Public Debt On Income Inequality
Public Debt On Income Inequality
Public Debt On Income Inequality
Abstract
Global income inequality becomes one of the severe problems in most econo-
mies, while government spending financed by public debt can be a good instru-
ment of fiscal policy to reduce this inequality in society. Does institutional quality
affect the public debt – income inequality relationship in advanced economies?
For the answer, the paper employs the system-GMM and PMG estimator to
examine the effects of public debt, institutional quality, and their interaction on
income inequality for a group of 30 advanced economies from 2002 through
2020. The paper finds some exciting results. Public debt and institutional quality
narrow income inequality, but their interaction term widens. Furthermore, eco-
nomic growth and unemployment increase income inequality, while education
decreases it. The findings suggest some necessary policy implications to narrow
income inequality through public debt and institutional quality.
Introduction
keeps a crucial role in the fiscal policy of governments. Compared with tax reve-
nue, government spending is an active instrument of governments in running
the economy and overcoming economic cyclicality. Governments actively spend
more for a recession economy with high unemployment (an expansionary fiscal
policy with increased government spending). However, they will spend less for
a hot economy with high inflation (a contractionary fiscal policy with decreased
government spending). In particular, governments can spend more to help low-
income individuals access healthcare and education through social transfers to
reduce the income difference between high-income individuals and low-income
individuals, narrowing income inequality in society. However, rising public
spending financed by borrowing leads to high public debt. Economic history
shows that public debt crises often lead to economic crises: the European debt
crisis in the second half of 2009 with high public debt in Portugal, Greece, Italy,
Ireland, and Spain, the financial crisis in East Asia officially in 1997 with the
collapse of the Thai baht, the Latin American debt crisis of the 1980s. These
economies often have to enforce austerity policies and lose economic sovereignty
to receive rescue packages from the IMF or World Bank. Their citizens face an
unstable economy with more unemployment. Therefore, governments should
control public debt with strict fiscal discipline to avoid a public debt crisis in the
future. Despite its significant role in reducing inequality in society, the effect of
government debt on wealth and income inequality remains a controversial topic.
Since the birth of the GINI index in 1912, several related studies have tested the
impact of public/government debt on inequality. However, no studies investigate
the contribution of institutional quality to the public debt – income inequality
relationship in advanced economies. Therefore, this paper will do it to contribute
to the literature.
Global income inequality is one of the severe problems, while increasing
public debt can lead to a debt crisis and social instability. In particular, institu-
tional quality can significantly contribute to the public debt – income inequality
relationship in advanced economies. Given these facts, the paper employs the
system-GMM and PMG estimator to investigate the impacts of public debt, insti-
tutional quality, and their interaction on income inequality for a balanced panel
dataset of 30 advanced economies during the period 2002 – 2020.
The paper shows the structure as follows. The introduction presents the intro-
duction, while Section 1 gives an overview of global public debt as well as global
income inequality. The theoretical framework and literature review in Section 2
focus on the impact of government debt on inequality, and Section 3 notes the
methodology and research data. Meanwhile, Section 4 reports the results and dis-
cussion, and the last section provides a conclusion and some policy implications.
725
DESA (2020) says that many economies that experience high-income gaps
have enjoyed a decrease in income inequality. Several economies and regions
with low levels of income inequality in 1990 have seen increases in the income
gap. Germany, many Eastern European economies, and Nordic economies have
suffered rises in income inequality. Furthermore, some large middle-income
economies have enjoyed rises in income inequality since 1990. Notably, China’s
income inequality increased in both urban and rural areas.
Notably, the income share by the top 1% increased in 59 out of 100 econo-
mies. In 2015, the richest 1% earned more than 20% of all income in 18 econo-
mies, including the United States, the United Arab Emirates, Turkey, Thailand,
the Russian Federation, India, Chile, and Brazil. Although income inequality in
Brazil has decreased, the income share of the top 1% before transfers and taxes
increased to 28.3% in 2015 from 26.2% in 2001. In particular, the incomes of
726
the bottom 40% increased faster than average in France but slower than average
in the United States, meaning that France moved towards decreasing income
inequality while the United States did not.
Since the 2008 financial and economic crisis, the incomes of the top 10%
and the top 1% have fallen in most high-income economies. In the meantime,
the incomes of the bottom 10% have suffered a sustained decrease in around
one-third of advanced economies. Among them are economies (Spain, Ireland,
and Greece) that experienced the greatest income losses through the crisis.
Given the relevance, Chatzouz (2014) and Borissov and Kalk (2020) suggest
theoretical frameworks to note the impact of public debt on income inequality.
Chatzouz (2014) offers a simple analytical model to show how government debt
affects wealth inequality with the presence of altruism. Meanwhile, Borissov and
Kalk (2020) develop an economic growth model with government borrowing
financed by income taxes and the presence of positional concerns. The analysis
shows that policies focusing on narrowing initial inequality by government debt
can widen wealth inequality in the long run. Notably, this paper discovers that
institutional quality has a significant contribution to the public debt – income
inequality relationship in advanced economies. According to Li and Filer (2007),
advanced economies are those with rule-based governance (good institutional
quality). These economies have enough appropriate resources to handle the in-
come gap in society. They design, formulate and enforce regulations and policies
(institutional quality) to narrow income inequality between the rich and the poor.
They have higher levels of social spending and spend more on social protection
(Ortiz-Ospina and Roser, 2016). They use public spending financed by debt to
support the poor and low-income individuals through social transfers throughout
economic development, reducing the income difference between low-income
and high-income individuals. As a result, public debt and institutional quality
decrease income inequality.
However, because high public debt can cause a public debt crisis and social
instability, some regulations and policies (institutional quality) in these econo-
mies focus on controlling and managing strictly public debt. It leads to a decline
in public debt. Therefore, the interaction between public debt and institutional
quality can increase income inequality.
727
model for a group of 71 developing countries between 1986 and 2016. They find
that debt restructurings widen income inequality. In the same vein, Obiero and
Topuz (2021) employ the ARDL model for the data of time series in Kenya from
1970 through 2018. They note that both public and internal debt increase income
inequality in the long term.
In short, the literature review shows: (i) no studies examine the contribution of
institutional quality to the public debt – income inequality relationship in advanced
economies, (ii) no studies employ the PMG estimator and the system-GMM
estimator that can deal with serial autocorrelation and endogenous phenomena
in the empirical models. Governance/institutional quality can significantly affect
public debt. Tarek and Ahmed (2017) find that the three poor governance indica-
tors lead to high public debt in the MENA countries. Plus, Asamoah (2021) dis-
covers that institutional quality can narrow income inequality in developed and
developing countries. Institutional improvement can change public debt, which
can reduce/increase income inequality. Therefore, studying the impact of public
debt on income inequality without the role of institutional quality can be a short-
coming. This paper focuses on these issues as a new contribution to the literature.
3.1. Methodology
Following the literature review, the paper uses the empirical equation as follows:
GIN it = γ 0 + γ 1GIN it −1 + γ 2 DEBit + γ 3GOit + γ 2 ( DEB × GO )it + X it γ ′ + σ i + τ it (1)
where t and i are the time and country index. GINit is the Gini index, a proxy for
income inequality. Its value ranges from 0 to 100 where 0 notes complete equa-
lity (everyone has the same income) and 100 reports the highest level of income
inequality; GINit-1 is the lagged dependent variable; DEBit is public debt (% GDP);
GOit is one of the six governance indicator (control of corruption, political stability,
government effectiveness, rule of law, regulatory quality, voice and accountabil-
ity), a proxy for institutional quality; ( DEB × GO )it is the interaction between
public debt and institutional quality. Xit contains some control variables as eco-
nomic growth, education, and unemployment; σi is a country-specific, time-
invariant, unobserved effect and τit is an observed error term; γ0, γ1, γ2, and γ’ are
estimated parameters. Following Lee (2005) and Biglaiser and McGauvran
(2021), the paper uses education and economic growth as control variables. Fur-
thermore, it also uses unemployment in the empirical equations as unemploy-
ment can significantly contribute to income inequality.
729
The study applies Equation (1) to test the impacts of government debt, insti-
tutional quality, and their interaction on income inequality for a group of 30
advanced economies. It employs six governance indicators by the World Bank
(with values ranging from –2.5 to 2.5) to proxy for institutional quality. Daniel
et al. (2018) confirm that an “institutional void” can arise and impede policy
efforts to decrease economic inequality through the operations of efficient mar-
kets. From the views of individuals and firms, the following six governance
indicators have been suggested by World Bank (2021) to facilitate economic
activities, improve welfare, and reduce poverty and economic inequality:
• Control of corruption: Corruption has adverse impacts on the economy. It is
a constraint facing firms in developing economies (World Bank, 2021). Gupta
et al. (2002) indicate that corruption leads a high-income inequality and poverty in
several developing economies. Notably, higher corruption negatively affects efforts
in income distribution conducted by governments (Gyimah-Brempong, 2002).
• Government Effectiveness: This indicator supports the government to design,
issue, and enforce sound policies in which citizens are centric (Duho, 2020). Some
poor institutional factors, i. e. government ineffectiveness, can lead to a deteriora-
tion in the income distributions of developing economies (Acemoglu et al., 2001).
• Political Stability: Political instability leads to uncertainty in the economy
and impedes efforts in income distribution by governments. By contrast, political
stability enhances welfare by improving income distribution and removing ine-
quality from the economy (Shafique et al., 2006).
• Regulatory Quality: This indicator shows the government’s capability to de-
sign, issue, and enforce sound regulations and policies that promote efficient
economic activities (World Bank, 2021). Governments may achieve targets by
increasing spending on regulatory measures like equitable income distribution
(Shafique et al., 2006).
• Rule of Law: This indicator captures the independence and functioning of
the judiciary, including contract enforcement quality, property rights protection, the
police, and the likelihood of violence and crime (World Bank, 2021). Acemoglu
et al., (2001) argue that the absence of the rule of law can the income distribution
efforts in developing economies. By contrast, government effectiveness is neces-
sary to eradicate poverty and narrow income inequality (Kraay and Dollar, 2003).
• Voice and Accountability: This indicator is the guarantee of stability and
transparency of regulations and policies built by governments. It makes policyma-
kers responsible for failures in implementing regulations and policies. Accounta-
bility in public officials contributes to efficient resource allocations (Farrington,
2009). Perera and Lee (2013) indicate democratic accountability reduces the
income gap in some Asian countries.
730
where Y is the Gini index, a proxy for income inequality; Xit-1 is the deviation from
long-run equilibrium for group i at any period t, and ψ is the error-correction
731
coefficient. The vector captures the long-run coefficients. They express the
long-run elasticity of inequality corresponding with every variable in Zit-1. Mean-
while, the vector π captures the short-run responses of the Z variables. σi is
a fixed effect and τit is an error term. The study uses the value and significance
level of the speed of adjustment ψ (negative, smaller than 1) to examine the
validity of the PMG estimates.
Data consist of the GINI index, public debt, governance indicators, real per
capita GDP, primary school enrollment, and unemployment. The study extracts
them from World Bank and International Monetary Fund databases. The sample
contains 30 advanced economies2 between 2002 and 2020.
The study presents the descriptive statistics in Table 1 and definition of the
dataset and the matrix of correlation coefficients among variables in the Appendix
(Table A, Table B, and Table C).
Table 1
Descriptive Statistics
Variable Obs. Mean Std. Dev. Min Max
Income inequality (GIN) 570 31.612 4.252 23.6 42.5
(Slovenia, 2020) (Israel, 2010)
Public debt (DEB) 3.765 211.2
570 63.456 35.240
(Estonia, 2007) (Greece, 2020)
Economic growth (GDP) 8008.4 111968.4
570 40492.5 21573.0
(Lithuania, 2002) (Luxembourg, 2007)
Education (EDU) 95.648 126.575
570 102.189 4.177
(Latvia, 2006) (Latvia, 2017)
Unemployment (UNE) 2.01 27.466
570 7.648 4.134
(Czech, 2019) (Ireland, 2013)
Regulatory Quality (IN1) -0.189 2.469
570 1.304 0.711
(Greece, 2006) (Denmark, 2012)
Rule of Law (IN2) 0.197 2.353
570 1.374 0.474
(Italy, 2007) (Denmark, 2007)
Voice and Accountability -1.626 1.755
570 .774 0.545
(IN3) (Israel, 2009) (Finland, 2002)
Control of Corruption 0.148 2.047
570 1.333 0.363
(IN4) (Greece, 2016) (Netherlands, 2017)
Government Effectiveness 0.083 2.100
570 1.360 0.489
(IN5) (Greece, 2017) (Finland, 2014)
Political Stability (IN6) 0.570 1.800
570 1.224 0.286
(Israel, 2009) (Denmark, 2004)
Source: Stata software’s processing.
2
Austria, Belgium, Canada, Cyprus, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France,
Germany, Greece, Iceland, Italy, Israel, Ireland, South Korea, Luxembourg, Lithuania, Latvia,
Malta, Norway, Netherlands, Portugal, Switzerland, Slovak Republic, Spain, Slovenia, Sweden,
United Kingdom, United States.
732
The results in Table B show that public debt, education, and unemployment
are positively connected with income inequality, but economic growth is nega-
tively associated with it. The value of correlation coefficients among control
variables is low (lower than 0.8), so the study uses all in the empirical models.
However, the value of all correlation coefficients among governance indicators
in Table C is high (higher than 0.8), so the study uses them separately in the
empirical equations.
Table 2 and Table 3 show the two-step and one-step S-GMM estimates across
all empirical models for the group of 30 advanced economies. Each column is
the model corresponding with each governance indicator. The paper detects that
public debt is endogenous in estimation procedures, thus it uses public debt as an
instrumented variable in GMM style and income inequality, institutional quality,
economic growth, education, and unemployment as instrumental variables in IV
style.
The results in Table 2 and Table 3 indicate that public debt and institutional
quality reduce income inequality, but their interaction increases it. The main
result is that public debt narrows income inequality, and this negative effect is
hindered by institutional quality. Notably, although governance indicators (con-
trol of corruption, political stability, government effectiveness, rule of law, regu-
latory quality, and voice and accountability) are separately applied in the empiri-
cal equations, the results note that the sign and significance level of their and
interaction terms’ estimated coefficients are completely consistent. Furthermore,
economic growth and unemployment increase income inequality, but education
decreases.
Advanced economies are those with good institutional quality that have
enough appropriate resources to deal with the income gap in society. With rich
resources and high levels of development, governments in these economies for-
mulate and enforce policies and regulations (institutional quality) to reduce the
income difference between high-income and low-income individuals. Concern-
ing taxation, regulations and policies in these economies (which can be shown in
terms of regulatory quality and government effectiveness) focus on taxing high-
income people, not low-income people, and collect the tax revenue partly to
support low-income people. Regarding the control and collection of taxes, regu-
lations and policies (which can be expressed in terms of corruption control and
733
the rule of law) strictly control the income of the rich to eliminate the possibility
of tax evasion, thereby ensuring fairness for tax payment between the rich and
the poor. In particular, policies and regulations issued by the government are
always publicly and transparently monitored (voice and accountability), thus
ensuring a more equitable allocation of national resources in society, thus reduc-
ing the income gap between the rich and the poor, thus narrowing income ine-
quality. The paper finds it in Richmond and Triplett (2018), Matallah (2019),
and Law et al. (2020). Furthermore, they use high levels of public spending on
social protection (Ortiz-Ospina and Roser, 2016). They use spending financed by
public debt to support the poor and low-income individuals through social trans-
fers throughout economic development. In addition to social transfer, public
expenditures on health and education are allocated to help people improve their
skills and knowledge so that they can find appropriate jobs with high incomes. In
particular, these expenditures in developed countries are fairly distributed and
mostly spent for low-income and jobless people (the poor), so narrowing the
income difference between high-income and low-income individuals. The paper
finds the same result in Tung (2020).
However, high government debt can cause a debt crisis and social instability.
For example, the European debt crisis in the second half of 2009 with high pub-
lic debt in Portugal, Greece, Italy, Ireland, and Spain (developed economies) led
to economic and political instability in these economies. The number of poor and
homeless in these economies increased rapidly during this crisis period, especially
since the majority of the severely affected people were poor and low-skilled. To
quickly get out of this crisis, these economies must accept the austerity solutions
proposed by the IMF to receive bailouts. Accordingly, regulations and policies
(institutional quality) must be changed and adjusted to cut government expendi-
ture for retirees and jobless people, thereby focusing on reducing budget deficits
and controlling and managing government debt. In particular, all these regula-
tions and policies must reach a consensus among political parties (political sta-
bility), representing people's voices. In short, regulations and policies (institu-
tional quality) that are issued and implemented to control public debt may reduce
public debt. However, it leads to a decrease in public expenditures for the poor
and low-income people, while the rich are almost unaffected by these regulations
and policies, narrowing the income gap between the rich and the poor. As a re-
sult, the interaction between public debt and institutional quality widens income
inequality.
This finding recommends that governments in advanced economies can use
public debt to narrow income inequality in society. They should spend more on
education and health to support the poor to improve their skills and knowledge,
734
Table 2
Institutional Quality, Public Debt and Income Inquality: Two-step S-GMM
Estimates Dependent Variable: GINI Index (income inequality)
Variables IN1 IN2 IN3 IN4 IN5 IN6
*** *** *** *** ***
Gini index (–1) 0.930 0.923 0.908 0.937 0.922 0.919***
(0.023) (0.025) (0.021) (0.019) (0.025) (0.027)
Public debt –0.020*** –0.039*** –0.016*** –0.041*** –0.028** –0.088***
(0.007) (0.015) (0.005) (0.015) (0.013) (0.034)
Institutional quality –1.177*** –2.615*** –1.642*** –2.659*** –2.138*** –5.403**
(0.353) (0.911) (0.367) (0.909) (0.739) (2.190)
Public debt*Ins. quality 0.013*** 0.029*** 0.016*** 0.032*** 0.020** 0.073***
(0.004) (0.011) (0.004) (0.010) (0.009) (0.028)
Economic growth 0.006*** 0.007*** 0.005*** 0.005*** 0.007*** 0.010***
(0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.002) (0.003)
Education –0.027** –0.026* –0.020* –0.004 –0.027** –0.028*
(0.013) (0.014) (0.010) (0.012) (0.013) (0.015)
Unemployment 0.055** 0.061** 0.064*** 0.070** 0.053* 0.104**
(0.025) (0.030) (0.016) (0.028) (0.027) (0.041)
Instrument 11 13 13 12 12 11
Country/Observation 30/510 30/510 30/510 30/510 30/510 30/510
AR(2) test 0.216 0.233 0.279 0.114 0.186 0.269
Sargan test 0.578 0.564 0.266 0.741 0.452 0.720
Hansen test 0.647 0.805 0.660 0.838 0.689 0.867
Note: ***, **,* note significance level at 1%, 5%, 10% respectively.
Source: Stata software’s processing.
Table 3
Institutional Quality, Public Debt and Income Inquality: One-step S-GMM
Estimates Dependent Variable: GINI Index (income inequality)
Variables IN1 IN2 IN3 IN4 IN5 IN6
Gini index (–1) 0.925*** 0.917*** 0.905*** 0.928*** 0.919*** 0.910***
(0.011) (0.011) (0.013) (0.010) (0.011) (0.012)
Public debt –0.021*** –0.038*** –0.010** –0.044*** –0.040*** –0.097***
(0.005) (0.010) (0.005) (0.010) (0.008) (0.024)
Institutional quality –1.240*** –2.610*** –1.003** –2.996*** –2.729*** –6.129***
(0.287) (0.686) (0.448) (0.717) (0.556) (1.493)
Public debt*Ins. quality 0.013*** 0.028*** 0.008 0.033*** 0.028*** 0.080***
(0.003) (0.007) (0.005) (0.007) (0.006) (0.020)
Economic growth 0.006*** 0.008*** 0.003*** 0.006*** 0.008*** 0.012***
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.002)
Education –0.027*** –0.025** –0.001 –0.009 –0.032*** –0.030***
(0.011) (0.012) (0.008) (0.008) (0.011) (0.011)
Unemployment 0.057*** 0.056*** 0.047*** 0.074*** 0.060*** 0.121***
(0.020) (0.021) (0.017) (0.019) (0.020) (0.028)
Instrument 12 13 17 12 12 11
Country/Observation 30/510 30/510 30/510 30/510 30/510 30/510
AR(2) test 0.255 0.248 0.291 0.107 0.216 0.299
Sargan test 0.374 0.564 0.178 0.741 0.307 0.253
Note: ***, **,* note significance level at 1%, 5%, 10% respectively.
Source: Stata software’s processing.
736
The paper employs the PMG estimator for Equation (2) to test the robustness
of S-GMM estimates. It uses only economic growth as a control variable. The
PMG estimator requires the co-integration between regressors and the dependent
variable. So, the paper examines the stationary of all variables in the empirical
model to ensure that they all have the same order of co-integration. Then, it per-
forms the panel co-integration tests by Westerlund (2007).
The stationary tests in Table D (Appendix) report income inequality, public
debt, institutional quality, and economic growth are stationary at a significance
level of less than 10%, meaning that they have a co-integration of zero-order
I(0). The Westerlund tests in Table 4 note that three of four tests deny the null
hypothesis of no co-integration, suggesting that income inequality co-integrates
with public debt, six governance indicators, and economic growth.
Table 4
Westerlund Panel Co-integration Tests Normalized Variable: GINI Index
(Income inequality)
Covariates Gt Gα Pt Pα
Public debt –2.523** –7.992 –12.728*** –7.318***
Institutional quality 1 –2.080** –7.928 –11.238*** –7.526***
Institutional quality 2 –2.315*** –9.377*** –12.332*** –9.584***
Institutional quality 3 –2.371*** –9.326*** –13.408*** –8.422***
Institutional quality 4 –2.069** –7.988 –10.887*** –7.243***
Institutional quality 5 –2.418*** –8.498* –11.852*** –7.952***
Institutional quality 6 –4.342*** –8.914** –10.725*** –5.622*
Economic growth –2.624*** –8.234 –12.766*** –7.907***
Note: ***, **,* note significance level at 1%, 5%, 10% respectively.
Source: Stata software’s processing.
Table 5
Institutional Quality, Public Debt and Income Inequality: PMG Estimates Long
Run Co-integrating Vectors Dependent Variable: GINI Index (income inequality)
Variables IN1 IN2 IN3 IN4 IN5 IN6
*** ** *** ***
Public debt –0.041 –0.045 –0.008 –0.047 –0.271 –0.027
(0.016) (0.020) (0.007) (0.010) (0.050) (0.020)
Institutional quality –1.301* –3.239*** –1.447** –2.892*** –13.38*** –1.327
(0.774) (1.075) (0.687) (0.663) (2.151) (1.262)
Public debt*Ins. quality 0.029* 0.032*** 0.016** 0.024*** 0.002 0.010
(0.016) (0.012) (0.007) (0.007) (0.033) (0.015)
Economic growth 0.042*** 0.020** 0.024** 0.006 0.007 0.043***
(0.011) (0.010) (0.010) (0.007) (0.004) (0.011)
Error correction –0.522*** –0.542*** –0.557*** –0.552*** –0.339*** –0.523***
Observation 540 540 540 540 540 540
Log likelihood –373.453 –375.424 –377.215 –367.568 –416.977 –373.162
Note: ***, **,* note significance level at 1%, 5%, 10% respectively.
Source: Stata software’s processing.
737
The paper shows the results in Table 5. In line with the S-GMM estimates,
public debt and institutional quality narrow income inequality, but their interac-
tion term widens. Furthermore, economic growth enhances income inequality.
The significance level and value of the speed of adjustment at the bottom of
Table 5 report that PMG estimates are highly reliable.
Public spending financed by debt keeps a crucial role in running the economy,
while income inequality is one of the severe problems. Governments in these
economies can use public debt to deal with the income gap in society. In particu-
lar, institutional quality can significantly contribute to the public debt – income
inequality relationship. Given these facts, the paper investigates the impacts of
public debt, institutional quality, and their interaction on income inequality for
a group of 30 advanced economies from 2002 through 2020. It employs the
S-GMM and PMG estimator for estimation and robustness check. The results
show that public debt and institutional quality decrease income inequality, but
their interaction increases it. The main result shows that public debt narrows
income inequality in developed economies and this negative effect is impeded by
institutional quality. Furthermore, economic growth and unemployment widen
income inequality, but education narrows it.
The findings in the paper imply that governments in advanced economies can
use public debt to deal with income inequality in society between the rich and
the poor. They can design, formulate, and implement policies and regulations
(institutional quality) to increase public spending financed by debt to support the
poor and low-income individuals through social transfers. More importantly,
they should spend more on health and education to improve the poor’s skills and
knowledge, which enhances the poor’s income and reduces the income gap in
society. However, they should be prudent in controlling and managing public
debt to avoid a public debt crisis and social instability. Future research should
focus on the contribution of institutional quality to the external/domestic public
debt – income inequality relationship.
Reference
ACEMOGLU, D. – JOHNSON, S. – ROBINSON, J. A. (2001): The Colonial Origins of Com-
parative Development: An Empirical Investigation. American Economic Review, 91, No. 5,
pp. 1369 – 1401. DOI: 10.1257/aer.91.5.1369.
AKSMAN, E. (2017): Do Poverty and Income Inequality Affect Public Debt? Gospodarka
Narodowa. The Polish Journal of Economics, 292, No. 6, pp. 79 – 93.
DOI: 10.33119/GN/100744.
738
APERGIS, N. (2021): The Role of Fiscal Policy in the Link between Income Inequality and Bank-
ing Crises. Applied Economics Letters, 28, No. 15, pp. 1283 – 1287.
DOI: 10.1080/13504851.2020.1808570.
ARAWATARI, R. – ONO, T. (2017): Inequality and Public Debt: A Positive Analysis. Review of
International Economics, 25, No. 5, pp. 1155 – 1173. DOI: 10.1111/roie.12299.
ARELLANO, M. – BOND, S. (1991): Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo
Evidence and An Application To Employment Equations. The Review of Economic Studies,
58, No. 2, pp. 277 – 297. DOI: 10.2307/2297968.
ARELLANO, M. – BOVER, O. (1995): Another Look at the Instrumental Variable Estimation of
Error-components Models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, No. 1, pp. 29 – 51.
DOI: 10.1016/0304-4076(94)01642-D.
ASAMOAH, L. A. (2021): Institutional Quality and Income Inequality in Developing Countries:
A Dynamic Panel Threshold Analysis. Progress in Development Studies, 21, No. 2, pp. 123 – 143.
BIGLAISER, G. – MCGAUVRAN, R. J. (2021): The Effects of Debt Restructurings on Income
Inequality in the Developing World. European Journal of International Relations,
13540661211001425. DOI: 10.1177/14649934211016715.
BORISSOV, K. – KALK, A. (2020): Public Debt, Positional Concerns, and Wealth Inequality.
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 170, February, pp. 96 – 111.
DOI: 10.1016/j.jebo.2019.11.029.
CARRERA, J. – DE LA VEGA, P. (2021): The Impact of Income Inequality on Public Debt. The
Journal of Economic Asymmetries, 24, No. C, e00216. DOI: 10.1016/j.jeca.2021.e00216.
CHATZOUZ, M. (2014): Government Debt and Wealth Inequality: Theory and Insights from
Altruism (No. 77007). Munich, Germany: University Library of Munich.
DANIEL, G. O. – FU, K. – DOLFSMA, W. (2018): Institutional Quality and Economic Develop-
ment in Sub-Saharan Africa: Can Management Effort and Bribes Compensate for Low-quality
Institutions? Journal of Economic Issues, 52, No. 2, pp. 473 – 482.
DOI: 10.1080/00213624.2018.1469920.
DEMIR, A. – PESQUÉ-CELA, V. – ALTUNBAS, Y. – MURINDE, V. (2020): Fintech, Financial
Inclusion and Income Inequality: A Quantile Regression Approach. The European Journal of
Finance, 28, No. 1, pp. 1 – 22. DOI: 10.1080/1351847X.2020.1772335.
DESA, U. (2020): World Social Report 2020: Inequality in a Rapidly Changing World. New York,
NY: Department of Economic and Social Affairs, United Nations.
DUHO, K. C. – AMANKWA, M. O. – MUSAH-SURUGU, J. I. (2020): Determinants and Con-
vergence of Government Effectiveness in Africa and Asia. Public Administration and Policy,
23, No. 2, pp. 199 – 215. DOI: 10.1108/PAP-12-2019-0039.
FARRINGTON, C. (2009): Putting Good Governance into Practice I: the Ibrahim Index of African
Governance. Progress in Development Studies, 9, No. 3, pp. 249 – 255.
DOI: 10.1177/146499340800900305.
GYIMAH-BREMPONG, K. (2002): Corruption, Economic Growth, and Income Inequality in
Africa. Economics of Governance, 3, No. 3, pp. 183 – 209. DOI: 10.1007/s101010200045.
GUPTA, S. – DAVOODI, H. – ALONSO-TERME, R. (2002): Does Corruption Affect Income
Inequality and Poverty? Economics of Governance, 3, No. 1, pp. 23 – 45.
DOI: 10.1007/s101010100039.
HOLTZ-EAKIN, D. – NEWEY, W. – ROSEN, H. S. (1988): Estimating vector Autoregressions
with Panel Data. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 56, No. 6, pp. 1371 – 1395.
DOI: 10.2307/1913103.
JUDSON, R. A. – OWEN, A. L. (1999): Estimating Dynamic Panel Data Models: A Guide for Macro-
economists. Economics Letters, 65, No. 1, pp. 9 – 15. DOI: 10.1016/S0165-1765(99)00130-5.
LAW, S. H. – NASEEM, N. A. M. – LAU, W. T. – TRINUGROHO, I. (2020): Can Innovation
Improve Income Inequality? Evidence from Panel Data. Economic Systems, 44, No. 4, 100815.
DOI: 10.1016/j.ecosys.2020.100815.
739
LEE, C. S. (2005): Income Inequality, Democracy, and Public Sector Size. American Sociological
Review, 70, No. 1, pp. 158 – 181. DOI: 10.1177/000312240507000108.
LI, S. – FILER, L. (2007): The Effects of the Governance Environment on the Choice of Invest-
ment Mode and the Strategic Implications. Journal of World Business, 42, No. 1, pp. 80 – 98.
DOI: 10.1016/j.jwb.2006.11.006.
LUO, W. (2020): Inequality and Government Debt: Evidence from OECD Panel Data. Economics
Letters, 186, January, 108869. DOI: 10.1016/j.econlet.2019.108869.
MAEBAYASHI, N. – KONISHI, K. (2021): Sustainability of Public Debt and Inequality in
a General Equilibrium Model. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 25, No. 4, pp. 874 – 895.
DOI: 10.1017/S1365100519000336.
MARCH, C. – VON WEIZSÄCKER, R. K. (2020): Coordinating Intergenerational Redistribution
and the Repayment of Public Debt: An Experimental Test of Tabellini (1991). Social Choice
and Welfare, 55, February, pp. 301 – 323. DOI: 10.1007/s00355-020-01242-6.
MATALLAH, S. (2019): The Triptych Migration-inward FDI-inequality in South Asian Coun-
tries: How Much Do Governance and Institutions Matter? Migration and Development, 8,
No. 1, pp. 93 – 118. DOI: 10.1080/21632324.2018.1449617.
KRAAY, A. – DOLLAR, D. (2003): Institutions, Trade, and Growth: Revisiting the Evidence.
Journal of Monetary Economics, 50, No. 1, pp. 133 – 162.
KAULIHOWA, T. – ADJASI, C. (2018): FDI and Income Inequality in Africa. Oxford Develop-
ment Studies, 46, No. 2, pp. 250 – 265. DOI: 10.1080/13600818.2017.1381233.
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND (2021a): 2021 Update of the IMF Global Debt Database.
Available at: <https://www.imf.org/en/News/Seminars/Conferences/2021/12/15/2021-update-
of-the-imf-global-debt-
data-
base#:~:text=The%202021%20update%20of%20the,percent%20of%20GDP%20in%202020>.
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND (2021b): Fiscal Monitor Update, January 2021. Availa-
ble at
<https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/FM/Issues/2021/01/20/fiscal-monitor-update-january-
2021>.
OBIERO, W. L. – TOPUZ, S. G. (2021): Do Public and Internal Debt Cause Income Inequality?
Evidence from Kenya. Journal of Economics, Finance and Administrative Science, 27, No. 53,
pp. 124 – 138. DOI: 10.1108/JEFAS-05-2021-0049.
ORTIZ-OSPINA, E. – ROSER, M. (2016): Government Spending. Published online at Our-
WorldInData.org. Available at <https://ourworldindata.org/government-spending>.
PERERA, L. D. H. – LEE, G. H. (2013): Have Economic Growth and Institutional Quality Con-
tributed to Poverty and Inequality Reduction in Asia? Journal of Asian Economics, 27, August,
pp. 71 – 86. DOI: 10.1016/j.asieco.2013.06.002.
PESARAN, M. H. – SHIN, Y. – SMITH, R. P. (1999): Pooled Mean Group Estimation of Dynamic
Heterogeneous Panels. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 94, No. 446, pp. 621 – 634.
RICHMOND, K. – TRIPLETT, R. E. (2018): ICT and Income Inequality: A Cross-national Per-
spective. International Review of Applied Economics, 32, No. 2, pp. 195 – 214.
DOI: 10.1080/02692171.2017.1338677.
RÖHRS, S. – WINTER, C. (2017): Reducing Government Debt in the Presence of Inequality.
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 82, September, pp. 1 – 20.
DOI: 10.1016/j.jedc.2017.05.007.
ROODMAN, D. (2009): How to Do xtabond2: An Introduction to Difference and System GMM in
Stata. The Stata Journal, 9, No. 1, pp. 86 – 136. DOI: 10.1177/1536867X0900900106.
SHAFIQUE, S. – HAQ, R. – ARIF, G. M. (2006): Governance and Income Inequality. The Paki-
stan Development Review, 45, No. 4, pp. 751 – 760.
TAREK, B. A. – AHMED, Z. (2017): Institutional Quality and Public Debt Accumulation: An
Empirical Analysis. International Economic Journal, 31, No. 3, pp. 415 – 435.
DOI: 10.1080/10168737.2017.1354906.
740
TUNG, L. T. (2020): Can Public Debt Harm Social Development? Evidence from the Asian-
Pacific Region. Journal of International Studies, 13, No. 2, pp. 48 – 61.
DOI: 10.14254/2071-8330.2020/13-2/4.
WONG, M. Y. (2017): Public Spending, Corruption, and Income Inequality: A Comparative Analy-
sis of Asia and Latin America. International Political Science Review, 38, No. 3, pp. 298 – 315.
DOI: 10.1177/0192512116642617.
WORLD BANK (2021): Worldwide Governance Indicators. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Available at: <https://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/>.
741
Appendix
Table A
Data Description
Variable Definition Type Source
Income inequality (GIN) Gini index measures the extent to which value World Bank
the distribution of income (or, in some cases,
consumption expenditure) among individuals
or households within an economy deviates
from a perfectly equal distribution.
Public debt (DEB) Gross debt consists of all liabilities that % IMF
require payment or payments of interest and/or
principal by the debtor to the creditor at a date
or dates in the future (% GDP)
Economic growth (GDP) GDP per capita is gross domestic product ln World Bank
divided by midyear population.
Education (EDU) Gross primary school enrollment ratio is the % World Bank
ratio of total enrollment, regardless of age, to
the population of the age group that officially
corresponds to the level of education shown.
Unemployment (UNE) Unemployment refers to the share of the labor % World Bank
force that is without work but available for and
seeking employment.
Regulatory Quality (IN1) “Regulatory Quality captures perceptions of
the ability of the government to formulate and
implement sound policies and regulations that
permit and promote private sector development.”
Rule of Law (IN2) “Rule of Law captures perceptions of the
extent to which agents have confidence in and
abide by the rules of society, and in particular
the quality of contract enforcement, property
rights, the police, and the courts, as well as the
likelihood of crime and violence.”
Voice and Accountability (IN3) “Voice and Accountability captures
perceptions of the extent to which a country’s
citizens are able to participate in selecting
their government, as well as freedom of
expression, freedom of association, and a free
media.”
Control of Corruption (IN4) “Control of Corruption captures perceptions of level World Bank
the extent to which public power is exercised
for private gain, including both petty and
grand forms of corruption, as well as “capture”
of the state by elites and private interests.”
Government Effectiveness (IN5) “Government Effectiveness captures
perceptions of the quality of public services,
the quality of the civil service and the degree
of its independence from political pressures,
the quality of policy formulation and
implementation, and the credibility of the
government's commitment to such policies.”
Political Stability (IN6) “Political Stability and Absence of
Violence/Terrorism measures perceptions
of the likelihood of political instability and/or
politically-motivated violence, including
terrorism.”
Source: Author.
742
Table B
The Matrix of Correlation Coefficients between Variables
GIN DEB GDP EDU UNE
GIN 1
DEB 0.242*** 1
GDP –0.134*** 0.053 1
EDU 0.173*** –0.011 –0.001 1
UNE 0.270*** 0.407*** –0.418*** 0.024 1
*** ** *
Note: , , note significance level at 1%, 5%, 10% respectively.
Source: Author.
Table C
The Matrix of Correlation Coefficients between Six Dimensions of Governance
IN1 IN2 IN3 IN4 IN5 IN6
IN1 1
IN2 0.929*** 1
IN3 0.448*** 0.414*** 1
IN4 0.847*** 0.827*** 0.409*** 1
IN5 0.944*** 0.923*** 0.496*** 0.858*** 1
IN6 0.883*** 0.807*** 0.651*** 0.777*** 0.856*** 1
Note: ***, **,* note significance level at 1%, 5%, 10% respectively.
Source: Author.
Table D
Fisher Type Unit Root Tests
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test Phillips-Perron test
Variables Prob > chi2 Prob > chi2
Without trend With trend Without trend With trend
Income inequality 52.894 42.426 69.221 104.949***
Public debt 59.773 80.610** 26.197 24.853
Institutional quality 1 73.156 56.127 224.666*** 157.362***
Institutional quality 2 96.673*** 65.915 120.871*** 105.612***
Institutional quality 3 95.006*** 66.252 224.916*** 157.084***
Institutional quality 4 61.690 67.764 77.742* 77.599*
Institutional quality 5 57.655 57.367 87.633*** 83.252**
Institutional quality 6 121.610*** 85.124** 114.410*** 103.406***
Economic growth 83.006** 46.863 62.778 27.851
Note: ***, **,* note significance level at 1%, 5%, 10% respectively.
Source: Author.