFC
These differences may be explained in part by how the pattern of financial market
liberalization/openness and market conditions affected net capital flows in the two peri-
ods and across the two countries, leading to varying policy responses. Shown in Figure
7, India—though much more financially closed generally than Brazil—set out on a gradual
process of external financial liberalization over the sample period. The number of liberaliza-
tion measures (positive steps in the figure) far exceeded the number of restrictive measures
(negative steps in the figure), so that over 50 net liberalization steps were taken between
2001 and the end of 2015. Brazil, on the other hand, used capital control more as a cyclical
policy instrument, at times loosening and at times tightening controls. The number of net
liberalization steps (positive) only slightly outnumbered the number of restrictive (negative)
For India, it appears that a rise in openness led to net capital outflows in the
pre-GFC, perhaps because of a tendency to liberalize outflows more than inflows, indirectly
creating incipient pressure for currency depreciation, and in turn prompting the central
bank to “absorb” the impact on the foreign exchange market by selling foreign exchange
24
(an official capital inflow). Less private capital inflow may also have adversely impacted
domestic investment, leading the Reserve Bank of India to respond by lowering the policy
rate. The effect of liberalization of inflows and outflows may have been more balanced
The results for Brazil, on the other hand, suggest that an increase in openness led
to a surge in net private capital inflows during the pre-GFC period, leading the central bank
to offset the impact on the foreign exchange market by making large USD purchases. The
capital inflow associated with greater openness during pre-GFC was also associated with
lower money market rates, suggesting that the central bank allowed private capital inflows
to loosen domestic financial market conditions. The contrasts with post-GFC, where a net
increase in openness was associated with net capital outflows and official sales of foreign
exchange reserves. Liberalization in this period may have been more directed to relaxation
Tradeoffs between interest rate and intervention policies are not explicitly ad-
dressed using our basic methodology. It is possible that “errors” in one policy function, i.e.
deviations from predicted values, are discretionary policy actions connected to the second
policy function. For example, unexpectedly low interest rates (intervention) may be linked
the exchange rate via the Taylor rule rather than direct intervention operations. In other
words, there may be tradeoffs and substitutions between the internal and external policy
25
We address this issue in two ways. Our first approach is to estimate the two
equations using a Three Stage Least Squares (3SLS) systems estimator12 . This method
takes into account systemic linkages among the errors of the two policy equations while
also accounting for the endogeneity of the reserve gap in the intervention equation. The
estimates, not reported for brevity are virtually identical to the extended model results
reported in Table 2, column 2 for both India and Brazil’s interest rate (Panel A) and
intervention (Panel B) policy equations13 . This indicates that the error terms in the two
equations are not significantly correlated in a simple way. This is confirmed by the simple
error correlations across the two equations– statistically insignificant correlation coefficients
of -0.16 (standard error 0.11) for India and 0.02 (standard error 0.11) for Brazil.
We also explore possible linkages between large policy errors in the two equations
since policy tradeoffs or conflicts may only be manifested during particular episodes. For
example, a country may not respond to substantial pressure on the exchange rate in the
Taylor rule if domestic conditions are clearly not warranting an interest rate change, placing
greater emphasis on intervention policy. We identify the intervention policy errors (interest
rate policy errors) that are equal to or larger than the 90th percentile in absolute value and
regress these on the associated interest rate policy (intervention policy) function errors in
Table 5. These results indicate that the equations are related in a highly non-linear way.
In particular, large intervention policy errors in both India and Brazil are negatively and
12
Greene (2012) shows that the seemingly unrelated regressions model, estimated equation by equation, is
inefficient compared with an estimator that makes use of the cross-equation correlations of the disturbances.
Following Greene (2012), we estimate both equations jointly with a three-stage least squares estimator (the
26
significantly correlated with corresponding interest rate policy errors. That is, unexpectedly
large USD purchases (sales) by the foreign exchange fund are associated with lower (higher)
than predicted interest rates. This suggests that episodes of especially large unexpected
intervention purchases/sales may be designed to limit the need for interest rate changes in
macro policy management. Interestingly, we do not find that large interest rate errors are
appear to serve as a “pressure valve” when policy conflicts arise, subordinate to interest
rate policy.
In this section we contrast our results for Brazil and India with two other emerging
markets, Chile and China. The contrasts between Chile and China are stark. Chile is a small
open economy with inflation targeting, high dependence on commodity exports, flexible
exchange rates and a very open capital account. China, on the other hand, is the largest
emerging market—the second largest economy in the world after the United States—with
and largely closed to (non-FDI) external capital flows. China is also characterized by heavy
Chile is included to check the robustness of the results to a small open market-
27
inflation targeting. China, of course, is the obvious choice to include in our study due
simply to its importance to the world economy, rapid growth and buildup of international
reserves. It is not a country of emphasis in this study, but rather an extension of our work,
because China’s macroeconomic institutions differ so markedly from other large EMs.
1.6.1 Chile
Chile was the second country in the world to adopt inflation targeting (IT), setting
its first annual target in September 1990, and IT was used as a device to bring inflation
its 2019 monetary policy report:15 ”The main objective of the Central Bank of Chile’s
monetary policy is to keep inflation low, stable, and sustainable over time. Its explicit
commitment is to keep annual CPI inflation at around 3% most of the time, within a range
of plus or minus one percentage point.”16 Although the main objective of policy is focused
on inflation, it does not preclude secondary objectives and several articles suggest that both
internal and external factors may play a role in determining domestic interest rates (e.g.
Edwards, 2015). Navdon and Vial (2016), for example, emphasize the impact of commodity
prices and the exchange rate on inflation in Chile. Nonetheless, monetary policy statements
from the central bank generally do not refer to output stabilization as a reason for policy
changes.
15
Monetary Policy Report, June 2019, Central Bank of Chile.
16
This quote continues to state that output stabilization is a derivative of achieving stable inflation, but
not an explicit objective of policy: “Low, stable inflation promotes economic activity and growth while
preventing the erosion of personal income. Moreover, focusing monetary policy on achieving the inflation
28
Table 6 shows the empirical estimates results for Chile. Panel A indicates that
over the full sample period interest rate policy responded significantly in the expected ways
to both inflation and the output gap. But the estimates suggest that greater focus in
Chile was on inflation targeting in the pre-GFC period and on output targeting during
the post-GFC period17 . In the pre-GFC period, improvements in the terms-of-trade (and
associated wealth gains and improving economy) were associated with interest rate hikes.
Rising current account surpluses, in tandem with increased financial market liquidity, led
to nominal interest rate declines. No statistically significant responses to either the terms-
of-trade nor the current account were found in the post-GFC period, reflecting in part a
low and largely unchanged policy interest rate during this period18 .
Panel B of Table 5 indicates that Chile’s intervention policy targeted the reserve
gap and was also impacted by the current account (with official purchases of USD declining
17
These differences are statistically significant. The z-statistic measuring the significance of the difference
in the output gap (inflation target) is -2.60 (1.74), significant at the 1% (5%) level.
18
These differences are statistically significant. The z-statistic for the difference in coefficients on the
terms-of-trade (current account) between the two periods is 2.83 (-2.40), significant at the 1% (5%) level.
29
with a rise in the surplus) during the post-GFC19,20 . There is no systemic evidence of
intervention policy directed towards exchange rate management in the full sample period
or either sub-sample.
1.6.2 China
of China (PBoC) uses more than one instrument for monetary policy and these instruments
have evolved over time (Chen et al., 2017). The PBoC currently uses seven instruments
of implementation of monetary policy, including the rediscount rate on loans to banks and
other benchmark interest rates.21 Moreover, stronger emphasis has been placed on targeting
interest rates as the major monetary policy instrument in recent years (He and Jia, 2019).
Given China’s extensive use of capital controls and direct involvement in the banking sec-
19
We do not have central bank data on intervention for Chile and China (as we do for India and Brazil).
We proxy for intervention by the change in international reserves, adjusted for interest earnings and valuation
effects (as in equation 3). We estimate interest earnings as the U.S. interest rate multiplied by lagged level
of reserves. This adjusted series is divided by the lag level of reserves and regressed on the U.S. interest
rate, as a proxy for valuation effects. The estimated coefficient on the U.S. interest rate is multiplied by the
observed U.S. interest rate in each quarter to extract valuation effects from our intervention measure. As
a robustness test of this approach, we made the same calculation of adjusted reserves for Brazil and India,
and correlated our estimated intervention with actual intervention data. The correlations are 0.71 and 0.62,
respectively, for Brazil and India. This suggests that our “adjusted reserve change” proxy for intervention
ratios, standing lending facility, medium-term lending facility, and pledged supplementary lending facility.
30
tor and foreign exchange market, we modify the intervention equation in two ways beyond
the models estimated for the other three countries investigated. First, we extend the in-
tervention equation by including the broad money supply as an explanatory variable (M2,
measured in USD as 100*log(M2) divided by the log lag of nominal GDP)22 . In addition we
taken because tight capital controls on the financial account in China could lead to either
Table 7 shows the empirical estimates for China. Panel A shows the Taylor rule
estimates and panel B the intervention rule estimates. It is apparent that the central bank
in China raises the policy rate in respond to an uptick in inflation, a very robust link that
holds across sample periods and model specifications. Policy rates are also linked to the
output gap, but with unexpected and significant negative sign, indicating that interest rates
are reduced the larger is the output gap. Since GDP is only available for China on an annual
basis, this result could be associated with the interpolation methodology. However, when
employing industrial production rather than GDP as the output measure25 , the significant
22
This follows Schroder (2017) who finds both M2 and portfolio equity liabilities as significant determi-
nants of reserve demand. The latter variable is not available past 2011 and not employed in our study. (It
from the Lane and Milesi-Ferretti database, updated online through 2011 only).
23
We instrument the contemporaneous current account in China with three lags of itself.
24
This is related to the discussion of what constitutes intervention, “passive” increases in reserves that
may be caused by interest earnings or valuation effects or “active” purchases and sales in the foreign exchange
market. This is further complicated in the Chinese case by extensive capital controls.
25
GDP data in China is only available at an annual level. Quarterly estimates of GDP are obtained by
implementing a cubic spline interpolation. As a result, it is not possible to decompose the approximate
quarterly series into the trend and cyclical components that would be needed to calculate the output gap. A
31
positive coefficient is also obtained, and stands in contrast to estimates from the other EMs
in the sample. There is also evidence that large current account surpluses in the pre-GFC
period were associated with substantial liquidity in the Chinese financial system, leading
the central bank to reduce interest rates. No estimated linkage with the terms-of-trade is
statistically significant.
responds to (albeit small) variations in the nominal exchange rate or to the broad money
supply (M2). However, we find a strong and robust intervention response to deviations in
the reserve gap—the central bank systemically reduces its USD purchases when the reserve
gap increases. This result holds across sub-samples and model specifications. This robust
result is obtained despite the massive buildup of reserves by China, far exceeding “adequate”
levels. Moreover, there is evidence that higher current account surpluses also led to more
USD purchases prior to the GFC period, as the foreign exchange fund moved to absorb
measure of the output gap in China. A potential concern with this methodology is that the variation in the
interpolated series is being driven by statistical noise rather than actual output fluctuations in China. To
alleviate this concern, the baseline Taylor rule in China is re-estimated using both the official annual measure
of industrial production, interpolated to a quarterly series, and a quarterly measure of industrial production
growth from the OECD. These two alternative measure of the output gap leaves the results qualitatively
unchanged. Most noteworthy is that negative and statistically significant coefficients on the output gap are
robust to using industrial production. Results omitted for brevity but are available from the authors upon
request.
26
This difference is statistically significant at the 1% level (z-statistic equals 2.65)
32
line with our previous results. On the other hand, the results for China are at odds with the
estimates for the other EMs. Estimation of the output gap in the Taylor rule is particularly
problematic due to the lack of reliable quarterly output data in China. Nonetheless, we
find a strong and robust inflation response in the Taylor rule and an intervention function
1.7 Conclusion
to achieve internal and external balance. India has quite stringent capital controls, and
follows a Taylor rule dominated by an output stabilization objective. Inflation has played
a much smaller part in influencing interest rates in India, mostly evident in recent years,
and the terms-of-trade occasionally plays a role. Brazil, by contrast, has a much more
financially open economy and follows an inflation target regime that generally dominates
influence interest rates in Brazil, we find no evidence that the central bank attempts to
External policies are more similar in Brazil and India despite differences in capital
control regimes. Intervention policies in both countries focus on exchange rate stabilization,
i.e. stabilizing the exchange rate with “leaning against the wind” foreign change purchases
and sales. In terms of an external financial stability objective, India uses intervention
operations to target reserves at a level justified by economic factors. Brazil, on the other
hand, started targeting a specific level of reserves only after the Global Financial Crisis
33
(GFC). Controlling for the exchange rate and the international reserves gap, both countries
still made large net quarterly purchases of foreign exchange on average over the sample
period.
plex, depending on market conditions and the specific actions taken to lift restrictions on
capital inflows or outflows. We find that greater financial openness affected India and Brazil
varying private capital movements and intervention policy responses. We also find that
conflicts in internal and external policy occur occasionally and, for both countries, very
est rate changes. That is, large unpredicted intervention purchases (sales) accommodate
low (high) interest rates, suggesting that external operations are subordinate to domestic
policy objectives.
The results for Chile, the extension of our study to a small open economy, suggests
the central bank follows a true Taylor rule in balancing output and inflation targets but with
more emphasis on inflation prior to the GFC and on output after the GFC. The exchange
rate does not appear as a factor either in setting interest rates or intervention operations,
and targeting a particular level of reserves only appears after the GFC. China has a more
complicated institutional framework for macroeconomic policy than the other three EMs,
and quality of output data is also a concern. Nonetheless, we find that Chinese interest rate
target.
34
In conclusion, each country has its own idiosyncratic policies, varying over time,
but commonalities emerge. Policy interest rates always respond to either inflation or output
gaps, frequently both, with varying intensities, and intervention is directed toward managing
targeted international reserve levels and usually to exchange rate stabilization. Terms-of-
trade and current account fluctuations also occasionally influence intervention operations.
In conflicts between interest rate and intervention policies, the former — focused on internal
1.8 References
[1] Aizenman, J. (2017). “International Reserves, Exchange Rates and Monetary Policy:
[2] Aizenman, J., Binici, M. (2016). “Exchange market pressure in OECD and emerging
economies: Domestic vs. external factors and capital flows in the old and new normal”,
[3] Aizenman, J., Hutchison, M., Noy, I. (2011). “Inflation Targeting and Real Exchange
Rates in Emerging Markets”, World Development, May (Vol. 39, No. 5).
[5] Cavallino, P. (2019). “Capital Flows and Foreign Exchange Intervention”, American
35
[6] Central Bank of Brazil (2019). “Minutes of the 223rd Meeting of the Monetary Policy
[7] Chamon, M., Garcia, M., Souza,L. (2017). “FX Interventions in Brazil: A synthetic
[8] Chen, H., Chow, K., Tilmann, P. (2017). “The Effectiveness of Monetary Policy in
China: Evidence from a Qual VAR”, China Economic Review 43 (April), pp. 216-231.
[9] Chinn, Menzie D., Ito, Hiro (2006). “What Matters for Financial Development? Cap-
[10] Cortes, G.S., Paiva, C. (2017). “Deconstructing credibility: The breaking of monetary
policy rules in Brazil”. Journal of International Money and Finance 74 (2017) 31–52.
[11] De Almeida, C.L., Peres, M.A., Souza, G., Tabak, B. (2003). “Optimal monetary
[12] Edwards, S. (2015). “Monetary Policy Independence under Flexible Exchange Rates:
An Illusion?”. The World Economy Volume 38, Issue 5 Pages: 773-898 May 2015.
[13] Farhi, E., Werning, I. (2012). “Dealing with the Trilemma: Optimal Capital Controls
with Fixed Exchange Rates”. NBER Working Paper No. 18199. 95p.
[14] Fernandez, A., Klein, M., Rebucci, A., Schindler, M., Uribe, M. (2016). “Capital
Control Measures: A New Dataset”. IMF Economic Review, Vol. 64 (3): 548-574,
2016.
36
[15] Gnabo, J., Mello, L., Moccero, D. (2010). “Interdependencies between Monetary
Policy and Foreign Exchange Interventions under Inflation Targeting: The Case of
[17] Greene, W.H. (2012) Econometric Analysis. Prentice Hall Publishers, 7th Edition.
[18] Gupta, A.S., Sengupta, R. (2014). “Is India Ready for Flexible Monetary Targeting?”,
019 (June).
[19] He, Z., Jia, G. (2019), “An institutional analysis of China’s reform of their monetary
policy framework”, Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, Working Paper No. 925
(April).
[20] Hutchison, M., Pasricha, G. (2016). “Exchange Rate Trends and Management in
India”, in C. Ghate and K.M. Kletzer (eds.), Monetary Policy in India: A Modern
[21] Hutchison, M., Sengupta, R., Singh, N. (2013). “Dove or Hawk: Characterizing Mon-
etary Policy Regime Switches in India”, Emerging Markets Review 16, 183-202.
[22] Hutchison, M., Pasricha, G., Singh, N. (2012). “Effectiveness of capital controls in
India: evidence from offshore NDF market”. IMF Economic Review, 60(3), 395–438.
[23] International Monetary Fund (2012). Annual Report on Exchange Rate Arrangements
37
and Restrictions. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
[24] Jeanne, O. (2012). “Capital Account Policies and the Real Exchange Rate”. NBER
[25] Kaur, K. (2016), “Monetary Policy Behavior in India”, Journal of Business Thought
[27] Modenesi, A.M., Martins, N.M., Modenesi, R.L. (2013). “A modified Taylor rule
for the Brazilian economy: convention and conservatism in eleven years of inflation
[28] Navdon, A., Vial, J. (2016), “The evolution of inflation in Chile since 2000”, BIS
[29] Oliveira, F.N., Novaes, W. (2007), “The demand of foreign exchange derivatives in
brazil. hedge or speculation?”. Working Paper 152, Central Bank of Brazil. Mimeo.
[30] Pasricha, G.K., Falagiarda, M., Bijsterbosch, M., Aizenman, J. (2015). “Domestic and
No. 20822
[31] Pasricha, G.K. (2017). “Policy Rules for Capital Controls”, BIS Working Paper No.
38
[32] Patnaik, I., Shah, A. (2012). “Did the Indian Capital Controls Work as a Tool of
Macroeconomic Policy?”, Policy Corner, IMF Economic Review, Vol. 60, No. 3 (2012),
pp. 439-464.
[33] Schmidt-Hebbel, K., Tapia, M. (2002). “Inflation Targeting in Chile”, North American
[34] Schroder, M. (2017). “Mercantilism and China’s hunger for international reserves”,
[35] Stock, J., Wright, J., Yogo, M. (2002). “A Survey of Weak Instruments and Weak
• ∆e: Percent change in nominal exchange rate, closing price reported by the
Central Bank of Brazil and Reserve Bank of India. Quotations denominated in local cur-
rency per unit of US dollar. For quarterly data, exchange rate is for March 31st, June 30th,
September 30th, and December 31st (or the closest date available). We applied the log
terly GDP series reported by the Central Bank of Brazil. Log of output series filtered by
Hodrick-Prescott (HP) tecnhique. Output gap is the cyclical component of the HP-filtered
39
log(GDP) series.
• π: Inflation calculated as the anualized log change over local price index. India
is the wholesale price index, Brazil is the IPCA (National Index of Consumer Prices, elab-
orated by the Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics). Percent Annualized change,
• π ∗ : India does not publish inflation target. We assume the implicit target con-
stant through the whole period. For Brazil, IT is officially defined by the National Monetary
Council and the Central Bank is required by law to pursue it, with some allowed deviations
(tolerance bands). The IT changes through time. For 2019, it is defined as 4.25% with a
• (π − π ∗ ): The inflation gap is measured as the deviation from the target, i.e.
[100 × (ln(CP It ) − ln(CP It−4 )) − inflation target] = [100 × (ln(CP It ) − ln(CP It−4 )) − π ∗ ].
• i: Money market rate defined and controlled by the Central Bank of Brazil and
Reserve Bank of India, respectively. For Brazil we have used the “SELIC” rate, and for
India we’ve used 3 months money market defined by RBI & India: 1999Q1-2018Q4; Brazil:
2000Q1-2018Q4;
• i∗ : The US interest rate is the 3-Month Treasury Bill Rate, published by the
40
Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED).
detailed dataset for the period 2001-2015 with quarterly frequency. Each data series counts
the number of capital flow measures (for example, number of easings of inflow controls or
tightenings of outflow controls) undertaken by each country. The variables used from the
dataset weighted each policy action by the share of the country’s international assets or li-
abilities that the measure was designed to influence. The policy actions in the dataset were
counted by effective dates and included changes for which the announcement and effective
dates are different. From the dataset we explored two specific series: “wgt nettighteningin”,
and “wgt neteasingout”, that correspond to number of net inflow tightenings, weighted, and
stand the degree of openness of the countries studied, we have transformed the first series
“net inflow tightenings” to “net inflow easing” by inverting its sign (a positive tightening
means a negative easing and a negative tightening means a positive easing). With the
quarterly values of easing inflow and easing outflow we chose to work with the cumula-
tive measures of both easing inflow and outflow combined. As this variable was intended
to measure openness, we need to measure the easing policies, regardless of inflow or outflow.
41
• R∗ : The Reserve Target values are from IMF “Assessing Reserve Adequacy”.
The institution’s work compares the reserve holdings and alternative metrics of reserve ad-
equacy. This reserves adequacy measure was initially developed in the IMF Board Paper
”Assessing Reserve Adequacy” - RAM1 (February 15, 2011), and adjusted in the latest
IMF Board Paper ”Assessing Reserve Adequacy- Specific Proposals” (December 19, 2014),
in order to reflect the outflows during the Global Financial Crisis which were not addressed
in RAM1. The IMF Reserve Adequacy estimates adequate volume of reserves for a specific
country taking into account exports, imports, broad money, and other liabilities.
and the adequate level proposed by the IMF (R∗ ). Log-transformation and percentage pre-
• Appreciation: Dummy variable that assumes value equals to 1 if the local cur-
rency appreciates versus US dollar, i.e., ∆e < 0 and value equals 0 otherwise (∆e ≥ 0).
• Spot Intervention: Amount of USD bought and sold in the spot market relative
• Forward Intervention: Amount of USD bought and sold in the forward market
42
• Terms of Trade: Ratio of exports over imports. We have used the following
monthly series elaborated by the IMF: Commodity Export Price Index, Individual Com-
Price Index, and Individual Commodites Weighted by Ratio of Imports to Total Commod-
• Current account: Quarterly data on the net current account balance is obtained
from the IMF. The series is normalized by dividing the current account balance by the first
43
Table 1.1: Descriptive Statistics
Panel A: Entire Sample, 1999Q1 - 2018Q4
India Brazil
44
Panel A: Interest Rate Policy Dependent Variable: it
India Brazil
(1) (2) (1) (2)
c 1.13∗∗∗ 1.16∗∗ 3.51∗∗∗ 5.87∗∗∗
(0.39) (0.56) (1.31) (1.38)
Ŷ 0.11∗∗∗ 0.11 ∗∗∗ 0.03 0.03
(0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.04)
π − π∗ 0.02 0.02 0.60∗∗∗ 0.60∗∗∗
(0.02) (0.02) (0.22) (0.16)
∆e 0.03 0.03 0.02 0.03∗
(0.06) (0.06) (0.02) (0.015)
it−1 0.82∗∗∗ 0.81∗∗∗ 0.65∗∗∗ 0.66∗∗∗
(0.05) (0.05) (0.11) (0.04)
t.o.t. −0.00 −0.013∗∗
(0.00) (0.012)
current account −0.04 0.11
(0.03) (0.17)
R2 0.83 0.82 0.85 0.86
Num. obs. 80 76 79 79
45
Panel A: Interest Rate Policy Dependent Variable: it
India Brazil
Pre-Crisis Post-Crisis Pre-Crisis Post-Crisis
(1) (2) (3) (4) (1) (2) (3) (4)
c 1.48∗∗∗ 0.39 0.86 −6.32∗∗ 8.66∗∗∗ 5.13 1.90∗∗ −0.15
(0.50) (0.85) (0.53) (2.68) (1.55) (3, 30) (0.76) (1.27)
Ŷ 0.12∗ 0.18∗∗∗ 0.16∗∗∗ 0.15∗∗∗ 0.01 0.03 0.02 0.01
(0.07) (0.06) (0.03) (0.04) (0.03) (0.05) (0.02) (0.01)
π − π∗ −0.02 0.04 0.04∗∗ 0.03∗∗ 0.60∗∗∗ 0.61∗∗∗ 0.50∗∗∗ 0.43∗∗∗
(0.05) (0.07) (0.01) (0.02) (0.16) (0.17) (0.09) (0.08)
∆e −0.02 −0.03 0.08 0.10 0.01 −0.02 0.01 0.01
(0.03) (0.02) (0.08) (0.09) (0.03) (0.03) (0.01) (0.01)
it−1 0.79∗∗∗ 0.57∗∗∗ 0.86∗∗∗ 0.85∗∗∗ 0.41∗∗∗ 0.30∗∗∗ 0.74∗∗∗ 0.72∗∗∗
(0.05) (0.13) (0.08) (0.09) (0.08) (0.07) (0.07) (0.10)
t.o.t. 0.02∗ 0.07∗∗ 0.06 0.02
(0.01) (0.03) (0.04) (0.02)
cur. acc. −0.07∗∗ −0.07 0.13 −0.15
(0.03) (0.06) (0.22) (0.10)
R2 0.85 0.84 0.86 0.87 0.78 0.80 0.93 0.94
Num. obs. 40 36 40 40 39 39 40 40
46
Panel A: Interest Rate Policy - Pre GFC
Dependent Variable: it
India Brazil
(1) (2) (1) (2)
c 1.987∗∗∗ 3.2289∗∗∗ 6.4176∗ 8.8692∗∗
(0.3249) (0.8176) (3.4913) (4.1772)
Ŷ 0.1277∗∗ 0.2475∗∗∗ −0.0176 0.0041
(0.0691) (0.0578) (0.0390) (0.0416)
π − π∗ −0.0276 .0909 0.5248 0.5183
(0.0489) (.0849) (0.3105) (0.3798)
∆e 0.0323 0.0590 0.0089 0.0006
(0.0336) (0.0373) (0.0294) (0.0279)
it−1 0.5994∗∗∗ 0.4054∗∗∗ 0.5103∗ 0.4080
(0.0455) (0.1175) (0.2598) (0.3249)
iU S 0.2474∗∗∗ 0.236∗∗∗ 0.1872 0.2717
(0.0511) (0.0473) (0.2306) (0.3268)
openness −0.0809∗∗∗ −0.6089∗
(0.0284) (0.3550)
R2 0.8908 0.8766 0.8198 0.8369
Num. obs. 40 32 32 32
47
Dependent Variable ǫtaylor India Brazil
c 0.14 0.87∗∗∗
(0.12) (0.10)
ǫintervention |(|ǫintervention |) > p90 −0.21∗ −0.09∗
(0.11) (0.04)
R2 0.17 0.05
Num. obs. 16 16
48
Panel A: Interest Rate Policy Dependent Variable: it
Full Sample Pre-Crisis Post-Crisis
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
c 0.76∗∗∗ 1.60∗∗∗ 0.40 −2.98∗∗∗ 1.79∗∗∗ 2.11
(0.25) (0.54) (0.35) (0.95) (0.52) (1.43)
Ŷ 0.07 ∗∗∗ 0.10 ∗∗∗ 0.02 −0.03 0.21∗∗∗ 0.18∗∗
(0.03) (0.02) (0.03) (0.04) (0.06) (0.07)
π−π ∗ 0.20 ∗∗∗ 0.18 ∗∗∗ 0.22∗∗∗ 0.28 ∗∗∗ 0.05 0.07
(0.06) (0.05) (0.04) (0.05) (0.12) (0.11)
∆e 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.00 −0.01
(0.02) (0.02) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
it−1 0.64∗∗∗ 0.58∗∗∗ 0.74∗∗∗ 0.65∗∗∗ 0.44∗∗∗ 0.40∗∗∗
(0.08) (0.09) (0.08) (0.09) (0.05) (0.04)
t.o.t. −0.01 0.04∗∗∗ −0.00
(0.00) (0.01) (0.01)
current account −0.07 −0.11 ∗∗ −0.06
(0.04) (0.05) (0.05)
R2 0.81 0.82 0.84 0.88 0.84 0.85
Num. obs. 80 76 40 36 40 40
49
Panel A: Interest Rate Policy Dependent Variable: it
Full Sample Pre-Crisis Post-Crisis
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
c 2.17 ∗∗∗ 1.77 ∗ 1.57∗∗∗ 2.13 ∗∗∗ 2.86∗∗∗ 4.81
(0.66) (0.90) (0.33) (0.41) (0.92) (3.20)
Y −0.39∗∗ −0.41∗ −0.28∗ −0.39∗∗∗ −0.76∗∗ −0.86∗∗
(0.18) (0.24) (0.15) (0.07) (0.35) (0.40)
π − π∗ 0.10∗∗∗ 0.16∗∗∗ 0.04∗ 0.12∗∗∗ 0.22∗∗∗ 0.17∗∗
(0.04) (0.04) (0.02) (0.03) (0.06) (0.07)
∆e 0.00 −0.02 0.01 0.01 −0.07 −0.05
(0.02) (0.03) (0.03) (0.02) (0.05) (0.05)
it−1 0.28 ∗∗ 0.17 0.52 ∗∗∗ 0.36 ∗∗∗ 0.08 0.05
(0.13) (0.12) (0.13) (0.08) (0.12) (0.15)
t.o.t. 0.01 0.00 −0.01
(0.01) (0.00) (0.02)
current account −0.07∗∗∗ −0.07∗∗∗ −0.04
(0.02) (0.01) (0.12)
R2 0.31 0.37 0.33 0.47 0.35 0.36
Num. obs. 65 64 37 36 28 28
50
Figure 1.1: Output Gap
51
Figure 1.2: Inflation
52
Figure 1.3: Money Market Interest Rates
53
Figure 1.4: Exchange Rates
54
Figure 1.5: Reserves, Reserve Adequacy and Foreign Exchange Market Intervention
55
Figure 1.6: Reserve Gap
56
Figure 1.7: Capital Openness
57
Chapter 2
Risk Sharing
2.1 Introduction
Classic economic theories identify frictions in the goods market as an explanation for the
lack of consumption risk sharing among countries. For instance, Obstfeld and Rogoff (2001)
argue that trade costs make it costly for countries to share risk through the exchange of
goods and can therefore account for the low cross-country consumption correlations ob-
We test the theory empirically by exploiting the variation in trade costs amongst
country pairs. We find that regional trade agreements (RTA hereafter) facilitate bilateral
58
risk sharing between trade partners for a panel of 178 countries over the 1970-2014 pe-
riod. This finding based on policy shifts supports the viewpoint that reducing trade costs
establishing a gravity model of consumption risk sharing. As trade costs increase in geo-
graphical distance, we hypothesize and then confirm that bilateral risk sharing is weaker
for countries which are more distant from each other. Lastly, we find that geographical
distance becomes less relevant for consumption risk sharing once countries are RTA mem-
bers. All the evidence points towards the importance of trade costs for explaining imperfect
Following the literature, including Sorensen and Yosha (1998) and Kose et al.
(2009), we measure a country’s consumption risk sharing as the response of its relative
consumption growth to its relative output growth. A greater response suggests a lower
degree of consumption risk sharing. Consider the extreme case where two countries that face
output risk cannot trade assets or ship goods across borders, each country’s consumption
is equal to its own output. There is no risk sharing between the two countries since the
difference in their consumption growth equals that in output growth. In contrast, when
risk sharing is perfect the level of a country’s consumption does not fluctuate with its
own current output but that of the aggregate economy. As a result, the output difference
between countries does not influence their relative consumption to each other’s.
In this paper we focus on bilateral risk sharing which has received little attention
coincides with the allocation of a social planner who makes centralized decisions regardless
59
of bilateral economic exchanges. Nevertheless, in the real world there exist frictions of
different magnitudes across country pairs that segment complete markets and make bilateral
both cross-sectional and time-series variations in trade costs across country pairs. As dis-
cussed earlier, our empirical analysis consists of three parts. To start with, we examine
whether RTAs promote bilateral risk sharing. An RTA is a treaty between two or more
countries that aims to foster trade partnership. By regulating tariffs and other forms of
trade barriers, RTAs reduce the trade costs among member countries. Therefore, we ex-
amine consumption patterns around RTA events to uncover the relationship between trade
costs and risk sharing. We conduct this analysis for a panel of 178 countries who consti-
tute 31684 country pairs over the 1970-2014 period. We interact a dummy variable that
equals 1 when a pair of countries both participate in an RTA and 0 otherwise with the two
countries’ difference in output growth. With the difference in their consumption growth as
the dependent variable, the coefficient of the interaction term reveals the influence of RTAs
on bilateral risk sharing. After controlling for time fixed effects, we find that participating
in an RTA lowers the response of relative consumption to output growth by about 0.11
(equivalent to 0.9 standard deviations). The result is robust when we employ both pooled
demonstrates the impact of trade costs on consumption risk sharing. Geographical distance
is acknowledged to be a vital determinant for trade costs. The more distant countries
60
are from one another, the higher trade costs it incurs to ship goods between them. If
consumption risk sharing is hampered by trade costs, we should expect that country pairs
with greater geographical distance in between exhibit weaker risk sharing. We conduct a
two-step analysis to test this hypothesis. In the first step we calculate the bilateral risk-
sharing coefficients using the real GDP and consumption data of the 178 countries over
the 1970-2014 period in our sample. In the second step we confirm that the risk-sharing
coefficients are negatively correlated with geographic distance and positively correlated with
the product of GDPs for country pairs. We call this finding a gravity model of consumption
risk sharing. The gravity model has emerged as a workhorse in the literature due to its
empirical success in predicting bilateral trade flows. More recently, it has been applied
economic linkages across countries.1 This paper contributes to this stand of literature by
establishing a gravity model of consumption risk sharing. Based on the regression results,
growth for a country pair by 0.11 ( or 0.36 standard deviations). The result remains robust
when controlling for other common gravity variables including GDP per capita, population,
Last but not least, we bring the previous analyses together to build the causal
link between trade ties and the gravity model. Trade may not be the only channel through
which geographic distance influences risk sharing. Specifically, countries can share risks
1
For instance, Portes and Rey (2005) show that a gravity model explains international transactions in
financial assets. Ramos and Surinach (2017) use a gravity model to analyze bilateral migration in Europe.
Lustig and Richmond (2019) study the gravity effect in the factor structure of exchange rates.
61
through financial exchanges and labor mobility. Since the literature has acknowledged the
importance of geographic distance for migration and financial flows, additional evidence is
needed to attribute the gravity model of risk sharing to the trade channel. To this end,
we incorporate RTAs and geographic distance in a single regression. If the trade channel
contributes to risk sharing across countries, we should expect that geographic distance
becomes less relevant for risk sharing in the presence of RTAs. We confirm the hypothesis
and an interaction term of the RTA dummy, distance and output growth. As a result, we
conclude that trade costs can at least partially explain why risk sharing deteriorates as the
geographical distance between countries increases. This finding echoes the main argument
of the paper that trade costs impede consumption risk sharing across countries. Therefore,
lifting trade barriers will yield welfare gains by strengthening countries’ ability to share
First and foremost, imperfect consumption risk sharing remains to be one of the major
front, papers including Obstfeld and Rogoff (2001), Dumas and Uppal (2001), and Backus
and Smith (1993) study the role of trade costs in the goods market when explaining the
lack of international risk sharing. Our paper provides empirical evidence for their theories
country pairs. Besides trade costs, financial frictions that prohibit countries from trading
state-contingent assets have been acknowledged to impede cross-country risk sharing (e.g.
62
Lewis (1996) and Kollmann (1995)). In an empirical paper that also exploits institutional
changes like ours, Kose et al. (2009) examine whether financial liberalizations facilitate risk
sharing and find little evidence. In our paper we control for country-pairs’ financial liber-
alization status when studying RTA events that do not coincide with financial integration
the patterns and consequences of cross-country risk sharing. For instance, Kalemli-Ozcan
et al. (2003) find that countries or regions with better risk sharing exhibit higher indus-
trial specialization. We follow their two-step approach in our paper when constructing the
measure of risk sharing first and then exploring its correlation with variables of interest.
In Section 3.2 we establish the gravity model by finding that risk sharing increases with
country-pairs’ GDP but decreases with geographic distance. Moreover, Fitzgerald (2012)
builds a structural model to disentangle the effects of financial frictions and trade costs on
the lack of consumption risk sharing. Our paper focuses on providing empirical evidence in
the trade channel. In addition, Callen et al. (2015) evaluate the degree of risk sharing that
can be achieved by small sets of countries given that pooling worldwide risk is costly. In a
similar spirit, we examine pairwise risk sharing acknowledging the difficulty of sharing risks
This paper also contributes to the extensive empirical literature on the gravity
model. Since being introduced by Isard (1954) and Tinbergen (1962), the model has
merged as a classic framework in the trade literature due to its success in matching bi-
lateral trade flows. More recently, seminal works including Anderson and van Wincoop
63
(2003) and Eaton and Kortum (2002) refine the theoretical foundations of the framework
that rationalize empirical regularities of bilateral trade. In addition to trade, the gravity
model has recently been applied to a wide range of topics including financial assets (e.g.
Portes and Rey (2005), Martin and Rey (2004), and Okawa and van Wincoop (2012) and
labor migration (e.g. Lewer and Van den Berg (2008) and Ramos and Surinach (2017). Our
paper contributes to this literature by exploring the role of geographic distance in shaping
consumption allocations.
The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows: Section 2 describes the data and
2.2 Data
data on regional trade agreements, GDP, consumption, and geographical distance among
countries. In this section we describe how we collect and analyze the data.
We obtain the information on regional trade agreements from the World Trade Or-
(CEPII). The dummy for regional trade agreements (RTA) is 1 for the period where a pair
of countries both participate in a specific RTA. The WTO classifies RTAs into four groups:
customs unions, economic integration agreements, free trade agreements, and partial scope
64
agreements. We do not consider the last group as RTAs in our analysis since they only cover
specific goods and services. Meanwhile we exclude the events where economic integration
agreements coincide with policies that promote financial integration to isolate the effect of
Figure 2.1 displays the global map of RTAs as of July 2019. There are close to
300 RTAs signed bilaterally or multilaterally by groups of countries. Figure 2.2 tracks the
historical occurrence of RTAs. It illustrates that the coverage of RTAs has been remarkably
expanded over the decades. Table 2.6.1 provides the list of countries in our sample. For the
countries that have ever joined in any RTA from 1950 to 2014, we also list the number of
RTAs they have been a member of, number of countries that have ever been their partners
in any RTA, and the average duration (in years) of RTAs they have participated in.
Source: WTO
65
Figure 2.2: Historical RTAs
66
2.2.2 GDP, consumption, and risk sharing
We collect the real GDP, real consumption, and population data from the Penn
World Table (PWT) version 9.0. Our sample covers 178 countries over the 1970-2014 period.
Following the literature including Sorensen and Yosha (1998) and Kose et al.
(2009), we measure a country’s consumption risk sharing as the response of its relative
consumption growth to its relative output growth. Specifically, we are interested in bilat-
eral risk sharing so that we can exploit pair-specific factors including RTAs and geographic
distance in order to provide a more robust understanding of the factors that shape risk-
∆log cit − ∆log cjt = αij + βijt (∆log yit − ∆log yjt ) + ǫijt , (2.1)
where ∆log cit (∆log cjt ) denotes the growth of log real per-capita consumption of country
i(j) at time t, and ∆log yit (∆log yjt ) denotes the growth of log real per-capita output.
A higher coefficient βijt suggests a lower degree of consumption risk sharing. In the
case with perfect risk sharing, relative consumption growth should not vary with relative
output growth, which yields a coefficient of 0. In the opposite case where there is no risk
sharing, a country’s consumption is solely determined by its own output. In this scenario
relative consumption growth should equal relative output growth across countries such that
βijt = 1. Therefore, the better a country is able to share its risks with another, the smaller
will be the influence of its relative output on consumption (measured by a lower value for
βijt ). For simplicity, we define the bilateral risk-sharing coefficient as RSijt ≡ 1 − βijt . A
Table 2.1 shows the summary statistics of RSijt estimated with the annual data
67
from 1970 to 2014 for all the country pairs in our sample. Each cell reports the mean
value and the standard error is in parenthesis. Column (1) reports the coefficients for the
years when two countries are RTA partners, column (2) reports the coefficients for the years
when they are not bound by any RTA, and column (3) reports the difference between the
two coefficients. All the estimates across the three columns are significantly different from
zero at the 1% level. From the table when country-pairs are regional trade partners, the
mean value of risk-sharing coefficients is 0.572, which is much higher than the value 0.416
when countries are not partners under RTAs. If we split countries into different groups, we
find the RTAs benefit risk-sharing between industrial and developing countries to a greater
extent compared to risk-sharing between countries in the same income group. Across all
types of country pairs, there is a robust pattern that risk sharing improves under RTAs.
To exemplify the pattern, we estimate the risk-sharing coefficients RSijt over six-
year rolling windows and show them graphically for a group of European countries. As is
illustrated in Figure 2.3, bilateral risk sharing remarkably improves after the Single Market
2
Austria, Sweden, and Finland became the new member states of the treaty in 1995. The Switzerland
was not an official member, but it signed a separate treaty with the members under EFTA.
68
Table 2.1: Summary Statistics of Risk-sharing Coefficients
This table reports bilateral risk sharing coefficients RSijt ≡ 1−βijt , where βijt is estimated
from equation 2.1. Column (1) reports the coefficients for the years when two countries
are RTA partners, and column (2) reports the coefficients for the years when they are not
bound by an RTA. Each cell reports the average value in the relevant subsample and the
69
Figure 2.3: Bilateral Risk Sharing before and after RTAs
Evolution of risk sharing measured as RSijt = 1−βijt for selected pairs of countries. Vertical
influence bilateral risk sharing. The benchmark measure of geographic distance between
two countries comes from the CEPII, which calculates population-weighted distance between
the biggest cities of those two countries. For robustness, we also consider simple distance
calculated with the geographical coordinates (latitudes and longitudes) of the capital cities.
70
2.3 Empirical Analysis
ties on risk sharing. First we test whether regional trade agreements promote bilateral risk
sharing. Second we empirically establish a gravity model of risk sharing. Last we combine
the two pieces and find that geographical distance is less of an obstacle for risk sharing in
In this section we study consumption patterns around RTA events to provide evi-
dence for the influence of trade costs on consumption risk sharing. We take two approaches
to evaluate the impact of RTAs: pooled panel regressions and fixed effects models. The for-
mer approach allows us to exploit both cross-sectional and time-series variations in country
over time.
We use annual data for a panel of 178 countries who constitute 31684 country pairs
over the 1970-2014 period. Our pooled panel regression has the following specification
where ∆cit (cjt ) denotes the change in real consumption per capita of country i(j) at time t
and ∆yit (yjt ) denotes that of the real output per capita. As discussed earlier, the response of
the relative consumption growth to the relative output growth measures the two countries’
ability to share risks. Moreover, RT Aijt is a dummy variable that equals 1 for the periods
71
where the country pair participates in a regional trade agreement and 0 otherwise. A nega-
tive β3 suggests that bilateral risk sharing improves in the presence of RTAs. ηt represents
time fixed effects, which captures the world aggregate output shock at time t. ηi , ηj repre-
sent country fixed effects that capture time-invariant country-specific characteristics. The
standard errors ǫijt are clustered at country pairs to control for potential heteroskedasticity
that could potentially influence bilateral consumption risk sharing as controls, including the
product of the two countries’ population and GDP per capita in logs at time t, as well as
the two countries’ product of GDP volatility over the sample period.
Table 2.2 reports the estimation results. Panel A presents the results for the full
sample of country pairs formed by 178 countries. The coefficient estimate for the relative
output growth is around 0.3 in all the regressions. The fact that it is between 0 and 1 in
value suggests imperfect risk sharing. More importantly, the coefficient of the interaction
term with RTA and relative output growth is significantly negative, which implies that
participating a regional trade agreement facilitates a country pair’s bilateral risk sharing.
Based on the estimates, being RTA partners lowers the response of a country pair’s relative
consumption growth to output growth by 0.11 (or 0.9 standard deviations). The result holds
when we control for population, GDP per capita, and GDP volatility of the country pair.
These variables do not appear to exhibit correlations with relative consumption growth.
We then focus on the sub-sample of country pairs who have ever participated in
the same RTAs over the sample period. As is shown in Panel B, the absolute value of the
coefficient estimate for the interaction term increases, which implies that RTAs play a more
72
vital role in consumption risk sharing for countries that have a history of regional trade
partnership.
Next we employ the panel approach with a fixed effects model to quantify the im-
pact of RTAs. By including country-pair fixed effects, this approach controls for unobserved
systematic differences across country pairs around RTA events. Table 2.2 Panel C reports
the results. It demonstrates that the response of relative consumption growth to output
growth decreases by 0.112 once a country pair joins an RTA. The coefficient estimate in
this fixed effects model is similar in magnitude to that in the pooled regression for the full
access to broader goods and capital markets may change bilateral risk-sharing patterns, we
control for country-pairs’ ties with the rest of the world. To this end, we introduce the
2.6.2, the GATT/WTO membership and financial liberalization do not appear to have
a significant effect. Furthermore, the coefficient estimate for the interaction term with
RTA and relative Output growth stays significant. The fact that our finding is robust to
controlling for countries’ financial liberalization status indicate that barriers in the trade
channel remain to impede consumption risk sharing even if frictions in the asset market are
To sum up, the coefficient estimate for the interaction term of RTA and relative
output growth remains statistically and economically significant across alternative specifica-
73
tions. The finding supports the theory that reducing trade barriers promotes cross-country
risk sharing.
The dependent variable is country i’s relative consumption growth to that of country j. ∆ Output is country i’s relative
output growth to that of country j. RTA is a dummy variable which is 1 when country i and j both participate in a regional
trade agreement at t. Population is the product of the country pair’s population at t in logs. GDP is the product of the
country pair’s GDP per capita at t in logs. GDP volatility is the product of the standard deviation of the two countries’
per-capita GDP over time. The regressions include time fixed effects. In addition, pooled regressions include country fixed
effects and the panel approach includes country-pair fixed effects. Clustered standard errors reported in parentheses. ***,
**, and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level.
After establishing the importance of trade costs for risk sharing by exploiting policy
particular, we explore the implications of geographic distance for bilateral risk sharing.
74
The international economics literature has a long tradition of empirically studying
how geographical distance influences economic linkages across countries. For instance, since
being developed by Isard (1954) and Tinbergen (1962), the gravity model in international
trade remains to be a workhorse due to its empirical success in predicting bilateral trade
patterns. More recently, the gravity model has been applied to a growing range of areas to
document that economic ties between two countries — including financial and migration
flows — are inversely proportional to the geographic distance between them (e.g. Portes
and Rey (2005) and Ramos and Surinach (2017)). Nevertheless, little is known about the
impact of distance on macro fundamentals. Our paper fills the gap in the literature by
increase with geographic distance: the farther away countries are located from one another,
the higher trade costs it incurs to ship goods between them. If trade costs impede risk
sharing, we should expect that country pairs with greater geographical distance in between
exhibit weaker consumption risk sharing. Therefore, we hypothesize that there is a gravity
We test this hypothesis using a two-stage regression. In the first stage we compute
the bilateral risk-sharing coefficients for all the country pairs using annual data over the
∆log cit − ∆log cjt = αij + βij (∆log yit − ∆log yjt ) + ǫijt . (2.3)
In the second stage we regress the estimated βij on geographic distance distij :
75
We will confirm the hypothesis if γ is positive, which implies that countries which
are more distant from each other tend to exhibit a lower degree of consumption risk sharing.
In addition to the baseline specification with distance only, we augment the analysis with
standard gravity regressors including dummies for contiguity, common language, common
legal system, and time-averaged product of population in logs and GDP per capita in logs.
The values of these variables are sourced from the CEPII gravity database.
Table 2.3 reports the results of the second-stage regression. The coefficients for
geographic distance are significantly positive across all the specifications. The estimates
indicate that bilateral risk sharing decreases by about 0.01 (or 0.36 s.d.) for a 1% increase
in geographic distance. The results obtain when other gravity variables are controlled
for. Moreover, we find that bilateral risk sharing improves as a country-pair’s economic size
increases. From Column (4), a 1% increase in the product of GDP per capita raises bilateral
risk sharing by 0.051. This result indicates that more economically developed countries are
more likely to share risks with each other. Meanwhile, bilateral risk sharing decreases by
0.034 for a 1% increase in the product of population. One potential explanation is that,
there is a higher level of intra-national risk sharing in a more populous economy which
dampens the need for inter-national risk sharing. In terms of other gravity variables in
Table 2.3, we find that sharing a common language promotes bilateral risk sharing, while
having a common legal system yields less consistent results. When we control for country
sizes, similarity in legal systems does appear to facilitate risk sharing as shown in column
(4). In the same column the coefficient estimate for contiguity is positive, which contradicts
our expectation that country pairs that share borders should exhibit stronger risk sharing.
76
However, contiguity does promote risk sharing when geographic distance is controlled for,
as suggested by the sign of the interaction term in column (4). To sum up the main
findings in Table 2.3, we confirm that the signs of distance and GDP in this gravity model
of consumption risk sharing are the same as those in other gravity models including trade,
77
Table 2.3: A Gravity Model of Risk-sharing
Dep Var: βij (1) (2) (3) (4)
78
In the next step we conduct two sensitivity analyses to verify the robustness of
the gravity model. Specifically we consider an alternative measure of distance and a more
The benchmark measure of geographic distance between two countries comes from
the CEPII, which calculates population-weighted distance between the biggest cities of
those two countries. For robustness, we also consider simple distance calculated with the
geographical coordinates of the capital cities. Results reported in Table 2.6.3 suggest that
Equation 2.3 where we define and estimate the risk-sharing coefficients, we use the difference
in output growth between a pair of countries (denoted as ∆log yit − ∆log yjt ) to reflect
the countries’ idiosyncratic risks. By doing so, we implicitly assume that the two countries
have the same degree of exposure to the global shocks. In other words, when loadings of
aggregate shocks (denoted as βi , βj ) are the same, the difference in idiosyncratic risks can
be written as
(∆log yit − βi ∆log ywt ) − (∆log yjt − βj ∆log ywt ) = ∆log yit − ∆log yjt , (2.5)
where ywt is the world output per capita. However, this assumption is not valid in some
cases so that the difference in output growth is also driven by the countries’ distinct degrees
check where we adjust for countries’ different loadings of aggregate risks. First we estimate
βi , βj from
∆log yit = αi + βi ∆log ywt + ǫit , ∆log yjt = αj + βj ∆log ywt + ǫjt . (2.6)
79
Second we calculate bilateral risk-sharing coefficients from the response of consumption to
∆log cit −∆log cjt = αij +βij [(∆log yit −βi ∆log ywt )−(∆log yjt −βj ∆log ywt )]+ǫijt . (2.7)
Table 2.4 presents the result for this robustness check. Compared to Table 2.3, the coeffi-
cient estimates have identical signs and similar values. The magnitude of the coefficient for
distance is greater by about 0.003, indicating that geographic distance plays a more crucial
role in shaping risk sharing patterns when we control for countries’ different exposure to
world aggregate risks. The gravity model of risk sharing remains robust.
80
Table 2.4: Gravity model - Robustness check
Dep Var: βij (1) (2) (3) (4)
**, and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level.
81
2.3.3 Gravity Model and RTA
As the last part of the empirical analysis, we bring all the previous pieces together
and study the relationship between the gravity model of risk-sharing and regional trade
agreements (RTA). The finding will allow us to examine the impact of policy obstacles in
the trade channel on the lack of efficient risk sharing across countries.
with geographical distance among countries. All the countries share risks perfectly regard-
less of the physical distance among them. Nevertheless, there exist frictions that positively
comove with distance in the channels of risk sharing. For example, shipping costs in trade,
informational asymmetries in finance, migration cost in labor mobility are factors that pro-
hibit the channels from working efficiently to ensure perfect risk sharing. These frictions
rise with geographic distance, making risk sharing across country pairs that are physically
distant from each other increasingly difficult. These frictions can justify the gravity model
This paper focuses on trade in the goods market as a channel for risk sharing,
but frictions increase with geographic distance in various channels. Therefore, we need
additional empirical evidence to build the causal link between trade and the gravity model.
To this end, we exploit variations in RTAs as in Section 3.1 in order to attribute the gravity
Besides the lower shipping costs due to the shorter traveling distance, countries
that are physically closer to each other obtain better risk sharing through trade since they
typically face fewer trade policy distortions under RTAs. RTAs are usually signed to reduce
82
trade barriers including tariffs and quotas in order to protect the common economic interest
of a geographic region. If the trade channel contributes to risk sharing across countries,
we should expect that geographic distance poses a smaller obstacle for risk sharing in the
presence of RTAs.
∆log cit − ∆log cjt = α + β1 (∆log yit − ∆log yjt ) + β2 (ln distij )
+ηt + ηi + ηj + ǫijt .
In this specification we are particularly interested in β5 , the coefficient for RT A × log dist ×
∆y. A negative β5 implies that geographic distance impedes risk sharing to a less extent
The results presented in Table 2.5 confirm this hypothesis. The coefficients for
the three-way interaction term are significantly negative across all the regression specifi-
consumption risk sharing by 0.016 (or 0.13 s.d.) more in the absence of RTAs. The inter-
pretation of the find is that, if geographic distance is a proxy for barriers to risk sharing,
RTAs overcome these barriers regardless of distance. This finding remains robust when I
add dummies for contiguity, common language, common legal system, and time-averaged
product of population in logs, GDP in logs, and GDP volatility in the regressions. These
standard gravity controls do not show significant correlations with cross-country relative
consumption growth. The only variable that has a significant coefficient other than the
three-way interaction term is the relative output growth, implying that the failure of con-
83
sumption risk sharing is not fully explained by the listed variables. This could be driven by
the fact that there exist frictions in other channels of consumption risk sharing.
Moreover, we conduct an exercise with two stage least squares (2SLS) in order to
further identify the mechanism through which distance and RTA affect risk sharing. To
implement 2SLS, we project trade with all the gravity variables including distance and
RTA in the first step. As a second step we include the projected trade as a control variable
when testing regression 2.9. As reported in Table 2.6.4, the coefficient for the interaction
term with RTA, distance and relative output growth is no longer significant. This finding
establishes the causality that RTA and distance affect consumption patterns through their
influence on trade.
Based on these results, we confirm our hypothesis that one important channel
through which we justify the gravity model established earlier is trade in goods. Geographic
distance matters for risk sharing because they covary with trade costs. Hence once trade-
promoting policies are considered, distance becomes less relevant in shaping consumption
risk sharing patterns. Furthermore, distance and RTA no longer matter for consumption
These findings support the main argument of the paper that trade costs impede
consumption risk sharing across countries. Therefore, efforts to lift trade barriers will
84
Table 2.5: Gravity Model with RTA
Dep Var: ∆ Consumption Pooled Regression Panel Approach
(1) (2) (3) (4)
∆ Output 0.309*** 0.310*** 0.310*** 0.308***
(0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005)
RTA -1.90e-11 -2.11e-11 -2.12e-11 -3.28e-11
(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.005)
RTA × Distance 2.61e-12 2.86e-12 2.86e-12 4.33e-12
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001)
RTA × Distance × ∆ Output -0.016*** -0.016*** -0.016*** -0.016***
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.002)
Contiguity 1.66e-12 1.67e-12
(0.000) (0.000)
Language 5.12e-14 5.28e-14
(0.000) (0.000)
Legal 1.25e-13 1.32e-13
(0.000) (0.000)
GDP -3.90e-13
(0.000)
Population 4.24e-13
(0.001)
GDP volatility 9.04e-14
(0.000)
Constant -7.20e-13 -8.57e-13 -4.16e-12 -1.68e-13
(0.001) (0.001) (0.013) (0.001)
Country Pair FE Y
Country FE Y Y Y
Time FE Y Y Y Y
Observations 1,419,887 1,418,802 1,418,802 1,419,887
R-squared 0.210 0.211 0.211 0.195
The dependent variable is country i’s relative consumption growth to that of country j. ∆
Output is country i’s relative output growth to that of country j. Independent variables
include the log of geographic distance between two countries in kms, a dummy for RTA
which is 1 when country i and j both participate in a regional trade agreement at t, dum-
mies for contiguity, common language, legal system, and time-averaged product of popu-
lation in logs, GDP p.c. (per capita) in logs, and GDP p.c. volatility. The regressions
include time fixed effects. In addition, pooled regressions include country fixed effects and
the panel approach includes country-pair fixed effects. Clustered standard errors reported
in parentheses. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level.
85
2.4 Conclusion
country pairs, this paper empirically evaluates the role of trade costs in explaining the lack
of international consumption risk sharing. We obtain three major findings from a large panel
of countries over the period 1970-2014. First, bilateral risk sharing improves once a pair
of countries become partners under a regional trade agreement. Moreover, a gravity model
of consumption risk sharing obtains since bilateral risk sharing decreases in geographical
distance between countries. In addition, this effect is more pronounced in the absence of
regional trade agreements. All the evidence supports the argument that trade costs impede
This paper contributes to the growing literature that extends the gravity model
of trade to other topics including migration, financial flows, and exchange rate determina-
tion among others. Since these cross-country economic linkages also play an essential role
in international risk sharing, disentangling the influence of each channel can help us better
understand the global consumption pattern. Fitzgerald (2012) sets a nice example by quan-
tifying financial frictions and trade costs in explaining the lack of cross-country risk sharing.
Future work should incorporate other channels to account for the growing interdependence
across countries. Counterfactual analysis based on such structural frameworks will allow
policy implications, these papers call for the need of policies that aim to reduce the frictions
in the channels of risk sharing. Doing so will allow the global community to yield welfare
86
2.5 References
[1] Anderson, J. E. and van Wincoop, E. (2003). Gravity with gravitas: A solution to the
[2] Backus, D. K. and Smith, G. W. (1993). Consumption and real exchange ratesin
dynamic economies with non-traded goods. Technical report, Queen’s Economics De-
[3] Bekaert, G., Harvey, C. R., and Lundblad, C. (2004). Does financial liberalizationspur
[4] Callen, M., Imbs, J., and Mauro, P. (2015). Pooling risk among countries.Journalof
[5] Dumas, B. and Uppal, R. (2001). Global diversification, growth, and welfare withim-
70(5):1741–1779.
[7] Fitzgerald, D. (2012). Trade costs, asset market frictions, and risk sharing.Amer-ican
[8] Isard, W. (1954). Location theory and trade theory: short-run analysis.TheQuarterly
[9] Kalemli-Ozcan, S., Sorensen, B. E., and Yosha, O. (2003). Risk sharing andindustrial
87
93(3):903–918.27
[10] Kollmann, R. (1995). Consumption, real exchange rates and the structure of inter-
[11] Kose, M. A., Prasad, E. S., and Terrones, M. E. (2009). Does financial globalization-
[12] Lewer, J. J. and Van den Berg, H. (2008). A gravity model of immigration.Economics
letters, 99(1):164–167.
[13] Lewis, K. K. (1996). What can explain the apparent lack of international con-sumption
[14] Lustig, H. and Richmond, R. J. (2019). Gravity in the exchange rate factor struc-
[15] Martin, P. and Rey, H. (2004). Financial super-markets: size matters for asset-
[16] Obstfeld, M. and Rogoff, K. (2001). The six major puzzles in international macroe-
[18] Portes, R. and Rey, H. (2005). The determinants of cross-border equity flows.Journal
88
[19] Ramos, R. and Surinach, J. (2017). A gravity model of migration between the encand
[20] Sorensen, B. E. and Yosha, O. (1998). International risk sharing and europeanmone-
[21] Tinbergen, J. (1962). Shaping the world economy; suggestions for an international
economic policy.
2.6 Appendices
Albania 4 39
Algeria 2 69
Angola 2 21
Anguilla 1 28
Antigua n Barbuda 2 42
Argentina 7 44
Armenia 7 9
Aruba 1 28
Australia 10 27
Austria 41 105
Azerbaijan 5 6
89
Bahamas 2 42
Bahrain 4 17
Bangladesh 7 52
Barbados 2 42
Belarus 4 7
Belgium 44 105
Belize 2 42
Benin 3 52
Bermuda 1 28
Bhutan 4 7
Bolivia 5 43
Bosnia 3 35
Botswana 3 16
Brazil 8 46
Brunei Darussalam 8 16
Bulgaria 39 105
Burkina Faso 2 14
Burundi 4 16
Cambodia 6 15
Cameroon 3 74
Canada 10 14
Cape Verde 1 14
90
Cayman Islands 1 28
Central African 1 5
Chad 1 5
Chile 27 91
China 13 23
Colombia 11 80
Comoros 2 16
Congo 2 6
Congo, D.R. 0 0
Costa Rica 13 44
Côte d’Ivoire 2 14
Croatia 38 105
Cyprus 40 105
Denmark 44 105
Djibouti 1 1
Dominica 2 42
Dominican Republic 4 35
Ecuador 6 71
Egypt 9 105
El Salvador 11 39
Equatorial Guinea 1 5
91
Estonia 40 105
Ethiopia 2 16
Fiji 4 42
Finland 41 105
France 44 105
Gabon 1 5
Gambia 1 14
Georgia 10 37
Germany 44 105
Ghana 2 52
Greece 43 105
Grenada 2 42
Guatemala 10 38
Guinea 2 52
Guinea-Bissau 1 14
Haiti 1 14
Honduras 11 39
Hong Kong 4 7
Hungary 40 105
Iceland 29 61
India 18 52
Indonesia 8 48
92
Iran 2 42
Iraq 2 51
Ireland 44 105
Israel 8 49
Italy 44 105
Jamaica 2 42
Japan 13 15
Jordan 8 51
Kazakhstan 7 8
Kenya 4 16
Kuwait 3 16
Kyrgyzstan 6 8
Lao 9 17
Latvia 40 105
Lebanon 3 47
Lesotho 4 25
Liberia 1 14
Lithuania 40 105
Luxembourg 44 105
Macao 1 1
Macedonia 5 40
Madagascar 2 29
93
Malawi 3 21
Malaysia 13 48
Maldives 3 7
Mali 2 14
Malta 40 105
Mauritius 6 51
Mexico 20 85
Moldova 7 43
Mongolia 0 0
Montserrat 2 42
Morocco 8 85
Mozambique 2 51
Myanmar 7 48
Namibia 3 16
Nepal 4 7
Netherlands 44 105
New Zealand 10 28
Nicaragua 10 76
Niger 2 14
Nigeria 2 52
Norway 28 60
Oman 4 17
94
Pakistan 10 52
Palestine 3 33
Panama 16 44
Paraguay 7 21
Peru 17 84
Philippines 9 53
Poland 40 105
Portugal 42 105
Qatar 3 16
Romania 39 105
Russia 8 12
Rwanda 4 16
Saint Lucia 2 42
Sao Tome 0 0
Saudi Arabia 3 16
Senegal 2 14
Seychelles 3 41
Sierra Leone 1 14
Singapore 22 63
Slovakia 40 105
Slovenia 40 105
South Africa 4 44
95
South Korea 14 84
Spain 42 105
Sri Lanka 8 47
St. Kitts 2 42
Sudan 4 64
Suriname 2 42
Swaziland 5 25
Sweden 41 105
Switzerland 29 62
Syria 3 44
Taiwan 6 7
Tajikistan 2 7
Tanzania 5 58
Thailand 12 48
Togo 2 14
Trinidad n Tobago 3 82
Tunisia 7 88
Turkey 20 57
Turkmenistan 5 6
Turks n Caicos 1 28
U.A.E. 4 16
96
Uganda 4 16
Ukraine 17 45
United States 14 15
Uruguay 7 21
Uzbekistan 4 6
Venezuela 4 43
Viet Nam 9 48
Virgin Islands 1 28
Yemen 1 15
Zambia 3 21
Zimbabwe 5 86
This table reports the list of countries in our sample. For the countries that participated in any
regional trade agreement (RTA) from 1950 to 2014, we list the number of RTAs they were a
member of, the number of countries that were ever their partners in any RTA, and the average
97
Table 2.6.2: Bilateral Risk Sharing and RTA — Robustness
Dep Var: Pooled Regression Panel Approach
∆ Consumption A. Full Sample B. RTA Sample C. FE Model
(1) (2) (3)
pate in a regional trade agreement at t. WTO and BHL denote the number
Bekaert et al. (2004) in the country-pair. The regressions include time fixed
98
Table 2.6.3: A Gravity Model of Risk-sharing — Robustness with Alternative Distance
Dep Var: βij (1) (2) (3) (4)
99
Table 2.6.4: A Gravity Model of Risk-sharing — Robustness with Projected Trade
Dep Var: ∆ Consumption Pooled Regression Panel
(1) (2) (3) (4)
∆ Output 0.138*** 0.138*** 0.138*** 0.135***
(0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005)
RTA -0.001 -4.37E-04 -0.001 2.23e-4
(0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.008)
RTA × Distance 1.07E-04 1.33E-05 3.28E-05 -1.15e-4
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001)
RTA × Distance × ∆ Output 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.002
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
T\
rade 2.35E-04 3.21E-04 3.35E-04 5.19e-4
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Contiguity -7.55E-04 -7.96E-04
(0.001) (0.001)
Language -2.56E-04 -2.52E-04
(0.000) (0.000)
Legal -1.13E-04 -8.16E-05
(0.000) (0.000)
GDP -9.45E-04
(0.002)
Population 0.002
(0.003)
GDP volatility 4.09E-04
(0.001)
Constant -0.004 -0.006 -0.05 -0.01
(0.005) (0.005) (0.055) (0.007)
Country FE Y Y Y Y
Year FE Y Y Y Y
Observations 431,132 431,132 431,132 431,132
R-squared 0.112 0.112 0.112 0.0839
The dependent variable is country i’s relative consumption growth to that of coun-
try j. ∆ Output is country i’s relative output growth to that of country j. Indepen-
dent variables include the log of geographic distance between two countries in kms,
a dummy for RTA which is 1 when country i and j both participate in a regional
dummies for contiguity, common language, legal system, and time-averaged prod-
uct of population in logs, GDP p.c. (per capita) in logs, and GDP p.c. volatility.
The regressions include time fixed effects. Clustered standard errors reported in
parentheses. ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level.
100
Chapter 3
from changes
The foreign exchange (FX) market is a significant part of the financial markets.
It allows one country’s money exchange for another, defining the exchange rate between
them. Derived from comparing exchange rates and interest rate differentials, the theoretical
concept of covered interest rate parity (CIP) holds when there are no arbitrage opportunities
among these financial instruments. Despite this theoretical assumption, and its use in open
economy and monetary models, empirical research has shown that CIP does not necessarily
hold in practice.
101
Before the Global Financial Crisis (GFC), CIP was observed for most advanced
economies. Small deviations from it were arbitraged in the short run. However, after the
GFC, large and persistent deviations were observed for the most liquid currencies in the FX
market. This research empirically studies the deviation from CIP and the possible drivers
Some factors that can cause the deviation (“basis”) and the incapacity of being
arbitraged away have been identified in the literature. They are usually explained by:
transactions costs, counter-party credit risk, lack of liquidity in secondary markets, and d)
papers have tried to explain the deviations by using models and/or empirical analysis to
explain and quantify it. Funding shortage and counterparty risk are present in most of the
Between 2001 and 2007, the world economy experienced a period of stability and
growth, followed by a global financial crisis and a period of dollar squeeze in 2008-2012. As
the most liquid currency, several international banks increased their holdings of US dollar
assets. This dollar funding was raised, primarily, through market operations: the bank
raises domestic currency through deposits and lends them against US dollars. In normal
times, it is done through the interbank market, operations with central banks, and FX swaps
to convert domestic currency funding into dollars. With the financial crisis and the Lehman
Brothers bankruptcy, lenders became risk averse, increasing the difficulty of keeping these
operations active.
Several research papers present in their theoretical models and empirical analysis
102
an important role for intermediaries. Despite the theoretical assumption of costless arbi-
trage, the actual no arbitrage condition requires a lot of resources, and regulatory require-
ments also raise the its cost. Before the crisis, the collateral and margining requirements
for arbitraging interest rates and exchange rate differentials were much less prohibitive in
Given the scenario of positive basis in some currencies, the understanding of possi-
ble causes is an interesting and current research question. I begin this paper with a selected
and critical literature review of theoretical models, empirical analysis and stylized facts de-
veloped to explain currency basis. With this map, I am able to identify the literature gaps
cross-country setup. Most of the work has been done for specific currencies like US dollar,
Euro and Japanese Yen, and this broader approach aims to compare deeply the drivers for
the deviation. Additionally, the channels in the literature have been evaluated in single
fashion, i.e., added in some theoretical model alone. I have claimed to see how relevant the
Based on data from Bloomberg, the World Bank, and the Bank of International
Settlement (BIS), I have tested how several variables might get potential explanations for
the deviations in a different set of countries. The following sections start with the literature
review - divided before and after the GFC (and this last period grouped by theoretical
and empirical evidences). After that, I present the methodology and data, as well as
justifications for the choices. Then the results are presented, and the paper concluded.
103
3.2 CIP analysis through time
The CIP literature can be divided in two periods: before and after the 2008 GFC.
In the first period, CIP was empirically confirmed to hold in practice. This means that
small deviations were arbitraged away in short durations. After the 2008 crisis, some papers
identified substantially deviations, and these basis have been showing persistent behavior,
raising questions about the CIP concept. A large literature tests the CIP condition before
the global financial crisis and documents large CIP deviations during the crisis. This work
proposed models to explain them. Several mechanisms serve as motivation for the modeling
policy and zero lower bound, and corporate funding cost arbitrage (Bottazzi et al. (2013);
Ivashina et al. (2015); Amador et al. (2016); Liao (2016)). Some models approached the
& Pedersen, 2011). The CIP deviation may also be some component of a model with a
distinct primary goal, such as exchange rate determination (Gabaix and Maggiori, 2015).
As the channels of liquidity during the crisis were scarcer, a model proposed by
Bottazzi et al. (2013) proposed the cross-currency basis (which captures the deviations from
CIP) as the relative value of the scarcer currency. This hypothesis was able to match the
104
data, by checking collaterals as funding constraints. In a crisis, banks are more reluctant
Ivashina et al. (2015) approached the problem by the credit quality of the banks,
that ultimately work as intermediaries for these operations. Using the financial friction as
a way to sharp bank behavior, this channel also matches the data.
The zero-lower bound (ZLB) limitation faced in the crisis was also explored as a
channel for explaining the deviation from CIP. The constraint on nominal interest rates
works as a source of limitation to arbitrage (Amador et al. (2016)). Liao (2016) examined
the issue through the lens of corporate fund cost. To explain it, the author developed a
hampered arbitrage.
Garleanu and Pedersen (2011) had a similar approach as Liao (2016), which was
aimed for explaining deviations from LOOP. In their reasoning, a funding-liquidity crisis
raises the price gaps between securities with identical cash-flows but different margins.
Gabaix and Maggiori (2015) explored the topic in a model with moral hazard and imperfect
financial markets.
asset pricing (He and Krishnamurty (2012); Brunnermeier and Sannikov (2014)). Addi-
tionally, Gromb and Vayanos (2010) survey offers useful information on limits to arbitrage,
Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009) on funding liquidity, Vayanos and Vila (2009) and Green-
105
3.2.2 Empirical evidence
The literature on deviations from CIP also contains papers with a purely empirical
approach, without focusing on developing new models. In this section, I present some of
these papers and their methodology. This section will be important for discussing proxies,
Baba et al. (2008) analyzed the deviation in money markets in the second half of
2007. They identified the use of swap markets to circumvent US dollar funding shortages
and linked it with deviations from CIP. Their analysis contemplated a small window of 2007
and 2008.
Coffey et al. (2009) explored margin conditions and the cost of capital as drivers
of CIP deviations, especially during the crisis period. With increasing uncertainty about
counterparty risk and scarcer swap lines, a breakdown of arbitrage transactions in the
Adding more emphasis in the post-crisis period, Du et al. (2017) identified the CIP
in investment demand and funding supply across currencies. Costly financial intermediation
can explain why the basis is not arbitraged away post crisis.
Rime et al. (2016) also focused on the role of money market segmentation on
CIP deviations. With funding liquidity differences, it becomes impossible for FX swap
Sushko et al. (2016) linked the estimated dollar hedging demand (quantities) to
the variation in CIP deviations (prices). The authors argue that the degree to which CIP
106
holds depends more the relationship between the forward and spot price than the interest
rate differential, by showing that the CIP deviations rely mostly to hedge the USD forward.
This is explained by the cost associated to this hedge over regulatory aspects: it causes
some allocation on the balance sheet. With limits to arbitrage, CIP arbitrageurs charge
a premium in the forward markets for taking the other side of FX hedgers’ demand in
proportion to their balance sheet exposure. This will allow us to proxy the USD funding
needs in FX swap markets by banks through the financial system net liabilities.
By mapping all the different approaches and proxies discussed in the literature, it
is interesting to check how this proxies perform together and across a larger set of countries,
instead of a particular one. Being able to identify possible the “top drivers” to the phe-
nomena has immediate applications to policy makers, like monetary authorities. Potential
candidates for drivers are justified theoretically from the economic and financial literature.
• Are the variables used as possible drivers in the literature extensible to the new
set of countries?
• What are the commonalities and differences in the deviations from CIP among
countries?
107
Some common explaining factors can be identified in the literature about deviation
for CIP, regardless of whether they have a theoretical or empirical approach. According to
literature review, liquidity and counterparty risk play a big role in driving these deviations,
but other factors might help explain it (demand for US dollars, risk from global banks,
financial variables).
Traditionally, this deviations were around zero in developed countries, and it seems
reasonable the recent literature focuses over the most relevant currencies in the FX market,
like US dollar, Euro, and Japanese Yen. Nevertheless, according to the Bank of International
Settlement (BIS) Foreign Exchange Survey realized in 2019 (BIS, 2019), the group composed
by Australian dollar (AUD), Canadian dollar (CAD), Swiss franc (CHF), Pound Sterling /
British Pound (GBP), and Singapore dollar (SGD), respond for approximately 25% of the
daily turnover on the foreign exchange market (table 1 below). Given this relevance and
the trend of participation, it is interesting to check how deviations from CIP behaved for
this group.
108
Table 3.3.1: OTC foreign exchange turnover by currency pair
USD / EUR 892 26.8 1099 27.7 1292 24.1 1172 23.1 1584 24.0
USD / JPY 438 13.2 567 14.3 980 18.3 901 17.8 871 13.2
USD / GBP 384 11.6 360 9.1 473 8.8 470 9.3 630 9.6
USD / AUD 185 5.6 248 6.3 364 6.8 262 5.2 358 5.4
USD / CAD 126 3.8 182 4.6 200 3.7 218 4.3 287 4.4
USD / CHF 151 4.5 166 4.2 184 3.4 180 3.6 228 3.5
Source: Bank of International Settlements -Triennial Central Bank Survey on Foreign Exchange
and OTC. Net-net basis, daily averages in April, in billions of US dollars and percentages,
adjusted for local and cross-border inter-dealer double-counting. I have omitted the pairs US-
D/CNY (Chinese Yuan), USD/HKD (South Korean Won) and USD/INR (Indian Rupee) with
4.1%, 3.3% and 1.7% of participation in 2019 due to lack of information for the calculations executed.
It is a relevant research question to investigate how the deviations from CIP be-
haved for these currencies, and to investigate if the same factors found on the literature can
be applied to this new set. In the scenario where similar evidence is found, it is possible to
extend the reach of the models that absorb these stylized facts to a wider range of coun-
tries. If the empirical behavior for this new set of currencies shows a different outcome,
then a natural consequence of the research would be to explore other possible factors that
might explain such behavior, and how the existing models can be extended to absorb such
109
As the analysis was conducted with linear regressions, the possible limitations of
heteroskedasticity was contemplated by robustness on the errors. Despite the fact that
these variables could be evaluated as time series, these are mostly financial instruments and
concepts constructions (like bid-ask spread, terms of trade), or institutional statistic (bank
concentration). To enhance the results interpretation, I have added a lagged term for the
cross-currency basis. The high frequency of the data adds much noise to the evaluation.
Even considering it, it’s safe to assume that the simple model proposed captures significant
part of the variance – with R-squared close to 1 for the countries sample).
Finally, due to some differences in the time frame for the variables – some were
available in daily basis, while others were available as year basis 1 - the analysis was con-
ducted over levels, and not changes. This is the reason why the discussion was concentrated
In this section, I will present, discuss, and justify the variables selected for my
analysis. The research question of this paper is to evaluate possible drivers for deviation for
1
The banking concentration, for example, was given as a year number. I have conducted a cubic spline
interpolation for quarterly frequency to add some disturbance. It wouldn’t make economic sense to transform
it to daily frequency, as the bank concentration doesn’t change that fast. This fact limited the change analysis
of the variables, so I have concentrated only on the interpretation of the coefficient signs.
2
Following the literature, I have also considered as proxies: volume of currency pairs(liquidity), demand
for USD (risk), implied volatility and risk-reversal-25-Delta (financial). All these variables have a high
correlation with the covariates used and haven’t added explanation power to the results. For space limitation,
I have maintained them out of the results showed, but they are available upon request.
110
CIP for the selected countries. The first step is to measure the basis over these currencies.
For this, I will use the approach of Du et al. (2017) on considering the basis as the spread
“Let’s take the scenario of European banks with liabilities in dollars. As the euro
falls against the dollar, the cost of these payments increases. The situation is worsened by
US investors fear to lend to any European firms and banks. Through a cross-currency swap,
banks can raise funding in Europe in euro and transform this into dollars at a fixed currency
exchange rate that is agreed up front. The basis swap will allow the bank to transform their
dollar liability into a euro liability they can fund more easily. The cross-currency basis swap
will convert the lump sum that the bank borrowed in euros into a lump sum in dollars. The
counterparty in the cross-currency basis swap will actually pay the bank a little less than
the euro rate and pocket the difference between the euro rate and the rate on the swap. If
banks are desperate for dollar funding, they will be willing to receive less interest on the euro
interest on the swap. Cross-currency basis swaps are quoted as this difference in interest
received. Turning this around, it is extremely cheap for US banks to convert euro liabilities
into dollars. Then, the cross-currency basis swap rate measures deviations from the CIP
condition where interest rates are Libor interest rate swap rates.”
111
Figure 3.3.1: Cross Currency Swap and Basis
Dollar Demand vs. Euro Basis Swap Rate Swap EUR → USD Swap USD → EUR
As demand for dollar funding has increased the euro dollar basis swap rate has
fallen sharply and has become strongly negative. The data collected from Bloomberg for
the currencies selected was compiled in the tables below for one year of maturity.
112
The literature review argued an increase on the deviations from CIP after the
GFC, with some persistent behavior. Following Coffey et al. (2009) and Du et al. (2017),
the period break proposed to analyze the deviation is composed by two intervals: the first
part goes from January 1st, 2000 to September 15th, 2008, the official bankruptcy date of
the Lehman Brothers. The second period goes from September 16th, 2008 until December
31st, 2018. The averages and standard deviation are presented on table 3 and illustrated
on figures 2 and 3.
113
Table 3.3.3: Summary Statistics for Cross-Currency Swap Basis Points
From table 3 we can see a significant change in the deviation from the covered
interest rate parity for these currencies. The increase is observed not only in the mean
115
basis, but also in their volatilities. The only exception is seen over the Singaporean dollar
(SGD), which has a somehow stable standard deviation on the basis (but still with a rise
in the mean).
The additional variables presented in the literature review and which will compose
Liquidity proxies
The liquidity proxies used are the spread over the exchange rate spot and the
spread over the exchange rate future contract. The first is the difference between the prices
quoted for an immediate sale (offer) and an immediate purchase (bid) for the spot exchange
rate. The latter is the difference between the prices quoted for an immediate sale (offer)
and an immediate purchase (bid) for future exchange-rate contracts. The data for both
Risk proxy
The risk proxy used in this paper and based in the literature is the average CDS
(Credit Default Swap) of the G-Sibs (Global Sistemically important banks). I have selected
the list of thirty banks defined by the Financial Stability Board (FSB) and have calculated
their average premium. Ideally, it should obtain a measure of risk for these institutions
that are responsible for intermediating the swap trades. The banks defined as G-Sibs by
116
Financial Market and Macro Variables
Trade, Bank concentration and VIX. The terms of trade is a widely used measure in the
literature. It is defined as the ratio of export prices to import prices, and it can be defined
as the amount of import goods an economy can purchase per unit of export goods. It is
used in this paper as a context for demand for USD, and its information was obtained on
Bloomberg. The Bank Concentration is calculated by the World Bank. It measures the
The Volatility Index (VIX) measures of the stock market’s expectation of volatility
implied by S&P 500 index options, calculated and published by the Chicago Board Options
Exchange (CBOE). It is a widely used measure of global risk and its data was also obtained
on Bloomberg.
3.4 Results
A primary and simple check regarding the impact of the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy
over the deviations from CIP was done through a t-test and mean comparison between the
two periods. Despite a illustrative representation of the different behaviors through figures
117
Table 3.4.1: T-tests for mean differences pre x post Lehman
Tables 6-10 compile the regressions for all currencies having the basis as the de-
pendent variable and the statistical significance of each independent variable described on
sections 3.1.2 - 3.1.4, added accordingly to its economic meaning and relation to the litera-
ture.
Additionally, I added a dummy for post crisis period (September 15th, 2008, the
Lehman Bank bankruptcy). This dummy represents a fixed effect for pre and post period,
allowing me to control for unobservable differences in CIP before and after crisis. There
was a concern regarding the scenario where CIP was just at a different level after the crisis
for reasons not captured by the regressors, indicating the necessity of time fixed effect
control for it. As the data has daily frequency not only on the dependent variable, but
also in the regressors, this was ruled out. As I am looking for the potential changes in
the relationship between the explanatory variables and CIP during the crisis, then I will
look for the interaction among dummies and regressors for pre and post crisis periods. For
illustration purposes, I will also add the regressions without the dummies. I will start with
118
a baseline model (regressions 1 and 3), which contemplates most used liquidity variables
– spread for spot and future contracts and terms of trade. Additionally, I will evaluate
an extended model, which will embrace also other variables used as possible drivers for
deviation on CIP, like Bank concentration, average CDS premia for global systemically
important banks, and global volatility index (regressions 2 and 4). Both models were added
Where:
119
• Future – Spread future (section 3.1.2)
• D – dummy for the period related to the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy (D = 0 before the
The regression results are presented on tables 6-10. The economic intuition of an
increase on the cross-currency swap basis points (taken as the proxy for the deviation of
covered interest rate parity) implies that its related to a decrease in market liquidity. This
was expected to be seen or correlated with an increase in the spread of both spot and future
contracts. The term of trade variable is defined as the ratio of exports over imports. This
on the liquidity. That said, it is expected that terms of trade would be negatively related
The group of variables added on regressions (2) and (4) – bank concentration,
average CDS for G-Sibs and VIX – is expected to be related to the basis in the following
fashion.
As the trades for cross currency swaps are mostly over-the-counter trades, they
are conducted through banks, and not by the brokerage firms directly on exchange houses
120
(like NYSE, CBOE, for example). If a local firm is willing to do a cross-currency swap
and its local financial system is more concentrated, i.e., offer less options for this firm, it is
expected that the basis for the operation would be higher. The hypothesis for this variable
As the CDS is a security against the default for any specific asset issuer, the G-
Sibs average CDS evaluates how the market is pricing the risk of these financial institutions
to not honor their operations. The higher the CDS premium for this group pf banks, less
confident the clients will be to conduct transactions with, implying a positive relation with
CIP deviation. On the other hand, there is an argument that this lack of confidence on
these banks would contribute for their lower rates, increasing the number of operations.
We see that there are arguments on both directions, and the regressions will help to clarify
VIX is the S&P 500 Volatility Index – a largely used measure of stocks’ market
The table below summarizes the hypothesis for the variable directions.
It is important to note that the Australian dollar goes in the opposite direction of
121
all the other currencies due to the form it is quoted in the market. To circumvent that, I
have transformed the AUD/USD quotation, i.e., the amount of US dollar required to buy
one Australian dollar, to USD/AUD, the amount of Australian dollars to buy one US dollar.
The baseline cases, regressions (1) and (2) contemplates the whole period without
a dummy variable for the period after Global Financial Crisis. The addition of the second
group of control variables (regression 2) doesn’t’ change neither the significance not the
signs of the coefficients for the first regression (1). The only exception is for the Canadian
dollar, which start having the terms of trade as significant on regression 2, in contrast to
regression 1.
Regarding the expected signs, the results are mixed. The spot spread has the
hypothesized sign for all currencies, besides GBP, although none of it are significant. The
future spread has the hypothesized sign only for AUD dollar and CHF, with only CAD
and CHF significant. This means that these variables are weakly explanatory in this set-
up. For the terms of trade, the coefficients are significant for all currencies, despite AUD.
The comparison between regressions (3) and (4) is similar as the one done above
– (1) and (2), with the shift for the post-GFC considered. When the second group of inde-
pendent variables are considered, the interaction term with future spread loses significance
for the AUD and gain significance for the SGD. All other coefficients for the first block are
122
the same in terms of significance.
Regarding the expected signs hypothesized on table 5, the results are also far for
conclusion. While AUD matches the expected signs, all other currencies show deviances
from it (CAD shows divergence is spot and future spread, as well as terms of trade; CHF
shows divergence on future spread, terms of trade, and VIX; GBP shows divergence on
VIX; and SGD shows divergence on future spread, terms of trade, bank concentration and
VIX).
This section focuses mostly on the most complete set-up, i.e., regression (4). For
the five countries evaluated (tables 6-10), only UK and Singapore (tables 9 and 10) show
a significant result for the second group of interactions - bank concentration, average CDS
of G-Sibs and VIX. The bank concentration coefficient shows opposite signs for these two
countries, weakening its interpretation. In a set of five countries, three don’t show signif-
icance, and the two other present conflicted intuition. It definitely suggests some deeper
analysis and treatment to understand how it is related to the deviations from CIP, and also
Regarding the average CDS of G-Sibs, it was discussed above how both signs
for the coefficient could have an economic interpretation. The empirical results for the
regression over UK and Singapore show consistency in the positive sign, suggesting that the
increase in the risk perception for these banks widens the basis.
For the VIX, the results shown for both UK and Singapore are also consistent
with the hypothesis: a larger volatility implies a higher risk perception, which correlates
123
with an increase in the basis / deviation from CIP. Even though the results are satisfactory
for two out of three variables for UK and Singapore, it is interesting to explore a deeper
institutional country analysis in order to identify why these variables are not significant for
Australia, Canada, and Switzerland. In some degree, we can say that the results suggest
the financial and macro variables as highly correlated with this new scenario of deviation
from CIP. The cause for the Singapore result might be caused by its particular degree of
freedom over its financial market, which caused less risk aversion over its currency.
Regarding the spot and future spread, the results are mixed. Australian dollar
and Canadian dollar show no correlation, while swiss franc show significance only in the
future spread, the British Pound show significance (at 10% level) only for the spot spread,
and the Singaporean dollar show significance in both spot and future spread.
The significance on terms of trade (Australian dollar and Canadian dollar) can be
an indication of the real export channel getting higher weight through this period.
The lack of significance of the bid-ask spread for spot and/or future markets for
some currencies is intriguing. The increase of CIP post GFC has as one of main hypothesis
the liquidity constraint. Also, one of the most practiced proxies for liquidity concerns the
bid-ask spread. Nevertheless, we see that the significance over the interaction with the post-
Lehman dummy is present over independent variables with institutional characteristics, like
terms of trade and bank concentration, and global factors, like VIX and the CDS premium
of G-Sibs (UK and Singapore). This fact raises questions about the proper intervention
For example, one of the first responses from the Fed to the crisis was the incentive
124
to some mergers in order to absorb the more problematic banks. It’s noteworthy that the
main idea was to “stop the bleeding” and avoid bank-runs through all the system, but this
result try to shed light about the cost of a higher bank concentration as a narrower set of
Regarding the VIX and the G-Sibs CDS (British Pound and Singaporean dollar),
the main lesson provided by this result was well explored: the lack of regulation and criteria
the increase on leverage and risk profile for all the major banks.
125
Table 3.4.3: Australian dollar Cross-Currency Swaps regressions
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Variables AUD CCS AUD CCS AUD CCS AUD CCS
Spot spread 5.911 6.554 -0.516 -0.636
(3.954) (4.241) (1.182) (1.42)
Future spread 0.0257 0.0702 -0.005 -0.00161
(0.0325) (0.0705) (0.00626) (0.00678)
Terms of trade -0.000124 -0.00284 -0.00171 0.000953
(0.00145) (0.00213) (0.00133) (0.00219)
D * (Spot spread) 9.203 9.323
(6.109) (6.236)
D * (Future spread) 0.383* 0.252
(0.233) (0.276)
D * (Terms of trade) -0.00560* -0.00717*
(0.003) (0.00417)
Bank Concentration 0.00723 0.00495
(0.00604) (0.00494)
Average CDS G-Sibs 0.00189 -0.00407
(0.00126) (0.0031)
VIX -0.0107 0.00606
(0.00736) (0.00603)
D * (Bank Concentration) 0.0673
(0.0558)
D * (Average CDS G-Sibs) 0.00569
(0.00365)
D * (VIX) -0.00886
(0.0144)
Lag – CCS 0.981*** 0.973*** 0.968*** 0.955***
(0.0151) (0.0185) (0.0238) (0.0304)
D 0.402 -5.83
(0.258) (5.16)
Constant 0.182 -0.281 0.175 -0.242
(0.138) (0.506) (0.131) (0.389)
126
Table 3.4.4: Canadian dollar Cross-Currency Swaps regressions
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Variables CAD CCS CAD CCS CAD CCS CAD CCS
Spot spread 67.23 49.94 92.72 33.04
(98.63) (133.1) (146.5) (156.9)
Future spread -0.000768*** -0.000721*** -0.000600*** -0.000420***
(0.000211) (0.000209) (0.000155) (0.000159)
Terms of trade 0.00735 0.0176** 0.00165 -0.0122
(0.00502) (0.00861) (0.0091) (0.0121)
D * (Spot spread) -19.13 -36.78
(181.4) (214.1)
D * (Future spread) -0.00425 -0.000337
(0.0202) (0.0187)
D * (Terms of trade) 0.0291** 0.0586***
(0.0135) (0.02)
Bank Concentration 0.00758 0.0249***
(0.00587) (0.00916)
Average CDS G-Sibs -0.00119* 0.00169
(0.000688) (0.00406)
VIX 0.0124 0.00445
(0.00879) (0.00986)
D * (Bank Concentration) 0.00346
(0.0121)
D * (Average CDS G-Sibs) 0.00244
(0.00424)
D * (VIX) 0.00543
(0.0156)
Lag – CCS 0.990*** 0.984*** 0.978*** 0.955***
(0.00272) (0.00458) (0.00559) (0.0102)
D -0.554*** -1.817*
(0.174) (1.01)
Constant -0.0888** -0.988* 0.128 -1.955***
(0.0431) (0.594) (0.0838) (0.744)
127
Table 3.4.5: Swiss Franc Cross-Currency Swaps regressions
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Variables CHF CCS CHF CCS CHF CCS CHF CCS
Spot spread 72.38 109.5 -18.39 50.98
(57.89) (68.47) (79.45) (97.75)
Future spread -0.00229** -0.00257*** -0.00222 -0.00233**
(0.00104) (0.000527) (0.00151) (0.00094)
Terms of trade 0.0167** 0.0351*** 0.0193*** 0.0263***
(0.00657) (0.0126) (0.00733) (0.0092)
D * (Spot spread) 114.1 67.36
(99.2) (120.3)
D * (Future spread) -2.134** -3.254***
(0.866) (0.907)
D * (Terms of trade) -0.012 0.0594
(0.045) (0.0847)
Bank Concentration 0.0734*** 0.0235
(0.0191) (0.0195)
Average CDS G-Sibs -0.00298** -0.00291
(0.00133) (0.00205)
VIX -0.00959 0.000695
(0.00833) (0.00543)
D * (Bank Concentration) 0.0518
(0.0356)
D * (Average CDS G-Sibs) 0.000355
(0.00247)
D * (VIX) -0.0228
(0.0169)
Lag – CCS 0.993*** 0.976*** 0.983*** 0.972***
(0.00316) (0.00649) (0.00662) (0.00753)
D -0.693 -4.376
(0.472) (2.706)
Constant -0.0207 -6.453*** 0.0836** -2.008
(0.0413) (1.742) (0.0405) (1.83)
128
Table 3.4.6: British Pound Cross-Currency Swaps regressions
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Variables GBP CCS GBP CCS GBP CCS GBP CCS
Spot spread -7.495 -38.14 -5.415 -5.805
(54.8) (33.69) (4.411) (4.382)
Future spread 0.303 0.0687 -0.233 -0.226
(0.456) (0.177) (0.146) (0.141)
Terms of trade -1.795*** -1.988*** -0.0239 -0.0392**
(0.0718) (0.101) (0.0146) (0.0177)
D * (Spot spread) 27.90* 26.73*
(14.38) (14.31)
D * (Future spread) 0.247 0.244
(0.155) (0.15)
D * (Terms of trade) 0.130** -0.0283
(0.056) (0.0895)
Bank Concentration -0.0814*** 0.000711
(0.0155) (0.00211)
Average CDS G-Sibs -0.0413*** -0.00735**
(0.00485) (0.00294)
VIX -0.788*** 0.00753
(0.0451) (0.00662)
D * (Bank Concentration) 0.0574***
(0.0216)
D * (Average CDS G-Sibs) 0.00632**
(0.00315)
D * (VIX) -0.0577***
(0.0193)
Lag – CCS 0.303*** 0.164*** 0.985*** 0.966***
(0.0494) (0.0318) (0.00874) (0.00971)
D -1.033** -3.201
(0.438) (1.95)
Constant -0.147 26.61*** 0.0595 0.121
(0.247) (1.628) (0.0475) (0.193)
129
Table 3.4.7: Singaporean dollar Cross-Currency Swaps regressions
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Variables SGD CCS SGD CCS SGD CCS SGD CCS
Spot spread 0.26 0.862 -261.5*** -363.9***
(19.13) (22.3) (94.98) (138.1)
Future spread -0.000353 -0.000505 0.0285 0.0531**
(0.000816) (0.000695) (0.0187) (0.0232)
Terms of trade 0.0320*** 0.0478*** 0.0236** 0.0179
(0.00748) (0.00987) (0.01) (0.0186)
D * (Spot spread) 267.7*** 372.8***
(95.65) (138.8)
D * (Future spread) -0.0288 -0.0537**
(0.0187) (0.0232)
D * (Terms of trade) 0.0159 0.0164
(0.0122) (0.0202)
Bank Concentration -0.0600*** 0.0292
(0.0126) (0.039)
Average CDS G-Sibs -0.00430*** -0.0192***
(0.000854) (0.00394)
VIX -0.0237*** -0.0033
(0.00638) (0.00778)
D * (Bank Concentration) -0.140***
(0.0506)
D * (Average CDS G-Sibs) 0.0146***
(0.0038)
D * (VIX) -0.0184*
(0.0103)
Lag – CCS 0.916*** 0.826*** 0.914*** 0.807***
(0.0189) (0.0284) (0.0193) (0.0305)
D 0.0125 13.57***
(0.0835) (4.964)
Constant -0.0336 6.384*** -0.00146 -2.495
(0.033) (1.267) (0.0615) (3.933)
130
3.4.2 Some extensions
To improve the power of the results, I have also run a panel analysis for the data to
observe how would that differ from the cross countries results (without the lagged variables).
They are available on table 11 and show similar results from the cross-country analysis.
As a frequent argument in the literature about the deviation from CIP resides
131
on the lack of liquidity for the markets, I have checked how the Cross-country swap basis
points behaved for the same six pairs of currencies for the period around the Quantitative
Easing. I have run the same t-test for the means, but now comparing the QE1 and QE2
announcements dates, and also for a smaller window – two weeks before and two weeks
Source: Elaborated by the author. The QE1 date was Nov 25, 2008.
Source: Elaborated by the author. The QE2 date was Aug 10, 2010.
The weaker results, with some currencies showing no difference in their means
132
between the periods, is consistent with the idea that market liquidity is not the main
driver for the deviation of CIP. The period of analysis for the change due to specific event
(the QE announcements) was chosen to be small in an attempt to isolate its effect over the
deviation from CIP. If extended to a larger period, the effect would be probably be impacted
from other market variables as well. That said, the regressions for these window were not
reproduced due to the small dataset and limited explanation power. This limitation raises
a possibility for a future study with intraday data around the QE announcements.
In this paper, I have empirically conducted an evaluation over the deviation from
covered interest rate parity. Through an extensive literature review, I have mapped possible
drivers for explaining the failure of the no arbitrage condition in the foreign exchange market
after the great financial crisis. I have also extended the analysis for a set of countries
not explored in the literature despite having a significant weight in the FX market. I
have obtained results that claim for a larger reason for the deviation than only liquidity
constraints, which open channels for further empirical analysis as well as different channels
for theoretical proposals on monetary policies models. The lack of consistency of some
drivers discussed in the literature when evaluated in a cross-country set-up raises a question
of how important institutional characteristics of a country are when evaluating its deviation
from CIP. Despite the rise in the deviation from the CIP being a real fact obtained through
the empirical observations, its mechanisms are still not clear enough. This is an important
contribution for the theoretical developments aiming to absorb the failure to no arbitrage
133
condition in their models.
3.6 References
[1] Amador, M., Bianchi, J., Bocola, L., and Perri, F. (2016). Exchange rate policies at the
zero lower bound. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 23266:1 38.
[2] Avdjiev, S., Du, W., Koch, C., and Shin, H. S. (2016). The dollar, bank leverage and
the deviation from covered interest parity. BIS Working Papers, WP 592:1 37.
[3] Baba, N., Packer, F., and Nagano, T. (2008). The spillover of money market turbulence
to fx swap and cross-currency swap markets. BIS Quarterly Review, March:1 14.
[4] Bank for International Settlements (2019). Triennial central bank survey.
[5] Bottazzi, J.-M., Luque, J., Pascoa, M. R., and Sundaresan, S. (2013). Dollar short-
age, central bank actions, and the cross currency basis. Working Paper, Columbia
[6] Brunnermeier, M. K. and Pedersen, L. H. (2009). Market liquidity and funding liq-
[8] Coffey, N., Hrung, W. B., and Sarkar, A. (2009). Capital constraints, counterparty
risk, and deviations from covered interest rate parity. Federal Reserve Bank of New
134
[9] Du, W., Tepper, A., and Verdelhan, A. (2017). Deviations from covered interest rate
[10] Gabaix, X. and Maggiori, M. (2015). International liquidity and exchange rate dy-
[11] Garleanu, N. and Pedersen, L. H. (2011). Margin-based asset pricing and deviations
from the law of one price. Review of Financial Studies, 24 (6):1980 2022.
[12] Greenwood, R. and Vayanos, D. (2014). Bond supply and excess bond returns. Review
[13] Gromb, D. and Vayanos, D. (2010). Limits of arbitrage. Annual Review of Financial
[14] He, Z. and Krishnamurthy, A. (2012). A model of capital and crises. Review of
[15] Ivashina, V., Scharfstein, D. S., and Stein, J. C. (2015). Dollar funding and the lending
[16] Liao, G. (2016). Credit migration and covered interest rate parity. Harvard Business
School - Project on Behavioral Finance and Financial Stability, Working Paper 2016-
07:1 58.
[17] Nakisa, R. C. (2011). A financial bestiary : introducing equity, fixed income, credit,
135
[18] Rime, D., Schrimpf, A., and Syrstad, O. (2017). Segmented money markets and
[19] Sushko, V., Borio, C., McCauley, R., and McGuire, P. (2016). The failure of covered
interest parity: Fx hedging demand and costly balance sheets. BIS Working Paper,
590:1 67.
[20] Vayanos, D. and Vila, J.-L. (2009). A preferred-habitat model of the term structure
of interest rates. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 15487:1 59.
3.7 Appendix
JP Morgan Chase Bank of China Ind. and Comm. Bank of China Lim.
136