And Angelo Melino
And Angelo Melino
And Angelo Melino
DOLLAR RIVALS
Jeffrey A. Frankel
This paper was written for a session titled, “Can the Dollar-Based System Be Improved or
Replaced?” for a conference on 50 Years of Floating, held at the Peterson Institute for
International Economics, Washington DC, March 24, 2023. It is forthcoming in a book edited by
Doug Irwin and Maurice Obstfeld. The author would like to thank Obstfeld and Angelo Melino
for useful suggestions. The opinions expressed in this paper are those of the authors alone and do
not reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research
The author has disclosed additional relationships of potential relevance for this research. Further
information is available online at http://www.nber.org/papers/w31476
NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been
peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies
official NBER publications.
© 2023 by Jeffrey A. Frankel. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two
paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including ©
notice, is given to the source.
Dollar Rivals
Jeffrey A. Frankel
NBER Working Paper No. 31476
July 2023
JEL No. F33
ABSTRACT
Written on the 50th anniversary of floating exchange rates, this paper deals with possible
alternatives to a unipolar dollar-based system. It considers (1) measures of international currency
use; (2) potential challengers to the dollar; (3) network externalities; and (4) the plausibility of
gold and digital currencies, as alternatives to regular currencies. On the one hand, network
externalities operate in favor of the status quo: the dollar as the single leading international
currency. On the other hand, the danger of abuse of exorbitant privilege – for example, by
debasing the currency or repeated use of sanctions – operates in favor of challengers. A good
guess is that the dollar will continue to lose market share slowly to others, but will remain in the
lead.
Jeffrey A. Frankel
Harvard Kennedy School
79 JFK Street
Cambridge, MA 02138
and NBER
jeffrey_frankel@harvard.edu
The ques�on of the interna�onal currency status of the dollar versus its poten�al rivals is
not new, but has been accorded an unusual amount of aten�on in the last few years, among
scholars and non-scholars alike. With more data available than ever before, it is a good �me to
take stock.
The topic of the last session of the PIIE conference in March 2023 was possible alterna�ves
to a unipolar dollar-based system. Consider four sub-topics: (1) measures of interna�onal
currency use; (2) poten�al challengers to the dollar; (3) the ques�on whether a mul�-polar
currency system is consistent with the existence of network externali�es; and (4) the plausibility
of gold and digital currencies, as alterna�ves to regular currencies.
1 Kindleberger (1967).
2The schematic table began with Cohen (1971) and was adopted with slight modifications by
Kenen (1983) and Frankel (1992), among others.
2
`
The first criterion is the most salient, perhaps because the data on central banks’ reserve
holdings are readily available. The dollar’s share of foreign exchange reserves has been declining
gradually since the turn of the century. In 1999, when the newborn euro took the place of the
French franc and German mark 3, the dollar cons�tuted 71 % of allocated holdings. By the end of
2022 its share had declined to 58 %. 4 That is a rate of decline of about ½ percentage points per
year. But the share of the dollar remains far ahead of the share of the second-place
interna�onal currency, the euro, which is 20 % and not gaining. If the dollar’s share were to
con�nue declining at the same rate, it would take another 70 years for it to fall to the euro’s
share.5 The euro is in turn well ahead of the yen, which remains in third place. The yen is
followed by pound sterling in fourth. The much-ballyhooed renminbi has moved into fi�h place
only rela�vely recently, having passed the Canadian dollar and Australian dollar.
Each use of the currencies interna�onally6 is highly correlated with the other uses, both
causally and sta�s�cally. Causally, Gopinath and Stein (2018, 2021), for example, show that
interna�onal use of a currency to invoice trade (unit of account) is bi-direc�onally related to use
of the currency financially (store of value, par�cularly in the case of a currency with safe-haven
proper�es, like the dollar and yen). Sta�s�cally, a correla�on is evident as well. The ranking is
similar by different measures: the dollar remains number one, not only by the criterion of
reserve holdings, but also by the criteria of denomina�ng or invoicing trade 7, as well as
denomina�on of interna�onal debt and loans, foreign exchange turnover, 8 and global
payments. According to an overall measure of interna�onal currency use computed at the
3
Before that, Mathieson and Eichengreen (2000) characterize the currency composi�on of
reserves as stable in the 1980s and 1990s. But the dollar share in fact declined a�er 1977, in
tandem with the value of the dollar, and only recovered in the late 1990s.
4 This is as a share of allocated foreign exchange reserves reported by the IMF’s COFER site
($6,471 billion / $ 11,089 billion). Prasad (2019) points out that the unallocated propor�on of
global reserves has become less of a limita�on of the COFER sta�s�cs since China began to
share the currency breakdown of its reserves with the IMF, phased in over 2014-18.
5This calcula�on assumes that the euro’s share remains unchanged. If central banks switched
out of dollars into euros, the catch-up date would be correspondingly sooner.
6 Aiyar, et al (2023).
7 Engel (2006), Goldberg and Tille (2008), Gopinath (2015), and Boz et al (2020).
8
BIS (December 2022). As of April 2022, the dollar is used in almost three �mes as many
foreign exchange transac�ons as the euro, its nearest compe�tor, whether measured by simple
spot trades or deriva�ves. Again, following the dollar and euro in the ranking comes the yen,
pound, renminbi, Australian dollar, Canadian dollar, and Swiss franc, in that order.
3
`
Federal Reserve, the dollar remains three �mes as important as the euro, and far more
important than the yen, pound, or renminbi. 9
Only in the case of global SWIFT payments,10 does the euro come close to the dollar’s
share as of 2023: 32.6 % of payments versus 41.7%. The SWIFT rankings again put the renminbi
in fi�h place, at a mere 2.3 %. Admitedly, recent growth in the renminbi (RMB) would show up
more strongly if data on the Cross-Border Interbank Payment System, which China launched in
2015, or other non-SWIFT alterna�ve payments systems could be included.
2. The challengers
When the Breton Woods system came undone fi�y years ago, it seemed that the dollar
had lost its special status. Ini�ally, some expected that the IMF’s SDR could fill the gap. 11 A�er
all, the SDR had originally been proposed and created as a means of repairing the Breton
Woods system by offering an alterna�ve to dollar reserves. But the synthe�c unit never caught
on as an interna�onal currency. 12 To be sure, 12 countries, many of them in Africa or the
Mideast, had pegged their currencies to the SDR by 1979, rising to 16 in 1982. As a percentage
of peggers, this was a rise from 16.4 per cent in 1979 to 22.5 per cent in 1982. But it was all
downhill from there. By 1995, the number had declined to only three (Libya, Myanmar, and
Seychelles). The SDR largely fell out of use, except as an interna�onal reserve asset for central
banks. 13 The SDR lacks the advantage of a home base where it is the indigenous na�onal
currency. In the common analogy, if the dollar is akin to the English language, as the world’s
lingua franca, then the SDR is akin to the world’s Esperanto. The SDR and Esperanto were both
deliberately designed for maximum usefulness, and yet remain litle used in prac�ce, precisely
because they were created ar�ficially, rather than growing organically out of a home base.
9 Bertaut, et al, (2021), Figure 10. The measure is a weighted average of five criteria.
10SWIFT (April, 2023). The Society for Worldwide Interna�onal Financial Telecommunica�ons is
a messaging system that accompanies inter-bank transac�ons. It provides the highest-frequency
measure of interna�onal currency use. Chau, Ilzetski, and Rogoff (2022).
13The IMF occasionally s�ll issues new batches of SDRs, notably in August 2009 in response to
the Global Financial Crisis. Truman (2022).
4
`
Excitement over rival currencies tends to come in waves of pessimism regarding the role
of the dollar. 14 In the last 40 years, a procession of currencies have been characterized as
candidates to challenge the dollar as premier interna�onal currency. The Deutsche Mark from
1973 to 1990, 15 the Japanese Yen from 1984 to 1991 16, and the Euro in the 2000s17, each had its
turn. Since around 2009, it has been the turn of the RMB. 18
Predic�ons that the RMB might challenge the dollar for the number one spot by 2020
obviously were premature. Although China’s currency has two of the three necessary
condi�ons to be a leading interna�onal currency -- economic size and the ability to keep its
value -- it s�ll lacks the third: deep, liquid, open financial markets. Much as the Chinese
government craves the global stature of a major interna�onal currency, it has not been willing
to give up capital controls and to achieve free conver�bility. In par�cular, it effec�vely halted its
efforts to interna�onalize Chinese financial markets a�er 2014, when ten years of net capital
inflows gave way to ten years of net capital ou�lows. It has further been observed that China
does not have the democra�c form of government, free media, and independent central bank
that characterize the homes to most interna�onal currencies.
In 2023, the five BRICs countries -- Brazil, Russia, India, China and South Africa – began
talking about establishing a new currency19, to be an alterna�ve to the dollar. Details are
scarce. China would dominate a BRICS currency, by sheer economic size. But it is hard to
imagine that five such disparate countries could live with a common currency, whether or not it
would be China’s yuan. Russia has proposed that the BRICS currency might be a new basket of
the five na�onal currencies. If such a new synthe�c currency is envisioned alongside the five
exis�ng currencies, it would fail for lack of a home base, like the SDR but more so.
14 For example, one wave of declara�ons that the dollar was on its way out came in 1995, at the
nadir of a 10-year decline in its foreign exchange value against the mark and yen (not that there
need be any connec�on between interna�onal use of a currency and its exchange rate). E.g.,
Kindleberger (1995), Kunz (1995), and Frankel (1995).
15 Tavlas (1993).
16 Frankel (1984), Tavlas and Ozeki (1992), Hale (1995), and Takagi (2011).
17Alogoskoufis and Portes (1992), Bergsten (1997), Portes and Rey (1998), Frieden (2000), Chinn
and Frankel (2007), Posen (2008) and Goldberg (2010).
18Dobson and Masson (2009), Ito (2010), Park and Song (2010), Eichengreen (2011b),
Subramanian (2011a, 2011b), Prasad and Ye (2012), Frankel (2012), and Zhang (2022).
19 “Why a Brics currency is a flawed idea,” Paul McNamara, Financial Times, Feb. 10, 2023.
5
`
Arslanalp, et al (2022), point out that the con�nued gradual move of global central bank
reserve holdings out of dollars is not primarily into any of the aforemen�oned challengers, but
rather into new rela�vely small reserve currencies, like the Canadian dollar, Australian dollar,
South Korean won, Swedish krona, and Norwegian krone. In addi�on, some other rela�vely
small currencies, like the Singapore dollar, South African rand and New Zealand dollar, are held
as reserves or as anchors to peg to, by a few s�ll-smaller countries in their regions. One might
add these rela�vely small units to the list of interna�onal currencies, though obviously not as
candidates for a leader. It is interes�ng to note that the dollar could con�nue to lose market
share indefinitely, while yet remaining in the number one slot.
Kindleberger (1981), Krugman (1984), Matsuyama et al (1993), and Gopinath and Stein (2018,
20
2021).
21
Including Lindert (1969), Krugman (1984), Chinn and Frankel (2007) and Iancu et al (2020),
among others.
22
Schenk (2010).
6
`
currencies can exist simultaneously. Eichengreen and Flandreau (2009, 2012) and Chitu, et al,
(2014, 2017) argue that the dollar in fact surpassed the pound quite soon a�er World War I, by
1925. A reasonable interpreta�on of the numbers is that interna�onal use of the dollar in the
1920s and 1930s atained approximately the same level as the pound and that the dollar only
pulled decisively ahead a�er World War II.
The global monetary system can be usefully viewed as a tradeoff between the advantage of
a single currency (network externali�es) and the disadvantage: namely, that the issuing country
may abuse its exorbitant privilege, provoking countries to look for alterna�ves (Farhi and
Maggiori, 2017). Abusing the exorbitant privilege used to mean “debasing the currency” --
excessive budget deficits, money growth, current account deficits, infla�on, and deprecia�on.23
Econometric es�ma�on of the determina�on of interna�onal currency shares included the
ability of a country’s currency to hold its value. (The other two most standard kinds of
determinants are country size, as already men�oned, and the openness and liquidity of the
country’s financial markets.) 24
Lately, overuse of exorbitant privilege has taken on a second meaning. It has been
increasingly evident that frequent American use of sanc�ons can provoke some countries to
move away from reliance on dollars.
Most interna�onal sanc�ons historically have accomplished rela�vely litle, especially if they
were applied without strong mul�lateral support. Experts tended to view them usually as just a
way for a country to register a clear protest, one of the few op�ons in between armed
interven�on and doing nothing. But sanc�ons have been used more o�en in recent years,
par�cularly financial sanc�ons.
The US government’s exploita�on of the dollar’s global dominance in order to extend the
extraterritorial reach of US law and policy has been deemed “weaponiza�on of the dollar.” 25 An
atempt to shut Iran out of the interna�onal banking system was among the economic sanc�ons
applied against the country in response to its threatened development of nuclear weapons.
Ini�ally, in 2005, the US had mul�lateral support. True, Europeans occasionally grumbled about
23 The 1973 collapse of the monetary system was not simply the culmina�on of the Triffin
Dilemma (1960), but was accelerated by the fiscal and monetary expansion of the Vietnam War
era, under Presidents Lyndon Johnson and Richard Nixon. Since 1973, the US has accumulated
another $31 trillion in na�onal debt, ataining the highest ra�o to GDP since the end of World
War II.
24 Dooley, Lizondo, and Mathieson (1989), Mathieson and Eichengreen (2000), Chinn and
Frankel (2007), Ito and McCauley (2020), Aizenman et al (2020), Lusinyan et al (2020), Arslanalp
et al, (2022), and Chinn et al (2022).
25 Frankel, 2019, "How a Weaponized Dollar Could Backfire," The Guardian, Oct. 23.
7
`
US extraterritoriality, suspec�ng that the US might be quicker to impose large penal�es on
European banks than on their American peers for viola�ng sanc�ons. In any case, sanc�ons
were relaxed when Iran agreed to halt its nuclear weapons program under a 2015 nuclear deal,
the Joint Comprehensive Plan of Ac�on.
The sanc�ons lost much of their mul�lateral support when Donald Trump reinstated them in
September 2020. Trump in 2018 had withdrawn the US from the 2015 agreement, which Iran
had not been viola�ng. For this reason, in the eyes of the interna�onal community, 26 it became
harder to jus�fy sanc�ons in the name of a global public good and easier to characterize them
as an abuse of the American exorbitant privilege. Not just China, but Europe as well looked for
channels to pay for purchases of Iranian oil outside the US-controlled banking system. The
episode fed concerns that the dollar might lose its long-standing primacy.
When Russia seized Crimea and invaded the eastern provinces of Ukraine in 2014, financial
sanc�ons were intended to be an important component of the mul�lateral response. Their
effects turned out to be rather limited. Worse, the Moscow government spent the subsequent
seven years building up its financial defenses. With the aid of substan�al current account
surpluses, Russia’s central bank accumulated $643 billion worth of interna�onal reserves, equal
to an impressive 40% of GDP. Furthermore, the Bank of Russia, almost alone among the world’s
central banks, deliberately shi�ed the composi�on of its interna�onal reserves out of dollars,
and into renminbi, other currencies, and gold.
Before the 2022 invasion of Ukraine, cu�ng off Russian banks from the global financial
system, via the SWIFT messaging system or otherwise, seemed an ambi�ous goal. In the event,
the US and its allies were able to accomplish that and a lot more. The US Treasury, together
with the EU, Japan, other G-7 countries, Switzerland, Korea and Singapore, jointly took almost
unprecedentedly strong ac�on on February 28. They denied the Russian authori�es (the central
bank plus the sovereign wealth fund) access to their foreign exchange reserves and other assets
held overseas, thereby disarming the carefully prepared defenses. As a result, the ruble
suddenly plummeted 30%, on top of earlier declines, bringing it below one cent in value.
Over �me, however, the ruble fully recovered. Even though the western countries applied
sanc�ons at the outer end of what was expected before the invasion, the effect as of 2023
seems to have been less than expected. Facilita�ng evasion of sanc�ons is the expansion of
alterna�ve payment mechanisms, in renminbi or other non-dollar currencies.
A few recent studies examine whether the countries that are geopoli�cally the least aligned
with the US and thus the most exposed to the threat of sanc�ons are generally the ones that
have been shi�ing their reserve holdings out of dollars. Eichengreen et al (2017) use a dummy
variable reflec�ng whether the country in ques�on has a defense pact with the US. Mosler and
Potra�e (2020) use the rate at which the country votes in agreement with the US in United
26
Politico, September 21, 2020.
8
`
Na�ons General Assembly resolu�ons. Arslanlap, et al (2022), use both variables. The case of
Russia notwithstanding, the general finding is litle significant effect of these geopoli�cal
variables on dollar holdings.
Na�onal currencies are not necessarily the only sort of interna�onal reserves, nor, for that
mater, the only sort of interna�onal unit of account or means of payment. One alterna�ve
asset, though un�l recently considered by most economists “a relic of the barbarous past”, is
now regaining an ac�ve role as a component of interna�onal reserves. That is gold. The other
alterna�ve is a new one: cryptocurrency (a sign of a barbarous future?).
We long thought that central bank holdings of gold were an anachronism. Monetary
authori�es in many countries s�ll held some gold, but did not treat it as an ac�ve part of their
interna�onal reserves. That is, they did not buy or sell it. In recent years, however, central
banks, especially in Asia, have been ac�vely buying (and selling) gold.27 Ferran� (2023) finds
that from 2016 to 2021, those countries that face a higher risk of US sanc�ons increased the
share of gold in their interna�onal reserves more than countries facing a lower risk of US
sanc�ons.
Ferran� (2023) also explores whether it is sensible for a country that faces a modest risk of
sanc�ons to diversify some of its central bank’s por�olio out of US Treasuries and into
cryptocurrency, specifically bitcoin. 28 (The cryptocurrency ques�on is dis�nct from the ques�on
whether countries will issue Central Bank Digital Currencies that are used interna�onally. 29)
Somewhat surprisingly, he concludes that the answer is yes: Given that bitcoin is the asset that
is the hardest for US authori�es to block, one does not have to make op�mis�c assump�ons
about the future return to bitcoin to find that the possibility of sanc�ons gives bitcoin a place in
some por�olios and gives it a fundamental long-run value.
27
Arslanalp, Eichengreen and Simpson-Bell (2023).
28
Also, Smales (2019) and Aysan et al (2019).
29
CBDCs, if successful, would be merely another technological step akin to -- but probably less
important than -- the laying of the first successful trans-Atlan�c cable in 1865, which allowed
the real-�me trading of dollars for pounds (“cable”). CBDCs would not eliminate the need for
an interna�onal vehicle currency, a role now played by the dollar. Eichengreen (2021).
9
`
The U.S. currency has withstood repeated blows over the last five decades, most of them
self-inflicted. An example is the danger that repeated standoffs over the debt ceiling between
the two poli�cal par�es will eventually force the US Treasury to default at least par�ally on its
obliga�ons.
So far, there is s�ll litle sign of the dollar losing its posi�on as the leading interna�onal
currency. Various measures show it s�ll comfortably in the number one posi�on. Strikingly,
when a global shock raises percep�ons of risk on the part of financial markets, investors s�ll
rush to the US dollar as the safe haven currency. This is true even when the shock originates in
the United States, as was the case with the 2008 Global Financial Crisis.
The explana�on for the dollar’s staying power is easily iden�fied: Lack of an alterna�ve. The
euro remains wounded from the 2010 crisis among its periphery members and there is a
paucity of highly rated government bonds issued in the currency. The economies of Japan, the
United Kingdom, and Switzerland are not big enough to sustain the number one role. China is
big enough, but s�ll lacks financial markets that are sufficiently deep, open and liquid. With
respect to the store-of-value func�on of an interna�onal reserve asset, the recent resuscita�on
of gold could well become more important in the future. Even bitcoin could conceivably join
the roster. But these two assets cannot fulfill the func�ons of a unit of account or a means of
payments, at least not as capably as the dollar.
Let us keep in mind the dis�nc�on between an interna�onal currency and the leading
interna�onal currency. It is normal for an important economy like the eurozone or China to
conduct some of its trade in its own currency, rather than en�rely in dollars. It is even normal
for such a currency to be used in some transac�ons between other pairs of countries in its
region. This does not make it a plausible candidate to supplant the dollar as number one
interna�onal currency.
Perhaps the need to balance network externali�es against the danger of abuse of exorbitant
privilege can give rise to an equilibrium in which there is a handful of interna�onal currencies of
equal size. There may be an a priori logic suppor�ng the number three (dollar, euro, and RMB).
If there is only one premier interna�onal currency in the system, its government has a strong
incen�ve to run deficits and profit from the interna�onal seigniorage. But if there are three
currencies, there is a check on the seigniorage. Every �me that two of them are tempted to
collusively abuse the exorbitant privilege, the third government can keep them honest by
exercising greater monetary discipline, thereby offering a higher rate of return on its currency
and atrac�ng holders away from the first two.
But beter suited to the data than the triumvirate would be an equilibrium in which the
dollar has a substan�ally greater role than the euro, the euro has a substan�ally greater role
than the third-place currency, and so on, as in Zipf’s Law. 30 If the dollar can withstand the
11
`
References
Aiyar, Shekhar, Jiaqian Chen, Christian H. Ebeke, Roberto Garcia-Saltos, Tryggvi Gudmundsson,
Anna Ilyina, Alvar Kangur, 2023, "Geo-Economic Fragmentation and the Future of
Multilateralism." Staff Discussion Notes 2023, no. 001, International Monetary Fund.
Aizenman, Joshua, Yin-Wong Cheung, and XingWang Qian, 2020, “The currency composition of
international reserves, demand for international reserves, and global safe assets,” J. Int. Money
Finance.
Alogoskoufis, George and Richard Portes, 1992, "European Monetary Union and Interna�onal
Currencies in a Tripolar World," in Mathew Canzoneri, Vitorio Grilli and Paul Masson (eds),
Establishing a Central Bank: Issues in Europe and Lessons from the U.S. (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press), pp.273-302.
Arslanalp, Serkan, Barry Eichengreen, and Chima Simpson-Bell, 2022, "The stealth erosion of
dollar dominance and the rise of nontraditional reserve currencies,” Journal of International
Economics 138.
Arslanalp, Serkan, Barry Eichengreen, and Chima Simpson-Bell, 2023. “Gold as Interna�onal
Reserves: A Barbarous Relic No More?” Working Paper WP/23/14, IMF.
Aysan, Ahmet Faruk, et al, 2019, “Effects of the geopoli�cal risks on Bitcoin returns and
vola�lity.” Research in International Business and Finance 47, Jan., pp. 511–518.
Bank for International Settlements, 2022, Triennial Central Bank Survey of Foreign Exchange,
Dec..
Bergsten, C. Fred, 1997, “The Dollar and the Euro,” Foreign Affairs, July/August, 83-95.
Bertaut, Carol, Bastian von Beschwitz and Stephanie Curcuru, 2021, “The International Role of
the US Dollar,” Fednotes, October 6, Federal Reserve Board.
Boz, Emine, Camila Casas, Georgios Georgiadis, Gita Gopinath, Helena Le Mezo, Arnaud Mehl,
and Tra Nguyen, 2020, “Patterns in Invoicing Currency in Global Trade,” International Monetary
Fund.
Chinn, Menzie, and Jeffrey Frankel, 2007, “Will the Euro Eventually Surpass the Dollar as
Leading International Reserve Currency?” in G7 Current Account Imbalances: Sustainability and
Adjustment, edited by Richard Clarida (University of Chicago Press). NBER WP No. 11510.
Chinn, Menzie D., Hiro Ito, and Robert N. McCauley, 2022, "Do central banks rebalance their
currency shares?" Journal of International Money and Finance 122.
12
`
Chau, Vu, Ethan Ilzetski, and Kenneth Rogoff, 2022, "Zipf's Law for International currencies,"
Harvard University, March.
Chitu, Livia, Barry Eichengreen and Arnaud Mehl, 2014. "When Did the Dollar overtake sterling
as the leading international currency? Evidence from the bond markets." Journal of
Development Economics 111 (2014): 225-245.
Cohen, Benjamin J., 1971, The Future of Sterling as an International Currency (London:
Macmillan).
Dobson, Wendy, and Paul Masson, 2009, “Will the Renminbi Become a World Currency?” China
Economic Review, vol. 20, no. 1, pp. 124–35.
Dooley, Michael, J. Saul Lizondo, and Donald Mathieson, 1989, "The Currency Composi�on of
Foreign Exchange Reserves," IMF Staff Papers 36, pp. 385-434.
Eichengreen, Barry, 2010,. “Managing a Mul�ple Reserve Currency World,” The 21st Century
International Monetary System, edited by Jeffrey Sachs, Masahiro Kawai, Jong-Wha Lee, and
Wing Thye Woo (Manila: Asian Development Bank).
Eichengreen, Barry, 2011a, Exorbitant Privilege: The Rise and Fall of the Dollar and the Future of
the International Monetary System (Oxford: Oxford University Press).
Eichengreen, Barry. 2011b. “The Renminbi as an Interna�onal Currency.” Journal of Policy
Modeling 33 (5): 723-30.
Eichengreen, Barry (2021), "Will Central Bank Digital Currencies Doom Dollar
Dominance?" Project Syndicate 9.
Eichengreen, Barry, and Marc Flandreau. 2009. “The Rise and Fall of the Dollar (or When Did the
Dollar Replace Sterling as the Leading Reserve Currency?” European Review of Economic
History 13.3: 377-411.
Eichengreen, Barry, and Marc Flandreau, 2012, “The Federal Reserve, the Bank of England and
the Rise of the Dollar as an Interna�onal Currency, 1914–39,” Open Economies Review 23, no. 1:
57-87.
Eichengreen, Barry, and Jeffrey Frankel 1996, "The SDR, Reserve Currencies, and the Future of
the International Monetary System," in The Future of the SDR in Light of Changes in the
International Financial System, edited by Michael Mussa, James Boughton, and Peter Isard
(International Monetary Fund).
Eichengreen, Barry, and Donald Mathieson, 2001, “The Currency Composi�on of Foreign
Exchange Reserves: Retrospect and Prospect,” in The Impact of EMU on Europe and the
Developing Countries, edited by Charles Wyplosz (Oxford University Press).
13
`
Eichengreen, Barry, Arnaud Mehl, and Livia Chitu, 2017, How Global Currencies Work (Princeton
University Press).
Farhi, Emmanuel, and Mateo Maggiori. 2018, "A model of the interna�onal monetary
system." Quarterly Journal of Economics 133.1: 295-355.
Ferranti, Matthew, 2023, “Hedging Sanctions Risk: Cryptocurrency in Central Bank Reserves,” PhD
thesis, Chapter 2 of Department of Economics, Harvard University, May 3.
Frankel, Jeffrey, 1984, “The Yen/Dollar Agreement: Liberalizing Japanese Capital Markets,” Policy
Analyses in International Economics No. 9 (Ins�tute for Interna�onal Economics: Washington,
DC).
--- 1992, "On the Dollar," in The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance (MacMillan
Press Reference Books, London).
----, 1995, "Still the Lingua Franca: The Exaggerated Death of the Dollar," Foreign Affairs, 74,
4, July/August, 9-16
---- 2012, "Internationalization of the RMB and Historical Precedents," Journal of Economic
Integration, vol.27, no.3, pp. 329-365.
Frieden, Jeffry, 2000, “The Political Economy of The Euro as an International Currency,” in The
Euro as a Stabilizer in the International Economic System, edited by Robert Mundell and
Armand Clesse (Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers).
Goldberg, Linda. 2010. “Is the Interna�onal Role of the Dollar Changing?” Current Issues in
Economics and Finance 16 (1), January.
Goldberg, Linda S., and Cédric Tille, 2008, "Vehicle currency use in interna�onal trade." Journal
of international Economics 76.2: 177-192.
Gopinath, Gita, 2015, “The international price system,” Jackson Hole Symposium, volume 27
(Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City). NBER WP 21646.
Gopinath, Gita, and Jeremy C. Stein (2018). Trade invoicing, bank funding, and central bank
reserve holdings. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 108, pp. 542-46.
Gopinath, Gita, and Jeremy C. Stein, 2021, “Banking, Trade, and the Making of a Dominant
Currency,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 136, Issue 2, May: 783–830.
Grubel, Herbert G., 1963, World Monetary Reform: Plans and Issues, (Stanford: Stanford
University Press).
Hale, David, 1995, "A Yen for Change: Why the Yen as a Reserve Currency is Not Far-fetched,"
The International Economy, May/June.
14
`
Iancu, Alina, Lusinyan, Lusine, Yiqun Wu, Andrea Gamba, Sakai Ando, Gareth Anderson, Neil
Meads, Ethan Boswell, and Shushanik Hakobyan (2020), Reserve Currencies in an Evolving
International Monetary System. No. 20/002. Interna�onal Monetary Fund.
Ito, Takatoshi, 2010, “China as Number One: How about the Renminbi?” Asian Economic Policy
Review, vol. 5, no. 2, December, pp. 249–76.
Ito, Hiro, and Robert N. McCauley, 2020, "Currency composi�on of foreign exchange
reserves." Journal of International Money and Finance 102: 102104.
Kenen, Peter, 1983, The Role of the Dollar as an Interna�onal Currency, Occasional Papers No.
13 (New York: Group of Thirty).
Kenen, Peter B.,1987, "Changing Views About the Role of the SDR and Implica�ons for its
Atributes," in Sidney Dell, ed., The International Monetary System and its Reform, Part II
(Amsterdam: North Holland), pp.373-385.
Kindleberger, Charles, 1967, “The Poli�cs of Interna�onal Money and World Language,” Essays
in International Finance no. 61 (Princeton University Press).
Kindleberger, Charles, 1981, International Money (London: George Allen & Unwin).
Kindleberger, Charles, 1995, “Is the Dollar Going the Way of Sterling, the Guilder, the Ducat, and
the Bezant?” The International Economy, 9, no. 3, May/June: 609-11. Reprinted in Kindleberger,
Essays in history: financial, economic, personal (University of Michigan Press), 1999.
Krugman, Paul, 1984, "The Interna�onal Role of the Dollar: Theory and Prospect," in John Bilson
and Richard Marston (eds), Exchange Rate Theory and Practice (Chicago: University of Chicago
Press), pp.261-278.
Kunz, Diane, 1995, "The Fall of the Dollar Order," Foreign Affairs 74, pp.22-27.
Lindert, Peter, 1969, “Key Currencies and Gold: 1900–1913,” Princeton Studies in International
Finance No.24, August, pp. 16-22.
Matsuyama, Kiminori; Nobuhiro Kiyotaki and Akihiko Matsui. 1993. “Toward A Theory of
Interna�onal Currency,” Review of Economic Studies 60, April: 283-307.
Mosler, Mar�n, and Niklas Potra�e, 2020, "Interna�onal poli�cal alignment during the Trump
presidency: vo�ng at the UN general assembly." International interactions 46, no. 3: 481-497.
Obs�eld, Maurice. 2011, "The SDR as an interna�onal reserve asset: what future?” Interna�onal
Growth Centre, March..
Obs�eld, Maurice, and Haonan Zhou, 2022, “The global dollar cycle,“ Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity , Fall. NBER WP 31004.
Park, Yung Chul, and Chi-Young Song, 2010, “RMB Interna�onaliza�on: Prospects and
Implica�ons for Economic Integra�on in East Asia,” Asian Economic Papers, October.
15
`
Portes, Richard, and Helene Rey, 1998, “The Emergence of the Euro as an Interna�onal
Currency,” Economic Policy volume 13 (26), 306-343. NBER WP No. 6424.
Posen, Adam S., 2008,"Why the euro will not rival the dollar." International Finance 11.1: 75-
100.
Prasad, Eswar, 2019, “Has the dollar lost ground as the dominant interna�onal currency?”
Brookings Ins�tu�on.
Prasad, Eswar, and Le (Sandy) Ye. 2012. The Renminbi’s Role in the Global Monetary System
(Washington, DC: Brookings).
Rey, Helene, 2001, “Interna�onal Trade and Currency Exchange,” Review of Economic Studies
68, no. 2, April, 443-464.
Schenk, Catherine, 2010, The Decline of Sterling: Managing the Retreat of an Interna�onal
Currency (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
Smales, L. A., 2019, “Bitcoin as a safe haven: Is it even worth considering?” Finance Research
Letters 30, pp. 385–393.
Solomon, Robert, 1976, The International Monetary System, 1945-1976: An Insider's View (New
York: Harper and Row).
Subramanian, Arvind. 2011a. “Renminbi Rules: The Condi�onal Imminence of the Reserve
Currency Transi�on.” Working Paper Series No. 11-14 (Washington, D.C.: Peterson Ins�tute for
Interna�onal Economics), September.
Subramanian, Arvind. 2011b. Eclipse: Living in the Shadow of China’s Economic Dominance
(Washington, DC: Peterson Ins�tute for Interna�onal Economics).
SWIFT, accessed April 2023, “RMB Tracker: Monthly repor�ng and sta�s�cs on renminbi (RMB)
progress towards becoming an interna�onal currency,”
Takagi, Shinji, 2011, “Interna�onalizing the Yen, 1984–2003: Unfinished Agenda or Mission
Impossible?” in Y. W. Cheung and G. Ma, eds., Asia and China in the Global Economy (Singapore:
World Scien�fic Publishing)..
Tavlas, George, 1993, “The Deutsche Mark as an Interna�onal Currency,” in Dilip Das, ed.,
International Finance: Contemporary Issues (Routledge, London), 566-579.
Tavlas, George, and Yuzuru Ozeki, 1992, “The Interna�onaliza�on of Currencies: An Appraisal of
the Japanese Yen.” IMF Occasional Paper No. 90 (Washington, D.C.: IMF).
Triffin, Robert, 1960, Gold and the Dollar Crisis (New Haven: Yale University Press).
Truman, Edwin M, 2022, "The IMF should enhance the role of SDRs to strengthen the
interna�onal monetary system." PIIE Working Paper 22-20 (Peterson Ins�tute for Interna�onal
Economics, Washington, DC).
16
`
Williamson, John, 2009. “Why SDRs Could Rival the Dollar,” PIIE Policy Brief 09-20, September
(Peterson Ins�tute for Interna�onal Economics, Washington, DC).
Zhang, Longmei, 2023, "Capital Account Liberaliza�on and China’s Financial Integra�on." M-
RCBG Associate Working Paper Series, Harvard University.
17
`