Reading (Ch.1)
Reading (Ch.1)
Reading (Ch.1)
1
The Science of Macroeconomics
The whole of science is nothing more than the refinement of everyday thinking.
—Albert Einstein
W
hy have some countries experienced rapid growth in incomes over
the past century while others stay mired in poverty? Why do some
countries have high rates of inflation while others maintain stable
prices? Why do all countries experience recessions and depressions—recurrent
periods of falling incomes and rising unemployment—and how can government
policy reduce the frequency and severity of these episodes? Macroeconomics,
the study of the economy as a whole, attempts to answer these and many relat-
ed questions.
To appreciate the importance of macroeconomics, you need only read the
newspaper or listen to the news. Every day you can see headlines such as
INCOME GROWTH REBOUNDS, FED MOVES TO COMBAT INFLA-
TION, or STOCKS FALL AMID RECESSION FEARS. These macroeconomic
events may seem abstract, but they touch all of our lives. Business executives fore-
casting the demand for their products must guess how fast consumers’ incomes
will grow. Senior citizens living on fixed incomes wonder how fast prices will
rise. Recent college graduates looking for jobs hope that the economy will boom
and that firms will be hiring.
Because the state of the economy affects everyone, macroeconomic issues play
a central role in national political debates.Voters are aware of how the economy
is doing, and they know that government policy can affect the economy in pow-
erful ways. As a result, the popularity of the incumbent president often rises
when the economy is doing well and falls when it is doing poorly.
Macroeconomic issues are also central to world politics, and if you read the
international news, you will quickly start thinking about macroeconomic ques-
tions. Was it a good move for much of Europe to adopt a common currency?
Should China maintain a fixed exchange rate against the U.S. dollar? Why is the
United States running large trade deficits? How can poor nations raise their
standard of living? When world leaders meet, these topics are often high on
their agenda.
3
4| PART I Introduction
Although the job of making economic policy belongs to world leaders, the
job of explaining the workings of the economy as a whole falls to macroecono-
mists. Toward this end, macroeconomists collect data on incomes, prices, unem-
ployment, and many other variables from different time periods and different
countries. They then attempt to formulate general theories to explain these data.
Like astronomers studying the evolution of stars or biologists studying the evo-
lution of species, macroeconomists cannot conduct controlled experiments in a
laboratory. Instead, they must make use of the data that history gives them.
Macroeconomists observe that economies differ across countries and that they
change over time. These observations provide both the motivation for develop-
ing macroeconomic theories and the data for testing them.
To be sure, macroeconomics is a young and imperfect science. The macroecon-
omist’s ability to predict the future course of economic events is no better than the
meteorologist’s ability to predict next month’s weather. But, as you will see, macro-
economists know quite a lot about how economies work. This knowledge is use-
ful both for explaining economic events and for formulating economic policy.
Every era has its own economic problems. In the 1970s, Presidents Richard
Nixon, Gerald Ford, and Jimmy Carter all wrestled in vain with a rising rate of
inflation. In the 1980s, inflation subsided, but Presidents Ronald Reagan and
George Bush presided over large federal budget deficits. In the 1990s, with Pres-
ident Bill Clinton in the Oval Office, the economy and stock market enjoyed a
remarkable boom, and the federal budget turned from deficit to surplus. But as
Clinton left office, the stock market was in retreat, and the economy was heading
into recession. In 2001 President George W. Bush reduced taxes to help end the
recession, but the tax cuts also contributed to a reemergence of budget deficits.
President Barack Obama moved into the White House in 2009 in a period of
heightened economic turbulence. The economy was reeling from a financial crisis,
driven by a large drop in housing prices and a steep rise in mortgage defaults. The
crisis was spreading to other sectors and pushing the overall economy into anoth-
er recession.The magnitude of the downturn was uncertain as this book was going
to press, but some observers feared the recession might be deep. In some minds, the
financial crisis raised the specter of the Great Depression of the 1930s, when in its
worst year one out of four Americans who wanted to work could not find a job.
In 2008 and 2009, officials in the Treasury, Federal Reserve, and other parts of gov-
ernment were acting vigorously to prevent a recurrence of that outcome.
Macroeconomic history is not a simple story, but it provides a rich motivation
for macroeconomic theory.While the basic principles of macroeconomics do not
change from decade to decade, the macroeconomist must apply these principles
with flexibility and creativity to meet changing circumstances.
CASE STUDY
The Historical Performance of the U.S. Economy
Economists use many types of data to measure the performance of an econo-
my. Three macroeconomic variables are especially important: real gross domes-
tic product (GDP), the inflation rate, and the unemployment rate. Real GDP
CHAPTER 1 The Science of Macroeconomics | 5
measures the total income of everyone in the economy (adjusted for the level
of prices). The inflation rate measures how fast prices are rising. The unem-
ployment rate measures the fraction of the labor force that is out of work.
Macroeconomists study how these variables are determined, why they change
over time, and how they interact with one another.
Figure 1-1 shows real GDP per person in the United States. Two aspects of
this figure are noteworthy. First, real GDP grows over time. Real GDP per per-
son today is about eight times higher than it was in 1900. This growth in aver-
age income allows us to enjoy a much higher standard of living than our
great-grandparents did. Second, although real GDP rises in most years, this
growth is not steady. There are repeated periods during which real GDP falls,
the most dramatic instance being the early 1930s. Such periods are called
recessions if they are mild and depressions if they are more severe. Not sur-
prisingly, periods of declining income are associated with substantial econom-
ic hardship.
FIGURE 1-1
Real GDP per person First oil price shock
(2000 dollars) World Great World Korean Vietnam
40,000 Second oil price shock
War I Depression War II War War
32,000
9/11
16,000 terrorist
attack
8,000
4,000
1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
Year
Real GDP per Person in the U.S. Economy Real GDP measures the total
income of everyone in the economy, and real GDP per person measures the
income of the average person in the economy. This figure shows that real
GDP per person tends to grow over time and that this normal growth is
sometimes interrupted by periods of declining income, called recessions
or depressions.
Note: Real GDP is plotted here on a logarithmic scale. On such a scale, equal distances on
the vertical axis represent equal percentage changes. Thus, the distance between $4,000 and
$8,000 (a 100 percent change) is the same as the distance between $8,000 and $16,000
(a 100 percent change).
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce and Economic History Services.
6| PART I Introduction
FIGURE 1-2
Percent
20
Inflation 15
9/11
10 terrorist
attack
5
−5
Deflation −10
−15
−20
1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
Year
The Inflation Rate in the U.S. Economy The inflation rate measures the percent-
age change in the average level of prices from the year before. When the inflation
rate is above zero, prices are rising. When it is below zero, prices are falling. If the
inflation rate declines but remains positive, prices are rising but at a slower rate.
Note: The inflation rate is measured here using the GDP deflator.
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce and Economic History Services.
Figure 1-2 shows the U.S. inflation rate.You can see that inflation varies substan-
tially over time. In the first half of the twentieth century, the inflation rate averaged
only slightly above zero. Periods of falling prices, called deflation, were almost as
common as periods of rising prices. By contrast, inflation has been the norm dur-
ing the past half century. Inflation became most severe during the late 1970s, when
prices rose at a rate of almost 10 percent per year. In recent years, the inflation rate
has been about 2 or 3 percent per year, indicating that prices have been fairly stable.
Figure 1-3 shows the U.S. unemployment rate. Notice that there is always
some unemployment in the economy. In addition, although the unemployment
rate has no long-term trend, it varies substantially from year to year. Recessions
and depressions are associated with unusually high unemployment. The highest
rates of unemployment were reached during the Great Depression of the 1930s.
These three figures offer a glimpse at the history of the U.S. economy. In the
chapters that follow, we first discuss how these variables are measured and then
develop theories to explain how they behave. ■
CHAPTER 1 The Science of Macroeconomics | 7
FIGURE 1-3
Percent unemployed
World Great World Korean Vietnam First oil price shock
War I Depression War II War War Second oil price shock
25
20
9/11
terrorist
attack
15
10
0
1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
Year
The Unemployment Rate in the U.S. Economy The unemployment rate measures
the percentage of people in the labor force who do not have jobs. This figure shows
that the economy always has some unemployment and that the amount fluctuates
from year to year.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor and U.S. Bureau of the Census (Historical Statistics of the United States:
Colonial Times to 1970).
learns a lot from them nonetheless. The model illustrates the essence of the real
object it is designed to resemble. (In addition, for many children, building
models is fun.)
Economists also use models to understand the world, but an economist’s
model is more likely to be made of symbols and equations than plastic and
glue. Economists build their “toy economies” to help explain economic vari-
ables, such as GDP, inflation, and unemployment. Economic models illustrate,
often in mathematical terms, the relationships among the variables. Models
are useful because they help us to dispense with irrelevant details and to focus
on underlying connections. (In addition, for many economists, building mod-
els is fun.)
Models have two kinds of variables: endogenous variables and exogenous vari-
ables. Endogenous variables are those variables that a model tries to explain.
Exogenous variables are those variables that a model takes as given. The pur-
pose of a model is to show how the exogenous variables affect the endogenous
variables. In other words, as Figure 1-4 illustrates, exogenous variables come from
outside the model and serve as the model’s input, whereas endogenous variables
are determined within the model and are the model’s output.
FIGURE 1-4
How Models Work Models are simplified theories that show the key
relationships among economic variables. The exogenous variables are
those that come from outside the model. The endogenous variables are
those that the model explains. The model shows how changes in the
exogenous variables affect the endogenous variables.
To make these ideas more concrete, let’s review the most celebrated of all eco-
nomic models—the model of supply and demand. Imagine that an economist
wanted to figure out what factors influence the price of pizza and the quantity
of pizza sold. He or she would develop a model that described the behavior of
pizza buyers, the behavior of pizza sellers, and their interaction in the market for
pizza. For example, the economist supposes that the quantity of pizza demanded
by consumers Q d depends on the price of pizza P and on aggregate income Y.
This relationship is expressed in the equation
Qd = D(P, Y ),
where D( ) represents the demand function. Similarly, the economist supposes
that the quantity of pizza supplied by pizzerias Q s depends on the price of pizza P
CHAPTER 1 The Science of Macroeconomics | 9
and on the price of materials Pm, such as cheese, tomatoes, flour, and anchovies.
This relationship is expressed as
Q s = S(P, Pm ),
where S( ) represents the supply function. Finally, the economist assumes that the
price of pizza adjusts to bring the quantity supplied and quantity demanded into
balance:
Q s = Q d.
These three equations compose a model of the market for pizza.
The economist illustrates the model with a supply-and-demand diagram, as in
Figure 1-5. The demand curve shows the relationship between the quantity of
pizza demanded and the price of pizza, holding aggregate income constant. The
demand curve slopes downward because a higher price of pizza encourages con-
sumers to switch to other foods and buy less pizza. The supply curve shows the
relationship between the quantity of pizza supplied and the price of pizza, holding
the price of materials constant. The supply curve slopes upward because a higher
price of pizza makes selling pizza more profitable, which encourages pizzerias to
produce more of it. The equilibrium for the market is the price and quantity at
which the supply and demand curves intersect. At the equilibrium price, con-
sumers choose to buy the amount of pizza that pizzerias choose to produce.
This model of the pizza market has two exogenous variables and two endoge-
nous variables. The exogenous variables are aggregate income and the price of
FIGURE 1-5
materials. The model does not attempt to explain them but instead takes them as
given (perhaps to be explained by another model). The endogenous variables are
the price of pizza and the quantity of pizza exchanged. These are the variables
that the model attempts to explain.
The model can be used to show how a change in one of the exogenous vari-
ables affects both endogenous variables. For example, if aggregate income
increases, then the demand for pizza increases, as in panel (a) of Figure 1-6. The
model shows that both the equilibrium price and the equilibrium quantity of
pizza rise. Similarly, if the price of materials increases, then the supply of pizza
decreases, as in panel (b) of Figure 1-6. The model shows that in this case the
FIGURE 1-6
P1
Q2 Q1 Quantity of pizza, Q
CHAPTER 1 The Science of Macroeconomics | 11
equilibrium price of pizza rises and the equilibrium quantity of pizza falls. Thus,
the model shows how changes either in aggregate income or in the price of
materials affect price and quantity in the market for pizza.
Like all models, this model of the pizza market makes simplifying assumptions.
The model does not take into account, for example, that every pizzeria is in a
different location. For each customer, one pizzeria is more convenient than the
others, and thus pizzerias have some ability to set their own prices. The model
assumes that there is a single price for pizza, but in fact there could be a differ-
ent price at every pizzeria.
How should we react to the model’s lack of realism? Should we discard the
simple model of pizza supply and demand? Should we attempt to build a more
complex model that allows for diverse pizza prices? The answers to these ques-
tions depend on our purpose. If our goal is to explain how the price of cheese
affects the average price of pizza and the amount of pizza sold, then the diversi-
ty of pizza prices is probably not important. The simple model of the pizza mar-
ket does a good job of addressing that issue. Yet if our goal is to explain why
towns with ten pizzerias have lower pizza prices than towns with two, the sim-
ple model is less useful.
their newsstand prices only every three or four years. Although market-clearing
models assume that all wages and prices are flexible, in the real world some
wages and prices are sticky.
The apparent stickiness of prices does not make market-clearing models use-
less. After all, prices are not stuck forever; eventually, they adjust to changes in
supply and demand. Market-clearing models might not describe the economy at
every instant, but they do describe the equilibrium toward which the economy
gravitates. Therefore, most macroeconomists believe that price flexibility is a
good assumption for studying long-run issues, such as the growth in real GDP
that we observe from decade to decade.
For studying short-run issues, such as year-to-year fluctuations in real GDP
and unemployment, the assumption of price flexibility is less plausible. Over
short periods, many prices in the economy are fixed at predetermined levels.
Therefore, most macroeconomists believe that price stickiness is a better assump-
tion for studying the short-run behavior of the economy.
Nobel Macroeconomists
The winner of the Nobel Prize in economics is ing an infinite discounted sum of one-period util-
announced every October. Many winners have ities, but you couldn’t prove it by me. To me it
been macroeconomists whose work we study in felt as if I were saying to myself: ‘What the hell.’”
this book. Here are a few of them, along with Robert Lucas (Nobel 1995): “In public school sci-
some of their own words about how they chose ence was an unending and not very well organized
their field of study: list of things other people had discovered long ago.
Milton Friedman (Nobel 1976): “I graduated from In college, I learned something about the process
college in 1932, when the United States was at the of scientific discovery, but what I learned did not
bottom of the deepest depression in its history attract me as a career possibility. . . . What I liked
before or since. The dominant problem of the time thinking about were politics and social issues.”
was economics. How to get out of the depression? George Akerlof (Nobel 2001): “When I went to
How to reduce unemployment? What explained the Yale, I was convinced that I wanted to be either an
paradox of great need on the one hand and unused economist or an historian. Really, for me it was a
resources on the other? Under the circumstances, distinction without a difference. If I was going to
becoming an economist seemed more relevant to be an historian, then I would be an economic his-
the burning issues of the day than becoming an torian. And if I was to be an economist I would
applied mathematician or an actuary.” consider history as the basis for my economics.”
James Tobin (Nobel 1981): “I was attracted to Edward Prescott (Nobel 2004): “Through discus-
the field for two reasons. One was that economic sion with [my father], I learned a lot about the way
FYI
theory is a fascinating intellectual challenge, on the businesses operated. This was one reason why I
order of mathematics or chess. I liked analytics and liked my microeconomics course so much in my
logical argument. . . . The other reason was the first year at Swarthmore College. The price theory
obvious relevance of economics to understanding that I learned in that course rationalized what I
and perhaps overcoming the Great Depression.” had learned from him about the way businesses
Franco Modigliani (Nobel 1985): “For awhile it was operate. The other reason was the textbook used
thought that I should study medicine because my in that course, Paul A. Samuelson’s Principles of Eco-
father was a physician. . . . I went to the registration nomics. I loved the way Samuelson laid out the the-
window to sign up for medicine, but then I closed ory in his textbook, so simply and clearly.”
my eyes and thought of blood! I got pale just think- Edmund Phelps (Nobel 2006): “Like most Ameri-
ing about blood and decided under those condi- cans entering college, I started at Amherst College
tions I had better keep away from medicine. . . . without a predetermined course of study or without
Casting about for something to do, I happened to even a career goal. My tacit assumption was that I
get into some economics activities. I knew some would drift into the world of business—of money,
German and was asked to translate from German doing something terribly smart. In the first year,
into Italian some articles for one of the trade associ- though, I was awestruck by Plato, Hume and James.
ations. Thus I began to be exposed to the economic I would probably have gone into philosophy were it
problems that were in the German literature.” not that my father cajoled and pleaded with me to
Robert Solow (Nobel 1987): “I came back [to try a course in economics, which I did the second
college after being in the army] and, almost with- year. . . . I was hugely impressed to see that it was
out thinking about it, signed up to finish my possible to subject the events in those newspapers I
undergraduate degree as an economics major. had read about to a formal sort of analysis.”
The time was such that I had to make a decision If you want to learn more about the Nobel
in a hurry. No doubt I acted as if I were maximiz- Prize and its winners, go to www.nobelprize.org.1
1 The first five quotations are from William Breit and Barry T. Hirsch, eds., Lives of the Laureates,
4th ed. (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2004). The next two are from the Nobel Web site. The last
one is from Arnold Heertje, ed., The Makers of Modern Economics, Vol. II (Aldershot, U.K.: Edward
Elgar Publishing, 1995).
CHAPTER 1 The Science of Macroeconomics | 15
Summary
1. Macroeconomics is the study of the economy as a whole, including growth
in incomes, changes in prices, and the rate of unemployment. Macroecono-
mists attempt both to explain economic events and to devise policies to
improve economic performance.
2. To understand the economy, economists use models—theories that simplify
reality in order to reveal how exogenous variables influence endogenous
variables. The art in the science of economics is in judging whether a
16 | PART I Introduction
K E Y C O N C E P T S
Q U E S T I O N S F O R R E V I E W
P R O B L E M S A N D A P P L I C AT I O N S
1. What macroeconomic issues have been in the affect the price of ice cream and the quantity of
news lately? ice cream sold. In your explanation, identify the
2. What do you think are the defining characteris- exogenous and endogenous variables.
tics of a science? Does the study of the economy 4. How often does the price you pay for a haircut
have these characteristics? Do you think macro- change? What does your answer imply about the
economics should be called a science? Why or usefulness of market-clearing models for analyz-
why not? ing the market for haircuts?
3. Use the model of supply and demand to explain
how a fall in the price of frozen yogurt would