1theses 10
1theses 10
BY
MARTHA GETACHEW
ADDI S AB AB A
J UNE , 2 0 0 3
ACKNOWLEDGMENT
1.1 Background……………………………...…………………………..1
1.2 Statement of the problem. ………….……………………………….2
1.3 Objectives of the Study…………………………………………...…6
1.4 Hypothesis of the Study……………………………………………..7
Chapter 4: METHODOLOGY………………………………..…...……43
6.1 Conclusion……………………………………………………..…..91
6.2 Limitation of the Study………………………………………….…93
6.3 Policy Implication…………………………………………...……..93
References………………………………………………………….……...96
Appendix 1: Results of Chapter five……………….………………….....101
Appendix 2: Results of Data property……………………………….…...107
Appendix 3: Questionnaire………………………………………....……110
LIST OF TABLES
Page
Table 1.1 Current and Future HIV/AIDS infected population and adult
prevalence rate, 2002 and 2010……………………………...….4
Table 2.1 Classification and Functions of ARVs……………………….....11
Table 2.2 Too early and too late prescriptions of ARVs………………..…13
Table 4.1 Expected signs and relationships of variables………………..…56
Table 5.1 Socio-demographic characteristics of respondents………...….101
Table 5.2 Age and family size of respondents…………………………...101
Table 5.3 Knowledge and practice of respondents……………………....102
Table 5.4 Attitude of respondents towards ARVs………………….……102
Table 5.5 Reasons for not paying…………………………………….…..102
Table 5.6 Willingness to pay amounts……………………...………..…..103
Table 5.7 Summary statistics of willingness to pay……………………...103
Table 5.8 Willingness to pay and initial bid price…………………….....103
Table 5.9 Willingness to pay and occupational status of respondents...…103
Table 5.10 Test for free riding…………………………………...……....103
Table 5.11 Correlation matrix of income and WTP………………...……104
Table 5.12 Result of the Tobit estimation…………………………………75
Table 5.13 Result of the CLAD estimation………………………….…….82
Table 5.14 Results of the 25th and 75th quantile regressions………….….106
Table 5.15 Estimated total WTP and demand……………...…………..….86
LIST OF FIGURES
Page
Figure 1.1 Essential enzymes and ARV drugs……………...……………..12
Figure 3.1 Economic Valuation………………………………………...…24
Figure 4.1 Bidding game with Birr 350 to Birr 150 starting points……….46
Figure 5.1 Estimated demand curve for ARV drugs………………...….....87
LIST OF ABBREVIATION
In this study, the willingness to pay of people living with HIV/AIDS for anti-
440 adults living with HIV/AIDS. The research result indicates that the mean
willingness to pay for the drugs is Birr 163.6 and the median is Birr 100, per
willingness to pay reveals that individuals with larger family size, with others
paying for their treatment cost other than themselves and with spouse
deceased are less willing to pay for the drugs. Individuals with higher income
are more willing to pay. Older respondents are also willing to pay more.
acquiring the drugs, if the drugs be marketed. This calls for the participation of
equityisdesired.
Key words: Contingent valuation method, Willingness to pay, antiretroviral
drugs, CLAD
CHAPTER ONE
INTRODUCTION
1.1 BACKGROUND
The HIV/AIDS pandemic continues to be an alarming problem for Ethiopia where 2.6
million, including about 250,000 children are HIV positive and an estimated 400,000
Ethiopians have already developed AIDS. The number of PLWHA is growing rapidly in
the country in general and in Addis Ababa in particular. The incidence of voluntary HIV
testing and counselling as well as early entry into the continuum of care directed at
PLWHA is very low. These circumstances are aggravated in Addis Ababa by a general lack
of awareness of the confidential services that are available to HIV/AIDS clients (UNAIDS,
2002). Of the total residents of Addis Ababa, 17% live with HIV/AIDS. In other words, one
in six adults (15-49 years old) is already infected with the virus. Frighteningly, a vast
It is estimated that by 2004, of the total death in Addis Ababa, 60% will be an outcome of
AIDS- this in other words means out of five people that die, three would be due to AIDS
1
(MOH, 2000). While the epidemic results death on people in all age range, the effect it has
people in this age group will die every day because of AIDS. The consequence of such a
death toll will definitely have an adverse effect on the socio-economic development of the
country.
There is no cure for HIV/AIDS, but in developed countries, AIDS is being turned into a
manageable and treatable illness instead of death sentence with the use of life prolonging
HIV/AIDS drugs. Data from the United States show that the combination therapies known
75% and AIDS- related morbidity by 73% over three years. Similarly in the Brazilian state
of São Paulo, AIDS-related mortality has declined by 32% since protease inhibitors became
However, in the African region, the number of HIV infected people who can access and
afford ARV therapy is still very small. Of the 25 million people that are living with the
virus, only 10,000-25,000 people were receiving ARV therapy in the year 2001
(UNAIDS/WHO, 2001). The high price of many AIDS drugs –especially ARV drugs- is
one of the main barriers to their availability in developing countries. Fortunately, the price
of ARV drugs is coming down (discussed in detail in the next chapter) as a direct response
by major drug companies to the UNAIDS and WHO ARV Accelerated Initiatives in several
countries. Similarly, some companies in Brazil, Thailand and India are producing generic
products that are much cheaper and affordable to more people in the developing countries.
2
Hence, it is anticipated that in the next few years there will be a bigger number of people in
Ethiopia is ranked as the 168th country in human development, where most of its population
has “low access” to essential drugs. In terms of priority in public expenditure, over a nine
years period (1990-1999) the public expenditure on health slightly increased from 0.9% to
1.2% of GDP. On the other hand, the total expenditure on military expenditure increased
from 8.5% to 9.4% of GDP over the same period. The Gini1 index, which measures
inequality over the entire distribution of income or consumption, indicates that it is 55.1%
for the country. With regard to human poverty index, the country is ranked as 87th out of 88
With regard to the HIV profile of the country, Ethiopia is the 16th highest in HIV/AIDS
prevalence and the third largest number of people living with the virus next to South Africa
and India. Official reports estimate that 2.2 to 2.6 million people are currently infected
with HIV/AIDS where around two million are adults and 200 to 250 thousand children
(MOH, 2002 and UNAIDS, 2002). While the number of new AIDS cases reported to the
Ministry of health in 2001 are 15,202 this figure was estimated to be as high as 219,400.
The peak ages for AIDS cases are 25 to 29 for both males and females. This implies that
given the average incubation period between the time of infection and emergence of full
3
blown AIDS is about eight years, the mean age at which people become infected is 15 to 24
years.
Of the total infected population, about 91% of infections occur among the economically
active age group, 15-49 years. This indisputably has a huge social and economic impact on
For 2001, the estimated adult HIV prevalence rate was 6.6% where the highest prevalence
was observed among the age group 15-24. Compared to rural prevalence rate, which is
years by 2001 and 59 years by 2014. However, due to the increase in HIV-related deaths,
instead of 53 years in 2001 the life expectancy declined to 46years and 50 instead of 59 by
2014.
Ethiopia is identified to be hit by the Next Wave of HIV/AIDS among four other countries -
Nigeria, Russia, India and China (NIC, 2002). By 2010, it is estimated that the five
countries, which comprise over 40% of the world’s population, will have the largest
number of HIV/AIDS case on earth if nothing is done presently. The following table shows
the estimates of current and future HIV/AIDS-infected population and adult prevalence rate
1
The Gini coefficient will be equal to 0 when the distribution is completely egalitarian while if the society’s
total income accrues to only one person/household unit, leaving the rest with no income at all the coefficient
will be equal to 1, or 100%.
4
Table 1.1. Current and future HIV/AIDS-infected population and adult prevalence rate,
2002 2010
27%) will be the highest among the five countries. Because of the high current rate of adult
prevalence, widespread poverty, low educational levels, and the government’s limited
capacity to respond more actively, 7-10 million Ethiopians will probably be infected by
The development of ARVs helps to improve the survival and quality of life of many people
living with HIV/AIDS. Despite the remarkable success of the drugs, however, their prices
are very expensive. According to UNAIDS (2002), the projected annual expenditure
requirements for HIV/AIDS care and support by 2005, excluding the costs of infrastructure
required for delivery of effective HIV treatment are US$ 4,400 million. Out of this more
than half, 69%, is taken by sub-Saharan Africa. The estimated figure for South and South
East Asia is 15%, East Asia and Pacific 1.8%, Latin America and Caribbean 12 %. The
5
remaining 0.45% and 1.13% go to East Europe and Central Asia, and North Africa and
In particular, it is estimated that treatment of all people living with HIV/AIDS with
HAART could represent 1% of the GDP in Latin America, 14.6% in South East Asia and
It is argued that the provision of a fully subsidized ARV treatment program by the
transmission programme, which is estimated to cost 2.28 million USD per year (Policy
framework, 2002).
Clinical trials for vaccine against HIV are underway and have progressed to phase III
human testing in the US, Canada, Netherlands, and Thailand. However, a vaccine is
developed to protect against certain viral subtypes of HIV in the test countries, which
probably will not be effective against the most common subtypes of HIV in countries which
will be hit by the Next Wave of HIV/AIDS-Nigeria, Ethiopia, Russia, India and China
(NIC, 2002). This leaves the countries to focus on anti-AIDS education to bring
behavioural change to prevent new cases and ARV drugs to prolong the lifetime of people
already living with the virus until a highly effective vaccine is developed for these
countries.
The direct result of the inaccessibility of ARV drugs in health structures in Ethiopia is the
development of ARV distribution channels outside the health care system. Currently,
6
although ARV drugs are not officially available in the country, some patients are
nonetheless receiving ARV treatment (UNAIDS, 2002). The drugs are traded in the
“parallel market” for prices from Birr 1,000 to Birr 5,000 (US$115-$575) per month.
The Ethiopian government is considering provision of the drugs for free only in the case of
when the drugs are available in the market, will be based on user fees for other individuals
living with the virus. With respect to this the Ethiopian government seems to strike a
middle ground between abandoning all other drugs and buy only ARVs and distribute the
drugs for free to all PLWHA, and leaving this totally to the private sector.
To estimate the willingness to pay of people living with HIV/AIDS for anti-retroviral
drugs
7
The hypothesis of the paper on the value of life is based on the assumption stated by
Johansson (1995). Individuals prefer to stay alive even if this virtually means with a zero
income i.e.,
y = income
and some finite positive level, which is often arbitrarily set equal to one, where 0 is the
worst possible health status and 1 is the best possible health status.
In other words, V (p, 0, z1) > V (p, y, z0) where z1 means being alive, z0 means being dead,
and y > 0. Thus, it is not possible to define a willingness to pay such that the inequality is
turned into equality i.e., even if the individual pays his/her entire income the inequality
remains.
employment status, years of living with the virus and treatment cost of opportunistic
8
infections whereas most socio-demographic characteristics of individuals are not
significant factors for determining the willingness to pay for ARV drugs.
CHAPTER TWO
intercourse and Utero-from infected mothers to newborn children or contact with infected
blood. The virus survives by replicating inside CD42 blood cells, which normally protect
the body against infection. Currently two families of this virus are known- HIV-1 and HIV-
2 where the latter was discovered three years later. These exhibit extensive genetic
diversity, although both result in AIDS. The transmission rate of HIV-2 appears to be lower
compared with HIV-1 and the rate of progression to disease may also be slower.
3
There are four phases of HIV infection . Soon after entering the body, HIV starts to
replicate and destroy CD4 cells. Generally a decrease in CD4 count is correlated with HIV
disease progression, which can be identified by running a blood test. This first phase is
2
CD4 test, cluster differentiation test, could be used to measure how much damage has been done by HIV to a
person’s immune system.
3
Mainly extracted from Sande and Moelling, (2000) . Guide to HIV/AIDS Therapy, 9th ed.
9
called the acute HIV syndrome stage; in this stage the virus causes flu-like symptoms
A few weeks after the first stage, the viral load (level of virus in the body) levels gradually
decrease and CD4 cell counts rise again. This phase of the disease is called the
asymptomatic stage. Patients sometimes remain in this stage of infection for several
months or even years. During this time, the virus continues to replicate and attack CD4
cells, although the harmful effects of HIV on the immune system do not necessarily cause
symptoms. As the virus continues to replicate in the second stage, the viral load eventually
In the third phase, the symptomatic stage, patients may begin to develop recurring
symptoms of enlarged lymph nodes, weight loss, fever, diarrhoea, rashes, sores, or oral
infections.
Full-blown AIDS is the last stage of HIV infection in which people consequently suffer
from certain conditions, including opportunistic infections- infections that develop due to
lowered immunity. People with AIDS may die from these opportunistic infections rather
Although HIV infection is incurable and there is no vaccine that has been proven to prevent
the virus, it does not mean that there is no way of prolonging life for carriers of the virus.
Anti-retroviral drugs boost the immune system and help it to fight HIV infections. This can
mean that instead of becoming sicker, a person with AIDS can regain good health. If the
drugs are taken properly they work by suppressing the HIV virus so that it drops to a very
low level in the body. When this happens, the immune system gradually recovers and
10
regains its ability to fight infections, which is reflected by a rise in the CD4 count. In
healthy adults there are between 700 and 1500 CD4 cells per cubic millimetre of blood. A
count below 500 is considered a sign of a depressed immune system; below 200 heightens
the risk of opportunistic infections; below 100 signifies severe immune damage (Panos,
2001). Studies show that dramatic reductions in the viral load can be achieved by using
ARV drugs.
There are currently three types of anti-retroviral drugs: Nucleoside Reverse Transcriptase
The ideal treatment strategy for people living with HIV/AIDS is triple combination, which
involves the use of one protease inhibitor and two reverse transcriptase inhibitors
(Unicef/UNAIDS, 2001).
Studies show that using triple combination therapy reduces not only viral load by 99% but
also the rate of mortality due to HIV/AIDS by as much as half. Among those in triple
11
Delavirdine mesylate Non-Nucleoside RTI ”
Didenosine (ddI) Nucleoside RTI ”
Efavirenz Non-Nucleoside RTI ”
Indinavir Protease Inhibitor ”
Lamivudine (3TC) Nucleoside RTI ”
Nelfinavir Protease Inhibitor ”
Ritonavir Protease Inhibitor ”
Saquinavir Protease Inhibitor ”
Stavudine (d4T) Nucleoside RTI ”
Zalcitabine (ddC) Nucleoside RTI ”
Source: Sande and Moelling, 2000.
*RTI = reverse transcriptease inhibitors
**MTCT = mother-to-child transmission
Therapeutic antiretroviral drugs target essential enzymes of the virus to supress HIV/AIDS
Viral RNA is copied into Viral DNA integrates Viral proteins are cut
DNA by virus specific into the by the virus-specific
enzyme chromosomes of the PROTEASE for
REVERSE target cell. assembly of the new
TRANSCRIPTASSE INTEGRASE particle and its
maturation
DDI Indinavir
D4T Nelfinavir
DDC Amprenavir
3TC
12
Abacavir
Nevirapine
Non-Nucleoside RTI Delavirdine
Efavirez
Improvement of a patient’s quality of life is determined by the starting time of taking the
ARV drugs. Prescribing the drugs both too early and too late in a patient’s illness has its
own adverse effects. This is especially true for patients with asymptomatic HIV infection.
13
viral suppression resistance if viral suppression is
-Possible decreased risk of HIV sub-optimal
transmission. -Limitation of future ARV
treatment options.
Source: HIV 101, 2001
Therefore, if the drugs are prescribed too early, the drugs’ side effects may be noxious,
while the health of the person living with the virus may deteriorate if prescription is too
late. Most guidelines focus on CD4 counts because it is possible to begin therapy by
determining the infection level. Even if the US and the British ARV guidelines mandate
commencement of ARV therapy if a patient’s CD4 count is below 350 and recommend
treatment if the count is in the range of 350 to 500, clinical trial and observational data
indicate that since the risk of opportunistic diseases increases markedly when the CD4 cell
count declines to <200 cells/mm3, patients with this level of CD4 cell count or clinically
defined AIDS should be offered the therapy (HIV101, 2001). This is also supported by
Gebregiorgis (2001) who argues that least developed countries should stick to a CD4 count
of <200, as this is the only proven standard for treatment. However, in resource-poor
settings CD4 and viral load counts are unlikely to be available on all patients. When to start
ARVs is then determined by clinical symptoms such as oral candidiasis, weight loss greater
The assumed positive impacts of ARVs are reduction in the need for inpatient hospital
their time within the workforce; the reduction of the number of new infections. This
assumes that a reduction in viral load leads to reduced infectivity and also that there is a
14
decline in risky behaviour, including an increase in the practice of voluntary counselling
and testing. However, recent studies indicate that for a certain percentage of all people
living with AIDS, ARVs are ineffective (Forsythe, 1998). It may also induce people to
become careless and spread the disease if HIV infection is perceived to be a treatable
disease. Moreover, the costs of ARVs may far exceed any economic benefit.
It is generally accepted that the most effective form of treatment is a combination of three
ARVs, including one protease inhibitor. However, because the protease inhibitors are new
and relatively expensive, many developing countries don’t view providing access to this
full complement drugs as an affordable option (Forsythe, 1998). Floyd and Gilks (1997)
identified that triple combination therapies’ cost range from US$ 662 to $993 per month,
double combination therapies range in costs from US$ 403 to $773 per month, while the
one therapy, Nevirapine, costs US$272 per month. At the beginning of year 2000 the price
of combination ARV drugs to treat one patient for one year was typically between US$
Pharmaceutical companies primarily undertake R&D and hold patents in their new
discoveries, which only they have the right to manufacture and sell. Most of these
15
Generics Manufactures, on the other hand, primarily produce medicines based on
the formulae of the patented companies. They may do some additional research to
produce their own versions. These are based both in the North and the developing world
(Panos, 2002). Generic or non-patented drugs can be much cheaper than patented ones
because in the case of imitation the cost stream is much smaller than investing in
innovation.
The primary goal of both pharmaceutical and generic companies is to make profit. For
pharmaceuticals, profit comes from the sales of patented drugs. Even if pharmaceutical
companies recognize that ARVs are very expensive to be affordable for developing
countries, they are also concerned that if they offer discounts there might be arbitrage
opportunities (Forsythe, 1998). For generics, profit generally comes form selling drugs that
are non-patented, no longer patented or patented elsewhere- at prices lower than those of
their competitors. Generic ARVs are being produced in countries that ignore patents, such
as Brazil, India and Thailand. However, these countries are not free from pressure from the
giant companies.
To ensure steady future demand for the drugs, the pharmaceutical companies ask
developing countries to sign extended contracts for the purchase of ARVs. Recently,
Two international attempts have been made to increase access to the drugs. The first effort,
Accelerating Access Initiative, was launched in May 2000 by the joint UN programme on
HIV/AIDS (Panos, 2002). By the end of 2000, prices of US$500 to US$800 were being
16
negotiated by low- and-middle income countries for therapies based on patented and
generic drugs. By December 2001, certain generic combinations were on offer for as low as
US$350 per person per year (Unicef/UNAIDS, 2001). The second international attempt to
increase access to drugs was the Global Fund for HIV/AIDS, Tuberculosis and Malaria.
This was launched in October 2002, which announced that generic drugs could be
Squibb, Glaxo Wellcome, Merck and co., and HoffmanLa Roche) have dropped their third
world prices for components of HAART, which for those who can afford has turned to be
good news.
ARV T RE AT M E NT S AT M A CR O L E VE L
Analysing ARV treatments at macro level could involve - affordability, cost effectiveness,
for ARV treatment, ARV treatment cost per person and total resources of the country. A
WHO/UNAIDS (1998) estimation of the total cost required to have an ARV treatment
programme to treat the whole adult HIV/AIDS infected people in Ethiopia reveals that this
will cost 1.35 billion USD per year. If only people with actual AIDS cases are to be treated,
17
then 200 million USD per year is required. This does not include the total cost required for
capacity building – the human and physical resources required for ARV treatment. These
are:
• Laboratory services capable of offering the sophisticated tests required for monitoring
ARV treatments
• Patient follow-up to ensure compliance with drugs and/or manage side effects
• Strengthened health education concerning safe feeding practices for mothers receiving
According to one survey in Addis Ababa carried out by UNWECP in 2001, the majority of
hospitals and higher clinics in the city deliver fragmented services to HIV/AIDS
clients/patients. Not all hospitals and higher clinics have laboratories for HIV screening or
confirmatory testing. Furthermore, the majority of health facilities do not use supportive
laboratory services to conduct staging of the disease or to monitor the progress of ARV
treatment in their patients. There are only five licensed diagnostic facilities that perform
limited types of HIV tests. Of these facilities only two conduct CD4 cell count and viral
(Policy Framework, 2002). The Ethiopian government therefore does not consider a fully
subsidized ARV treatment program to be affordable to the country. However, the total cost
of treatment and testing for the prevention of MTCT program is estimated at 2.28 million
USD per year, which is believed to be affordable to the country. The cost of PMTCT
Proportion of women that have access to antenatal care (35%ANC coverage)= 1,140,000
Total cost for treatment and testing cost 570,000+1,710,000 = 2.28 mill USD
Cost Effectiveness: the decision to use ARV treatment by an individual is based on the
willingness and ability to pay. However, the decision whether ART is likely to represent a
analysis. The guidance module on ARV treatments of WHO/ UNAIDS (1998) suggests that
prevention of MTCT is the most cost effective. Triple combination therapy for infected
adults, however, is cost effective in countries with per capita incomes over USD 8,000.
Cost Saving Potential: If ARV treatments prevent HIV- related health problems like TB,
then they will result in some cost savings. However, Floyd and Gilks (1998) note that
therapies would only be cost saving in countries with average per capita incomes of at least
US$ 8,776.
19
Equity and Access: This is concerned with the distribution of resources for ARV
treatment. Equity addresses the issue of who is likely to benefit from ARV treatment, which
has an important implication for financing policy. The second issue addressed is the
fairness of such an access. WHO/UNAIDS (1998) guidance module states that since ARV
treatments require specialized staff and equipment, urban populations are more likely to
have access to them than rural populations and some marginalized and vulnerable groups.
With respect to financing, different options can be considered including public funding,
national insurance and social security schemes, private insurance, voluntary sector or
donor financing and development loans. The WHO/UNAIDS guideline states that:
“unless the public sector can afford to provide a substantial portion of the funding required
for ARV therapy, or unless social insurance is wide spread, it is unlikely that provision to
The ARV drugs supply and use policy of the Federal Democratic Repulic of Ethiopia was
formulated in 2002, fifteen years after one of anti-retroviral agent (AZT/Zidovudine) was a
common medical practice to prescribe to AIDS patients in other parts of the world.
20
• Prolonging and improving the quality lives of PLWHA thereby making them
productive and contribute to the well being of their families and development of
their country.
With regard to supply strategies of ARV drugs the policy, among some other more, outlines
the following:
The government shall supply ARV drugs used for prevention of MTCT to the
ARV drugs shall be exempted from taxation; supplied at a reduced price through
21
CHAPTER THREE
LITERATURE REVIEW
The first section of this chapter describes some of the methods of economic valuation
including revealed preference method, stated preference method and human capital
willingness to pay. The last section of the chapter reviews empirical CV studies in
health economics.
Several practical methods can be used to measure willingness to pay for goods and services
in general and health services in particular. The three most frequently used and/or
22
suggested methods are indirect methods using market data, survey techniques, and the
human capital approach (Johansson, 1995). The first two are the most common ways of
service has positive economic value, then preferences show up through individuals’
willingness to pay (WTP) for the good or service in question. WTP in the market is made
up of two components: the price or what is actually paid and the consumer’s surplus or the
excess of WTP over the price. The latter is then a measure of the net gain from the purchase
of a marketed good. On the other hand, in a pure non-market context, all WTP is
consumer’s surplus because there is no market price. A disservice, or “bad”, has negative
economic value shown up by the WTP to avoid the bad in question, as a willingness to
accept (WTA) compensation to tolerate the disservice (Summary Guide, 2002). For cost
benefit analysis based on the Hicks-Kaldor compensation test, WTP would seem to be the
appropriate measure for gainers from some resource allocation decision, and WTA the
proper measure for losers from that same allocation (Bateman and Turner, 1997).
These methods are referred to as indirect methods since the preference revelation is indirect
via a market. In these methods market prices are used to evaluate risks. For example, the
economic value of noise nuisance can be reflected in house prices where houses in noisy
areas are likely to be cheaper than comparable houses in quieter but otherwise similar areas
(Summary Guide, 2002). This method is used to study individuals’ averting behaviour
where by they buy themselves a risk reduction for money. WTP can be estimated either by
23
observing the prices that people pay for goods in various markets or by observing
individual expenditures of money or time to obtain goods, or to avoid their loss, and by
inferring WTP amounts (Abelson, 1996). Revealed preference uses direct observation of
actual values for complementary effects. The different approaches used to measure value
impacts are:
Travel cost model, which is used to value recreational assets via the expenditures on
travelling to the site. The idea is to collect information about preferences from people’s
actual behaviour. In other words, people do not buy the commodity (visit an area) unless
they find it worth its price (travel cost). However, this method captures only use values and
Direct choice model or random utility model uses choices between alternative options
instance is the presence of an air conditioner in a home or in a car to reduce exposure to air
pollution. However, not only the cost of averting behaviour is inherently difficult to
measure but also measuring the cost of averting behaviour is complicated by the fact that
Hedonic Pricing measures the effects that show up in labour markets (or property
markets). This is the most common indirect method used to study wage differentials in the
labour market. Given firms’ and workers’ institutional environment, wage differentials can
24
be explained as firms’ different offers of wages depending on what health risks are
involved, and workers’ different preferences for safety. If a firm has undertaken risk
reduction measures, the maximum wage it is willing to offer will be lower than otherwise.
In general, some argue that revealed preference studies, whether based on labour market
data or consumer behaviour, make untested assumptions about individuals’ risk perceptions
This is the modern name for the survey method. Stated preference approaches are based on
constructed markets. That is, under this approach people are asked to state the economic
value they attach to those goods and services under consideration. The stated preference
approach elicits economic values by using two methods: the contingent valuation method
where respondents to a questionnaire are asked for their WTP and choice modelling which
refers to a variety of procedures for inferring WTP from sets of rankings or ratings of
Mitchell and Carson (1993) acknowledge Robert K. Davis (1963) to be the first to use
CVM for the estimation of the benefits of outdoor recreation. This method provides the
The following figure summarizes the concepts that have been introduced so far.
25
Fig.3.1 Economic valuation
From the above figure it is obvious that the objective of economic valuation technique is to
uncover the total economic value of the good in question. The value may accrue to users-
persons who make direct or indirect use of the good and to those who make no direct use of
the good (non-users); an instance for the latter is the WTP for endangered species, even
though the individual may not have seen, or expect to see, the species in question.
Under this view, the value of an individual is equal to the value of his/her contribution to
total production, and assumes that this value can be measured as his/her earnings
26
(Johansson, 1995). This implies that the value of preventing someone’s statistical death or
injury is equal to the gain in the present value of his/her future earnings.
Where: Πt+i = probability of the individual surviving from age t to age t+i
r = discount rate
According to this approach. The value of preventing the death of an individual who is
presently at age t is the discounted present value of that individual’s earnings over the
The implication of the approach is that not only is the statistical life of retired people has
zero value but also the statistical life of children is likely to be worth less than that of adults
in or near their best period of earnings. The latter is due to the fact that because of
discounting and the time lag before children become productive participants in the
economy, the human capital approach places a much lower value on saving children’s lives
compared with saving the lives of adults in their peak earnings years. People whose value
of production is not reflected by wage payments (like housewives) are also difficult to
handle within the human capital approach framework. Another shortcoming of this method
is it does not take into account the indirect damage due to death and injuries. Furthermore,
this approach is highly criticized for being not consistent with the individualistic foundation
of welfare economics since it does not take people’s own preferences on changes in the
27
3.2 THE CONTINGENT VALUATION METHOD
Contingent valuation is a method of estimating the value that a person places on a good or
service. Rather than inferring from observed behaviours in regular market places, the
approach asks people to directly report their willingness to pay to obtain a specified good or
When an estimation of WTP is carried out for marginal changes in the probability to die
within a given period of time then one is dealing with an ex post scenario while it is ex ante
if the concern is with the WTP for marginal changes of the expected life span (Zweifel,
1997).
Let’s consider a simple model in which individual’s utility is a function of risk of death and
φ= 1 if “life”
0 “death”
Hence, U(φ, Y)
iii. Uy[φ, Y] >0, Uyy [φ, Y] <0 i.e., U (φ,Y) is twice continuously differentiable, strictly
Assumption ii states that the marginal utility of wealth in case of survival is higher than in
The above are the two conditional utility functions, which can be written as:
If the dummy variable (1-φ) is replaced by Π, the probability of death, then the expected
utility of the individual can be obtained by weighing the utility payoffs obtained in the
states of nature “life” and “death” by their respective probabilities and adding them up.
Hence,
∂EU ∂EU
dEU [Π, Y ] = dY + dΠ = 0 ……………….………………(4)
∂Y ∂Π
{
= (1 − Π )U1' [Y ] + Π U 0' [Y ]}dY + (U 0 [Y ] − U1[Y ])dΠ
29
To get the marginal rate of substitution between changes in risk and wealth, let’s solve with
respect to dY/dΠ,
dY U1 [Y ] − U 0 [Y ]
m[Π, Y] = = > 0 ……………..………………(5)
dΠ dEU = 0 (1 − Π )U1' [Y ] + ΠU 0' [Y ]
The above equation states how much the individual’s wealth must increase in order to
compensate him/her for an infinitesimal increase in the risk of death (or decrease in the
probability of survival). In other words, the monetary value of a marginal reduction of the
death risk corresponds to the individual’s marginal rate of substitution between his/her
wealth and his/her probability of survival. The numerator shows the utility difference
between “life” and “death” at a given level of wealth, which is positive due to assumption
(i) and the denominator shows the expected value of the marginal utility of wealth, which is
∂m 2
=d Y =
( ) > 0 ………………………..(6)
− (U1[Y ] − U 0 [Y ]) U 0' [Y ] − U1' [Y ]
∂Π dΠ 2
{(1 − Π )U [Y ] + ΠU [Y ]}
'
1
'
0
2
implying the response of the marginal rate of substitution to an increase in the initial level
of the death risk Π. The expression is positive because the first term in parentheses in the
numerator is positive due to assumption (i) and the second is negative due to assumption
(ii). Therefore, the marginal rate of substitution and hence the marginal WTP for
infinitesimally small changes in death risk rises with an increase from its initial level.
30
Similarly, to examine how the marginal rate of substitution, m(Π, Y), changes with a
variation of the initial level of wealth, let’s differentiate (5) with respect to y
∂m(Π , Y ) =
( )
EUy U1' [Y ] − U 0' [Y ] − (U1[Y ] − U 0 [Y ])EUyy
> 0 ………………………(7)
∂Y (EUy )2
2
EUyy = ∂ EU = (1 − Π )U1'' [Y ] + Π U 0'' [Y ] < 0
∂Y 2
In line with assumptions (i) and (ii), the numerator on the right hand-side of (7) is positive
and so is the denominator. Therefore, the marginal WTP for a reduction of the death risk
A contingent valuation survey generally provides a direct way of eliciting WTP values by
asking a sample of households what they would be willing to pay for a good or service.
Telephone survey, mail survey, and in-person interviews are the various methods used to
directly query individuals about their WTP. Telephone and in-person interviews allow
respondents to ask questions whereas not only is this not possible in mail survey but also
this method does not provide one the luxury of conducting follow-up questions about WTP
depending on the answers given to previous questions. It is argued that telephone and mail
surveys are less cheap, particularly in developed countries, but produce less quality WTP
data. In-person interviews in general help to produce the highest quality WTP data, though
31
very expensive since these are labour intensive. In most LDC situations telephone and mail
surveys may not be practical, leaving in-person surveys as the method of choice.
a) Bias Issues
CVM surveys are prone to various types of bias, which occur in the design as well as in the
Hypothetical bias: If the researcher does not create a believable and meaningful set of
questions that will simulate a market for the good/service in question with sufficient
plausibility or if the scenario is not consistent with reality, then the responses people give to
the hypothetical questions are likely to be careless, which do not reflect their taste
preferences. Bateman and Turner (1997), however, argue that WTP formats unlike WTA
formats, do not suffer from hypothetical bias because usually respondents are familiar with
Strategic bias/free riding: If respondents believe payments of their WTP will be collected
from them, and believe also that there is a good chance the good/service will be provided
even if they understate their true WTP amounts, they tend to underbid their WTP - this is
strategic classic free rider. On the other hand, respondents may ‘over pledge’ i.e., they
would be expected to overbid if they believe they will not actually have to pay the amount
they state, yet believe that the stated amount can influence provision of the good/service.
32
Starting point bias: This type of bias occurs when the respondent’s WTP amount is
influenced by a value introduced by the scenario. Confronted with a Birr figure where s/he
is uncertain about the value of the good/service in question, a respondent may regard the
proposed amount as conveying an approximate value of the good’s/service’s true value and
anchor her/his WTP amount on the proposed amount. Hence such “bidding hint” lead
respondents to take cognitive short-cuts to arrive at a decision rather than thinking seriously
about their true WTP. Therefore, this is an effect such that the final amount at the end of a
bidding game (see next section) is systematically related to the initial bid value.
Payment Vehicle bias: WTP may depend on choice of payment vehicle where different
payment vehicles may cause strategic behaviour. This bias occurs when the payment
vehicle is either misperceived or is itself valued in a way not intended by the researcher.
Bateman and Turner (1997) suggest that researchers can effectively eliminate such
problems by avoiding controversial payment methods and instead use that vehicle which is
most likely to be used in real life to elicit payment for the good in question.
Question ordering bias/ sensitivity of sequencing: WTP varies with where in a sequence
values are elicited for several different programmes or different levels of a programme. For
some goods there is a natural sequence to the provision of the good that prescribes the order
of questions, and respondents answering later questions are intended to take their answers
to earlier questions into account. Here the question order may influence the amounts given
33
for one or more of the goods that are being valued, despite the interviewer’s instructions to
Interviewer and respondent Bias: Respondents may have a tendency to answer with yes in
giving true preferences. For instance, if the interviewer is highly educated or attractive the
respondent may feel inhibited about expressing a low WTP bid. Hence in this Yea-saying
bias, elicited WTP are too high. This can be minimized by using mail or telephone rather
than face-to-face method of interview. On the other hand, in Nay-saying bias, respondent
may have the tendency to counter the interviewer if the former dislikes the latter. In this
Non-response Bias: Respondents may refuse to answer or they may give ludicrously high
WTP or untrue zero WTP (Protest Zeros). This may be because they oppose the payment
vehicle or are ambivalent. If protest zeros are removed from the sample, higher WTP may
result.
Warm glow effect: Also known as mental account bias or part-whole bias. WTP may not
vary with the size of the programme because respondents do not reveal preferences but
general approval. That is, the individual’s WTP responses fail to distinguish between
specific good which is under analysis and the wider group of goods into which that specific
good falls. The dimensions of a good that are particularly prone to this misperception are its
geographic distribution, its benefit composition, and the package of policies of which it is a
34
part. Geographical part-whole occurs when a respondent values a good whose spatial
attributes are larger or smaller than the spatial attributes of the researcher’s intended good.
Benefit part-whole bias is related to the fact when a respondent includes a broader or a
respondent values a broader or a narrower policy package than the one assumed by the
Information bias: Respondents may not be familiar with the commodity being valued or
WTP may vary with information provided. Bateman and Turner (1997), however, note that
the important factor is to ensure that such information is seen to be true, constant across the
sample, and not designed to induce bias towards a particular result, polemic and implicit
Other biases that may occur during a CV survey include: Framing effects bias where WTP
depends on how the question is framed. For instance, whether the glass is seen as half full
or half empty (Summary Guide, 2002); Preference imprecision bias occurs when
respondents are unable to cite precise WTP; Reference dependency bias refers to the
situation when WTP varies with the reference point as perceived by the respondent.
Apart from the afore mentioned problems of CVM, Whittington (2002) tried to categorize
the sources of problems in CVM when applied in a developing country. He identified three
main reasons why many CV studies conducted in developing countries are so bad. The first
is poor survey implementation due mainly to poorly trained enumerators and the resulting
enumerator bias. This is the principal-agent problem in which the researcher (principal)
35
typically does not know the enumerators (the agents) before the survey and has no long-
scenarios. This is the same as hypothetical bias, in which case CV researchers themselves
Failure to test for the effect of variations in survey design on the results of contingent
valuation studies is the third problem with CV surveys conducted in developing countries.
For instance in iterative bidding (see next section) researchers may not do split-sample
experiment to test whether respondents’ WTP would be influenced by the magnitude of the
initial price that they received and the sequence of follow-up questions. However, in my
opinion these biases may also be common in developed countries and could not be argued
In general, although there are several sources of bias in CVM and some particularly
pronounced in developing countries, Abelson (1996) notes that most of them can be dealt
with appropriate survey techniques. Similarly, Bateman and Turner (1997) also highlight
that CVM surveys can be designed to reduce bias problems to an acceptable level.
b) Elicitation Techniques
from one or more than one bias discussed in the previous section.
36
Open-ended format: Individuals may be asked to state their maximum WTP or
minimum WTA amount with no value being suggested to them. For instance, respondents
could be asked “What is the maximum you would be willing to pay for….?”. This
elicitation technique produces continuous bid variables. The method is straightforward and
no anchoring bias occurs because it does not provide cues about what the value of the
change might be. The other advantage of the technique is it is very informative since
maximum WTP can be identified for each respondent. However, the format leads to
unrealistically large bids and generally unreliable responses. This is because it might be
very difficult for respondents to come up with their true maximum WTP ‘out of the blue’.
In addition, free riding behaviour may occur, which will result in a downwardly biased
estimates of WTP.
individuals are presented with a single payment that they accept or reject. This method asks
“Are you willing to pay $X?” It is argued that this method is incentive compatible i.e., it is
in the respondent’s strategic interest to accept the bid, if his/her WTP is greater than or
equal to the price asked or reject otherwise so that the respondent is telling the truth. Even
though it minimizes non-response and avoids outliers, there could be some degree of Yea-
saying. Apart from the existence of starting point bias it is criticized for being inefficient in
that less information is available from each respondent i.e., the researcher only knows
whether WTP is above or below a certain amount. Hence, larger samples and stronger
37
Double-bounded dichotomous choice: the question might run as “Would you pay
$X amount?” If the response is yes then the next question is “ and would you pay $X+Y”
or “and would you pay $X-Y” if the response to the first question is no. The actual WTP
then lies between X and Y if s/he accepted to pay $X in the first question but rejected
$X+Y in the second. Though the double bounded dichotomous choice method is more
efficient than single bounded dichotomous choice as more information is elicited about
each respondent’s WTP , all the limitations of the latter procedure still apply. Other cons of
this technique include anchoring and yea- saying biases in addition to the possible loss of
incentive compatibility (truth telling) due the fact that the second question may not be
Iterative Bidding: under this elicitation format individuals are asked to respond
either to increasing figures until they reach their maximum WTP or to reducing figures if
they are not WTP the initial figure suggested. It is believed that this method facilitates
respondents’ thought process and encourages them to consider their preferences carefully.
Because of the initial bid prices usually anchoring bias exists. Moreover, it may lead to a
large number of outliers and yea saying. Another drawback of the method is it cannot be
Payment card elicitation technique: this format is developed by Mitchell and Carson in
1986, as an alternative to bidding game (Mitchell and Carson, 1993). Respondents are
provided with a range of values from which to select. The question would be like “which of
the amounts listed below best describes your maximum WTP?” One advantage of this
38
method over bidding game is it avoids starting point bias. Bateman and Turner (1997),
however, indicate that anchoring of bids within the range given in the card may occur with
most respondents assuming that such a range contains the “correct” valuation (range bias).
In comparison to bidding game, payment card elicitation method reduces the number of
outliers. Though values in the card serve as a benchmark, there may be vulnerability to bias
relating to the range of the numbers used in the card and the location of the benchmarks.
CVM techniques have been widely used for the purpose of estimating environmental
benefits in particular. Recently, however, a lot of studies have tried to assess health
care/services by applying CVM. Johansson (1995) emphasizes that CVM is appropriate for
health studies since biases are minimized and the problems in using the CVM are somewhat
smaller, or at least different, when the method is applied to health care, which is primarily a
private good than when it is applied to large environmental changes or other public projects
Different researchers used CVM to elicit WTP for different programmes. For instance,
Cameron (1988) surveyed the WTP of patients, physicians, and managed care executives
for diagnostic certainty for peptic ulcer disease and gastroesophageal reflux disease; Bishai
and Lang (2000) elicited the WTP for a month reduction in waiting time for cataract
surgery using bidding elicitation method; Pol and Cairns (1999) applied dichotomous
choice question with follow up to examine inter-temporal preferences for non-fatal changes
39
in own health; Tambour and Zethracus (1998) used CVM to estimate the WTP for hormone
replacement therapy; Bonato et al (2001) elicited the WTP for three possible health care
memory and at least one other cognitive function most common among aged people.
The review of 42 health care contingent valuation studies by Diener et al (1998) that were
published between 1984-1996 shows the use of CVM in valuing different health care
surgical, pharmaceuticals and hypothetical- upon which the CVM is applied. Some of the
studies were performed to assist in pricing and demand forecasts for a product and some to
assist with programme evaluation. The latter was specially concerned with the implication
programme. The vast majority of the studies reviewed by Diener et al (1998) have been
compensating variation- WTP designs. The review of the 42 studies indicted that 55% of
contingent valuation studies in health care surveyed persons either currently diseased or
undergoing the treatment intervention- ex post analysis; 36% of the studies obtained
responses from non-users that are at future risk of contracting the disease or in need of the
intervention- ex ante analysis, while 10% of the studies asked respondents from the general
population which may include respondents from the afore mentioned groups. The majority
of the studies not only used target groups but also valued certain outcomes, and valued
goods from a purely private market perspective. It was also found that all of the elicitation
methods described in the above sub-section were employed almost equally by the 42
40
In 1997 and 1998, two studies estimated the WTP for reduced incontinence symptoms. The
first was by Johansson et al (1997) in Sweden where 461 patients with urge or mixed
incontinence were asked to state their WTP for a reduction in incontinence symptoms using
mail survey. The result showed that in terms of magnitude of risk reduction, patients with
incontinence problems were willing to pay more for a 50% than 25% reduction in the
number of micturitions and leakages. The second study conducted in the United States by
O’Conor et al (1998) also found that the mean WTP for a 50% reduction to be much higher
(US$ 245) than for a 25% reduction (US$ 88) in micturitions and leakages.
Another health care study using CVM was done by Krupnick, et al (2000). In this intensive
study, they administered a mortality risk reduction survey on 930 persons aged from 40 to
70 years in Ontario. By treating risk reduction as a private good (i.e., estimating each
respondent’s WTP to reduce his/her own risk of dying), they estimated what older people
would pay for a reduction in their risk of dying in addition to assessing the impact of health
status on WTP. They reported that age has no effect on WTP until roughly age 70 and
above and the health status with the exception of having cancer, has no effect. However, the
researchers found that being mentally healthy raises WTP substantially. In this study the
elicitation technique used was follow-up dichotomous choice to obtain WTP for risk
respondents were first asked if they were WTP for a product that, when used and paid for
over the next ten years, will reduce baseline risks by 5 in 1000 over the next 10 years
period (5 in 10,000 annually). In the second WTP question, risks were reduced by 1 in 1000
41
(1 in 10,000 annually). This question was used to serve two purposes- on the one hand, it’s
possible to test whether respondents were willing to pay anything today for a future risk
reduction and on the other hand, to test for internal consistency of responses because WTP
today for a future risk change should be less than WTP today for an immediate risk change.
Their finding suggests that responses were consistent with economic theory, and that WTP
was sensitive to the magnitude of the risk reduction. Regardless of the estimation procedure
they used, it was found that mean WTP for the 5 in 1000 risk reduction was statistically
greater than mean WTP for 1 in 1000 risk reduction, which made their estimates pass the
Another application of the CVM related to health care and services was carried out by
Belaineh Taye (2002) in Ethiopia. He estimated the WTP of 300 households in West Shoa
zone for insecticide-impregnated bed nets against malaria by using the open-ended
elicitation technique. He tried to present two scenarios to the households on how to acquire
the bed nets- in cash and in credit. His result shows that the WTP for insecticide
impregnated bed net in credit was higher (Birr65.05) than the WTP in cash (Birr 44.26).
Probably the first application of CVM for the evaluation of HIV/AIDS services anywhere
HIV/AIDS services in Kenya. Apart from evaluating the costs and benefits of four
HIV/AIDS services- voluntary counselling and testing (VCT), chronic care services, ARV
therapy, and a hypothetical AIDS vaccine- he assessed the factors that influence how
people value these services. In addition to these the researcher also tried to evaluate the
42
validity of CV in assessing benefits for HIV/AIDS programmes in developing countries. To
obtain the data, the study employed the payment card elicitation technique. WTP was
elicited using three survey instruments- VCT clients at the time of being counselled and
tested were asked about their WTP only for VCT; VCT clients six months after having
received their results were asked to state their WTP for chronic care services and ARVs
while in the third survey instrument, people within the general community were asked to
state their WTP for VCT, chronic care services, ARVs, an AIDS vaccine and their
willingness to contribute to an AIDS charity. Respondents were also encouraged to rank the
four services from highest community priority to the lowest. It was found that VCT was
given a high value intervention while AIDS vaccine was rated as the second highest
community priority. ART was ranked the least of all the health services. The findings of
Forsythe’s study indicate that PLWHA cited that they were willing to pay 11% of their
monthly household expenditures for ARV therapy. The amount of WTP obtained from the
data ($10.92 per month) was relatively smaller than the actual prices of the therapy ($210-
282 per month). The estimation thus indicates that in Kenya the price of ARV therapy
would need to be about $120 a year in order to be affordable for the government. With
regard to determinates of WTP it was found that household spending was closely related to
WTP responses across all four services. A focus on ARVs reveals that spending on
medications also had high correlation to WTP. The variables- number of visits to health
centre and having ever received chronic care service- were found to have weak correlation
43
While Forsythe claims that his research is the first application of CVM for the evaluation of
HIV- related programmes, it is not the only one. Whittington et al. (2002) analysed the
hypothetical vaccine that would provide lifetime protection against HIV/AIDS, they
estimated the WTP of uninfected adults. The CV survey was administered to 234 adults
aged 18-60 years. The results of the estimates of private demand indicate that individuals
anticipate sizable personal benefits from such a vaccine, and that they would be willing to
allocate a substantial proportion of their income to be protected in this way from HIV
infection. It was also found in the research that individuals with higher incomes, with
spouses deceased or partners, and with perceived risks of becoming infected are WTP more
44
CHAPTER FOUR
METHODOLOGY
The application of WTP in the areas concerning changes in individuals' economic welfare
individuals' preferences. This presupposes that individuals treat longevity more or less like
any other good rather than as a hierarchical value. This economic approach for the
valuation of individual's WTP to increase his/her own life expectancy can be derived by
focusing on ex ante perspective- before the uncertainty about the individual's death during a
specified period of time is resolved; or ex post perspective- each individual knowing if s/he
is to die "now" or live a while longer. The former perspective is criticized for being morally
In this paper it is assumed that the availability of ARV drugs is most probably highly
valued by PLWHA than people without it. This is also attested by the findings of Forsythe
(2001) where HIV-positive clients had a higher WTP to have access to ARVs relative to
HIV-negative clients. Therefore, this study followed an ex post approach where by the
contingent valuation survey was used to solicit the willingness to pay for the drugs by
people living with the virus. Furthermore, instead of asking individuals from the society
whether they are HIV positive (especially due to stigma) and would pay for the drugs, only
45
residents of Addis who were willing to reveal themselves as carriers of the virus were
There are two national associations of PLWHA registered as NGOs to enable them to
operate. These are Dawn of Hope and Mekdim Ethiopia whose primary objective is to
protect the rights of members and to contribute to HIV/AIDS prevention activities. The
target population of this research is people living with the virus. The sample respondents
were drawn from the members Dawn of Hope and Mekdim Ehiopia. Attempt has also been
made to contact some medical doctors who have clients living with the virus.
From the above target group, sample was drawn by using opportunity sampling, which is a
whoever happens to be available from the population of interest. When members of the
respective associations contacted the association for some reason or another interviews were
conducted. Since the interviewers themselves were workers in the associations, it was also
possible to solicit responses when they visited members in their homes. At the same time,
clients with the virus of some doctors were also interviewed when they visited their doctors for
diagnosis. The total sample size of the survey was 440, which was obtained according to the
availability of people. A sample of 270 respondents from Dawn of Hope, 165 from Mekdim
46
4.3 Questionnaire Design
The CV survey begins with the description of the objective of the paper. This is followed
by socio-demographic questions. Part two of the questionnaire presented questions that help
to identify the knowledge, attitude and practice of respondents with respect to the drugs.
The next section of the questionnaire was the payment question, in which respondents were
presented with an initial bid amount and increasing (decreasing) amounts until the
respondent declined (or accepted) to pay. Respondents were asked if they would purchase
the drugs at $350 per year (approximately Birr 250 per month) or not. This threshold figure
is based on the current price of the drugs in the other parts of the world (UNAIDS, 2002
However, since starting point bias occurs when the respondent’s WTP amount is specified
by a value introduced by the scenario, the paper used five different initial bid amounts (350,
300, 250, 200, 150) in order to take care of the “starting point bias” problem - an effect
related to the initial bid value. Those who responded “No” would be asked if they would be
willing to purchase the drugs at a lower cost. If they were still unwilling to buy the drugs at
all then they were asked to state or name the reason why they would not. On the other hand,
those who responded “Yes” were given a follow-up question in which s/he is willing to pay
a higher price (See Annex III for the copy of questionnaire used).
47
Figure 4.1. Bidding Game with Birr 350 to Birr 150 starting points.
Y Stop
Y bov e 5 Above5000
Y 501-600? NN Stop N
Stop Y ……..?
Y 400-500? N Stop
350? N Stop
N
Y Stop
. 250-3Y00? N Stop Y Stop Y Stop
. NN Y 51-100? 1-50?
, 151-200? N N Stop
. Y Y
. Y Above
.
Stop
Y 301-400? StY N
. Y 200-300? N Stop Stop
1.5150? N Stop 5000?
. N Y StopY Stop Y …..?
0 Y
… 51-100? Stop Stop
. N
T. he interview was conducted under two s1c-5e0n? arios: Satsosupming the drug lengthens life
years by indefinite years and ten years. This will also provide a test for consistency of
results with economic theory, in which WTP should be sensitive to the magnitude of
risk/mortality reduction.
Respondents then were asked some questions to identify the determinants of WTP. In
the last part of the survey questionnaire, respondents were asked about their attitude
from English to Amharic great care was taken so as not to offend or irritate
respondents.
48
4.4 Methods of Data Collection
A total of twelve persons (10 enumerators and 2 supervisors) participated in the survey. All
of the twelve participants were workers in the two associations that live with the virus, a
deliberate action designed to avoid interviewer bias. This is so because the researcher
A pilot survey was conducted by the researcher and some adjustments, such as including more
questions, re-ordering the questions and excluding offensive words were executed. Prior to the
main survey both enumerators and supervisors were trained. The fieldwork for the year 2003
started in the second week of February and was completed in the second week of March. The
excellent cooperation from workers of the associations, especially DOH facilitated the
fieldwork.
We may observe the dependent variable only when Yi>0. However, the observed values of
the dependent variable may sometimes have a discrete jump to zero. A dependent variable
with the property that has a discrete jump at zero is known as a limited dependent variable.
When the dependent variable is limited by some value either from above or below, the data
is said to be censored (Chay and Powell, 2001). Suppose y* has a normal distribution, with
49
mean µ and variance σ2. We may consider a sample of size η (y1* , y2* ,…, yn* ) and record
only those values of y* greater than a constant c and for those values of y*≤c, we record the
value c.
The data is also said to be censored if the characteristics of respondents are available so that
the factors impacting on the decision not to be willing to pay for (for the drugs, in this
particular case), can be assessed. Some examples of censored data in empirical literatures
forwarded by Greene (2000) are: the number of extramarital affairs; the number of hours
worked by a woman in the labour force; the number of arrests after release from prison, etc.
Each of these studies analyses a dependent variable that is zero for a significant fraction of
the observations.
However, the first applications of the limited dependent variable model was given by Tobin
regressions.
x = income
50
Then the household maximum utility U(y,z) is subject to the budget constraint y+z ≤ x with
subject to y+z ≤ x but not the other constraint, and assume that:
y* = β1+ β2x+u……………………………………….…(1)
Where u may be interpreted as the collection of all the unobservable variables that affect
the utility function. The solution to the original problem, denoted by y is:
y= y* if y* > y0
0 if y*≤ y0……………………….………..…(2)
Tobin (1958) assumed that y* is normally distributed and y0 to be the same for all
(zero) observations and nonlimit (continuous) observations. Particularly, the standard OLS
regression using censored data will typically result in coefficient estimates that are biased
Χi β 1 1 ( yi − Χ i β )2
L= Π 1 − Φ σ ⋅ Π exp −
σ2
…………….(4)
2Π σ 2 2
yi / yi =0 i yi / yi >0 i
51
The first part of the likelihood resembles the probit while the second part resembles the
likelihood of conventional OLS on those sample points that are not censored (i.e., greater
Χ β 1 1 ( yi − Χ i β )
2
l = ∑ ln 1 − Φ i + ∑ ln − ………………..(5)
yi / yi =0 σ y i / y i > 0 2Π σ 2 2 σ2
However, Greene (2000) and Johnston &DiNardo (1997) emphasize that if the underlying
disturbances are not normally distributed, then the usual estimator based on (5) is
inconsistent.
The coefficients of the Tobit model may not be sensibly interpreted. The expected value of
Where z = Χβ/ σ,
Furthermore, the expected value of y for observations above the limit, y*, is simply Χβ plus
= Χβ + σ ƒ(z) / F(z)
52
Consequently, the basic relationship between the expected value of all observations, Ey,
Ey = F(z)Ey*………………………………………….(iii)
The McDonald and Moffitt marginal effect decomposition then is obtained by considering
∂Ey ∂Ey * ∂F ( z )
= F ( z ) + Ey * ………………………………………..(iv)
∂χ i ∂χ i ∂χ i
The interpretation is that the change in the mean of y with respect to χi has two components.
One effect works by changing the conditional mean of y (the change in y of those above the
limit, weighted by the probability of being above the limit) and the other by changing the
probability that an observation will be positive (the change in the probability of being
Jim Powell (1984) proposed censored least absolute deviations (CLAD) estimator as an
model. This method does not impose normality and homoscedasticity on the distribution of
the disturbance term. In other words, it requires weaker assumptions on the error term than
53
Considering the standard index model:
y* = Xβ + ε
Powell notes that if y* were observed, and if the error term was systematically distributed
around 0, then standard OLS would produce consistent estimates of the parameters. Since
is not observed and all observations where εi < - Xiβ are omitted.
n * ∧
min ∑ ( yi − χ i β ) 2 …………………………………………….(7)
∧ i =1
β
∧
That is, β is the estimator that minimizes the sum of squared errors. Instead, however, one
may choose to minimize the sum of the absolute value of the errors:
n * ∧
min ∑ yi − χ i β ……………………………..…..……….(8)
∧ i =1
β
which is called the least absolute deviations (LAD) estimator. This can be rewritten as
54
n ∧ ∧
min ∑ ( yi − χ i β ) •ψ ( yi − χ i β ) …………………………….(9)
* *
∧ i =1
β
where the sign function ψ (•) takes on values of 1, 0, -1 (positive, zero, or negative). The
n ∧
0 = ∑ χ i' • ψ ( yi* − χ i β ) …………………………………(10)
i =1
implying that it is the sign and not the magnitude of the residuals that matters. Therefore,
Amemiya (1985) points out that Powell's estimator is attractive because it is the only
known estimator that is consistent under general non-normal distributions and that in large
samples, this estimator appears to perform much better than the various estimators of the
Tobit model.
This paper used both the Tobit and Powell's Censored Limited Absolute Deviation
(CLAD) to estimate the parameters of the data. In the latter case, the Bootstrap method is
used to estimate the standard errors. The Bootstrap due to Efron (1979) is a recently
constructed general technique for estimating sampling distributions (as cited in Jonston and
DiNardo, 1997). The bootstrap is believed to hold a great promise in many applications and
is finding its way into more and more applied econometric research. Researchers usually try
confidence intervals and for tests of significance. This, however, is often the hardest part of
55
the work and the reason for why asymptotic methods are quite often used for interval
estimation and hypothesis testing. The bootstrap provides a simple means for obtaining an
approximate sampling distribution of the statistic. This, however, is not as exact as the
exact distribution and is computationally longer to obtain results than by using the
asymptotic distribution. The bootstrap is preferred due to the fact that even if it is
results are conditional on observed data, not based on large sample approximations.
smedian = 4 f 2 (0)
Where ƒ(0) is a consistent estimate of the value of the probability density function at 0. It is
possible to generate estimate of the distribution by using the data and then calculate ƒ2(0).
(i) draw a large number of samples of size n from the distribution ƒ(x)
(iii) calculate the square root of the variance of these estimated medians across a large
number of replications.
one has a precise knowledge of the distribution generating the samples in the first place.
Since one does not know this, Efron suggested the use of the sample data to generate an
estimate of the distribution. That is, use the empirical distribution to learn about the actual
56
1. Generate a random sample Xi with replacement from the original sample X4.
∧ i
2. Compute the median M for this new sample.
∧ i
3. Store the value of M
Johnston and DiNardo (1997) underline that the number of bootstrap replications, θ, should
2
1 n ∧ ∧
σ boot = ∑
θ − 1 i =1
M i − M i (•)
θ ∧
∧ 1
where M (•) =
θ
∑M i
i =1
The contingent valuation method was used to elicit the willingness to pay of people living
with the virus for antiretroviral drugs, which lengthen the lives of the particular individuals.
MWTP = β0+ β1SDV+ β2TC+ β3YLV+ β4HS+ + β5I+ β6XY+ β7WP+ β8BP+ β9FR
marital status, religion, educational status, occupational status, family size and
family head.
TC = Total cost incurred for treatment of opportunistic diseases for the last
two months
YLV = Year(s) of living with the virus
HS = Current health status
4
We are drawing a sample of size n from the original sample, thus putting the probability 1/n on each
57
I = Total income of the individual (personal, family, transfer)
XY = Payment for another person living with the virus in the family of the
individual
WP = Responsibility of payment of total treatment cost for the last two months
BP = Initial bid price bias
FR= Free riding
The longer the individual lives with the virus the higher
Years of living will be the WTP because the individual is most probably
with the virus suffering and will be willing to do anything to stop it.
(YLV) ? On the other hand, those people who didn’t live with the
virus that long may not want to suffer for the their
remaining lives so that they may have a higher WTP
for the drugs.
59
Current Health Status If the individual’s current health status can be categorized
Dummy Variable( HS) under “good” or “bad” then s/he may have higher WTP
1 if bad (+) for the drugs when the health status deteriorates.
0 good
? The higher the treatment cost of different OIs for the last
Cost of Treatment two months the higher will be the WTP for the drugs
(TC) to shift the cost. However, Forsythe (2001) found a
negative sign where people who have already spent
a lot of money on medications, particularly medications
that are ineffective, are unwilling or unable to pay more
for ARVS. Therefore, sign is to be tested.
Who paid for (-) If it is already the responsibility of others to pay for the
treatment cost for the treatment cost of the individual for the last two months
last two months(WP) then this is an indication that s/he will likely have less
1 others willingness and ability to pay for the private good under under
0 self consideration.
Payment for another (-) If there is another person living with the virus and if
person living with it is the responsibility of the individual to pay for the
the virus in the drugs to that individual too then the less will be the
family WTP of the individual for the drugs.
(XY)
Dummy Variable
1 if yes
0 otherwise
Starting price of the
Bidding game ? To be tested
(BP)
Free riding ?
(FR)
To be tested
Dummy Variable
1 if others pay
0 otherwise
60
Chapter Five
In this chapter, results of the CV survey are presented and analyzed using both descriptive
and multivariate regression analysis. For the descriptive analysis SPSS 11:0 is used while
the STATA software (version 7.0) is used to run Tobit and CLAD to estimate the
In this section, the CV survey results are summarized in six sub-sections. The first part
designed to capture their knowledge, attitude and practice (KAP) of the drugs. The third
section of the analysis is on the WTP amounts of the respondents. The next two parts
4
Refer Annex 1 for summary tables
61
concentrate on the economic characteristics of respondents and health related indicators.
Finally, the general attitudes of respondents are summarized. The remaining three sub-
Data on the gender of the 440 respondents shows that 264(60%) are female out of which
91(72.3%) are family head while 176(40%) are male respondents and 134(76.1%) of them
The mean age of the respondents is 33 years. The youngest respondent is 18 years old while
the oldest is 65 years old. The total number of respondents in the age range 18-49 years is
426 (97%). This reflects the fact that around 91% of infections in the country occur among
economically active age group (15-49 years). The proportion of respondents within the age
group 18-25 years old is 80 (18.2%). The majority of the respondents, 167(38%), fall into
the age range 26-33 years followed by 134(30.5%) of respondents between 34-41 years.
Those between 42-49 years are 45(10.2%). Only 12(2.7%) and 2(0.5%) of the respondents
are among the age group 50-57 and 58-65 years, respectively.
The average family size of the respondents is 3.85, ranging from 1 to 12. Out of the 440
interviewees, 205 (46.6%) have 1 to 3 family members, which suggests a somewhat smaller
family size among the majority of the respondents. Family size of 4-6 individuals is
62
Data on marital status reveals that 170(38.6%) respondents are currently married, which is
followed by those whose spouses are deceased, 132(32%). The rest of the respondents
Most of the respondents, 282(64.1%), indicated that they are Orthodox Christians. Eighty-
two (18.6%) of the respondents are Protestants and 65(14.8%) are Muslims. The rest of the
respondents indicated that they are either Catholic (1.4%) or Jehovah (1.1%).
In terms of educational status, most of the respondents, 196(44.55%), have completed high
school followed by 102(23.2%) respondents that have completed primary education. Those
that have beyond secondary education level are 64(14.5%). Twenty-eight (6.4%)
respondents indicated that they have only below 4th grade training. The rest of the
respondents, 30(6.8%) and 20(4.5%) are either illiterate or able to read and write,
respectively.
The last variable that is considered in this sub-section is the occupational status of
respondents. Those who claimed to have their own business account for 17.3% of the total
respondents where as those that work as private employees and civil servants are 55
(12.5%) and 33(7.5%), respectively. NGO workers constitute 16.1% of the total
established by PLWHA while 31(7%) indicated that they are daily labourers. However, the
majority of the respondents, 161(36.6%) are found to be unemployed during the survey.
5.1.2 KAP
63
In this section the knowledge, attitude and practice of respondents with regard to ARV
Interviewees were asked if they ever heard about ARV drugs before the day of the
interview. Even though almost all, 99.5%, confirmed that they have heard about the drugs
before, only 28(6.4%) of the respondents are or have been using the drugs purchasing from
Out of the 440 respondents, 177(40.2%) reported that they know people that use the drugs
Respondents were asked if they knew or heard about the current ‘underground’ price of the
drugs in the country and if they thought this was reasonable. Those who think that the
current price is not fair compared to the living status of the population are 99.5% while
2(0.5%) of the respondents admitted that they do not know about the on going price in the
country.
To evaluate the perception of respondents towards the drugs, they were asked to give their
opinion about for how long the drugs extend the life of a person living with the virus. More
than half, 243(55.2%), of the respondents either do not have a clue or claim that only God
knows. Among those respondents that guessed the years, 11(2.5) believe that the drugs
extend life years from 2 to 3 years; 79(18%) think that it extends from 5 to 10 years;
44(10%) conjecture from 10 to 15 years; 34(7.7%) guess from 15 to 20 years. Out of the
total respondents, 8(1.8%) and 3(0.7%) respondents speculated that the drugs lengthen life
years from 20 to 25 and 25-30 years, respectively. The rest 18(4.1%) respond that once the
64
Respondents' perception about the side effects of these drugs was also used as a means of
evaluating their knowledge regarding the drugs. The response to this particular question
ranges from 'no toxicity' to 'very high toxicity'. However, 233(53%) let us know that they
do not have a clue about the side effects of the drugs. Those who think the side effects to be
'modest' and 'low' are 66(15%) and 64(14.5%), respectively. The two extremes, 'very high
toxicity' and 'no toxicity' are chosen by 28(6.4%) and 49(11.1%), interviewees,
respectively.
In spite of their ignorance or speculation with regard to for how long the drugs lengthen life
years of PLWHA once they start taking the drugs, respondents were made to assume two
different scenarios- the drugs lengthen life years indefinitely and ten years.
Out of the total 440 respondents, 242(55%) are either unable or unwilling (protest votes) to
pay for the drugs. The majority, 210(47.7%) respondents, indicated that they do not have
the ability to pay for the drugs. The other 32 respondents appear to have “protest votes”
where their responses generally are recognized not to reflect the true worth of the service,
but rather a protest against the idea of consumers having to pay any amount for a certain
good or service (Mitchell and Carson, 1993). Out of these 26(5.9%) claimed that there is no
chance they would pay for the drugs because only God can extend their life years. The rest
4(0.9%) and 2(0.5%) respondents are unwilling to pay because they believe that the drugs
65
should be given for free or because of the side effects, respectively. Hence WTP responses
The minimum stated price that respondents are willing to pay is Eth. Birr 50 while the
The mean WTP of respondents if the drugs lengthen life years indefinitely is Birr 163.64
while it is Birr 148.48 if the drugs are effective only for 10 years. On the other hand, the
median WTP of respondents if the triple combinations lengthen life years indefinitely is
Birr 100 whereas it is Birr 50 if the drugs are going to extend life years by only 10 years.
One of the statistical issues under the analysis of WTP is to consider whether to use the
mean or median WTP estimates. In this study the median WTP is used to estimate the WTP
of PLWHA for ARV drugs and the determinants of their WTP amounts. This is due to the
fact that the mean is very sensitive to assumptions about the valuation function, skewness
in the distribution and to outliers in the data, which our data is no exception (refer Annex 2)
If the market price of ARV triple combination per month is to be Birr 1-50, 105(53%) and
92(46.5%) of the respondents are willing to pay when the expected life extension is 10 and
indefinite years, respectively. When market price ranges from Birr 51-100 per month, it is
chosen by 40(20.2%) and 44(22.2%) respondents when the expected life years extension is
10 and indefinite years, respectively. Nine(4.5%) and 16(8.1%) respondents are willing to
pay from Birr 101-150 per month for the drugs if life extension is 10 and indefinite years,
66
respectively. Willingness to pay for the drugs if market price is between Birr 151-350 is
observed in 21(10.6%) respondents if the drugs extend life years by 10 years and in
19(9.6%) respondents for a 10 years life extension. The reverse is true when the market
price for triple combinations is from Birr 351-550 i.e., 19(9.6%) respondents willing to pay
for 10 life years extension and 21(10.6%) respondents if it is indefinitely. In the last
category of WTP, Birr 551-2000, only 4(2%) and 6(3%) respondents out of 198 individuals
who showed interest to pay are willing to pay the above amount if the drugs lengthen life
67
Out of the total 198 respondents that stated their willingness and ability to pay for the
drugs, 73.24% responded that they themselves (60.6%) or their families (12.6%) are going
to pay while 26.8% stated that it is the responsibility of others- either their respective
the majority of the respondents are unemployed. The fact that being unemployed does not
necessarily mean that the respondents have zero income level because the survey considers
total income of an individual: not only income earned per month by the individual but also
family and transfer income. Most of the respondents that showed interest in paying the
second interval of the WTP amount, work in different NGOs. This is also true for the WTP
category Birr 151-350. Those that have their own business are the majority that showed
To evaluate the total income of respondents per month, three sources were identified- the
respondent’s earning, family income and transfer income. The latter refers to money
income transferred from the respective associations, relatives or friends to the individual.
The mean income of the respondents is Eth Birr 367 per month.
Out of the 440 respondents, 144(32.7%) of them have a total income below Eth. Birr 120
per month. Respondents that get total income from Birr 150 to 250 per month are
78(17.7%). This range is almost mated by the next income figure, Birr 300–400, where
77(17.5%) of the respondents get per month. Out of the total interviewees, 50(31.4%) and
33(7.5%) of the respondents fall into income group Birr 450-550 and Birr 600-700 per
month, respectively. Only 11(2.5%) of the respondents have total income Eth Birr 750-850
per month. In the last category of income, 47(10.7%) of the respondents get above Birr 900
per month.
69
The mean income of the 198 respondents that stated different willingness to pay amounts is
Birr 583. Comparing this with the mean WTP indicates that these people are prepared to
allocate 28% of their income if the drugs are effective indefinitely and 25% if only 10
years.
health condition and 116(26.4%) in ‘modest’ health status. Some 114(25.9%) respondents
think that their health status is very good and they neither visited a doctor nor prescribed
medicine for themselves for the last tow months. These are categorized as having ‘very
good’ health status. Out of the total respondents, 59(13.4%) of them have ‘bad’ health
status and only 12(2.7%) show to have ‘very bad’ health condition.
The cross tabulation of the above two variables in this sub-section reveals that, out of the
99 respondents that knew they were living with the virus for less than a year, the majority,
31respondents, have ‘good’ health status. The same is true for those who have known that
they are HIV+ from 1 to 2 years and 3 to 4 years. However, those individuals who
responded that they knew for 5 to 6 years and 7 to 8 years, their health status is categorized
under ‘modest’. Out of the 20 individuals that have been living with the virus for 9 to 10
years, most of them, 35%, have ‘bad’ health status. Of the 5 respondents that knew about
the virus they are living with for 11-12 years, 4 of them have ‘very bad’ health condition
and both of the respondents that reported to be living with the virus for 13 years also have
71
From the total respondents in the survey, 294 of them reported to have incurred treatment
cost for the last two months. These respondents were asked how much they spent and who
paid for the medical expenses. The average total cost is found to be Birr 255, which is 64%
Respondents that spent from Birr 1-50 are 103, out of which 26(25.2%) paid out of their
pocket; for 7(6.8%) respondents their families covered the cost, for another 7(6.8%)
respondents the organization they work in paid for the medical cost. However, for the
majority, 63.2% of the respondents, the respective associations covered the treatment costs.
Those respondents that claimed to incur a medical cost of Eth Birr 100-200 for the last two
months are 83 and again for the majority, 52(62.6%) of the respondents, the cost was
covered by the associations whereas for 24(30%) respondents either the individuals
themselves or their families paid for the treatment cost. For the rest 7(7.4%) individuals that
incurred the above figure, the organizations that they work in paid for treatment. Of the 69
respondents that reported to pay from their pocket, 11(16%), of them paid Birr 250-350 for
the last two months for medical treatment; 7(10.1%) around Birr 440-550; only two
respondents paid Birr 550-650 and another two above Birr 700. Of the total respondents
that incurred medical cost for the last two months, 181 respondents’ costs were covered by
the respective associations. Out of these, the associations paid Birr 250-350 for 30(16.6%)
respondents; Birr 400-500 for 19 individuals; and Birr 555-700 for four respondents.
Data related with the issue of another HIV+ person living with the respondents reveal that
156(35.5%) of them actually have a person/s living with the virus at home. Of these
79(50.6%) are the spouses of the respondents; 47(30.1%) constitute the child/children of
72
the respondent; 10(6.4%) relatives living with the respondents in the same house;
18(11.5%) of the respondents who claimed to be living with other HIV+ persons, the
persons are his/her spouse and child/children. The rest 2(1.3%) out of the 156 respondents
However, even if 156 of the respondents responded that they live with another HIV+
person, only 26(16.7%) showed willingness to pay for the other person/s if the drugs
become available in the market whereas 130(83.3%) of them refused to have this
responsibility.
All of the 440 respondents were asked to give their opinion about the responsibility of
distributing the drugs. The majority of respondents, 215(48.9%), believe that government
has the responsibility of distributing the drugs for free; 52(11.8%) said it should be left to
the NGOs operating in the country to dispense the drugs for free; 155(35%) asserted that
both government and NGOs should jointly distribute the drugs for free. Around 5(1.1%)
respondents urged their respective associations to take the responsibility of giving out the
drugs to their members. Those who suggested that, on the one hand, government should
distribute the drugs for free for those unable to pay and, on the other hand, private
pharmacies should sell to those that can pay are 11(2.5%). Two individuals out of the 440
respondents said that government, NGOs and the associations must work together for the
73
Respondents were inquired if the Ethiopian government has given proper attention till the
day of the interview. Of the total 440 interviewed, 396(90%) disagree (most of them
strongly) with the suggested idea while the rest 44(10%) respondents believe that it is doing
The last question presented to respondents was if they would be interested to pay more than
what they have stated before if their income increases and their economic situation changes
for the better. The majority, 408(93.5%), of the respondents confirmed this while 32(7.3%)
stated that no matter what their economic situation is, they are not WTP for the drugs. The
reason given by the majority, 26(81.3%) of them is only the Lord could extend their life
years and not the drugs. The rest four and two respondents are totally unwilling to pay for
the drugs because they believe either it should be given for free or it has high toxicity. This
question has helped the researcher to check whether there is internal consistency in the
responses of interviewees. For instance, it would have been contradictory on the part of the
respondent if s/he gave a reason for the protest vote as “only God can help me” in section
three but then assert that s/he would pay a positive amount if her/his economic situation
To test the accuracy of the CV survey of this study, construct and scope validity tests are
carried out. Construct test refers to the theoretical validity test, which involves assessing the
degree to which the findings of a study are consistent with theoretical expectations
(Mitchell and Carson, 1993). The most common test for construct validity of CV studies is
the correlation between willingness and ability to pay (Forsythe, 2001). This is so because
74
if people were overbidding without giving any thought to their economic limitations, one
would expect that there would be no correlation between income and WTP.
The data of the survey reveal that there is a significant level of correlation between income
of the respondents and their WTP (Table 5.11). The correlation coefficient between total
income of respondents and their WTP for the drugs per month life is extended indefinitely
is 0.63 whereas the correlation coefficient of total income and WTP if the drugs extend life
years by 10 years is 0.64. Both of the Pearson correlation coefficients are significant at 0.01
level of significance.
Another test of the validity of a CV study is to test if respondents can distinguish the
order for WTP to provide accurate estimates, respondents should be WTP more for an
intervention that has a larger impact. In other words, they should place a higher value on
the drugs if these lengthen life years indefinitely than only ten years.
Respondents have apparently passed the scope sensitivity test because their WTP for ARV
drugs when life years are extended indefinitely is greater than when the effectiveness is
only ten years, which is consistent with economic theory stated in the third chapter i.e.,
WTP should be sensitive to the magnitude of mortality/risk reduction and should be higher
Studies whose WTP amounts are highly correlated with the starting points are so biased as
to be invalid (Mitchell and Carson, 1993). Pearson correlation coefficients of the two WTP
75
amounts were tested (Table 5.8) and the result shows that the correlation coefficient
between the WTP for indefinite years extension and starting point is 0.024. Similarly
Pearson correlation coefficient between WTP for ten years extension and starting point is
0.044, which both of the coefficients are insignificant. Therefore, this descriptive analysis
suggests that the CV survey may not suffer from starting point bias.
Respondents may over pledge their WTP amount if they believe that others are going to
pay for the intervention under consideration. To test whether this CV survey suffers from
free riding problem, comparison between the population median WTP and the median WTP
pay for the drugs is made. If the latter is far higher than the former it is to be concluded that
As can be seen from Table 5.10, the median WTP is Birr 50 for both indefinite and ten
years scenarios, which is not actually far from the median WTP of the population. Hence, it
is possible to conclude in this descriptive analysis that the CV survey carried out for this
techniques and property of the data used in the regression analysis. The determinants of
76
WTP for ARV drugs by PLWHA were estimated with a sample size of 408 records (after
Table 5.12 presents results of the parametric estimation of the censored regression using the
collected data. The model estimates determinant parameters of WTP for ARV drugs
assuming that 210 observations are left-censored (at zero) and 198 uncensored
observations. The pseudo R2 is 0.28 indicating that 28% of the variation in WTP is
explained by the independent variables identified in the study. The likelihood ratio for the
As stated in the previous chapter, to meaningfully analyze the magnitude of the effects of
the regressors on the dependent variable, it is necessary to analyze their marginal effects.
This involves decomposing the unconditional mean into the effect on the probability of
WTP and the effect on the conditional level of WTP. For continuous variables in the model
these marginal effects are used to calculate elasticities at the sample means to allow a
quantification of the magnitude of the effects to be made. The effect of the discrete or
using elasticities. Instead, marginal effects are used to calculate percentage changes in the
dependent variable as a result of the variable moving from zero to one, ceteris paribus
(Newman, 2001).
77
Table 5.12 Results of the Tobit Estimation
The result in the above table reveals that apart from employment status and family size, all
estimation. When a person living with the virus is categorized as employed, the WTP
increases and this variable is found to be statistically significant at 1% level. The marginal
coefficients indicate that an employed person increases the expected value of WTP by
68.7%, holding all other variables constant. The probability that an employed person will
78
The estimated elasticity coefficient for family size is not only negative, as hypothesized,
but also is statistically significant at 1% level. The marginal coefficient indicates that an
additional member in the family would decrease the WTP of the individual by 12%.
The finding of this parametric estimator shows that income elasticity is highly significant,
line with economic theory that states that income has a direct effect on demand for normal
goods and services. Hence, a 1% increase in income will increase WTP of the individual by
58%.
The elasticity coefficient of total treatment cost for the last two months reveals that the
higher the cost, the higher would also be the WTP of the individual, which this variable is
found to be statistically significant at 5% level. The reason might be that PLWHA would
like to shift the cost of treatment to ARV drugs rather than treat opportunistic infections.
Thus, a 1% increase in the treatment cost of OIs will result in a 32% increase in the WTP of
the individual for antiretroviral drugs, holding all other variables constant.
The fact that other parties (organization or association) pay for the treatment cost for the
last two months, instead of him/herself, implies a decrease in the expected value of the
WTP by 37.7%, ceteris paribus. Again others cover for treatment cost also means that the
The explanatory variable, initial bid price was used as a test for starting price bias. The
result shows that this variable is significant at 5% level of significance. However, free
79
riding is identified to be not a problem of the study. This is in conformity with the result of
Before dwelling into the discussion of the result of censored limited absolute deviation,
Mitchell and Carson (1993) underscore that contingent valuation surveys are particularly
susceptible to outliers because WTP amounts, unlike ordinary scales, are unbounded at the
upper end and this survey is no exception. Even if it is possible to delete outliers on an ad
hoc basis, Mitchell and Carson (1993) argue that this procedure suffers from the obvious
drawback that it opens the researcher to criticism. Instead the authors suggest to use robust
An attempt was also made to test whether the data of the survey encounters econometric
The two useful parameters, skewness and kurtosis, are used to characterize the normality of
while kurtosis measures the thickness of the tails of the distribution (Greene, 1997).
The test for these coefficients that is carried out for continuous variables in the data shows
that WTP, total income, treatment cost and years of living with the virus prove non-
2
Refer Annex 2 for attached results
80
normality since the skewness and kurtosis coefficients of these variables are different from
was used. However, the result shows that multicollinearity is not a serious problem of the
data because a correlation coefficient between any of two regressors is not found to be as
high as 0.8, which is the rule of thumb for the detection of multicollinearity (Gujarati,
1995).
A Cook-Weisberg test3 for heteroskedasticity was carried out. Using fitted values, the test
result shows that the null hypothesis of constant variance is rejected since the calculated χ2
at one degree of freedom obtained from the estimated model is 557.65 with prob> χ2 =
0.0000. This implies that there is heteroskedasticity problem in the model. This, however, is
Therefore, non-normality and heteroskedasticity are detected in the data. This fact coupled
with the result of the descriptive ananlysis, where 242 observations are censored at zero,
necessitate the use of censored quantile regression (CLAD). This is so because, unlike the
standard estimators of the censored regression model such as Tobit or other maximum
81
In this section, results of the censored least absolute deviation (CLAD) method of Powell
(1984) are presented. The estimation model proceeds by minimizing the (positive) sum of
The estimation procedure followed in this paper is the one outlined by Johnston and
2. Use this estimate of β to drop observations for which the predicted value is
negative.
As discussed in the methodology part, CLAD estimates the standard errors using the
bootstrapping method. Johnston and DiNardo (1997) propose that the bootstrap replications
should be set as high as is practical. In this study the replication is set to 1000.
Even if it is not uncommon to find low R2 results from CV studies, Mitchell and Carson
(1993) note that CV studies are open to question if the R2 fails to show at least 0.15. The
pseudo R2 from the CLAD estimation is 0.339, which makes this particular study to be
reliable. This result is an improvement over the parametric estimation, which is 0.28.
3
This test was carried out using hettest stata command by first estimating the data using OLS
4
The regression command bsqreg is used
82
Unlike the parametric estimation result, age of respondents is found to be significant at
10% level. The sign of this explanatory variable is positive indicating that as age increases,
With respect to marital status, compared with unmarried people both estimation techniques
show that those that are married, divorced or whose spouses deceased have lesser WTP.
significance. The explanation might be that most probably these people lost their spouses
due to the virus and have to support the remaining members of the family, which obviously
increases the burden of responsibility. In addition, due to the high treatment cost for the late
spouse, the widower/widowed may have exhausted his/her resources. Hence, their WTP is
negative and statistically significant at 1% level. One explanation is the greater the family
size the higher is the consumption expenditure in which case the individual is expected to
Income also exhibits consistency in both estimators- positive and highly significant
83
Among the health status indicators, total cost for the last two months is found to be positive
and significant, but in this estimation it is at 10% level, instead of 5% as in the case of the
Tobit estimation.
WP, the responsibility of treatment cost coverage, also exhibited different level of
significance (5% level of significance instead of 1%) with the sign of the coefficient being
unchanged.
The initial bid price is found to be positively and weakly affecting (at 10% level of
Both the parametric and semiparametric estimation methods found free riding as not a
As can be seen in Table 5.13 among the socio-demographic variables that are statistically
insignificant, the sign of sex is negative in both the Tobit and CLAD estimators suggesting
that female respondents are more WTP than male respondents. A priori the contrary was
hypothesized. Another variable, religion, was also found to be insignificant. This is in line
with Forsythe’s result (2002) that found religion to be an insignificant determinate of the
WTP for ARV therapies. With regard to educational status, compared to illiterate
individuals,those that have primary and secondary level of education are more WTP for the
drugs. Surprisingly, both the parametric and semiparametric methods show that compared
with illiterate people, those who have post-secondary education have less WTP. Even
though this variable is insignificant, it needs further investigation. Employment status was
84
found to be significant by the parametric estimation technique but not in the semiparametric
86
On the other hand, the 75th quantile regression showed
that employment status, like the Tobit result, is
significant but this time only at 10% level. Family size
and income are also significant in this estimation at 1%
level of significance and family head at 10%.
Post secondary education has positive sign across these
new quantile estimations implying that compared to
illiterate people, respondents having this level of
education are more WTP for ARVs. However, all of the
educational status variables are still insignificant. In
both the 50th and 75th quantile regressions, being a
family head implies more WTP whereas the 25th
quantile estimation shows the opposite effect. Another
variable that changed its sign, from negative to
positive, is years of living with the virus. In both the
25th and 50th quantile regressions, the longer the years
of living with the virus, the lesser the WTP of
individuals whereas the effect of this variable is direct
on the dependent variable when the 75th quantile
regression is run.
The estimations of the data of this paper empirically assessed the determinants of the WTP
Apart from standard parametric model used on censored data, notably the Tobit model, a
assumptions about the functional form of the disturbance term. The results of both
87
In the Tobit estimation, employment status and family size were found to be determinants
of WTP among the stated socio-demographic variables. Treatment cost for the last two
months and the responsibility of treatment cost coverage were also found to be statistically
The censored regression suffers from a number of specification problems. The disturbance
term is not normally distributed or homoskedastic. The fact that relaxing these two
assumptions of the model can make significant changes on the parameter estimates is
highlighted by the literature on the Tobit model. The results of the semiparametric
estimation technique shows that apart from family size, two other socio-demographic
variables, age and spouse deceased, were found to be statistically significant. However,
unlike the result of the parametric estimator, employment status was insignificant in
affecting WTP. The findings of this paper support the important role of income in
determining the WTP of respondents. Treatment cost and responsibility of coverage for this
cost were found to have the expected signs and were statistically significant.
In both estimation techniques, the initial bid price was shown to create bias on the final
response of respondents. However, this is one of the disadvantages of using a bidding game
as an elicitation method where even if individuals were randomly assigned five different
initial bid prices, the starting price had influenced the value respondents place on the drugs.
The study was, however, exempt from free riding problem and in general reliable.
Across the 25th, 50th and 75th quantile regressions, both income and family size are found to
be determining factors of the WTP of individuals, with expected signs. Comparing the
88
results of the 25th and 50th quantile regressions reveals that age, family size, income, total
treatment cost, responsibility of treatment cost payment and bid price are found to
However, when the results of the 75th and median regression are compared, only family size
and income are the common explanatory variables that are statistically significant.
Not surprisingly enough, the constant term is negative and found to be significant by all of
the estimators (Tobit, median and 75th quantile regression) at 1% level except by the 25th
respondents who were unwilling/unable to pay for the reason described earlier.
Since CLAD is an improvement over the Tobit model, only the results of the former
In this sub-section, an attempt is made to estimate the demand function of respondents for
ARV drugs.
Respondents WTP at
WTP Interval ∧ Sample Total WTP least
WTP distribution that amount (cumm.)
89
151-200 175.5 5 1.2 878 46 11.25
201-250 225.5 3 0.7 677 41 10.05
251-300 275.5 5 1.2 1,378 38 9.35
301-350 325.5 6 1.5 1,953 33 8.15
351-400 375.5 6 1.5 2,253 27 6.65
401-450 425.5 11 2.7 4,681 21 5.15
451-500 475.5 1 0.25 476 10 2.45
501-550 525.5 3 0.7 1,577 9 2.2
551-600 575.5 1 0.25 576 6 1.5
601-650 625.5 1 0.25 626 5 1.25
801-850 825.5 1 0.25 826 4 1.0
901-950 925.5 1 0.25 926 3 0.75
951-1050 1000.5 1 0.25 1,001 2 0.5
1500-2000 1750 1 0.25 1,750 1 0.25
Total 408 100.0 32,302
In table 5.15 from the WTP intervals, WTP midpoints are calculated. The grand total WTP
(Birr 32,302) indicates that this is the amount all of the respondents living with HIV/AIDS
are expected to pay per month if ARV drugs are made available in the market.
In the table, it can be seen that as the monthly payment increases, the number of people
willing to pay the increased figures declines. From this relationship the demand curve for
ARVs can be derived by plotting WTP midpoints on the vertical axis and the number of
respondents willing to pay at least that class mark on the horizontal axis.
90
Fig. 5.1 Estimated Demand Curve for
ARV Drugs
1800
1650
1500
1350
WTP (Midpoint)
1200
1050
900
750
600
450
300
150
No. of Respondents
The above demand curve has the form of a rectangular hyperbola, being asymptotic to both
axes, indicating a constant elasticity demand. This demand is usually associated with the
N = α / pη……………………………………………….(1)
N= PLWHA
η = elasticity coefficient
91
The implication of this function is, unlike the case of the straight line demand curve, here
people spend exactly the same amount when price is high as they do when price is low. As
one moves along the constant elasticity demand curve, the fall in the ratio of P/N is exactly
It is useful to note that a demand curve of constant elasticity has its own particular algebraic
form. This form involves the logarithms of quantity (N) and price (WTP midpoints)
It is the linear equation (2) that would actually be fitted statistically to the observation
reduced to logarithmic form. Therefore, estimating the double log function by fitting the
data indicates that α = 11.2. The implication of this result is respondents who spend their
entire allowance on ARVs each month would have a constant expenditure demand curve
for ARVs. The constant, 11.2, is equal to the amount of the allowance.
As mentioned above, η stands for elasticity. It follows that the proportionate change in the
number of people is a constant multiple of the proportionate change in price along the
demand curve. The estimation result for the elasticity coefficient is η = -1.448. According
to microeconomic theory, a constant elasticity demand curve with η > 1 has the property
that a price cut will always increase total expenditure and for one with η < 1 , by contrast, a
price cut will always reduce total expenditure (Frank, 1994). Hence, the coefficient of P,
92
1.448, indicates that whenever the price of ARVs declines, total expenditure of people
would increase.
Chapter six
6.1 CONCLUSION
Ethiopia is one of the most seriously affected countries in the world by HIV/AIDS. The
country, with just 1% of the world’s population, contributes 9% of the worldwide cases of
HIV/AIDS. The country is also identified, among other four countries, to be hit by the Next
Wave of HIV/AIDS.
Clinical trials for vaccine against HIV are underway, which protect against certain viral
subtypes of HIV in the test countries. The vaccine probably will not be effective against the
most common subtypes of HIV in countries that will be hit by the Next Wave of
HIV/AIDS- Nigeria, Ethiopia, Russia, India and China leaving the countries to focus on
anti-AIDS education to bring behavioural change to prevent new cases and ARV drugs to
93
This study tried to answer the question: “How much are people living with HIV/AIDS
willing to pay for anti-retroviral drugs” and attempted to identify the determinants of
willingness to pay for the drugs. The contingent valuation method was employed to assess
the above two objectives. CVM can be a very effective preference elicitation tool as long as
respondents understand the context and content of survey instrument. The survey results
revealed that 99.5% of the sample respondents were aware of ARV drugs, though many had
hazy idea for how long the drugs extend life years and/or the side effects of the drugs.
With the exception of 32 individuals, generally, respondents showed interest in the drugs.
However, 48% of the respondents that showed interest claimed to have no ability to pay for
the drugs if the drugs are available in the market. Among those that stated different
amounts of willingness to pay, the mean WTP per month is Birr 163.64 per month if the
drugs are effective for indefinite years and Birr 148.48 if only for ten years. The median
WTP of the respondents if the triple combination lengthens life years indefinitely is Birr
100 per month and Birr 50 for ten years. The stated figures are far below the current market
price of the drugs in other parts of the world, Birr 250 per month (UNAIDS, 2002 and
Walgate, 2002).
In relation to income, individuals were found to be willing to spend from 25%-28% of their
94
used, whose result was compared to the Tobit results. CLAD is preferred because it makes
no assumptions about the nature of the WTP data. In other words, it does not impose
The Tobit technique found employment status, income and treatment cost to significantly
and positively influence the WTP of individuals, whereas family size and the responsibility
of payment to the treatment cost were found to decrease the willingness to pay of
respondents significantly.
Results of the CLAD (50th quantile) estimation reveal that apart from family size, two other
socio-demographic variables, age and marital status (particularly those with spouse
deceased) were found to significantly determine the WTP for the drugs. Specifically, the
older the individual and the higher the income, the more would be the willingness to pay.
On other hand, those with spouse deceased, with larger family size and with others to pay
for their treatment cost have lesser willingness to pay for the drugs.
Finally, a comparison of the regression results for the 25th, 50th and 75th quantile regressions
indicated that some of the variables have different effects on the respondents’ WTP.
The attempt to derive the demand of respondents for ARVs resulted in a rectangular
responsiveness of individuals for a 1% cut in price was found to be a 1.4% increase in the
95
In general, the CV survey was found to be free of major biases and is reliable. It passed the
scope sensitivity and construct validity tests. Free riding was also not detected from the
responses of the individuals. However, even though the descriptive analysis showedd that
starting point bias did not exist in the survey, the contrary was found when bid price was
As stated in third chapter of this paper, respondents were asked to assume two
cases: the drugs lengthening lifetime by indefinite and ten years. However, WTP
tends to be affected by the order in which the years are presented (Krupnick et al,
2000). This research therefore will not be exempted from this effect.
The second limitation of the research is it attempted to derive the value of the drugs
by focusing exclusively on those who are in need rather than the general
community.
The research was conducted in Addis Ababa and did not include people living with
Among the different explanatory variables, income is found to be the most important
determinant of the willingness to pay for anti-retroviral drugs in both estimation techniques.
In the descriptive analysis, it was shown that 48% of the interviewed were constrained by
low income. This of course is the reflection of the general poverty of the country where it is
96
ranked 87 out of 88 developing countries in terms of human poverty index (UNDP, 2002).
This implies that the willingness to pay of the respondents for the drugs is highly
constrained by the low income. The inference from this would be the provision of anti-
retrovirals could not completely be left to the market. Different stakeholders- the Ethiopian
role in the provision of the drugs at lower price. The fact that if prices are reduced people
would be more willing to pay is substantiated by the findings of the estimated demand
elasticity coefficient.
Treating opportunistic infections is costly- the average treatment cost for the two months
before the survey is Birr 255. For 63.2% respondents that went to a medical centre to be
treated the organizations they work in or the respective associations established by
PLWHA covered for the treatment expenses. One of the assumed positive impacts of the
availability of ARV drugs is the reduction in the frequent visits to medical centres for
the treatment of opportunistic diseases. Hence, it is possible for the associations to divert
their resource for the provision of the drugs to their members.
The survey result shows that 90% of those interviewed think the Ethiopian government
has not exerted its best effort to bring the drugs to the country. It can change this image
by offering special tax incentive or by providing subsidy to local investors to endorse
domestic generic production of the drugs. This may be expected to dramatically
decrease the price of ARV drugs that are supposed to be imported in the near future.
Almost 47% of the respondents who participated in the survey believe that non-
governmental organizations (NGOs) operating in the country should play a role in the
distribution of the ARV drugs. It is true that “improvement and advancement of the
quality of life of those who are disadvantaged and vulnerable” is included in the mission
statement of NGOs (Code of Conduct, 1999). Hence, NGOs operating in the country can
play a multifaceted advocacy role. The first is creating awareness among the community
of people living with the virus. The survey showed that more than 55% had no idea for
how long the drug extends life years or about the toxicity. Since NGOs work at grass-
root level, they could sensitize people on the issue.
NGOs could also involve themselves in constructive policy dialogue with the
government to undertake active measures towards the drugs.
The third advocacy role could be played with their parent organizations. Though NGOs
receive financial or material assistance from donors to operate their programmes,
donors’ interests are more in favour of prevention and control (UNAIDS, 2002).
International organizations functioning in the country, in particular, could convince their
97
parent organizations and donors to give attention to care and support to people living
with HIV/AIDS to raise funds for the importation of the drugs.
For further research, it is possible to include both people living with and without the
virus to elicit their willingness to pay for the drugs. This would enable researchers to
identify the value attached to the drugs by people falling into the two categories.
Furthermore, researchers should be able to avoid the limitations of this particular
research to check if results are different from what is indicated in this study.
REFERENCES:
Abelson, Peter. (1996). Project Appraisal and Valuation: General Principles and Six Case
Management.
Belaineh Taye (2001). Economic Cost of Malaria on Rural Households, and Willingness to
Pay for Bed Nets: The Case of Selected Rural Kebeles in ILU Woreda of West
Shoa Zone
Bishai, D.M and Lang, H.C (2000). The WTP for Wait Reduction: The Disutility of
Queues for Cataract Surgery in Canada, Denmark, and Spain, Journal of Health
Bonato, D., Nocera, S., and Telser,H (2001). The CVM in Health Care: An Economic
15(3): 355-379
Chay, K and Powell, J., (2001). Semi Parametric Censored Regression Models, Journal of
Diener, A., O’Brien, B., and Gafni, A. (1998). Health Care Contingent Valuation Studies:
ECA (Economic Commission for Africa). (January 2002). “HIV in sub-Saharan Africa”
FHI (Family Health International) (October 1998). “Impact on HIV” Vol. 1, number 1,
Floyd, K. and Gilks, C. (1997). Cost and Financing Aspects of Providing Anti-Retroviral
99
Greene, W.H. (1993). Econometric Analysis, 2nd ed.
Krupnick et al. (September, 2000). Age, Health and the Willingness to Pay for Mortality
McDonald, J.F. and Moffitt, R.A., (1980). The Issues of Tobit Analysis, Review of
Mitchell, R. and Carson, R. (1993). Using Surveys to Value Public Goods: The Contingent
Valuation Method.
Newman, Carol, (2001). A Double Hurdle Model of Irish Households’ Meat Expenditure
NIC (National Intelligence Council) (2002). “Next Wave of HIV/AIDS: Nigeria, Ethiopia,
100
O’Conor, M., et al (1998). Urge Incontinence- Quality of life and patients’ Valuation of
and Development.
Panos Institute (December, 2002). “Patents, Pills ,and Public Health: Can TRIPS deliver?”
Pol, V., and Cairns, J. (1999). Individual Time Preferences for Own Health: An Application
6(10): 649-654.
“Policy framework on the Provision and Use of ARV Drugs in Ethiopia” (March 2002).
Ethiopian Government.
“Policy on Antiretroviral Drugs: Supply and Use of the Federal Democratic Republic of
Ethiopia”. (2002).
Powell, J.L (1984). Least Absolute Deviations Estimation for the Censored Regression
Antiretroviral.
U.K.
101
UNAIDS (2002) “Assessment Report on Services Available in Addis Ababa to Diagnose,
Infections”.
World “
Walgate, Robert. (2002). As AIDS Drugs Prices Plummet for Third World, Questions Still
Around.
Whitehead et al. (May, 2000). Willingness to Pay for a Coastal Recreational Fishing
Resource Economics)
Whittington et al. (2002). Private demand for a HIV/AIDS Vaccine: Evidence from
Guadalajara, Mexico.
102
WHO/UNAIDS (1998). Introducing Antiretroviral Treatments into Health Systems:
Module 2.
104
2-3 years 11 2.5
5-10 years 79 18.0
Effectiveness 10-15 years 44 10.0
15-20 years 34 7.7
20-25 years 8 1.8
25-30 years 3 0.7
Indefinite years 18 4.1
Toxicity Very high 28 6.4
Modest 66 15.0
Low 64 14.5
No toxicity 49 11.1
Do not Know 233 53.0
105
150 31 60 91
200 58 52 110
250 24 55 79
300 53 29 82
350 32 46 78
Total 198 242 440
Indefinite 10 years
Pearson 0.0024 0.044
Correlation
Sig. (2-tailed) 0.713 0.905
106
female
male
SEX
0
00
-2
00 50
15 -10
1 0
95 -95
1 0
90 -85
1 0
80 -65
1
60 600
1- 0
55 -55
107
1 0
50 -50
WTP amount
1
10 00
-1
51
50
1-
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
Count
0 0
00 00
-2 -2
00 0 00 0
15 105 15 105
1- 1-
95 950 95 950
1- 1-
90 850 90 850
1- 1-
80 650 80 650
1- 1-
60 600 60 600
1- 1-
55 550 55 550
1-
108
1-
50 500 50 500
1- 1-
45 450 45 450
1- 1-
40 00 40 400
4 1-
1- 35 350
WTP amount
15 50 1-
WTP amount
1 10 00
1-
10 00 -1
-1 51
51 50
50 1-
1-
50
45
40
35
30
25
20
1
Mean AGE Mean family size
Table 5.14 Results of the 25th and 75th quantile regressions
109
Normality Test
Statistics WTP Income TC YLV
Number of Obs. 408 408 408 408
Skewness 3.313 .757 .990 1.280
Std. Error of Skewness .121 .121 .121 .121
Kurtosis 13.402 -.534 .240 1.185
Std. Error of Kurtosis .241 .241 .241 .241
WTP
400
300
200
100
Frequency
0
0.0 2.5 5.0 7.5 10.0 12.5 15.0 17.5 20.0
WTP
Multicollinearity test
Sex age married Divorced widowed Muslim Orth/
Cath
Sex 1.000
Age 0.396 1.000
married 0.104 -0.053 1.000
divorced -0.008 0.094 -0.292 1.000
widowed -0.119 0.223 -0.523 -0.244 1.000
Muslim 0.173 0.164 -0.021 0.078 0.007 1.000
OrthCath -0.075 -0.103 -0.034 0.124 -0.047 -0.170 1.000
primary -0.049 -0.087 -0.127 0.064 0.060 0.172 -0.017
110
secondary -0.072 -0.103 0.084 -0.056 -0.037 -0.155 0.059
Bsecondary 0.285 0.241 0.078 -0.007 -0.083 0.017 -0.033
employed 0.290 0.329 0.073 0.045 -0.028 0.100 0.002
FS 0.052 0.257 0.134 -0.057 0.022 0.078 -0.130
BP -0.002 -0.049 0.023 0.031 -0.027 -0.063 -0.022
YLV -0.005 0.234 0.014 -0.063 0.098 -0.009 -0.076
TC 0.030 0.168 0.001 0.073 0.080 0.062 -0.050
WP -0.125 -0.013 0.022 0.050 0.012 0.049 -0.014
FH 0.013 0.282 0.100 0.024 0.237 0.085 -0.089
Income 0.236 0.277 0.103 -0.007 -0.026 0.018 -0.019
XY 0.157 0.150 0.158 0.018 -0.112 0.048 0.010
HS -0.108 -0.010 -0.038 -0.021 0.081 -0.003 -0.082
FR -0.077 0.017 0.009 -0.076 0.062 -0.080 0.003
TC WP FH Income XY HS FS
TC 1.000
WP 0.460 1.000
FH 0.150 0.065 1.000
Income 0.110 -0.155 0.138 1.000
XY 0.042 -0.066 0.131 0.257 1.000
HS 0.527 0.260 0.044 -0.093 -0.040 1.000
FS 0.043 0.079 0.107 0.049 0.010 0.006 1.000
111
Test for outliers
30
292
20 104
86
185
301
217
99
268
282
10 199
2
294
288
299
150
269
163
103
309
305
182
33
76
202
408
221
205
112
113
364
144
124
405
59
407
29
390
389
404
290
277
-10
N= 408
WTP
QUESTIONNAIRE
Interviewer’s Name_____________
Date of the Interview____________
Supervisor’s Name______________
Date of Supervision_____________
Hello. My name is Martha Getachew. I am doing my Msc thesis on “willingness to pay for
antiretroviral drugs”, which I believe will help policy makers in their decision. The research
will be a successful story only if you help me by answering the questions below.
The interview is totally voluntary and if you feel uncomfortable in any of the questions you
are free not to answer.
1. Sex_______
112
2. Age_______
3. Marital Status
a. Married c. Single
b. Divorced d. Spouse deceased
4. Religion
a. Orthodox d. Muslim
b. Protestant e. Other___________
c. Catholic
5. Educational status
a. Illiterate d. Primary education complete
b. Able to read and write e. High school complete
c. Below 4th grade f. Beyond High school
6. Occupational Status
a. Civil servant e. Daily labourer
b. Own business f. Association employee
c. Private employee g. Unemployed
d. NOG worker h.Other___________
Studies show that using antiretroviral drugs lengthens the life years of people living with
the virus. These drugs are being distributed in the other parts of the world.
1. Have you ever heard/read/discussed about anti-retroviral drugs before this survey?
a) Yes
b) No
2. Do you use these drugs or have you ever used these before?
a) Yes
b) No
3. Do you know any one (family member or friend) who uses these drugs?
a) Yes
b) No
4. Do you think the current price in the country is reasonable?
a) Yes
b) No
c) Don’t know
5. For how long do you think these drugs lengthen the life of a person living with the
virus?_____________
113
6. What do you think about the side effects of the drugs?
a. Very high toxicity d. No toxicity
b. Modest toxicity e. Don’t know
c. Low toxicity
Anti-retroviral drugs are assumed to lengthen the lifetime of people living with
HIV/AIDS for sometime and reduce the possibility of having opportunistic infections.
The Ethiopian government is thinking of providing ARVs for free only to prevent
mother-to-child transmission whereas other HIV carriers will be charged user fees.
This research will try to assess how much you are willing and able to pay for the triple
combinations.
1. Let’s assume that triple combination lengthens the lifetime of people living with
the virus for indefinite years. Keeping in mind the limitations of your (family’s)
income, if the price of triple combination is Birr 200 per month are you willing and
able to pay for the drug?
a) Yes
b) No
Note to interviewer: If the response is “Yes” go to the next table; ask the figures till
the respondent refuses to pay. However, if the answer to the above question is
“No”go to quesion number 2
114
2. If the answer to question 1 is “No”, keeping in mind again the limitations of your
(or family’s) income, are you willing and able to pay from 150 per month for the
triple combination if the drug lengthens your lifetime by indefinite years?
a) Yes
b) No
Note to the interviewer: If the response is “Yes” to the above question go to next
table. However, if the answer is “No” go to the question number 3.
Birr per month Yes Specifically No
How much?
51-100
1-50
Note to the interviewer: If the respondents says “Yes” to any of the payment
questions go to question 4. However, if the respondent doesn’t show any interest in
the payment then go to the next question.
3. If you are not willing to pay at all for the drugs, would you tell me the reason?
Because:
a) I believe the drugs do not lengthen life years
b) I believe the drugs should be given for free
c) I have no income
d) I believe it has toxicity/side effects
e) I believe that only God can cure me
f) Other___________
4. If the drugs become available in the market and lengthen life years indefinitely
whose responsibility is to pay for the drugs for you?
a. Myself
b. My family
c. The organization I work in
d. The association I am a member in
e. Other___________________
5. Let’s assume that triple combination lengthens the lifetime of people living with the
virus for ten years. Keeping in mind the limitations of your (family’s) income, if the
price of triple combination is Birr 200 per month are you willing and able to pay for
the drug?
a) Yes
b) No
115
Note to interviewer: If the response is “Yes” go to the next table; ask the figures till
the respondent refuses to pay. However, if the answer to the above question is
“No”go to quesion number 2
6. If the answer to question 1 is “No”, keeping in mind again the limitations of your
(or family’s) income, are you willing and able to pay from 150 per month for the
triple combination if the drug lengthens your lifetime by ten years?
a) Yes
b) No
Note to the interviewer: If the response is “Yes” to the above question go to next
table. However, if the answer is “No” go to the question number 3.
Birr per month Yes Specifically No
How much?
51-100
1-50
Note to the interviewer: If the respondents says “Yes” to any of the payment
questions go to question 4. However, if the respondent doesn’t show any interest in
the payment then go to the next question.
7. If you are not willing to pay at all for the drugs, would you tell me the reason?
Because:
8. If the drugs become available in the market and lengthen life years by ten years
whose responsibility is to pay for the drugs for you?
a. Myself
b. My family
c. The organization I work in
d. The association I am a member in
e. Other___________________
1. How long has it been since you knew you have the virus in your blood?________
2. How do you evaluate your health status?
a. Very good d. Bad
b. Good e. Very bad
c. Modest
3. For the last two months, for how long did you visit a hospital, clinic or health station
for treatment?____________
4. For the last two months, without visiting a hospital, clinic or health station, did you
prescribe anti-pain for yourself?
a. Yes
b. No
5. For the last two months, how much did you spend for treatment cost?__________
6.If you incurred any treatment cost for the last two months, who covered for the expense?
a. Myself
b. My family
c. My organization
d. My association
e. Other___________
7. Are a family head?
a. Yes
b. No
8. If response to the above question is “Yes” how many persons depend on you?_____
9. Do you work and earn income?
a. Yes
b. No
If “Yes” how much do you earn?
Note to the interviewer: if the response is in terms of per month write the answer
under “monthly”- do the same for others accordingly.
117
10. Is there anyone in the house who works and earns income?
a. Yes
b. No
If “Yes” how much do they earn?
Number ofDaily Weekly Monthly Annually
workers
1.
2.
3.
4.
11. Do you get financial support from relatives, friends, association or others?
a. Yes
b. No
If “Yes” how much do you get?
Daily Weekly Monthly Annually
12. Is there anyone else in your family that is also HIV positive
a. Yes
b. No
Note to the interviewer: If the response to the above question is “Yes” ask the next
question; if “No” go to the next section.
1. In your opinion how do you think the distribution of the drugs be carried out?
a. Government should distribute for free
b. NGOs should distribute for free
c. Pharmacies should distribute the drugs by charging users
d. Other______________________
2. If your economic status changes for the better are willing to pay for the drugs?
a. Yes
118
b. No
3. In your opinion do you think the Ethiopian government has exerted its best effort to
import the drugs to the country?
a. Yes
b. No
119