Lecture 3
Lecture 3
Lecture 3
Additional Issues:
5. Personal Investments
6. Embedded Options
A. The Value of Options at a High Level (More later)
B. Decision Trees (*)
C. Option Adjusted Spread (OAS) (*)
7. P/E Multiples
1
2
Introduction to Uncertainty
So far in this course, we have only concerned ourselves with a world of perfect certainty -- ie, all
cash flows could be projected perfectly. We did this to demonstrate some of the important
concepts regarding NPV analysis -- namely, what cash flows count, how to obtain the discount
rate with the appropriate timing, and how to perform the mathematical operation.
But this is obviously not a realistic assumption -- we live in a world where we can only predict a
range of possible outcomes. Welcome to the world of uncertainty. In this world, we need to
readdress how to obtain the correct cash flows and obtain the proper discount rate; the
mathematical operations, however, remain the same from lecture 2 (except when we get to
options).
Ex: An Investment costs $1000. You know that it will produce a cash flow in two years of either
$2100 or $100 -- each possibility equally likely. You know the appropriate annual discount rate
is 8%. Is this a good investment?
A: Expected Cash flow = .5*2100+.5*100=1100.
NPV = -1000+1100/1.08^2 = -57. So reject project.
In the above case, the discount rate was given. But in the real world, this is not the case.
Determining the proper discount rate to use in the NPV calculation is a big part of the game
when performing DCF analysis under uncertainty.
2
3
At this point, we will add the second of the four major assumptions of the course: Investors
prefer a dollar guaranteed over a dollar in expectation. This aspect of human behavior is called
risk aversion. (Remember that this is due to the diminishing returns of wealth). What it means to
us is that the riskier an investment is, the higher the expected return must be in order to attract
these risk-averse investors. Therefore, the manager of a firm must use a higher discount rate for
projects of greater risk since investors demand more return to compensate them for this added
risk.
The following table shows how risk and return relate for four types of securities:
The risk premium is the additional return above the riskless rate (here the T-bill) required for a
particular investment based on the additional risk associated with it. In this table, the market
seems to demand over 8% in premium to go from short t-bills to stocks and over 7% in premium
for stocks over bonds during this time period. These premia seemed to have held up for many
years but recent data shows a decrease in the risk premium of at least a point – so that many
assume a market risk premium of stocks over bonds of about 6%.
In this course, we will assume that returns from historical events are expected to have a 7-8%
premium but current premia are 6-7%.
3
4
So, when choosing a discount rate for a risky project in our NPV analysis, we need two things:
1) How do we measure the risk of the project
2) How do we numerically translate the risk into a required return number.
These are the jobs of a good Asset Pricing Model (APM). Is there an APM which perfectly
performs these duties? We don't know. So, does that mean we should forget about the whole
thing and just go on to capital structure? NO! The models we have are better than using nothing.
They all capture the kind of risk we care about -- namely, market-wide forces -- and give a
reasonable conversion of risk to return. Even if they are not perfect, they force managers to take
into consideration the important issues.
We will not derive any APMs in this course. Instead, we will merely apply them as formulas for
translating risk into return for our problems. We begin with the most famous one -- CAPM.
From Investments, you learned that the following formula translates risk into return:
Ri = Rf + βi * (Rm-Rf)
where Ri is the required return on the investment, Rf is the riskless rate, βi is the beta of the
investment representing both the volatility of the investment and its correlation to the market,
and Rm-Rf is the risk premium for the market. For our purposes, we can rewrite this equation as:
where β is the measure of risk inherent in the investment. A β of 0 is a riskless project (and
thus Rf is the proper discount rate) and a β of 1 is equally risky as the entire market (and thus
Rm, the market return, is the proper discount rate).
In more intuitive terms, β measures the investment’s sensitivity to the market. E.g., a β of 1
means the investments moves in synch with the market, a β of 0.5 means the investment moves
only half as much as the market and a β of 2 means the investment moves twice as much as the
market, on average. So, an investment with a β of 2 is expected to move twice as much as the
market does at a given time.
NOTE: From the definition of β, we see that an investment which is very volatile but
independent from changes in the market economy -- ie, a correlation of zero to the market -- has
4
5
a β of 0 and therefore is discounted at the riskless rate. This risk is said to be firm-specific or
idiosyncratic and is ignored for the purposes of public corporations where investors can diversify
it away. The only risk that matters for a project which is part of a larger portfolio is its market-
related or undiversifiable or systematic risk.
Example 1: You have a project which costs $1000 and generates an expected cash flow in one
year of $1150. You determine its β to be 1.5. The one year risk-free rate is 3.5%. Assume from
above that the market risk premium is 8.6%. (Always assume this unless you are explicitly told
otherwise. Remember that the risk premium is the difference between the market return and the
risk-free rate.) Should you undertake this project?
A: NPV = -1000+1150/(1+Ri)
Ri = 3.5% + 1.5 * 8.6% = 16.4%
NPV = -12. So reject the project.
(Note that return numbers used are for the future not the past. Whatever has happened last year
is irrelevant in determining proper discount rates. For example, if the market was flat last year,
you do not use a risk premium of 0.)
Example 2: You have a project which costs $1000 and generates an expected cash flow in one
year of $1150. It has a volatility of 30% (much larger than the one above), but is uncorrelated to
the market. Should you take it?
A: NPV = -1000+1150/(1+Ri)
Ri = 3.5% + 0 * 8.6% = 3.5%
NPV = 111. So take it.
5
6
So, the recipe for choosing the risk-adjusted discount rate via CAPM can take one of two forms:
The preferred method is:
• If the risky cash flow comes within one year, use the T-bill rate and plug into CAPM.
• If it arrives later, use the following formula:
R = T-bond rate of same maturity + β * (Market Risk Premium over This Bond)
[AS AN ASIDE:
The alternative described from the text footnote is (only different for the multi-year scenario):
• If the risky cash flow comes within one year, use the T-bill rate and plug into CAPM.
• If it arrives later, use the following formula:
R = (T-bond rate of same maturity – 1) + β * (Market Risk Premium over Short T-Bill)]
6
7
Overall Recipe
I. Cash Flows
A. Determine all relevant cash flows (size and timing)
How does each characteristic of the project effect my economic wealth and when?
B. Take average of each cash flow type for each time period
7
8
EXAMPLE:
An investor is determining whether to rent for a year the Grape Poupon vineyard. Assume the
land is rented in Year 0 and the rent is paid up-front, the wine is produced in Year 1, and then
sold at the end of Year 5. The vineyard is 100 acres and the owner asks $2000 per acre. The
vineyard is expected to yield enough grapes to produce 20,000 bottles of wine. Harvesting costs
in Year 1 are $1000 per acre. Production costs in Year 1 are $3/bottle. Both costs are paid at the
end of year 1. The wine is held in inventory (assume no cost) for four years and is sold in Year
5. In five years the price of this type of wine will be correlated with the state of the economy.
There is a 25% chance the wine can be sold for $20/bottle, a 50% chance it can be sold for
$25/bottle, and a 25% chance that the price in five years will be $50. The of the price of wine
is 0.6. The 3-month T-bill is 3.5%, the one-year Treasury note rate is 5%, and the 5-year T-bond
has a rate of 7.9%. The market price for risk is 7% over T-bonds. Would you rent the vineyard
and produce the wine?
Answer:
First we must determine the cash flows.
Time 0: Pays rent of 2000*100 = 200,000
Year 1: Pays harvesting costs of 1000/acres * 100 = 100,000
Pays production costs of 20000 bottles * 3 = 60,000
Year 5: Earns 20000*(.25*20+.5*25+.25*50) = 600,000
Doing the operation gives negative NPV either way, so don’t do it.
8
9
4 Computing Betas
So far, we have assumed that you knew the beta of a project. This is very rarely given to you
(except for occasional exam and homework problems). In this section, we will discuss how to
obtain the proper beta to be used in the CAPM.
NOTE: Sometimes a time-adjusted, risk-adjusted cost of capital is given to you. If so, this
number is usable as long as it is the risk-adjusted discount rate that your investors will use when
doing DCF analysis.
There are sources available for looking up the beta for a firm.
A "beta book" is supplied by Merrill Lynch and Value Line. Also, the Center for Research in
Security Prices (CRSP) at the University of Chicago calculates an equity beta based on the firm's
historical sensitivity to the market. You can simply look up your firm in one of these books and
pull out the beta of the firm. But there are two problems with this.
1) These books only list total firm betas -- not project betas. Therefore, you want to use a beta
that is most similar to your project at hand as opposed to an entire firm which may be in several
businesses. For example, if your firm is a conglomerate and is interested in expanding in the oil
industry, using your whole firm beta will not give an accurate beta since your firm beta is an
average of each of your project's betas.
2) The correct beta to use is the asset beta -- not an equity beta. That is, we care about the risk
of the project independent of how levered our position in it is. (Remember that at this point in
the course, we are ignoring capital structure.)
We will address each of these problems in order.
9
10
One major problem with the above approach is that the beta figures we've obtained for the
"comps" are equity betas whereas our formula requires an asset beta. We need a mathematical
transformation for computing asset betas from equity betas.
Fortunately, the CAPM tells us that the beta of a combined investment is just the weighted
average of the individual betas (where the beta is weighed by market value). Since the assets of a
firm is just the combination of its debt and equity, we can use the following formula:
βA = D/(D+E) βD + E/(D+E) βE
So, you can see that the beta of equity is not the same as the beta of assets -- which is what we
want. The relationship between the two becomes clearer when rearranging the above expression
as:
βE = βA + D/E (βA-βD)
= (Business Risk) + (Financial Risk)
So, in the case of an unlevered firm (D=0), the equity beta equals the asset beta and perfectly
captures the business risk of the project. However, levered firms (D>0) will have higher betas
for their equity than what is appropriate to perfectly capture the risk of the project. In these
cases, we want to use the equation above to derive the asset beta. This approach is called
"Unlevering Beta".
Since we want the asset beta but only have the equity beta, we need to plug into the equation
above the appropriate values. D and E seem easy enough to get, but the debt beta is not trivially
obtained.
For firms with very little chance of default, an appropriate debt beta is zero. And for the example
we will do below, this is precisely what we are going to assume (as well as for the American
Chemical case). In these cases, the above equation reduces to:
βA = βE E/(D+E)
10
11
In the cases where a firm has risky debt, however, there are basically two methods for obtaining
a debt beta.
1) Back the beta out using the CAPM equation by plugging in the expected return on the bonds.
The problem with this method is that we observe the "promised return" or yield not the expected
return which captures the possibility of default. That is, we want to know the expected return
which uses expected cash flows -- not the yield on the security which uses the maximum cash
flows that the debtholders will receive. To the extent that default probabilities are difficult to
determine, this method becomes quite imprecise.
2) Another equally imprecise but much simpler approach is to use the historical betas associated
with the debt's bond rating. That is, bonds of equal bond rating should, in the mind of the rating
agency responsible, should have similar default probabilities. So, given the bond rating, just look
up the appropriate debt beta from the table below.
11
12
EXAMPLE:
(For the purposes of this example we will assume that debt will not default and that the
appropriate debt beta is 0.)
The magazine National Review is considering a project aligned with its current business. You
are the CFO and are given the expected cash flows projected over time if the project is
undertaken. In order to determine whether the project should be accepted, you need to know the
proper discount rate to use. In turn, you need to know what is a suitable project beta to plug into
the CAPM formula. You remember what you learned in business school and proceed as follows.
The National Review is a bi-weekly magazine that promotes conservative opinion. Since the
magazine is private, obtaining the project beta requires the use of data from other firms. The
best-case scenario is to use a portfolio of publicly-traded firms that focus solely on delivering
intellectual opinion via the magazine outlet. These comparable firms could be considered twins
of National Review. The problem is that such comparables do not exist. So, one must use
broader sources. One excellent source is Value Line Investment Surveys. Their publishing
industry contains 17 firms which include publishers of books, magazines and newspapers, as
well as printing firms and so forth. However, there are only five firms with significant magazine
operations (at least 20% of sales from magazine operations). Table 1 lists these five publicly-
traded firms. All five firms have widely different subscribers. Moreover, each firm has business
units in addition to its magazine operations. The common characteristics across these firms,
however, is their magazine publications. Though the number of firms here is small, other
operations of each firm tend to cancel one another out such that the overall portfolio resembles
that of the magazine industry.
Next, you obtain the listed betas for these 5 "comps". You pull off the betas from Value line as
well as from CRSP. These figures are reported in Table 2. The CRSP and Value line betas are
comfortably close to one another. (Also, notice that the betas are around 1. What does that
mean?)
Next, you know that these numbers are equity betas while you want asset betas. Remembering
the equation above, you obtain the market values of debt and equity for each of the five firms
and choose as the equity beta the average of the Value Line and CRSP numbers. (See Table 3).
You plug these into the "Unlevering Beta" calculation of E/(D+E)* βE giving the asset beta
column in Table 3. Taking a simple average of these five figures gives the resulting asset beta of
0.89.
Now, you can go on to obtain the project discount rate and consequently evaluate the project.
NOTE: You should use the risk measure associated with the project you are investing in -- not
necessarily the risk measure for your firm.
12
13
TABLE 1
Firm Description
------------------------------ -------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Reader’s Digest Assoc. Publisher of magazine and books and markets home entertainment
products. Reader’s Digest accounts for more than 25% of sales.
Source: Value Line Investment Survey (December 3, 1993). McGraw-Hill, Meredith, Playboy
Enterprises and Reader’s Digest Association are in Value Line’s publishing industry; Time-
Warner is in the entertainment industry.
13
14
TABLE 2
Notes: Value Line betas come from the December 3, 1993 issue. The CRSP betas are based on
a regression analysis of each stock’s monthly return on the value-weighted index of all NYSE,
AMEX, and NASDAQ stocks. The CRSP betas are calculated using the 60 months of stock
return history over the 1988-1992 period. Stock price data for Reader’s Digest Assoc. is
available for only 38 months during this period.
14
15
TABLE 3
Notes: Equity beta for each firm is the average of the Value Line and CRSP betas from Table 7.
Debt and equity figures come from Standard & Poor’s Compustat service. Asset betas are
calculated using the asset beta equation described in the text.
15
16
There are certain situations where deviation from this Valuation approach is accepted.
5 Personal Investments
Our APM approach only applies to cases where the cash flows of the project can be combined in
a large portfolio of well-diversified investments. In the case of private projects which can not be
placed in a diversified portfolio, the investor must use a personal discount rate which captures
her/his distaste for risk. Here, introspection is required and the Fisher separation theorem no
longer holds. But fortunately, for most corporations, the above methodology works well.
HIGHLIGHT:
Can the theory of how to price financial options improve the way bosses invest
their companies' money?
BODY:
TALK to a company boss about financial options and he might smile at the
prospect of exercising his generously priced share-options. Or shudder, maybe,
at the reminder of the firm's incomprehensible hedging strategy. He will
almost certainly not think about his recent decision to build a new widget
factory, or to postpone the launch of the exciting new fax-cum-roller-blade
that marketing says customers are baying for.
He should, however. For when he took those decisions, he probably obeyed the
rules of financial-options pricing theory. Or so says a new book * by two
economists, Avinash Dixit of Princeton University and Robert Pindyck of the
Massachusetts Institute of Technology's Sloan School. In it, they attempt to
integrate options theory and the traditional model of how firms decide where
to direct their investment. Their merged theory, they say, better explains
what really goes on inside firms, and clears up some real-world riddles the
old approach left unsolved.
At business schools, managers learn to calculate the "net present value" (NPV)
of a mooted investment. They forecast future profits, then discount them using
a "discount rate" to reflect the higher value that money has today than in the
future (usually the interest rate on government bonds plus a bit to offset the
riskiness of the investment). That gives the present value of future profits.
If this number is bigger than the present value of the costs of investing in
the project -- that is, the NPV is positive -- then go ahead, says orthodox
theory. Otherwise, think again.
16
17
opportunities. More often, in an uncertain world, it offers a valuable chance
to learn more about the likely fate of the project.
It follows, then, that the cost of that killed option (the value of waiting
for better information) ought to be included when calculating NPV. Before a
project goes ahead, the present value of profits should exceed the investment
costs by at least the value of keeping the option alive.
In the money
In fact, that is what usually happens in practice. Most bosses do their basic
NPV sums, but add in a margin to help them feel comfortable. For instance,
they may discount predicted profits using a "hurdle" required rate of return
that is often two or three times the standard discount rate. Applying options-
pricing theory to a big sample of typical business projects, the two
economists found that such hurdle rates are perfectly sensible. However, the
new "real options" theory allows bosses to set them on a more rational basis
than gut instinct.
The theory also explains why firms often respond slowly to changes in tax,
interest rates or demand -- all of which, orthodox theory suggests, should
elicit an instant response. Bosses are more interested in changes in
uncertainty. Consider, for illustration, a government that cuts interest rates
and taxes to boost investment, but as a result sows the seeds of longer-term
economic troubles. It may actually increase uncertainty and cause firms to
invest less.
The theory will be most useful in areas where the uncertainties are relatively
apparent. The sums are already being churned over in the computers of some oil
firms, for instance. There is one main risk in developing an oil field -- a
17
18
change in the oil price. Property developers, electric utilities and drugs
companies are also investigating how to apply the theory in practice. It may
work less well in, say, judging whether to invest in finding a cure for
cancer, or in evaluating strategic decisions where long-term goals matter more
than financial results.
Even so, the theory is likely to prove a big advance on the old NPV method.
Though its aim is to improve company decision-making by showing how bosses can
learn from financial markets, it can also help people in financial markets to
understand firms better. Projects that a firm has not yet invested in may be
at least as valuable to it as the ones that are going ahead -- especially in a
volatile market. Might bosses boost their firms' share price by telling
analysts about all the lucrative things they are not doing?
18
19
Heard on the Street
06/01/1994
The Wall Street Journal
PAGE C2
But it's not high-brow business that has fans excited about
American Greetings stock. It's the grass-roots popularity of
American Greetings cards at places like Wal-Mart and Walgreen.
That's where the growth is, says Frederic E. Russell, a Tulsa,
Okla., money manager who owns more than 50,000 shares.
Yet the company's growth appears better than average. Wall Street
looks for earnings to rise to about $2.02 a share in the current
fiscal year, which ends in February 1995, from $1.54 in the past
fiscal year. Next year, analysts expect earnings of $2.26 a
share.
Mr. Russell says the Big Three of the card industry -- Hallmark,
American Greetings and Gibson Greetings -- control more than 90%
of the market. All three are doing well, as time-pressed
Americans turn to cards to get their messages across.
The stock is down about 18% from the peak of 34 1/4 it reached in
19
20
December. One reason: Doubts about the profit potential of the
company's new CreataCard kiosks.
American Greetings has sprinkled the country with some 8,000 such
kiosks, where customers can prepare customized cards for friends
or loved ones. "They've preempted everyone by being the first out
there," says Jeffrey S. Stein, analyst with McDonald & Co., who
speaks for the bulls. But bears argue that the kiosks don't seem
to be catching on enough to boost profits much.
Even if the kiosks were to bomb, Mr. Murphy thinks the company
can show solid, steady 12% earnings growth. If the kiosks are a
success, he sees growth at 14% to 15%. The stock in his opinion
is worth at least 34, and as much as 40 if CreataCard works out
well.
"The company keeps punching out 15% earnings gains," says Edward
Cimilucca, director of research at J.W. Seligman, a New York
money-management firm. The greeting-card field, he says, is "a
very nice business," and CreataCard is "an authentic new product"
that should contribute to profits before long.
Mr. Cimilucca likes the way American Greetings has reduced debt
and improved its profit margins. Debt is below $100 million now,
down from about $250 million two years ago, while operating
margins should exceed 13% of sales this year, compared with about
12% last fiscal year, he says.
What could go wrong? One threat would be a price war, like the
one that raged through the industry in the late 1980s.
But those dangers don't appear major. For now, the tide seems to
be going American Greetings ' way, as more card shoppers turn to
mass merchandise outlets. That should buoy American Greetings at
the expense of rival Hallmark, which depends primarily on its own
specialty card shops, says Rudy Hokanson, an analyst with C.J.
Lawrence/Deutsche Bank Securities Corp.
20
21
Common shares outstanding: 74 million
*includes $17.2 million charge from accounting change
21
22
22