Gower Davies Principles of Modern Company Law.
Gower Davies Principles of Modern Company Law.
Gower Davies Principles of Modern Company Law.
In addition to the general updating which a book of this scope requires for
a new edition, there have been three drivers of change in the corporate law
area since the ninth edition of 2012. First, the Supreme Court has
continued to be active in the area of core corporate law, unusually so by
historical standards. Even the old chestnut, piercing the veil, has given the
Justices something to chew on in VTB Capital Plc v Nutritek International
Corp [2013] UKSC 5 and Petrodel Resources Ltd v Prest [2013] UKSC
34. These decisions confirm the limited scope of that doctrine in English
law, whilst demonstrating the availability of alternative techniques for
handling the underlying problem. Re-assertion of orthodoxy was also the
main thrust of Eclairs Group Ltd v JKX Oil and Gas Plc [2015] UKSC 71
on directors’ use of powers for an improper purpose, though dicta in the
case generate some uncertainties for the future. The Supreme Court’s latest
and perhaps conclusive statement on the availability of proprietary
remedies for breach of fiduciary duty is to be found in FHR European
Ventures LLP v Mankarious (No.2) [2014] UKSC 45. Finally, in Bilta
(UK) Ltd v Nazir [2015] UKSC 23 the Court began the process of bringing
order out of the chaos left by its previous decision in Stone & Rolls Ltd v
Moore Stephens [2009] UKSC 39 concerning the availability of the
illegality defence where the company has been used as a vehicle for fraud
by its only directors and shareholders.
On the domestic legislative front, life has been quiet since the passing of
the Companies Act 2006, but the Small Business, Enterprise and
Employment Act 2015 has had a significant impact in some particular
areas of company law, despite the lack of any explicit reference to
companies in the title. The requirement for the revelation of controlling
positions in all companies aims to make it less easy for companies to be
used to hide criminal or otherwise objectionable activities. One might say
that this is using the law in an attempt to limit the ‘negative externalities’
of the corporate form. It is thus quite different from the beneficial
ownership disclosures long required (and at a much lower level) in relation
publicly traded companies, which are motivated by more traditional
company and market concerns. Consequently, we deal with the new
disclosure rules in Ch.2, whilst leaving the established ‘major
shareholdings’ rules in Ch.26. In addition, the 2015 Act underlines
government’s view that the promotion of small businesses and enterprise
requires enhanced creditor protection in relation to limited companies, in
this case through reforms both to the procedures for disqualifying directors
(Ch.10) and to those for recovering compensation from directors who
engage in wrongful trading (Ch.9). Legislative reversal of the courts’ (at
least initial) unwillingness to apply directors’ duties to shadow directors
goes in the same direction.
Finally, the shape of the substantive reforms resulting from the financial
crisis of 2007–9, which were inchoate at the time of the previous edition,
have now become clearer. Not surprisingly, given the nature of the crisis,
the reforms have focussed on banks and other financial institutions rather
than on companies across the board. Nevertheless, the reform of financial
markets has had an impact on the rules governing access by companies to
the capital markets and their obligations once admitted, as discussed in
Part 6 of the book. This is an area where EU law frequently takes the lead
and a significant change here has been the Community’s increasing use of
Regulations, rather than Directives, to effect the reforms, with a
consequent change in the balance between EU and domestic rules in
implementing the changes. At the time of writing the future shape of this
body of rules is subject to considerable political uncertainty.
We would like to thank very warmly Professor Eva Micheler of the
London School of Economics and Political Science for updating Ch.27 on
Transfer of Shares, for which she has taken responsibility over a number
of editions.
Sarah Worthington would like to thank Michael Lok for his significant
research assistance in the updating of particular parts of this edition; that
he managed to provide this help while also conducting an increasingly
busy and successful practice in Hong Kong is testament to his energy and
organisation.
We have sought to state the law as at the end of February 2016,
although some references to later material have been possible.
PLD, SEW
June 2016
Table of Abbreviations
PAGE
Preface v
Table of Abbreviations vii
Table of Cases xxxix
Table of Statutes xciii
Table of Statutory Instruments cxxi
Table of European Material cxxvii
Table of Takeovers Code cxxxv
PARA
PART 1
Introductory
PART 2
Separate Legal Personality and Limited Liability
7. CORPORATE ACTIONS
INTRODUCTION 7–1
CONTRACTUAL RIGHTS AND LIABILITIES 7–4
Contracting through the board or the 7–5
shareholders collectively
Constructive notice and the rule in 7–6
Turquand’s case
Statutory protection for third parties 7–9
dealing with the board
(a) “In favour of a person dealing 7–10
with a company in good faith”
(b) “Dealing with a company” 7–11
(c) Persons 7–12
(d) The directors 7–13
(e) Any limitation under the 7–14
company’s constitution
(f) The internal effects of lack of 7–15
authority
Contracting through agents 7–16
Agency principles 7–18
Establishing the ostensible authority 7–20
of corporate agents
Knowledge 7–24
Knowledge of the constitution as an 7–26
aid to third parties?
Ratification 7–27
Overall 7–28
The ultra vires doctrine and the 7–29
objects clause
TORT AND CRIME 7–30
Tortious liability
Vicarious liability 7–31
Assumption of responsibility 7–32
Fraud 7–33
Recovery by the company from the 7–34
agent
Liability of non-involved directors 7–35
Accessory liability 7–36
Direct liability 7–37
Criminal liability 7–38
Regulatory offences 7–39
Identification 7–40
Beyond “directing mind and will” 7–41
Criminal liability of directors 7–42
Corporate manslaughter 7–43
Sanctions 7–44
Personal liability under the 2007 7–45
Act
Failure to prevent criminal acts 7–46
Litigation by the company 7–47
CONCLUSION 7–48
8. LIMITED LIABILITY AND
LIFTING THE VEIL
THE RATIONALE FOR LIMITED LIABILITY 8–1
LEGAL RESPONSES TO LIMITED LIABILITY 8–5
Disclosure of information 8–6
LIFTING THE VEIL 8–7
Under statute or contract 8–8
At common law 8–10
The “single economic unit” 8–11
argument
Façade or sham 8–12
The agency and trust arguments 8–13
The interests of justice 8–14
Impropriety 8–15
CONCLUSION 8–17
9. PERSONAL LIABILITY FOR
ABUSES OF LIMITED LIABILITY
PREMATURE TRADING 9–3
FRAUDULENT AND WRONGFUL TRADING 9–4
Civil liability for fraudulent trading 9–5
Wrongful trading 9–6
Shadow directors 9–7
The declaration 9–8
Impact of the wrongful trading 9–9
provisions
PART 3
Corporate Governance: The Board and Shareholders
CONCLUSION 14–81
15. SHAREHOLDER DECISION-
MAKING
THE ROLE OF THE SHAREHOLDERS 15–1
SHAREHOLDER DECISION-MAKING
WITHOUT SHAREHOLDER MEETINGS
The nature of the problem 15–6
Written resolutions 15–8
Where written resolutions not 15–10
available
The procedure for passing written 15–11
resolutions
Written resolutions proposed by 15–13
members
Wider written resolution provisions 15–14
under the articles
Unanimous consent at common law 15–15
IMPROVING SHAREHOLDER PARTICIPATION
Analyses of shareholder participation 15–22
The role of institutional investors 15–25
Conflicts of interest and inactivity 15–27
“Fiduciary investors” 15–29
The UK Stewardship Code 15–30
The role of indirect investors 15–31
Governance rights—voluntary 15–34
transfer arrangements for all
companies
Information rights—mandatory 15–40
transfer options in traded
companies
THE MECHANICS OF MEETINGS 15–42
What happens at meetings? 15–43
Types of resolution 15–44
Wording and notice of proposed 15–47
resolutions
Convening a meeting of the 15–48
shareholders
Annual general meetings 15–49
Other general meetings 15–51
Meetings convened by the court 15–53
What is a meeting? 15–55
Getting items onto the agenda and 15–56
expressing views on agenda items
Placing an item on the agenda 15–57
Circulation of members’ statements 15–59
Notice of meetings and information 15–60
about the agenda
Length of notice 15–61
Special notice 15–63
The contents of the notice of the 15–65
meeting and circulars
Communicating notice of the 15–66
meeting to the members
Attending the meeting
Proxies 15–67
Corporations’ representatives 15–72
Voting and verification of votes
Voting as a governance issue 15–73
Votes on a show of hands and polls 15–75
Verifying votes 15–76
Establishing who is entitled to vote 15–77
Publicity for votes and resolutions 15–78
“Empty” voting 15–81
Miscellaneous matters
Chairman 15–82
Adjournments 15–83
Class meetings 15–84
Forms of communication by the 15–85
company
Forms of communication to the 15–86
company
CONCLUSION 15–87
16. DIRECTORS’ DUTIES
INTRODUCTION 16–1
TO WHOM AND BY WHOM ARE THE DUTIES
OWED?
To whom are the general duties owed
and who can sue for their breach?
The company 16–4
Individual shareholders 16–5
Other stakeholders 16–7
By whom are the general duties
owed?
De facto and shadow directors 16–8
Senior managers 16–11
Former directors 16–13
Directors of insolvent companies 16–14
DIRECTORS’ DUTIES OF SKILL, CARE AND
DILIGENCE
Historical development 16–15
The statutory standard 16–16
Remedies 16–20
INTRODUCTION TO DIRECTORS’ VARIOUS
DUTIES OF GOOD FAITH AND LOYALTY
Historical background 16–21
Categories of duties 16–22
INTRODUCTION 18–1
INFORMAL INVESTIGATIONS: DISCLOSURE 18–2
OF DOCUMENTS AND INFORMATION
PART 4
Corporate Governance—Majority and Minority
Shareholders
PART 5
Accounts and Audit
PART 6
Equity Finance
28. TAKEOVERS
INTRODUCTION 28–1
THE TAKEOVER CODE AND PANEL 28–3
The Panel and its methods of
operation
The status and composition of the 28–4
Panel
Internal appeals 28–5
Judicial review 28–6
Powers of the Panel 28–7
Sanctions 28–9
The “cold shoulder” and criminal 28–11
sanctions
THE SCOPE OF THE CITY CODE 28–13
Transactions in scope 28–14
Companies in scope
Full jurisdiction to the Panel 28–15
Divided jurisdiction 28–16
THE STRUCTURE OF THE CODE 28–18
THE ALLOCATION OF THE ACCEPTANCE 28–19
DECISION
Post-bid defensive measures 28–20
Defensive measures in advance of the 28–21
bid
The break-through rule 28–22
Disclosure of control structures 28–25
TARGET MANAGEMENT PROMOTION OF AN 28–26
OFFER
Disclosure and independent advice 28–27
Compensation for loss of office 28–28
Gratuitous payments 28–29
Contractual compensation 28–32
Competing bids 28–33
A duty to auction or a duty to be 28–34
even-handed?
Binding the target board by 28–36
contract
EQUALITY OF TREATMENT OF TARGET 28–37
SHAREHOLDERS
Partial bids 28–38
Level and type of consideration 28–39
Mandatory offers 28–41
Exemptions and relaxations 28–43
Acting in concert 28–44
Interests in shares 28–45
Conclusion 28–46
To whom must an offer be made? 28–47
Wait and see 28–48
THE PROCEDURE FOR MAKING A BID 28–49
Before the approach to the target 28–50
board
Company-triggered disclosures 28–51
Sanctions 28–53
Interests in shares and acting in 28–54
concert
Before a formal offer is made to the 28–55
target shareholders
Put up or shut up 28–56
Initial announcements 28–57
The formal offer
Conditions 28–58
Timetable 28–59
Bid documentation 28–61
Employees’ interests 28–62
Profit forecasts and valuations 28–63
Liability for misstatements 28–64
Dealings in shares 28–65
Solicitation 28–66
The post-offer period
Bidding again 28–68
The bidder’s right to squeeze out 28–69
the minority
Challenging the squeeze-out 28–73
The sell-out right of non-accepting 28–75
shareholders
CONCLUSION 28–77
29. ARRANGEMENTS,
RECONSTRUCTIONS AND
MERGERS
THE FUNCTION OF SCHEMES OF 29–1
ARRANGEMENT
Mergers 29–2
Takeovers 29–3
Other cases 29–4
Creditors’ schemes 29–5
THE MECHANICS OF THE SCHEME OF 29–6
ARRANGEMENT
Proposing a scheme 29–7
Convening and conducting meetings 29–8
The sanction of the court 29–11
Additional requirements for mergers 29–12
and divisions of public companies
CROSS-BORDER MERGERS 29–16
Employee participation 29–20
Further uses of cross-border mergers 29–22
REORGANISATION UNDER SECTIONS 110 29–24
AND 111 OF THE INSOLVENCY ACT 1986
CONCLUSION 29–26
30. MARKET ABUSE
INTRODUCTION 30–1
APPROACHES TO REGULATING INSIDER
DEALING
Disclosure 30–5
Prohibiting trading 30–6
Relying on the general law 30–7
Directors’ fiduciary duties 30–8
Breach of confidence 30–9
Misrepresentation 30–10
Prohibiting insider dealing 30–11
THE CRIMINAL JUSTICE ACT 1993 PART V 30–12
Regulating markets 30–13
Regulating individuals 30–15
Inside information 30–16
Particular securities or issuers 30–17
Specific or precise 30–18
Made public 30–19
Impact on price 30–21
Insiders 30–22
Recipients from insiders 30–23
Mental element 30–24
Prohibited acts 30–25
Defences 30–26
General defences 30–27
Special defences 30–28
CRIMINAL PROHIBITIONS ON MARKET 30–29
MANIPULATION
REGULATORY CONTROL OF MARKET
ABUSE
Background 30–30
Insider dealing 30–31
Dealing 30–32
Inside information 30–37
Persons covered and exemptions 30–38
Market manipulation
Transactions and orders to trade 30–39
Dissemination of information 30–40
Misleading behaviour and market 30–41
distortion
Accepted market practices 30–42
Safe harbours 30–43
Share buy-backs 30–44
Price stabilisation 30–45
ENFORCEMENT AND SANCTIONS 30–47
Investigation into market abuse 30–48
Sanctions for market abuse 30–51
Penalties 30–52
Injunctions 30–53
Sanctions for breach of the criminal 30–54
law
Restitution orders and injunctions 30–55
Disqualification 30–56
CONCLUSION 30–57
PART 7
Debt Finance
SECURITY INTERESTS
The legal nature of security interests 32–2
The benefits of taking security 32–4
THE FLOATING CHARGE
The practical differences between 32–5
fixed and floating charges
Crystallisation 32–8
Automatic crystallisation 32–9
Priority accorded to floating charges 32–10
Negative pledge clauses 32–11
Subordination agreements 32–12
Statutory limitations on the floating 32–13
charge
(i) Defective floating charges 32–14
(ii) Preferential creditors 32–15
(iii) Sharing with unsecured 32–17
creditors—the “prescribed
part”
(iv) Costs of liquidation 32–18
(v) Powers of the administrator 32–20
Distinguishing between fixed and 32–21
floating charges
REGISTRATION OF CHARGES
The purpose of a registration system 32–24
The reformed registration system
What has to be registered 32–26
The mechanics of registration 32–27
Geographical reach of the 32–28
registration provisions
The effect of failure to register 32–29
PART 8
Insolvency and its Consequences
Breckland Group Holdings Ltd v London and Suffolk 3–25, 14–6, 14–11, 17–3
Properties [1989] B.C.L.C. 100
Breitenfeld UK Ltd v Harrison [2015] EWHC 399 (Ch); 16–52
[2015] 2 B.C.L.C. 275
Brenfield Squash Racquets Club Ltd, Re [1996] 2 B.C.L.C. 20–19
184 Ch D
Brian D Pierson (Contractors) Ltd, Re [1999] B.C.C. 26; 9–9
[2001] 1 B.C.L.C. 275; [1999] B.P.I.R. 18 Ch D
(Companies Ct)
Brian Sheridan Cars Ltd, Re; sub nom Official Receiver v 10–3
Sheridan [1995] B.C.C. 1035; [1996] 1 B.C.L.C. 327
Ch D (Companies Ct)
Bridge v Daley [2015] EWHC 2121 (Ch) 17–18, 17–21
Bridgewater Navigation Co, Re [1891] 2 Ch.317 CA 23–7, 23–8
Briess v Woolley; sub nom Briess v Rosher [1954] A.C. 16–5
333; [1954] 2 W.L.R. 832; [1954] 1 All E.R. 909;
(1954) 98 S.J. 286 HL
Brightlife Ltd, Re [1987] Ch. 200; [1987] 2 W.L.R. 197; 32–9, 32–15, 32–21, 32–22
[1986] 3 All E.R. 673; (1986) 2 B.C.C. 99359; [1986]
P.C.C. 435; (1987) 84 L.S.G. 653; (1987) 131 S.J. 132
Ch D (Companies Ct)
Bristol & West Building Society v Mothew (t/a Stapley & 16–20, 16–52, 16–101
Co); sub nom Mothew v Bristol & West Building
Society [1998] Ch. 1; [1997] 2 W.L.R. 436; [1996] 4
All E.R. 698; [1997] P.N.L.R. 11; (1998) 75 P. & C.R.
241; [1996] E.G. 136 (C.S.); (1996) 146 N.L.J. 1273;
(1996) 140 S.J.L.B. 206; [1996] N.P.C. 126
Bristol Airport Plc v Powdrill; sub nom Paramount Airways 32–2, 32–46
Ltd (No.1), Re [1990] Ch. 744; [1990] 2 W.L.R. 1362;
[1990] 2 All E.R. 493; [1990] B.C.C. 130; [1990]
B.C.L.C. 585; (1990) 87(17) L.S.G. 28 CA (Civ Div)
Britannia Homes Centres Ltd, Re [2001] 2 B.C.L.C. 63 CA 10–3
(Civ Div)
British & Commonwealth Holdings Plc v Barclays Bank 12–9, 13–28, 13–49, 29–11
Plc [1996] 1 W.L.R. 1; [1996] 1 All E.R. 381; [1996] 5
Bank. L.R. 47; [1995] B.C.C. 1059; [1996] 1 B.C.L.C.
1; (1995) 139 S.J.L.B. 194 CA (Civ Div)
British Airways Board v Parish [1979] 2 Lloyd’s Rep. 361; 9–20
(1979) 123 S.J. 319 CA (Civ Div)
British American Nickel Corp Ltd v MJ O’Brien Ltd [1927] 31–30, 31–31
A.C. 369 PC (Can)
British Asbestos Co Ltd v Boyd [1903] 2 Ch. 439 Ch D 7–7
British Association of Glass Bottle Manufacturers v 4–36
Nettlefold [1911] 27 T.L.R. 527
British Diabetic Association v Diabetic Society Ltd [1995] 4–25
4 All E.R. 812; [1996] F.S.R. 1 Ch D
British Eagle International Airlines Ltd v Compagnie 33–20, 33–23
Nationale Air France [1975] 1 W.L.R. 758; [1975] 2 All
E.R. 390; [1975] 2 Lloyd’s Rep. 43; (1975) 119 S.J. 368
HL
British Equitable Assurance Co Ltd v Baily; sub nom Baily 19–27
v British Equitable Assurance Co [1904] 1 Ch. 374 CA
British India Steam Navigation Co v IRC (1880–81) L.R. 7 31–6
Q.B.D. 165 QBD
British Midland Tool Ltd v Midland International Tooling 16–101
Ltd [2003] EWHC 466 (Ch); [2003] 2 B.C.L.C. 523
British Murac Syndicate Ltd v Alperton Rubber Co Ltd 19–27
[1915] 2 Ch. 186 Ch D
British Racing Drivers Club Ltd v Hextall Erskine & Co 16–70
[1996] 3 All E.R. 667; [1996] B.C.C. 727; [1997] 1
B.C.L.C. 182; [1996] P.N.L.R. 523 Ch D
British Telecommunications Plc v One in a Million Ltd; 4–26
Marks & Spencer Plc v One in a Million Ltd; Virgin
Enterprises Ltd v One in a Million Ltd; J Sainsbury Plc
v One in a Million Ltd; Ladbroke Group Plc v One in a
Million Ltd [1999] 1 W.L.R. 903; [1998] 4 All E.R.
476; [1999] E.T.M.R. 61; [1997–98] Info. T.L.R. 423;
[1998] I.T.C.L.R. 146; [2001] E.B.L.R. 2; [1999] F.S.R.
1; [1998] Masons C.L.R. 165; (1998) 95(37) L.S.G. 37;
(1998) 148 N.L.J. 1179 CA (Civ Div)
British Thomson Houston Co Ltd v Federated European 7–21
Bank Ltd [1932] 2 K.B. 176 CA
British Thomson Houston Co Ltd v Sterling Accessories 7–35
Ltd; British Thomson Houston Co Ltd v Crowther &
Osborn Ltd [1924] 2 Ch. 33 Ch D
British Union for the Abolition of Vivisection, Re [1995] 2 15–54
B.C.L.C. 1 Ch D
British Waggon Co v Lea & Co; Parkgate Waggon Co v 2–22
Lea & Co (1879–80) L.R. 5 Q.B.D. 149 QBD
Brook v Masters. See Brooks v Armstrong 9–6
Brooks v Armstrong; sub nom Brook v Masters [2015] 16–15
EWHC 2289 (Ch); [2015] B.C.C. 661; [2016] B.P.I.R.
272
Brown v British Abrasive Wheel Co Ltd [1919] 1 Ch. 290 19–8, 19–9, 19–11
Ch D
Brumark Investments Ltd, Re; sub nom IRC v Agnew; 32–21, 32–22, 32–23
Agnew v IRC [2001] UKPC 28; [2001] 2 A.C. 710;
[2001] 3 W.L.R. 454; [2001] Lloyd’s Rep. Bank. 251;
[2001] B.C.C. 259; [2001] 2 B.C.L.C. 188
Brumder v Motornet Service and Repairs Ltd [2013] 16–15, 16–17
EWCA Civ 195; [2013] 1 W.L.R. 2783; [2013] 3 All
E.R. 412; [2013] B.C.C. 381; [2013] 2 B.C.L.C. 58;
[2013] I.C.R. 1069; [2013] P.I.Q.R. P13; (2013)
157(38) S.J.L.B. 41
Brunningshausen v Glavanics (1999) 46 N.S.W.L.R. 538 16–6
CA (NSW)
Brunton v Electrical Engineering Corp [1892] 1 Ch. 434 Ch 32–11
D
Bryanston Finance Ltd v De Vries (No.2) [1976] Ch. 63; 33–6
[1976] 2 W.L.R. 41; [1976] 1 All E.R. 25; (1975) 119
S.J. 709 CA (Civ Div)
BTH v Federated European Bank. See British Thomson
Houston Co Ltd v Federated European Bank Ltd
BTR Plc, Re [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 675 Ch D (Companies Ct) 29–8
BTR Plc (Leave to Appeal), Re [2000] 1 B.C.L.C. 740 CA 29–3, 29–11
(Civ Div)
Buchler v Talbot; sub nom Leyland DAF Ltd, Re [2004] 9–10, 32–3, 32–18, 32–38
UKHL 9; [2004] 2 A.C. 298; [2004] 2 W.L.R. 582;
[2004] 1 All E.R. 1289; [2004] B.C.C. 214; [2004] 1
B.C.L.C. 281; (2004) 101(12) L.S.G. 35; (2004) 154
N.L.J. 381; (2004) 148 S.J.L.B. 299
Buenos Ayres Great Southern Ry Co Ltd, Re; sub nom 23–8
Buenos Ayres Great Southern Ry Co Ltd v Preston
[1947] Ch. 384; [1947] 1 All E.R. 729; [1948] L.J.R.
131; 176 L.T. 468 Ch D
Bugle Press, Re; sub nom Houses & Estates Ltd, Re; HC 8–12, 28–74
Treby’s Application [1961] Ch. 270; [1960] 3 W.L.R.
956; [1960] 3 All E.R. 791; (1960) 104 S.J. 1057 CA
Burberry Group Plc v Fox-Davies [2015] EWHC 222 (Ch); 27–18
[2015] 2 B.C.L.C. 66
Burge v Haycock [2001] EWCA Civ 900; [2002] R.P.C. 28 4–25
Burgess v Purchase & Sons (Farms) Ltd [1983] Ch. 216; 27–7
[1983] 2 W.L.R. 361; [1983] 2 All E.R. 4 Ch D
Burgoine v Waltham Forest LBC [1997] B.C.C. 347; 16–128
[1997] 2 B.C.L.C. 612 Ch D
Burkinshaw v Nicolls; sub nom British Farmers Pure 27–6
Linseed Cake Co, Re (1877–78) L.R. 3 App. Cas. 1004
HL
Burland v Earle [1902] A.C. 83 PC (Can) 5–18, 16–113, 16–122, 16–124, 19–4,
23–8
Burry & Knight Ltd, Re [2014] EWCA Civ 604; [2014] 1 19–11, 27–18
W.L.R. 4046; [2015] 1 All E.R. 37; [2014] B.C.C. 393;
[2015] 1 B.C.L.C. 61
Bushell v Faith [1970] A.C. 1099; [1970] 2 W.L.R. 272; 14–51, 15–44, 19–19, 19–24, 20–7
[1970] 1 All E.R. 53; (1970) 114 S.J. 54 HL
Byblos Bank SAL v Rushingdale Ltd SA; Byblos Bank 32–37
SAL v Barrett; Byblos Bank SAL v Khudhairy; sub
nom Rushingdale SA v Byblos Bank SAL (1986) 2
B.C.C. 99509; [1987] B.C.L.C. 232; [1986] P.C.C. 249
CA (Civ Div)
Byng v London Life Association Ltd [1990] Ch. 170; 15–55, 15–82, 15–83
[1989] 2 W.L.R. 738; [1989] 1 All E.R. 560; (1989) 5
B.C.C. 227; [1989] B.C.L.C. 400; [1989] P.C.C. 190;
(1989) 86(16) L.S.G. 35; (1989) 139 N.L.J. 75; (1989)
133 S.J. 420 CA (Civ Div)
C Evans & Son Ltd v Spritebrand Ltd [1983] Q.B. 310; 7–36
[1985] 1 W.L.R. 317; [1985] 2 All E.R. 415; (1985) 1
B.C.C. 99316; [1985] P.C.C. 109; [1985] F.S.R. 267;
(1985) 82 L.S.G. 606; (1985) 129 S.J. 189 CA (Civ
Div)
Cabra Estates Plc v Fulham Football Club. See Fulham
Football Club Ltd v Cabra Estates Plc
Cadbury Schweppes Plc v Halifax Share Dealing Ltd 27–6
[2006] EWHC 1184 (Ch); [2006] B.C.C. 707; [2007] 1
B.C.L.C. 497; (2006) 103(24) L.S.G. 29; (2006) 150
S.J.L.B. 739
Cadbury Schweppes Plc v IRC (C–196/04) [2007] Ch. 30; 6–24
[2006] 3 W.L.R. 890; [2006] S.T.C. 1908; [2006]
E.C.R. I-7995; [2007] 1 C.M.L.R. 2; [2007] All E.R.
(EC) 153; [2006] C.E.C. 1026; [2008] B.T.C. 52; 9
I.T.L. Rep. 89; [2006] S.T.I. 2201 ECJ (Grand
Chamber)
Calgary and Edmonton Land Co Ltd (In Liquidation), Re 29–4
[1975] 1 W.L.R. 355; [1975] 1 All E.R. 1046; (1974)
119 S.J. 150 Ch D
Calmex Ltd, Re [1989] 1 All E.R. 485; (1988) 4 B.C.C. 4–23
761; [1989] B.C.L.C. 299; [1989] P.C.C. 233 Ch D
(Companies Ct)
Canada Safeway Ltd v Thompson [1951] 3 D.L.R. 295 16–136
Canadian Aero Service v O’Malley [1973] 40 D.L.R. (3d) 16–11, 16–92, 16–93, 16–94, 16–95,
371 Sup Ct (Can) 16–101
Canadian Land Reclaiming & Colonizing Co, Re; sub nom 16–8
Coventry & Dixon’s Case (1880) L.R. 14 Ch. D. 660
CA
Candler v Crane Christmas & Co [1951] 2 K.B. 164; [1951] 22–46
1 All E.R. 426; [1951] 1 T.L.R. 371; (1951) 95 S.J. 171
CA
Cane v Jones [1980] 1 W.L.R. 1451; [1981] 1 All E.R. 533; 3–22, 15–19
(1980) 124 S.J. 542 Ch D
Caparo Industries Plc v Dickman [1990] 2 A.C. 605; [1990] 22–32, 22–45, 22–46, 22–7, 22–50, 22–
2 W.L.R. 358; [1990] 1 All E.R. 568; [1990] B.C.C. 51, 26–26, 28–64
164; [1990] B.C.L.C. 273; [1990] E.C.C. 313; [1955–
95] P.N.L.R. 523; (1990) 87(12) L.S.G. 42; (1990) 140
N.L.J. 248; (1990) 134 S.J. 494 HL
Cape Breton Co, Re. See Bentinck v Fenn
Capital Cameras Ltd v Harold Lines Ltd [1991] 1 W.L.R. 32–10
54; [1991] 3 All E.R. 389; [1991] B.C.C. 228; [1991]
B.C.L.C. 884 Ch D
Cardiff Savings Bank, Re; sub nom Marquis of Bute’s Case 16–15
[1892] 2 Ch. 100 Ch D
Carecraft Construction Co Ltd, Re [1994] 1 W.L.R. 172; 10–2
[1993] 4 All E.R. 499; [1993] B.C.C. 336; [1993]
B.C.L.C. 1259 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Cargill v Bower (No.2) (1878–79) L.R. 10 Ch. D. 502 Ch D 7–35
Cargo Agency Ltd, Re [1992] B.C.C. 388; [1992] B.C.L.C. 10–3
686 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Carl Zeiss Stiftung v Rayner & Keeler Ltd (Pleadings: 4–5
Striking Out) [1970] Ch. 506; [1969] 3 W.L.R. 991;
[1969] 3 All E.R. 897; [1969] R.P.C. 194; (1969) 113
S.J. 922 Ch D
Carlton Holdings, Re; sub nom Worster v Priam 28–73
Investments, Ltd [1971] 1 W.L.R. 918; [1971] 2 All
E.R. 1082; (1971) 115 S.J. 301 Ch D
Carney v Herbert [1985] A.C. 301; [1984] 3 W.L.R. 1303; 13–57
[1985] 1 All E.R. 438; (1984) 81 L.S.G. 3500 PC (Aus)
Carrington Viyella Plc, Re (1983) 1 B.C.C. 98951 Ch D 20–14
Carruth v ICI Ltd; sub nom ICI Ltd, Re [1937] A.C. 707 15–75, 15–84
HL
Cartesio Oktató és Szolgáltató Bt (C–210/06); sub nom 6–24, 6–25
Application Brought by Cartesio Oktató és Szolgáltató
Bt (C–210/06) [2009] Ch. 354; [2009] 3 W.L.R. 777;
[2009] Bus. L.R. 1233; [2009] All E.R. (EC) 269;
[2008] E.C.R. I–9641; [2009] B.C.C. 232; [2010] 1
B.C.L.C. 523; [2009] 1 C.M.L.R. 50; [2009] C.E.C. 557
Cartmell’s Case, Re; sub nom County Palatine Loan and 16–34
Discount Co Re v Cartmell’s Case; County Palatine
Loan and Discount Co, Re (1873–74) L.R. 9 Ch. App.
691 CA
CAS (Nominees) Ltd v Nottingham Forest FC Plc [2002] 20–12
B.C.C. 145; [2002] 1 B.C.L.C. 613 Ch D (Companies
Ct)
Castell & Brown Ltd, Re; sub nom Roper v Castell & 32–10, 32–11
Brown Ltd [1898] 1 Ch. 315 Ch D
Castiglione’s Will Trusts, Re; sub nom Hunter v Mackenzie 13–5
[1958] Ch. 549; [1958] 2 W.L.R. 400; [1958] 1 All E.R.
480; (1958) 102 S.J. 176 Ch D
Catalinas Warehouses & Mole Co Ltd, Re [1947] 1 All E.R. 23–8
51 Ch D
Cavendish Square Holdings BV v Makdessi. See Makdessi
v Cavendish Square Holdings BV
Cedarwood Productions Ltd, Re; sub nom Secretary of 10–12
State for Trade and Industry v Rayna [2001] 2 B.C.L.C.
48; (2001) 98(20) L.S.G. 42 Ch D
Celtic Extraction Ltd (In Liquidation), Re; Bluestone 33–16
Chemicals Ltd v Environment Agency; sub nom
Official Receiver (as Liquidator of Celtic Extraction Ltd
and Bluestone Chemicals Ltd) v Environment Agency
[2001] Ch. 475; [2000] 2 W.L.R. 991; [1999] 4 All E.R.
684; [2000] B.C.C. 487; [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 555; [2000]
Env. L.R. 86; [1999] B.P.I.R. 986; [1999] 3 E.G.L.R.
21; [1999] 46 E.G. 187; (1999) 96(32) L.S.G. 33;
[1999] N.P.C. 92
Central and Eastern Trust Co v Irving Oil Ltd (1980) 110 13–47
D.L.R. (3d) 257 Sup Ct (Can)
Centros Ltd v Erhvervs- og Selskabsstyrelsen (C–212/97) 6–4, 6–22
[2000] Ch. 446; [2000] 2 W.L.R. 1048; [2000] All E.R.
(EC) 481; [1999] E.C.R. I–1459; [1999] B.C.C. 983;
[2000] 2 B.C.L.C. 68; [1999] 2 C.M.L.R. 551; [2000]
C.E.C. 290
Champagne Perrier-Jouet SA v HH Finch Ltd [1982] 1 27–10, 27–11
W.L.R. 1359; [1982] 3 All E.R. 713; (1983) 80 L.S.G.
93; (1982) 126 S.J. 689 Ch D
Chan v Zacharia (1984) 154 CLR 178 High Ct (Aust) 16–115
Chandler v Cape Plc [2012] EWCA Civ 525; [2012] 1 8–8
W.L.R. 3111; [2012] 3 All E.R. 640; [2012] I.C.R.
1293; [2012] P.I.Q.R. P17
Channel Collieries Trust Ltd v Dover St Margaret’s & 7–7
Martin Mill Light Ry Co [1914] 2 Ch. 506 CA
Charles Forte Investments v Amanda [1964] Ch. 240; 27–7, 33–6
[1963] 3 W.L.R. 662; [1963] 2 All E.R. 940; (1963) 107
S.J. 494 CA
Charnley Davies Ltd (No.2), Re [1990] B.C.C. 605; [1990] 20–15, 20–16
B.C.L.C. 760 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Charterbridge Corp v Lloyds Bank Ltd [1970] Ch. 62; 9–14, 16–42
[1969] 3 W.L.R. 122; [1969] 2 All E.R. 1185; [1969] 2
Lloyd’s Rep. 24; (1968) 113 S.J. 465 Ch D
Charterhouse Capital Ltd, Re [2015] EWCA Civ 536; 16–6, 19–8, 19–9, 19–11, 28–69
[2015] B.C.C. 574; [2015] 2 B.C.L.C. 627
Charterhouse Investment Trust v Tempest Diesels Ltd 13–53
(1985) 1 B.C.C. 99544; [1986] B.C.L.C. 1 Ch D
Chartmore Ltd, Re [1990] B.C.L.C. 673 Ch D 10–3
Chase Manhattan Equities Ltd v Goodman [1991] B.C.C. 30–10, 30–54
308; [1991] B.C.L.C. 897 Ch D
Chaston v SWP Group Plc [2002] EWCA Civ 1999; [2003] 13–46, 13–48, 13–49, 13–55, 13–57
B.C.C. 140; [2003] 1 B.C.L.C. 675
Chatterley-Whitfield Collieries Ltd, Re. See Prudential
Assurance Co Ltd v Chatterley–Whitfield Collieries Ltd
Cheah Theam Swee v Equiticorp Finance Group Ltd [1992] 32–12
1 A.C. 472; [1992] 2 W.L.R. 108; [1991] 4 All E.R.
989; [1992] B.C.C. 98; [1992] B.C.L.C. 371; (1992)
89(1) L.S.G. 32; (1991) 135 S.J.L.B. 205; [1991] N.P.C.
119 PC (NZ)
Chesterfield Catering Co Ltd, Re [1977] Ch. 373; [1976] 3 20–21
W.L.R. 879; [1976] 3 All E.R. 294; (1976) 120 S.J. 817
Ch D
Chesterfield United Inc, Re [2012] EWHC 244 (Ch); [2012] 33–7
B.C.C. 786; [2013] 1 B.C.L.C. 709
Chez Nico (Restaurants) Ltd, Re [1991] B.C.C. 736; [1992] 16–6, 28–71, 28–74
B.C.L.C. 192 Ch D
Child v Hudson’s Bay Co, 24 E.R. 702; (1723) 2 P. Wms. 23–1
207 Ct of Ch
China and South Seas Bank Ltd v Tan [1990] 1 A.C. 536; 32–37
[1990] 2 W.L.R. 56; [1989] 3 All E.R. 839; [1990] 1
Lloyd’s Rep. 113; (1989) 86(46) L.S.G. 37; (1989) 139
N.L.J. 1669; (1990) 134 S.J. 165 PC (HK)
Choppington Collieries Ltd v Johnson [1944] 1 All E.R. 15–65
762 CA
Cinematic Finance Ltd v Ryder [2010] EWHC 3387 (Ch); 17–21
[2010] All E.R. (D) 283; [2012] B.C.C. 797
Citco Banking Corp NV v Pusser’s Ltd [2007] UKPC 13; 19–9, 19–10, 19–11
[2007] Bus. L.R. 960; [2007] B.C.C. 205; [2007] 2
B.C.L.C. 483
Citibank NA v MBIA Assurance SA; sub nom Citibank NA 31–29
v QVT Financial LP [2007] EWCA Civ 11; [2007] 1
All E.R. (Comm) 475; [2008] 1 B.C.L.C. 376; [2007] 1
C.L.C. 113
City & County Investment Co, Re (1879–80) L.R. 13 Ch. 29–25
D. 475 CA
City Equitable Fire Insurance Co Ltd, Re [1925] Ch. 407; 16–15, 16–17, 16–21, 16–125
[1924] All E.R. Rep. 485 CA
City Index Ltd v Gawler; sub nom Charter Plc v City Index 16–135
Ltd [2007] EWCA Civ 1382; [2008] Ch. 313; [2008] 2
W.L.R. 950; [2008] 3 All E.R. 126; [2008] 2 All E.R.
(Comm) 425; [2007] 2 C.L.C. 968; [2008] P.N.L.R. 16;
[2008] W.T.L.R. 1773; (2008) 105(2) L.S.G. 27
City Investment Centres Ltd, Re [1992] B.C.L.C. 956 10–11
Civil Service Co-operative Society v Chapman [1914] 30 9–20
T.L.R. 679
CL Nye Ltd, Re [1971] Ch. 442; [1970] 3 W.L.R. 158; 32–32
[1970] 3 All E.R. 1061; (1970) 114 S.J. 413 CA (Civ
Div)
Clark v Cutland [2003] EWCA Civ 810; [2004] 1 W.L.R. 20–16
783; [2003] 4 All E.R. 733; [2004] B.C.C. 27; [2003] 2
B.C.L.C. 393; [2003] O.P.L.R. 343; [2003] Pens. L.R.
179; [2004] W.T.L.R. 629; [2003] W.T.L.R. 1413;
(2003) 147 S.J.L.B. 781
Clark v Urquhart; Stracey v Urquhart; sub nom Urquhart v 25–33
Clark; Urquhart v Stracey [1930] A.C. 28; (1929) 34 Ll.
L. Rep. 359 HL
Clark v Workman [1920] 1 Ir.R. 107 16–35
Clark Boyce v Mouat [1994] 1 A.C. 428; [1993] 3 W.L.R. 16–52
1021; [1993] 4 All E.R. 268; (1993) 143 N.L.J. 1440;
(1993) 137 S.J.L.B. 231; [1993] N.P.C. 128 PC (NZ)
Clay Hill Brick Co v Rawlings [1934] 4 All E.R. 100 7–20, 7–21
Claygreen Ltd, Re. See Romer–Ormiston v Claygreen Ltd
Clayton’s Case. See Baring v Noble, Clayton’s Case
Clenaware Systems Ltd, Re. See Harris v Secretary of State
for Business, Innovation and Skills
Cleveland Trust Plc, Re [1991] B.C.C. 33; [1991] B.C.L.C. 11–20, 12–2, 12–5, 12–8, 27–19
424 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Cloverbay Ltd (Joint Administrators) v Bank of Credit and 18–14, 32–38
Commerce International SA; sub nom Cloverbay Ltd
(No.2), Re [1991] Ch. 90; [1990] 3 W.L.R. 574; [1991]
1 All E.R. 894; [1990] B.C.C. 414; [1991] B.C.L.C. 135
CA (Civ Div)
Clydebank Football Club Ltd v Steedman, 2002 S.L.T. 109; 12–10
2000 G.W.D. 31–1217 OH
CMS Dolphin Ltd v Simonet [2002] B.C.C. 600; [2001] 2 16–94, 16–101, 16–114, 16–137
B.C.L.C. 704; [2001] Emp. L.R. 895 Ch D
Cohen v Selby; sub nom Simmon Box (Diamonds) Ltd, Re 16–18, 17–2
[2002] B.C.C. 82; [2001] 1 B.C.L.C. 176 CA (Civ Div)
Coleman v Myer [1977] 2 N.Z.L.R. 225 CA (NZ) 16–6
Coleman Taymar Ltd v Oakes [2001] 2 B.C.L.C. 749; 16–111
(2001) 98(35) L.S.G. 32; (2001) 145 S.J.L.B. 209 Ch D
Colin Gwyer & Associates Ltd v London Wharf 9–14, 9–15
(Limehouse) Ltd; Eaton Bray Ltd v Palmer [2002]
EWHC 2748 (Ch); [2003] B.C.C. 885; [2003] 2
B.C.L.C. 153; [2003] B.P.I.R. 1099; (2003) 100(7)
L.S.G. 34
Collen v Wright, 120 E.R. 241; (1857) 8 El. & Bl. 647 Ex 7–30
Ct
Colonial Bank v Cady; London Chartered Bank of Australia 27–10
v Cady; sub nom Williams v Colonial Bank; Williams v
London Chartered Bank of Australia (1890) L.R. 15
App. Cas. 267 HL
Colonial Bank v Whinney (1886) L.R. 11 App. Cas. 426 23–1
HL
Colonial Trusts Corp Ex p. Bradshaw, Re (1880) L.R. 15 32–6
Ch. D. 465 Ch D
Comet Group Ltd (In Liquidation), Re [2014] EWHC 3477 33–7
(Ch); [2015] B.P.I.R. 1
Commissioners of HM Revenue and Customs v Holland.
See Revenue and Customs Commissioners v Holland
Compania de Electricidad de la Provincia de Buenos Aires 3–18
Ltd, Re [1980] Ch. 146; [1979] 2 W.L.R. 316; [1978] 3
All E.R. 668; (1978) 122 S.J. 14 Ch D
Company, Re (1988) 4 B.C.L.C. 80 20–8
Company (No.00996 of 1979), Re. See Racal
Communications Ltd, Re
Company (No.003729 of 1982), Re [1984] 1 W.L.R. 1090; 33–5
[1984] 3 All E.R. 78; (1984) 81 L.S.G. 2693; (1984)
128 S.J. 580 Ch D
Company (No.004475 of 1982), Re [1983] Ch. 178; [1983] 2–21, 20–4, 20–13
2 W.L.R. 381; [1983] 2 All E.R. 36; [1983] B.C.L.C.
126; (1983) 127 S.J. 153 Ch D
Company (No.007623 of 1984), Re (1986) 2 B.C.C. 99191; 24–6
[1986] B.C.L.C. 362 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Company (No.005287 of 1985), Re [1986] 1 W.L.R. 281; 20–14
[1986] 2 All E.R. 253; (1985) 1 B.C.C. 99586; (1986)
83 L.S.G. 1058; (1985) 130 S.J. 202 Ch D (Companies
Ct)
Company (No.007828 of 1985), Re (1986) 2 B.C.C. 98951 20–2
Ch D
Company (No.008699 of 1985), Re (1986) 2 B.C.C. 99024; 2–21, 16–6, 20–4, 20–12, 20–13, 28–34
[1986] P.C.C. 296; [1986] B.C.L.C. 382 Ch D
Company (No.00477 of 1986), Re [1986] B.C.L.C. 376; 20–4
1986) 2 B.C.C. 99171 Ch D
Company (No.003160 of 1986), Re [1986] B.C.L.C. 391; 20–2
(1986) 2 B.C.C. 99276 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Company (No.003843 of 1986), Re (1987) 3 B.C.C. 624; 20–8
[1987] B.C.L.C. 562 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Company (No.00370 of 1987), Ex p. Glossop, Re; sub nom 20–12, 20–14
Company (No.00370 of 1987), Re, Ex p. Glossop
[1988] 1 W.L.R. 1068; (1988) 4 B.C.C. 506; [1988]
B.C.L.C. 570; [1988] P.C.C. 351; (1988) 85(41) L.S.G.
43; (1988) 132 S.J. 1388 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Company (No.005009 of 1987) Ex p. Copp, Re (1988) 4 9–7
B.C.C. 424; [1989] B.C.L.C. 13 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Company (No.006834 of 1988) Ex p. Kremer, Re (1989) 5 20–18
B.C.C. 218; [1989] B.C.L.C. 365 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Company (No.008126 of 1989), Re. See Hailey Group, Re
Company (No.008790 of 1990), Re [1992] B.C.C. 11; 33–5
[1991] B.C.L.C. 561 Ch D
Company (No.00330 of 1991) Ex p. Holden, Re [1991] 20–18
B.C.C. 241; [1991] B.C.L.C. 597 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Company (No.007936 of 1994), Re [1995] B.C.C. 705 Ch 20–21
D (Companies Ct)
Company (No.000836 of 1995), Re [1996] B.C.C. 432; 20–18
[1996] 2 B.C.L.C. 192 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Company (No.004415 of 1996), Re; Company (No.004413 20–12, 20–21
of 1996), Re; Company (No.004416 of 1996), Re
[1997] 1 B.C.L.C. 479 Ch D
Concord Trust v Law Debenture Trust Corp Plc [2005] 31–29
UKHL 27; [2005] 1 W.L.R. 1591; [2005] 1 All E.R.
(Comm) 699; [2005] 2 Lloyd’s Rep. 221; [2006] 1
B.C.L.C. 616; [2005] 1 C.L.C. 631; (2005) 155 N.L.J.
692
Connelly v RTZ Corp Plc (No.2) [1998] A.C. 854; [1997] 3 8–10
W.L.R. 373; [1997] 4 All E.R. 335; [1997] C.L.C. 1357;
[1997] I.L.Pr. 805; [1998] Env. L.R. 318; (1997) 94(32)
L.S.G. 28; (1997) 147 N.L.J. 1346; (1997) 141 S.J.L.B.
199 HL
Connolly Bros Ltd (No.2), Re; sub nom Wood v Connolly 32–11
Bros Ltd (No.2) [1912] 2 Ch. 25 CA
Consolidated Goldfields of New Zealand, Re [1953] Ch. 33–1
689; [1953] 2 W.L.R. 584; [1953] 1 All E.R. 791;
(1953) 97 S.J. 190 Ch D
Constable v Executive Connections Ltd [2005] EWHC 3 19–7
(Ch); [2005] 2 B.C.L.C. 638
Consumer and Industrial Press Ltd (No.1), Re (1988) 4 32–44
B.C.C. 68; [1988] B.C.L.C. 177; [1988] P.C.C. 436 Ch
D (Companies Ct)
Contex Drouzhba Ltd v Wiseman [2007] EWCA Civ 1201; 7–32
[2008] B.C.C. 301; [2008] 1 B.C.L.C. 631; (2007) 157
N.L.J. 1695
Continental Assurance Co of London Plc (In Liquidation),
Re. See Singer v Beckett
Continental Assurance Co of London Plc (No.4), Re Singer
v Beckett
Continental Assurance Co of London Plc, Re [1977] 1 10–11
B.C.L.C. 48
Cook v Deeks [1916] 1 A.C. 554 PC (Can) 5–13, 5–18, 16–104, 16–124, 16–127,
20–14
Cooper Chemicals Ltd, Re. See Gerald Cooper Chemicals
Ltd, Re
Copecrest Ltd, Re. See Secretary of State for Trade and
Industry v McTighe (No.1)
Cork & Brandon Ry v Cazenove, 116 E.R. 355; (1847) 10 23–1
Q.B. 935 QB
Coroin Ltd, Re [2012] EWCA Civ 179; [2012] B.C.C. 575; 3–21, 16–61, 16–86, 20–8, 20–13, 27–7
[2012] 2 B.C.L.C. 611
Corporate Jet Realisations Ltd, Re. See Green v Chubb
Cosslett (Contractors) Ltd, Re; sub nom Clark 32–2, 32–26
(Administrator of Cosslett (Contractors) Ltd) v Mid
Glamorgan CC [1998] Ch. 495; [1998] 2 W.L.R. 131;
[1997] 4 All E.R. 115; [1997] B.C.C. 724; [1999] 1
B.C.L.C. 205; 85 B.L.R. 1 CA (Civ Div)
Costa Rica Ry Co Ltd v Forward [1901] 1 Ch. 746 CA 16–62
Cotronic (UK) Ltd v Dezonie (t/a Wendaland Builders Ltd) 5–26, 5–28
[1991] B.C.C. 200; [1991] B.C.L.C. 721; CA (Civ Div)
Cottrell v King; sub nom TA King (Services) Ltd, Re 27–8
[2004] EWHC 397 (Ch); [2004] B.C.C. 307; [2004] 2
B.C.L.C. 413; [2005] W.T.L.R. 63
Coulthard v Neville Russell (A Firm) [1998] B.C.C. 359; 22–49
[1998] 1 B.C.L.C. 143; [1998] P.N.L.R. 276 CA (Civ
Div)
County Leasing Asset Management Ltd v Hawkes [2015] 33–33
EWCA Civ 1251; [2016] B.C.C. 102
Cousins v International Brick Co [1931] 2 Ch. 90 CA 15–70
Cowan de Groot Properties v Eagle Trust [1992] 4 All E.R. 16–136
700; [1991] B.C.L.C. 1045 Ch D
Cox v Ministry of Justice [2016] UKSC 10; [2016] 2 7–31
W.L.R. 806; [2016] I.C.R. 470; [2016] I.R.L.R. 370;
[2016] P.I.Q.R. P8
Cranleigh Precision Engineering Ltd v Bryant [1965] 1 16–110
W.L.R. 1293; [1964] 3 All E.R. 289; [1966] R.P.C. 81;
(1965) 109 S.J. 830 QBD
Craven-Ellis v Canons Ltd [1936] 2 K.B. 403 CA 14–30
Crawley’s Case. See Peruvian Railways Co, Re
Credit Lyonnais Bank Nederland NV (now Generale Bank 7–33
Nederland NV) v Export Credits Guarantee Department;
sub nom Generale Bank Nederland NV (formerly Credit
Lyonnais Bank Nederland NV) v Export Credits
Guarantee Department [2000] 1 A.C. 486; [1999] 2
W.L.R. 540; [1999] 1 All E.R. 929; [1999] 1 Lloyd’s
Rep. 563; [1999] C.L.C. 823; (1999) 96(10) L.S.G. 30;
(1999) 143 S.J.L.B. 89 HL
Cretanor Maritime Co Ltd v Irish Marine Management Ltd 32–10
[1978] 1 W.L.R. 966, CA
Crichton’s Oil Co, Re [1902] 2 Ch. 86 CA 23–8
Grøngaard, Criminal Proceedings against (C–384/02) 28–62
[2005] E.C.R. I–9939; [2006] 1 C.M.L.R. 30; [2006]
C.E.C. 241; [2006] I.R.L.R. 214 ECJ
Criterion Properties Plc v Stratford UK Properties LLC 16–26, 16–27, 16–30, 16–113, 16–136,
[2004] UKHL 28; [2004] 1 W.L.R. 1846; [2004] B.C.C. 16–137, 28–21
570; [2006] 1 B.C.L.C. 729; (2004) 101(26) L.S.G. 27;
(2004) 148 S.J.L.B. 760; [2004] N.P.C. 96 HL
Crompton & Co Ltd, Re; sub nom Player v Crompton & Co 32–8
Ltd [1914] 1 Ch. 954 Ch D
Cryne v Barclays Bank Plc [1987] B.C.L.C. 548 CA (Civ 32–37
Div)
CU Fittings Ltd, Re (1989) 5 B.C.C. 210; [1989] B.C.L.C. 10–11
556 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Cuckmere Brick Co v Mutual Finance [1971] Ch. 949; 32–38
[1971] 2 W.L.R. 1207; [1971] 2 All E.R. 633; (1971) 22
P. & C.R. 624; (1971) 115 S.J. 288 CA (Civ Div)
Cukurova Finance International Ltd v Alfa Telecom Turkey 27–10, 27–15
Ltd [2009] UKPC 19; [2009] Bus. L.R. 1613; [2009] 3
All E.R. 849; [2010] 1 All E.R. (Comm) 1173; [2009] 1
C.L.C. 701; [2009] 3 C.M.L.R. 11 PC
Cukurova Finance International Ltd v Alfa Telecom Turkey 32–39
Ltd [2013] UKPC 2; [2015] 2 W.L.R. 875; [2013] 4 All
E.R. 989
Cullen Investments Ltd v Brown [2015] EWHC 473 (Ch); 17–21
[2015] B.C.C. 539; [2016] 1 B.C.L.C. 491
Cumana Ltd, Re [1986] B.C.L.C. 430 20–14
Cumbrian Newspapers Group Ltd v Cumberland & 19–18, 19–19, 19–27
Westmorland Herald Newspaper & Printing Co Ltd
[1987] Ch. 1; [1986] 3 W.L.R. 26; [1986] 2 All E.R.
816; (1986) 2 B.C.C. 99227; [1987] P.C.C. 12; (1986)
83 L.S.G. 1719; (1986) 130 S.J. 446 Ch D
Currie v Cowdenbeath Football Club Ltd [1992] B.C.L.C. 20–8
1029
Curtain Dream Plc, Re [1990] B.C.L.C. 925Welsh 32–2
Development Agency v Export Finance Co Ltd [1992]
B.C.L.C. 148
Curtis Furnishing Stores Ltd (In Liquidation) v Freedman 13–56
[1966] 1 W.L.R. 1219; [1966] 2 All E.R. 955; (1966)
110 S.J. 600 Ch D
Curtis v Pulbrook [2011] EWHC 167 (Ch); [2011] 1 27–9
B.C.L.C. 638
Customer Systems Plc v Ranson [2012] EWCA Civ 841; 16–11
[2012] I.R.L.R. 769; (2012) 156(26) S.J.L.B. 31
Customs and Excise Commissioners v Hedon Alpha [1981] 16–133
Q.B. 818; [1981] 2 W.L.R. 791; [1981] 2 All E.R. 697;
(1981) 125 S.J. 273 CA (Civ Div)
CVC/Opportunity Equity Partners Ltd v Demarco Almeida 20–18, 20–19, 20–20
[2002] UKPC 16; [2002] B.C.C. 684; [2002] 2 B.C.L.C.
108
Cyona Distributors, Re [1967] Ch. 889; [1967] 2 W.L.R. 9–5
369; [1967] 1 All E.R. 281; (1966) 110 S.J. 943 CA
D’Jan of London Ltd, Re; sub nom Copp v D’Jan [1993] 15–19, 16–15, 16–133
B.C.C. 646; [1994] 1 B.C.L.C. 561 Ch D (Companies
Ct)
D’Nick Holding Plc, Re. See Eckerle v Wickeder
Westfalenstahl GmbH
Dafen Tinplate Co Ltd v Llanelly Steel Co (1907) Ltd 19–8
[1920] 2 Ch. 124 Ch D
Daimler Co Ltd v Continental Tyre & Rubber Co (Great 2–19
Britain) Ltd; Continental Tyre & Rubber Co (Great
Britain) Ltd v Thomas Tilling Ltd; sub nom Continental
Tyre & Rubber Co (Great Britain) Ltd v Daimler Co Ltd
[1916] 2 A.C. 307 HL
Daniels v Anderson (1995) 16 A.C.S.R. 607 16–16, 16–17
Daniels v Daniels [1978] Ch. 406; [1978] 2 W.L.R. 73; 16–124
[1978] 2 All E.R. 89; (1977) 121 S.J. 605 Ch D
Danish Mercantile Co v Beaumont [1951] Ch. 680; [1951] 17–5
1 All E.R. 925; (1951) 95 S.J. 300 CA
Daraydan Holdings Ltd v Solland International Ltd [2004] 16–108, 16–115
EWHC 622 (Ch); [2005] Ch. 119; [2004] 3 W.L.R.
1106; [2005] 4 All E.R. 73; [2004] W.T.L.R. 815;
[2004] N.P.C. 49
Darby Ex p. Brougham, Re [1911] 1 K.B. 95 KBD 5–2
Davidson & Tatham v Financial Services Authority (FSM 30–30
Case No.31) 12 October 2006
Davies v United Kingdom (42007/98) [2005] B.C.C. 401; 10–7
[2006] 2 B.C.L.C. 351; (2002) 35 E.H.R.R. 29 ECHR
Davis v Radcliffe [1990] 1 W.L.R. 821; [1990] 2 All E.R. 32–32
536; [1990] B.C.C. 472; [1990] B.C.L.C. 647; (1990)
87(19) L.S.G. 43; (1990) 134 S.J. 1078 HL
Dawson International Plc v Coats Paton Plc (No.1), 1989 16–35
S.L.T. 655; 1989 S.C.L.R. 452; (1989) 5 B.C.C. 405 IH
Dawson International Plc v Coats Paton Plc (No.2); sub 28–36
nom Dawson International Plc v Coats Patons Plc, 1993
S.L.T. 80; [1991] B.C.C. 276 OH
Dawson Print Group, Re (1987) 3 B.C.C. 322; [1987] 10–11
B.C.L.C. 601 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Day v Cook [2001] EWCA Civ 592; [2003] B.C.C. 256; 17–37
[2002] 1 B.C.L.C. 1; [2001] Lloyd’s Rep. P.N. 551;
[2001] P.N.L.R. 32
DC v United Kingdom (39031/97) [2000] B.C.C. 710 10–7, 18–14
ECHR
De Lasteyrie du Saillant v Ministère de l’Economie, des 6–24
Finances et de l’Industrie (C–9/02) [2005] S.T.C. 1722;
[2004] E.C.R. I-2409; [2004] 3 C.M.L.R. 39; [2006]
B.T.C. 105; 6 I.T.L. Rep. 666; [2004] S.T.I. 890 ECJ
(5th Chamber)
Dean v Prince [1954] Ch. 409; [1954] 2 W.L.R. 538; [1954] 27–7
1 All E.R. 749; 47 R. & I.T. 494; (1954) 98 S.J. 215 CA
DEG-Deutsche Investitions und Entwicklungsgesellschaft 16–62, 16–138
mbH v Koshy (Account of Profits: Limitations); sub
nom Gwembe Valley Development Co Ltd (In
Receivership) v Koshy (Account of Profits: Limitations)
[2003] EWCA Civ 1048; [2004] 1 B.C.L.C. 131; [2004]
W.T.L.R. 97; (2003) 147 S.J.L.B. 1086
Deloitte Haskins & Sells v National Mutual Life Nominees 22–46
[1993] A.C. 774; [1993] 3 W.L.R. 347; [1993] 2 All
E.R. 1015; [1993] B.C.L.C. 1174; (1993) 143 N.L.J.
883; (1993) 137 S.J.L.B. 152 PC (NZ)
Denham & Co, Re (1884) L.R. 25 Ch. D. 752 Ch D 16–18
Denis Hilton Ltd, Re [2002] 1 B.C.L.C. 302 Ch D 10–12
Derry v Peek; sub nom Peek v Derry (1889) L.R. 14 App. 21–27, 22–44, 25–32, 25–37
Cas. 337; (1889) 5 T.L.R. 625 HL
Destone Fabrics Ltd, Re [1941] Ch.319 CA 32–14
Devlin v Slough Estates Ltd [1983] B.C.L.C. 497 3–29
DHN Food Distributors v Tower Hamlets LBC; Bronze 8–8, 8–11
Investments Ltd (In Liquidation) v Tower Hamlets
LBC; DHN Food Transport v Tower Hamlets LBC
[1976] 1 W.L.R. 852; [1976] 3 All E.R. 462; 74 L.G.R.
506; (1976) 32 P. & C.R. 240; [1976] J.P.L. 363; (1976)
120 S.J. 215 CA (Civ Div)
Diamandis v Wills [2015] EWHC 312 (Ch) 14–30
Diamix Plc, Re; sub nom Fiske Nominees Ltd v Dwyka 28–70, 28–74
Diamond Ltd [2002] EWHC 770 (Ch); [2002] B.C.C.
707; [2002] 2 B.C.L.C. 123
Diamond Resorts (Europe) Ltd, Re [2012] EWHC 3576 29–19
(Ch); [2013] B.C.C. 275
Gambotto v WCP Ltd (1995) 182 C.L.R. 432 High Ct (Aus) 19–9, 19–11
Gamlestaden Fastigheter AB v Baltic Partners Ltd [2007] 20–16
UKPC 26; [2007] Bus. L.R. 1521; [2007] 4 All E.R.
164; [2007] B.C.C. 272; [2008] 1 B.C.L.C. 468
Gardner v Parker [2004] EWCA Civ 781; [2005] B.C.C. 46; 17–34, 17–37
[2004] 2 B.C.L.C. 554; (2004) 148 S.J.L.B. 792
Gebhard v Consiglio dell’Ordine degli Avvocati e 6–23
Procuratori di Milano (C–55/94) [1996] All E.R. (EC)
189; [1995] E.C.R. I–4165; [1996] 1 C.M.L.R. 603;
[1996] C.E.C. 175
Gee & Co (Woolwich) Ltd, Re [1975] Ch. 52; [1974] 2 15–17, 15–19
W.L.R. 515; [1974] 1 All E.R. 1149; (1973) 118 S.J. 65
Ch D
Geilfuss v Corrigan, 95 Wis. 651, 70 N.W. 306 (1897) 32–6
Geltl v Daimler AG (C–19/11) [2012] 3 C.M.L.R. 32; 26–6, 30–37
[2012] Lloyd’s Rep. F.C. 635 ECJ (2nd Chamber)
Gemma Ltd (In Liquidation) v Davies; sub nom Gemma 16–8
Ltd (In Liquidation), Re [2008] EWHC 546 (Ch);
[2008] B.C.C. 812; [2008] 2 B.C.L.C. 281; [2009] Bus.
L.R. D4
Gencor ACP Ltd v Dalby [2000] 2 B.C.L.C. 734; [2001] 8–16, 16–137
W.T.L.R. 825 Ch D
Generics (UK) Ltd v Yeda Research and Development Co 16–11
Ltd [2012] EWCA Civ 726; [2013] Bus. L.R. 777;
[2012] C.P. Rep. 39; [2013] F.S.R. 13
Geneva Finance Ltd, Re (1992) 7 A.C.S.L.R. 4 32–39
Genosyis Technology Management Ltd, Re. See Wallach v
Secretary of State for Trade and Industry
George Barker (Transport) Ltd v Eynon [1974] 1 W.L.R. 32–3, 32–8, 32–10, 32–40
462; [1974] 1 All E.R. 900; [1974] 1 Lloyd’s Rep. 65;
(1973) 118 S.J. 240 CA (Civ Div)
George Newman & Co, Re [1895] 1 Ch. 674 CA 15–17
Gerald Cooper Chemicals Ltd, Re [1978] Ch. 262; [1978] 2 9–5
W.L.R. 866; [1978] 2 All E.R. 49; (1977) 121 S.J. 848
Ch D
GHE Realisations Ltd (formerly Gatehouse Estates Ltd), Re 32–50
[2005] EWHC 2400 (Ch); [2006] 1 W.L.R. 287; [2006]
1 All E.R. 357; [2006] B.C.C. 139
GHLM Trading Ltd v Maroo [2012] EWHC 61 (Ch); 16–45
[2012] 2 B.C.L.C. 369
Giles v Rhind [2002] EWCA Civ 1428; [2003] Ch. 618; 17–37
[2003] 2 W.L.R. 237; [2002] 4 All E.R. 977; [2003]
B.C.C. 79; [2003] 1 B.C.L.C. 1; (2002) 99(44) L.S.G.
32
Gilford Motor Co Ltd v Horn [1933] Ch. 935 CA 8–15
GL Saunders Ltd (In Liquidation), Re [1986] 1 W.L.R. 215; 32–19
(1986) 83 L.S.G. 779; (1985) 130 S.J. 166 Ch D
Glasgow City Council v Craig [2008] CSOH 171; 2009 9–18
S.L.T. 212; [2010] B.C.C. 235; [2009] 1 B.C.L.C. 742;
[2009] R.A. 61
Glaxo Plc v Glaxowellcome Ltd [1996] F.S.R. 388 Ch D 4–23, 4–26
Global Energy Horizons Corp v Gray [2012] EWHC 3703 16–101
(Ch)
Global Torch Ltd v Apex Global Management Ltd. See FI
Call Ltd, Re
Globalink Telecommunications Ltd v Wilmbury Ltd [2002] 3–23
EWHC 1988 (QB); [2002] B.C.C. 958; [2003] 1
B.C.L.C. 145
Gluckstein v Barnes; sub nom Olympia Ltd, Re [1900] A.C. 5–13, 5–14, 5–16, 5–19, 16–113
240 HL
Godfrey Phillips Ltd v Investment Trust Ltd [1953] Ch. 23–8
449; [1953] 1 W.L.R. 41; [1953] 1 All E.R. 7; 46 R. &
I.T. 81; (1952) 31 A.T.C. 548; [1952] T.R. 507; (1953)
97 S.J. 8 Ch D
Goldtrail Travel Ltd (In Liquidation) v Aydin [2014] 16–120, 16–121, 19–6
EWHC 1587 (Ch); [2015] 1 B.C.L.C. 89
Gomba Holdings (UK) Ltd v Homan; Gomba Holdings 32–39
(UK) Ltd v Johnson Matthey Bankers Ltd; sub nom
Gomba Holdings (UK) Ltd v Homan & Bird [1986] 1
W.L.R. 1301; [1986] 3 All E.R. 94; (1986) 2 B.C.C.
99102; [1986] P.C.C. 449; (1987) 84 L.S.G. 36; (1986)
130 S.J. 821 Ch D
Gomba Holdings (UK) Ltd v Minories Finance Ltd 32–39
(formerly Johnson Matthey Bankers Ltd) (No.1) [1988]
1 W.L.R. 1231; [1989] 1 All E.R. 261; (1989) 5 B.C.C.
27; [1989] B.C.L.C. 115; [1989] P.C.C. 107; (1988)
85(36) L.S.G. 41; (1988) 132 S.J. 1323 CA (Civ Div)
Goodfellow v Nelson Line (Liverpool) Ltd [1912] 2 Ch. 16–122, 19–4, 31–30
324 Ch D
Governments Stock and Other Securities Investment Co Ltd 32–9
v Manila Ry Co Ltd; sub nom Government Stock
Investment and Other Securities Co v Manila Ry Co
[1897] A.C. 81 HL
Gower Enterprises Ltd (No.2), Re [1995] B.C.C. 1081; 10–3
[1995] 2 B.C.L.C. 201 Ch D (Comm Ct)
Grace v Biagioli [2005] EWCA Civ 1222; [2006] B.C.C. 20–13, 20–19
85; [2006] 2 B.C.L.C. 70; (2005) 102(48) L.S.G. 18
Gramophone & Typewriter Ltd v Stanley [1908] 2 K.B. 89 14–6
CA
Granada Group Ltd v Law Debenture Pension Trust Corp 16–70, 28–32
Plc [2015] EWHC 1499 (Ch); [2015] Bus. L.R. 1119;
[2015] 2 B.C.L.C. 604
Grant v Rails [2016] B.C.C. 293 9–9
Grant v United Kingdom Switchback Rys Co (1889) L.R. 7–27, 14–12
40 Ch. D. 135 CA
Gray v G-T-P Group Ltd; sub nom F2G Realisations Ltd (In 32–22
Liquidation), Re; Gray v GTP Group Ltd [2010] EWHC
1772 (Ch); [2011] B.C.C. 869; [2011] 1 B.C.L.C. 313
Grayan Building Services Ltd (In Liquidation), Re; sub 10–3, 10–9
nom Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Gray
[1995] Ch. 241; [1995] 3 W.L.R. 1; [1995] B.C.C. 554;
[1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 276; (1995) 92(1) L.S.G. 36; (1994)
138 S.J.L.B. 227 CA
Gray’s Inn Construction Co Ltd, Re [1980] 1 W.L.R. 711; 33–18
[1980] 1 All E.R. 814; (1980) 124 S.J. 463 CA (Civ
Div)
Great Wheal Polgooth Co, Re (1883) 53 L.J. Ch. 42 5–3
Green v Chubb; sub nom Corporate Jet Realisations Ltd , 33–7
Re [2015] EWHC 221 (Ch); [2015] B.C.C. 625; [2015]
2 B.C.L.C. 95
Green v El Tai [2015] B.P.I.R. 24 Ch D (Companies Ct) 16–42
Greenhalgh v Arderne Cinemas Ltd [1946] 1 All E.R. 512; 13–33, 19–16, 19–17, 19–18
90 S.J 248 CA
Greenhalgh v Arderne Cinemas Ltd [1951] Ch. 286; [1950] 16–35, 19–10, 31–30
2 All E.R. 1120; (1950) 94 S.J. 855 CA
Greenhalgh v Mallard [1943] 2 All E.R. 234 CA 19–28, 27–7
Greenwall v Porter; sub nom Greenwell v Porter [1902] 1 19–4, 19–28
Ch. 530 Ch D
Gregson v HAE Trustees Ltd [2008] EWHC 1006 (Ch); 16–7
[2009] Bus. L.R. 1640; [2009] 1 All E.R. (Comm) 457;
[2008] 2 B.C.L.C. 542; [2008] Pens. L.R. 295; [2008]
W.T.L.R. 1; [2008] 2 P. & C.R. DG
Greythorn Ltd, Re [2002] B.C.C. 559; [2002] 1 B.C.L.C. 28–73
437 Ch D
Grierson Oldham & Adams, Re [1968] Ch. 17; [1967] 1 28–74
W.L.R. 385; [1967] 1 All E.R. 192; (1966) 110 S.J. 887
Ch D
Griffin Hotel Co Ltd, Re [1941] Ch. 129; [1940] 4 All E.R. 32–8
324 Ch D
Griffith v Tower Publishing Co Ltd [1897] 1 Ch. 21 Ch D 2–22
Griffiths v Secretary of State for Social Services [1974] 32–41
Q.B. 468; [1973] 3 W.L.R. 831; [1973] 3 All E.R. 1184;
(1973) 117 S.J. 873 QBD
Griffiths v Yorkshire Bank Plc [1994] 1 W.L.R. 1427; 32–11, 32–19
(1994) 91(36) L.S.G. 36 Ch D
Grimaldi v Chameleon Mining NL (No.2) [2012] FCAFC 6 16–115
Grongaard, Criminal Proceedings against (C–384/02) 30–36
[2005] E.C.R. I-9939; [2006] 1 C.M.L.R. 30; [2006]
C.E.C. 241; [2006] I.R.L.R. 214 ECJ
Gross v Rackind; sub nom Citybranch Group Ltd, Re; City 20–1
Branch Group Ltd, Re; Rackind v Gross [2004] EWCA
Civ 815; [2005] 1 W.L.R. 3505; [2004] 4 All E.R. 735;
[2005] B.C.C. 11; (2004) 148 S.J.L.B. 661
Grosvenor Press Plc, Re [1985] 1 W.L.R. 980; (1985) 1 13–36
B.C.C. 99412; [1985] B.C.L.C. 286 ; [1985] P.C.C. 260;
(1985) 82 L.S.G. 2817; (1985) 129 S.J. 541 Ch D
Grove v Advantage Healthcare (T10) Ltd; sub nom 32–31
Advantage Healthcare (T10) Ltd, Re [2000] B.C.C. 985;
[2000] 1 B.C.L.C. 661 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Grovewood Holdings Plc v James Capel & Co Ltd [1995] 9–10
Ch. 80; [1995] 2 W.L.R. 70; [1994] 4 All E.R. 417;
[1995] B.C.C. 760; [1994] 2 B.C.L.C. 782; [1994] E.G.
136 (C.S.); (1994) 144 N.L.J. 1405 Ch D
Growth Management Ltd v Mutafchiev [2006] EWHC 2774 19–28
(Comm); [2007] 1 B.C.L.C. 645
GSAR Realisations Ltd, Re [1993] B.C.L.C. 409 Ch D 10–11
GT Whyte & Co Ltd, Re [1983] B.C.L.C. 311 Ch D 32–14
Guardian Assurance Co Ltd, Re [1917] 1 Ch. 431 CA 29–3
Guidezone Ltd, Re; sub nom Kaneria v Patel [2001] B.C.C. 20–8, 20–13, 20–22
692; [2000] 2 B.C.L.C. 321 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Guinness Peat Group Plc v British Land Co Plc [1999] 20–13, 20–20
B.C.C. 536; [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 243; [1998] N.P.C. 168
CA (Civ Div)
Guinness Plc v Saunders; Guinness v Ward [1990] 2 A.C. 3–25, 14–31, 16–30, 16–63, 16–112,
663; [1990] 2 W.L.R. 324; [1990] 1 All E.R. 652; 16–113
[1990] B.C.C. 205; [1990] B.C.L.C. 402; (1990) 87(9)
L.S.G. 42; (1990) 134 S.J. 457 HL
Gwembe Valley Development Co Ltd v Koshy (No.3). See
DEG–Deutsche Investitions und
Entwicklungsgesellschaft mbH v Koshy (Account of
Profits: Limitations)
H&K (Medway) Ltd, Re; sub nom Mackay v IRC [1997] 1 32–19
W.L.R. 1422; [1997] 2 All E.R. 321; [1997] B.C.C.
853; [1997] 1 B.C.L.C. 545 Ch D (Companies Ct)
H, Re. See Customs and Excise Commissioners v Hare
Haden Bill Electrical Ltd, Re. See R&H Electric Ltd v
Haden Bill Electrical Ltd
Hague v Nam Tai Electronics Inc [2006] UKPC 52; [2007] 13–9
2 B.C.L.C. 194
Hailey Group, Re; sub nom Company (No.008126 of 1989), 20–19
Re [1992] B.C.C. 542; [1993] B.C.L.C. 459 Ch D
(Companies Ct)
Halcyon House Ltd v Baines [2014] EWHC 2216 (QB) 16–11, 16–94, 16–100, 16–101
Halifax Plc v Halifax Repossessions Ltd [2004] EWCA Civ 4–24, 4–28
331; [2004] B.C.C. 281; [2004] 2 B.C.L.C. 455; [2004]
F.S.R. 45; (2004) 27(4) I.P.D. 27036; (2004) 148
S.J.L.B. 180
Hall v Cable and Wireless Plc; Martin v Cable and Wireless 26–26, 26–27
Plc; Parry v Cable and Wireless Plc [2009] EWHC 1793
(Comm); [2011] B.C.C. 543; [2010] 1 B.C.L.C. 95;
[2010] Bus. L.R. D40 QBD (Comm)
Hallett v Dowdall, 118 E.R. 1; (1852) 18 Q.B. 2; (1852) 21 2–14
L.J.Q.B. 98 QB
Halt Garage (1964) Ltd, Re [1982] 3 All E.R. 1016 Ch D 12–10, 14–32, 16–124
Hampton Capital Ltd, Re [2015] EWHC 1905 (Ch); [2016] 7–11, 7–16
1 B.C.L.C. 374
Hannam v Financial Conduct Authority [2014] UKUT 233 30–37
(TCC); [2014] Lloyd’s Rep. F.C. 704
Harben v Phillips (1883) L.R. 23 Ch. D. 14 CA 3–28, 15–67
Harborne Road Nominees Ltd v Karvaski [2011] EWHC 20–18
2214 (Ch); [2012] 2 B.C.L.C. 420
Harbro Supplies Ltd v Hampton [2014] EWHC 1781 (Ch) 16–101
Hardoon v Belilios [1901] A.C. 118 PC (HK) 27–8
Harlow v Loveday; sub nom Hill & Tyler Ltd (In 13–47, 13–57
Administration), Re [2004] EWHC 1261 (Ch); [2004]
B.C.C. 732; [2005] 1 B.C.L.C. 41; (2004) 101(26)
L.S.G. 27
Harlowe’s Nominees Pty Ltd v Woodside Oil Co (1968) 16–26
121 C.L.R. 483 High Ct (Aus)
Harman v BML Group Ltd; sub nom BML Group Ltd v 15–54
Harman [1994] 1 W.L.R. 893; [1994] B.C.C. 502;
[1994] 2 B.C.L.C. 674; (1994) 91(21) L.S.G. 40; (1994)
138 S.J.L.B. 91 CA
Harmer, Re; sub nom Harmer (HR), Re [1959] 1 W.L.R. 3–25
62; [1958] 3 All E.R. 689; (1959) 103 S.J. 73 CA
Harold Holdsworth & Co (Wakefield) Ltd v Caddies; sub 8–11
nom Caddies v Holdsworth & Co [1955] 1 W.L.R. 352;
[1955] 1 All E.R. 725; 1955 S.C. (H.L.) 27; 1955 S.L.T.
133; (1955) 99 S.J. 234 HL
Harris v A Harris Ltd; sub nom A Harris v Harris Ltd, 1936 16–124, 19–4
S.C. 183; 1936 S.L.T. 227 IH
Harris v Beauchamp Bros [1894] 1 Q.B. 801 CA 32–37
Harris v Secretary of State for Business, Innovation and 10–3
Skills; sub nom Clenaware Systems Ltd, Re [2013]
EWHC 2514 (Ch); [2015] B.C.C. 283; [2014] 1
B.C.L.C. 447
Harris Simons Construction Ltd, Re [1989] 1 W.L.R. 368; 32–44
(1989) 5 B.C.C. 11; [1989] B.C.L.C. 202; [1989] P.C.C.
229; (1989) 86(8) L.S.G. 43; (1989) 133 S.J. 122 Ch D
(Companies Ct)
Hawk Insurance Co Ltd, Re [2001] EWCA Civ 241; [2002] 29–6, 29–9
B.C.C. 300; [2001] 2 B.C.L.C. 480
Hawkes Bay Milk Corp Ltd v Watson [1974] 1 N.Z.L.R. 5–25
218
Hawkes v Cuddy; sub nom Neath Rugby Ltd, Re [2009] 20–19, 20–22
EWCA Civ 291; [2010] B.C.C. 597; [2009] 2 B.C.L.C.
427
Hawkesbury Development Co Ltd v Landmark Finance Pty 32–39
Ltd (1969) 92 WN (NSW) 199
Hawks v McArthur [1951] 1 All E.R. 22 Ch D 27–8, 27–10
Haysport Properties Ltd v Ackerman [2016] EWHC 393 16–11
Heald v O’Connor [1971] 1 W.L.R. 497; [1971] 2 All E.R. 13–56, 13–57
1105; (1970) 115 S.J. 244 QBD
Hearts of Oak Assurance Co Ltd v Att Gen [1932] A.C. 392 18–9
HL
Hedley Byrne & Co Ltd v Heller & Partners Ltd [1964] 22–44, 25–32, 25–38, 25–40
A.C. 465; [1963] 3 W.L.R. 101; [1963] 2 All E.R. 575;
[1963] 1 Lloyd’s Rep. 485; (1963) 107 S.J. 454 HL
Hellenic & General Trust, Re [1976] 1 W.L.R. 123; [1975] 29–8
3 All E.R. 382; (1975) 119 S.J. 845 Ch D
Helmet Integrated Systems Ltd v Tunnard [2006] EWCA 16–11
Civ 1735; [2007] I.R.L.R. 126; [2007] F.S.R. 16
Hely-Hutchinson v Brayhead Ltd [1968] 1 Q.B. 549; [1967] 7–12, 7–18, 7–20, 7–21, 16–30, 16–63,
3 W.L.R. 1408; [1967] 3 All E.R. 98; (1967) 111 S.J. 16–113
830 CA (Civ Div)
Henderson v Bank of Australasia (1890) L.R. 45 Ch. D. 330 15–47
CA
Henderson v Merrett Syndicates Ltd (No.1); Deeny v 16–20
Gooda Walker Ltd (Duty of Care); Feltrim
Underwriting Agencies Ltd v Arbuthnott; Hughes v
Merrett Syndicates Ltd; Hallam-Eames v Merrett
Syndicates Ltd; sub nom Arbuthnott v Fagan;
McLarnon Deeney v Gooda Walker Ltd; Gooda Walker
Ltd v Deeny [1995] 2 A.C. 145; [1994] 3 W.L.R. 761;
[1994] 3 All E.R. 506; [1994] 2 Lloyd’s Rep. 468;
[1994] C.L.C. 918; (1994) 144 N.L.J. 1204 HL
Henry Head & Co Ltd v Ropner Holdings Ltd [1952] Ch. 11–7
124; [1951] 2 All E.R. 994; [1951] 2 Lloyd’s Rep. 348;
[1951] 2 T.L.R. 1027; (1951) 95 S.J. 789 Ch D
Hepburn v Revenue and Customs Commissioners [2013] 5–25
UKFTT 445 (TC); [2013] S.T.I. 3031
Hercules Management Ltd v Ernst & Young (1997) 146 22–51
D.L.R. (4th) 577 Sup Ct (Can)
Heron International Ltd v Lord Grade; sub nom Heron 17–38, 28–34
International Ltd v Lew Grade [1983] B.C.L.C. 244;
[1982] Com. L.R. 108 CA (Civ Div)
Hickman v Kent or Romney Marsh Sheepbreeders 3–18, 3–23, 3–24, 3–25, 3–26
Association [1915] 1 Ch. 881 Ch D
Hilder v Dexter [1902] A.C. 474 HL 11–5
Hill & Tyler Ltd (In Administration), Re. See Harlow v
Loveday
Hill v Spread Trustee Co Ltd; sub nom Nurkowski, Re 33–18
[2006] EWCA Civ 542; [2007] Bus. L.R. 1213; [2007]
1 W.L.R. 2404; [2007] 1 All E.R. 1106; [2006] B.C.C.
646; [2007] 1 B.C.L.C. 450; [2006] B.P.I.R. 789; [2006]
W.T.L.R. 1009
Hillman v Crystal Bowl Amusements; Hillman v Ireton 15–72
Properties; Hillman v Calgary Development Co [1973]
1 W.L.R. 162; [1973] 1 All E.R. 379; (1972) 117 S.J. 69
CA (Civ Div)
Hindle v John Cotton Ltd (1919) 56 S.L.T. 625 16–29
Hirsche v Sims [1894] A.C. 654 PC 16–29
Hivac Ltd v Park Royal Scientific Instruments Ltd [1946] 16–100
Ch. 169 CA
HL Bolton Engineering Co Ltd v TJ Graham & Sons Ltd 7–40
[1957] 1 Q.B. 159; [1956] 3 W.L.R. 804; [1956] 3 All
E.R. 624; (1956) 100 S.J. 816 CA
HLC Environmental Projects Ltd, Re [2013] EWHC 2876 9–14, 16–26, 16–42, 16–133
(Ch); [2014] B.C.C. 337
Ho Tung v Man On Insurance Co Ltd [1902] A.C. 232 PC 15–19
Hoare & Co Ltd, Re (1933) 150 L.T. 374 28–74
Hodge v James Howell & Co [1958] C.L.Y. 446 CA 19–16
Hogg v Cramphorn [1967] Ch. 254; [1966] 3 W.L.R. 995; 3–25, 16–26, 16–30, 16–113
[1966] 3 All E.R. 420; (1966) 110 S.J. 887 Ch D
Hoicrest Ltd, Re; sub nom Keene v Martin [2000] 1 W.L.R. 27–19
414; [2000] B.C.C. 904; [2000] 1 B.C.L.C. 194; (1999)
96(44) L.S.G. 39; (1999) 143 S.J.L.B. 26 CA (Civ Div)
Holders Investment Trust, Re [1971] 1 W.L.R. 583; [1971] 19–12
2 All E.R. 289; (1970) 115 S.J. 202 Ch D
Holdsworth & Co v Caddies. See Harold Holdsworth & Co
(Wakefield) Ltd v Caddies
Hollicourt (Contracts) Ltd (In Liquidation) v Bank of 33–18
Ireland; sub nom Bank of Ireland v Hollicourt
(Contracts) Ltd; Claughton (Liquidator of Hollicourt
(Contracts) Ltd) v Bank of Ireland [2001] Ch. 555;
[2001] 2 W.L.R. 290; [2001] 1 All E.R. 289; [2001] 1
All E.R. (Comm) 357; [2001] Lloyd’s Rep. Bank. 6;
[2000] B.C.C. 1210; [2001] 1 B.C.L.C. 233; [2001]
B.P.I.R. 47; (2000) 97(45) L.S.G. 41 CA (Civ Div)
Holmes v Lord Keyes [1959] Ch. 199; [1958] 2 W.L.R. 15–75
772; [1958] 2 All E.R. 129; (1958) 102 S.J. 329 CA
Home & Colonial Insurance Co Ltd, Re [1930] 1 Ch. 102; 33–16
(1929) 34 Ll. L. Rep. 463 Ch D
Home & Office Fire Extinguishers Ltd, Re [2012] EWHC 20–13
917 (Ch)
Home Treat Ltd, Re [1991] B.C.C. 165; [1991] B.C.L.C. 3–22
705 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Hooper v Western Counties and South Wales Telephone Co 31–7
Ltd (1892) 68 LT 78
Hopkins v TL Dallas Group Ltd; Hopkins v TL Dallas & 7–18, 7–24
Co Ltd [2004] EWHC 1379 (Ch); [2005] 1 B.C.L.C.
543
Houghton v Nothard Lowe & Wills. See JC Houghton & Co
v Nothard Lowe & Wills Ltd
Houghton v Saunders [2015] 2 N.Z.L.R. 74 5–3
House of Fraser Plc v ACGE Investments Ltd; sub nom 19–16
ACGE Investments v House of Fraser; House of Fraser,
Re; House of Fraser Plc, Petitioner [1987] A.C. 387;
[1987] 2 W.L.R. 1083; 1987 S.C. (H.L.) 125; 1987
S.L.T. 421; 1987 S.C.L.R. 637; (1987) 3 B.C.C. 201;
[1987] B.C.L.C. 478; [1987] B.C.L.C. 293; [1987]
P.C.C. 364; [1987] 1 F.T.L.R. 54; (1987) 84 L.S.G. 491;
(1987) 131 S.J. 593 HL
Howard v Patent Ivory Manufacturing Co; sub nom Patent 7–12
Ivory Manufacturing Co, Re (1888) L.R. 38 Ch. D. 156
Ch D
Howard Smith Ltd v Ampol Petroleum Ltd [1974] A.C. 16–26, 16–27, 16–29, 16–30, 16–31,
821; [1974] 2 W.L.R. 689; [1974] 1 All E.R. 1126; 118 16–43
S.J.L.B. 330; (1974) 118 S.J. 330 PC (Aus)
Hudson Bay Apparel Brands LLC v Umbro International 7–19, 7–20
Ltd [2010] EWCA Civ 949; [2011] 1 B.C.L.C. 259;
[2010] E.T.M.R. 62 CA (Civ Div)
Hunt v Edge & Ellison Trustees Ltd; sub nom Torvale 7–12, 15–17, 15–20
Group Ltd, Re Ch D (Companies Ct)
Hunter v Hunter [1936] A.C. 222 HL 27–8
Hunter v Senate Support Services Ltd [2004] EWHC 1085 16–30, 16–43
(Ch); [2005] 1 B.C.L.C. 175
Hunting Plc, Re [2004] EWHC 2591 (Ch); [2005] 2 13–34, 19–16, 23–6
B.C.L.C. 211
Hurst v Crampton Bros (Coopers) Ltd [2002] EWHC 1375 27–7
(Ch); [2003] B.C.C. 190; [2003] 1 B.C.L.C. 304; [2003]
W.T.L.R. 659; [2002] 2 P. & C.R. DG21
Hussain v Wycombe Islamic Mission and Mosque Trust Ltd 15–19
[2011] EWHC 971 (Ch); [2011] Arb. L.R. 23; (2011)
108(20) L.S.G. 23
Hutton v Scarborough Cliff Hotel Co (Limited), B, 62 E.R. 23–6
717; (1865) 2 Drew. & Sm. 521 Ct of Chancery
Hutton v West Cork Ry (1883) L.R. 23 Ch. D. 654 (1883) 16–37, 16–140
L.R. 23 Ch. D. 654 CA
Hyde Management Services (Pty) Ltd v FAI Insurances 31–7
(1979–80) 144 C.L.R. 541 High Ct (Aus)
Hydrodan (Corby) Ltd (In Liquidation), Re; sub nom 9–7, 16–9, 32–4
Hydrodam (Corby) Ltd (In Liquidation), Re [1994]
B.C.C. 161; [1994] 2 B.C.L.C. 180 Ch D
I Fit Global Ltd, Re [2013] EWHC 2090 (Ch); [2014] 2 20–2, 27–19
B.C.L.C. 116
IC Johnson & Co Ltd, Re [1902] 2 Ch. 101 CA 32–30
Iesini v Westrip Holdings Ltd [2009] EWHC 2526 (Ch); 17–11, 17–19, 17–20, 17–21
[2010] B.C.C. 420; [2011] 1 B.C.L.C. 498
IFE Fund SA v Goldman Sachs International [2007] EWCA 31–28
Civ 811; [2007] 2 Lloyd’s Rep. 449; [2007] 2 C.L.C.
134; (2007) 104(32) L.S.G. 24
Igroup Ltd v Ocwen; sub nom IGroup Ltd, Re [2003] 32–31
EWHC 2431 (Ch); [2004] 1 W.L.R. 451; [2003] 4 All
E.R. 1063; [2003] B.C.C. 993; [2004] 2 B.C.L.C. 61;
(2003) 100(46) L.S.G. 24
IJL v United Kingdom (29522/95); GMR v United 18–14
Kingdom (30056/96); AKP v United Kingdom
(30574/96) [2002] B.C.C. 380; (2001) 33 E.H.R.R. 11;
9 B.H.R.C. 222; [2001] Crim. L.R. 133 ECHR
Illingworth v Houldsworth; sub nom Houldsworth v 32–6, 32–21
Yorkshire Woolcombers Association Ltd; Yorkshire
Woolcombers Association Ltd, Re [1904] A.C. 355 HL
Imam-Sadeque v Bluebay Asset Management (Services) 16–94
Ltd [2012] EWHC 3511 (QB); [2013] I.R.L.R. 344
Imperial Mercantile Credit Association (In Liquidation) v 16–60, 16–62, 16–103, 16–114, 16–137
Coleman; Imperial Mercantile Credit Association (In
Liquidation) v Knight; sub nom Liquidators of the
Imperial Mercantile Credit Association v Edward John
Coleman and John Watson Knight (1873) L.R. 6 H.L.
189
In a Flap Envelope Co Ltd, Re; sub nom Willmott v Jenkin 13–40
[2003] EWHC 3047 (Ch); [2003] B.C.C. 487; [2004] 1
B.C.L.C. 64
In Plus Group Ltd v Pyke [2002] EWCA Civ 370; [2003] 16–100, 16–101
B.C.C. 332; [2002] 2 B.C.L.C. 201
Industrial Development Consultants Ltd v Cooley [1972] 1 16–92, 16–94, 16–95, 16–101, 16–127
W.L.R. 443; [1972] 2 All E.R. 162; (1972) 116 S.J. 255
Assizes (Birmingham)
Industrial Equity (Pacific) Ltd, Re [1991] 2 H.K.L.R. 614 29–8
Industries and General Mortgage Co Ltd v Lewis [1949] 2 16–107
All E.R. 573; [1949] W.N. 333; (1949) 93 S.J. 577 KBD
Ing Re (UK) Ltd v R&V Versicherung AG [2006] EWHC 7–23, 7–27
1544 (Comm); [2006] 2 All E.R. (Comm) 870; [2007] 1
B.C.L.C. 108; [2006] Lloyd’s Rep. I.R. 653
IRC v Crossman; IRC v Mann; sub nom Paulin, Re; 23–2
Crossman, Re [1937] A.C. 26 HL
IRC v Lawrence; sub nom FJL Realisations Ltd, Re [2001] 32–41
B.C.C. 663; [2001] 1 B.C.L.C. 204; [2001] I.C.R. 424
CA (Civ Div)
IRC v Richmond; sub nom Loquitur, Re [2003] EWHC 999 16–112
(Ch); [2003] S.T.C. 1394; [2003] 2 B.C.L.C. 442; 75
T.C. 77; [2003] S.T.I. 1029; [2003] S.T.I. 1873
Inn Spirit Ltd v Burns [2002] EWHC 1731 (Ch); [2002] 2 12–14
B.C.L.C. 780; [2003] B.P.I.R. 413
Inquiry under the Company Securities (Insider Dealing) Act 18–2
1985 (No.1), Re; sub nom Investigation under the
Insider Dealing Act, Re; Lindsay v Warner [1988] A.C.
660; [1988] 2 W.L.R. 33; [1988] 1 All E.R. 203; (1988)
4 B.C.C. 35; [1988] B.C.L.C. 153; [1988] P.C.C. 133;
(1988) 85(4) L.S.G. 33; (1987) 137 N.L.J. 1181; (1988)
132 S.J. 21 HL
INS Realisations Ltd, Re. See Secretary of State for Trade
and Industry v Jonkler
Instant Access Properties Ltd, Re [2011] EWHC 3022 (Ch); 10–7
[2012] 1 B.C.L.C. 710
International Game Technology Plc, Re [2015] EWHC 717 29–19, 29–22
(Ch); [2015] Bus. L.R. 844; [2015] B.C.C. 866; [2015]
2 B.C.L.C. 45
International Sales & Agencies Ltd v Marcus [1982] 3 All 7–11, 7–15
E.R. 551; [1982] 2 C.M.L.R. 46 QBD
Inverdeck Ltd, Re [1998] B.C.C. 256; [1998] 2 B.C.L.C. 27–7
242 Ch D
Investigation under the Insider Dealing Act, Re. See Inquiry
under the Company Securities (Insider Dealing) Act
1985 (No.1), Re
Invideous Ltd v Thorogood [2014] EWCA Civ 1511 16–98
Ireland v Hart [1902] 1 Ch. 522 Ch D 27–10
Irvine v Irvine [2006] EWHC 406 (Ch); [2007] 1 B.C.L.C. 20–10, 20–19
349
Irvine v Union Bank of Australia (1876–77) L.R. 2 App. 7–8, 14–11
Cas. 366 PC (India)
Island Export Finance Ltd v Umunna [1986] B.C.L.C. 460 16–94, 16–101
Isle of Thanet Electric Supply Co, Re [1950] Ch. 161; 23–8
[1949] 2 All E.R. 1060; (1950) 94 S.J. 32 CA
Isle of Wight Ry v Tahourdin (1884) L.R. 25 Ch. D. 320 14–6
CA
IT Human Resources Plc v Land [2014] EWHC 3812 (Ch); 16–45
[2016] F.S.R. 10
Item Software (UK) Ltd v Fassihi; sub nom Fassihi v Item 16–11, 16–45, 16–100
Software (UK) Ltd [2004] EWCA Civ 1244; [2004]
B.C.C. 994; [2005] 2 B.C.L.C. 91; [2005] I.C.R. 450;
[2004] I.R.L.R. 928; (2004) 101(39) L.S.G. 34; (2004)
148 S.J.L.B. 1153
It’s a Wrap (UK) Ltd (In Liquidation) v Gula [2006] 12–12
EWCA Civ 544; [2006] B.C.C. 626; [2006] 2 B.C.L.C.
634; (2006) 103(21) L.S.G. 24
J Sainsbury Plc v O’Connor (Inspector of Taxes) [1991] 1 27–16
W.L.R. 963; [1991] S.T.C. 529; [1991] S.T.C. 318; 64
T.C. 208; [1991] B.T.C. 181; [1991] S.T.I. 529; (1991)
135 S.J.L.B. 46 CA (Civ Div)
J&S Insurance & Financial Consultants Ltd, Re [2014] 20–10, 20–13
EWHC 2206 (Ch)
Jackson & Bassford Ltd, Re [1906] 2 Ch. 467 Ch D 32–14
Jacobus Marler Estates Ltd v Marler (1913) 85 L.J.P.C. 5–18, 5–19, 16–113
167n
Jalmoon Pty Ltd (in liquidation) v Bow (1997) 15 A.C.L.C. 15–17
230
James v Thomas Kent & Co [1951] 1 K.B. 551; [1950] 2 14–55
All E.R. 1099; [1951] 1 T.L.R. 552; (1951) 95 S.J. 29
CA
James McNaughton Paper Group Ltd v Hicks Anderson & 22–50
Co [1991] 2 Q.B. 113; [1991] 2 W.L.R. 641; [1991] 1
All E.R. 134; [1990] B.C.C. 891; [1991] B.C.L.C. 235;
[1991] E.C.C. 186; [1955–95] P.N.L.R. 574; (1990) 140
N.L.J. 1311 CA (Civ Div)
James R Rutherford & Sons, Re; sub nom Lloyds Bank v 32–15
Winter [1964] 1 W.L.R. 1211; [1964] 3 All E.R. 137;
(1964) 108 S.J. 563 Ch D
Janata Bank v Ahmed [1981] I.C.R. 791; [1981] I.R.L.R. 16–12
457 CA (Civ Div)
Jarvis Plc v PricewaterhouseCoopers [2001] B.C.C. 670; 22–19
[2000] 2 B.C.L.C. 368; (2000) 150 N.L.J. 1109 Ch D
(Companies Ct)
JC Houghton & Co v Nothard Lowe & Wills Ltd [1928] 7–22
A.C. 1; (1927–28) 29 Ll. L. Rep. 63 HL
JE Cade & Son Ltd, Re [1991] B.C.C. 360; [1992] B.C.L.C. 20–8, 20–9, 33–6
213 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Jeavons Ex p. Mackay, Re; sub nom Jeavons Ex p. Brown, 33–20
Re (1872–73) L.R. 8 Ch. App. 643 CA
JEB Fasteners Ltd v Marks Bloom & Co [1983] 1 All E.R. 22–46, 22–52, 28–64
583 CA (Civ Div)
Jelf Group Plc, Re [2016] B.C.C. 289 29–3
Jesner v Jarrad Properties Ltd, 1993 S.C. 34; 1994 S.L.T. 20–13, 20–22
83; [1992] B.C.C. 807; [1993] B.C.L.C. 1032 IH (2
Div)
Jessel Trust Ltd, Re [1985] B.C.L.C. 119 Ch D 29–10
Jetivia SA v Bilta (UK) Ltd. See Bilta (UK) Ltd (In
Liquidation) v Nazir
JH Rayner (Mincing Lane) Ltd v Department of Trade and 2–9
Industry; Maclaine Watson & Co Ltd v Department of
Trade and Industry; Maclaine Watson & Co Ltd v
International Tin Council; TSB England and Wales v
Department of Trade and Industry; Amalgamated Metal
Trading Ltd v International Tin Council [1989] Ch. 72;
[1988] 3 W.L.R. 1033; [1988] 3 All E.R. 257; (1988) 4
B.C.C. 563; [1988] B.C.L.C. 404; [1989] P.C.C. 1;
[1989] P.C.C. 68; (1988) 132 S.J. 1494
JJ Harrison (Properties) Ltd v Harrison [2001] EWCA Civ 16–21, 16–62, 16–112, 16–138
1467; [2002] B.C.C. 729; [2002] 1 B.C.L.C. 162;
[2001] W.T.L.R. 1327
John Crowther Group Plc v Carpets International [1990] 16–35, 28–36
B.C.L.C. 460
John Shaw & Sons (Salford) Ltd v Shaw [1935] 2 K.B. 113 14–6, 17–2
CA
John v Rees; Martin v Davis; Rees v John [1970] Ch. 345; 15–83
[1969] 2 W.L.R. 1294; [1969] 2 All E.R. 274; (1969)
113 S.J. 487 Ch D
John Smith’s Tadcaster Brewery Co Ltd, Re; sub nom John 19–16
Smith’s Tadcaster Brewery Co Ltd v Gresham Life
Assurance Society Ltd [1953] Ch. 308; [1953] 2 W.L.R.
516; [1953] 1 All E.R. 518; (1953) 97 S.J. 150 CA
Johnson v Gore Wood & Co (No.1); sub nom Johnson v 17–35
Gore Woods & Co [2002] 2 A.C. 1; [2001] 2 W.L.R.
72; [2001] 1 All E.R. 481; [2001] C.P.L.R. 49; [2001]
B.C.C. 820; [2001] 1 B.C.L.C. 313; [2001] P.N.L.R. 18;
(2001) 98(1) L.S.G. 24; (2001) 98(8) L.S.G. 46; (2000)
150 N.L.J. 1889; (2001) 145 S.J.L.B. 29 HL
Joint Stock Discount Co, Re; sub nom Shepherd’s Case 27–7
(1866–67) L.R. 2 Ch. App. 16 CA
Joint Stock Discount Co v Brown (No.3) (1869) L.R. 8 Eq. 16–111
381 Ct of Chancery
Jones v Lipman [1962] 1 W.L.R. 832; [1962] 1 All E.R. 8–15
442; (1962) 106 S.J. 531 Ch D
Joseph Holt Plc, Re. See Winpar Holdings Ltd v Joseph
Holt Group Plc
JRRT (Investments) Ltd v Haycraft [1993] B.C.L.C. 401 27–8
Jubilee Cotton Mills Ltd, Re; sub nom Jubilee Cotton Mills 5–3, 5–16
Ltd (Official Receiver and Liquidator) v Lewis [1924]
A.C. 958 HL
Jupiter House Investments (Cambridge) Ltd, Re [1985] 13–36
B.C.L.C. 222
Kamer van Koophandel en Fabrieken voor Amsterdam v 6–7, 6–22, 6–23, 6–29
Inspire Art Ltd (C–167/01) [2003] E.C.R. I–10155;
[2005] 3 C.M.L.R. 34
Karak Rubber Co Ltd v Burden (No.2) [1972] 1 W.L.R. 13–45, 13–57, 13–58
602; [1972] 1 All E.R. 1210; [1972] 1 Lloyd’s Rep. 73;
(1971) 115 S.J. 887 Ch D
Kaupthing Singer & Freidlander Ltd (In Administration),
Re (2011). See Mills v HSBC Trustee (CI) Ltd
Kaupthing Singer & Friedlander Ltd (In Administration), 31–22
Re; sub nom Newcastle Building Society v Mill [2009]
EWHC 740 (Ch); [2009] 2 Lloyd’s Rep. 154; [2009] 2
B.C.L.C. 137
Kaye v Croydon Tramways Co [1898] 1 Ch. 358 CA 15–65
Kaye v Zeital. See Zeital v Kaye
Kaytech International Plc, Re; sub nom Secretary of State 10–5, 10–11, 16–10, 16–8
for Trade and Industry v Kaczer; Potier v Secretary of
State for Trade and Industry; Secretary of State for
Trade and Industry v Potier; Secretary of State for Trade
and Industry v Solly [1999] B.C.C. 390; [1999] 2
B.C.L.C. 351 CA (Civ Div)
Keech v Sandford, 25 E.R. 223; (1726) Sel. Cas. Ch. 61 Ct 16–89
of Chancery
Keenan Bros Ltd, Re [1986] B.C.L.C. 242 Sup Ct (Irl) 32–22
Kellar v Williams [2000] 2 B.C.L.C. 390 PC 11–1
Kelner v Baxter (1866–67) L.R. 2 C.P. 174 CCP 5–24, 5–26
Kemp v Baerselman [1906] 2 K.B. 604 CA 2–22
Kensington International Ltd v Congo [2007] EWCA Civ 8–12
1128; [2008] 1 W.L.R. 1144; [2008] 1 All E.R. (Comm)
934; [2008] 1 Lloyd’s Rep. 161; [2008] C.P. Rep. 6;
[2007] 2 C.L.C. 791; [2008] Lloyd’s Rep. F.C. 107;
(2007) 104(45) L.S.G. 31
Keypak Homecare Ltd (No.2), Re [1990] B.C.C. 117; 10–9
[1990] B.C.L.C. 440 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Khoshkhou v Cooper [2014] EWHC 1087 (Ch) 20–8, 20–19
Kingston Cotton Mill Co (No.1), Re [1896] 1 Ch. 6 CA 22–12
Kingston Cotton Mill Co (No.2), Re [1896] 2 Ch. 279 CA 22–36
Kinlan v Crimmin [2006] EWHC 779 (Ch); [2007] B.C.C. 13–10, 13–20, 15–20
106; [2007] 2 B.C.L.C. 67
Kinsela v Russell Kinsela Pty Ltd [1986] 4 N.S.W.L.R. 722 9–15
Kirby v Wilkins [1929] 2 Ch. 444 Ch D 15–31
Kitson & Co Ltd, Re [1946] 1 All E.R. 435 CA 20–22
Kleanthous v Paphitis [2011] EWHC 2287 (Ch); [2012] 17–21
B.C.C. 676; (2011) 108(36) L.S.G. 19
Kleinwort Benson Ltd v Malaysia Mining Corp Bhd [1989] 8–4
1 W.L.R. 379; [1989] 1 All E.R. 785; [1989] 1 Lloyd’s
Rep. 556; (1989) 5 B.C.C. 337; (1989) 86(16) L.S.G.
35; (1989) 139 N.L.J. 221; (1989) 133 S.J. 262 CA (Civ
Div)
Knight v Lawrence [1991] B.C.C. 411; [1993] B.C.L.C. 32–39, 32–40
215; [1991] 01 E.G. 105; [1990] E.G. 64 (C.S.) Ch D
Knightsbridge Estates Trust Ltd v Byrne [1940] A.C. 613 31–21, 31–6, 31–7
HL
Knowles v Scott [1891] 1 Ch. 717 Ch D 33–16
Konamaneni v Rolls Royce Industrial Power (India) Ltd 17–4
[2002] 1 W.L.R. 1269; [2002] 1 All E.R. 979; [2002] 1
All E.R. (Comm) 532; [2003] B.C.C. 790; [2002] 1
B.C.L.C. 336; [2002] I.L.Pr. 40 Ch D
Koninklijke Philips Electronics NV v Princo Digital Disc 7–36
GmbH [2003] EWHC 2588 (Pat); [2004] 2 B.C.L.C. 50
KR Hardy Estates Ltd, Re [2014] EWHC 4001 (Ch) 20–20
Kreditbank Cassel GmbH v Schenkers Ltd [1927] 1 K.B. 7–19, 7–22, 7–26
826 CA
Kung v Kou (2004) 7 HKCFAR 579 20–16, 20–17
Kuwait Asia Bank EC v National Mutual Life Nominees 9–15, 16–28, 16–36
Ltd [1991] 1 A.C. 187; [1990] 3 W.L.R. 297; [1990] 3
All E.R. 404; [1990] 2 Lloyd’s Rep. 95; [1990] B.C.C.
567; [1990] B.C.L.C. 868 PC
Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Ivens; sub nom 10–5
Country Farm Inns Ltd, Re [1997] B.C.C. 801; [1997] 2
B.C.L.C. 334 CA (Civ Div)
Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Joiner; sub nom 10–9
Synthetic Technology Ltd, Re [1993] B.C.C. 549 Ch D
(Companies Ct)
Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Jonkler; sub 10–2
nom INS Realisations Ltd, Re [2006] EWHC 135 (Ch);
[2006] 1 W.L.R. 3433; [2006] 2 All E.R. 902; [2006]
B.C.C. 307; [2006] 2 B.C.L.C. 239; (2006) 156 N.L.J.
273
Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v McTighe 10–7
(No.1); sub nom Copecrest, Re [1993] B.C.C. 844;
[1994] 2 B.C.L.C. 284 CA (Civ Div)
Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v McTighe 10–9
(No.2); sub nom Secretary of State for Trade and
Industry v McTigue [1997] B.C.C. 224; [1996] 2
B.C.L.C. 477
Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Palfreman, 1995 10–3
S.L.T. 156; 1995 S.C.L.R. 172; [1995] B.C.C. 193;
[1995] 2 B.C.L.C. 301 OH
Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Rayna. See
Cedarwood Productions Ltd, Re
Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Taylor; 10–11
Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Gash; sub
nom Company (No.004803 of 1996), Re; CS Holidays
Ltd, Re [1997] 1 W.L.R. 407; [1997] B.C.C. 172;
[1997] 1 B.C.L.C. 341 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Tjolle [1998] 16–8
B.C.C. 282; [1998] 1 B.C.L.C. 333; (1997) 94(24)
L.S.G. 31; (1997) 141 S.J.L.B. 119 Ch D
Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Van Hengel; sub 10–9, 10–11
nom CSTC Ltd, Re [1995] B.C.C. 173; [1995] 1
B.C.L.C. 545 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Worth; sub nom 10–3
Dicetrade Ltd, Re [1994] B.C.C. 371; [1994] 2 B.C.L.C.
113 CA (Civ Div)
Sedgefield Steeplechase Co (1927) Ltd, Re. See Scotto v
Petch
Segers v Bestuur van de Bedrijfsvereniging voor Bank–-en 6–22
Verzekeringswezen, Groothandel en Vrije Beroepen
(79/85) [1986] E.C.R. 2375; [1987] 2 C.M.L.R. 247
Selangor United Rubber Estates Ltd v Cradock (No.3) 13–45, 13–56, 13–57, 13–58, 16–134
[1968] 1 W.L.R. 1555; [1968] 2 All E.R. 1073; [1968] 2
Lloyd’s Rep. 289; (1968) 112 S.J. 744 Ch D
Selectmove Ltd, Re [1995] 1 W.L.R. 474; [1995] 2 All E.R. 33–5
531; [1995] S.T.C. 406; [1994] B.C.C. 349; 66 T.C. 552
CA (Civ Div)
Seven Holdings Ltd, Re [2011] EWHC 1893 (Ch) 17–21
Sevenoaks Stationers (Retail) Ltd, Re [1991] Ch. 164; 10–3, 10–9, 10–10
[1990] 3 W.L.R. 1165; [1991] 3 All E.R. 578; [1990]
B.C.C. 765; [1991] B.C.L.C. 325; (1990) 134 S.J. 1367
CA (Civ Div)
Sevic Systems AG v Amtsgericht Neuwied (C–411/03) 29–16
[2006] All E.R. (EC) 363; [2005] E.C.R. I–10805;
[2006] 2 B.C.L.C. 510; [2006] 1 C.M.L.R. 45; [2006]
C.E.C. 355
Shahar v Tsitsekkos; Kolomoisky v Shahar [2004] EWHC 15–17
2659 (Ch)
Sharma v Sharma [2013] EWCA Civ 1287; [2014] B.C.C. 16–86, 16–98, 16–118
73; [2014] W.T.L.R. 111
Sharp v Blank [2015] EWHC 3220 (Ch) 16–5, 16–6
Sharpley v Louth and East Coast Ry Co (1875–76) L.R. 2 25–39
Ch. D. 663 CA
Shearer v Bercain Ltd [1980] 3 All E.R. 295; [1980] S.T.C. 11–5, 11–7
359; 63 T.C. 698; [1980] T.R. 93; (1980) 124 S.J. 292
Ch D
Sheffield (Earl of) v London Joint Stock Bank Ltd; sub nom 27–10
Easton v London Joint Stock Bank (1888) L.R. 13 App.
Cas. 333 HL
Shepherd’s Case. See Joint Stock Discount Co, Re
Shepherds Investments Ltd v Walters [2006] EWHC 836 16–11, 16–45
(Ch); [2007] 2 B.C.L.C. 202; [2007] I.R.L.R. 110;
[2007] F.S.R. 15; (2006) 150 S.J.L.B. 536
Sheppard & Cooper Ltd v TSB Bank Plc (No.2) [1996] 2 32–37
All E.R. 654; [1996] B.C.C. 965 Ch D
Sherborne Associates Ltd, Re [1995] B.C.C. 40 QBD 9–9
(Mercantile Ct)
Sherborne Park Residents Co Ltd, Re (1986) 2 B.C.C. 3–25, 16–31
99528 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Shindler v Northern Raincoat Co [1960] 1 W.L.R. 1038; 14–55
[1960] 2 All E.R. 239; (1960) 104 S.J. 806 Assizes
(Manchester)
Shipway v Broadwood [1899] 1 Q.B. 369 CA 16–108
Short v Treasury Commissioners [1948] A.C. 534; [1948] 2 2–16, 23–1, 23–3
All E.R. 509; 64 T.L.R. 400; [1949] L.J.R. 143; (1948)
92 S.J. 573 HL
Shropshire Union Railways and Canal Co v R. (on the 27–10
Prosecution of Robson) (1874–75) L.R. 7 H.L. 496 HL
Shuttleworth v Cox Bros & Co (Maidenhead) Ltd [1927] 2 3–31, 19–8, 19–9, 19–10
K.B. 9 CA
Sidebottomv Kershaw Leese & Co Ltd [1920] 1 Ch. 154 19–8, 19–9
CA
Siebe Gorman & Co Ltd v Barclays Bank Ltd; sub nom 32–10, 32–21, 32–22
Siebe Gorman & Co Ltd v RH McDonald Ltd [1979] 2
Lloyd’s Rep. 142 Ch D
Sikorski v Sikorski [2012] EWHC 1613 (Ch) 20–10
Simm v Anglo-American Telegraph Co; Anglo-American 27–5
Telegraph Co v Spurling (1879–80) L.R. 5 Q.B.D. 188
CA
Simo Securities Trust, Re [1971] 1 W.L.R. 1455; [1971] 3 28–72
All E.R. 999; (1971) 115 S.J. 755 Ch D
Simtel Communications Ltd v Rebak [2006] EWHC 572 16–12
(QB); [2006] 2 B.C.L.C. 571
Sinclair Investments (UK) Ltd v Versailles Trade Finance 16–53, 16–108, 16–115
Ltd (In Administration) [2011] EWCA Civ 347; [2012]
Ch. 453; [2011] 3 W.L.R. 1153; [2011] 4 All E.R. 335;
[2011] Bus. L.R. 1126; [2011] 2 B.C.L.C. 501; [2011]
W.T.L.R. 1043; [2011] 2 P. & C.R. DG6
Singer v Beckett; sub nom Continental Assurance Co of 9–8, 9–9
London Plc (In Liquidation), Re [2007] 2 B.C.L.C. 287;
[2001] B.P.I.R. 733 Ch D
Singh v Singh [2014] EWCA Civ 103 17–21
Singla v Hedman [2010] EWHC 902 (Ch); [2010] B.C.C. 9–9
684; [2010] 2 B.C.L.C. 61
Sipad Holding v Popovic (1995) 19 A.C.S.R. 108 32–41
Skandinaviska Enskilda Banken AB (Publ), Singapore 7–23, 7–33
Branch v Asia Pacific Breweries (Singapore) Pte Ltd
[2011] SGCA 22 CA (Sing)
Skopas, The. See Resolute Maritime Inc v Nippon Kaiji
Kyokai (The Skopas)
Slavenburg’s Bank NV v Intercontinental Natural 2–32
Resources [1980] 1 W.L.R. 1076; [1980] 1 All E.R.
955; (1980) 124 S.J. 374 QBD
Smith v Bridgend CBC. See Smith (Administrator of
Cosslett (Contractors) Ltd) v Bridgend CBC
Smith v Butler [2012] EWCA Civ 314; [2012] Bus. L.R. 15–54
1836; [2012] B.C.C. 645
Smith v Croft (No.2) [1988] Ch. 114; [1987] 3 W.L.R. 405; 13–57, 17–21
[1987] 3 All E.R. 909; (1987) 3 B.C.C. 207; [1987]
B.C.L.C. 206; [1986] P.C.C. 209; [1987] 1 F.T.L.R.
319; (1987) 84 L.S.G. 2449; (1987) 131 S.J. 1038 Ch D
Smith v Croft (No.3) (1987) 3 B.C.C. 218; [1987] B.C.L.C. 19–6
355 Ch D
Smith v Henniker-Major & Co [2002] EWCA Civ 762; 7–12, 7–13, 7–27, 16–30
[2003] Ch. 182; [2002] 3 W.L.R. 1848; [2002] B.C.C.
768; [2002] 2 B.C.L.C. 655; (2002) 99(37) L.S.G. 36
Smith v Van Gorkam (1985) 488 A. 2d 858 16–18
Smith v White Knight Laundry Ltd [2001] EWCA Civ 660; 33–33
[2002] 1 W.L.R. 616; [2001] 3 All E.R. 862; [2001]
C.P. Rep. 88; [2003] B.C.C. 319; [2001] 2 B.C.L.C.
206; [2001] P.I.Q.R. P30
Smith & Fawcett Ltd, Re [1942] Ch. 304 CA 16–27, 16–40, 16–41, 16–43, 16–43,
27–7
Smith (Administrator of Cosslett (Contractors) Ltd) v 32–2, 32–22
Bridgend CBC; sub nom Cosslett (Contractors) Ltd (In
Administration) (No.2), Re [2001] UKHL 58; [2002] 1
A.C. 336; [2001] 3 W.L.R. 1347; [2002] 1 All E.R. 292;
[2001] B.C.C. 740; [2002] 1 B.C.L.C. 77; [2002] B.L.R.
160; [2002] T.C.L.R. 7; 80 Con. L.R. 172; [2001]
N.P.C. 161
Smith New Court Securities Ltd v Citibank NA; sub nom 5–17, 25–37, 25–39
Smith New Court Securities Ltd v Scrimgeour Vickers
(Asset Management) Ltd [1997] A.C. 254; [1996] 3
W.L.R. 1051; [1996] 4 All E.R. 769; [1997] 1 B.C.L.C.
350; [1996] C.L.C. 1958; (1996) 93(46) L.S.G. 28;
(1996) 146 N.L.J. 1722; (1997) 141 S.J.L.B. 5 HL
Smith Stone & Knight Ltd v Birmingham Corp [1939] 4 All 8–8
E.R. 116
Smithton Ltd (formerly Hobart Capital Markets Ltd) v 16–8, 16–9, 16–10, 16–70, 16–71
Naggar [2014] EWCA Civ 939; [2015] 1 W.L.R. 189;
[2014] B.C.C. 482; [2015] 2 B.C.L.C. 22; (2014)
158(29) S.J.L.B. 37
Société Générale v Walker; sub nom Société Générale de 27–10
Paris v Tramways Union Co Ltd (1886) L.R. 11 App.
Cas. 20 HL
Soden v British & Commonwealth Holdings Plc (In 33–26
Administration) [1998] A.C. 298; [1997] 3 W.L.R. 840;
[1997] 4 All E.R. 353; [1997] B.C.C. 952; [1997] 2
B.C.L.C. 501; (1997) 94(41) L.S.G. 28; (1997) 147
N.L.J. 1546 HL
Sound City (Films) Ltd, Re [1947] Ch. 169; [1946] 2 All 19–15
E.R. 521; 62 T.L.R. 677; [1947] L.J.R. 220; 176 L.T.
28; (1946) 90 S.J. 629 Ch D
South African Supply and Cold Storage Co, Re; sub nom 29–2
Wild v. South African Supply & Cold Storage Co
[1904] 2 Ch. 268 Ch D
South African Territories Ltd v Wallington [1898] A.C. 309 31–7
HL
South India Shipping Corp v Export-Import Bank of Korea 6–4
[1985] 1 W.L.R. 585; [1985] 2 All E.R. 219; [1985] 1
Lloyd’s Rep. 413; (1985) 1 B.C.C. 99350; [1985]
P.C.C. 125; [1985] Fin. L.R. 106; (1985) 82 L.S.G.
1005; (1985) 129 S.J. 268 CA (Civ Div)
South London Greyhound Racecourses Ltd v Wake [1931] 7–19, 7–22
1 Ch. 496 Ch D
South Western Mineral Water Co Ltd v Ashmore [1967] 1 13–56, 13–57
W.L.R. 1110; [1967] 2 All E.R. 953; (1967) 111 S.J.
453 Ch D
Southern v Watson [1940] 3 All E.R. 439 CA 8–13
Southern Foundries (1926) Ltd v Shirlaw [1940] A.C. 701; 14–55, 19–26, 19–27
[1940] 2 All E.R. 445 HL
Sovereign Life Assurance Co (In Liquidation) v Dodd 29–8
[1892] 2 Q.B. 573 CA
Sowman v Samuel (David) Trust Ltd (In Liquidation) 32–4
[1978] 1 W.L.R. 22; [1978] 1 All E.R. 616; (1978) 36 P.
& C.R. 123; (1977) 121 S.J. 757 Ch D
Spector Photo Group NV v Commissie voor het Bank-, 30–32
Financie- en Assurantiewezen (CBFA) (C–45/08)
[2010] Bus. L.R. 1416; [2010] All E.R. (EC) 278;
[2009] E.C.R. I–12073; [2011] B.C.C. 827; [2010] 2
B.C.L.C. 200; [2010] 2 C.M.L.R. 30; [2010] C.E.C.
591; [2010] Lloyd’s Rep. F.C. 295
Spectrum Plus Ltd (In Liquidation), Re; sub nom National 32–10, 32–6, 32–21, 32–23
Westminster Bank Plc v Spectrum Plus Ltd (In
Creditors Voluntary Liquidation) [2005] UKHL 41;
[2005] 2 A.C. 680; [2005] 3 W.L.R. 58; [2005] 4 All
E.R. 209; [2005] 2 Lloyd’s Rep. 275; [2005] B.C.C.
694; [2005] 2 B.C.L.C. 269; (2005) 155 N.L.J. 1045
Spence v Crawford [1939] 3 All E.R. 271; 1939 S.C. (H.L.) 5–17, 16–113
52; 1939 S.L.T. 305 HL
Spies v R. [2000] HCA 43; [2000] 201 C.L.R. 603 9–15
Sportech Plc, Petr [2012] CSOH 58; 2012 S.L.T. 895 13–36
Springbok Agricultural Estates Ltd, Re [1920] 1 Ch. 563 Ch 23–8
D
St Piran Ltd, Re [1981] 1 W.L.R. 1300; [1981] 3 All E.R. 20–12, 28–9
270; (1981) 125 S.J. 586 Ch D
St Regis Paper Company Ltd v R. See R. v St Regis Paper
Co Ltd
Stablewood v Virdi [2010] EWCA Civ 865; [2011] 27–8
W.T.L.R. 723; [2010] All E.R. (D) 204
Stainer v Lee [2010] EWHC 1539 (Ch); [2011] B.C.C. 134; 17–20, 17–27
[2011] 1 B.C.L.C. 537
Stakefield (Midlands) Ltd, Re; sub nom Secretary of State 10–6
for Business, Innovation and Skills v Doffman [2010]
EWHC 3175 (Ch); [2011] 2 B.C.L.C. 541
Stakefield (Midlands) Ltd, Re; sub nom Secretary of State 10–9
for Business, Innovation and Skills v Doffmann (No.2)
[2010] EWHC 3175 (Ch); [2011] 2 B.C.L.C. 541
Standard Chartered Bank Ltd v Walker [1982] 1 W.L.R. 32–37, 32–38
1410; [1982] 3 All E.R. 938; [1982] Com. L.R. 233;
(1982) 264 E.G. 345; (1982) 79 L.S.G. 1137; 264 S.J.
479 CA (Civ Div)
Standard Chartered Bank v Pakistan National Shipping 7–32
Corp (No.2); Standard Chartered Bank v Mehra [2002]
UKHL 43; [2003] 1 A.C. 959; [2002] 3 W.L.R. 1547;
[2003] 1 All E.R. 173; [2002] 2 All E.R. (Comm) 931;
[2003] 1 Lloyd’s Rep. 227; [2002] B.C.C. 846; [2003] 1
B.C.L.C. 244; [2002] C.L.C. 1330; (2003) 100(1)
L.S.G. 26; (2002) 146 S.J.L.B. 258 HL
Stanford Services, Re (1987) 3 B.C.C. 326; [1987] B.C.L.C. 10–10
607; [1987] P.C.C. 343 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Stanhope’s Case. See Agriculturist Cattle Insurance Co, Re
Stanley (Henry Morton), Re; sub nom Tennant v Stanley 1–1
[1906] 1 Ch. 131 Ch D
Staples v Eastman Photographic Materials Co [1896] 2 Ch. 23–8
303 CA
Starglade Properties Ltd v Nash [2010] EWCA Civ 1314; 16–135
[2011] Lloyd’s Rep. F.C. 102; [2011] 1 P. & C.R. DG17
Steedman v Frigidaire Corp [1933] 1 D.L.R. 161 PC 5–17
Steen v Law [1964] A.C. 287; [1963] 3 W.L.R. 802; [1963] 13–57
3 All E.R. 770 PC (Aus)
Stein v Blake (No.1) [1996] A.C. 243; [1995] 2 W.L.R. 33–23
710; [1995] 2 All E.R. 961; [1995] B.C.C. 543; [1995] 2
B.C.L.C. 94; (1995) 145 N.L.J. 760 HL
Stein v Blake (No.2) [1998] 1 All E.R. 724; [1998] B.C.C. 17–37
316; [1998] 1 B.C.L.C. 573 CA (Civ Div)
Steinberg v Scala (Leeds) Ltd [1923] 2 Ch. 452 CA 23–1
Stepney Corp v Osofsky [1937] 3 All E.R. 289 CA 2–19
Stewarts (Brixton) Ltd, Re [1985] B.C.L.C. 4 20–14
Sticky Fingers Restaurant Ltd, Re [1991] B.C.C. 754; 15–54
[1992] B.C.L.C. 84 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Stimpson v Southern Landlords Association [2009] EWHC 17–18
2072 (Ch); [2010] B.C.C. 387
Stocznia Gdanska SA v Latreefers Inc; Stocznia Gdanska 6–8
SA v Latvian Shipping Co (Abuse of Process); sub nom
Latreefers Inc, Re [2000] C.P.L.R. 65; [2001] B.C.C.
174; [2001] 2 B.C.L.C. 116; [2001] C.L.C. 126
Stone & Rolls Ltd (In Liquidation) v Moore Stephens (A 16–4, 22–41
Firm); sub nom Moore Stephens (A Firm) v Stone &
Rolls Ltd (In Liquidation) [2009] UKHL 39; [2009] 1
A.C. 1391; [2009] 3 W.L.R. 455; [2009] Bus. L.R.
1356; [2009] 4 All E.R. 431; [2010] 1 All E.R. (Comm)
125; [2009] 2 Lloyd’s Rep. 537; [2009] 2 B.C.L.C. 563;
[2009] 2 C.L.C. 121; [2009] Lloyd’s Rep. F.C. 557;
[2009] B.P.I.R. 1191; [2009] P.N.L.R. 36; (2009) 159
N.L.J. 1218; (2009) 153(31) S.J.L.B. 28
Stonegate Securities Ltd v Gregory [1980] Ch. 576; [1980] 33–5
3 W.L.R. 168; [1980] 1 All E.R. 241; (1980) 124 S.J.
495 CA (Civ Div)
Stothers v William Steward (Holdings) Ltd [1994] 2 27–7
B.C.L.C. 266; 1994] B.C.C. 284 CA (Civ Div)
Strahan v Wilcock [2006] EWCA Civ 13; [2006] B.C.C. 20–7, 20–19
320; [2006] 2 B.C.L.C. 555; (2006) 103(6) L.S.G. 30
Stroud Architectural Services Ltd v John Laing 32–11
Construction Ltd [1994] B.C.C. 18; [1994] 2 B.C.L.C.
276; 35 Con. L.R. 135; (1993) 9 Const. L.J. 337 QBD
Stupples v Stupples & Co (High Wycombe) Ltd [2012] 16–45
EWHC 1226 (Ch); [2013] 1 B.C.L.C. 729
Stylo Shoes Ltd v Prices Tailors Ltd [1960] Ch. 396; [1960] 33–5
2 W.L.R. 8; [1959] 3 All E.R. 901; (1960) 104 S.J. 16
Ch D
Suburban and Provincial Stores, Re [1943] Ch.156 CA 19–15
Sugarman v CJS Investments LLP [2014] EWCA Civ 1239; 15–46
[2015] 1 B.C.L.C. 1; [2014] 3 E.G.L.R. 127; [2015] 1 P.
& C.R. DG11
Sukhoruchkin v Van Bekestein [2014] EWCA Civ 399 16–9
Sunrise Radio Ltd, Re [2009] EWHC 2893 (Ch); [2010] 1 11–5
B.C.L.C. 367
Supply of Ready Mixed Concrete (No.2), Re. See Director
General of Fair Trading v Pioneer Concrete (UK) Ltd
Surrey Garden Village Trust, Re; sub nom Addington 33–6
Smallholders, Re [1965] 1 W.L.R. 974; [1964] 3 All
E.R. 962; (1965) 109 S.J. 552 Ch D
Sutherland (Duke of) v British Dominions Land Settlement 27–7
Corp Ltd [1926] Ch. 746 Ch D
Sutherland v British Dominions Corp. See Duke of
Sutherland v British Dominions Land Settlement Corp
Ltd
Swabey v Port Darwin Gold Mining Co (1889) 1 Meg. 385 14–55
CA
Swaledale Cleaners Ltd, Re [1968] 1 W.L.R. 1710; [1968] 27–7
3 All E.R. 619; (1968) 112 S.J. 781 CA (Civ Div)
Swallow Footwear Ltd, Re, Times, 23 October 1956 32–37
Swift 736 Ltd, Re. See Secretary of State for Trade and
Industry v Ettinger
Swiss Bank Corp v Lloyds Bank Ltd [1979] Ch. 548; 31–27
[1979] 3 W.L.R. 201; [1979] 2 All E.R. 853; (1979) 123
S.J. 536 Ch D
Sybron Corp v Rochem Ltd [1984] Ch. 112; [1983] 3 16–11
W.L.R. 713; [1983] 2 All E.R. 707; [1983] I.C.R. 801;
[1983] I.R.L.R. 253; (1983) 127 S.J. 391 CA (Civ Div)
Sycotex Pty Ltd v Baseler (1994) 122 A.L.R. 531 9–15
Synthetic Technology Ltd, Re. See Secretary of State for
Trade and Industry v Joiner
System Controls Plc v Munro Corporate Plc; sub nom 11–15
Systems Controls v Monro Corporate [1990] B.C.C.
386; [1990] B.C.L.C. 659 Ch D
Systemcare (UK) Ltd v Services Design Technology Ltd 8–8
[2011] EWCA Civ 546; [2012] 1 B.C.L.C. 14; [2011] 4
Costs L.R. 666
T&N Ltd, Re [2006] EWHC 1447 (Ch); [2007] Bus. L.R. 29–4, 29–5, 29–9
1411; [2007] 1 All E.R. 851; [2007] 1 B.C.L.C. 563;
[2006] B.P.I.R. 1283; [2006] Lloyd’s Rep. I.R. 817
Target Holdings Ltd v Redferns [1996] A.C. 421; [1995] 3 12–14
W.L.R. 352; [1995] 3 All E.R. 785; [1995] C.L.C. 1052;
(1995) 139 S.J.L.B. 195; [1995] N.P.C. 136 HL
Tatung (UK) Ltd v Galex Telesure Ltd (1989) 5 B.C.C. 325 32–11
QBD (Comm Ct)
Taupo Totara Timber Co v Rowe [1978] A.C. 537; [1977] 3 14–62, 28–32
W.L.R. 466; [1977] 3 All E.R. 123; (1977) 121 S.J. 692
PC (NZ)
Tay Bok Choon v Tahansan Sdn Bhd [1987] 1 W.L.R. 413; 20–7
(1987) 3 B.C.C. 132; [1987] B.C.L.C. 472; (1987) 84
L.S.G. 900; (1987) 131 S.J. 473 PC
Taylor v National Union of Mineworkers (Derbyshire Area) 3–29, 17–1
(Injunction) [1985] I.R.L.R. 99; [1985] B.C.L.C. 237
High Ct
Taylor v Walker [1958] 1 Lloyd’s Rep. 490 QBD 16–107, 16–108
Tech Textiles Ltd, Re; sub nom Secretary of State for Trade 10–3
and Industry v Vane [1998] 1 B.C.L.C. 259 Ch D
(Companies Ct)
Teck Corp Ltd v Millar (1972) 33 D.L.R. (3d) 288 Sup Ct 16–26
(BC)
Teekay Tankers Ltd v STX Offshore & Shipping Co [2014] 6–4, 6–5
EWHC 3612 (Comm); [2015] 2 All E.R. (Comm) 263;
[2015] Bus. L.R. 731; [2015] 2 B.C.L.C. 210; [2014] 2
C.L.C. 763
Telewest Communications Plc (No.1), Re [2004] EWCA 29–9
Civ 728; [2005] B.C.C. 29; [2005] 1 B.C.L.C. 752
Telewest Communications Plc (No.2), Re [2004] EWHC 29–11
1466 (Ch); [2005] B.C.C. 36; [2005] 1 B.C.L.C. 772
Telomatic Ltd, Re; sub nom Barclays Bank Plc v Cyprus 32–26, 32–30
Popular Bank Ltd [1993] B.C.C. 404; [1994] 1 B.C.L.C.
90 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Tennent v City of Glasgow Bank (In Liquidation) (1878– 25–39
79) L.R. 4 App. Cas. 615; (1879) 6 R. (H.L.) 69 HL
Tesco Stores Ltd v Brent LBC [1993] 1 W.L.R. 1037; 7–40, 7–41
[1993] 2 All E.R. 718; (1994) 158 J.P. 121; (1994) 13
Tr. L.R. 87; [1993] C.O.D. 280; (1994) 158 L.G. Rev.
78; (1993) 137 S.J.L.B. 93 DC
Tesco Stores Ltd v Pook [2003] EWHC 823 (Ch); [2004] 16–11
I.R.L.R. 618
Tesco Supermarkets Ltd v Nattrass [1972] A.C. 153; [1971] 7–40, 7–41
2 W.L.R. 1166; [1971] 2 All E.R. 127; 69 L.G.R. 403;
(1971) 115 S.J. 285 HL
Tett v Phoenix Property & Investment Co Ltd (1986) 2 27–7, 27–8
B.C.C. 99140; [1986] P.C.C. 210; [1986] B.C.L.C. 149;
(1986) 83 L.S.G. 116; (1985) 129 S.J. 869 CA (Civ
Div)
Theakston v London Trust Plc (1984) 1 B.C.C. 99095; 27–7
[1984] B.C.L.C. 390 Ch D
Thermascan Ltd v Norman [2009] EWHC 3694 (Ch); 16–13
[2011] B.C.C. 535
Thomas v Maxwell; sub nom Inquiry into Mirror Group 18–7
Newspapers Plc, Re [2000] Ch. 194; [1999] 3 W.L.R.
583; [1999] 2 All E.R. 641; [2000] B.C.C. 217; [1999] 1
B.C.L.C 690; (1999) 96(14) L.S.G. 31 Ch D
(Companies Ct)
Thomas Gerrard & Son Ltd, Re [1968] Ch. 455; [1967] 3 22–36
W.L.R. 84; [1967] 2 All E.R. 525; (1967) 111 S.J. 329
Ch D
Thomas Mortimer Ltd, Re [1965] Ch. 186 (Note); [1964] 3 32–14
W.L.R. 427 (Note) Ch D
Thomas Witter Ltd v TBP Industries Ltd [1996] 2 All E.R. 25–39
573 Ch D
Thompson v Renwick Group Plc [2014] EWCA Civ 635; 8–10, 16–36
[2015] B.C.C. 855; [2014] 2 B.C.L.C. 97; [2014]
P.I.Q.R. P18
Thorby v Goldberg (1964) 112 C.L.R. 597 High Ct (Aus) 16–35
Thorn EMI Plc, Re (1988) 4 B.C.C. 698; [1989] B.C.L.C. 13–38
612 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Thorniley v Revenue and Customs Commissioners; sub 32–17
nom Airbase (UK) Ltd, Re; Airbase Services
International Ltd, Re [2008] EWHC 124 (Ch); [2008] 1
W.L.R. 1516; [2008] Bus. L.R. 1076; [2008] B.C.C.
213; [2008] 1 B.C.L.C. 436
Threlfall v ECD Insight Ltd [2012] EWHC 3543 (QB); 16–11
[2013] I.R.L.R. 185
Thundercrest Ltd, Re [1994] B.C.C. 857; [1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 24–12
117 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Tiessen v Henderson [1899] 1 Ch. 861 Ch D 15–47, 15–65
Tilt Cove Copper Co Ltd, Re; sub nom Trustees Executors 32–37
and Securities Insurance Corp Ltd v Tilt Cove Copper
Co Ltd [1913] 2 Ch. 588 Ch D
Timmis, Re; sub nom Nixon v Smith [1902] 1 Ch. 176 Ch 16–138
D
Tintin Exploration Syndicate v Sandys (1947) 177 L.T. 412 11–14
TM Kingdom Ltd (In Administration), Re [2007] EWHC 32–50
3272 (Ch); [2007] B.C.C. 480
Tobian Properties, Re. See Annacott Holdings Ltd, Re
Tolhurst v Associated Portland Cement [1902] 2 K.B. 660 2–22
CA
Top Creative Ltd v St Albans DC [1999] B.C.C. 999; 33–32
[2000] 2 B.C.L.C. 379 CA (Civ Div)
Topham v Charles Topham Group Ltd [2002] EWHC 1096 11–20
(Ch); [2003] 1 B.C.L.C. 123
Torvale Group Ltd, Re. See Hunt v Edge & Ellison Trustees
Ltd
Toshoku Finance UK Plc (In Liquidation), Re; sub nom 33–24
Khan v IRC; Kahn v IRC; IRC v Kahn [2002] UKHL 6;
[2002] 1 W.L.R. 671; [2002] 3 All E.R. 961; [2002]
S.T.C. 368; [2002] B.C.C. 110; [2002] 1 B.C.L.C. 598;
[2002] B.P.I.R. 790; [2003] R.V.R. 106; [2002] B.T.C.
69; [2002] S.T.I. 237; (2002) 99(12) L.S.G. 33; (2002)
146 S.J.L.B. 55
Tottenham Hotspur Plc, Re [1994] 1 B.C.L.C. 655 Ch D 20–8
Touche v Metropolitan Ry Warehousing Co (1870–71) L.R. 5–21
6 Ch. App. 671 LC
Towcester Racecourse Co Ltd v Racecourse Association 3–21, 16–5
Ltd [2002] EWHC 2141 (Ch); [2003] 1 B.C.L.C. 260;
(2002) 99(45) L.S.G. 34
Towers v Premier Waste Management Ltd [2011] EWCA 16–95, 16–98, 16–101
Civ 923; [2012] B.C.C. 72; [2012] 1 B.C.L.C. 67;
[2012] I.R.L.R. 73
Transatlantic Life Assurance Co, Re [1980] 1 W.L.R. 79; 27–19
[1979] 3 All E.R. 352; (1979) 123 S.J. 859 Ch D
Transbus International Ltd (In Liquidation), Re [2004] 32–45
EWHC 932 (Ch); [2004] 1 W.L.R. 2654; [2004] 2 All
E.R. 911; [2004] B.C.C. 401; [2004] 2 B.C.L.C. 550
TransTec Plc, Re. See Secretary of State for Trade and
Industry v Carr
Transvaal Lands Co v New Belgium (Transvaal) Land & 16–52, 16–60, 16–113
Development Co [1914] 2 Ch. 488; 84 L.J. Ch. 94; 21
Mans. 364; [1914–15] All E.R. Rep. 987; 59 S.J. 27;
112 L.T. 965; 31 T.L.R. 1 CA
Travel Mondial (UK) Ltd, Re [1991] B.C.C. 224; [1991] 10–9
B.C.L.C. 120 Ch D (Companies Ct)
Trebanog Working Men’s Club and Institute Ltd v 8–8
MacDonald; Monkwearmouth Conservative Club Ltd v
Smith [1940] 1 K.B. 576 KBD
Trevor v Whitworth (1887) L.R. 12 App. Cas. 409 HL 12–8, 13–2, 13–44
Truculent, The. See Admiralty v Owners of the Divina (The
HMS Truculent)
Trustor AB v Smallbone (No.2) [2001] 1 W.L.R. 1177; 16–137
[2001] 3 All E.R. 987; [2002] B.C.C. 795; [2001] 2
B.C.L.C. 436; (2001) 98(20) L.S.G. 40; (2001) 151
N.L.J. 457; (2001) 145 S.J.L.B. 99 Ch D
TSB Nuclear Energy Investment UK Ltd, Re [2014] EWHC 29–12
1272 (Ch); [2014] B.C.C. 531
Tse Kwong Lam v Wong Chit Sen [1983] 1 W.L.R. 1349; 32–38
[1983] 3 All E.R. 54; (1983) 80 L.S.G. 2368; (1983)
127 S.J. 632 PC (HK)
Tudor Grange Holdings Ltd v Citibank NA [1992] Ch. 53; 32–39
[1991] 3 W.L.R. 750; [1991] 4 All E.R. 1; [1991]
B.C.L.C. 1009; (1991) 135 S.J.L.B. 3 Ch D
Tulsesense Ltd, Re; sub nom Rolfe v Rolfe [2010] EWHC 15–17, 15–19
244 (Ch); [2010] 2 B.C.L.C. 525; [2010] Bus. L.R. D99
Tussaud v Tussaud (1890) L.R. 44 Ch. D. 678 Ch D 4–25
Twinsectra Ltd v Yardley [2002] UKHL 12; [2002] 2 A.C. 16–135
164; [2002] 2 W.L.R. 802; [2002] 2 All E.R. 377;
[2002] P.N.L.R. 30; [2002] W.T.L.R. 423; [2002] 38
E.G. 204 (C.S.); (2002) 99(19) L.S.G. 32; (2002) 152
N.L.J. 469; (2002) 146 S.J.L.B. 84; [2002] N.P.C. 47
Twomax Ltd v Dickinson, McFarlane & Robinson, 1982 22–46
S.C. 113; 1983 S.L.T. 98 OH
Twycross v Grant (No.1) (1876–77) L.R. 2 C.P.D. 469 CA 5–3, 5–4
UBAF Ltd v European American Banking Corp (The 31–28
Pacific Colocotronis); Illustrious Colocotronis, The
[1984] Q.B. 713; [1984] 2 W.L.R. 508; [1984] 2 All
E.R. 226; [1984] 1 Lloyd’s Rep. 258; (1984) 81 L.S.G.
429; (1984) 128 S.J. 243 CA (Civ Div)
Uberseering BV v Nordic Construction Co Baumanagement 6–24, 6–25
GmbH (NCC) (C–208/00) [2005] 1 W.L.R. 315; [2002]
E.C.R. I–9919; [2005] 1 C.M.L.R. 1
UK Safety Group Ltd v Hearne [1998] 2 B.C.L.C. 208 Ch 14–31
D
Ultraframe (UK) Ltd v Fielding; Burnden Group Plc v 9–14, 16–9, 16–14, 16–71, 16–100, 16–
Northstar Systems Ltd (In Liquidation); Northstar 114, 16–135, 16–137, 32–8
Systems Ltd (In Liquidation) v Fielding [2005] EWHC
1638 (Ch); [2006] F.S.R. 17; [2007] W.T.L.R. 835;
(2005) 28(9) I.P.D. 28069
Ultramares Corp v Touche (1931) 174 N.E. 441 22–32
Unidare Plc v Cohen; sub nom Kilnoore Ltd (In 27–8
Liquidation), Re [2005] EWHC 1410 (Ch); [2006] Ch.
489; [2006] 2 W.L.R. 974; [2005] 3 All E.R. 730;
[2006] 2 B.C.L.C. 140; [2005] B.P.I.R. 1472
Union Music Ltd v Watson; Arias Ltd v Blacknight Ltd 15–54
[2003] EWCA Civ 180; [2004] B.C.C. 37; [2003] 1
B.C.L.C. 453
Uniq Plc, Re [2011] EWHC 749 (Ch); [2012] 1 B.C.L.C. 29–11
783; [2012] Bus. L.R. D18
United Australia Ltd v Barclays Bank Ltd [1941] A.C. 1; 16–108
[1940] 4 All E.R. 20 HL
United Pan Europe Communications NV v Deutsche Bank 16–110
AG [2000] 2 B.C.L.C. 461 CA (Civ Div)
University of Nottingham v Fishel [2000] I.C.R. 1462; 16–11
[2000] I.R.L.R. 471; [2001] R.P.C. 22; [2000] Ed. C.R.
505; [2000] E.L.R. 385; (2001) 24(2) I.P.D. 24009 QBD
Uruguay Central and Hygueritas Ry Co of Monte Video, Re 31–14
(1879) 11 Ch. D. 372 Ch D
US v Carpenter (1986) 791 F. 2d 1024 30–19
US v Chiarella (1980) 445 U.S. 222 30–22
Uxbridge Permanent Benefit Building Society v Pickard 7–19, 7–33
[1939] 2 K.B. 248 CA
VALE Epitesi kft’s Application (C–378/10) [2013] 1 6–26
W.L.R. 294; [2012] 3 C.M.L.R. 41; [2013] C.E.C. 422
ECJ (3rd Chamber)
Valletort Sanitary Steam Laundry Co Ltd, Re [1903] 2 Ch. 32–11
654 Ch D
Vandepitte v Preferred Accident Insurance Corp of New 31–14
York [1933] A.C. 70; (1932) 44 Ll. L. Rep. 41 PC
(Canada)
Vectone Entertainment Holding Ltd v South Entertainment 15–54
Ltd [2004] EWHC 744 (Ch); [2005] B.C.C. 123; [2004]
2 B.C.L.C. 224
Victor Battery Co Ltd v Curry’s Ltd [1946] Ch. 242 Ch D 13–56
Victoria Housing Estates Ltd v Ashpurton Estates Ltd; sub 32–30
nom Ashpurton Estates Ltd, Re [1983] Ch. 110; [1982]
3 W.L.R. 964; [1982] 3 All E.R. 665 CA (Civ Div)
Victoria Steamboats Co, Re [1897] 1 Ch. 158 Ch D 32–8, 32–37
Village Cay Marina Ltd v Acland [1998] B.C.C. 417; 27–7
[1998] 2 B.C.L.C. 327 PC
Vintage Hallmark Plc, Re; sub nom Secretary of State for 10–10
Trade and Industry v Grove [2006] EWHC 2761 (Ch);
[2008] B.C.C. 150; [2007] 1 B.C.L.C. 788
Virdi v Abbey Leisure. See Abbey Leisure Ltd, Re
Vivendi SA v Richards [2013] EWHC 3006 (Ch); [2013] 16–8, 16–9, 16–10
B.C.C. 771; [2013] Bus. L.R. D63
Vodafone Group Plc, Re [2014] EWHC 1357 (Ch); [2014] 13–36
B.C.C. 554; [2014] 2 B.C.L.C. 422
VTB Capital Plc v Nutritek International Corp [2013] 8–15, 8–16
UKSC 5; [2013] 2 A.C. 337; [2013] 2 W.L.R. 398;
[2013] 1 All E.R. 1296; [2013] 1 All E.R. (Comm)
1009; [2013] 1 Lloyd’s Rep. 466; [2013] B.C.C. 514;
[2013] 1 B.C.L.C. 179; [2013] 1 C.L.C. 153
W&M Roith Ltd, Re [1967] 1 W.L.R. 432; [1967] 1 All 16–41, 16–43
E.R. 427; (1966) 110 S.J. 963 Ch D
Waddington Ltd v Chan Chun Hoo Thomas [2009] 2 17–35
B.C.L.C. 82 CA (HK)
Walker v Standard Chartered Bank; Jasaro SA v Standard 14–51
Chartered Bank [1992] B.C.L.C. 535 CA (Civ Div)
Walker v Wimborne (1976) 137 C.L.R. 1 9–12
Wallace v Universal Automatic Machines Co [1894] 2 Ch. 32–8
547 CA
Wallach v Secretary of State for Trade and Industry; sub 9–22
nom Genosyis Technology Management Ltd, Re [2006]
EWHC 989 (Ch); [2007] 1 B.C.L.C. 208
Wallersteiner v Moir (No.1); sub nom Moir v Wallersteiner 13–45, 13–56, 13–57
(No.1) [1974] 1 W.L.R. 991; [1974] 3 All E.R. 217;
(1974) 118 S.J. 464 CA (Civ Div)
Wallersteiner v Moir (No.2) [1975] Q.B. 373; [1975] 2 17–27
W.L.R. 389; [1975] 1 All E.R. 849; (1975) 119 S.J. 97
CA (Civ Div)
Walls Properties Ltd v PJ Walls Holdings Ltd [2008] 1 I.R. 27–8
732
Walter Symons Ltd, Re [1934] Ch. 308 Ch D 23–8
Warman International Ltd v Dwyer (1995) 182 CLR 544 16–114
High Ct (Aus)
Waste Recycling Group Plc, Re [2003] EWHC 2065 (Ch); 29–11
[2004] B.C.C. 328; [2004] 1 B.C.L.C. 352; [2004] Env.
L.R. D2
Watson v Duff, Morgan & Vermont (Holdings) [1974] 1 32–30
W.L.R. 450; [1974] 1 All E.R. 794; (1973) 117 S.J. 910
Ch D
Watts v Financial Services Authority [2005] UKFSM 30–52
FSM022
Watts v Midland Bank Plc [1986] B.C.L.C. 15; (1986) 2 32–39
B.C.C. 98961 Ch D
Weatherford Global Products Ltd v Hydropath Holdings 16–94
Ltd [2014] EWHC 2725 (TCC); [2015] B.L.R. 69
Weavering Capital (UK) Ltd (In Liquidation) v Dabhia 16–17
[2013] EWCA Civ 71; [2015] B.C.C. 741
Webb v Earle (1875) L.R. 20 Eq. 556 Ct of Chancery 23–8
Webb, Hale & Co v Alexandria Water Co (1905) 21 T.L.R. 24–22
572
Webster v Sandersons Solicitors [2009] EWCA Civ 830; 17–35
[2009] 2 B.C.L.C. 542; [2009] P.N.L.R. 37; [2010]
Pens. L.R. 169; (2009) 106(32) L.S.G. 15
Welch v Bank of England [1955] Ch. 508; [1955] 2 W.L.R. 27–5
757; [1955] 1 All E.R. 811; (1955) 99 S.J. 236 Ch D
Welfab Engineers Ltd, Re [1990] B.C.L.C. 833 9–14
Welsh Development Agency v Export Finance Co Ltd 32–2, 32–3, 32–37, 32–40
[1992] B.C.C. 270; [1992] B.C.L.C. 148 CA (Civ Div)
WeSellCNC.com Ltd, Re [2013] EWHC 4577 (Ch) 33–15
Wessex Computer Stationers Ltd, Re [1992] B.C.L.C. 366 20–21
West Canadian Collieries, Re [1962] Ch. 370; [1961] 3 15–66
W.L.R. 1416; [1962] 1 All E.R. 26; (1961) 105 S.J.
1126 Ch D
West Mercia Safetywear Ltd (In Liquidation) v Dodd. See
Liquidator of West Mercia Safetywear Ltd v Dodd
Westbourne Galleries, Re. See Ebrahimi v Westbourne
Galleries Ltd
Westburn Sugar Refineries Ltd v IRC, 1960 S.L.T. 297; 53 12–3
R. & I.T. 365; 39 T.C. 45; (1960) 39 A.T.C. 128; [1960]
T.R. 105 IH (1 Div)
Westdeutsche Landesbank Girozentrale v Islington LBC 16–112
[1996] A.C. 669; [1996] 2 W.L.R. 802; [1996] 2 All
E.R. 961; [1996] 5 Bank. L.R. 341; [1996] C.L.C. 990;
95 L.G.R. 1; (1996) 160 J.P. Rep. 1130; (1996) 146
N.L.J. 877; (1996) 140 S.J.L.B. 136 HL
Westmid Packing Services Ltd (No.2), Re; sub nom 10–3, 10–10, 16–17
Westmid Packaging Services Ltd (No.3), Re; Secretary
of State for Trade and Industry v Griffiths (No.2) [1998]
2 All E.R. 124; [1998] B.C.C. 836; [1998] 2 B.C.L.C.
646
Westminster Corp v Haste [1950] Ch. 442; [1950] 2 All 32–18
E.R. 65; 66 T.L.R. (Pt. 1) 1083; (1950) 114 J.P. 340; 49
L.G.R. 67 Ch D
Westminster Property Group Plc, Re [1985] 1 W.L.R. 676; 28–53
[1985] 2 All E.R. 426; (1985) 1 B.C.C. 99355; [1985]
P.C.C. 176; (1985) 82 L.S.G. 1085; (1985) 129 S.J. 115
CA (Civ Div)
Westminster Property Management Ltd (No.1), Re; sub 10–7, 18–14
nom Official Receiver v Stern (No.1) [2000] 1 W.L.R.
2230; [2001] 1 All E.R. 633; [2001] B.C.C. 121; [2000]
2 B.C.L.C. 396; [2000] U.K.H.R.R. 332 CA (Civ Div)
Westminster Property Management Ltd (No.3), Re; sub 16–120, 19–6
nom Official Receiver v Stern (No.3) [2001] EWCA
Civ 1787; [2004] B.C.C. 581; [2002] 1 B.C.L.C. 119
Whaley Bridge Calico Printing Co v Green; Whaley Bridge 5–3, 5–4, 5–16
Calico Printing Co v Smith (1879–80) L.R. 5 Q.B.D.
109 QBD
Wharfedale Brewery Co Ltd, Re [1952] Ch. 913; [1952] 2 23–8
All E.R. 635; [1952] 2 T.L.R. 543 Ch D
Wheatley v Silkstone & Haigh Moor Coal Co (1885) L.R. 32–10
29 Ch. D. 715 Ch D
White v Bristol Aeroplane Co; sub nom British Aeroplane 19–16, 19–17
Co, Re [1953] Ch. 65; [1953] 2 W.L.R. 144; [1953] 1
All E.R. 40; (1953) 97 S.J. 64 CA
White Horse Distillers Ltd v Gregson Associates Ltd [1984] 7–36
R.P.C. 61 Ch D
White Star Line Ltd, Re [1938] Ch. 458 CA 11–14
Whitehouse v Carlton House Pty (1987) 162 C.L.R. 285 HC 16–29
(Aus)
Wilkinson v West Coast Capital [2005] EWHC 3009 (Ch); 16–96
[2007] B.C.C. 717
Will v United Lankat Plantations Co Ltd [1914] A.C. 11 HL 23–8
William C Leitch Bros Ltd, Re (No.1) [1932] 2 Ch. 71 Ch 9–5
D
William Metcalfe & Sons Ltd, Re [1933] Ch. 142 CA 23–7
Williams v Central Bank of Nigeria [2014] UKSC 10; 16–135, 16–139
[2014] A.C. 1189; [2014] 2 W.L.R. 355; [2014] 2 All
E.R. 489; [2014] W.T.L.R. 873; 16 I.T.E.L.R. 740;
(2014) 164(7596) N.L.J. 16
Williams v Natural Life Health Foods Ltd [1998] 1 W.L.R. 7–32, 22–34, 22–35
830; [1998] 2 All E.R. 577; [1998] B.C.C. 428; [1998] 1
B.C.L.C. 689; (1998) 17 Tr. L.R. 152; (1998) 95(21)
L.S.G. 37; (1998) 148 N.L.J. 657; (1998) 142 S.J.L.B.
166 HL
Williams v Redcard Ltd. See Redcard Ltd v Williams
Williams & Glyn’s Bank Ltd v Barnes [1981] Com. L.R. 31–25
205 High Ct
Wilson Lovatt & Sons Ltd, Re [1977] 1 All E.R. 274 Ch D 33–16
Wilson v Kelland [1910] 2 Ch. 306 Ch D 32–11
Windsor Steam Coal Co (1901) Ltd, Re [1928] Ch. 609 Ch 33–16
D
Winkworth v Edward Baron Development Co Ltd [1986] 1 9–15
W.L.R. 1512; [1987] 1 All E.R. 114; (1987) 3 B.C.C. 4;
[1987] B.C.L.C. 193; [1987] 1 F.L.R. 525; [1987] 1
F.T.L.R. 176; (1987) 53 P. & C.R. 378; [1987] Fam.
Law 166; (1987) 84 L.S.G. 340; (1986) 130 S.J. 954 HL
Winpar Holdings Ltd v Joseph Holt Group Plc; sub nom 28–71
Joseph Holt Plc, Re [2001] EWCA Civ 770; [2002]
B.C.C. 174; [2001] 2 B.C.L.C. 604; (2001) 98(28)
L.S.G. 42
Winthrop Investments Ltd v Winns Ltd [1975] 2 16–26, 16–31
N.S.W.L.R. 666 CA (NSW)
Wise v Perpetual Trustee Co Ltd [1903] A.C. 139 PC (Aus) 27–8
Wise v Union of Shop, Distributive and Allied Workers 3–25
[1996] I.C.R. 691; [1996] I.R.L.R. 609 Ch D
Wishart, Petr; sub nom Wishart v Castlecroft Securities Ltd 17–27
[2009] CSIH 65; 2010 S.C. 16; 2009 S.L.T. 812; 2009
S.C.L.R. 696; [2010] B.C.C. 161; 2009 G.W.D. 28–446
Wishart v Castlecroft Securities Ltd [2010] CSIH 2; 2010 17–27
S.L.T. 371; 2010 G.W.D. 6–101
WJ Hall & Co, Re; sub nom WJ Hall & Co Ltd, Re [1909] 23–8
1 Ch. 521 Ch D
Wood Preservation v Prior [1969] 1 W.L.R. 1077; [1969] 1 27–8
All E.R. 364; 45 T.C. 112; [1968] T.R. 353; (1968) 112
S.J. 927 CA
Wood, Skinner & Co Ltd, Re [1944] Ch. 323 Ch D 23–8
Woodford v Smith [1970] 1 W.L.R. 806; [1970] 1 All E.R. 15–67
1091 (Note); (1970) 114 S.J. 245 Ch D
Woodfull v Lindsley [2004] EWCA Civ 165; [2004] 2 16–94
B.C.L.C. 131; (2004) 148 S.J.L.B. 263
Woodroffes (Musical Instruments) Ltd, Re [1986] Ch. 366; 32–8, 32–9
[1985] 3 W.L.R. 543; [1985] 2 All E.R. 908; [1985]
P.C.C. 318; (1985) 82 L.S.G. 3170; (1985) 129 S.J. 589
Ch D
Woods v Winskill [1913] 2 Ch. 303 Ch D 32–18
Woolfson v Strathclyde RC; sub nom Woolfson v Glasgow 8–8
Corp, 1978 S.C. (H.L.) 90; 1978 S.L.T. 159; (1979) 38
P. & C.R. 521; (1978) 248 E.G. 777; [1979] J.P.L. 169
HL
Woven Rugs Ltd, Re [2002] 1 B.C.L.C. 324 Ch D 15–54
Wragg, Re [1897] 1 Ch. 796 CA 11–14
Wrexham Associated Football Club Ltd (In Administration) 7–8, 7–25
v Crucialmove Ltd [2006] EWCA Civ 237; [2007]
B.C.C. 139; [2008] 1 B.C.L.C. 508
Wright v Atlas Wright (Europe) Ltd; sub nom Atlas Wright 15–15, 15–17, 15–18, 15–20
(Europe) Ltd v Wright [1999] B.C.C. 163; [1999] 2
B.C.L.C. 301; (1999) 96(8) L.S.G. 29 CA (Civ Div)
Yagerphone Ltd, Re [1935] Ch. 392 Ch D 9–10
Yeovil Glove Co, Re [1965] Ch. 148; [1964] 3 W.L.R. 406; 32–14
[1964] 2 All E.R. 849; (1964) 108 S.J. 499 CA
Yorkshire Woolcombers Association Ltd, Re. See
Illingworth v Houldsworth
Yuen Kun Yeu v Att Gen of Hong Kong [1988] A.C. 175; 4–5
[1987] 3 W.L.R. 776; [1987] 2 All E.R. 705; [1987]
F.L.R. 291; (1987) 84 L.S.G. 2049; (1987) 137 N.L.J.
566; (1987) 131 S.J. 1185 PC
Yukong Line Ltd of Korea v Rendsburg Investments Corp 8–15, 9–15, 16–7, 16–9
of Liberia (The Rialto) [1998] 1 W.L.R. 294; [1998] 4
All E.R. 82; [1998] 1 Lloyd’s Rep. 322; [1998] B.C.C.
870; [1998] 2 B.C.L.C. 485; (1997) 94(39) L.S.G. 39;
(1997) 141 S.J.L.B. 212 QBD (Comm Ct)
Zanzibar (Government of) v British Aerospace (Lancaster 25–39
House) Ltd [2000] 1 W.L.R. 2333; [2000] C.L.C. 735
QBD (Comm Ct)
Zeital v Kaye; sub nom Dalmar Properties Ltd, Re; Kaye v 27–9, 27–16
Zeital [2010] EWCA Civ 159; [2010] 2 B.C.L.C. 1;
[2010] W.T.L.R. 913
Zinotty Properties Ltd, Re [1984] 1 W.L.R. 1249; [1984] 3 27–7
All E.R. 754; (1984) 1 B.C.C. 99139; [1985] P.C.C.
285; (1984) 81 L.S.G. 3589; (1984) 128 S.J. 783 Ch D
TABLE OF STATUTES
s.201(1) 33–27
(2) 33–27
(3) 33–27
(4) 33–27
s.202(1) 33–28
(2) 33–28
(3) 33–28
(4) 33–28
(5) 33–28
s.203(1) 33–28
(2) 33–28
(3) 33–28
(4) 33–28
s.204 33–28
s.205(1) 33–27
(b) 33–27
(2) 33–27
(3) 33–27
(4) 33–27
s.212 12–13, 17–2, 32–47, 33–1, 33–16, 33–
19, 33–16
s.213 6–8, 9–4, 9–5, 9–6, 9–7, 10–13, 33–1,
33–16, 33–19, 33–21
(2) 9–8
ss.213–215 32–46
s.214 6–8, 9–4, 9–6, 9–7, 10–13, 11–9, 16–
15, 32–4, 32–19, 33–1, 33–16, 33–19,
33–21
(1) 9–8
(2) 9–6
(3) 9–6, 9–9
(4) 9–6, 16–15
(6) 9–6
s.215 9–8
(2) 9–8
(3) 9–8
(4) 9–8
(5) 9–7
s.216 4–19, 9–18, 9–17, 9–18, 9–19
(3)(c) 9–18
(6) 9–18
(8) 6–8
s.217 9–18
(1) 9–18
(6) 6–8
Pt V 1–38, 4–37, 6–8, 32–17, 33–2
s.220 6–8
s.221(4) 6–8
s.225 33–2
Pt VI 33–2
s.230(2) 32–15
s.232 32–37
s.233(2)(a) 33–25
(b) 33–25
s.234 32–37
s.235 10–7, 33–7
s.236 10–7, 32–38, 33–7
s.238 12–9, 33–18, 33–21
ss.238–245 33–8
ss.238–246 33–2
s.239 12–9, 33–18, 33–21
s.240(2) 33–18
s.241 33–18
s.245 2–5, 32–14, 32–45, 33–18
(1) 32–14
(2)(a) 32–14
(b) 32–14
(3)(a) 32–14
(b) 32–14
(4) 32–14
(5) 32–14
(6) 32–14
s.246ZA 9–4, 9–5, 9–6
(2) 9–8
ss.246ZA–246ZC 32–46
s.246ZB 9–4, 9–6, 9–7
(1) 9–8
(2) 9–6
(3) 9–6
(4) 9–6
(6) 9–6
s.246ZD 9–10
s.246ZE 33–15
s.246ZF 33–15
Pt VII 33–2
s.247(1) 32–15, 32–38
s.249 32–14
s.251 9–7, 32–7, 32–21, 33–11
s.283(1) 27–21
(3)(a) 27–21
s.306 27–21
s.315 27–21
(3) 27–21
s.336 32–15
s.386 33–25
ss.386–387 32–15
s.387(4)(a) 32–15
Pt XIII 33–7
s.388(1) 32–38
(5) 33–7
s.389(2) 33–7
s.390(1) 32–38
(4) 32–38
(a) 10–16
ss.423–425 2–6
s.435 32–14
Sch.B1 32–43, 32–36
para.3(1) 32–43
(2) 32–35, 32–43
(3) 32–43
(4) 32–43
para.5 32–44
para.11 32–44
para.12 32–44
(1)(a) 32–44
para.14 32–35, 32–44
para.21 32–44
para.22 32–44
para.25(c) 32–44
para.28 32–44
para.36 32–44
para.39 32–45
para.41 32–44
para.42 32–45
para.43 32–45
(4) 32–45
para.44 32–45
para.46 32–44, 32–48
para.45 32–48
para.49(4) 32–45
(5) 32–45
(8) 32–45
para.53(2) 32–45
(3) 32–45
para.59 32–45
para.61 32–45
para.69 32–45
para.70 32–20, 32–45, 33–17
(2) 32–45, 33–17
para.71 32–45, 33–17
(3) 33–17
para.73 32–47
para.74 20–2, 32–47
(2) 32–47
(3) 32–47
(4) 32–47
(5) 32–47
(6) 32–47
para.75 32–47
para.76(2)(b) 32–50
para.78(4) 32–50
para.79(2) 32–50
(3) 32–50
para.99 32–49
(4) 32–46
para.107 32–45
Sch.1 32–4, 32–38, 32–45
Sch.2A 32–36
para.1(1) 32–35
para.2 32–35
(1) 32–37
(2) 32–37
Sch.4 33–7, 33–16, 33–24
Sch.4A 10–16
Sch.6 32–15, 33–7, 33–25
para.8 32–15
para.9 32–15
para.10 32–15
para.11 32–15
Company Directors Disqualification Act (c.46) 1–38, 3–4, 6–8, 10–1, 10–5, 10–12, 10–
14, 10–15, 10–17
s.1 10–1, 10–2
(1) 10–3
(a) 32–42
(b) 10–3
s.1A 10–1, 10–2
(1) 10–3
(b) 10–3
(2) 10–3, 10–5
s.2 10–12, 10–14, 10–16, 30–56
ss.2–5 10–12
s.3 10–14, 32–42
(2) 10–14
s.4 10–12
(1)(b) 10–12
(2) 10–12
s.5 10–14
(1) 10–14
(2) 10–14
s.5A 10–1, 10–12
s.6 10–1, 10–3, 10–5, 10–7
(1) 10–5
(b) 10–5, 10–8
(1A) 10–5
(2) 10–5
(3C) 10–1
(4) 10–3, 10–5
ss.6–8 10–6
s.7 10–1, 10–5
(1) 10–5
(2) 10–7
(2A) 10–5
(3)(d) 32–38
(4) 10–7
s.7A 10–7
s.8ZA(1) 10–6
(2) 10–6
s.8ZC(1) 10–6
s.8ZD(1) 10–6
(3) 10–6
s.8ZE(1) 10–6
s.8 10–1, 10–5, 18–13, 18–14, 30–56
(1) 10–1
(2) 10–5
(2B) 10–5
(4) 10–3, 10–5
s.8A 10–2
s.9 10–8
ss.9A–9E 10–17
s.10 10–13
s.11 10–16
s.12C 10–8
s.13 10–3
s.14 10–3
s.15 10–3, 10–16
(1)(a) 10–3
(b) 10–3
(2) 10–3
s.15A(1) 10–1
(3) 10–4
(4) 10–4
(5) 10–4, 17–10
ss.15A–15C 17–10
s.15B 17–10
(2) 10–4
(3) 10–4
s.16 10–1
(2) 10–12, 10–14
s.17 10–2
s.18 10–15
ss.21A–21C 10–5
s.22(2A) 10–1
(4) 10–5
(5) 10–5
(7) 32–42
ss.22A–22C 10–3, 10–17
ss.22E–22F 10–3, 10–17
Sch.1 10–8
Building Societies Act (c.53) 1–34, 4–1
Financial Services Act (c.60) 3–4
1988 Criminal Justice Act (c.33) 30–54
1989 Companies Act (c.40) 7–25, 9–24, 18–1, 18–3, 18–11, 20–14,
21–17, 21–31, 22–5, 33–11
s.112 7–9
1992 Friendly Societies Act (c.40) 1–34, 4–1
Trade Union and Labour Relations (Consolidation)
Act (c.52)
s.10(3) 4–36
Pt VI Ch.III 16–85
1993 Criminal Justice Act (c.36) 30–15, 30–54
Pt V 30–1, 30–4, 30–11, 30–12
s.52 28–62
(1) 30–12, 30–25
(2)(a) 30–25
(b) 30–25
(3) 30–13, 30–14
s.53 30–26
(1)(a) 30–27
(b) 30–28
(c) 30–27
(2)(a) 30–27
(b) 30–28
(c) 30–27
(3)(a) 30–25
(b) 30–27
(5) 30–26
(6) 30–27
s.54(2) 30–25
s.55 30–25
(1)(b) 30–25
(4) 30–25
(5) 30–25
s.56(1)(b) 30–18
(d) 30–21
(2) 30–25
s.57 30–25, 30–24
(1) 30–32
(2)(a) 30–22
(b) 30–23
s.58 30–19
(2) 30–20
(a) 30–20
(b) 30–20
(c) 30–20
(d) 30–19
(3) 30–20
s.59 30–13
s.60(2) 30–17
(4) 30–17
s.61 30–54
s.62 30–14
(1) 30–14
(2) 30–14
s.63 30–28
(2) 30–54
Sch.1 28–57, 30–26, 30–28
para.1 30–28
para.2(1) 30–19
1994 Insolvency Act (c.7) 32–46
s.2 32–41
Deregulation and Contracting Out Act (c.40) 4–4, 33–30
1995 Proceeds of Crime Act (c.11) 30–54
1996 Employment Rights Act (c.18) 20–6
Pt XII 32–16
s.189 32–16
1997 Building Societies Act (c.32) 1–34
1998 Competition Act (c.41) 16–4
Human Rights Act (c.42) 18–1, 18–14, 28–5, 28–6, 28–7, 29–25
s.6 25–28
(1) 28–6
s.8 28–8
1999 Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act (c.31) 3–23
s.6(2) 3–23
2000 Financial Services and Markets Act (c.8) 1–3, 1–18, 1–23, 1–36, 3–4, 3–7, 8–2,
13–24, 24–1, 25–5, 25–8, 25–10, 25–
17, 25–30, 25–33, 25–38, 25–44, 25–
44, 26–15, 26–26, 26–28, 28–3, 28–4,
28–9, 28–11, 30–4, 30–11, 30–30, 30–
32, 30–52
s.19 25–8
s.21 25–11
Pt VI 1–23, 25–10, 25–42, 25–43
s.73A 3–8, 25–5
s.74 1–18, 24–2, 25–5
s.75(2) 25–2
(3) 25–42
(4) 25–42
(5) 25–15
(6) 25–42
s.77(1) 25–42
(5) 25–42
s.79(3A) 25–17
s.80(1) 25–17
s.81(3) 25–24
s.82 25–29
s.84 25–22
s.85 25–30
(1) 25–17, 25–22
(2) 25–17, 25–20, 25–22
(3) 25–41
(4) 25–32
(5)(a) 25–19
(b) 25–19
s.86(1) 31–17
(a) 25–19
(b) 25–19
(c) 25–19
(d) 25–19
(e) 25–19
(1A) 31–17
(1B) 31–17
(2) 25–19
(3) 25–19
(4) 25–19
(7) 25–19
s.87A 25–28, 25–42
(1)(a) 25–44
(2) 25–22
(3) 25–23
(5) 25–23
(6) 25–23
s.87B(1)(a) 25–29
(b) 25–29
(c) 25–29
(2) 25–29
s.87C 25–28
s.87D 25–28, 25–42
s.87G 25–24
s.87H 25–44
s.87J 25–28
s.87K 25–42
s.87L 25–42
s.87O 25–42
s.87Q 25–22
s.88 25–27
s.89A 26–21
(1) 26–16
(3)(a) 26–16
s.89A–89G 26–15
s.89C 26–21
s,89F 26–21
s.89NA 26–31
(4) 26–31
s.90 5–7, 25–10, 25–32, 25–33, 25–34, 25–
35, 25–36
(1) 25–33
(3) 25–33
(6) 25–36
(7) 25–33
(8) 5–7, 25–36
(11) 25–33
(12) 25–23, 25–33
s.90A 21–28
s.91 30–40
(1) 25–43
(1A) 25–43
(1ZA) 26–30
(1B) 26–30
(2) 25–43
(2A) 26–30
(2B) 26–30
(3) 25–43, 26–30
s.93 25–43
ss.93–94 3–8
s.96 1–23
s.97 25–43, 26–30
s.102B 25–30, 31–17
Pt VIII 13–24, 30–30, 30–47
s.118 13–24
(1) 26–31
(5) 30–37
(9) 30–37
s.119 3–8
s.124 30–52
s.125 30–52
s.126 30–52
s.127 30–52
s.133(1) 30–52
(4) 30–52
s.133A 30–52
s.134 30–52
s.135 30–52
s.137A 28–11
s.138 28–9
s.138D 15–29
s.143 28–9, 28–11
Pt XI 25–43, 25–47
s.169 30–50
(4) 30–50
(7) 30–50
(8) 30–50
s.174(2) 30–52
s.235 1–36
s.262 1–36
s.263(3) 1–36
Pt XVIII 25–8
s.286(4A)–(4E) 25–8
Pt XXII 22–21
s.380 26–28
(6) 30–55
s.381 26–28, 30–53
(1) 30–53
s.382 26–28
(1) 26–28
(3) 26–28
(8) 26–28
(9) 30–55
(a) 26–28
s.383 26–28
(1)(b) 26–28
(5) 26–28
(10) 26–28
s.384 26–28
s.387 25–42, 25–43
s.392 30–52
s.393 30–52
s.397 28–65
s.400 7–42
s.401 25–41, 26–32
s.402(1)(a) 30–54
s.413 28–8
Sch.1ZA para.25 25–28
Sch.10 25–34
Sch.10A 21–28
Sch.11A para.9 25–19
Limited Liability Partnerships Act (c.12) 1–4, 1–5, 2–14
s.2(1) 1–6
Insolvency Act (c.39) 10–1, 10–2
2001 Criminal Justice and Police Act (c.16) 18–8
2002 Enterprise Act (c.40) 2–33, 31–21, 32–16, 32–34, 32–35, 32–
36, 32–44, 32–51
s.248 32–36
s.250 32–35
s.251 32–16
Sch.16 32–36
Sch.18 32–36
Sch.20 10–16
2004 Companies (Audit, Investigations and Community 1–12, 1–29, 3–9, 4–6, 18–1, 18–3, 22–
Enterprise) Act (c.27) 29
s.14 21–32
(2) 21–32
(7) 21–32
Pt 2 1–12, 4–12
s.26(1) 1–12
(3) 1–12
s.28 1–12
s.30 4–12
ss.30–31 1–12
s.32 4–12
s.33 14–14
s.35 1–12
(2) 4–6
s.36(3)–(6) 4–6
s.37 4–46
ss.41–51 1–12
s.44 17–10
s.45 14–24
s.46 14–49
s.52(1) 4–46
Pensions Act (c.35)
ss.43–51 28–62
2005 Charities and Trustee Investment (Scotland) Act (asp 1–30
10)
2006 Fraud Act (c.35)
s.9 9–4
s.12 7–42
Companies Act (c.46) 1–2, 1–3, 1–17, 1–20, 1–23, 1–29, 1–
30, 1–38, 3–1, 3–3, 3–5, 3–10, 3–16, 3–
30, 4–1, 4–5, 4–10, 4–13, 4–18, 4–33,
5–10, 6–3, 9–1, 9–17, 10–15, 11–7, 11–
12, 12–11, 13–2, 13–11, 13–33, 13–35,
13–44, 13–55, 14–2, 14–27, 14–66, 15–
7, 15–8, 15–14, 15–15, 15–29, 15–44,
16–1, 16–2, 16–4, 16–7, 16–15, 16–15,
16–37, 16–125, 16–127, 16–140, 17–3,
17–6, 18–1, 18–13, 19–14, 19–20, 20–
8, 20–14, 21–1, 21–24, 21–43, 22–2,
22–31, 22–42, 22–43, 23–11, 24–2, 24–
4, 24–18, 26–3, 26–15, 26–19, 27–7,
27–18, 28–69, 29–16, 29–25, 29–26,
30–3, 31–22
s.1(1) 4–5
s.3(1) 1–8
(2) 1–11
(3) 1–8
(4) 1–27
s.4(2) 1–27, 4–11
(a) 1–21
s.5 1–8
s.6(2) 1–12
Pt 2 4–4
s.7 9–1
(1) 1–3, 4–5, 4–33
(2) 4–5
s.8 4–5, 4–33
(1) 4–33
s.9 4–5
(1) 4–33
(2)(a) 4–5, 4–13
(b) 4–5, 6–18
(c) 4–5
(d) 4–5
(4)(a) 4–5
(b) 4–5
(c) 4–5
(d) 4–5
(5)(a) 4–5, 21–37
(b) 3–20, 4–5, 4–32
s.10 4–5, 11–11
s.11 4–5
s.12 4–5, 14–23
s.12A 4–5
s.13 4–5, 33–30
s.14 3–20, 4–7
s.15 4–7, 4–35
(3) 4–7
(4) 4–7, 4–34, 4–36
s.16(2) 4–5, 4–8
(3) 4–38
(5) 4–8
(6) 4–8
Pt 3 Ch.3 3–16, 13–21
s.17 3–16, 7–3, 7–14, 7–17, 16–24
(a) 7–14
s.18 3–13
(2) 3–15
(3)(a) 3–15
s.19 3–14
s.20 3–14, 4–5
(1) 3–15
(a) 3–15
(b) 3–15
(2) 3–15
s.21 3–31, 19–14, 19–18, 19–23, 19–25
(2) 3–31
(3) 3–31
s.22 3–32, 19–14, 19–23
(2) 3–32, 19–23
(3) 19–23
(a) 3–32
(b) 3–32
(4) 3–32
s.23 3–32
s.24 3–32
s.25 19–1
(1) 3–32
s.26 3–22, 3–31, 4–46
s.27 3–22
s.28 4–5, 19–14
(1) 7–29
s.29 3–16, 3–22, 7–14, 7–17
(1)(b) 15–21
ss.29–30 15–79, 16–24
s.30 3–22
s.31 7–29
(1) 7–29
s.33 3–17, 3–18, 3–19, 19–23, 27–8, 33–26
(1) 3–35
(2) 3–18
s.38(2) 4–46
s.39 7–29
(1) 7–29
s.40 3–17, 3–33, 7–9, 7–12, 7–13, 7–14, 7–
15, 7–17, 7–25, 7–28, 7–29, 16–31, 16–
63, 16–113
(1) 7–9, 7–25, 16–37
(2) 7–10, 7–11
(b) 7–10
(3) 7–14
(b) 3–17, 3–33
(4) 7–12, 7–15
(5) 7–5, 7–15, 16–31
(6) 7–12
s.41 7–12, 16–31, 16–37
(1) 7–12, 16–37
(2) 7–12, 16–31
(3) 7–12
(4) 16–31
(b) 7–12
(5) 7–12
(7)(b) 7–12
s.42 7–9
s.43 7–4
s.44 7–4, 27–5
s.45 4–13, 7–4
ss.51 5–25, 5–27, 5–28
(1) 5–25
Pt 5 Ch.6 9–20
s.53 4–16, 4–46
s.54 4–17
s.55 4–17
s.56 4–17
(3) 4–17
s.57 4–13, 6–7
s.58 16–18
ss.58–59 4–14
s.59 16–18
s.60 4–15
(1)(a) 4–15
(b) 4–15
(c) 4–15
s.61 4–15
s.62 4–15
s.64 4–23
(3) 4–24
s.65(1) 4–14
s.66 4–18, 4–23, 33–32
(3) 4–18
(4) 4–18
s.67 4–23
s.68(2)(a) 4–23
s.69(1) 4–27
(3) 4–28
(4) 4–27
(5) 4–27
s.70 4–27
s.73(1) 4–28
(3) 4–28
(4) 4–28
s.74 4–28
s.75 4–23
(2)(a) 4–23
s.76 4–23
(3)–(5) 4–23
s.77 4–31
(1) 4–24, 4–30
s.80 4–31
s.81(1) 4–31
(2) 4–31
(3) 4–31
s.82 4–20
(1) 9–20
(a) 4–13
(2)(a) 4–13
s.83 9–20
(1) 9–20
(2) 9–20
(3) 9–20
s.84 9–20
ss.86–87 21–37
s.88 6–18
(1) 4–14
Pt 7 4–39
s.90 9–3
(1) 4–40
(b) 11–8
(2)(b) 11–8
(e) 4–44
(4) 4–40
ss.90–96 4–40
s.90A 26–26
s.91 4–40, 9–3
(1)(a) 11–8
(d) 11–15
s.92 4–40
s.93 4–40, 11–16
s.94 4–40
(1)(b) 4–40
s.95 4–40
s.96 4–40
(5) 4–40
s.97 4–41
(1) 4–41
(2) 4–41
s.98 4–41, 13–5, 17–29
(3)–(6) 4–41
s.101 4–41
s.102(1)(a) 4–43
(c) 4–43
(2) 4–43, 4–44
s.103(4) 4–43
s.104 4–43
s.109(1)(a) 4–43
(c) 4–43
(2) 4–43, 4–44
s.105 4–45
(2) 4–44
(4) 4–43
s.111 4–43
s.112 9–24, 17–16, 27–16
(1) 4–33
(2) 24–21
Pt 8 Ch.2 2–40
s.113 14–22, 27–16, 27–20
(3) 27–16
(7) 16–12
s.114(2) 27–17
s.115 27–17, 27–20
s.116 27–18
s.117 27–18
s.122 27–20
(1) 24–22
(3) 24–22
(4) 24–22
s.123(2) 27–16
s.125 27–19
(1) 27–19
(2) 27–19
(3) 27–19
s.126 15–34, 15–35, 27–11, 31–12
s.127 27–5, 27–14, 27–16, 27–19
s.129(2) 27–17
s.132 27–17
s.136 13–4
s.137(1)(b) 13–4
(c) 13–4
(4) 13–4
s.144 13–4
Pt 9 15–33
s.145 15–36, 15–37, 15–39, 15–40, 15–40
(1) 15–35
(2) 15–36
(3)(f) 15–36
(4)(a) 15–36
(b) 15–36
s.146 15–68, 21–40
(1) 15–40
(2) 15–40
(3)(a) 15–40
(b) 15–40, 21–40
(5) 15–40
s.147 15–40
(4) 15–40
s.148(2)–(4) 15–40
(6) 15–40
(7) 15–40
(8) 15–40
s.149 15–68
s.150(2) 15–40
(3) 15–40
(4) 15–40
(5)(a) 15–40
s.151 15–33
s.152 15–38, 15–75
(2)–(4) 15–38
s.153 15–57
(1)(a) 15–59
(d) 22–22
Pt 10 16–1, 16–2, 16–85, 16–133
Ch.1 2–40
Ch.2 16–1, 16–3, 16–9, 16–11, 16–15, 16–
32, 16–56, 16–63
Ch.3 14–19, 16–3, 16–9, 16–52, 16–56, 16–
67, 16–109
Ch.4 9–24, 16–9, 16–52, 16–67, 16–68, 16–
69, 16–71, 16–77, 16–81, 16–84, 16–
109, 16–121, 19–4, 28–32
Ch.4A 14–41, 16–67, 16–68, 16–69, 16–109,
16–121, 19–4, 28–32
s.154 2–29, 14–2
s.155 14–2, 16–8
s.156 14–2
ss.156A–156C 16–8
s.157 14–27
(4) 14–27
(5) 14–27
s.158 14–27
s.160 14–25
s.161 7–7
s.162 14–23
s.163 14–23
s.164(1) 27–16
s.165 14–23
s.167 14–23
s.168 14–6, 14–8, 14–49, 14–50, 14–51, 14–
62, 14–66, 15–2, 15–10, 15–47, 15–54,
16–116, 20–7
(1) 14–49, 14–51
(2) 14–52
(5)(a) 14–53
(b) 14–52
s.169 14–52, 15–20
(1) 14–52
(2) 14–52, 15–10
(3) 14–52
(4) 14–52
s.170(1) 16–4, 16–35, 16–37, 16–101
(2) 16–13
(a) 16–94
(3) 16–2, 16–3
(4) 3–10, 16–2, 16–3, 16–16, 16–21, 16–
140
(5) 16–9, 16–10
ss.170 et seq. 16–12
s.171 3–24, 7–5, 7–15, 16–23, 16–24, 16–25,
16–30, 16–31, 16–32, 16–31, 16–98,
16–105, 28–21
(a) 16–30, 16–32
(b) 16–26, 16–29, 16–30, 16–31, 16–40,
16–41, 16–43
ss.171–174 16–119, 16–121
ss.171–177 16–109
s.172 16–39, 16–40, 16–43, 16–44, 16–46,
16–49, 16–50, 16–140, 17–8, 17–19,
17–20, 17–21, 21–25
(1) 16–26, 16–37, 16–38, 16–48
(a)–(f) 16–41
(c) 16–49
(f) 16–43, 28–21
(2) 16–40
(3) 16–49
s.173 16–33, 16–34, 16–35
(2)(a) 16–35
(b) 16–35
s.174 9–6, 16–15, 16–14, 16–20, 16–26, 16–
98, 16–109, 16–140, 21–27
s.175 16–54, 16–68, 16–86, 16–88, 16–96,
16–99, 16–100, 16–103, 16–105, 16–
107, 16–112, 16–119, 16–121, 16–127,
16–141
(1) 16–52, 16–86, 16–88, 16–99
(2) 16–52, 16–86, 16–88, 16–90, 16–92,
16–96
(3) 16–52, 16–54, 16–56, 16–86
(4) 16–98
(a) 16–86, 16–88, 16–90, 16–96
(b) 16–103
(6) 16–103, 16–121
(7) 16–86, 16–99
s.176 16–52, 16–68, 16–104, 16–107, 16–
108, 16–119
(3) 16–107
(7) 16–100
s.177 16–52, 16–56, 16–58, 16–59, 16–60,
16–62, 16–63, 16–65, 16–67, 16–70,
16–86, 16–101, 16–112, 16–119, 16–
121, 16–126, 16–127
(1) 16–57
(2) 16–61, 16–107
(b) 16–61
(3) 16–57, 16–107
(4) 16–65
(5) 16–60
(6)(a) 16–60, 16–86
(b) 16–60
(c) 16–60, 16–86
s.178 16–3, 16–21, 16–30, 16–62, 16–66, 16–
108, 16–109
(2) 16–20
(5) 16–104
s.179 16–22, 16–107
s.180(1) 16–63, 16–103
(a) 16–119
(b) 16–119
(2) 16–68
(3) 16–68
(4)(a) 16–107, 16–108, 16–121
(b) 16–102, 16–126, 16–127
s.181(2) 16–86
(b) 16–104
(5) 15–18
s.182 16–56, 16–59, 16–64, 16–66
(1) 16–64
(3) 16–65
(4) 16–65
(6)(b) 16–65
s.183 16–66
s.184 16–62
s.185 16–61, 16–62
(4) 16–61
s.186 16–65
s.187 16–59
(1) 16–59, 16–65
(2)–(4) 16–65
s.188 14–60, 14–61, 16–84
(1) 14–60
(3) 14–60
(4) 14–60
(6)(a) 16–69
s.189 14–60
s.190 16–60, 16–70, 16–71, 16–73, 16–76
(2) 16–71
(3) 16–71
(4)(a) 16–71
(b) 16–71, 16–69
(6) 16–72
s.191 16–71
(5) 16–71
s.192(a) 16–72
(b) 16–72
s.193 16–72
s.194 16–72
s.195 16–71, 16–73, 16–74, 16–75, 16–83
(2) 16–73
(c) 16–73
(3) 16–74, 16–76
(4) 16–76
(a) 16–75
(b) 16–75
(c) 16–75
(d) 16–75
(6) 16–76
(7) 16–76
(8) 16–74, 16–73
s.196 16–71, 16–73, 16–75, 16–83, 16–118
s.197 16–78, 16–79, 27–11
(1) 16–79
(3) 16–81
(4) 16–81
(5)(a) 16–69
(b) 16–81
s.198 16–79, 27–11
(2) 16–79
(3) 16–81
(5) 16–81
(6) 16–79
(a) 16–69
(b) 16–81
s.199 16–80
s.200 16–79
(4) 16–81
(5) 16–81
s.201 16–79, 16–80
(2) 16–79, 16–80
(4) 16–81
(5) 16–81
(6)(a) 16–69
s.202 16–80
s.203 16–79, 16–80
(1) 16–80
(3) 16–81
(4) 16–81
(5)(a) 16–69
(b) 16–81
s.204 16–82
ss.205–206 16–82
s.206(3) 16–82
s.207(1) 16–82
(2) 16–82
(3) 16–82
s.208(2) 16–82
(3) 16–82
(4) 16–82
s.209 16–82
s.210 16–82
s.213 9–6, 16–83
(2) 9–5
(4)(d) 16–83
s.214 9–5, 9–9, 9–10, 16–83, 16–118
(5) 9–6, 16–16
s.215 14–46, 14–62, 16–84
(1) 28–30
(3) 14–62, 28–31
s.216 28–31
s.217 14–62
(4)(a) 16–69
s.218 14–62
(4)(a) 16–69
s.219 14–62, 28–30
(1) 28–29, 28–31
(2) 28–29
(3) 28–29
(5) 28–29
(6) 28–30
(a) 16–69
(7) 28–31
s.220 14–62
(1)(a) 28–32
(b) 28–32
(c) 28–32
(d) 28–32
(3) 28–32
s.221 28–31
s.222(1) 14–62
(3) 28–29
s.223 14–60, 16–69, 28–30
s.225 16–68
s.226A 14–43
s.226B 16–68
ss.226B–226C 14–53
s.226C 14–59, 16–68, 28–32
s.226E 14–59
(1) 14–41
(2) 14–41
(3) 14–41
(4) 28–32
(5) 14–41
s.226F 16–68, 28–32
s.228 14–57
s.229 14–57
s.231 16–60
(4) 16–60
(5) 16–60
(6) 16–60
s.232 5–14, 16–126, 16–127, 16–128, 16–
129, 16–130, 16–132
(1) 16–125
(2) 16–128
(3) 16–128
(4) 16–126, 16–127
s.233 16–129
s.234 16–131, 16–132
(2) 16–130
(3) 16–130
(4)–(6) 16–130
s.235 16–132
s.236 16–131
s.237 16–131
s.238 16–131
s.239 13–20, 16–118, 16–124, 16–140, 17–3,
19–4
(2) 16–123
(a) 16–103
(3) 16–104, 16–121
(4) 16–104, 16–121
(5)(d) 16–121
(6)(a) 16–123
(b) 16–118
(7) 16–123, 16–124
s.240 14–23
s.241 14–23
s.242 14–23
s.243 14–23
s.244 14–23
s.245 14–23
s.246ZA
(2) 9–5
s.246ZB 9–5
(5) 9–6
s.246ZC 9–8
s.246 14–23
s.247 16–48, 16–50
s.248 16–62
s.250 13–40, 14–29, 16–8
(3) 16–42
s.251 16–59, 16–69
(1) 16–9
(2) 16–10
(3) 9–23, 16–10, 16–69
s.252 16–71, 19–2, 28–31
s.253 16–71
s.254 14–46, 16–71
s.255 14–46
s.256 16–79
s.257 7–15, 16–24
s.258 28–31
Pt 11 17–11, 17–14, 17–15, 17–32, 20–14,
20–15
s.260(1) 17–13, 17–16, 17–24
(a) 17–32
(2) 20–14
(3) 17–14
(4) 17–16
(5) 17–15
(c) 17–16
ss.260–264 17–13
s.261(2) 17–18
(4)(a) 17–25
s.262 17–22
(1) 17–22
(2) 17–22
(3) 17–22
(5)(a) 17–25
s.263 16–118, 17–2, 17–12
(1) 17–17, 17–22
(2)(a) 17–8, 17–19
(b) 17–8, 17–19
(c) 16–118, 17–8, 17–19
(3) 17–20, 17–21
(b) 17–20, 17–21
(c) 16–118, 17–8
(d) 17–8
(4) 17–20, 17–21
(5) 17–0
s.264 17–23
(1) 17–23
(5)(a) 17–25
s.265 17–32
(1) 17–13, 17–16
(3) 17–14
(4) 17–14
(5) 17–16
(6)(b) 20–14
(7) 17–15
(e) 17–16
ss.265–269 17–13
s.266(3) 17–18
(5)(a) 17–25
s.267 17–22
(1) 17–22
(2) 17–22
(3) 17–22
(5)(a) 17–25
s.268 17–12
(1) 17–17, 17–22
(a) 17–19
(b) 17–19
(c) 17–19
(2) 17–20, 17–21
(b) 17–20
(3) 17–20, 17–21
(4) 17–20
s.269 17–23
(1) 17–23
(5)(a) 17–25
s.270 4–5
s.271 4–5
s.276 21–37
s.277 15–87
s.281 15–42
(1) 15–8, 15–45
(2) 15–45
(3) 15–44, 16–68, 16–81
(4) 14–16, 15–18
(a) 15–15
(c) 15–15
s.282 15–44
(3) 15–45
(5) 15–65
s.283 15–44
(3) 15–44
(4) 15–45
(6) 15–44, 15–47, 15–65
(b) 15–65
s.284 15–4, 23–8
(4) 15–4
s.288(2) 15–10, 22–18
(3) 15–13
s.289 15–11
s.290 15–12
s.291 15–12
(2)(a) 15–12
(b) 15–12
(3) 15–12
(6) 15–12
(7) 15–12
s.292 15–9, 15–13, 21–8
(2)(a) 15–13
(b) 15–13
(c) 15–13
(4) 15–11, 15–13
(3) 15–13
(5) 15–13
s.293(1) 15–13
(2) 15–12
(3) 15–13
(6) 15–13
(7) 15–13
s.294 15–13
s.295 15–13
(2) 15–13
s.296(1) 15–12
(2) 15–12, 15–86
(3) 15–12
(4) 15–8, 15–11, 15–12
s.297 15–12
s.298 15–12
s.299 15–85
s.300 15–14
s.301 15–47
s.302 15–9, 15–51
s.303 15–51
(2)(b) 15–51
(4) 15–51
(5) 15–51
ss.303–306 15–9
s.304(3) 15–51
(4) 15–51
s.305(1) 15–51
(b) 15–51
(6) 15–51
(7) 15–51
s.306 15–54, 19–24
(1) 15–53
(2)–(4) 15–53
(2) 15–53
(5) 21–2
(6) 21–2
s.307 15–61, 15–62, 21–40
(1A)(b) 15–61
(2) 15–58
(3) 15–61
(4) 15–62
(5) 15–62
(6) 15–62
(7) 15–62
s.307A 15–61
s.309 15–85
s.310 15–66
(1) 15–66
(2) 15–66
s.311 15–65
(2) 15–47
(3) 15–65
s.311A 15–65
s.312 14–52, 15–47, 15–63, 22–20
(1) 15–47
(2) 15–63
(3) 15–63
(4) 15–63
s.313 15–66
s.314(4)(d) 15–59
ss.314–316 15–59
s.316 15–59
s.317 15–13, 15–59
s.318(1) 15–54
(2) 15–54
s.319 15–82
s.319A(1) 15–49
(2) 15–49
s.320 22–32
s.321 15–75
(1) 15–63
s.322 15–75
s.323 15–72
(2) 15–72
(3) 15–72
(4) 15–72
s.324(1) 15–68, 15–75
(2) 15–68, 15–72
ss.324–331 15–68
s.324A 15–70, 15–71
s.325 15–68
(2)–(4) 15–68
s.326 15–68
(1) 15–68
(2) 15–68
s.327 15–68
s.328 15–68
s.329 15–68, 15–75
s.330 15–70
(2) 15–70
(3) 15–70
(b) 15–70
(4) 15–70
(5)–(7) 15–70
(6)(c) 15–70
s.331 15–68
s.332 15–83, 33–10
s.333 15–86
s.334 15–84
(2) 15–84
(4) 15–84
(6) 15–84
s.335 15–84
(2) 15–84
(4) 15–84
(5) 15–84
s.336 15–8
(1) 15–48, 15–50
(1A) 15–8, 15–50
(3) 15–50
(4) 15–50
ss.336–340 15–48
s.337(2) 15–62
s.338 15–57, 15–63
(2) 15–57
(4) 15–57
ss.338–340 15–59
s.338A 15–49
(1) 15–49, 15–57
(2) 15–49, 15–57
(3) 15–49
(4) 15–49, 15–57
(5) 15–49
s.339(1) 15–57
s.340(1) 15–57
(2) 15–57
s.340B(1) 15–57
(2) 15–57
s.341 15–78
s.342 15–76
(4)(d) 15–76
s.343 15–76
(3)(b) 15–76
s.344 15–76
(2) 15–76
s.347(1) 15–76
s.348 15–76
s.349 15–76
(4) 9–20
s.350 15–76
s.351 15–76
s.352 15–76, 15–84
s.353 15–76
s.354 15–76
s.355 15–79
s.356 15–80
(2) 15–21
s.358(1) 15–79
(3) 15–79
s.359 15–79
s.360 15–61
s.360A 15–55
s.360C 15–8
Pt 14 16–85, 17–29, 21–23
s.364 16–85
s.365 16–85
s.366 16–85
(3) 16–85
(4) 16–85
(b) 16–85
s.367(1) 16–85
(2) 16–85
(3) 16–85
(4) 16–85
(5) 16–85
(6) 16–85
(7) 16–85
s.368 16–85, 19–19
s.369 17–29
(1) 16–85
(2) 16–85
(3) 16–85
(b) 16–85
(4) 16–85
s.370 17–29
(1)(b) 17–29
(5) 17–31
s.371(4) 17–30
(5) 17–30
s.372 17–30
s.373 17–26, 17–30
s.378 16–85
s.379(1) 16–85
Pt 15 21–5, 21–43
s.380 15–83
ss.381–384 14–44
s.382 21–3
(2) 21–4
s.383(1) 21–9
(4)–(7) 21–9
(6) 21–9
s.384(1) 21–4
(a) 21–2
(2) 21–4
(a) 21–9
s.384A 21–3
(2) 21–3
(3) 21–3
s.384B(1)(a) 21–2
(2) 21–3, 21–9
s.385 14–40, 14–44, 15–76, 16–69, 21–25,
22–22
(4)–(6) 14–40
s.386 21–7
(3) 21–7
(5) 21–7
ss.386–389 21–7
s.387(2) 21–7
(3) 21–7
s.388(2) 21–7
(3) 21–7
(4) 21–7
s.389(4) 21–7
s.390(2) 21–8
(3) 21–8
(5) 21–8
ss.390–392 21–8
s.391 15–50
(2) 15–50, 21–8
(3) 21–8
(4) 21–8
s.392(2) 21–8
(3) 21–8
(5) 21–8
s.393 21–14
(1) 21–14
(1A) 21–17
s.394 21–10, 21–29
ss.394A–394C 21–10
s.394B(2)(b) 21–20
s.395 6–6, 21–13
(2) 21–13
(3)–(4B) 21–13
(4) 21–13
(5) 21–13
s.396 21–16
(2A) 21–17
(4) 21–14
(5) 21–14
s.399 21–9
(2) 21–10
(2A) 21–9
s.400(1)(a) 21–11
(b) 21–11
(c) 21–11
(2)(a)–(b) 21–11
(c)–(d) 21–11
(e)–(f) 21–11
s.401(1)(a) 21–11
(b) 21–11
(c) 21–11
(2)(a)–(c) 21–11
(d)–(e) 21–11
(f)–(g) 21–11
s.402 21–12
s.403 21–13
(1) 21–13
(3) 21–13
(4)–(5B) 21–13
(5) 21–13
(6) 21–13
s.404(1) 21–9, 21–16
(4) 21–14
(5) 21–14
s.405 21–12
s.407 21–10, 21–13
s.408 21–10
s.409 21–21
s.410 21–21
s.412 14–44
(2) 14–46
(4) 14–46
s.413 16–81
s.414(4) 21–29, 22–43
(5) 21–29
s.414A 21–24, 21–29
s.414B 21–24
s.414C 21–25
(1) 21–24
(2) 21–25
(3) 21–25
(4) 21–25
(5) 21–25
(6) 21–25
(7) 21–25
(8)(a) 21–25
(b) 21–25
(11) 21–25, 28–25
(13) 21–25
(14) 21–25
s.414D(1) 21–29
(2) 21–29, 22–43
(3) 21–29
s.415 21–29
(1A) 21–23
s.415A 21–23
s.416(1) 21–23
(3) 21–23
s.417(5)(c) 21–25
s.418(2) 22–30
(4) 22–30
(5) 22–30
(6) 22–30
s.419(1) 21–29
(3) 22–43
s.419A 21–29
s.420 14–39, 21–29
s.421(2A) 14–39
s.422(2) 22–43
s.422A 14–39
s.423(1) 14–58, 21–40
(2) 21–40
(3) 21–40
s.424(2) 21–42
(a) 21–42
s.425 14–22
s.426 21–41
(2) 21–41
(3) 21–41
(5) 21–41
s.426A 21–41
s.430 15–85, 21–39, 21–41
s.431 21–40
s.432 21–40
s.433 21–39
s.434 21–39
s.435 21–39
s.436 21–39
s.437 15–49, 15–57
(3) 21–42
ss.437–438 21–42
s.439 14–39, 14–41, 14–42
(5) 14–42, 14–59
s.439A 14–39, 14–41, 14–58
s.441 2–39, 21–33
(1) 14–58
s.442 15–57, 21–34
s.444(1) 21–36
(3) 21–36
s.444A 21–36
s.445(3) 21–36
(4) 21–36
s.446 21–35
s.447 21–35
s.448 1–27, 2–6, 4–10, 8–6, 21–36
s.451 21–34
s.452 21–34
s.453 21–34
s.454 21–31
(2) 21–31
s.456(1) 21–32
(1)–(3) 21–31
(2)–(7) 21–31
(5)–(6) 21–31
s.457 3–9, 21–31, 21–32
s.459 16–6, 21–31, 28–47
ss.460–462 21–31
s.463 16–15, 21–27, 21–28
(1) 21–27
(2) 21–27
(3) 21–27
(4) 21–28
(5) 21–28
s.464 21–17
s.465(3) 21–5
s.466 21–9
s.467(1) 21–5
(2)(a) 21–6
(4) 21–25
s.468 3–5
s.471 21–35
(2) 21–40
s.472 21–21
Pt 16 14–21
Ch.2 14–19
s.474(1) 21–2, 21–6
s.475 22–4
(2)–(4) 22–6
s.476 22–6
s.477(1) 22–6
s.478(a) 22–6
(b) 22–6
ss.478–479 22–6
s.479(1) 22–6
s.479A 22–7
(1) 22–7
(2) 22–7
s.479B(a) 22–7
s.479C(3) 22–7
s.480(1) 22–8
(za) 22–8
(2) 22–8
s.482(1) 22–9
s.485 21–17
(3) 21–17
s.487 21–17, 22–3
(2)(b) 21–17
(c) 22–17
(d) 21–17
s.488 22–17
s.489(3) 22–17
(4) 22–17
s.491(1)(b) 22–17
(1A) 22–14
(1B) 22–14
s.492(1) 21–17
s.493 21–17
s.494 22–13
s.495 22–43
(1) 21–30
(3) 22–3
(3A) 22–3, 22–6
(4) 22–3
(b) 22–3
(c) 22–3
s.496 21–26, 22–3
s.497A 22–3
s.498(1) 22–3
(2) 21–7, 22–3
(3) 22–30
(4) 14–47, 22–3
(5) 22–3
s.498A 22–3
s.499 22–30
(1) 22–30
(2) 22–30
(3) 22–30
(4) 22–30
s.500 22–30
s.501 22–30
(1) 22–30
s.502(1) 22–16
(2) 22–16, 22–18
s.503 21–30
(3) 22–31
s.504 22–14
(3) 22–31
s.506 21–30
s.507 22–43
(1)–(3) 22–43
ss.508–509 22–43
s.510 15–10, 15–47, 22–18
(3) 22–18
(4) 22–18
s.511 22–18
(2) 22–18
(3)–(5) 22–18
(3)–(6) 15–10
(6) 22–18
s.513 22–18
s.514 22–20
s.515(2) 22–20
(3) 22–20
(4)–(7) 22–20
s.516(1) 22–18
s.518 22–19
(3) 22–19
s.519 22–19
(1) 22–19, 22–20
(2A) 22–19
(3A) 22–19
s.519A(3) 22–19
s.520 22–19
(1) 22–20
s.521 22–19
(1) 22–20
s.522 22–19
(1) 22–20
s.523(1) 22–20
s.527(2) 22–22
(3) 22–22
(5) 22–22
(6) 22–22
ss.527–531 15–58, 22–22
s.528(4) 22–22
s.529(2) 22–22
(3) 22–22
s.531 22–22
s.532 22–42
s.534(3) 22–42
s.535(1) 22–42
s.536 22–42
s.537(1) 22–42
(2) 22–42
Pt 17 Ch.6 11–16, 24–7
s.540(2) 23–11
s.541 23–1
s.542(1) 11–3
(2) 11–3
(3) 11–19
s.543 23–11
s.544 2–25
s.547 11–9, 11–14
s.548 11–7
s.549 14–18
(1) 24–5
(3) 24–5
(3)–(4) 24–5
(6) 24–5
s.550 24–4
s.551 13–9, 28–21
(2) 24–5
(3) 24–5
(4) 24–5
(a) 24–5
(b) 24–5
(6) 24–5
(7) 24–5
(8) 24–5
s.552 11–14
(3) 11–14
s.553 11–7, 11–14, 27–6
s.554 24–21, 31–22
s.555 11–11
(4)(c) 23–6
s.556(3) 23–6
s.558 24–18
s.560(1) 24–7
(2)(b) 24–11
(3) 13–26
s.561 24–9, 24–10
(2) 24–7
(4) 24–9
s.562 24–9, 24–10, 24–12
(4) 24–9
(5) 24–9, 24–16
s.563(3) 24–12
s.564 24–7
s.565 24–7
s.566 14–37, 24–7
s.567 24–10
(3) 24–10
s.568 24–10
(4) 24–10, 24–12
(5) 24–10, 24–12
s.569 14–18, 24–10
(1) 24–10
(2) 24–12
ss.569–571 14–37
s.570 24–10, 28–21
(1) 24–10
(2) 24–12
s.571 24–10
(1) 24–10
(2) 24–12
(5)–(7) 24–10
(6) 24–5
s.572 24–10
s.573 24–11
(3) 24–12
(5) 24–12
s.577 24–7
s.578(1) 24–20
(b) 24–20
(2) 24–20
(3) 24–20
(4) 24–20
(5) 24–20
s.579(1) 24–20
(2) 24–20
(3) 24–20
(4) 24–20
s.580 11–3
(1) 11–4
(2) 11–4
s.581 23–5
s.582(1) 11–14
s.583(3) 11–15
(c) 11–15, 31–3
(d) 11–15
(5) 11–15
s.584 11–15
s.585 11–15
(1) 5–22
(2) 11–15
(3) 11–15
s.586 4–11, 11–8, 11–18
(3)(d) 11–16
s.587 11–15
(1) 11–15
(2) 11–15
(3) 11–15
(4) 11–15
s.588(2) 11–18, 27–6
(3) 11–18
s.589 11–18
(1) 11–18
(3) 11–18
(4) 11–18
(5) 11–18
(6) 11–18
s.591 11–15
s.593(1) 11–16
(2) 11–16
(3) 11–16, 11–18
ss.593 et seq. 5–9
ss.594–595 11–16
s.596(1) 11–16
(3)–(5) 11–16
s.598 5–8, 11–17
(1)(a) 11–17
(2) 11–17
s.599(1)(c) 11–17
s.601 11–17
s.603 11–17
(a) 4–40, 5–8
s.604(3)(b) 11–18
s.605 11–18
(1) 11–16
(3) 11–16, 11–18, 27–6
(4) 11–18
s.606 11–18
(4) 11–18
(5) 11–18
(6) 11–18
s.610 11–6, 11–7, 12–2
(2) 11–7
(3) 11–7
(4) 13–30
s.611 11–7
(2)–(5) 11–7
s.612(4) 11–7
ss.612–613 11–7
s.613(3) 11–7
s.616(1) 11–7
s.617 23–11
(5) 13–33
s.618 13–33
s.620 12–2, 23–11
s.622(1) 11–19
(3) 11–19
(5) 11–19
(6) 11–19
s.624(1) 11–19
s.626 11–19
s.627 11–19
s.628 11–19
s.629 19–18
s.630 14–18, 19–14, 19–15, 19–17, 19–18,
19–19, 19–20
(1) 19–19
(3) 19–14
(4) 19–14
(5) 19–14
(6) 19–14
s.631 19–14, 19–15, 19–20
s.632 19–15
s.633 19–15
(1) 19–15
(5) 19–15
s.634 19–15
s.636 23–6
s.637 23–6
s.641 13–30
(1)(a) 13–40
(b) 13–34
(2) 13–9
(2A) 29–3
(2B) 29–3
(3) 13–33
(4) 13–34
(a) 13–33
(b) 13–33
s.642(1) 13–41
(2) 13–42
(3) 13–42
(4) 13–15, 13–42
s.643 13–40, 13–41
(1) 13–40
(1) 24–2
(3) 24–2
(5) 24–2
s.760 24–2
s.761 4–11, 4–38, 9–3, 11–8
(2) 11–8
(4) 11–8
s.762 11–8
(1)(c) 5–4
s.763 4–11, 11–8
(4) 4–38
s.764(1) 11–8
(3) 11–8
(4) 11–8
s.765 4–11, 11–8, 11–19
(1) 11–19
(2) 11–8
s.766 11–19
s.767(1) 9–3, 11–8
(2) 9–3, 11–8
(3) 9–3, 11–8
(4) 11–8
s.768 27–5, 27–14, 31–22
(2) 27–5
s.769 24–21, 31–22
s.770 31–22
s.771 20–2, 27–7, 27–21, 31–22
(1) 27–7, 27–13
s.773 27–21
s.774 27–21
s.776 31–22
s.778 31–22
s.779 24–22
(2) 24–22
(3) 24–22
(4) 24–22
ss.784–790 27–4
Pt 21A 2–42
s.790ZF 2–45
ss.790A–790ZG 2–42
s.790C 4–5
(7) 2–42
(10) 2–42
s.790D 2–45
s.790E 2–45
s.790F 2–45
s.790G 2–45
s.790H 2–45
s.790I 2–45
s.790M 2–42, 2–45, 4–5
(1) 2–44
s.790N 2–46
s.790O 2–46
(4) 2–46
s.790P 2–46
s.790R 2–46
s.790U(1) 2–44
s.790W 2–46
Pt 22 16–27, 28–51, 28–54
s.793 27–7, 28–51, 28–52, 28–53
(2) 28–51
(5) 28–51
(6) 28–51
ss.793–797 15–77
ss.793 et seq. 16–27
s.794 28–53
s.795 28–53
s.796 28–53
s.797(1) 28–53
s.798 28–53
s.799 28–53
s.800 28–53
(3) 28–53
(a) 28–53
(b) 28–53
(4) 28–53
s.801 28–53
(1) 28–53
s.802 28–53
s.803(2) 28–52
(3) 28–52
s.804 28–52
(2) 28–52
s.805 28–52
(1) 28–52
(2) 28–52
(4) 28–52
(5) 28–52
(6) 28–52
(7) 28–52
s.806 28–52
s.807 28–52
s.808 28–51
ss.808–819 28–51
s.820(1) 28–54
ss.820–823 28–54
s.824 28–54
(2)(a) 28–54
(b) 28–54
(5) 28–54
(6) 28–54
s.825 28–54
(1)–(3) 28–54
(4) 28–54
Pt 23 12–2, 13–41
s.829(1) 12–9
(2) 12–9
(b) 13–41
s.830 12–3, 12–4, 12–5
(1) 23–8
(2) 12–3
s.831 4–40, 12–4, 12–5, 13–7
(1) 12–2
(2) 12–2
(4)(a) 12–2
(c) 12–4
ss.832–835 12–3
s.836(2) 12–5
(a) 12–6
(b) 12–6
s.837(2) 12–5
(3) 12–5
(4) 12–5
(5) 12–5
s.838 12–6
s.839 12–6
s.840 12–7
s.841 12–3
s.844 12–3
s.845(1) 12–11
(2) 12–11
(3) 12–11
s.846 12–3, 12–11
s.847 12–12
(2) 12–12
(3) 12–12
(4) 12–12
(a) 13–56
s.851(1) 12–8
(2) 12–11
s.853(4) 12–3
s.853A 21–38
s.853L 21–38
Pt 24 21–38
s.859(3) 32–26
(4) 32–26
s.859A 32–24, 32–28
(1) 32–26
(2) 32–26
(4) 32–27, 32–32
(6) 32–26
(7) 32–2, 32–26
s.859D 32–26
s.859E 32–27
s.859F 32–27, 32–30
(2) 32–30
(3) 32–30
s.859G 32–28
s.859H 32–26, 32–29
(4) 32–29
s.859L 32–32
(1)–(3) 32–27
(4) 32–27
(5) 32–27
s.859M 32–31
s.859P 32–28
s.859Q 32–28
Pt 25 32–24
Ch.A1 32–25
Ch.1 32–25
Ch.1A 32–32
Ch.2 32–5, 32–25
s.860(7) 32–25, 32–26
s.874 32–25, 32–26
s.876(1)(b) 32–27
s.890K 4–5
Pt 26 19–21, 29–1, 29–13, 29–14, 19–15
s.895 14–18, 29–1, 29–2, 31–31
(1) 29–6
s.896 29–6
(1) 29–8
(2) 29–7
ss.896–899(1) 29–6
s.897 29–10
(1) 29–10
(b) 29–10
(2) 29–10
(3) 29–10
(4) 29–10
(5)–(8) 29–10
s.898 29–10
s.899 29–11, 31–31
s.899(1) 29–3, 29–10
ss.899–901 3–32
s.900 29–2, 29–12
(1) 29–2
(2)(a) 29–2
(d) 29–2
(e) 29–12
Pt 27 29–2, 29–12, 29–13
s.902(1)(c) 29–13
(2) 29–14
(a) 29–14
(b) 29–14
(3) 29–13
s.904(1)(a) 29–14
(b) 29–14
ss.905–906A 29–13
s.908 29–13
s.909 29–13
s.910 29–13
s.915 29–13
s.915A 29–13
ss.916–917 29–13
s.918 29–13
s.918A 29–13
s.919 29–14
ss.920–921A 29–13
s.923 29–13
s.924 29–13
s.925 29–13
s.931 29–13
s.932 29–13
ss.935–937 29–13
Pt 28 Ch.2 28–15
Ch.3 28–15, 28–70
s.942 28–4
(2) 28–6
(3)(a) 28–7
(b) 28–5
s.943 28–6, 28–7
(2) 28–7
(3) 28–7
(a) 28–7
s.944(1) 28–6, 28–7
s.945 28–6, 28–7
s.946 28–7
s.947 28–6
(1)–(3) 28–8
(10) 28–8
s.948 28–8
s.949 28–8
s.950 28–17
s.952 28–10
(2)–(8) 28–10
s.953 28–12
(2) 28–12
(4) 28–12
s.954 28–10
s.955 28–9
(2) 28–9
(4) 28–6
s.956(1) 28–6
(2) 28–6
ss.957–959 28–4
s.961 28–6
ss.966–967 28–24
s.968(6) 28–24
s.974(1) 28–70
(2) 28–70
(3) 28–70
(4) 28–70
s.975(2) 28–72
s.976 28–71
s.978 28–71
(2) 28–71
(3) 28–71
s.979 19–8
(2) 28–70, 28–73
(4) 28–70
(5) 28–72
s.980 28–73
s.981 28–73
(2) 28–73
(4) 28–73
(5) 28–73
s.982 28–73
(4) 28–73
s.983(1) 28–75
(2)(b) 31–3
(2)–(4) 28–75
(3)(b) 31–3
(6) 28–75
(7) 28–75
(8) 28–75
s.984(1)–(4) 28–76
(5)–(7) 28–76
s.985 28–76
s.986(1) 28–73
(3) 28–76
(4) 28–74
(9) 28–73
(10) 28–73
s.987 28–70
s.988 28–75
s.989 31–3
s.990 28–70, 31–3
Pt 29 9–4
s.993 9–4, 9–5
Pt 30 19–15, 20–1, 20–23
s.994 16–27, 16–97, 18–5, 20–2, 20–4, 20–5,
20–6, 20–7, 20–8, 20–9, 20–12, 20–13,
20–14, 20–15, 20–17, 20–21, 20–22,
27–7, 32–47
(1) 20–1
(1A) 20–1, 22–18
(2) 20–2, 27–21
(3) 20–2
(4) 20–2
s.995 20–2
s.996 20–14, 20–16, 20–19, 20–20, 20–21
(2) 20–19
(a) 20–19
(b) 20–19
(c) 20–15, 20–19
(d) 20–19
(e) 20–19
(3) 28–24
Pt 31 33–1, 33–29
s.1000 33–29
(2) 33–29
(3) 33–29
(4)–(6) 33–29
(7)(a) 33–30
s.1001 33–29
(1)–(4) 33–29
s.1002 33–29
s.1003 33–11
(2) 33–30
(3) 33–30
(4) 33–30
(5) 33–30
(6)(a) 33–30
s.1004 33–30
(1)(a) 33–30
s.1005 33–30
s.1006(1) 33–30
s.1009 33–30
s.1011 33–30
s.1012 33–30
s.1024(1) 33–32
(3) 33–32
(4) 33–32
s.1025(1) 33–32
(2) 33–32
(3) 33–32
(4) 33–32
(5) 33–32
s.1026 33–32
s.1027(2) 33–32
(3) 33–32
(4) 33–32
s.1028(1) 33–32
(2) 33–32
(3) 33–32
(4) 33–32
s.1029(1) 33–33
(2) 33–33
s.1030(1) 33–33
(2) 33–33
(3) 33–33
(4) 33–33
(5) 33–32
s.1031(1) 33–33
(2) 33–33
(3) 33–33
s.1032(1) 33–33
(2) 33–33
(3) 33–33
s.1033 33–32
Pt 32 18–8
Pt 33 Ch.1 1–33
s.1040(3) 1–33
(4) 1–33
s.1041 1–33
s.1042 1–33
s.1043 1–32
(1)(a) 1–32
(b) 1–32
(c) 1–32
(d) 1–32
(2) 1–32
(3) 1–32
(4) 1–32
Pt 34 6–3, 6–8, 6–9
s.1044 6–3
s.1045 6–7
s.1046 6–5
s.1047(1) 6–7
(2) 6–7
(3) 6–7
(4) 6–7
(5) 6–7
s.1048 6–7
s.1049 6–6
s.1051 6–6
s.1052 6–7
s.1053(2) 6–6
s.1056 6–5
s.1058 6–6
s.1060 21–37
s.1066 4–7, 4–13
s.1068(3) 4–33
(5) 4–33
s.1079 33–18
s.1085 21–37
s.1086 21–37
s.1087 21–37
s.1089 21–37
s.1090 21–37
s.1091(3) 21–37
s.1099 4–18
s.1103(1) 6–6
s.1105 6–6
s.1112 11–11
s.1121 14–22
(3) 14–22
s.1122 14–22
s.1126(2) 18–2
(3) 18–2
s.1129 18–2
s.1132 18–3
s.1136 15–79, 27–17
s.1139(2) 6–5
(b) 6–5
s.1145 15–85
s.1146 15–86
s.1150 11–16
(2) 11–16
ss.1151–1152 11–16
s.1153 11–16
s.1157 9–6, 12–5, 12–13, 12–14, 16–30, 22–42
s.1158 16–85, 16–96
s.1159 9–24
s.1161 21–10
(1) 21–10
s.1162 9–24, 21–10
(2)(a) 21–10
(b) 21–10
(c) 21–10
(3) 21–10
(4) 21–10
(5) 21–10
s.1163 16–71
s.1166 23–10
s.1169 22–8
s.1173 16–12
(1) 16–71, 16–79, 22–34
s.1176 18–13
Pt 40 10–1
s.1184 10–1
s.1189 10–15
Pt 41 4–20
Ch.2 4–20
s.1192(2) 4–20
(3) 4–20
ss.1192–1199 4–20
s.1193(4) 4–20
s.1194(3) 4–20
s.1197(5) 4–20
s.1198(2) 4–20
s.1200 4–20
s.1206 4–20
s.1207 4–20
s.1212 29–17
(1) 22–34
(a) 22–11
(b) 22–27
s.1214 29–17
(1)–(3) 22–12
(5) 22–12
(6) 22–12
s.1215(1) 22–12
s.1217 3–9, 22–11
s.1221 22–27
ss.1239–1247 22–27
s.1248(3) 22–12
ss.1248–1249 22–12
s.1261(1) 22–12
s.1266 26–15
ss.1277–1280 15–27
s.1278 15–27
s.1279 15–27
s.1280 15–27
s.1282 9–11
ss.1288–1292 3–5
Sch.1A 2–42
Pt 1 4–5
Ch.5 2–45
Sch.1B 2–45
Sch.2 28–8
Sch.4 para.6 15–86
Sch.5 15–85, 33–30
para.6 15–85
para.9(a) 15–85
(b) 15–85
para.10(1) 15–85
(2) 15–85
(3) 15–85
para.11 15–85
para.12 15–85
para.13(1) 15–85
para.14 15–85
Sch.6 9–24
Sch.7 9–24, 21–10
para.4 21–10
(3) 21–10
Sch.10 3–9
para.6 22–27
para.17 22–33
Sch.10A 26–26, 26–30
para.1 26–26
para.2 26–25, 26–26
para.3(4) 26–26
para.5 26–26
para.6 26–26
para.7(1) 26–26
(2) 26–26, 26–27
(3) 26–26
para.10(3) 26–30
Legislative and Regulatory Reform Act (c.51) 3–5
2007 Corporate Manslaughter and Corporate Homicide Act 7–2, 7–43, 7–44, 7–45, 7–46
(c.19)
s.1(3) 7–43
(6) 7–44
s.2 7–43
(5) 7–43
s.8 7–43
s.9 7–44
s.10 7–44
s.18 7–45
s.20 7–43
Bankruptcy and Diligence etc (Scotland) Act (asp 3)
s.40 32–10
(5) 32–10
(6) 32–10
s.41 32–10
s.45 32–8
2010 Bribery Act (c.23) 3–4, 7–46, 16–107
s.7 7–46
s.8 7–46
s.14 7–46
2011 Charities Act (c.25) 1–30, 4–1, 22–5
Pt 11 1–30
s.105(9) 16–22
ss.178 et seq. 10–3
s.197 7–29
s.198 7–29
2012 Financial Services Act (c.21) 30–30
Pt IA 25–10
Pt 7 28–65, 30–4, 30–19, 30–29, 30–51, 30–
54, 30–55
s.89 26–32, 30–29
(2) 26–32
(3) 30–43
s.90 26–32, 30–29, 30–39
(1) 30–29
(2) 30–29
(3) 30–29
(4) 30–29
(9) 30–43
(a) 30–29
(b) 30–29
(10) 30–29
s.92 26–32
2013 Enterprise and Regulatory Reform Act (c.24) 28–32
s.82 14–41
2014 Co-operative and Community Benefit Societies Act 1–32, 1–35, 4–1, 4–18
(c.14)
2015 Small Business, Enterprise and Employment Act 2–42, 4–5, 10–1, 10–5, 10–6, 21–38,
(c.26) 24–22, 26–14, 32–45, 32–46, 33–15
s.33 21–2
s.34 21–2
s.84 24–22
s.87 14–2, 16–8
s.89(1) 16–9
s.94 27–16
s.110 17–10
s.117 9–4
s.127 32–50
s.164(1) 27–16
Sch.4 24–22
Sch.5 27–16
TABLE OF STATUTORY INSTRUMENTS
Pt 3 6–5
reg.17 6–5
Pt 4 6–5
reg.30 6–3
reg.31(1)(b) 6–6
(2) 6–6
reg.32(5) 6–6
reg.33 6–6
reg.34 6–6
reg.38 6–6
Pt 5 6–6
Ch.3 6–6
Pt 6 6–6
regs 60–61 6–6
reg.62 6–6
reg.63 6–6
reg.66 6–6
Pt 7 6–6
reg.67 6–6
Pt 8 6–6
reg.68 6–3
reg.77 6–6
Registrar of Companies and Applications for Striking
Off Regulations (SI 2009/1803)
reg.7 6–6
Limited Liability Partnerships (Amendment) 1–4
Regulations (SI 2009/1833)
Overseas Companies (Execution of Documents and
Registration of Charges) Regulations (SI
2009/1917)
Pt 2 6–7
Pt 3 32–28
Legislative Reform (Limited Partnerships) Order (SI 1–4, 1–5
2009/1940)
Community Interest Company (Amendment) 1–12
Regulations (SI 2009/1942)
Companies (Share Capital and Acquisition by 13–35
Company of Own Shares) Regulations (SI
2009/2022) reg.3
European Economic Interest Grouping (Amendment) 1–38
Regulations (SI 2009/2399)
European Public Limited–Liability Company 1–42, 14–66, 14–67
(Amendment) Regulations (SI 2009/2400)
European Public Limited–Liability Company 1–42
(Employee Involvement) (Great Britain)
Regulations (SI 2009/2401)
European Public Limited-Liability Company 1–42
(Employee Involvement) (Northern Ireland)
Regulations (SI 2009/2402)
Companies (Authorised Minimum) Regulations (SI
2009/2425)
reg.2 11–8
Unregistered Companies Regulations (SI 2009/2436) 1–32
Companies (Companies Authorised to Register) 1–33
Regulations (SI 2009/2437)
Companies (Unfair Prejudice Applications) 20–1, 20–19
Proceedings Rules (SI 2009/2469)
Companies (Disqualification Orders) Regulations (SI 10–15
2009/2471)
2011 Companies (Disclosure of Auditor Remuneration and 22–13
Liability Limitation Agreements) (Amendment)
Regulations (SI 2011/2198)
Regulated Covered Bonds (Amendment) Regulations 31–19
(SI 2011/2859)
Open-Ended Investment Companies (Amendment) 1–36
Regulations (SI 2011/3049)
2012 Supervision of Accounts and Reports (Prescribed
Body) and Companies (Defective Accounts and
Directors’ Reports) (Authorised Person) Order (SI
2012/439)
reg.4 21–31
Statutory Auditors (Amendment of Companies Act 21–17
2006 and Delegation of Functions etc) Order (SI
2012/1741)
Registrar of Companies (Fees) (Companies, Overseas
Companies and Limited Liability Partnerships)
Regulations (SI 2012/1907)
Sch.1 para. 8 4–5
Regulated Covered Bonds (Amendment) Regulations 31–19
(SI 2012/2977)
2013 Financial Services Act 2012 (Misleading Statements
and Impressions (Order (SI 2013/637)
art.2 26–32
Companies Act 2006 (Strategic Report and Directors’ 16–39
Report) Regulations (SI 2013/1970)
2013 Companies (Receipt of Accounts and Reports) 21–41
Regulations (SI 2013/1973)
reg.5 21–41
Large and Medium-Sized Companies and Groups
(Accounts and Reports) (Amendment) Regulations
(SI 2013/1981)
Sch.8 14–44, 14–45
Pt 3 14–58
Pt 4 14–44, 14–58
Pt 5 14–44
Pt 6 14–44
2014 Companies (Striking Off) (Electronic 33–29
Communications) Order (SI 2014/1602)
Company, Limited Liability Partnership and Business 4–17
Names (Sensitive Words and Expressions)
Regulations (SI 2014/3140)
Reports on Payments to Government Regulations (SI 21–22
2014/3209)
2015 Company, Limited Liability Partnership and Business 4–17
(Names and Trading Disclosures) Regulations (SI
2015/17)
reg.2 4–13
reg.3 4–15
regs 4–6 4–14
reg.7 4–18
reg.8 4–18
Sch.2 4–18
Sch.3 4–18
Companies Act 2006 (Amendment of Part 17) 29–3
Regulations (SI 2015/472)
Companies, Partnerships and Groups (Accounts and 21–1
Reports) Regulations (SI 2015/980)
reg.8 21–36
Transparency Regulations (SI 2015/1755) 26–2
2016 Insolvency (Amendment) Rules (SI 2016/187) 33–15
Register of People with Significant Control 2–42
Regulations (SI 2016/339)
Statutory Auditors and Third Country Auditors 22–2
Regulations (draft)
reg.2 22–36
reg.3(1) 22–11
(d)–(f) 22–27
(g) 22–29
(h) 22–29
(2) 22–11
Pt 4 22–27
reg.4 22–29
reg.8 22–15
Sch.1 para.7 22–15
Sch.2 22–29
TABLE OF EUROPEAN MATERIAL
Directives
1968 Dir.68/151 on co-ordination of safeguards for the 4–34, 5–28, 6–5, 6–11, 6–16, 7–9
protection of the interests of members and others
[1968] OJ L65/8 (First Company Law Directive)
art.2(1)(b) 3–20
art.3 21–37
art.9(2) 32–39
art.11(1)(a) 4–36
art.12(2) 4–37
1977 Dir.77/91 on co-ordination of safeguards for the 6–11, 6–16, 11–2, 11–3, 11–8, 11–10,
protection of the interests of members and others 11–13, 11–17, 12–15, 13–24, 13–25,
[1977] OJ L26/1 (Second Company Law Directive) 13–35, 13–39, 13–44, 13–46, 13–59,
24–1, 28–69
art.2(b) 7–29
art.6 11–8
art.10 11–17
art.10A 11–17
art.10B 11–17
art.11 5–8, 11–17
art.15(1)(a) 12–2, 12–5
(c) 12–3, 12–5
art.17 11–9
art.23 13–46, 13–51
(1) 13–44
art.23A 13–44
art.25 13–51
art.32 13–35
1978 Dir.78/660 on the annual accounts of certain types of 6–11, 6–16, 21–1, 21–13, 21–16, 21–
companies [1978] OJ L222/11 (Fourth Company 17, 21–18, 21–29, 22–5
Law Directive)
art.33(2)(c) 12–3
art.43(1) 16–81
(13) 16–81
art.46A 6–15
Dir.78/855 on mergers of public limited liability 6–11, 6–16, 29–2, 29–12, 29–12, 29–
companies [1978] OJ L295/36 (Third Company 15, 29–17
Law Directive)
1982 Dir.82/891 on the division of public limited liability 6–11, 6–16, 29–2, 29–12, 29–12, 29–15
companies [1982] OJ L378/47 (Sixth Company Law
Directive)
1983 Dir.83/349 on consolidated accounts [1983] OJ 6–11, 6–16, 9–24, 21–1, 21–13, 21–16,
L193/1 (Seventh Company Law Directive) 21–17, 21–18, 21–29
Dir.83/459
art.43(1) 16–81
(13) 16–81
1984 Dir.84/253 on the approval of persons responsible for 6–11, 22–2, 22–5
carrying out the statutory audits of accounting
documents [1984] OJ L126/20 (Eighth Company
Law Directive)
1988 Dir.88/627 on the information to be published when a 26–15
major holding in a listed company is acquired or
disposed of [1988] OJ L348/62
1989 Dir.89/228 25–18
Dir.89/592 co-ordinating regulations on insider 30–11, 30–14, 30–16, 30–18, 30–26
dealing [1989] OJ L334/30
art.1 30–18
art.2(3) 30–14
(4) 30–28
art.5 30–14
Dir.89/666 on disclosure requirements [1989] OJ 6–3, 6–4, 6–5, 6–7, 6–11
L395/36 (Eleventh Company Law Directive)
art.2 6–5
art.8 6–5
Dir.89/667 on single-member private limited-liability 1–3, 2–15, 6–11
companies [1989] OJ L395/40 (Twelfth Company
Law Directive)
art.5 16–60
1993 Dir.93/22 on investment services in the securities field 25–8
[1993] OJ L141/27
1994 Dir.94/19 on deposit-guarantee schemes [1994] OJ
L135/5
art.1(5) 6–4
2001 Dir.2001/34 on the admission of securities to official 25–5, 25–6, 25–10, 25–15, 25–17, 25–
stock exchange listing and on information to be 44, 31–23
published on those securities [2001] OJ L184/1
(Consolidated Admissions Requirements Directive)
(CARD)
Title III Ch.II 25–15
Ch.III 25–15
art.5 25–5
art.8 25–6
art.11 25–15
art.20 25–17
art.43 25–15
art.44 25–15
art.46 25–15, 31–23
art.48 25–15
art.49 25–15
(2) 25–15
art.54 25–15
art.56 25–15
art.58 25–15
art.60 31–23
art.62 25–15
arts 89–97 26–15
art.105 25–5
Annex 1 25–22
Dir.2001/86 supplementing the Statute for a European 1–42, 6–13, 14–67
company with regard to the involvement of
employees [2001] OJ L294/22
2002 Dir.2002/14 establishing a general framework for 3–36
informing and consulting employees in the
European Community [2002] OJ L80/29
Dir.2002/47 on financial collateral arrangements 27–10, 27–15
[2002] OJ L168/43
2003 Dir.2003/6 on insider dealing and market 6–14, 26–9, 30–11, 30–30, 30–30
manipulation [2003] OJ L96/16 (Market Abuse
Directive) (MAD)
Dir.2003/51 on the annual and consolidated accounts 21–1
of certain types of companies, banks and other
financial institutions and insurance undertakings
[2003] OJ L178/16 (Accounts Modernisation
Directive)
Dir.2003/53 [2003] OJ L178 21–16
Dir.2003/58 on disclosure requirements in respect of 6–16
certain types of companies [2003] OJ L221/13
art.1 21–37
Dir.2003/71 on the prospectus to be published when 6–14, 24–3, 25–10, 25–17, 25–18, 25–
securities are offered to the public or admitted to 19, 25–22, 25–26, 25–27, 25–30, 25–
trading [2003] OJ L345/64 (Prospectus Directive) 32, 25–33, 25–35, 25–36, 25–42, 25–
(PD) 44, 26–2, 26–6, 28–16, 30–46, 31–17,
31–18
art.1(2)(h) 25–19
art.2(1)(e) 25–19
(m) 25–44
(n) 25–44
(2) 25–19
art.3 25–17, 25–22
(2) 25–19
(a) 25–19
(b) 25–19
(c) 25–19
(d) 25–19, 31–17, 31–18
(e) 25–19
(3) 25–20
art.4(1)(a) 25–19
(b) 25–19
(d) 25–19
(e) 25–19
(2) 25–20
(a) 25–21
(h) 25–21
art.5(1) 25–22, 25–23
(2) 25–23
(3) 25–25
(4) 25–22
art.6 25–32, 25–35
(2) 25–23, 25–33
art.7(2)(b) 31–17, 31–18
(e) 25–19
(g) 25–19
art.8 25–22
(2) 25–29
art.9(3) 25–25
art.11 25–25
art.12 25–25
art.13 25–28
(4) 25–28
(6) 25–28
art.14 25–30
art.15 25–30
(5) 25–19
art.16 25–24
art.17 31–17
(1) 25–44
(2) 25–44
art.18 25–44
art.20 25–44
art.21(3) 25–32
(a)–(c) 25–28
(d)–(h) 25–42
art.23 25–44
art.25 25–43
Dir.2003/72 supplementing the Statute for a European 1–40
Co-operative Society with regard to the involvement
of employees [2003] OJ L207/25
2004 Dir.2004/25 on takeover bids [2004] OJ L142/12 6–14, 9–23, 15–5, 28–4, 28–5, 28–6,
(Takeovers Directive) (TD) 28–7, 28–9, 28–12, 28–13, 28–14, 28–
15, 28–16, 28–17, 28–18, 28–20, 28–
22, 28–23, 28–33, 28–74
Recital (18) 28–25
art.1(1) 28–13, 28–17
art.2(1)(a) 28–13, 28–14
(d) 28–44
(e) 28–70
art.3 28–18
(1) 28–7
art.4 28–4, 28–7, 28–16
(1) 28–4
(2)(b) 28–16
(c) 28–16
(e) 28–16
(5) 28–7
(6) 28–5, 28–6
art.5 28–41
art.6(5) 28–8
art.9 28–18, 28–20, 28–23, 28–24
(2) 28–33
art.10 21–23, 28–25
art.11 28–22, 28–23, 28–24, 28–25
art.12 28–23
(2) 28–23
(3) 28–20, 28–23, 28–24
art.15 28–69, 28–70
Dir.2004/39 on markets in financial instruments 25–8
[2004] OJ L145/1 (MIFID)
Title II 25–8
Title III 25–8
art.44 25–8
Annex II Pt 1 25–19
Dir.2004/109 on the harmonisation of transparency 6–14, 21–6, 21–32, 21–39, 26–2, 26–3,
requirements in relation to information about issuers 26–4, 26–5, 26–8, 26–14, 26–15, 26–
whose securities are admitted to trading on a 17, 26–20, 26–24, 26–25, 26–26, 26–
regulated market [2004] OJ L390/38 (Transparency 27, 26–29, 26–31, 28–25, 30–40
Directive) (TD)
Ch.III 26–15
art.2(1)(d) 26–16
art.4 21–34, 26–3
art.5(2) 26–3
(4) 26–3
art.6 26–4
art.7 26–25, 26–26
art.9 26–21
(1) 26–17
(2) 26–18
(4) 26–22
(5) 26–22
(6) 26–22
(6a) 26–22
art.10 26–19, 26–21
(a) 26–19
(b) 26–19
(e) 26–19
(f) 26–19
(g) 26–19
(h) 26–19
art.12 26–19
(2) 26–17, 26–18
(5) 26–19
(6) 26–23
art.13 26–19, 26–20, 26–21
(1) 26–20, 26–21
(a) 26–23
(b) 26–19
(2) 26–22
art.13a 26–21
art.15 26–18
art.21 26–8, 26–13, 26–23
art.21a 26–23
art.22 26–23
art.24 21–32, 26–29
art.28(1) 26–29
(c) 26–30
arts 28–28b 26–29
art.28a 26–29
art.28b 26–29
(2) 26–31
art.30(1) 26–29
2005 Dir.2005/56 on cross–border mergers of limited 1–40, 6–12, 6–29, 29–16, 29–17, 29–
liability companies [2005] OJ L310/1 (Cross-Border 20, 29–23, 29–26
Mergers Directive)
Recital (3) 6–27
art.1 29–16
art.4(1)(b) 6–27, 29–23
art.16(1) 29–21
(2) 29–21
(3)(h) 29–21
(4)(a) 29–21
(c) 29–20
2006 Dir.2006/43 on statutory audits of annual accounts 6–11, 21–11, 22–2, 22–5, 22–29
and consolidated accounts [2006] OJ L157/87
(Eighth Directive on Auditors)
Ch.2 22–27
art.1(2)(f) 22–2
art.22 22–12, 22–18
art.22a 22–15
art.26 22–28
art.32 22–11
(4b) 22–11
art.38 22–18
art.39 22–24
(1) 22–24
(2) 22–24
(3) 22–24
(4) 22–24
(6) 22–25
Dir.2006/46 on the annual accounts of certain types of
companies [2006] OJ L224/1
art.1(7) 6–15
Dir.2006/68 on the formation of public limited liability 6–16, 11–13, 13–35, 13–44
companies and the maintenance and alteration of
their capital [2006] OJ L264/32
2007 Dir.2007/14 on implementation of certain provisions
of Dir.2004/109 on the harmonisation of
transparency requirements in relation to information
about issuers whose securities are admitted to
trading on a regulated market [2007] OJ L69/27
art.3 26–3
art.10 26–19
art.11(1) 26–20
Dir.2007/36 on the exercise of certain rights of 6–12, 6–15, 14–39, 15–67, 15–69
shareholders in listed companies [2007] OJ L184/17
(Shareholder Rights Directive)
art.7 15–77
art.12 15–67
art.14 15–75, 15–78
Dir.2007/63 on the requirement of an independent 6–16, 29–13
expert's report on the occasion of merger or division
of public limited liability companies [2007] OJ
L300/47
2009 Dir.2009/49 on disclosure requirements for medium- 6–16
sized companies and the obligation to draw up
consolidated accounts [2009] OJ L164/42
Dir.2009/65 on undertakings for collective investment 31–20
in transferable securities [2009] OJ L302/32
(UCITS)
art.52(1)(a) 31–20
(4) 31–20
Dir.2009/109 on reporting and documentation 1–23, 6–16, 29–12
requirements in the case of mergers and divisions
[2009] OJ L259/14
2010 Dir.2010/73 on the prospectus to be published when 25–10, 25–19
securities are offered to the public or admitted to
trading [2010] OJ L327/1
2012 Dir.2012/6 on the annual accounts of certain types of 21–3
companies as regards micro-entities [2012] OJ
L81/3
Dir.2012/30 on co-ordination of safeguards for the 13–51, 24–1, 24–4, 24–14, 24–16
protection of the interests of members and others in
respect of the formation of public limited liability
companies and the maintenance and alteration of
their capital [2012] OJ L315/74
art.29 24–4
art.32 24–20
art.33 24–6
2013 Dir.2013/34 on the annual financial statements, 14–39, 21–1, 21–2, 21–3, 21–4, 21–11,
consolidated financial statements and related reports 21–14, 21–18, 21–21, 21–22, 21–29,
of certain types of undertakings [2013] OJ L182/19 22–2
Ch.10 21–22
art.2 21–2, 21–6
art.3 21–4, 21–6
(11) 21–2
(12) 21–2
art.4 21–14
(3) 21–14, 21–17
(4) 21–14
art.6 21–15
art.8 21–16
(6) 21–18
art.10 26–19
art.13(2) 21–18
art.14 21–20
art.16(2) 21–21
(3) 21–21
arts 16–18 21–21
art.17 21–21
(1)(r) 21–21
art.18 21–21
art.19 21–24
(11) 30–6
(12) 30–6
(13) 30–7
art.19a 21–24
art.22 21–10
art.23 21–20
art.29 21–24
art.29a 21–24
art.33 21–29
(2) 21–29
art.34 22–5
art.35 21–26
art.36 21–20
(1)(b) 21–21
(3) 21–20
Dir.2013/50 on transparency requirements in relation 26–2, 26–15
to information about issuers whose securities are
admitted to trading on a regulated market [2013] OJ
L294/13
2014 Dir.2014/56 on statutory audits of annual accounts 22–2
and consolidated accounts [2014] OJ L158/196
Dir.2014/57 on criminal sanctions for market abuse 30–4
[2014] OJ L173/179 (Market Abuse Directive)
Dir.2014/65 on markets in financial instruments 25–8, 25–19
[2014] OJ L173/349 (MIFID II)
Dir.2014/91 on undertakings for collective investment 31–20
in transferable securities as regards depositary
functions, remuneration policies and sanctions
[2014] OJ L257/186
Dir.2014/95 on the disclosure of non-financial 21–1, 21–24
information [2014] OJ L330/1
2015 Dir.2015/849 on the prevention of the use of the 2–42
financial system for the purposes of money
laundering or terrorist financing [2015] OJ L141/73
(Fourth Money Laundering Directive)
Regulations
2001 Reg.2157/2001 on the Statute for a European 1–38, 1–42, 6–13, 6–27, 14–66, 29–20
company (SE) [2001] OJ L294/1
Recital (14) 14–66
Preamble 20 1–42
Title III 3–36
art.2 1–44
art.3(2) 1–38
art.4 1–38
art.5 3–36
art.7 6–27
art.8 6–19, 6–27
art.9 2–42, 3–36
(1)(c) 1–42, 3–36, 14–66
art.10 1–42, 3–36
art.11 1–42, 4–14
art.16 1–37
art.38 3–36, 14–66
art.39(1) 14–66
(2) 14–66
(3) 14–66
(5) 14–66
art.40(1) 14–66
(2) 14–66
art.41(3) 14–66
(4) 14–66
art.43(2) 3–36
art.47(4) 14–66
art.48 14–66
art.56 3–36
art.63 1–42
art.64 6–27
art.66 1–44
art.69(a) 6–27
2002 Reg.1606/2002 on the application of international 21–1, 21–18, 21–19, 21–29, 21–30, 21–
accounting standards [2002] OJ L243/1 (IAS 31, 22–3
Regulation)
Recital (9) 21–14
art.2 21–18
art.3 21–19
(2) 21–19
art.4 21–13, 21–18
art.5 21–13, 21–18
art.6 21–19
2003 Reg.1435/2003 on the Statute for a European Co- 1–40
operative Society [2003] OJ L207/1 (SCE)
2004 Reg.809/2004 on information contained in 25–10, 25–15, 25–22, 25–27, 25–28,
prospectuses as well as the format, incorporation by 25–29, 25–42, 25–43, 25–44
reference and publication of such prospectuses and
dissemination of advertisements [2004] OJ L149/1
(Prospectus Regulation)
art.3 25–22
art.4a 25–22
art.5(4) 25–19
art.8 30–46
art.9 30–46
art.10 30–46
art.21(2) 31–17
art.28 25–25
art.29 25–30
art.30 25–30
art.33 25–30
art.34 25–30
Annex I 31–17
para.1 25–35
para.13 25–27
para.14.1 5–4
Annex III para.6.5 30–46
Annex IV 31–17
Annex V 31–17
Reg.2086/2004 on the adoption of certain international 21–18, 21–19
accounting standards in accordance with
Reg.1606/2002 on the insertion of IAS 39 [2004]
OJ L363/1
2005 Reg.1864/2005 on international accounting standards 21–19
[2005] OJ L299/45
2007 Reg.1569/2007 establishing a mechanism for the 25–44
determination of equivalence of accounting
standards applied by third-country issuers of
securities [2007] OJ L340/66
2010 Reg.1095/2010 establishing a European Supervisory
Authority (European Securities and Markets
Authority) [2010] OJ L331/84
art.17 30–49
art.19 30–42, 30–49
2012 Reg.486/2012 on the format and the content of the 25–19
prospectus, the base prospectus, the summary and
the final terms and as regards the disclosure
requirements [2012] OJ L150/1
2013 Reg.575/2013 on prudential requirements for credit
institutions and investment firms [2013] OJ L176/1
art.129 31–20
2014 Reg.537/2014 on specific requirements regarding 22–2
statutory audit of public-interest entities [2014] OJ
L158/77
art.1 22–2
art.2(16) 22–14
art.4(3) 22–25
art.5 22–13
(4) 22–13, 22–25
(5) 22–13
art.6(3) 22–25
art.7 22–21
art.10 22–3
art.11 22–25
art.12 22–21
(3) 22–21
art.13 22–29
art.16 22–14, 22–17, 22–25
(4) 22–25
(5) 22–25
(6) 22–14
art.17 22–14
(7) 22–14
art.21 22–36
art.23(3) 22–29
art.24(1) 22–11, 22–29
art.26 22–29
art.27(1)(c) 22–25
art.29 22–29
arts 30–30b 22–29
art.30a 22–29
Reg.596/2014 [2014] OJ L173/1 (Market Abuse 26–2, 26–5, 26–6, 26–9, 26–12, 26–15,
Regulation) 26–24, 26–25, 26–26, 26–29, 26–30,
26–31, 30–1, 30–4, 30–6, 30–30, 30–
31, 30–32, 30–34, 30–36, 30–37, 30–
38, 30–39, 30–40, 30–41, 30–42, 30–
43, 30–44, 30–46, 30–47, 30–48, 30–
49, 30–50, 30–51, 30–57
Recital (50) 26–6
Ch.4 30–47
Ch.5 30–47
art.2 26–6
art.3(1) 26–11
(25) 26–11
(26) 26–11
art.5 30–43
art.7 26–6
(1) 30–31
(2) 26–6, 30–37
(4) 30–37
art.8(1) 30–31, 30–35
(2) 30–36
(3) 30–36
(4) 30–35
(5) 30–38
art.9(1) 30–38
(2) 30–38
(3) 30–32
(4) 30–38
(5) 30–38
(7) 30–38
art.10(1) 30–36
(3) 30–36
art.12 30–39
(1)(a) 30–39
(b) 30–39
(c) 26–31, 30–40
(d) 30–40
(2)(a) 30–41
(b) 30–41
(c) 30–41
art.13 30–42
(2) 30–42
(3) 30–42
(4) 30–42
(5) 30–42
(6) 30–42
art.14 30–32, 30–33
art.15 30–39
art.17 26–6, 26–8
(1) 26–8
(4) 26–6
(5) 26–7, 27–7
(6) 26–6
(7) 26–6
art.18 26–8
(6) 26–8
art.19(1) 26–13
(2) 26–13
(3) 26–13
(5) 26–11
(6)(g) 26–13
(7) 26–12
(8) 26–12
(14) 26–14
art.21 30–40
art.23(2) 30–48
art.24 30–49
art.25(1) 30–49
(2) 30–49
(5) 30–49
(6) 30–49
(7) 30–49
art.26 30–50
art.27 30–48
art.28 30–48
art.30 30–51
(2)(i) 26–30
(j) 26–30
(3) 30–51
art.32 30–48
(4) 30–48
art.34 30–52
Reg.909/2014 on improving securities settlement in 31–12
the European Union and on central securities
depositaries (CSDs) [2014] OJ L257/1 (CSDR)
Recital (11)
art.3 31–12
(1) 27–4
art.76(2) 27–4
art.79 31–12
2015 Reg.2015/761 supplementing Dir.2004/109 on certain
regulatory technical standards on major holdings
[2015] OJ L120/2
art.5 26–23
Reg.2015/848 on insolvency proceedings [2015] OJ 6–8
L141/19
TABLE OF TAKEOVERS CODE
City Code on Takeovers and Mergers 3–1, 3–14, 14–19, 16–6, 16–27, 19–3,
20–12, 22–45, 28–3, 28–4, 28–5, 28–6,
28–7, 28–8, 28–9, 28–10, 28–11, 28–
12, 28–13, 28–14, 28–15, 28–17, 28–
18, 28–19, 28–20, 28–21, 28–23, 28–
26, 28–27, 28–29, 28–33, 28–34, 28–
35, 28–36, 28–37, 28–38, 28–39, 28–
41, 28–42, 28–44, 28–45, 28–46, 28–
48, 28–49, 28–50, 28–54, 28–55, 28–
56, 28–57, 28–58, 28–62, 28–63, 28–
64, 28–65, 28–68, 28–69, 28–70, 28–
72, 28–74, 28–75, 28–76, 28–77, 29–7,
29–12, 29–13, 30–28
Definitions 28–44, 28–45, 28–56, 28–65
Introduction A8 28–4
Introduction 2(a) 28–37, 28–64
(b) 28–18
(c) 28–7
Introduction 3(a)(i) 28–15
(ii) 28–15
(b) 28–14
Introduction 4(b) 28–18
Introduction 6(b) 28–5
Introduction 6–8 28–5
Introduction 9(a) 28–5, 28–8
Introduction 10 28–7
(b) 28–10
Introduction 11(b) 28–10
General Principle 1 28–18, 28–37, 28–39
General Principle 2 28–18, 28–36
General Principle 3 28–18, 28–20
General Principle 4 28–65
General Principle 5 28–58
General Principle 6 28–56
General Principle 7 28–20
r.1 28–55
(a) 28–55
(b) 28–55
r.2.1 28–57
r.2.2 28–56, 28–57
r.2.3 28–56, 28–57
r.2.4 28–57
n.1 28–57
r.2.6 28–56
r.2.7 28–56
r.2.8 28–56
r.2.12 28–62
r.3 28–27, 28–55
r.3.1 28–27
n.1 28–27
r.3.2 28–27
n.2 28–27
r.3.3 28–27
r.4.1 30–28
r.4.2 28–65
r.4.3 28–67
r.4.5 28–72
r.5 28–35
r.6 28–39
n.3 28–39
r.6.1 28–39, 28–40
(c) 28–39
r.6.2 28–39, 28–40
rr.8.1–8.3 28–65
r.9 28–41, 28–43, 28–44, 28–46
n.1 28–44
r.9.1 28–41, 28–44
n.2 28–44
n.7 28–43
nn.8–15 28–43
r.9.2 28–44
r.9.3 28–41, 28–58
(b) 28–58
r.9.4 28–58
n.1 28–41
r.9.5 28–41
n.3 28–41
r.9.6 28–41
r.9.7 28–41
r.10 28–58
r.11.1 28–40
(c) 28–40
n.4 28–40
n.5 28–40
r.11.2 28–40
n.1 28–40
r.12 28–41, 28–58
r.13 28–56, 28–57, 28–58
r.13.4 28–58
r.13.5 28–58
r.14 28–47
r.14.1 n.3 28–47
r.15 28–47, 28–72
r.16 28–27
r.16.1 28–39
n.1 28–39
n.3 28–39
r.19 28–62, 28–66
r.19.1 28–63
n.9 28–63
r.19.4 28–66
n.1 28–66
n.2 28–66
n.3 28–66
n.4 28–66
n.5 28–66
r.19.5 28–66
n.1 28–66
n.3 28–67
r.19.6 28–67
r.19.7 28–62
r.19.8 28–62
r.20.1 28–67
n.3 28–67
r.20.2 28–34
n.1 28–34
n.3 28–34
r.20.3 28–27
r.21 28–20, 28–21, 28–23
r.21.1 28–20
n.2 28–20
r.21.1(a) 28–20
(b) 28–20
n.2 28–20
r.21.2 28–36
(b) 28–36
n.1 28–36
n.2 28–36
r.23 28–61
r.23.2 28–62
r.24 28–61
r.24.2 28–62
r.24.5 28–29
r.24.6 28–27
r.25 28–27, 28–61
r.25.2 28–62
n.2 28–27
n.4 28–27
n.5 28–27
r.25.5 28–29, 28–32
r.25.9 28–62
r.28 28–63
r.28.1 28–63
r.28.2 28–63
r.28.3 28–63
r.28.4 28–63
r.28.5 28–63
r.29 28–63
r.30.1 28–56, 28–59
r.31.1 28–39, 28–59
r.31.2 28–59
r.31.3 28–59
r.31.4 28–75
r.31.5 28–59
r.31.6 28–59
n.4 28–35
r.32.1 28–39, 28–59
r.32.2 28–59
r.32.3 28–39, 28–59
r.32.4 28–59
r.32.5 28–60
r.32.6 28–62
r.33.1 28–60
r.33.2 28–60
n.2 28–60
r.34 28–35
r.35 28–58
r.35.1 28–58, 28–68
r.35.2 28–58, 28–68
r.35.3 28–68
r.36 28–38
r.36.1 28–38
r.36.2 28–38
r.36.3 28–38
r.36.4 28–38
r.36.6 28–38
r.36.7 28–38
r.37 28–43
r.37.1 n.2 28–43
r.37.3 28–20
Appendix 1 28–43
Appendix 7 28–14
Appendix 7.3(f) 28–36
PART 1
INTRODUCTORY
2–4
The Salomon case established that (a) provided the formalities of
the Act are complied with, a company will be validly
incorporated, even if it is only a “one person” company; and (b)
the courts will be reluctant to treat a shareholder as personally
liable for the debts of the company by “piercing the corporate
veil”.7 Whereas acceptance of the former argument would have
involved denying the separate legal personality of the company,
the second could have been upheld without that consequence,
though it would have involved undermining the concomitant of
separate legal personality, i.e. limited liability (see below).
2–5
The objection of the unsecured creditors in this case was based
on the overvaluation of the business which was sold to the
company in exchange for shares and debentures in it. In the case
of a public company today, the business would be the subject of
an independent valuation so far as it was used to pay up shares,8
but in the case of a private company, or even of debentures
issued by a public company, the main protection of unsecured
creditors lies in disclosure of the company’s financial position.9
Unlike some countries, English law has developed no significant
doctrine whereby loans to a company by its major shareholders
are treated as equity. Even today, the best the unsecured
creditors could hope for is that a floating charge securing a
debenture might be at least partially invalidated if there was
either a successful petition for a winding-up or an administration
order within two years of the creation of the charge.10 In this
case, Salomon was able to give himself protection against the
downside risks of his business by taking a position as secured
creditor through the debentures, whilst taking the full benefit of
any upside gains through his (in effect) 100 per cent
shareholding.11
2–6
Of course, this decision does not mean that a promoter can with
impunity defraud the company which he forms, or swindle his
existing creditors. In the Salomon case it was argued that the
company was entitled to rescind the sale of the business in view
of its wilful overvaluation by Salomon. But the House held that
there was no basis for rescission on the facts, since all the
shareholders were fully conversant with what was being done
and had effectively affirmed the deal. Had Salomon concealed
the profit from his fellow shareholders, the position would have
been different.12 Nor was there any fraud on Salomon’s pre-
incorporation creditors, all of whom were paid off in full out of
the purchase price. Otherwise, they or Salomon’s trustee in
bankruptcy might have been entitled to upset the sale.13
2–7
In any event, since the Salomon case, the complete separation of
the company and its members has never been doubted. The
decision opened up new vistas to company lawyers and the
world of commerce. Not only did it finally establish the legality
of the “one-person” company (long before EC law required this)
and showed that incorporation was as readily available to the
small private partnership and sole trader as to the large public
company, but it also revealed that it was possible for a trader not
merely to limit his liability to the money which he put into the
enterprise but even to avoid any serious risk to the major part of
that by subscribing for secured debentures rather than shares.
This result at the time seemed shocking, and the decision was
much criticised.14 A partial justification for it is that the public
deal with a limited company at their peril and know, or should
know, what to expect.15 In particular a search of the company’s
file at Companies House should reveal its latest annual accounts
and whether there are any charges on the company’s assets.16
2–8
Nonetheless, the doctrine of separate corporate personality is
what underpins much of the success of companies as effective
business structures, and its inviolability was further reinforced in
Prest v Petrodel,17 where the Supreme Court affirmed the
importance of the doctrine and indicated that the courts may only
“pierce the corporate veil” in exceptionally limited
circumstances.18
LIMITED LIABILITY
2–9
It follows from the fact that a corporation is a separate person
that its members are not as such liable for its debts.19 Hence, in
the absence of express provision to the contrary, the members
will be completely free from any personal liability for the
company’s debts. The rule of non-liability also applies to
obligations other than debts: the company is liable and not the
member.
2–10
However, the principle applies only so long as we concentrate on
the position of members as such, and remains true, once the
company ceases to be a going concern, only subject to the
particular terms of the shareholding—then, members may be
required to make contributions to the company’s assets if their
shares were issued on that basis. Something more should be said
about each of these qualifications on limited liability.
2–11
First, members who become involved in the management of the
company’s business, for example as directors, will find that
separate legal personality does not necessarily protect them from
personal liability. Although acting on behalf of the company,
they may have done things which have made them personally
liable to the company or to outsiders. The most obvious example
is that of a tort committed in the course of directorial duties. The
extent to which those acting on behalf of companies are
personally liable for their acts to third parties depends on the
operation of the doctrines of agency and rules such as
assumption of responsibility in tort law and identification in
criminal law. These are matters discussed in Ch.7.
2–12
Secondly, although the doctrine of separate legal personality
normally shields members (as such) from personal liability so
long as the company is a going concern, it does not necessarily
extend further. If a company enters insolvent liquidation, the
question becomes whether the liquidator acting on behalf of the
company can seek contributions from its members so as to bring
the company’s assets up to the level needed to meet the claims of
the company’s creditors. In the case of an unlimited company,20
s.74 of the Insolvency Act does indeed impose on the members
such an obligation to contribute to the assets of the company. In
the case of companies limited by shares or by guarantee,21
however, that obligation is limited (hence, by transfer, the term
“limited company”) and is not, as it is with unlimited companies,
open-ended.
In the case of a company limited by shares, each member is
liable to contribute when called upon to do so the full nominal
value of the shares held insofar as this has not already been paid
by the shareholder or any prior holder of those shares (which it
normally will have been). In the case of a guarantee company,
each member is liable to contribute a specified amount (normally
small) to the assets of the company in the event of its being
wound up while a member, or within one year after ceasing to be
a member. In effect the member, without being directly liable to
the company’s creditors, is in both cases a limited guarantor of
the company. When, therefore, obligations are incurred on
behalf of a limited company, the company is liable and not the
members, though in the case of a guarantee company or of partly
paid shares the company may ultimately be able to recover a
contribution from the members towards the discharge of its
obligations. However, in the typical case of a company limited
by shares with fully paid shares in issue, no further liability will
arise for the member in the absence of specific statutory
provision to the contrary, which provisions are rare.22
2–13
By contrast, an unincorporated association, not being a legal
person, cannot itself be liable, and obligations entered into on its
behalf can bind only the actual officials who purport to act on its
behalf, or the individual members if the officials have actual or
apparent authority to bind them. In either event the persons
bound will be liable to the full extent of their property unless
they expressly or impliedly restrict their responsibility to the
extent of the funds of the association, as the officials may well
do. Hence the extent to which the member will be liable depends
on the terms of the contract of association. In the case of a club,
and presumably most learned and scientific societies, there will
generally be implied a term that the members are not personally
liable for obligations incurred on behalf of the club.
2–14
And the position is different again for members of a partnership,
being an association carrying on business for gain. Each partner
is an agent of all the others, and acts done by any one partner in
“carrying on in the normal way business of the kind carried on
by the firm” bind all the partners.23 Only if the creditor knows of
the limitation placed on the partner’s authority will the other
members escape liability.24 Moreover, an attempt to restrict the
partners’ liability to partnership funds by a provision to that
effect in the partnership agreement will be ineffective even if
known to the creditors25; the partners can restrict their financial
liability, in respect of acts otherwise authorised, only by an
express agreement to that effect with the creditor concerned.26
This explains the pressure, which bore fruit in 2000, for the
creation of an incorporated legal entity with the internal
flexibility of a partnership but the advantage of limited liability,
i.e. the limited liability partnership.27
2–15
The overall result of the broad recognition by the courts of the
separate legal entity of the company and of the limited liability
of its members is to produce at first sight a legal regime which is
very unfavourable to potential creditors of companies, a situation
which they have naturally sought to readjust by contract in their
favour, so far as is in their power. For large lenders, especially
banks, there are a number of possibilities, to be used separately
or cumulatively. Apart from the obvious commercial response of
charging higher interest rates on loans to bodies whose members
have limited liability, such lenders may seek to leap over the
barrier created by the law of limited liability by exacting as the
price of the loan to the company personal guarantees of its
repayment from the managers or shareholders of the company,
guarantees which may be secured on the personal assets of the
individuals concerned. Instead of or in addition to obtaining
personal security by contracting around limited liability, large
lenders may seek to improve the priority of their claims by
taking security against the company’s assets. As we shall see
later on in this chapter, chancery practitioners in the nineteenth
century were quick to respond to this need by creating the
flexible and all-embracing instrument of the floating charge to
supplement the traditional fixed charge mechanisms which were
already available.
However, these self-help remedies may not be practicable for
trade creditors or employees28 and, even in the case of large
lenders, there is a strong danger that, when things begin to go
wrong, the controllers of the company will take risks with the
company’s capital which were not within the contemplation of
the parties when the loan was arranged. For these reasons,
although the legislature has not overturned Salomon v Salomon
and, indeed, under the influence of EU law,29 the one-person
company is now expressly recognised by domestic law, the
Companies and Insolvency Acts are full of provisions whose
purpose cannot be completely understood except against the
background of limited liability. In particular, the extensive
publicity and disclosure obligations placed upon limited liability
companies,30 the provisions relating to wrongful trading,31 and
the expanded provisions on the disqualification of directors,
especially on grounds of unfitness,32 must all be seen in this
light.
PROPERTY
2–16
One obvious advantage of corporate personality is that it enables
the property of the association to be more clearly distinguished
from that of its members. In an unincorporated society, the
property of the association is the joint property of the members.
The rights of the members to that property differ from their
rights to their separate property, since the joint property must be
dealt with according to the rules of the society and no individual
member can claim any particular asset. By virtue of the trust the
obvious complications can be minimised but not completely
eradicated. And the complications cause particular difficulty in
the case of a trading partnership both as regards the true nature
of the interests of the partners33 and as regards claims of
creditors.34 By contrast, on incorporation, the corporate property
belongs to the company, and members have no direct proprietary
rights to it but merely to their “shares” in the undertaking.35 A
change in the membership, which causes inevitable dislocation
to a partnership firm, leaves the company unconcerned; the
shares may be transferred, but the company’s property will be
untouched and no realisation or splitting up of its property will
be necessary, as it will on a change in the constitution of a
partnership firm.
2–17
Identification of the company’s property is not the only
advantage; corporate personality also enables that property to be
segregated from the members’ personal assets. Thus, the claims
of the business creditors will be against the property of the
company and the claims of the members’ personal creditors
against the property of the member. Neither set of creditors is in
competition with the other; and each has to monitor the
disposition only of the assets against which its claims lie.36
SUING AND BEING SUED
2–18
Closely allied to questions of property are those relating to legal
actions. The difficulties in the way of suing, or being sued by, an
unincorporated association have long bedevilled English law.37
The problem is obviously of the greatest practical importance in
connection with trading bodies, and in fact has now been solved
in the case of partnerships by allowing a partnership to sue or be
sued in the firm’s name. Hence, there is now no difficulty so far
as the pure mechanics of suit are concerned—although there
may still be complications in enforcing the judgment.
In the case of other unincorporated bodies (such as clubs and
learned societies) not subject to special statutory provisions, the
problems of suit are still serious. Sometimes its committee or
other agents may be personally liable or authorised to sue.
Otherwise, the only course is a “representative action” whereby,
under certain conditions, one or more persons may sue or be
sued on behalf of all the interested parties.38 But resort to this
procedure is available only subject to compliance with a number
of somewhat ill-defined conditions, and the law, which has been
inadequately explored, is obscure and difficult. The result is apt
to be embarrassing to the society when it wishes to enforce its
rights (or, more properly, those of its members) though it has
compensating advantages when it wishes to evade its duties.39
Needless to say, none of these difficulties arises when an
incorporated company is suing or being sued: the company as a
legal person can take action to enforce its legal rights and can be
sued for breach of its legal duties.
PERPETUAL SUCCESSION
2–19
One of the obvious advantages of an artificial person is that it is
not susceptible to “the thousand natural shocks that flesh is heir
to”. It cannot become incapacitated by illness, mental or
physical, and it has not (or need not have) an allotted span of
life.40 This is not to say that the death or incapacity of its human
members may not cause the company considerable
embarrassment; obviously it will if all the directors die or are
imprisoned, or if there are too few surviving members to hold a
valid meeting, or if the bulk of the members or directors become
enemy aliens.41 But these vicissitudes of the flesh have no direct
effect on the disembodied company.42 The death of a member
leaves the company unmoved; members may come and go but
the company can go on forever.43 The insanity of the managing
director will not be calamitous to the company provided that he
is removed promptly; he may be the company’s brains, but
lobectomy is a simpler operation than on a natural person.
2–20
Once again, the disadvantages in the case of an unincorporated
society can be minimised by the use of a trust. If the property of
the association is vested in a small body of trustees, the death,
disability or retirement of an individual member, other than one
of the trustees, need not cause much trouble. But, of course, the
trustees, if natural persons, will themselves need replacing at
fairly frequent intervals and the need for constant appointment of
new trustees is a nuisance if nothing worse. Indeed, it may be
said that the trust never functioned at its simplest until it was
able to enlist the aid of its own child, the incorporated company,
to act as a trust corporation with perpetual succession.
Moreover, the trust can obviate difficulties easily only when a
member, or his estate, has, under the constitution of the
association, no right to be paid a share of the assets on death or
retirement, which, of course, is the position with the normal club
or learned society. But on the retirement or death of a partner,
the default rule is that the partnership is automatically dissolved,
so far at any rate as the departing partner is concerned,44 and he
or his estate will be entitled to be paid his share. The resulting
dislocation of the firm’s business can be reduced by special
clauses in the articles of partnership, providing for a formula for
valuation of his share and for deferred payment, but cannot be
eradicated altogether.45
2–21
With an incorporated company these problems do not arise.
Although the member or his estate is not generally entitled to be
paid out by the company, if the member (or a personal
representative, trustee in bankruptcy, or receiver) wishes to
realise the value of the shares, these can be sold, whereupon the
purchaser will, on entry in the share register, become a member
in place of the former holder. This is not always as easy as it
sounds, however. The seller might not be able to find a
purchaser at all, especially one who meets any restrictions which
might be imposed on transfer,46 and the other members might not
have sufficient free capital to purchase the shares. Now,
therefore, but subject to stringent conditions, purchase by the
company is allowed,47 as it has long been under the laws of
many other countries.
2–22
The continuing existence of a company, irrespective of changes
in its membership or its management, is helpful in other
directions also. When an individual sells a business to another,
difficult questions may arise regarding the performance of
existing contracts by the new proprietor,48 the assignment of
rights of a personal nature,49 and the validity of agreements made
with customers ignorant of the change of proprietorship.50
Similar problems may arise on a change in the constitution of a
partnership.51 Where the business is incorporated and the sale is
merely of the shares, none of these difficulties arises. The
company remains the proprietor of the business, performs the
existing contracts and retains the benefits of them, and enters
into future agreements. The difficulties attending vicarious
performance, assignments and mistaken identity do not arise.
2–23
Although a company may shift control of its business by means
of a transfer of its shares to new investors, it does not follow that
it will always choose this method of effecting the change of
control. The directors or shareholders of the company could
decide instead to sell the underlying business of the company to
the new investors, who, perhaps, may form their own company
in order to take the new business. In this case, the transferring
company (rather than its shareholders) will be left holding the
consideration received on the sale of its business. This method is
particularly likely to be attractive to the transferring company if
it is divesting itself of control of only part of its business (though
even then a transfer of control by sale of shares may be possible
if the relevant part of the business is held in a separate group
subsidiary company). When a company disposes of the whole or
part of its business (as opposed to the shareholders deciding to
transfer their shares), the difficulties mentioned in the previous
paragraph in relation to the sale of a business by an
unincorporated entity arise in relation to companies as well. To
sum up, a company,52 unlike an unincorporated body, has the
option to shift control by means of a transfer of shares, but it
may choose instead to dispose of the underlying business (or
even just of the assets used in the business).
TRANSFERABLE SHARES
2–24
Incorporation, with the resulting separation of the business
(owned by the company) from the shares (owned by its
members), greatly facilitates the transfer of the members’
interests. Without this formal incorporation of the business
enterprise, approximately the same ends can be achieved through
the device of the trust coupled with an agreement for
transferability in the deed of settlement. But in this case, even
after transfer, the member will remain liable for the firm’s debts
incurred during the time when he or she was a member.53 This
ongoing liability (i.e. the absence of limited liability associated
with companies) means that opportunities to transfer are, in
practice, much restricted.
A partner has a proprietary interest which can be assigned
(subject to the terms of the partnership deed), but the assignment
does not operate to divest the partner of status or liability as a
partner; it merely affords the assignee the right to receive
whatever the firm distributes in respect of the assigning partner’s
share.54 The assignee can be admitted into partnership in the
place of the assignor only if the other partners agree55 and the
assignor will not be relieved of any existing liabilities as a
partner unless the creditors agree, expressly or impliedly, to the
release.56
2–25
With an incorporated company, freedom to transfer members’
interests, both legally and practically, can be readily attained.
The company can be incorporated with its liability limited by
shares, and these shares constitute items of property which are
freely transferable in the absence of express provision to the
contrary, and in such a way that the transferor drops out57 and
the transferee steps into his shoes.
2–26
Even in an incorporated company, the power to transfer may, of
course, be subject to restrictions. In a private company some
form of restriction was formerly essential in order to comply
with the then current statutory definition; although this is no
longer a statutory requirement, it is still a desirable provision if
such a company is to retain its character as an incorporated
private partnership. In practice, these restrictions are usually so
stringent as to make transferability largely illusory. Nor is there
any legal objection arising out of the Companies Act to
restrictions in the case of a public company, although such
restrictions, except as regards partly paid shares, are unusual,
and are prohibited by the Listing Rules if the shares are to be
marketed on the Stock Exchange.58 But there is this fundamental
difference: in a partnership, transferability depends on express
agreement and is subject to legal and practical limitations,
whereas in a company it exists to the fullest extent in the absence
of express restriction. The partnership relationship is essentially
personal, and where a private company is, functionally, an
incorporated partnership, the same approach is maintained.59 On
the other hand, the relationship between members of a public
company is essentially impersonal and financial and hence there
is usually no reason to restrict changes in membership.
MANAGEMENT UNDER A BOARD STRUCTURE
2–27
A further important feature of company law is that it provides a
structure for the pursuit of larger and riskier endeavours by
allowing many people to participate, via the purchase of shares,
and separating that participation from the management of the
company, which is delegated to a smaller and expert group of
people who partly constitute and who are partly supervised by a
board of directors. This separation of what is conventionally, but
controversially, termed “ownership” of the company (i.e.
shareholding) from its “control” (i.e. management) is a feature of
large companies and it is therefore important that the
organisational law governing companies should deal with its
consequences. By contrast, as with transferable shares, this is not
a feature of small companies, where “owners” and “managers”
are often identical people, or substantially so. Then, as noted in
Ch.1,60 the corporate machinery for separating these roles may
be more of a hindrance than a help, but it is crucial in the
efficient functioning of large companies.
2–28
The legal implications of this development were first explored in
the US by A.A. Berle and G.C. Means in The Modern
Corporation and Private Property,61 which drew attention to the
revolutionary change thus brought about in our traditional
conceptions of the nature of property. Today, the great bulk of
large enterprise, at least in the US and the UK, is in the hands
not of individual entrepreneurs but of large public companies in
which many individuals have property rights as shareholders in
the enterprise to which they have directly or indirectly
contributed capital. After home ownership, direct or indirect62
investment in companies probably constitutes the most important
single item of property for most people, and yet whether this
property brings profit to its “owners” no longer depends on their
energy and initiative but on that of the management from which
they are divorced. The modern shareholder in a public company
has ceased to be a quasi-partner and has become instead simply a
supplier of capital. If a person invests in the older forms of
private property, such as a farm or a shop, he or she becomes
tied to that property and the business endeavour. The modern
public company provides a new type of property in which the
relationship between the “owner” and the business plays little
part; and indeed the owner can realise the wealth represented by
the property whenever needed, by selling shares, and therefore
without removing the business property from the enterprise
which requires it indefinitely. “The separation of ownership
from management and control in the corporate system has
performed this essential step in securing liquidity.”63
Even when, as is increasingly the case, shareholding in large
companies is concentrated in the hands of institutional
shareholders, such as pension funds and insurance companies,
which do have a more significant potential for intervention in
management than individual shareholders, such participation is
discontinuous or episodic and usually precipitated by some crisis
in the company’s affairs rather than a day-to-day way of
managing the company.64
2–29
Despite the fact that the board, and especially the “managing
director” or the “chief executive officer”, is the driving force
behind the operation of the large company, the British
Companies Act, unlike its continental counterparts, says very
little about the board of directors. The Act insists there be
directors, but only two are required in the case of a public
company and, in the case of a private company, one will do.65
Many sections of the Act impose administrative burdens on the
directors or assume in some other way the existence of a board
of directors, but the composition, structure and functions of the
board are left to a very high degree to companies to decide
themselves, through their articles of association66 or through
mere corporate practice. In the case of listed companies,
however, this private ordering by companies themselves has
become significantly qualified by the development in the last 18
years of the UK Corporate Governance Code and its
predecessors.67
2–30
In the face of this “hands off” approach on the part of the Act,
can the claim be made good that British company law provides
machinery, except in the most rudimentary way, whereby the
separation of ownership and control can flourish? The most
obvious answer to this question consists in pointing to the duties
created originally by the common law, but now restated in the
Act, which aim to require the directors to exercise the powers
conferred upon them competently and loyally in the interests of
the company, which is normally to be seen as the interests of the
shareholders.68 Thus, one may say that the approach of company
law to the regulation of the separation of ownership from control
is to allow companies maximum freedom to decide on the
division of powers between shareholders and board and on the
functions of the board, but then to concentrate on the regulation
of the way the board discharges the powers conferred upon it,
whatever they may be. How successfully this is done is the topic
of later chapters. All we need note here is the importance of the
fact that in large companies there are two decision-making
bodies, shareholders in general meeting and the board of
directors, and that in terms of management functions the board is
invariably the more important organ.
BORROWING
2–31
So far we have considered only the advantages or disadvantages
which flow inevitably or naturally from the fact of incorporation.
But incorporation also has important consequences in respect of
borrowing and taxation.
2–32
At first sight one might suppose that a sole trader, or partners,
being personally liable, would find it easier than a company to
raise money by borrowing. In practice, however, this is not so,
since a company is often able to grant a more effective charge to
secure the proposed indebtedness. The ingenuity of equity
practitioners led to the evolution of an unusual but highly
beneficial type of security known as the floating charge; i.e. a
charge which “floats” over all the assets of the company falling
within a generic description, but without preventing the chargor
from disposing of those assets in the usual course of business, at
least until something occurs to cause the charge to become
crystallised or fixed. This type of charge is particularly suitable
when a business has no fixed assets, such as land, which can be
included in a normal security, but carries a large and valuable
stock-in-trade. Since this stock needs to be turned over in the
course of business, a fixed charge is impracticable because the
consent of the chargee would be needed every time anything was
sold, and a new charge would have to be entered into whenever
anything was bought. A floating charge obviates these
difficulties; it enables the stock to be turned over, but (if defined
widely enough) attaches to whatever it is converted into and to
whatever new stock is acquired.
In theory, there is no reason why such charges should not be
granted by sole traders and ordinary partnerships as well as by
incorporated companies (and now, LLPs). But two pieces of
legislation have effectively precluded that. The first was the
“reputed ownership” provision in the bankruptcy legislation
relating to individuals.69 This provision never applied to the
winding-up of companies, and has now been repealed for
individuals by the Insolvency Act 1986.70 The second, which
still remains, is that the charge, insofar as it relates to chattels,
would be a bill of sale within the meaning of the Bills of Sale
Acts 1878 and 1882, which apply only to individuals and not to
companies.71 Hence it would need to be registered in the Bills of
Sale Registry,72 and, what is more important, as a mortgage bill
it would need to be in the statutory form,73 which involves
specifying the chattels in detail in a schedule. Compliance with
the latter requirement is obviously impossible, since in a floating
charge the chattels are, by definition, indeterminate and
fluctuating.
2–33
When, belatedly, we eventually get round to reforming, as many
common law countries have done, our antiquated law relating to
security interests in movables, we shall be able to repeal the Bills
of Sale Acts and thus make it practicable for unincorporated
firms to borrow on the security of floating charges,74 or some
comparable form of security on the lines of that provided by
art.9 of the American Uniform Commercial code. In the
meantime, use of this advantageous form of security is in
practice restricted to bodies corporate. By virtue of it the lender
can obtain an effective security on “all the undertaking and
assets of the company both present and future” either alone or in
conjunction with a fixed charge on its land.75 By so doing the
lender can place himself in a far stronger position than if merely
the personal security of the individual trader supported the loan.
It therefore happens not infrequently that a business is converted
into a company solely in order to enable further capital to be
raised by borrowing. And sometimes, as the Salomon case76
shows, a trader by “selling” his business to a company which he
has formed can give himself priority over his future creditors by
taking a debenture, secured by a floating charge, for the purchase
price.77
TAXATION
2–34
Once a company reaches a certain size, the attraction of limited
liability is likely to outweigh all other considerations when
business people are considering in what form to carry on their
activities. Investors are unlikely to be willing to put money into a
company where their liability is not limited, especially if they
are to have no or little control over the running of the company.
However, with small businesses, where it is feasible to give all
the investors a say in management, it is likely that tax
considerations will play a major part in determining whether the
business will be set up in corporate form or as a partnership,
especially as in such cases where, as we have seen, limited
liability may not be available in practice vis-à-vis large lenders.78
This is not the place to examine the tax considerations which
may cut one way or another at different times on this issue. What
should be noted, however, is that in the case of small companies,
the investors’ return on their capital may take the form of the
payment of directors’ fees rather than dividends, so that
participation in the management of the company may be the
means for the investor both to safeguard the investment and to
earn a return on it.79
FORMALITIES AND EXPENSE
2–35
Turning from advantages to costs, incorporation is necessarily
attended with formalities, loss of privacy (see below) and
expense greater than that which would normally apply to a sole
trader or partnership. A sole trader already exists. A partnership
arises out of the facts of a relationship, and does not need a
formal agreement provided the parties are carrying on a business
in common with a view of profit.80 An unincorporated firm can
conduct its affairs without any formality and publicity beyond
that which may be prescribed by the regulations (if any)
applying to the particular type of business. If the business is
carried on under a name different from the true name of the sole
trader or those of all the partners, it will have to comply with the
provisions on business names (as would a company trading
under a pseudonym)81 but these are not onerous. The business,
unless it is insolvent, can eventually be wound up equally
cheaply, privately and informally. An incorporated company, on
the other hand, necessarily involves formalities, publicity and
expenses at its birth, throughout its active life, and on its final
dissolution.
2–36
The costs of formation, at least of a private company (and most
companies are formed as private even if they become public later
in life), are very low, however. A competent incorporation agent
should be able to set up a basic company for less than £200.
British law does not require a private company, unlike a public
one, to have a minimum share capital.82 Consequently, the
incorporators can borrow what money they need to set the
company up and do not need to sink their own money into it,
which, indeed, they may not have. However, the combination of
no minimum capital and limited liability could be an invitation
to trading at the expense of the creditors, and so British law,
even if it has no ex ante minimum capital requirement, has
developed significant ex post controls on those who behave in
this way after the company has been formed.83
2–37
Once the company is set up, there are also ongoing formalities
and reporting requirements to meet. These ensure a degree of
transparency that is not demanded of sole traders or partnerships.
At the least, the documents on the public record remain accurate
(so, for example, changes to the company’s directors, and to its
constitution must be filed84), and the state of the company
business must be made visible, at least to some extent, to those
who might deal with the company in the future—so security
granted over the company’s assets should be registered,85 and
annual accounts may need to be filed.86
2–38
Finally, we have noted at a number of points in this chapter that
the requirement of two separate decision-making organs,
shareholders’ meeting and board of directors, may seem over-
elaborate for small companies, though something has now been
done to alleviate this problem without, however, going to the
extent of permitting small companies to adopt a single decision-
making body.87
PUBLICITY
The company’s affairs
2–39
As already noted, the costs of incorporation also come with the
much greater publicity required of a company as against a
partnership, since the former is required, but the latter is not, to
make their annual accounts available publicly through filing at
Companies House.88 Until recently, small companies were
required, in addition, to produce accounts in what was an over-
elaborate format and to have those accounts audited, but these
requirements have now been relaxed.89
The company’s members and directors
2–40
Further, since a company can only act through the individuals
behind the company—principally its board of directors, but also
its members in general meeting—it is probably not surprising
that there should be public registers of both the directors and the
members, with more details required of the former (although
now increasingly limited by concerns of privacy and personal
safety).90
2–41
Disclosure of a company’s members was never especially
reliable, however, for the simple reason that s.126 prohibits
trusts of any sort from being entered on the register of members.
This means that the “real” owners of shares are not necessarily
discoverable, even when the (disclosed) legal owner must
comply absolutely with their directions on voting and
distribution of the economic benefits of the shareholding. This is
now the subject of significant change, as outlined below.
“People with significant control”—the PSC Register
2–42
From 2016, almost all companies will be required to keep, open
to the public, a register of “people with significant control”,
called the company’s PSC Register (ss.790C(10), 790M).91 This
does not require the company to disclose every beneficial
interest in its shareholdings, but it does require disclosure of
every person (human or corporate) who is able to exert
“significant influence or control” over the company’s business,
with that phrase defined in the Act, amplified by Regulations,92
and then supplemented by formal statutory Guidance93—all seen
as necessary, given the potential breadth of the definition.
2–43
The government’s objectives in implementing these reforms on
transparency in corporate control is to ensure that the “UK is,
and is seen to be, an open and trusted place to invest and do
business. Knowing who ultimately owns and controls our
companies will contribute to that objective”; and, in addition, to
“deter and disrupt the misuse of companies,94 and identify and
sanction those responsible when illegal activity does take
place”.95
2–44
To these ends, the company must keep a register of people “with
significant control over the company” (s.790M(1)). Interestingly,
the information is not to be removed from the Register until 10
years after the person ceases to have such control (s.790U(1)). A
person is deemed to have such control (i.e. to be a PSC) if they
meet at least one of the following five conditions:
(i) directly or indirectly hold more than 25 per cent of the
nominal share capital; or
(ii) directly or indirectly control more than 25 per cent of the
votes at general meetings; or
(iii) directly or indirectly are able to control the appointment or
removal of a majority of the board; or
(iv) actually exercise, or have the right to exercise, significant
influence or control over the company; or
(v) actually exercise or have the right to exercise significant
influence or control over any trust or firm (which is not a
legal entity) which has significant control (under one of the
four conditions above) over the company.
Both the Act, the Regulations and the formal statutory Guidance
contain detailed provisions relating to the interpretation of these
five conditions.96
The real breadth in the disclosure rules is embraced by the
expression “significant influence or control”. The statutory
Guidance indicates that influence and control are alternatives,
and that neither needs to be in fact exercised by the PSC, nor
exercised by the PSC with a view to its own economic benefit.
“Control” indicates that the PSC is able to direct the company’s
activities, while “influence” indicates that the PSC can ensure (in
fact, rather than as a matter of legal right) that the company
generally adopts the activities which the PSC desires.97 As
illustrations of the latter, the Guidance suggests that such
influence could arise because the PSC owns intellectual
property, or was the company’s founder, or is indeed a shadow
director.98 If interests are held jointly, then the above tests are to
be applied to each person as if each joint holder held the entire
interest (Sch.1A regs 11, 12). The intended breadth is clear—the
goal is to identify exactly who is pulling the strings behind the
corporate veil.99
Of course, this definition is so wide that it embraces those
whose control or influence is far from sinister, and whose
identity ought not to be necessarily revealed as a PSC. Thus the
Guidance excludes parties who merely have the ability to
exercise the usual veto rights given to all members to protect
their personal interests (e.g. in amending the constitution,
preventing share dilution, limiting corporate borrowing, or
winding up the company). Similarly exempted are parties such
as the company’s professional advisers, third party suppliers etc.,
liquidators, the company’s own managing director, and any non-
executive directors with a casting vote.100
These inclusions and exclusions amply demonstrate the
tightrope being walked in articulating a satisfactory and
workable definition of PSCs.
2–45
Even with a watertight definition of a PSC, the next difficulty is
how the company is to collect the information it is required to
register. The company has a duty to gather the necessary
information and keep it up to date (ss.790D, 790E), and the
requested parties a corresponding duty to supply the information
and keep it up to date (ss.790G, 790H), with the company and
every officer or other party in default otherwise held to have
committed an offence (s.790F, 790I and Sch.1B). The
company’s arm is strengthened, in that failure by an individual
or legal entity to respond to the company’s enquiries will give
the company the ability (without a court order) to disenfranchise,
and impose other restrictions on, any shares held by the
individual.101 The risk of misinformation is not insignificant, and
the company is required to confirm all the details before they are
registered (s.790M), although quite how this is to be done is not
clear. In addition, given the possible risks associated with
disclosing these details of significant corporate “control or
influence”, there are extensive provisions on protecting both
information and individuals from relevant disclosures (s.790ZF,
Sch.1A Ch.5).
2–46
Once the details have been gathered, the company must make its
own PSC Register open to inspection by the public without
charge (ss.790N, 790O),102 or alternatively it may elect to have
the register kept by Companies House for this purpose (s.790W).
Access to the Register is not unrestricted, however. Those
seeking inspection must provide their name, address and the
purpose for which they seek access (ss.790O(4), with it being an
offence to knowingly or recklessly mislead in this regard, or to
pass on the information so gleaned to other parties—s.790R). It
is easy to see that without this restriction, access might be
abused, but at this distance it is difficult to predict quite which
purposes the courts might regard as proper, other than searches
by government agencies seeking evidence of identity when
pursuing suspected illicit activities. We will see these “proper
purpose” restrictions in operation in other contexts where access
to registers is sought,103 however, and here too the company is
given a time-limited right to apply to court to seek an order that
it need not make the requested disclosure (s.790P).
2–47
These provisions may seem unremarkable to those who are
unfamiliar with the history of companies in the UK, but they
represent one of the more radical departures from the status quo
seen for some time.104 No doubt they reflect the reality that
companies can be used for evil as well as good, and the
corporate form has to date provided an effective shield of
anonymity behind which those in real control can hide. Perhaps
these days there is in any event greater recognition that, even
when the corporate activities are all for the good, companies
wield such power and influence (over 95 per cent of businesses
are run through companies) that it is perhaps as well to have
some means of knowing who really lies behind the corporate
structure.
CONCLUSION
2–48
The balance of advantage and disadvantage in relation to
incorporation no doubt varies from one business context to
another, at least as far as small firms are concerned; for large
trading organisations, the arguments in favour of incorporation
are normally conclusive. This may reflect the firms’ respective
needs for expert centralised management and capital to finance
their operations. For large firms the division between board and
shareholders, transferable shares and the conferment of limited
liability on the shareholders are helpful for the raising of capital.
As for the large firm which does not have a large capital
requirement, such as large professional firms, these have happily
traded as partnerships in the past and were, indeed, often
required to do so by the rules of the relevant profession, most of
which have now been relaxed. Unlimited liability was seen as a
badge of professional respectability. However, the threat of
crippling damages awards for professional negligence led the
accountancy profession in particular to press for an appropriate
form of limited liability vehicle for the conduct of their
businesses. As we saw in Ch.1,105 this led to the creation of the
limited liability partnership, which combines the limited liability
of the company with the flat internal hierarchy of the
partnership. However, where the large firm means also a need
for a large amount of risk capital, the corporate form
predominates.
The main policy issue, therefore, has been how far small firms
should have easy access to the corporate form. Ever since the
decision in Salomon v Salomon,106 English law has leant in
favour of not restricting access, and the Company Law Review
endorsed that approach.107 As we shall see in Pt 2, the issue is
essentially about the access of small business to limited liability,
since that feature of incorporation has a major potential impact
on third parties who deal with the company, whilst separate legal
personality, management under a board structure and
transferable shares seem either benign, as far as third parties are
concerned, or of concern only to those within the company.
1 A company, even if it has only one member, is a “corporation aggregate” as opposed to
the somewhat anomalous “corporation sole” in which an office, e.g. that of a bishop, is
personified.
2 Salomon v Salomon [1897] A.C. 22 HL.
3
Salomon v Salomon [1897] A.C. 22 HL at 49, per Lord Macnaghten.
4 Salomon v Salomon [1897] A.C. 22 HL at 31.
5 Salomon v Salomon [1897] A.C. 22 HL at 51.
6
For an early statutory recognition of the same principle, see the House of Commons
(Disqualification) Act 1782, which disqualified those holding Government contracts
from election to Parliament but expressly provided (s.3) that the prohibition did not
extend to members of incorporated companies holding such contracts.
7
See further Ch.8.
8
See para.11–13. However, since Salomon was the only beneficial shareholder, it really
mattered little to him whether he was issued with 20,000 or 10 shares in exchange for
the business, for the value of the shares in aggregate (no matter how many or how few),
would be the same, i.e. they represent the economic value (if any) of the business.
However, independent valuation might protect creditors from being misled about the
value of the assets contributed to the company, and also enable any new shareholders to
ensure their relative financial inputs were reflected in the relative size of their
shareholding.
9 See below, Ch.21.
10 Insolvency Act 1986 s.245. See para.32–14.
11
But, in this particular case, Salomon seems to have been one of the victims rather than
the villain of the piece for he had mortgaged his debentures and used the money to try to
support the tottering company. However, the result would have been the same if he had
not, and even if he had been the only creditor to receive anything from the business,
which was “his” in fact though not in law.
12 See para.5–2 and paras 5–23 et seq.
13 Under what are now ss.423–425 of the Insolvency Act 1986.
14 See, e.g. O. Kahn-Freund, “Some Reflections on Company Law Reform” in (1944) 7
M.L.R. 54 (a thought-provoking article still well worth study) in which it is described as
a “calamitous decision”. For a more positive assessment see D. Goddard, “Corporate
Personality—Limited Recourse and its Limits” in R. Grantham and C. Rickett (eds)
Corporate Personality in the Twentieth Century (Oxford: Hart Publishing, 1998). On the
rationales for limited liability, see para.8–1.
15 Although there are undoubtedly many who think that “Ltd” is an indication of size
and stability (which “Plc” may be but “Ltd” certainly is not) rather than a warning of
limited access to assets (i.e. access confined to the company’s assets, however few, with
no access to the shareholders’).
16 And in the House of Lords no sympathy was wasted on those who do not search the
registers: “A creditor who will not take the trouble to use the means which the statute
provides for enabling him to protect himself must bear the consequences of his own
negligence”: [1897] A.C. 22 at 40, per Lord Watson.
17 Prest v Petrodel [2013] UKSC 34.
18
See Ch.8; and note also Antonio Gramsci Shipping Corp v Aivars Lembergs [2013]
EWCA Civ 730.
19 This sentence was quoted and relied on by Kerr LJ in Rayner (Mincing Lane) Ltd v
Department of Trade [1989] Ch.72 at 176 as an accurate statement of English law
although, as he pointed out, it is not accurate in relation to most Civil Law countries—
including Scotland so far as partnerships are concerned—or to international law: ibid. at
176–183.
20 See above, para.1–27.
21
See above, paras 1–8 and 1–11.
22
See Ch.9.
23
Partnership Act 1890 s.5. This applies equally to Scotland thus largely negativing the
consequence of recognising the Scottish firm as a separate person.
24
Partnership Act 1890 ss.5 and 8.
25
Re Sea, Fire and Life Insurance Co (1854) 3 De G.M. & G. 459.
26
Hallett v Dowdall (1852) 21 L.J.Q.B. 98.
27
Limited Liability Partnerships Act 2000. See para.1–4.
28
Unless and to the extent that they have a statutory preference, unsecured creditors are
in the worst possible world. Limited liability normally stops them suing the shareholders
or directors, whilst the fixed and floating charges of the big lenders often soak up all the
available assets of the company.
29See Council Directive 89/667 on single-member private limited liability companies
[1989] O.J. L395, 12 December 1989.
30See below, Ch.21, but note s.448 whereby the directors of unlimited liability
companies are not normally required to deliver accounts and reports to the registrar for
general publication.
31
See para.9–6.
32 See Ch.10.
33 See Partnership Act 1890 ss.20–22; Re Fuller’s Contract [1933] Ch. 652.
34
Partnership Act 1890 s.23, and the Insolvent Partnerships Order 1994 (SI 1994/2421),
as amended.
35“Shareholders are not, in the eye of the law, part owners of the undertaking. The
undertaking is something different from the totality of the shareholdings”: per Evershed
LJ in Short v Treasury Commissioners [1948] 1 K.B. 116, 122 CA; affirmed [1948] A.C.
534 HL.
36
R. Kraakman and H. Hansmann, “The Essential Role of Organizational Law” (2000)
110 Yale L.J. 387.
37 As we saw above (para.1–3) this problem seems to have lain behind the former
restriction of the number of partners to a maximum of 20.
38CPR 19.6, permitting representative actions. The provision is strictly interpreted:
Emerald Supplies Ltd v British Airways Plc [2010] EWCA Civ 1284.
39“An unincorporated association has certain advantages when litigation is desired
against them”: per Scrutton LJ in Bloom v National Federation of Discharged Soldiers
(1918) 35 T.L.R. 50, 51 CA.
40 Insolvency Act 1986 s.84(1)(a) envisages that the period of the company’s duration
may be fixed in the articles, but this is rarely done in practice and, even if it were, the
company would not automatically expire on the expiration of the term; the section
provides that expiration of the term is a ground on which the members by ordinary
resolution may wind the company up voluntarily. It is otherwise with chartered
companies: see para.1–31, fn.89.
41
cf. Daimler Co v Continental Tyre and Rubber Co [1916] 2 A.C. 307 HL.
42
As Greer LJ said in Stepney Corporation v Osofsky [1937] 3 All E.R. 289 at 291 CA:
a corporate body has “no soul to be saved or body to be kicked”. This epigram is
believed to be of considerable antiquity. G. Williams, Criminal Law: The General Part,
2nd edn (London: Steven & Sons), p.856, has traced it back to Lord Thurlow and an
earlier variation to Coke, cf. the decree of Pope Innocent IV forbidding the
excommunication of corporations because, having neither minds nor souls, they could
not sin: see C.T. Carr, The General Principles of the Law of Corporations (Cambridge:
CUP, 1905), p.73. In Rolloswin Investments Ltd v Chromolit Portugal SARL [1970] 1
W.L.R. 912 it was held that since a company was incapable of public worship it was not
a “person” within the meaning of the Sunday Observance Act 1677 so that a contract
made by it on a Sunday was not void (the court was unaware that before the case was
heard the Act had been repealed by the Statute Law (Repeals) Act 1969).
43During the Second World War all the members of one private company, while in
general meeting, were killed by a bomb. But the company survived; not even a nuclear
bomb could have destroyed it. And see the Australian case of Re Noel Tedman Holding
Pty Ltd (1967) Qd.R. 561 Qd Sup Ct where the only two members were killed in a road
accident.
44
And, in the absence of contrary agreement, as regards all the partners: Partnership Act
1890 s.33.
45 Also see below, para.2–23.
46
For an unsuccessful attempt to use the unfair prejudice provisions to secure the return
to the shareholder’s estates of the capital represented by his shares see Re A Company
[1983] Ch. 178; and see also the explanation of this case in Re A Company [1986]
B.C.L.C. 382 (para.20–8).
47
See para.13–17.
48
Robson v Drummond (1831) 2 B. & Ad. 303; cf. British Waggon Co v Lea (1880) 5
Q.B.D. 149.
49 Griffith v Tower Publishing Co [1897] 1 Ch. 21 (publishing agreement held not
assignable); Kemp v Baerselman [1906] 2 K.B. 604 CA (agreement not assignable if
question of one party’s obligation depends on the other’s “personal requirements”), cf.
Tolhurst v Associated Portland Cement [1902] 2 K.B. 660 CA.
50 Boulton v Jones (1857) 2 H. & N. 564.
51See Brace v Calder [1895] 2 Q.B. 253 CA where the retirement of two partners was
held to operate as the wrongful dismissal of a manager. And see also Partnership Act
1890 s.18. In practice such difficulties are often avoided by an implied novation.
52 Of course, even in relation to companies this proposition applies only to companies
limited by shares and not to guarantee companies.
53This assumes the member was, as a member, personally liable; this is not always the
case. See above, para.2–7.
54 Partnership Act 1890 s.31.
55
Partnership Act 1890 s.24(7).
56 Partnership Act 1890 s.17(2) and (3).
57
Companies Act 2006 s.544. Subject only to a possible liability under ss.74 and 76 of
the Insolvency Act 1986 if liquidation follows within a year and the shares were not
fully paid up or were redeemed or purchased out of capital. On the latter see para.13–18.
58
See para.25–15.
59
In recent years the courts have shown a welcome tendency to recognise this functional
reality in applying the legal rules to such incorporated partnerships: see especially
Ebrahimi v Westbourne Galleries Ltd [1973] A.C. 360 HL. See below, Ch.20.
60
See above, para.1–28 and below, Ch.15.
61
New York, 1933, reprinted in 1968 with a new preface.
62 For most people the investment is indirect, perhaps even not conscious, as in the case
of contributions to occupational pension schemes.
63 See above, fn.61 at p.284.
64
See P. Davies, “Institutional Investors in the United Kingdom” in D. Prentice and P.
Holland (eds), Contemporary Issues in Corporate Governance (Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 1993).
65 Companies Act 2006 s.154.
66
See below, Ch.14.
67
See para.14–69.
68 See below, Ch.16.
69 Bankruptcy Act 1914 s.38(1)(c).
70
This reform was a result of the Cork Committee (1982) Cmnd. 8558, Ch.23. Its repeal
had been recommended in the Report of the Blagden Committee 25 years earlier: (1957)
Cmnd.221.
71 This was always accepted in relation to mortgages in the light of s.17 of the 1882 Act.
It was later held, after an exhaustive review of the conflicting authorities, that both Acts
apply only to individuals: Slavenburg’s Bank v International Natural Resources Ltd
[1980] 1 W.L.R. 1076.
72For some reason registration of a bill of sale against a tradesman destroys his credit,
whereas registration of a debenture against a company does not. This can only be
explained on the basis that the former is exceptional, whereas the latter is usual and
familiarity has bred contempt.
731882 Act s.9. Nor could it cover future goods: see ss.5 and 6(2), ibid allows a limited
power of replacement but not anything as fluid as a floating charge.
74
Farmers can already do so under the Agricultural Credits Act 1928 which permits
individuals to grant to banks floating charges over farming stock and agricultural assets
and excludes the application of the former reputed ownership provision and the Bills of
Sale Acts: see ss.5 and 8(1), (2) and (4). Farming stock and agricultural assets are more
readily distinguishable from a farmer’s other assets (than, say, the stock of an antique
dealer who lives over his shop) thus meeting the difficulty referred to in the text.
75 The implications of floating charges are discussed more fully below, in Ch.32.
76
Salomon v Salomon [1897] A.C. 22 HL.
77
The ability of the fixed and floating chargeholder to “scoop the pool” of the
company’s assets has now been restricted, after long debate, by the Enterprise Act 2002,
which requires “a prescribed part” of the company’s assets to be kept available for the
unsecured creditors. See below, Ch.32.
78
As noted, in the case of professional businesses the rules of the governing
professional body may require the partnership form, though in fact many professional
bodies have become more flexible on this issue in recent years.
79
See Ch.20.
80
Partnership Act 1890 s.1(1). Typically there is an agreement, but this can be written
on a half-sheet of notepaper or be an informal oral agreement.
81
See para.4–20.
82 See para.11–8.
83 See Chs 9 and 10.
84
See paras 3–20 et seq.
85
See para.32–26.
86 See Chs 21 and 22.
87 See Ch.15.
88
Public filing is seen to be a quid pro quo of limited liability. Thus, unlimited
companies are not required to file their accounts publicly (s.441) whereas the limited
liability partnership (above, para.1–4) is subject to the publicity regime applied to
companies: Limited Liability Partnerships Regulations 2001 (SI 2001/1090) Pt II.
89
See Chs 21 and 22.
90Companies Act 2006 Pt 10 Ch.1 (directors) and Pt 8 Ch.2 (members); and below, Chs
14 and 24 respectively.
91
The mechanics for achieving this objective are rather intricate. SBEEA 2015 inserts a
substantial new Pt 21A (ss.790A–790ZG) and SCh.1A into the Companies Act 2006,
and that is supplemented by Regulations and formal statutory Guidance. The new rules
will apply to all UK companies, except those subject to the disclosure requirements of
DTR 5 (e.g. LSE main market and AIM companies) (s.790C(7)), and legal entities with
voting shares admitted to trading on a regulated market in an EEA state other than the
UK, or in Japan, the USA, Switzerland and Israel (s.790C(7) and (draft) Regulations).
This is because these companies are already required to make details of major
shareholdings public. The provisions will also apply to LLPs and UK registered Societas
Europaea (on the latter, see also art.9 of Regulation 2157/2001 EC of 8 October 2001).
Generally, see
https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/486520/BIS-
15-622-register-of-people-with-significant-control-consultation-response.pdf [Accessed
29 January 2016]. The EU has also introduced similar measures in the Fourth Money
Laundering Directive (EU 2015/849) which came into force on 25 June 2015 and must
be implemented by all Members States by 26 June 2017.
92 The Register of People with Significant Control Regulations 2016 (SI 2016/339):
http://www.legislation.gov.uk/uksi/2016/339/pdfs/uksi_20160339_en.pdf [Accessed 29
May 2016].
93
For the current (April 2016) Statutory Guidance, see
https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/523120/PSC_statutory_guidance_com
[Accessed 29 May 2016].
94
For money laundering, tax evasion, corruption, terrorist financing, etc.
95
BIS, The Register of People with Significant Control (PSC Register) (October 2014),
as stated in the Foreword:
https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/395478/bis-
14-1145-the-register-of-people-with-significant-control-psc-register-register-final-1.pdf
[Accessed 29 January 2016].
96
See the sources cited in earlier footnotes.
97
But with this expressly being wider than the definition of a “shadow director” of the
company. As to the latter, see para.16–9.
98
See para.16–9.
99
See Guidance, Section 1.
100 See Guidance, paras 4.2–4.6.
101 The details are in the Regulations: see fn.91, above.
102
The information on the PSC Register will also need to be confirmed to Companies
House at least every 12 months and will be held by it on a publically searchable
database.
103 See para.19–11.
104
By comparison, other disclosure rules are considered in detail in Ch.26.
105
See above, para.1–4.
106 See above, para.2–1.
107 Developing, paras 9.61–9.71.
CHAPTER 3
SOURCES OF COMPANY LAW AND THE COMPANY’S
CONSTITUTION
Sources 3–1
Primary legislation 3–3
Secondary legislation 3–5
Delegated rule-making 3–7
Common law 3–10
Review and reform 3–11
The Company’s Constitution 3–13
The significance of the constitution 3–13
Model articles of association 3–14
What constitutes the constitution? 3–16
The legal status of the constitution 3–18
Shareholder Agreements 3–33
The European Company 3–36
SOURCES
3–1
As far as domestic companies are concerned, the immediate
sources of the rules applicable to them, and the hierarchy of
those sources, are the ones familiar to students of other bodies of
law. They are: primary legislation, secondary legislation, rule-
making by legislatively recognised bodies, the common law of
companies, and the company’s own constitution (in particular,
its articles of association). Of these, the last may perhaps appear
unfamiliar, but students of contract law are used to idea that the
rules applicable in any particular situation are as likely to be
found in the terms of the parties’ agreement as in legislative or
common law rules, and students of trade union law or of the law
of other types of association know that the particular
association’s rule-book is an important source of law, at least for
its members. As to the third category, legislation may delegate to
bodies outside the legislature the power to make rules relevant to
companies. These bodies may themselves be agencies created by
statute or they may be pre-existing bodies which the legislature
recognises for the purposes of rule-making.
Finally, and standing outside the above hierarchy but with
links to it, there may be examples of “self-regulation” where the
relevant rules have no legislative or common law foundation, but
are nevertheless observed in practice, as a result of non-legal
pressures, including the threat that government might intervene
with legislation if the self-regulatory rules were not obeyed.
Historically, the leading example of this phenomenon in our area
was the City Panel on Takeovers and Mergers, and the Code it
administers, but these were put on a statutory basis by the
Companies Act 2006, implementing the Community Directive
on takeovers, though its non-statutory methods of working have
survived to a considerable extent.1 Thus, self-regulation is a less
obvious feature of company law than it used to be.
3–2
Whatever the source of the rule, one should also note that its
content may be located on a spectrum running from “hard” to
“soft”. At the “hard” end, the obligation may be imposed by the
rule without giving those to whom it applies any choice as to
whether they comply with it (a “mandatory” rule). Moving along
the spectrum, the rule may permit those to whom it prima facie
applies to modify or remove the obligation. Such rules,
conventionally called “default rules”, are in fact quite common
in company law. What is the function of such a rule, given that
the parties themselves are apparently free to deprive it of
regulatory force? Where the obligees can easily remove the
obligation, the rule may nevertheless have the important function
of relieving parties of the task of working out the best rule for
themselves. In formulating the default rule, the legislature will
have tried to identify the rule which most parties in the relevant
situation would devise for themselves. Only if the particular
parties want something different from that normally adopted will
they have to go through the process of altering the rule. Thus, a
number of provisions in the Act on shareholder meetings apply
only “subject to any provision in the company’s articles”.2 Since
it is relatively easy for companies to make different provisions in
their articles upon formation of the company or later, these
provisions may be regarded as a pure type of default rule.
In other cases the procedure for amending the position
produced by the default rule may be more demanding and the
regulatory objectives of such a rule may also be more
sophisticated. For example, many rules relating to the duties of
directors may be disapplied by the shareholders, by majority
vote, either before or after the breach of duty.3 The purpose of
such a rule may be to induce the directors to bargain with the
shareholders over the handling of conduct which would
otherwise be in breach of duty. This rule contains a more
demanding procedure because those upon whom the obligation
is imposed (the directors) need to obtain the consent of another
group of people within the company (the shareholders) for the
modification of the rule, and are thus forced to disclose to the
shareholders their actual or potential wrongdoing. Such a rule
may be useful where the rule-maker cannot predict what the
result should be in a particular class of case (otherwise it could
use a mandatory rule) nor does it think it wise to leave it to the
directors themselves to modify the rule (because of their conflict
of interest).
Finally, the procedure for amending the rule may be so
demanding that in practice little use is made of it. In such a case,
it is doubtful whether the rule should be regarded as in substance
a default rule. This may be true of the example given in the
previous paragraph. Thus, if the only way in which directors can
secure shareholder modification of the default rule is to call a
meeting of the shareholders to discuss each case of breach of
duty as it arises, then in a large company they may regard such a
procedure as so cumbersome and unpredictable that they treat
the default rule as in fact mandatory.4 Whether they then choose
to comply with it or to break the rule and hide the breach is a
different question.
At the “soft” end of the spectrum are “rules” which are in fact
only recommendations or exhortations. No sanction is attached
to the breach of the rule. Each obligee decides for itself whether
and how far to comply with the recommendation. A possible
way of injecting some bite into recommendations is to put them
on a “comply or explain basis”. In this situation, the only formal
obligation imposed by the rule is to explain publicly how far the
recommendations have been complied with and the reasons for
any areas of non-compliance. Such disclosure meets all the
formal obligations of the rule, even if it shows that the
recommendations have not been complied with at all, but
publicity may generate extra-legal pressures on the company to
comply (or to comply more fully) with the recommendations.
The primary example of such a mechanism in British company
law is the UK Corporate Governance Code,5 in relation to which
a “comply or explain” obligation is imposed.
Primary legislation
3–3
The principal legislative source of rules is the Companies Act
2006, the latest in a line of Acts produced as the original
legislation of the mid-nineteenth century has been reformed
periodically. This latest effort involved the most comprehensive
review of the area since company law’s inception, and the
resulting legislation is said to be the longest ever to be passed by
Parliament.
The process began in 1998 with the then Secretary of State
commissioning an independent review of company law.6 This
Company Law Review (“CLR”) was carried out with the support
of DTI civil servants, a Project Director, a permanent Steering
Group7 and Consultative Committee, and a series of ad hoc
Working Groups.8 The Steering Group produced a number of
consultative documents, some very large, and a two-volume final
report. In its Final Report it declared its aims to have been to
produce a company law that was “primarily enabling or
facilitative” and to “strip out regulation that is no longer
necessary”. This would not mean an absence of statutory law, for
the framework of company law “should provide the necessary
safeguards to allow people to deal with and invest in companies
with confidence”.9
The immediate response of the Government was enthusiastic,
but developments were rather slow.10 A Bill was finally
introduced into Parliament in November 2005, received Royal
Assent a year later, and was then phased in over a period of time,
ending on 1 October 2009. The result is an Act of some 1,300
sections and 16 Schedules. This may seem an odd result for a
legislative process aimed to be facilitative. Two points can be
made in mitigation of its length. First, enabling legislation is not
to be confused with the absence of statutory law: often confining
law narrowly takes more statutory words than a sweeping
prohibition. Secondly, the Act is drafted in a lengthy way,
paradoxically to make it more user-friendly. Few people read an
Act from beginning to end. What they need to be able to do is to
find quickly the provisions relevant to their problem. Setting out
the provisions in a disaggregated form (for example, separate
provisions for public and private companies on a particular topic,
even if the provisions are similar) is helpful in that regard.
3–4
Other legislation is also important. Provisions relating to the
insolvency of companies were hived off into an Insolvency Act
of 1986, which also contains provisions dealing with the period
before the company enters insolvency and intended to protect
creditors in that period.11 In the same year, a Financial Services
Act (now replaced by the Financial Services and Markets Act
2000) took over the provisions relating to the public offering and
listing of shares, and the 2000 Act has been modified
subsequently to take account of the burgeoning EU law in this
area.12 These two examples illustrate perennial problems of
classification. Should rules on the insolvency of companies go in
a company law consolidation or an insolvency law
consolidation; equally, should rules on share issues by
companies go in a company law consolidation or a capital
markets or securities law consolidation? There are arguments
both ways, but it is the case that, functionally, important parts of
the law relating to companies are not to be found in Acts which
contain the word “company” in their title.13
Secondary legislation
3–5
One major difficulty attending legislation as long as the
Companies Act is that a major commitment of parliamentary
time by the- Government is required to get such legislation onto
the statute books. Once there, ministers are likely to take the
view that company law has had its turn for some while and will
be reluctant to devote additional parliamentary time to proposals
for its further reform. This can be a distinct disadvantage for
those parts of the Act which relate to matters where the technical
or economic context is changing rapidly and fairly frequent
updating of the legislation would be desirable. One solution to
this problem is greater use of subordinate legislation, amending
primary legislation but for which the process of parliamentary
scrutiny is much reduced and which therefore is much less time-
consuming.14 The 2006 Act contains important examples of this
technique in particular areas, for example, companies’ accounts15
or share capital,16 both areas likely to be affected by changes
occurring outside the UK (whether at EU or broader
international levels) to which it was desirable for the
Government to be able to respond quickly. The CLR proposed a
general power to use secondary legislation to amend the Act, but
this was dropped after opposition from Parliament.17
It is also the case that the EU obligations of the UK in relation
to company law may be implemented by secondary legislation
under general powers conferred by the European Communities
Act 1972, which powers are not confined to the company law
area. However, it is not absolutely clear how far this power
extends beyond the minimum necessary to transpose, for
example, a Directive into domestic law.
3–6
Although quicker to implement than primary legislation,
secondary legislation suffers from two defects. The first is that
the rules are subject to less democratic scrutiny than an Act of
Parliament. For this reason, the Company Law Review, whilst
proposing greater use of secondary legislation, also
recommended that “the basic principles and architecture of the
new framework would be set out in primary legislation”.18 The
second is that secondary legislation may not be as expert as rules
produced by rule-makers closer to the regulated, despite the
conscientious consultation process in which the relevant
Department engages before making secondary rules. This second
defect can be overcome by delegation of law-making powers to a
more expert body than the Department.
Delegated rule-making
The Financial Conduct Authority
3–7
A primary example of delegation beyond central government in
the current law is the rule-making power conferred upon the
Financial Conduct Authority (“FCA”). The FCA makes three
types of rules which are of particular interest to us. First, it took
over from the Stock Exchange the long-standing and originally
self-regulatory task of laying down Listing Rules (“LR”) for
companies whose securities have been entered onto the “official
list”.19 In exercising this function, it is referred to as the UK
Listing Authority (“UKLA”). Some of the EU obligations of the
UK are implemented through the LR, but, as we have noted in
Ch.1, they have also been used to promote purely domestic
policies and thus to introduce for listed companies an additional
set of core rules that are not applied to non-listed companies. It
has also introduced further sets of rules—Prospectus Rules
(“PR”) and Disclosure and Transparency Rules (“DTR”). These
are heavily driven by the need to transpose EU law in the UK,
however, the transposition has had the further impact of shifting
some topics from the companies legislation to the FCA’s rules.20
Here it is interesting that Parliament has proceeded with
transposition not primarily by way of direct amendment of the
FSMA, but by giving the FCA extended rule-making powers.
Finally, it was required in the FSMA to produce a Code of
Market Conduct (“MAR”) to flesh out the meaning of the
statutory prohibition on market abuse, which we consider in
Ch.30.
3–8
In short, the FCA has power to issue elaborate sets of rules,
without the need for formal approval by either Parliament or a
Governmental Department.21 The public interest is protected,
however, by the statutory requirement to publish a statement of
policy on the imposition of sanctions for breaches of the Rules.22
Thus, although the FCA is a private company formed under the
Companies Act, in fact a company limited by guarantee,23 and is
financed by a levy on those who engage in financial services
business, it has extensive public functions and is itself subject to
controls thought to be appropriate to a public body.
Financial Reporting Council
3–9
The second area where delegated rule-making is to be found on a
substantial scale in the present law is in relation to corporate
governance, accounting standards, the accuracy of accounts,
auditing standards and the regulation of auditors and
accountants. This is an area where the Financial Reporting
Council (“FRC”) and its various subsidiaries are immensely
important. Their functions were much enhanced as a result of
reforms implemented in the UK in the wake of the Enron and
related scandals in the US,24 and the impact of their rule-making
has grown further as a result of the 2008 financial crisis. These
functions are analysed in Chs 21 and 22, and that analysis need
not be anticipated here. What needs to be noted, however, is that,
like the FCA, the FRC acquires its powers by way of delegation
from the Secretary of State (who can therefore re-allocate
them).25 Like the FCA, the FRC and its subsidiaries are
companies limited by guarantee, but its directors are appointed
by the Secretary of State, so that the FRC, although more expert
than a Government Department (and partly financed by those it
regulates), is tied into the governmental machinery.
Common law
3–10
In spite of the bulk of the Companies Act and its satellite
legislation, it does not contain a code of company law. The
British Companies Acts have never aspired to lay down all the
rules which sustain the core features of company law, as
identified in the previous chapter. However, the 2006 Act goes
further in that regard than previous Acts. The Law Commissions
recommended that there should be a statutory statement of the
common law duties of directors (though not of the remedies for
breach)26 and the English Law Commission that the law relating
to the enforcement of those duties should be both reformed and
stated in legislative form.27 Both these sets of recommendations
were broadly endorsed by the Company Law Review, and were
included in the 2006 Act, thus effecting a major extension of
statutory company law.28
Although these reforms significantly altered the balance
between statute law and common law in company law, they may
have a much less pronounced effect upon the role of the judges
in developing company law. So far as directors’ duties are
concerned, although the statutory statement largely replaces the
existing common law and equitable rules, it is drafted as a
relatively “high level” statement. Consequently, the pre-existing
case law will remain relevant where the statement simply
repeats, rather than reforms, the common law; and recourse
throughout the statement to broad standards, rather than precise
rules, means the judges will have an important role in
developing and applying the standards, just as they have had in
respect of those standards which were embodied in statute from
the beginning.29 Indeed, in performing this task, s.170(4) of the
2006 Act specifically, and uniquely for a UK statute, requires
that “[t]he general duties shall be interpreted and applied in the
same way as common law rules or equitable principles, and
regard shall be had to the corresponding common law rules and
equitable principles in interpreting and applying the general
duties”. As to the enforcement of these statutory directors’
duties, the reform creates a greater judicial discretion to allow or
refuse derivative actions, so that the judges are, if anything,
more important under the Act than the prior common law.
Review and reform
3–11
It is clear that company law consists of a complex and diverse
body of rules. Keeping this law under review is now, in the
main, the task of the Department of Business, Innovation and
Skills (“BIS”),30 which is the Government Department currently
responsible for company and insolvency law, among many other
matters. As for financial services law, including public offerings
of securities and their listing, the Treasury is the leading source
of policy. As noted above, in recent years the Law Commissions
(English and Scottish) have also played an important part in
company law reform.
The Company Law Review, carried out by the DTI and
referred to above, may be seen as the latest in a series of reviews
of company law carried out by the various predecessors of BIS
since the introduction of incorporation by registration in the
middle of the nineteenth century. Its method of operation was
rather different from that of its predecessors, however. They had
consisted of small committees of enquiry which took formal
evidence but did not engage in widespread consultation; they
also tended to concentrate on particular aspects of the subject
thought to need reform, rather than upon a comprehensive
review. The two most recent Committee reports of this older
type which are still important for an understanding of the current
law are the Jenkins31 and Cohen32 Committee reports (so referred
to after the names of their chairmen).
3–12
In the long term, however, the CLR was unconvinced that ad
hoc, periodic, comprehensive reviews of the type it had
undertaken were the best way forward, because they depend so
heavily upon governmental commitment to devote the necessary
resources to the exercise. It recommended instead that a standing
Company Law and Reporting Commission should have the remit
of keeping company law under review and reporting annually to
the Secretary of State its views on where, if anywhere, reform
was needed. In addition, the Secretary of State would be obliged
to consult the Commission on proposed secondary legislation.33
In this way, it was hoped, company law reform would become a
continuing and expert process, so that less weight would need to
be placed on ad hoc, across-the-board reviews. This proposal
was, however, rejected by the Government,34 so the ad hoc
approach remains the order of the day.
THE COMPANY’S CONSTITUTION
The significance of the constitution
3–13
A remarkable feature of British company law is the extent to
which it leaves regulation of the internal affairs of a company to
the company itself through rules laid down in its constitution, in
particular in its articles of association (which prescribe the
regulations for the company35). In fact, the principle is that the
articles may deal with any matter which is not, or to the extent
that it is not, regulated through any of the sources mentioned
above. This is not stated explicitly in the Act, but is rather an
assumption upon which the Act is drafted, too obvious to be
worth stating. However, the crucial point is not just the formal
relationship between the articles and the other sources of
company law, especially the Act, but the extent to which
substantive matters, central to the company’s operation, are left
to be regulated by the articles. Examples of important matters
which are regulated mainly by the articles are the division of
powers between the shareholders and the board of directors, and
the composition, structure and operation of the board of
directors.36 Many jurisdictions regulate these matters through
their companies legislation, rather than the company’s
constitution, and this is true of systems as otherwise different as
those of Germany and the US.37
In the American case, it is true, the legislation often uses
default rules, which can be changed by appropriate provisions in
the company’s constitution, so that, where this is the case, the
shareholders can ultimately adopt the set of rules they want, as is
the case in Britain. For example, para.8.01 of the Model
Business Corporation Act gives a broad management power to
the board of a US company, but allows the shareholders, in the
constitution or by shareholder agreement, to cut down that
provision if they wish and allocate decisions to themselves;
whereas the directors of a British company have management
powers only to the extent that they are given to the board by the
articles (as, normally, they are, and the default model articles for
all companies are in this form38). The ultimate practical division
of powers between board and shareholders, in similar types of
company, may thus be equivalent in the two countries despite
their different starting points.
The German and, even, the American approach can be said to
be based on the principle that the allocation of powers to the
organs of the company is the result of a legislative act, even if,
within limits, the shareholders may alter the initial legislative
allocation. By contrast, since the shareholders control the
constitution (see below), the British approach can be said to
represent the view that the shareholders constitute the ultimate
source of managerial authority within the company and that the
directors obtain their powers by a process of delegation from the
shareholders, albeit a delegation of a formal type which, so long
as it lasts, may make the directors the central decision-making
body on behalf of the company.39 In each of these jurisdictions,
however, the practical allocation of power ultimately depends on
the ease with which the default rules may be overridden.40 If the
shareholders agree to override the default rules at the time the
company is formed, the barriers are often relatively low. On the
other hand, if they only decide later that the legislative default
rules (in the US) or the model articles (in the UK) should be
amended, then the process is inevitably more complicated: issues
of who is entitled to propose the necessary resolutions and call
the necessary meetings (the directors or a shareholder), and what
level of voting support is necessary to adopt the change (a
simple majority or some sort of super majority) will, in practice,
determine the ease with which changes can be effected.
Model articles of association
3–14
In the British scheme it is essential that a company have articles,
and this is reflected in the provisions in the Act authorising the
Secretary of State to promulgate model articles of association for
companies of different types41 and giving those statutory models
default status.42 This power is long standing, and from time to
time lettered “tables” of model articles were issued under it, with
those for companies limited by shares being invariably “Table
A”. Many companies still exist whose articles are based on the
Table A of 1985 or the earlier one of 1948 or, conceivably, even
earlier versions. The current statutory models are contained in
the Companies (Model Articles) Regulations 2008/3229, and are
applicable to companies incorporated on or after 1 October 2009.
These new models are no longer denoted by lettered tables, and
in addition, following the CLR,43 there are now separate model
articles for private and public companies limited by shares
(previously Table A articles applied to both), and also for
companies limited by guarantee.44 Given the range of companies
falling under the companies legislation, it is surprising that a
single model set of articles for companies limited by shares was
thought for so long to be adequate.45
3–15
When a limited company is formed, it will be treated as having
adopted the relevant model articles, except to the extent that it
chooses to have different articles, either in whole or in part.46
This means that those registering the company could say
nothing, in which case the model will apply in full.47 At the other
extreme, they could expressly exclude the model entirely and
adopt a set of articles which contains very different provisions.
Typically, however, companies adopt an intermediate position,
registering articles which adopt the default model subject to a list
of specific amendments. Section 20(1)(b) suggests that choice
may be expressed implicitly, by adopting articles which in one
or more respects are inconsistent with the model, and then the
model will apply to govern matters not dealt with by the
company, i.e. the model performs a gap-filling role in such a
case. This does mean that the full articles of the company can be
established only through the laborious process of taking the
model articles and applying the specified changes to it, which
hardly amounts to a transparent exposition of the company’s
regulations. Any different approach—despite the requirement
that the articles “must be contained in a single document”48—
would, however, lose the crucial gap-filling role of the model
articles mandated by s.20(1)(b).
The version of the model which is implied into the company’s
articles (unless excluded) is that which existed when the
company was formed. The subsequent promulgation of a revised
version of the model will not affect companies already
registered, but only those registered in the future.49 Hence the
fact, noted above, that there are many companies in existence for
whom the relevant model is Table A of 1948. For the
practitioner, therefore, the replacement of one model by another
is not a reason to forget the learning about former models.
Under the British structure the company cannot work
effectively without fairly elaborate articles, and the models aim
to supply that need for those who do not wish, or cannot afford,
to work out their own internal regulations.
What constitutes the constitution?
3–16
Unlike its predecessors, the 2006 Act defines the company’s
constitution. The term includes the articles of association but is
not limited to them. Also included are “any resolutions or
agreements to which Chapter 3 [of Pt 3] applies”.50 Chapter 3
applies to special resolutions of the shareholders (whether passed
as such or by virtue of unanimous agreement among the
members)51; any resolution or agreement of a class of members
binding all the members of the class (for example, a resolution
varying class rights)52; any unanimous resolution or agreement
adopted by the members of a class provided that it would not
otherwise be binding on them unless passed by a particular
majority or in a particular manner; and any other resolution or
agreement to which the chapter applies by virtue of any
enactment.53 In practice, the most important category is special
resolutions of the shareholders. Given its much reduced legal
status, it is not surprising that the memorandum of association no
longer features as part of the company’s constitution.54
3–17
As might be expected, shareholder agreements, considered
below, are not generally regarded as part of the company’s
constitution; but that rule has one important exception, noted in
passing here.55
The legal status of the constitution
3–18
The common law tends to classify the rule-books of associations,
whether they are clubs, trade unions, friendly societies or other,
as contractual in nature. The articles of association are no
exception to this principle, though in this case the classification
is done by the Act. Section 33 of the Act provides that “the
provisions of the company’s constitution bind the company and
its members to the same extent as if there were covenants on the
part of the company and of each member to observe it”. The
wording of this important section can be traced back, with
variations, to the original Act of 1844.56 What is clear, however,
is that the articles constitute a rather particular form of contract,
and the peculiarities of that contract need to be noted here.
(i) The parties to the contract
3–19
It is clear from the express statutory wording of s.33 that the
articles constitute a contract between the company and each
member. It is thus a multi-party contract, like many other
contracts found in the commercial world, and is enforceable by
any one party against any other. This feature is commonly used
when there is breach or threatened breach of articles which
confer on members a right of pre-emption (or first refusal) when
another member wishes to sell his shares,57 or impose a duty on
the remaining members or the directors to buy the shares of a
retiring member (a less common provision).58 What makes this
contract different, as we shall see, is that not all of its provisions
will be enforced in the courts.59
(ii) The contract as a public document
3–20
Although the articles of association have a contractual status,
they are clearly more than a private bargain among the company
and its members. The company’s articles become a public
document at the moment of formation, either because the
relevant model articles, themselves a public document, will
apply or because the company supplies to the registrar for public
registration its own articles which amend or even fully replace
the statutory model.60 Publicity of the company’s constitution
has always been a requirement of British company law, and
since 1968 is in any event a requirement of EU company law.61
Thus, those who deal with the company have a legitimate
expectation that the registered articles represent an accurate
statement of the company’s internal regulations.
3–21
Because of this special feature, the courts have concluded that
standard contract law should apply to the articles only with
certain qualifications. In particular, the courts are reluctant to
apply to the statutory contract any contract law doctrines which
might result in the articles being held to have a content
substantially different from that which someone reading the
registered documents would have understood them to have.
Thus, the Court of Appeal has held that articles cannot later be
rectified to give effect to what the incorporators actually
intended but failed to embody in the registered document, since
the reader of the registered documents could have no way of
guessing that any error had been made in transposing the
incorporators’ agreement into the document.62
Equally, that Court has refused to imply terms into the
statutory contract from extrinsic evidence of surrounding
circumstances where that evidence would probably not be
known to third parties who would thus have no basis for
anticipating that any such implication was appropriate.63
Further, in this case Steyn LJ was of the view that for the
same reasons the statutory contract “was not defeasible on the
grounds of misrepresentation, common law mistake, mistake in
equity, undue influence or duress”.64
These decisions by the courts on the meaning of the
company’s constitutional documents support the policy
underlying the statutory provision on the conclusiveness of the
certificate of incorporation.65 Both conduce to protection of third
parties by enabling the third party to rely on what he or she finds
upon a search of the public registry.66
3–22
However, the policy behind these cases is somewhat undermined
by those decisions which have allowed the doctrine of informal,
unanimous shareholder consent to be applied to changes to the
company’s constitution. Under this doctrine, which is discussed
further in Ch.15, decisions taken informally by shareholders will
nevertheless be effective, if taken unanimously. Although the
Act requires informal resolutions altering the articles to be
communicated to the Registrar,67 the informality alone means
this is unlikely to happen, and then the registered constitution
will no longer reflect the actual set of articles.68 Failure to inform
the registrar is a criminal offence and may attract civil penalties,
but the validity of the alteration appears not to be affected by
non-compliance.69
(iii) Limits to the provisions which can be enforced:
only rights “as a member”
3–23
The standard answer to the question, at common law, of who can
enforce a contract is: the parties to the contract.70 Since it is
members who are party to the contract with the company, it
follows that non-members cannot enforce the contract, even if
they are intimately involved with the company, for example, as
directors. Suppose, however, a person is both a member of the
company and one of its directors. Can he or she enforce rights
conferred by the articles, even if that right is conferred upon the
claimant in his or her capacity as director of the company? The
answer appears to be in the negative. The decisions have
constantly affirmed that the section confers contractual effect on
a provision in the articles only in so far as it affords rights on a
member “qua member”, or as a member.71 As Astbury J said in
the Hickman case72:
“An outsider to whom rights purport to be given by the articles in his capacity as
such outsider, whether he is or subsequently becomes a member, cannot sue on
those articles, treating them as contracts between himself and the company, to
enforce those rights.”
The same applies to the contract between the members inter se.73
On the wording of the section it would be difficult to interpret
it as creating a contract with anyone other than the company and
the members. Furthermore, there is perhaps sense in restricting
the ambit of the section to matters concerning the affairs of the
company, although the Act itself is not explicitly worded
restrictively. The question is whether it is justified to restrict the
statutory wording still further, so that it applies only to matters
concerning a member in his capacity of member.74 As a
consequence of this interpretation, a promoter, who becomes a
member, cannot enforce a provision that the company shall
reimburse the expenses he or she incurred75 nor a solicitor, who
becomes a member, a provision that he or she shall be the
company’s solicitor.76 More important, this approach to the
section apparently prevents a member who is also a director or
other officer of the company from enforcing any rights
purporting to be conferred by the articles on directors or officers.
Only if he or she has a separate contract, extraneous to the
articles, will the director have contractual rights and obligations
vis-à-vis the company or fellow members. For this reason,
executive directors will be careful to enter into service contracts
with their company (into which it is entirely permissible to
incorporate provisions from the articles of association)77 in order
to safeguard their remuneration, and non-executive directors
would be well advised to do so also.78
3–24
It is somewhat anomalous to treat directors as “outsiders” since
for most purposes the law treats them as the paradigm “insiders”
(which members, as such, are not) and they will breach their
fiduciary duties and duties of care if they do not act in
accordance with the company’s constitution.79 It also produces
some strange results. Hickman’s case concerned a provision in
the articles stating that any dispute between the company and a
member should be referred to arbitration and this was enforced
as a contract. But in the later case of Beattie v Beattie Ltd,80
where there was a similar provision, the Court of Appeal, relying
on the dictum in Hickman, held that a dispute between a
company and a director (who was a member) was not subject to
the provision because the dispute was admittedly in relation to
the director qua director. In the still later case of Rayfield v
Hands,81 the articles of a private company provided that a
member intending to transfer his shares should give notice to the
directors “who will take the said shares equally between them at
a fair value”. A member gave notice but the directors refused to
buy. Vaisey J felt able to hold that the provision was concerned
with the relationship between the member and the directors as
members and ordered them to buy.82
3–25
However, academic argument has been made to the effect that
the Hickman principle can be side-stepped, in most or all cases,
by the identification of an appropriate membership right. In
1957, Lord Wedderburn, in his seminal article on Foss v
Harbottle,83 pointed out that, in Quinn & Axtens Ltd v Salmon,84
the Court of Appeal and the House of Lords allowed a managing
director, suing as a member, to obtain an injunction restraining
the company from completing transactions entered into in breach
of the company’s articles which provided that the consent of the
two managing directors was required in relation to such
transactions. This, in effect, showed that a member had a
membership right to require the company to act in accordance
with its articles, which right could be enforced by the member
even though the result was indirectly to protect a right which
was afforded to him as director. If this is correct, the supposed
principle, that there is a statutory contract between the company
and its members only in respect of matters affecting members
qua members, is effectively outflanked—and, if so, whether it
can then still apply to the statutory contact between members
inter se seems debatable.85
3–26
Despite the criticisms which can be levelled against the Hickman
principle, when the Company Law Review consulted on the
question of whether this aspect of the Act required reform,86 a
positive response was not forthcoming and the recommendation
from the CLR was accordingly to leave the law as it is.87 Perhaps
this indicates that, although the Hickman principle may not be
wholly desirable, the costs of contracting around it are not high.
Consequently, practice has accommodated itself to the rule. On
the other hand, when the common law of privity of contract was
reformed, it is perhaps easier to understand why there was no
pressure to change the current rule to one which would permit
non-members to enforce rights in their favour contained in the
articles.88
(iv) Further limits to the provisions which can be
enforced: not mere procedural irregularities
3–27
Although the Company Law Review was content to let the
“member qua member” aspect of the statutory contract remain
undisturbed, the same cannot be said of a related aspect of the
contract with which we must deal. Even though a member sues
as a member and even though he or she sues to enforce a
provision in the articles which appears to confer a right on the
member, he or she may nevertheless be defeated by the
argument that the provision does not confer a personal right on
the member but creates only an obligation on the company,
breach of which constitutes “a mere internal irregularity” on the
company’s part. The consequence of the categorisation of the
breach of the articles as an internal irregularity is that the
decision whether to sue to enforce the provision is a matter for
the shareholders collectively, whereas personal rights, not
surprisingly, can be enforced by individual shareholders.
The issue has tended to arise particularly in relation to those
provisions dealing with the convening and conduct of meetings
of shareholders or the selection of members of the board. These
are areas where there are statutory provisions, but they are of a
limited nature and much is left to be regulated in the company’s
articles.89 If, for example, the chairman of a shareholders’
meeting acts in breach of the provisions of the articles governing
meetings, is that an infringement of the shareholders’ personal
rights or a mere internal irregularity? There are a number of
decisions of the courts over the past 150 years putting such
breaches in one category or the other, but it is difficult to discern
the principled basis on which the classification was carried out.
The importance, if not the nature, of the distinction is shown by
two ultimately irreconcilable cases from the 1870s, MacDougall
v Gardiner90 and Pender v Lushington.91 In the former the
decision of the chairman of the shareholders’ meeting
wrongfully (i.e. in breach of the articles) to refuse a request for a
poll was held to be an internal irregularity, whilst in the latter the
refusal of a chairman to recognise the votes attached to shares
held by nominee shareholders was held to infringe their personal
rights. Each decision has spawned a line of equally
irreconcilable authorities. In truth, there is a conflict here
between proper recognition of the contractual nature of the
company’s constitution and the traditional policy of non-
interference by the courts in the internal affairs of companies.
3–28
As Smith has suggested,92 ultimately the only satisfactory
solution is to choose which policy is to have priority. Moreover,
it is surely clear today that it ought to be the former. It can
hardly be argued in modern law that it is an example of
excessive interference by the courts to hold a company (or any
other association) to the procedures which it itself has adopted in
its constitution for its internal decision-making (until such time
as it decides to change those internal rules according to the
procedures set down for that to occur).93 Indeed, it might even be
suggested that effective protection of this procedural entitlement
of members is basic to any satisfactory system of company
law.94
3–29
Part of the confusion may have arisen because of a failure to
appreciate that the same situation may give rise to wrongs both
by and against the company, and the individual shareholder’s
position will vary according to which wrong he seeks to redress.
Thus, the chairman of a shareholders’ meeting who breaches the
relevant provisions of the articles may both put the company in
breach of its contract with the members and him- or herself be in
breach of duty to the company for not observing the provisions.
An analogy is provided by the decision in Taylor v NUM
(Derbyshire Area).95 The plaintiff successfully sued his trade
union96 in a personal capacity to obtain an injunction restraining
the officials of the union from continuing a strike which it was a
breach of the union’s rule-book (in fact, beyond its capacity) to
conduct, but failed in his claim for an order requiring the same
officials to restore to the union the funds already expended on
the strike, because he did not have standing to bring a derivative
action on behalf of the union.97 The same analysis may often be
applicable to breaches of the articles.98 In other words, the
company may be regarded as breaching its contract with the
member if it seeks to act upon a resolution improperly passed
and should be restrainable by the member, but for the loss (say
the wasted costs of organising the meeting) caused to the
company by the chair of the meeting in not conducting it in
accordance with the company’s regulations, the company is the
proper plaintiff.99
3–30
An alternative line of attack on the above decisions might be
provided by the general membership right, postulated by
Professor Wedderburn and noted above, to have the affairs of the
company conducted in accordance with the articles, for that right
was also put forward by him as a personal right. Consequently,
this general right, if recognised by the courts or the legislature,
would defeat both the “outsider right” argument and the “mere
internal irregularity” argument against shareholder enforcement
of the articles of association. After some hesitation, the
Company Law Review decided to take a bold approach which
amounted, in effect, to the acceptance of Professor
Wedderburn’s argument, at least on the matter of the range of
provisions enforceable by the member as member. All duties
imposed in favour of members under the constitution should be
enforceable by individual shareholders.100 In principle, if the
company acted in breach of such duties, then the member would
be able to bring an action to enforce the company’s rule-book.
Or the member would be able to sue another member if the
obligation was laid by the articles on that member. This would
not mean that every breach of the articles by a corporate officer
would entitle each shareholder to sue the company for damages.
Damages would be an available remedy only if the shareholder
personally101 had suffered loss as a result of the breach. In the
case of a breach of procedure in the conduct of a meeting, a
remedy other than damages might well be more appropriate, for
example, an injunction preventing the company from acting on
an improperly passed resolution. In other cases no remedy at all
might be ordered. If the breach of procedure had been purely
technical and it was clear that the resolution would have been
passed even if the correct procedure had been followed, the court
should not grant any remedy at all and might even award costs
against the complainant shareholder. This proposal was subject
to one qualification: it would be possible for the shareholders to
opt, by an appropriate provision included therein, for some or all
of the articles not to be enforceable. In such a case, the relevant
articles would not be enforceable as a contract,102 even if they
would be under the current law. Thus, general contractual
enforcement of the articles would be the default rule, and in any
case it should be clear which articles were enforceable and
which not.
However, the 2006 Act does not take up this proposal and so
the uncertainties of the case law, discussed above, remain.
(v) Altering the contract
3–31
It is crucial that the articles, as part of the constitution of an
ongoing organisation, be capable of amendment from time to
time. Section 21 expressly provides that “a company may amend
its articles by special resolution”.103 Thus, a member enters into a
contract on terms which are alterable by the other party (the
company, acting through the shareholders collectively),104 rather
in the same way as a member of a club agrees to be bound by the
club rules as validly altered from time to time by the members as
a whole, or a worker agrees to be employed on the terms of a
collective agreement as varied from time to time by the
employer and trade union. That a majority of the members
should normally be able to alter the articles by following a
prescribed procedure and thus alter for the future the contractual
rights and obligations of individual shareholders is hardly
surprising. It reflects the fact that the company is an association
and that some process of collective decision-making is needed,
in relation to its constitution, if it is to be able to adapt to
changing circumstances in the business environment. The
alternative would be constitutional change only with the consent
of each individual shareholder, which would be very difficult to
obtain in many cases and which would give unscrupulous
individuals golden opportunities for disruptive behaviour.
3–32
On the other hand, the ability of the majority to bind the
minority through decisions which alter the articles of the
company creates the potential for opportunistic behaviour on the
part of the majority towards the minority. As we shall see in Chs
19 and 20, company law has developed some general standards
which address this problem, which arises in all situations where
the majority may bind the minority, whether the matter at issue
is an amendment to the articles or not.
Here we need note only two particular restrictions on the
majority’s power to alter the articles. One is highly precise. The
consent of the individual member is required if he or she is to be
bound by an alteration which requires members to subscribe for
further shares in the company or which increases liability to
contribute to the company’s share capital or pay money to the
company.105
The other restriction is of a procedural nature and enables the
shareholders to contract around the principle of majority rule for
alteration of the articles. The normal rule is that the company
cannot contract out of its power to alter the articles.106 However,
s.22 enables the shareholders to “entrench” provisions of the
company’s constitution, i.e. to make them capable of amendment
or repeal “only if conditions are met, or procedures complied
with, that are more restrictive than those applicable in the case of
a special resolution.”107 Those additional restrictions may not
make the articles completely unalterable108—probably a wise
provision, because even a member who insists on such a
provision may subsequently change his or her mind. However,
amendment or repeal could be made conditional on the consent
of a particular member or a higher percentage of the members
than a special resolution requires. Entrenched status can be
conferred upon provisions in the articles either upon the
formation of the company or subsequently, but in the latter case
only with the unanimous consent of the members.109 The
registrar must be given notice of the adoption of entrenchment
provisions and of their removal110; and the company must certify
compliance with the entrenchment provisions whenever it alters
its articles.111 Thus, the principle that the constitution of the
company can be altered by a three-quarters majority of the
members can in fact be set aside by using the entrenchment
provisions, though for most companies it would be unwise to do
so on a significant scale.112
SHAREHOLDER AGREEMENTS
3–33
The freedom of the shareholders to fashion the company’s
constitution facilitates the input of a significant element of
“private ordering” into the rules governing the company, but the
articles of association are not the only method whereby the
shareholders can generate their own rules for the governance of
their affairs. An alternative method is an agreement, concluded
among some or all the shareholders, but existing outside and
separate from the articles and to which the company itself may
or may not be a party. Such an agreement is not normally treated
as part of the constitution of the company, though it may have an
effect which is rather similar to a provision in the articles, and so
there are exceptions to this general rule.113
3–34
The main advantages of the shareholder agreement over the
articles are that the agreement is a private document which does
not have to be registered at Companies House and that it derives
its contractual force from the normal principles of contract law
and not from the Act, so that the limitations discussed above on
the statutory contract do not to apply to shareholder agreements.
3–35
The main disadvantages are that the shareholder agreement does
not automatically bind new members of the company, as the
articles do.114 A new member of the company will not be bound
by the agreement unless that person assents to it and so the
shareholder agreement may not continue to bind all the
members. Securing the assent of new members may or may not
be easy to bring about. Nor does the Act provide an overriding
mechanism for majority alteration to the shareholder agreement.
The parties to that agreement may provide such a mechanism,
but if they do not do so, then, under normal contractual rules, the
consent of each party to the agreement would be necessary to
effect a change. In addition, the protection provided by such an
agreement may be more limited than supposed, since remedies
for breach may be restricted to damages rather than an order for
specific performance, and indeed the company cannot agree to
be bound in matters which are contrary to the Companies Act. In
short, a shareholder agreement displays both the advantages and
disadvantages of private contracting.
We discuss shareholder agreements and other methods of
protecting minority shareholders, such as the issue of shares with
special rights attached to them, in Ch.19.
THE EUROPEAN COMPANY
3–36
As far as the European Company is concerned, a hierarchy of
sources of rules is set out in the European Company Statute.115
The primary source of rules for the SE is EU law, as one would
expect, in the shape of the European Company Statute, which
applies directly in the Member States without the need for
transposition, which a Directive requires.116 The second source
of law for the SE is its own statutes (or constitution or articles of
association, as we might term them), but only to the extent that
the Regulation expressly permits the SE through its statutes to
regulate a particular matter. In fact, some highly significant
choices are expressly given by the Regulation to the SE, to be
made through its statutes, for example, the choice between a
one-tier and a two-tier board.117 However, as we noted in Ch.1,118
the European Regulation does not aim to provide a
comprehensive code of company law for the SE. Much is
referred to the law of the state in which the SE is registered, and
so domestic law becomes an important source of rules for the
SE. The Regulation contemplates two types of domestic law as
being relevant. The third source is thus domestic law passed
specifically in order to embed the Regulation in the domestic
company law or to exercise choices conferred by the SE Statute
on the Member States in relation to the SE.119 For example,
Member States may, but need not, lay down rules about the
maximum and minimum number of members of a one-tier board
(if the SE chooses this system of governance)120 or a Member
State may reduce below 10 per cent the figure for the proportion
of shareholders who are entitled to insist that an item be added to
the agenda of a meeting of the SE’s shareholders.121
However, the more important domestic (and fourth) source of
rules for the SE is likely to be the rules applying to public
companies in the jurisdiction of registration. These rules will
apply to the SE automatically and without the need for special
national implementing legislation. Often, the SE Statute says in
relation to a particular subject-matter that these domestic rules
shall apply (for example, in relation to the legal capital of the
SE),122 but this is declared generally to be the principle in
relation to matters not governed, or to the extent not governed,
by the regulation itself.123 Thus, much of the law governing
domestic public companies limited by shares will apply to the
SE. Indeed, the main interest of the SE as a legal form can be
said to lie in those relatively limited areas where the domestic
rules are trumped by rules emanating from EU law and the EU
rules are significantly different from those which domestic law
applies to its public companies,124 and it is on those aspects that
the later chapters in this book will concentrate. An obvious
example is the requirement for the domestic legislature to make
a two-tier board model of governance available for the SE to
take up, if it so wishes.
The final source of rules for the SE under the regulation
brings the statutes of the SE back into the picture once again.
They are a source of law “in the same way as for a public
limited-liability formed in accordance with the law of the
Member State in which the SE has its registered office”.125 As
we have seen, the domestic law makes the articles a major
source for the rules governing the internal affairs of the public
company, and this will be the case also for the SE, except to the
extent that the regulation itself has occupied ground which the
domestic company law leaves to the articles of association. This
will probably mean that the statutes of a British-registered SE
will be an important source of rules, but a less important source
than for a domestic public company, because Title III of the
regulation governs the structure of the European Company
(board of directors and shareholders’ meeting) more extensively
than does the Companies Act or the common law in relation to a
domestic company.
However, the EU rules relating to the SE are not to be found
wholly in the regulation. The crucial issue of employee
involvement in the SE126 is dealt with at EU level by a
Directive.127 Directives do require transposition into domestic
law. Moreover, if the Directive is properly transposed, the
domestic law becomes the source of obligation in the national
legal system, not the Directive. Consequently, the employee
involvement Directive, despite the importance of its subject-
matter, has no greater impact on the sources of domestic
company law than do any of the many other EC Directives
which have played a part in shaping modern British company
law,128 and so it need not be considered further here.
1 See below, Ch.28.
2 See below, Ch.15.
3
See below, Ch.16.
4For an insightful discussion of default rules see S. Deakin and A. Hughes, “Economic
Efficiency and the Proceduralisation of Company Law” (1999) 3 C.F.I.L.R. 169.
5 See below, Ch.14.
6
DTI, Company Law Reform: Modern Company Law for a Competitive Economy
(1998).
7 The editors of this edition were involved, Paul Davies substantially, as a member of the
Steering Group from March 1999, and Sarah Worthington to a limited degree, as a
member of one of the Working Groups. Comments on the Review in this book should be
read in the light of that fact.
8
See Final Report II, Annex E for details.
9
Final Report I, para.9.
10
See Modernising Company Law, Cm. 5553, July 2002—also in two volumes; and
then Company Law Reform, Cm. 6456, March 2005.
11
See Ch.9.
12
See para.6–14 and Chs 25 and 26.
13
Other important examples of separate legislation are the Bribery Act 2010 (applying
not just to corporate businesses—see paras 7–46 and 16–107) and the Company
Directors Disqualification Act 1986 (see below, Ch.10), which at least has the word
“Company” in its title and seems to have become a separate Act because it consolidates
provisions previously found partly in the Companies Acts and partly in the Insolvency
Act.
14 Instead of three readings and a committee stage in each House of Parliament over
several months, as in the case of an Act, there will be only a single short debate, and in
the case of subordinate legislation subject to “negative resolution”, there will not even be
a debate unless MPs take the necessary steps to initiate one. See Companies Act 2006
ss.1288–1292.
15 2006 Act s.468.
16 2006 Act s.657.
17
Final Report I, paras 5.7 and 5.10 and Modernising, I, p.9. Some power to reform by
statutory instrument is now given to Government across legislation generally by the
Legislative and Regulatory Reform Act 2006.
18 Final Report I, para.5.4.
19
For the meaning of this term see para.25–5.
20
Mainly the rules on disclosure on interests in shares on the part of directors and
“major” shareholders. See Ch.26.
21 As ss.73A and 119 of FSMA 2000 contemplate.
22 FSMA 2000 ss.93–94.
23 See above, para.1–8.
24
The main legislative expression of these reforms was the Companies (Audit,
Investigation and Community Enterprise) Act 2004, some parts of which have survived
the 2006 Act.
25
2006 Act ss.457 and 1217 and Sch.10.
26Company Directors: Regulating Conflicts of Interest and Formulating a Statement of
Duties, Cm. 4436, 1999.
27 Shareholder Remedies, Cm. 3769, 1997.
28 See below, Chs 16 and 17.
29 For example, the unfair prejudice provisions, discussed in Ch.20.
30
Its predecessors were the Department for Business, Enterprise and Regulatory Reform
(“BERR”), and, before that, the Department of Trade and Industry (“DTI”), responsible
for the CLR.
31
Report of the Company Law Committee, Cmnd. 1749, 1962.
32
Report of the Committee on Company Law Amendment, Cmnd. 6659, 1945.
33
Final Report I, para.5.22.
34
Modernising, I, pp.48–49.
35
2006 Act s.18.
36
Although, for listed companies, the UK Corporate Governance Code now trespasses
upon the autonomy of the company, at least in the sense that it requires “comply or
explain” conformity with defined best practices. See below, Ch.14.
37
See for Germany the Aktiengesetz, Pt Four, subdivisions One and Two, and for the
US, the Model Business Corporation Act, Ch.8.
38 See SI 2008/3229 Sch.3, the model articles for public companies, art.3: “Subject to
the articles, the directors are responsible for the management of the company’s business,
for which purpose they may exercise all the powers of the company”. The model article
for private companies limited by shares is in similar terms.
39
See below, Ch.14.
40
See above, para.3–2.
41 2006 Act s.19.
42 2006 Act s.20.
43
Final Report II, Ch.17.
44
The model for private companies limited by shares is in Sch.1, and that for public
companies in Sch.3. The model for private companies limited by guarantee is in Sch.2.
45Probably the facility of company formation agents in developing their own standard
model articles for different classes of company met much of the need in practice.
462006 Act s.20(1). This presumption applies whatever the type of limited company. By
contrast, s.8(2) of CA 1985 created a default only in the case of companies limited by
shares.
47 2006 Act s.20(1)(a)—unless there is no model prescribed, in which case it must
register articles of association: s.18(2).
48 2006 Act s.18(3)(a).
49 2006 Act s.20(2).
50 2006 Act s.17.
51 See paras 15–15 and 15–44.
52
See Ch.19. This could be an ordinary resolution of the class, if it binds all the
members of the class.
53 2006 Act s.29.
54 For the residual function of the memorandum, see para.4–5.
55
They are included as part of the constitution for the purposes of s.40: see s.40(3)(b)
and para.7–14.
56
The current provision makes explicit the fact that the company too is bound by the
rules (important in giving members rights against the company). Practitioners had long
treated earlier versions of the articles as binding between member and company despite
the statutory wording making no reference to the company, although on the basis of only
a first instance authority: Hickman v Kent or Romney Marsh Sheepbreeders Association
[1915] 1 Ch. 881. The treatment of the articles as a deed has also been removed from the
current section, thus removing the consequence that a debt owed by the member to the
company was a “specialty” debt, with its special limitation period, rather than an
ordinary one. Contrast s.14(2) of CA 1985 and s.33(2) of CA 2006; and cf. Re
Compania de Electridad de Buenos Aires [1980] Ch. 146 at 187.
57
Borland’s Trustee v Steel [1901] 1 Ch. 279 (member seeking declaration that rights of
pre-emption in articles were valid); cf. Lyle & Scott v Scott’s Trustees [1959] A.C. 763
HL; and see para.27–7.
58
Rayfield v Hands [1960] Ch. 1, where Vaisey J was prepared to make an order in
effect for specific performance.
59 See below, paras 3–23 to 3–30.
60
2006 Act ss.9(5)(b) and 14.
61
Directive 68/151/EEC [1968] O.J. 41 art.2(1)(b).
62 Scott v Frank F. Scott (London) Ltd [1940] Ch. 794 CA.
63 Bratton Seymour Service Co Ltd v Oxborough [1992] B.C.L.C. 693 CA. In this case
the majority were in effect seeking to avoid the prohibition on alterations to the
constitution without individual shareholder consent which have the effect of increasing
the shareholder’s financial liability to the company (see s.25 and below, para.19–1). See
also Towcester Racecourse Co Ltd v Racecourse Association Ltd [2003] 1 B.C.L.C. 260,
where, in any event, the judge regarded the suggested implied terms as inconsistent with
the express terms of the articles. But contrast AG v Belize Telecom [2009] B.C.C. 433,
where the extrinsic evidence was known to the third parties. See also Re Coroin Ltd
[2011] EWHC 3466 (Ch) (affirmed [2012] B.C.C. 575), where the court was prepared to
admit the shareholder agreement pursuant to which the articles were adopted as extrinsic
evidence.
64 Bratton Seymour Service Co Ltd v Oxborough [1992] B.C.L.C. 693 at 698 CA. On the
other hand, investor protection was not inconsistent with the implication of terms based
on the construction of the language used in the articles, for here the basis of the
implication was available to those who read the company’s constitution.
65 See below, para.4–7.
66
A further and important restriction on the remedies available in respect of breaches of
the corporate constitution, namely the supposed rule that damages were not available to
a shareholder in an action against his company so long as he remained a member, seems
to have been removed by what is now s.655, originally inserted by the 1989 Act.
67
2006 Act ss.29 and 30. And see below, para.15–15.
68 Cane v Jones [1980] 1 W.L.R. 1451; Re Home Treat Ltd [1991] B.C.L.C. 705.
69 2006 Act ss.26 and 27.
70
The Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999 does not apply to the company’s
constitution: s.6(2) of that Act.
71
While this restriction on the types of rights which can be enforced is well-supported
by precedent (even if difficult to explain), it is less clear whether the restriction also
limits enforcement to those provisions which impose obligations on a member “as a
member”. It seems not: see Rayfield v Hands [1960] Ch. 1, where the provision
concerned the liabilities of members qua directors; and Lion Mutual Marine Insurance v
Tucker (1883) 12 Q.B.D. 176 CA, where the provision concerned the liabilities of
members qua insurers.
72
Hickman v Kent or Romney Marsh Sheepbreeders’ Association [1915] 1 Ch. 881 at
897.
73
London Sack & Bag Co v Dixon & Lugton [1943] 2 All E.R. 763 CA.
74
The Hickman case may reflect the high regard in which the courts then held the
doctrine of privity of contract.
75 Re English & Colonial Produce Co [1906] 2 Ch. 435.
76 Eley v Positive Life Association (1876) 1 Ex. D. 88 CA.
77
Relatively little is needed for the court to conclude that the articles have been
incorporated into the service contract, but there must be something: see Globalink
Telecommunications Ltd v Wilmbury Ltd [2003] 1 B.C.L.C. 145.
78
On directors’ contracts see Ch.14.
79
2006 Act s.171. See paras 16–24 et seq.
80 Beattie v Beattie Ltd [1938] Ch. 708 CA.
81 Rayfield v Hands [1960] Ch. 1.
82 What he would have held had one of the directors not been a member is unclear.
83
See “Shareholders’ Rights and the Rule in Foss v Harbottle” in [1957] C.L.J. 193,
especially at 210–215. See also Beck in (1974) 22 Can.B.R. 157 at 190–193.
84 Quinn & Axtens Ltd v Salmon [1909] 1 Ch. 311 CA; affirmed [1909] A.C. 442 HL.
For subsequent dicta in support of this view see, e.g. Re Harmer Ltd [1959] 1 W.L.R. 62
at 85 and 89 CA; Re Richmond Gate Property Co [1965] 1 W.L.R. 335 (see (1965) 28
M.L.R. 347 and (1966) 29 M.L.R. 608 at 612); Hogg v Cramphorn [1967] Ch. 254;
Bamford v Bamford [1970] Ch. 212; Re Sherbourn Park Residents Co Ltd (1986) 2
B.C.C. 99 at 528; Breckland Group Holdings v London & Suffolk Properties [1989]
B.C.L.C. 100 (see (1989) 52 M.L.R. 401 at 407–408); Guinness Plc v Saunders [1990] 2
A.C. 663 HL; Wise v USDAW [1996] I.C.R. 691 at 702.
85For subsequent academic discussion of the principle, see Goldberg in (1972) 33
M.L.R. 362; Prentice in (1980) 1 Co. Law 179; Gregory in (1981) 44 M.L.R. 526;
Goldberg (replying) in (1985) 48 M.L.R. 121; Drury in [1989] C.L.J. 219; and
Worthington, (2000) 116 L.Q.R. 638.
86 Formation, paras 2.6–2.8.
87
Completing, paras 5.66–5.67.
88 See above, fn.70.
89
See Chs 14 and 15, below.
90
MacDougall v Gardiner (1875) 1 Ch.D. 13.
91
Pender v Lushington (1877) 6 Ch.D. 70.
92
R.J. Smith, “Minority Shareholders and Corporate Irregularities” (1978) M.L.R. 147.
93
This argument would lack force only if, as is not usually the case for companies or,
indeed, most associations, the procedure for amending the rules on how decisions are to
be taken was the same as the one for taking substantive decisions.
94
Such a statement would surely be regarded as uncontroversial if made in relation to
trade union law. cf. O. Kahn-Freund, Kahn-Freund’s Labour and the Law, 3rd edn
(Stevens, 1983), pp.286 et seq. The courts do not lack techniques for dealing with
members whose complaints are purely “technical”, i.e. where it is clear that the same
result would have been arrived at even if the proper procedure had been followed:
Harben v Phillips [1974] 1 W.L.R. 638.
95
Taylor v NUM (Derbyshire Area) [1985] B.C.L.C. 237. For the application of the
distinction between personal and derivative actions to companies in an ultra vires
context, see Moseley v Koffyfontein Mines [1911] 1 Ch. 73 CA.
96
To which this distinction between personal rights and mere internal irregularities also
applies.
97 See Ch.17 for a discussion of derivative actions in relation to companies.
98
But note Devlin v Slough Estates Ltd [1983] B.C.L.C. 497, refusing to recognise that
the particular article in question, relating to the preparation of the company’s accounts,
conferred a right upon individual shareholders (as contrasted with “the company”).
99 There is some suggestion in the language used in MacDougall v Gardiner and Pender
v Lushington (see above, fnn.90 and 91), respectively, that the decisions are to be
explained on the basis that the two courts simply fastened on two different legal aspects
of a single situation.
100
Completing, para.5.73; Final Report I, paras 7.34–7.40.
101 On the crucial distinction between corporate and individual loss, see para.17–34.
102Though they could still be used as the basis for an unfair prejudice remedy: see
Ch.20, below. That remedy today is probably the mechanism by which complaints of
breaches of the articles are most often litigated.
103 Changes in the articles must be notified to the registrar: s.26. In the case of charitable
companies the power to amend the articles is subject to the requirement of the charities
legislation operating in the three UK jurisdictions: s.21(2), (3).
104 Shuttleworth v Cox Bros & Co (Maidenhead) Ltd [1927] 2 K.B. 9 at 26 CA, per
Atkin LJ; Malleson v National Insurance and Guarantee Corp [1894] 1 Ch. 200 at 205,
per North J.
105 2006 Act s.25(1).
106On the impact of this principle on contracts outside the articles, see paras 19–25 et
seq.
107
Under the prior law, entrenchment could be achieved by placing the provision in the
memorandum of association and subjecting it to restrictive alteration conditions—and
the prior law did seem to permit making a provision unalterable in any circumstances
(other than a court order). See CA 1985 s.17(2)(b). The new scheme follows that
proposed by the CLR: Formation, para.2.27.
108
2006 Act s.22(3)(a) expressly provides that entrenchment cannot prevent alteration
by agreement of all the members.
109
2006 Act s.22(2). On formation all the subscribers in effect agree to the contents of
the articles and subsequent members join on the basis of what those articles provide.
110
2006 Act s.23.
111
2006 Act s.24.
112
The entrenchment provisions can be overridden by a court order: s.22(3)(b), (4). See,
for example, ss.899–901 and Ch.29.
113Shareholder agreements are included within the meaning of the constitution of the
company for the purposes of s.40: see s.40(3)(b) and para.7–14.
114
2006 Act s.33(1) says that the articles bind the company and the members, meaning
those who at any one time are the members of the company.
115 Council Regulation 2157/2001/EC art.9.
116
However, since the provisions on worker involvement in the SE are contained in a
Directive, which needs transposition, the Regulation applies in the Member States only
together with the national provisions transposing the Directive. For the UK see European
Public Limited-Liability Company Regulations (SI 2004/2326) Pt 3 (hereafter European
Company Regulations).
117 Regulation 2157/2001/EC art.38. See further below, para.14–64.
118 See above, para.1–40.
119See the European Company Regulations Pt 4 (exercising options) and Pts 2 and 5–7
doing various types of “embedding”.
120 SE Statute art.43(2).
121
SE Statute art.56.
122 SE Statute art.5.
123 SE Statute arts 9(1)(c) and 10.
124
Of course, some of the mandatory rules to be found in the Regulation may in fact
track the domestic rules with perhaps minor changes.
125 Reg.2157/2001/EC art.9(1)(c)(iii).
126 See further below, Ch.14.
127 Directive 2002/14/EC [2002] O.J. L80/29.
128 Discussed generally in Ch.6.
CHAPTER 4
FORMATION PROCEDURES
Introduction 5–1
“Promoters” and their Dealings with the Company 5–2
Meaning of “promoter” 5–2
Duties of promoters 5–6
Remedies for breach of promoters’ duties 5–15
Remuneration of promoters 5–21
Preliminary Contracts Entered Into by Promoters 5–23
Companies’ Pre-Incorporation Contracts 5–24
Conclusion 5–29
INTRODUCTION
5–1
In the earlier chapters we examined the advantages of
incorporation, the processes for achieving that status, and the
various sources of rules regulating the corporate form once
created.1 And in later chapters we look in detail at the law as it
applies to companies, paying particular attention to the sources
of a company’s capital and the various constraints on its use,2 as
well as the legal constraints on the powers exercised by the
company’s management, especially by its directors.3 All these
various legal rules are designed to ensure that the company is
run as a success, thus enabling the company’s shareholders,
creditors and other stakeholders to prosper.
Extensive though these rules are, they leave a window of time
which is potentially unregulated. This is the period during which
individuals with good ideas for a new business set to work on
creating a company and bringing it into existence ready to do
business. This may seem a relatively unimportant time in the
scheme of things, especially now that buying a company off the
shelf makes the process so quick.4 But two particular problems
are common. The first is the intuitive concern with the probity of
transactions between the newly formed company buying assets,
for example, from the very people who set the company up and
determine its first steps. The risk is that these deals overly
advantage the originators, or “promoters”, at the expense of the
company and those persuaded to become its members. Secondly,
there is the practical problem of how a company not yet in
existence can enter into contracts which bind the company once
it is formed. In agency terms, this is a case where the principal is
not “undisclosed” (indeed, its expected genesis is usually made
clear), but is “non-existent” at the time of the deal. This too may
seem an unlikely problem, but it is sometimes (although
increasingly rarely) simply the case that a time-sensitive
opportunity presents itself before the company can be formed,
and yet those involved do not want to be personally liable; they
want—for all the reasons we have already considered—to have
the deal pursued under a corporate umbrella.
We take each problem in turn. They raise quite different
issues, the first dealt with primarily by the common law, the
second by a combination of the common law and statute.
“PROMOTERS” AND THEIR DEALINGS WITH THE COMPANY
Meaning of “promoter”
5–2
Much of the current law on promoters emerged in the nineteenth
century, when there were no restrictions on inviting the public to
subscribe for shares in newly formed companies, and the
caricature “company promoter” was an individual of dubious
repute who made it his profession to form bogus companies and
foist them off on a gullible public, to the latter’s detriment and
his own profit. But even in those days a much more typical
example was the village grocer who converted his business into
a limited company.5 The motivations of each might be different,
and the grocer less likely than the professional to abuse his
position since he can be expected to remain the majority
shareholder in his company, whereas the promoter, if a
shareholder at all, usually intends to off-load his holdings onto
others as soon as possible. But both create, or help to create, the
company, and seek to sell it something, whether it be their
services or a business. Both are well-placed to take advantage of
their position by obtaining a recompense grossly in excess of the
true value of what they are selling.6 For that reason it has long
been held that both should be subjected to rather onerous
common law and equitable duties, given the power that they
wield over the company. The parallels with the rules applying to
directors of companies already in existence will be clear when
we come to consider those rules.7
5–3
But who should be subject to such tough rules? Both the
professional promoter and the village grocer are promoters to the
fullest extent, in that each “undertakes to form a company with
reference to a given project, and to set it going and takes the
necessary steps to accomplish that purpose”.8 But a person who
has taken a much less active and dominating role may also be a
promoter. Indeed, the potential activities of promoters are so
varied that no comprehensive definition has ever been
formulated, beyond confining it to activities related to bringing a
company into existence.9 The expression may, for example,
cover any individual or company that arranges for someone to
become a director, places shares, or negotiates preliminary
agreements.10 Nor need he or she necessarily be associated with
the initial formation of the company; one who subsequently
helps to arrange the “floating off” of its capital (in the manner
explained in Ch.25) will equally be regarded as a promoter.11 On
the other hand, those who act in a purely ministerial capacity,
such as solicitors and accountants, will not be classified as
promoters merely because they undertake their normal
professional duties12; although they may if, for example, they
have agreed to become directors or to find others who will.13
5–4
Who constitutes a promoter in any particular case is therefore a
question of fact,14 and the promoter’s role continues until the
particular functions of promotion come to an end.15 The
expression has never been clearly defined either judicially16 or
legislatively, despite the fact that it is frequently used both in
decisions and statutes; this vagueness is apt to be embarrassing
when legislation requires promoters to be named or transactions
with them to be disclosed.17
5–5
In many ways the risks of promotion are now lower. In private
companies the rules very easily merge with those applying to
corporate directors, since in this context the promoter usually
becomes, and was always intended to become, a director of the
newly formed company. And, as far as public companies are
concerned, these days, promoters cannot simply invite the public
to subscribe for shares in any proposed new venture: only a
public company can invite the public to subscribe for shares, and
before a public company is listed on the Main Market of the
Stock Exchange or quoted on the Alternative Investment Market,
it must be able to show some track record. Consequently, here
too the duties of the promoters are often swallowed up in such
cases in those of the directors.18 But corporate promotion
continues, even if on a smaller scale, and indeed more recently
there has been an increase in public offers of unlisted shares,
including shares in new start-up ventures, so the law on
promoters may become increasingly important again.
Duties of promoters
5–6
The problems which must be dealt with are clear. Promoters are
in a particularly advantaged position to sell their own assets or
services to the company at an inflated price; to mislead likely
investors into buying shares in the new company; and, once that
is done, perhaps to induce the company to confirm that all is
proper, and any breach might be waived.
(a) Statutory rules
5–7
The early Companies Acts contained no provisions regarding the
liabilities of promoters, and current legislation remains largely
silent on the subject, merely imposing liability for untrue
statements in listing particulars or prospectuses to which they are
parties.19 Since these rules apply only to public offers and not to
company formations unaccompanied by a public offer or the
introduction of the securities to a public market, discussion of
them is postponed to Ch.25.
5–8
There are also statutory rules relating to sales of assets to public
companies. Article 11 of the Second Company Law Directive
was intended to ensure that, when a public company acquired a
substantial non-cash asset20 from its promoters within two years
of its entitlement to commence business, an independent
valuation of that asset and approval by the company in general
meeting should be required. But, as we shall see,21 as
implemented by the UK this applies only to acquisitions from
the subscribers to the memorandum, who need not be the true
promoters and generally are not. However, when a private
company re-registers as a public one (a more common
occurrence than initial formation as a public company) a similar
requirement applies to such acquisitions from anyone who was a
member on the date of re-registration,22 and that may well catch
a promoter. This, therefore, affords an additional statutory
protection against the risk that promoters will seek to off-load
their property to the company at an inflated price, but one which
can be avoided by the promoters ceasing to be members prior to
the re-registration.
5–9
Finally, if the promoter exchanges his or her own assets for
shares, then there are also statutory rules designed to prevent
issues of shares at a discount. But these too are focused on
public companies rather than private ones, where it is largely left
to the common law and equitable rules to regulate the problem.23
(b) Common law and equitable rules
5–10
Thus, in the main, promoters’ duties have been developed by the
courts. Promoters are of course subject to the general law on
fraud, misrepresentation, negligence, unjust enrichment, and so
on, and in the right context these duties can be important. But
their most significant duties are equitable. In a series of cases in
the last quarter of the nineteenth century, the courts were alert to
the possibilities of abuse inherent in the promoter’s position, and
thus determined that promoters stand in a fiduciary position
towards the company,24 with all the duties of disclosure and
accounting which that implies. These fiduciary restrictions
profoundly affect three particular contexts: unless promoters
obtain the fully informed consent of the company, they cannot
enter into any sale or purchase transactions with the company
(the conflict between their personal interest in the transaction
and their duty to obtain the best price for the company is
obvious), or be remunerated, or take commissions from third
parties (absent consent, these both constitute secret profits).
These fiduciary duties have not been restated in the 2006 Act, as
directors’ fiduciary duties have been,25 and so they remain
regulated by the common law. However, the two sets of rules are
likely to continue to influence each other, and the detail of
promoters’ duties and their application can be gleaned from the
analogous cases concerning directors.26
(c) Full disclosure and consent
5–11
The main difficulty with promoters’ fiduciary duties has been
deciding how to effect proper disclosure to, and obtain approval
from, the company—the company being an artificial entity. As
we will see later, the powers of the company are generally
exercised by the board of directors or (where that is not possible
or where otherwise agreed) by the shareholders in general
meeting.27 But adopting either option typically raises a very real
practical problem: voting may in either case be dominated by the
promoter, thus allowing the promoter to be judge in his or her
own cause. That does not seem right, and here, as elsewhere, the
courts have struggled towards an effective solution to the
problem.28
5–12
The first leading case on the subject, Erlanger v New Sombrero
Phosphate Co,29 suggested that it was the promoter’s duty to
ensure that the company had an independent board of directors
and to make full disclosure to it. In that case Lord Cairns said30
that the promoters of a company:
“stand undoubtedly in a fiduciary position. They have in their hands the creation
and moulding of the company; they have the power of defining how, and when, and
in what shape, and under what supervision, it shall start into existence and begin to
act as a trading corporation…I do not say that the owner of property may not
promote and form a joint stock company and then sell his property to it, but I do
say that if he does he is bound to take care that he sells it to the company through
the medium of a board of directors who can and do exercise an independent and
intelligent judgment on the transaction.”
5–13
Such a decision would undoubtedly be effective, but will
anything less suffice? An entirely independent board would be
impossible in the case of most private and many public
companies, and since Salomon v Salomon31 it has never been
doubted that the fully informed consent of the members would
be equally effective. In that famous case it was held that the
liquidator of the company could not complain of the sale to it at
an obvious over-valuation of Mr Salomon’s business, all the
members having acquiesced therein. Note, however, that in this
case the shareholders’ consent was unanimous, and so it might
be thought irrelevant that Salomon himself held the
overwhelming majority of the shares: all who could agree on the
company’s behalf had done so; there was no dissent. But could
Salomon have carried such a vote against a unanimously
opposed independent minority? Logic suggests not, yet the cases
pull both ways.32 Even the older cases saw the problem. This
was evident in the speeches of the House of Lords in the second
great landmark case in the development of this branch of the
law, Gluckstein v Barnes.33 That case made it clear that a
promoter could not escape liability by disclosing to a few cronies
who constituted the company’s initial members, when it was the
intention immediately to float off the company to the public or to
induce some other dupes to purchase the shares. “It is too
absurd”, said Lord Halsbury with his usual bluntness:
“to suggest that a disclosure to the parties to this transaction is a disclosure to the
company. They were there by the terms of the agreement to do the work of the
syndicate, that is to say, to cheat the shareholders; and this, forsooth, is to be treated
as a disclosure to the company, when they were really there to hoodwink the
shareholders.”
6–1
This chapter discusses three main issues. First, how far are
companies incorporated outside the UK subject to British
company law if they carry on business within the UK? Secondly,
to what extent does the freedom of companies within the EU to
carry on business across borders suggest that the EU should take
action to harmonise the company laws of the Member States?
Thirdly, what is the extent of the freedom companies have to
choose the country in which their registered office is located or
subsequently to move it to another jurisdiction? The third issue
is closely related to the second. The effect of a change of the
jurisdiction in which the registered office is located is a change
in the company law to which the company is subject from the
transferor jurisdiction’s law to that of the transferee jurisdiction.
Free movement of a company’s registered office is a necessary
but not a sufficient condition for competition among the Member
States in the provision of company laws which companies find
attractive. If such competition develops, that may lead to
convergence among the company laws of the Member States,
even if there is no harmonisation of company law at EU level. In
other words convergence of Member States’ company laws may
result from “top-down” harmonisation by the EU or from
“bottom up” competition among the Member States (or, of
course, from a mixture of the two processes). The first issue is
also linked to the second, since it raises the question of whether
the UK is happy to allow the internal relations of companies
operating in the UK to be determined by foreign law.
OVERSEAS COMPANIES
6–2
British law might have refused to recognise companies not
incorporated in one of the UK jurisdictions,1 thus putting in
jeopardy the validity in those jurisdictions of transactions
entered into by non-UK incorporated companies and in effect
requiring companies which wished to carry on business in the
UK to do so through a British subsidiary. In fact, British law has
never adopted such an approach. As Lord Wright said in 1933:
“English courts have long since recognised as juristic persons
corporations established by foreign law in virtue of the fact of
their creation and continuance under and by that law”.2 Indeed,
as we shall see below, to adopt a different rule today would be a
breach of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union
(“TFEU”). Thus, as a general rule,3 a company incorporated
outside the UK, whether within the EU or not, need not form a
British subsidiary company in order to do business in the UK. It
may trade through an agency or branch in this country or,
indeed, simply contract with someone in the UK without
establishing any form of presence in this country.4 Of course,
when a company incorporated elsewhere intends to carry on a
substantial business in the UK, it is likely to form a British
subsidiary in order to do so. This might be regarded as a sign of
commitment to the British economy, and it also allows the
foreign parent company to ring-fence its British operations by
putting them in a separate subsidiary with limited liability.5 The
point, however, is that the foreign company is not obliged to take
this route; it can do business here in its own right, if it so wishes.
This long-standing stance of British law towards foreign
companies conducting business in the UK means that it is
broadly content to leave the regulation of the internal affairs of
such companies to the law of the jurisdiction in which they have
their registered office, even though those dealing with it may not
be aware of its jurisdictional location and the implications of this
fact for its governing company law. To combat this risk a
requirement is imposed on overseas companies with a significant
presence in the UK, to make public disclosures which match
those of required of domestic companies.
6–3
The rules on disclosure by foreign companies are to be found in
Pt 34 of the Act and regulations made under it. This Part is
entitled “overseas companies”,6 a term that might be thought to
conjure up a picture of companies formed in some distant and
exotic location, as they sometimes are, though in fact it may be
only the Straits of Dover or the Irish Sea which separate the
country of incorporation from the UK. An overseas company is
simply “a company incorporated outside the United Kingdom”.7
The regulatory objectives of this Part are relatively modest. They
are principally to ensure that there is available in the UK some
basic information about a company incorporated elsewhere
which has established a presence in this country from which it
does business. That information is, essentially, the information a
British company would have to provide on incorporation8 or as
part of its annual financial returns,9 plus some information
relating to those who represent the overseas company in the UK.
However, some provisions go beyond disclosure.
Immediately prior to the 2006 Act this was an area of law
which, despite its modest objectives, was overly complicated,
because there were two sets of provisions, each containing
slightly different disclosure requirements, for overseas
companies. This arose in part because the Act does not attempt
to regulate all overseas companies which do business in the UK
(for example, over the internet) but only those which have some
sort of base in the UK. However, two different connecting
factors emerged as ways of defining that base. One was the
result of the UK’s implementation of the Eleventh Company
Law Directive10 which used the concept of a “branch” to define
the connection which an overseas company needed to have with
the UK to fall within the overseas companies rules. The other
connecting factor was the traditional domestic one, based on the
company having a “place of business” in the UK. Even this
might not have been problematic if both connecting factors had
been linked to the same set of disclosure requirements. However,
the two connecting factors were linked to slightly different
disclosure requirements, so that companies could not simply
proceed on the basis that they did not need to decide whether
they operated a branch or a place of business. Rather, they had to
decide between the two, in order to determine which disclosure
regime applied.11 Although it was clear that a company subject
to both regimes must comply with the EU rules if they were
more demanding than the domestic ones (which was generally
the case), companies might be far from clear whether the EU
regime applied to them or only the domestic one.12
The CLR recommended,13 and the Government accepted and
eventually implemented,14 the re-establishment of a single
regime. This is based on a single set of disclosure requirements,
derived from the Eleventh Directive, but using a multi-pronged
connecting factor. The Overseas Companies Regulations 200915
are expressed to apply whenever an overseas company opens an
“establishment” in the UK; but “establishment” is defined to
mean a branch within the meaning of the Eleventh Directive or a
place of business which is not a branch.16 Thus, either a branch
or a place of business will trigger the operation of the provisions
relating to overseas companies, but the crucial point is that the
disclosure rules will not now vary according to whether the
“establishment” test is met on the basis of a branch or a place of
business.17
Establishment: branch and place of business
6–4
The terms “branch” and “place of business” obviously overlap to
a large extent, but it seems that both at the top and at the bottom
of the spectrum a place of business may exist even though a
branch does not. To take the bottom end, this situation may arise
because, it seems, activities ancillary to a company’s business
may constitute a place of business but not a branch. It is difficult
to be absolutely certain about this, because the Eleventh
Directive does not define a “branch” whilst the Regulations do
not define a “place of business”, but it seems to be the case. It
has been said in case law that establishing a place of business, as
opposed to merely doing business, in this country requires “a
degree of permanence or recognisability as being a location of
the company’s business”.18 However, it is not fatal to the
establishment of a place of business that the activities carried on
there are only subsidiary to the company’s main business, which
is carried on outside the UK, or are not a substantial part of the
company’s overall business.19 As to the meaning of a branch
some clues may be derivable from the EU legislation referring to
bank branches.20 This does contain a definition of a bank branch,
from which some guidance may be obtainable. That definition
refers to a place of business through which the bank “conducts
directly some or all of the operations inherent in the business”.21
So it may be that purely ancillary activities, such as warehousing
or data processing, do not constitute the establishment of a
branch though they could amount to a place of business. To like
effect is the definition of a branch adopted by the Court of
Justice for the purposes of the Brussels Convention: a branch has
the appearance of permanency and is physically equipped to
negotiate business with third parties directly.22 At the other end
of the spectrum, a company incorporated outside the UK but
which has its head office here,23 clearly has a place of business
in the UK, but it might be argued that this is not a branch, since a
branch supposes that the head office is elsewhere.24
Disclosure obligations
6–5
The Act and the Overseas Companies Regulations impose
disclosure requirements on an overseas company having an
establishment in the UK in all phases of its life. An overseas
company which opens an establishment must file with the
Registrar within one month information relating to both itself
and the establishment.25 Subsequent alterations in the registered
particulars must also be notified.26 Failure to do so constitutes a
criminal offence on the part of both company and any officer or
agent of the company who knowingly and wilfully authorises or
permits the default,27 but, apparently, does not affect the validity
of transactions the company may enter into through its
unregistered operation. There is no need in a book of this nature
to go into the detail of what is required, but it should be noted
that the requirements are more limited where the company is
incorporated in an EEA Member State than where this is not
so.28 This reflects the approach of the Eleventh Directive.29
Overall, the policy can be said to be to put the person dealing
with the overseas company through its establishment in a similar
informational position as would obtain if the company were one
incorporated under the Act.
A crucial concern of those who deal with overseas companies
is how to serve legal documents on the company. The particulars
relating to the establishment must give the name and service
address of every person resident in the UK authorised to accept
service on behalf of the company or a statement that there is no
such person.30 In addition, the information must state the extent
of the powers of the directors of the overseas company to
represent the company in dealings and in legal proceedings31 and
give a list of those authorised to represent the company as a
permanent representative of the company in respect of the
branch.32
6–6
On-going disclosure requirements fall into two categories. First,
the “trading disclosure” rules which apply to domestic
companies33 are adapted so as to apply to overseas companies
“carrying on business in the United Kingdom”.34 These rules are,
rightly, not confined to those overseas companies which have an
establishment in the UK, though doing business “in” the UK is
not defined. The aim of the rules is to provide third parties with
certain information at the point at which they deal—or are likely
to deal—with overseas companies. Thus, the company must
display its name and country of incorporation at every location at
which it carries on business35; its name on its business letters and
a wide range of analogous documents36; and, where it has an
establishment in the UK, a range of further information on these
documents.37 There are penalties for non-compliance,38 but non-
compliance also carries civil consequences on the same basis as
that applied to domestic companies.39
Secondly, annual reporting requirements are applied to
overseas companies, but, in this case, only if they have an
establishment in the UK.40 These requirements vary according to
whether the overseas company is required by the law of the
country in which it is incorporated (its “parent” law) to prepare,
have audited and to disclose annual accounts. If it is,41 the
overseas company discharges its disclosure obligations by
delivering to the Registrar a copy of the accounting documents
prepared in accordance with the parent law.42 The “accounting
documents” include not only the accounts themselves (including
the consolidated accounts, if relevant) and auditors’ report but
also the directors’ report.43 The company has the relatively
generous period of three months from the date the documents
were first disclosed under the parent law to file them with the
Registrar.44 If it is not so required, the overseas company is
subject to a version of the accounting and filing requirements
applied to domestic companies.45 In addition to the option,
available to domestic companies, to file accounts in accordance
with International Accounting Standards, the overseas company
may choose to prepare its accounts in accordance with its parent
law.46 However, the accounts of companies in this second
category are not subject to an audit requirement. Despite the
absence of an audit requirement, the obligation to produce
annual accounts is clearly a burdensome one for overseas
companies which are not required by their parent law to do so—
though there must now be few countries in the world which do
not require their companies to produce annual financial
statements.
Finally, if an overseas company closes an establishment in the
UK, it must give notice to the Registrar.47 As to the overseas
company itself, it must give information to the Registrar if it is
wound up or becomes subject to insolvency proceedings.48
The Act lays down a general rule that documents delivered to
the Registrar must be in English.49 However, the company’s
memorandum or articles of association may be delivered in
another language, provided they are accompanied by a certified
translation into English.50
Execution of documents and names
6–7
Although the overseas companies provisions are primarily
concerned with disclosure, there are two sets of further
provisions going beyond this. One set is largely facultative. It
applies, with appropriate modifications, the domestic rules about
execution of documents and seals to overseas companies,
whether or not that company has an establishment in the UK or
even whether or not it can be said to do business “in” the UK.51
The second set applies to company names and is regulatory in
intent.52 An overseas company is required to register, on
creation, the name of its establishment in the UK. That name
may be its corporate name or the name under which it proposes
to carry on business in the UK (its alternative name).53 In
principle, the domestic rules on company names54 are applied to
the overseas company’s registered name.55 Despite apparent
contravention of the domestic policy, however, an overseas
company which is registered in an EEA Member State is exempt
from the domestic name controls over its corporate name, except
those relating to permitted characters in a corporate name.56 The
Eleventh Directive does not provide for controls on the choice of
name by overseas companies and the virtual non-application of
such controls to the corporate names of EEA companies seems
to have been the result of a fear that to impose them would
infringe the freedom of establishment rules of the EU.57
Other mandatory provisions
6–8
In the final analysis, Pt 34 applies the equivalent of only a small
part of the British Act to overseas companies and, as we have
seen, where the home state requires the production of public,
audited accounts, even Pt 34 relies on the rules of the state of
incorporation rather than on the rules of the British Act. Some
further protection for third parties, based on British law, may
apply as a result of provisions in the Insolvency Act 1986. Thus,
the rules restricting the re-use by successor companies of the
name of a company which has gone into insolvent liquidation58
apply to overseas companies. This is achieved by use of the
formula that the relevant sections of the 1986 Act apply also to
companies “which may be wound up under Part V of this Act”.59
Part V of the 1986 Act permits the court in certain circumstances
compulsorily to wind up an unregistered company, the definition
of which is broad enough to include overseas companies.60 To
fall within Pt V the overseas company need not have an
established place of business in Great Britain nor, indeed, any
assets here at the time the application for winding up is made.61
The courts have also accepted that the jurisdiction to wind up
unregistered companies brings into play certain other sections of
the Insolvency Act, even though those sections do not in terms
apply to “Part V” companies.62 These include the important
provisions relating to fraudulent and wrongful trading.63
Important though these provisions may be, they apply only to
companies which are have been placed in an insolvency
procedure in the UK, which in the case of an overseas company
may well not happen.64 Finally, the Company Directors
Disqualification Act 198665 also applies to a company
incorporated outside Great Britain if it is a company capable of
being wound up under the Insolvency Act 1986.66
COMPANY LAW AT EU LEVEL
Harmonisation
6–9
The underlying policy of Pt 34 of the Act is to rely on the
company law of the state of incorporation when a foreign
company does business in the UK. When the European
Economic Community was founded in the middle of the 1950s, a
very different approach was taken in the Treaty of Rome. It was
expected that, in the Community, companies based in one
Member State would penetrate more readily the economies of
other Member States, without necessarily establishing
subsidiaries in those States. It was decided that this was
acceptable only if accompanied by a programme for the
mandatory harmonisation by the Community of the company
laws of the Member States.67 In other words, in the minds of the
drafters of the original EC Treaty, freedom of establishment for
companies and harmonisation of company laws in the EU were
closely linked. Consequently, what is today art.50(2)(g) TFEU
provides that the Council of Ministers by qualified majority vote,
on a proposal from the European Commission and with the
consent of the European Parliament,68 may adopt Directives69
which aim to protect the interests of members “and others”70 by
“co-ordinating to the necessary extent the safeguards which…are
required by Member States of companies and firms …with a
view to making such safeguards equivalent throughout the
Union”. Thus, reliance on other Member States’ company laws
was to be accompanied by EU legislation which made those laws
“equivalent”, at least in certain respects.
The proposed programme for extensive mandatory
harmonisation, from the top down, of Member States’ domestic
company laws got off to an impressive start, but by the middle
1990s, if not earlier, it had run out of steam, with only part of the
proposed programme of “company law directives” enacted. This
may have been because the theory linking freedom of
establishment with a need for harmonised company law was
never satisfactorily articulated. There was little empirical
evidence that “members and others” were suffering in the EU’s
single market from the lack of harmonised company laws. There
was also the criticism that, once a policy had been embodied in
EU company law, it was more difficult to change it than in the
case of domestic legislation, at least for the majority of Member
States. In other words, the EU legislative process was more
“sticky” than national ones.
6–10
In any event, for harmonisation to be fully successful, (a) there
must exist a common best rule for all the Members States; (b)
the EU Commission, which has a monopoly on the initiation of
Community legislation, must be able to identify it; and (c) the
participants in the Community’s legislative process must accept
the common rule. None of these characteristics was ever
completely in place. The structure of shareholding (dispersed or
concentrated) differs across the Member States, at least in
relation to large companies, so that the dominant problem in
some jurisdictions is the relationship between management and
shareholders as a class and in other jurisdictions that between
controlling and non-controlling shareholders. In some Member
States board level representation of employees is an important
part of the domestic industrial relations system, whilst in others
it is not. Both features made the identification of a single
common rule very difficult in the most sensitive areas of
company law. As to the EU Commission, it never had the time
or the resources to develop the highly sophisticated comparative
law analysis which legislating for an ever-growing block of
countries requires. Finally, since the adoption of legislation
requires a supermajority vote of the Member States, there is
plenty of scope for the states to defend national interests,
normally by watering down the proposals put forward by the EU
Commission. It may be difficult to say whether the resistance of
a Member States is driven by the fact that the EU Commission
has proposed an inefficient rule for that state or by pressure from
incumbent national interests which will lose out if the efficient
rule is adopted.
6–11
Nevertheless, some parts of the proposed programme of
company law directives were enacted by the middle of the
1990s. This period saw the adoption of the First (safeguards for
third parties),71 Second (formation of public companies and the
maintenance and alteration of capital),72 Third (mergers of public
companies),73 Fourth (accounts),74 Sixth (division of public
companies),75 Seventh (group accounts),76 Eighth (audits),77
Eleventh (branches)78 and Twelfth (single-member companies)
Directives,79 though they were not adopted in that precise order.
Subsequently, there have been significant directives on
takeovers, cross-border mergers and shareholders’ rights
(though, significantly, the twenty-first century directives are no
longer allocated a number in an overall proposed programme of
directives). However, the Directives are not equally important
for the UK. Some of them did not significantly alter the existing
national law, because the EU rule reflected existing national law
or because Member States were given a range of options in
implementing the Directive and could choose to preserve the
status quo or because the subject-matter of the Directive was not
important in the UK.80 As far as the UK is concerned, the most
important Directives have been the First (which triggered a
review of the common law rules on ultra vires and agency as
they applied to companies)81; the Second (which led to a
tightening of the rules on dividend distributions and legal capital
generally)82; and the Fourth (which led to a re-thinking of the
relationship between the law and accountancy practice).83 Of
lesser impact were the Eighth on audits84 and the Eleventh on
branches.85 Apart from the Second, which froze the law on legal
capital in an unideal position, the impact of the Directives on UK
company law has been beneficial overall.
By contrast, some proposals were never adopted by the
Community legislature because it proved difficult to obtain the
necessary level of Member State support for the more
controversial proposed harmonisation measures. This was true,
in particular, of the proposed Fifth Directive which dealt with
two sensitive topics upon which Member States are pretty
equally split: should the board be a one-tier structure (as is the
practice in the UK) or a two-tier one, consisting of separate
supervisory and management boards, and, even more
controversial, should employee representation on the board
(whether one-tier or two-tier) be mandatory?86 The Fifth
Directive was never adopted. For many years, the issue of
mandatory employee representation also held up agreement on
the European Company (see below) and on a Directive on cross-
border mergers, and the issue was resolved there only by
abandoning any significant commitment to uniformity, or even
equivalence, of rules on employee representation. Instead, the
matter is regulated, mainly though not exclusively, according to
the model required by the law of the state from which the
merging company with the highest level of representation
comes.87 Equally controversial has been the draft Ninth Directive
on corporate groups, where the majority of states deal with
group problems through general mechanisms of company law,
whereas Germany has developed a separate regime for
addressing issues of minority shareholder and creditor protection
in group situations.
A new approach and subsidiarity
6–12
Such was the state of uncertainty into which the company law
harmonisation programme had fallen by the end of the twentieth
century that, at the end of 2001, the Commission appointed a
High Level Group of Experts with the brief of providing
“recommendations for a modern regulatory European company
law framework”. The HLG’s Final Report88 proposed a “distinct
shift” in the approach of the EU to company law. Instead of the
emphasis being, as hitherto, on the protection of members and
creditors, the focus in future should be on what the Group saw as
the “primary purpose” of company law: “to provide a legal
framework for those who wish to undertake business activities
efficiently, in a way they consider to be best suited to attain
success”.89 Although the proper protection of members and
creditors was an element of an efficient system of company law,
those protections themselves should be subject to a test of
efficiency. The Commission responded to the Group’s Report in
2003 by producing a company law Action Plan which largely
accepted the Group’s recommendations.90
What were the main features of the new approach? First, the
role of the EU in the area of company law became a more
modest, though still significant, one. So long as the EU’s task
was viewed as one of harmonising Member States’ company
laws so as to produce equivalent protections across the Member
States, no serious question could be raised about the central role
of the EU in this process and the whole of company law was in
principle open to EU regulation. By definition, harmonisation of
national systems (if it is to be achieved by legislative fiat) is
something which only EU law can guarantee and national laws
cannot.91 However, once the goal is put in terms of identifying
an efficient framework for company law, the issue of
subsidiarity92 is clearly raised. It is not obvious that the EU, in
principle, is better equipped to identify an efficient system of
company law than the Member States, especially as national
contexts differ substantially. An important implication of this
new approach therefore was that the EU should concentrate, as
far as new Directives were concerned, on those areas of
company law where it has an especial legislative advantage,
principally in relation to cross-border corporate issues.93 The
most significant Directives adopted in the company law area
since the adoption of the Action Plan have fitted this pattern: the
Cross-Border Mergers Directive (2005)94 and the Directive on
Shareholder Rights (2007).95 However, it should be noted, in
relation to the latter, that although the driving concern of the
Commission was the difficulties facing a shareholder in Member
State A wishing to exercise voting rights in a company
incorporated and listed in Member State B, the Directive
approaches this issue by conferring minimum rights on all
shareholders in companies whose shares are traded on a
regulated market. It is the limitation of the Directive to
companies with publicly traded shares which really indicates the
cross-border impetus of the Directive.
EU forms of incorporation
6–13
An alternative approach to harmonisation is for the EU itself to
provide the corporate vehicle for businesses to adopt rather than
for this to be a purely national competence. Unlike with the
harmonisation of national company laws, there is no specific
Treaty power for the EU to engage in this activity, and so
proposals had to be put forward under the “gap-filling” powers
in the Treaty, which require unanimous Member State consent.96
This necessarily made progress difficult. After many years the
EU achieved success with the creation of an optional form of EU
incorporation, the European Company (“SE”),97 designed
essentially for large companies and aimed at providing a
mechanism for the cross-border amalgamation of public
companies. The proposals had been beset by the same two
problems as afflicted the Fifth Directive proposal (above). These
problems were solved by giving the SE a choice between one-
tier and two-tier board structures and by making employee
representation mandatory for the SE only if one of the founding
companies was already subject to such requirements under its
national law. More generally, the law applicable to the SE
depends heavily on the company law of the state in which it is
registered, so that the degree of uniformity achieved is limited.
However, it may have helped in securing adoption that the SE,
unlike the Fifth Directive, did not require changes in national
law but made available to national companies, if they wished to
use it, a form of EU re-incorporation. Those supporting the SE
proposal hoped it would encourage cross-border mergers (the
founding companies are normally required to be in different
Member States), either at top company level or within corporate
groups. In fact, there is little evidence that the SE has been used
extensively for this purpose—or, indeed, extensively used at all
except in a few Member States.98 Nevertheless, it has clearly not
been an outright failure.99
The EU was emboldened by the adoption of the SE later to
propose a European Private Company (“SPE”) form of EU
incorporation. This, however, is in effect a disguised
harmonisation measure (it was to be available to individuals and
had only a weak cross-border requirement). It constituted in fact
a direct challenge to national regimes for private companies and
it ran into predictable opposition from some of the Member
States and was abandoned by the EU.100 The effect of this defeat
was to push the EU into producing a reduced but hybrid proposal
for Single Person Company (“SUP”—societas unius personae).
This is based on art.50 TFEU, where only a qualified majority
vote of the Member States is required, and indeed it is formally
an addition to the Twelfth Directive mentioned above,101 but it
requires Member States in effect to introduce a new form of
incorporation into their national laws and to give that form of
incorporation a common EU name (the “SUP”).102
The single financial market and company law
6–14
An even more important conclusion which was drawn from
taking subsidiarity seriously was that the creation of a single
financial market in Europe was a more appropriate area for EU
activity than a harmonised company law. The integration of
national capital markets was seen as a crucial aspect of the
construction of the Single Market, more so than company law
harmonisation, which was, so to speak, the price for freedom of
establishment (also an essential feature of the Single Market)
rather than a direct contributor to the Single Market. One
consequence of the focus on securities law was to favour the
adoption of some Directives which had been regarded previously
as examples of the company law harmonisation process—the
line between company and securities law being inexact. Thus, a
Directive on takeover bids103 was adopted in 2004, which had
originally been proposed as the Thirteenth Directive in the
company law series, but it eventually emerged without that
formal designation. Equally, rules on disclosure of financial
information by companies, a traditional area of company law
when viewed through the lens of shareholder protection, could
be re-packaged in a securities market context and presented as
investor protection measures.
However, the focus of the EU on the single capital market did
not just operate as a way of taking forward what might be
regarded as “really” company law initiatives. Most financial
market measures at EU level were aimed mainly at companies in
their capacity as fund raisers on public markets. Clear examples
were the Directives dealing with initial process of raising capital
through public offers and the admission of securities to trading
on public markets; subsequent disclosure to the market by
issuers and, to some extent, their shareholders; and ensuring the
non-distorted functioning of securities and other markets. The
first two sets of Directives are discussed in more detail in Chs 25
and 26, below, and the third in Ch.30. All that need be noted
here is that the first area (public offers and admission to trading)
became a focus of EU action as long ago as the 1970s, so that for
some time the company law and securities law programmes of
the EU proceeded in parallel. However, a major change of gear
occurred with the adoption in 1999 of a Financial Services
Action Plan (“FSAP”),104 which led to a significant level of
legislative activity in the succeeding years and to the production,
in particular, of Directives on prospectuses,105 on disclosure by
issuers (the Transparency Directive),106 and on market
manipulation (the Market Abuse Directive).107 Not surprisingly,
after the financial crisis of 2007 onwards, an intensification of
regulation in this area occurred. A number of the earlier
Directives were re-cast in a stronger form. In addition, in many
cases the new EU instruments emerged as Regulations rather
than Directives, since the available legal base for financial
market legislation (art.114 TFEU) permitted the EU to adopt
“measures” (not just Directives) “for the approximation of the
provisions laid down…in Member States which have as their
object the establishment and functioning of the internal market”.
The FSAP was accompanied by a further innovation in
legislative procedure at EU level, known as the “Lamfalussy”
procedure for the regulation of European securities markets.108
Under this approach the EU Directive or Regulation will
sometimes contain only the principles of the legislation and the
detail is laid down subsequently by the Commission, after
consultation with (now) the European Securities Markets
Authority, but without the need to go through the full EU
legislative process.109 The Commission has two broad types of
secondary legislative powers: a narrower power relating to
“technical standards” and a broader power relating to “delegated
acts”.110 In both cases power to issue secondary legislation must
be specifically conferred on the Commission by the parent
Directive or Regulation. Where the Commission acts, the parent
Directives and Regulations have to be read along with various
implementing instruments (Directives or Regulations) issued by
the Commission, which constitute a very significant part of the
legislative process.
Corporate governance
6–15
A further implication of the new approach recommended by the
High Level Group was that EU law-making, where this was
required, should be less reliant on detailed Directives of the
traditional type and make more use of Recommendations111 and
of instruments which imposed disclosure requirements rather
than substantive rules.112 This approach was initially particularly
apparent in the sensitive area of corporate governance. Thus, the
topics of board composition113 and directors’ remuneration114
have been dealt with at EU level in this way—indeed through
Commission rather than EU recommendations—with the
recommendations again confined to publicly traded companies.
Further, the EU rules on corporate governance codes take the
form of a comply or explain obligation (as indeed is typical of
national corporate governance codes) but with the content of the
code being determined, not by the EU, but by national-level
bodies.115 However, nothing is stable in the battle over law-
making between central and national levels. At the time of
writing agreement is likely at EU level on an expansion of the
Shareholder Rights Directive,116 which will substantially extend
the mandatory EU rules in the area of corporate governance, so
that they are as much concerned with constraining shareholder
behaviour as giving shareholders’ rights.
Reform of the existing directives
6–16
Some minor steps have also been taken to address the point
about the “stickiness” of EU legislation. In fact, the Commission
moved on this front ahead of the High Level Group’s Report. It
adopted in 1996 the Simpler Legislation for the Single Market
(“SLIM”) initiative. This was a general initiative, not confined to
company law, but several of the initial company law directives
have been amended through the SLIM process, albeit with only
modest results.117 In 2015 the Commission proposed to “codify”
in a single document the core company law Directives on the
basis that this would make access to them easier.118
CORPORATE MOBILITY
6–17
Corporate mobility can mean a number of things, perhaps most
obviously the question of what constraints exist on a company’s
freedom to move its head office from one jurisdiction to another,
something it may want to do in order to obtain the benefit of a
more favourable tax regime. However, for the purposes of this
chapter corporate mobility refers to the constraints on the
freedom of a company to choose the jurisdictional location of its
registered office and, having made an initial choice, to move it
to another legal jurisdiction, without at the same time having to
locate its head office or any other aspect of its operations in the
jurisdiction of registration or to move them on a subsequent
change of jurisdiction. This is a significant question because,
under the British conflicts of law rules and those of most other
jurisdictions, the company law applicable to a company is
determined by the jurisdictional location of its registered office.
If a company can freely choose its initial jurisdiction for
incorporation and subsequently alter it, it is in a position to
choose and subsequently alter the company law to which it is
subject. However, that freedom will be constrained if its exercise
imposes requirements on the location of its operational activities.
If we assume that entrepreneurs are free to choose and
subsequently alter the law applicable to their company, then the
scene is set, potentially, for regulatory competition among states
as they seek to offer the law which is most attractive to
companies and for regulatory arbitrage by companies as they
move to the jurisdiction which offers the law which they favour.
Corporate mobility does not in itself ensure regulatory
competition by states and regulatory arbitrage by companies.
Regulatory competition also requires that states conceive it to be
in their interests to attract incorporations and regulatory arbitrage
requires that companies perceive that the advantages of choosing
the most favourable law outweigh any potential disadvantages.
Without corporate mobility, however, regulatory competition
will be weakened.
Nor does it follow that the result of competition would be that
companies (or companies of a particular type) incorporate
overwhelmingly in a particular state. This is certainly what has
happened in the US where regulatory competition has led a large
proportion of publicly traded companies to incorporate in the
state of Delaware. It might be, instead, that states all bring their
company laws in line with the model which companies prefer (in
order not to lose incorporations) so that what competition
produces is not migration of companies but convergence of
states’ company laws. In this perspective, the power to transfer
the registered office would put some pressure on those
responsible for company law in a particular jurisdiction to ensure
that it remained attractive to businesses. The CLR thought this
was the correct approach in principle: “In general, it is desirable
that businesses should remain in Great Britain because it is
attractive for them to do so, and not because company law in
some sense locks them in”.119 If Member States reacted in this
way to competition, then the result might be characterised as
harmonisation of company laws “from the bottom up” rather
than “from the top down”, as under the EU’s original
programme of company law Directives, discussed in para.6–9.
Alternatively, competition might lead not to harmonisation on a
single model but to a form of “specialisation” in which different
Member States offer somewhat different corporate laws, each
adapted to the dominant form of business organisation to be
found in their jurisdiction. Whatever the precise result, it would
be the operation of competitive pressures rather than legislative
fiat which determined the nature and extent of the harmonisation
process.120
As we shall see below, whilst corporate mobility has long
been freely available in the US, in the EU that is not (or not yet)
fully the case. Some jurisdictions (such as the UK ones) have
long made the choice of company law on initial incorporation
available and as a result of decisions of the Court of Justice of
the European Union (“CJEU”), interpreting the Treaty
provisions on freedom of establishment, this principle now
applies throughout the EU. Freedom subsequently to alter the
applicable company law by moving the registered office,
however, is much less securely available—even for UK-
incorporated companies or foreign-incorporated companies
which wish to move into a British jurisdiction. We begin with a
brief discussion of the purely domestic rules on corporate
mobility before moving onto the more challenging question of
how far they have been modified by EU law.
Domestic rules
6–18
As we have seen in para.6–2, British law recognises the
existence of companies validly formed under the law of a foreign
jurisdiction when they carry on business in the UK. This
principle is applied even if the company carries on no business
in its state of incorporation but operates entirely in the UK—and
it was always intended by its founders that it should do so. So,
the British rule of recognition of a foreign company is simply its
valid incorporation elsewhere (the “incorporation rule”). Thus, at
the point of initial incorporation of a company, the founders
have a free choice of the applicable company law. As far as
British law is concerned, they may choose any jurisdiction for
incorporation and then carry on business entirely in the UK. The
alternative recognition rule, used by some Member States of the
EU, is the “real seat” rule, which requires the registered office to
be in the same jurisdiction as the company’s headquarters (or
place of central management). Such a state would refuse to
incorporate a company whose central management is not present
in that state. Even more important, this state might well refuse to
recognise the existence of a company validly incorporated in
another jurisdiction under that jurisdiction’s rules, but carrying
out no or only insignificant activities there, thus putting its
contracts and property in jeopardy in the state where it operates.
If a company incorporated in a foreign jurisdiction, but
operating in the UK, wishes to move its registered office to
another foreign jurisdiction, that is a matter for the jurisdictions
involved. If the foreign jurisdictions allow this to happen, British
law will recognise the result. However, British law is directly
engaged if a company registered in one of the UK jurisdictions
wishes to move its registered office to a foreign jurisdiction—or
if a company registered in a foreign jurisdiction wishes to move
its registered office to the one of the UK jurisdictions. Curiously,
in contrast with its liberal stance at the point of incorporation,
British law provides no simple mechanism whereby a company
may make such a move, even as between the British
jurisdictions. When the founders apply to register a company in
the UK, they must state in which of the three UK jurisdictions its
registered office is to be situated: England and Wales, Scotland
or Northern Ireland.121 There is no simple mechanism provided
whereby the registered office can be changed subsequently from
the jurisdiction of incorporation to another.122 Thus, a company
which is formed with its registered office in England and Wales
cannot decide by resolution to transfer its registered office to
Scotland, still less to some other Member State of the EU or to a
state outside the EU.123 Nor will it accept an incoming company
on the basis of a simple resolution of its shareholders to move
the registered office to the UK.
6–19
However, it is possible to produce indirectly a transfer of
registered office into or out of the UK. The transferring company
might go into (solvent) liquidation in its current jurisdiction and
in that process transfer its assets to a company incorporated in
the new jurisdiction, but the tax consequences of such a way of
proceeding make that course of action unattractive. Within the
UK the company might use a scheme of arrangement to effect a
merger with another company located in the new jurisdiction.124
Or the transferring company might make use of the EU’s cross-
border merger Directive to move its registered office into or out
of the UK.125 But a simple transfer of the registered office is not
a technique which is made available. On the other hand, these
alternative mechanisms contain a reasonably high level of
protection for shareholders, creditors and perhaps other interests.
These protections are built into the scheme of arrangement and
cross-border merger mechanisms. When the liquidation
mechanism is used, the assets of the company are valued at the
time of transfer and that value is paid by the new company to the
former owner, thus protecting both existing shareholders and
existing creditors. The transferring company’s creditors are
protected because the transferring company will receive the
proceeds of the sale against which they can assert their claims,
and the liquidation gives the shareholders of the transferring
company an exit route from the company and some assurance
that the transferring company’s assets have been properly
valued.
However, it is difficult to believe that adequate protection for
members and creditors could not be provided through a set of
rules applying to a simple transfer of the registered office. The
Company Law Review proposed such a scheme for exit from a
UK jurisdiction,126 which was based on that laid down in the
European Company Statute.127 The SE is empowered to move its
registered office from one EU State to another (albeit provided it
moves its head office as well, which was not a feature of the
CLR’s proposals). Moreover, the CLR proposals envisaged the
possibility of transfer of the registered office outside the EU and
also within the UK (which is not a matter for EU regulation).
The basis of the proposal was that transfer in principle should be
permitted (i.e. the opposite of the present law) but subject to
adequate safeguards for shareholders and creditors. The main
elements of protection for members would be the requirement
that the board draw up a detailed proposal about the transfer, that
the proposal should require approval by special resolution of the
shareholders (thus requiring a three-quarters majority approval)
and that dissenting members should have the power to apply to
the court which might order such relief as it thought appropriate.
Thus, for shareholders, the protective techniques invoked were
disclosure, supermajority approval and court control. For the
protection of creditors, it was additionally proposed that the
directors would have to declare the company to be solvent and
able to pay its debts as they fell due for the 12 months after
emigration, the creditors would have the right to apply to the
court to challenge the proposal and the company would have to
accept service in the UK even after emigration in respect of
claims arising from commitments incurred before emigration.128
Transfer would have been permitted, on compliance with
these rules, to any EU or EEA Member State, but transfer to a
non-EU state would be dependent upon the Secretary of State
having approved that state for this purpose, the criteria for
approval being related mainly to levels of creditor protection,
especially for creditors resident outside the state. Finally, for
transfer within the UK a less detailed proposal would need to be
developed by the board and the right of dissenting shareholders
to apply to the court would be removed. The full range of
creditor protections, however, would apply since there are
significant differences in security and property law between the
three jurisdictions.129 However, the Government rejected the
CLR’s proposals for international migration, on grounds of
feared loss of tax revenues.130
EU law: initial incorporation
6–20
We now turn to the question of how far the above rules have
been modified by EU law. Corporate mobility is an area where
EU law has had a significant impact, but, unusually for company
law, law developed by the CJEU rather than the EU legislature
has been the driver of reform to date. The court has proceeded
mainly on the basis of its interpretation of the freedom of
establishment provisions of the Treaty. Article 49 TFEU
prohibits restrictions on the freedom of establishment of
nationals of one Member State in the territory of another
Member State and adds that such prohibition also applies “to
restrictions on the setting up of agencies, branches or
subsidiaries”.131 Just to make things absolutely clear, art.54
TFEU requires companies “formed in accordance with the law
of a Member State and having their registered office, central
administration or principal place of business within the
Community” to be treated in the same way as natural persons
who are nationals of a Member State. The EU has from time to
time mooted the adoption of a directive dealing with corporate
mobility and it may be that, after a period of not being interested
in the topic, it is about to return to the EU’s agenda.132 There is a
strong case for a Directive, since the CJEU has not been able to
resolve all the issues surrounding corporate mobility. To put it
briefly, the Court has established freedom for the founders to
choose the applicable corporate law at the point of incorporation
but has not yet established fully corporate mobility thereafter.
Since UK domestic law already provided choice of law at the
point of incorporation, the impact of the Court’s rulings to date
has been to benefit founders who wanted to operate in other
Member States of the EU through companies incorporated in one
of the UK jurisdictions where that other Member State applied
the “real seat” theory or in some way qualified its application of
the “incorporation” theory.
6–21
The first proposition which seems to have emerged from the
CJEU’s decisions is that a company validly established under the
law of Member State A must be recognised by Member State B,
even if B would not recognise the company as validly
established under its own rules. This is also the domestic UK
rule. As understood in the UK, its “incorporation rule” turns on
valid incorporation in another Member State but it does not seek
to evaluate the incorporation rules set by that state.133
Consequently, if B is a real seat state, the rules about the location
of operational activities would have to be respected for
incorporation to take place in B and, in consequence, for British
law to recognise the incorporation.
6–22
The starting point for the Court’s development of the law was its
decision in the Centros case.134 In Centros, the Court held that
Denmark had infringed a company’s freedom of establishment,
when that company was incorporated in England, but carried on
all its business in Denmark and the Danish authorities refused to
register its Danish operations as a branch. It was clear that the
British incorporation had been effected in order to avoid the
Danish minimum capital requirements. However, the Danish
position was perhaps weakened by the fact that the Danish
authorities admitted that the branch would have been registered,
if the company had carried on some business in the UK, even
though its main business was in Denmark, Denmark being an
incorporation rule state. This reduced the force of the argument
that the minimum capital rules were a necessary protection for
Danish creditors. More important was the decision in Inspire
Art,135 also involving an incorporation theory state, the
Netherlands. Dutch law thus had no difficulty about recognising
the existence of a company incorporated in another Member
State (again the UK) and so did not refuse to register its branch.
However, Dutch law did apply to “pseudo-foreign” companies
(i.e. those incorporated elsewhere but for the purpose of doing
business wholly in the Netherlands) certain rules of Dutch law,
notably its minimum capital rules. The CJEU held that creditor
protection did not justify the imposition of requirements
additional to those imposed by the state of incorporation:
creditors were sufficiently protected by the fact that the company
in question did not hold itself out as a Dutch company but as one
governed by English law.
6–23
These two decisions had a substantial impact in practice.
Entrepreneurs from other Member States, not intending to do
business in the UK, may choose to incorporate in the UK in
order to avoid minimum capital requirements and expensive
formation formalities in their home jurisdictions; and this
produced the expected response in the shape of other Member
States seeking to reduce or remove their minimum capital
requirements for private companies.136 This was a clear case of
corporate mobility leading to regulatory arbitrage by companies
to which the Member States affected responded by harmonising
their laws on or towards the British model, at least in the narrow
area of legal capital and, perhaps, formation procedures.
A particularly interesting aspect of the Inspire Art decision
was the implication that the Eleventh Directive on branches137
determined the maximum level of regulation a Member State
was permitted to impose on companies incorporated in other
Member States—subject, however, to one important exception.
Restrictions of freedom of establishment by national legislatures
are permitted, provided they meet the “Gebhard test”,138 that is,
they are non-discriminatory, pursue a legitimate objective in the
public interest, are appropriate to ensuring the attainment of that
objective and do not go beyond what is necessary to attain it.
This is the general formula used by the Court to determine the
extent to which Member States may constrain the fundamental
free movement provisions of the Treaty. The test, it can be seen,
sets out very general standards and it is not clear how much
freedom it gives to Member States to impose national rules on
pseudo-foreign companies. Would it be lawful, for example, for
the German legislature to require a pseudo-foreign company to
abide by its domestic rules on mandatory representation for
workers on the boards of large companies?
EU law: subsequent re-incorporation
6–24
The Court of Justice has not had to decide squarely a case
involving post-incorporation transfer of the registered seat alone.
All the litigation to date has involved companies which
transferred their headquarters or central administration to
another jurisdiction and either did not want to change the
applicable law or wished to change the applicable law at the
same time as moving the headquarters. Some transfer cases can
be disposed of under the proposition identified above about B
recognising valid incorporations in A. In Uberseering139 a
company transferred its centre of administration from an
incorporation theory state (in this case the Netherlands) to a real
seat theory state (in this case Germany). The German courts
refused to recognise the company’s legal personality and so it
could not sue to enforce its contractual rights in a German court.
The CJEU held that this was an infringement of the Dutch
company’s freedom of establishment. Since the company was
still validly incorporated under Dutch law, German law was
obliged to recognise its existence, even though the company did
not meet the standards for incorporation under German law.140
Although not a case about transfer of the registered office,
Uberseering does establish the proposition that, provided a
company acts in compliance with the rules of its state of
incorporation, it has a EU law, right to transfer its headquarters
to another state within the EU. For UK courts, the significance
of the proposition is limited, since in a UK jurisdiction transfer
of the headquarters would not cast doubt on the validity of the
incorporation in the UK. The importance of the proposition is
that the state receiving the headquarters must continue to
recognise the validity of the UK incorporation.141
However, it is unclear whether the first proposition relates
solely to compliance with company law rules of the state of
incorporation. UK company law places no obstacles in front of
transfer of the headquarters but what about tax law? An early
decision of the European Court suggested that the transferring
state had considerable freedom in this regard. In Daily Mail142 an
English-incorporated company wished to transfer its central
administration outside the UK, whilst keeping its registered
office in the UK, but was discouraged from doing so by a
swingeing domestic tax demand. The domestic restrictions were
upheld. Although some doubt on the validity of exit taxes under
the Treaty provisions on freedom of establishment was generated
in cases subsequent to Daily Mail,143 that decision has not been
overruled.
6–25
The second proposition which has emerged from the cases and
which does have significance for a company seek to transfer its
registered office is that the Member State’s incorporation rules,
whatever they may be, must be applied in an equal fashion to
domestic and foreign companies. However, implicit in this
proposition is acceptance that the state of current incorporation
remains in control of its rules for valid incorporation—subject to
any relevant EU Directives. In particular, if it is a real seat state,
the Treaty provisions on freedom of establishment do not require
it to abandon those rules. This illustrated by the decision in
Cartesio.144 Like Uberseering, this was a case where the
company transferred its headquarters (from Hungary to Italy)
and did not want to change its applicable law. Unlike
Uberseering, the question for the Court was the validity of the
company’s continued incorporation in the transferring state
(Hungary), not its recognition in the transferee state. Also, unlike
in Uberseering, the transfer of the headquarters out of Hungary
did affect the validity of its continued incorporation in Hungary,
whose officials refused to continue the company’s registration in
that state. The Court (Grand Chamber) upheld the Hungarian
decision, on the grounds that the determination of the factors
required for the validity or continued validity of incorporation in
a Member State was a matter for that state, not for EU law.145
However, the court did go out of its way to address the situation
which was not before it, i.e. where the company wishes to
transfer its registered office in order to change the applicable
law. Here, by contrast, the Courts approach was different. The
Cartesio facts were to be “distinguished from the situation where
a company governed by the law of one Member State moves to
another Member State with an attendant change as regards the
national law applicable, since in the latter situation the company
is converted into a form of company which is governed by the
law of the Member State to which it has moved”. Here the
Court’s view was that the national legislation of the transferor
state was not justified “by requiring the winding up or
liquidation of the company, in preventing that company from
converting itself into a company governed by the law of the
other Member State, to the extent that it is permitted under that
law to do so”.146
6–26
In Vale147 the situation arose which was in many ways the
converse of the situation in Cartesio. In Vale an Italian company
de-registered in Italy with a view to transferring both its
registered office and its business to Hungary, but the Hungarian
authorities refused to effect the transfer, on the grounds that the
domestic re-incorporation provisions did not apply to foreign-
incorporated companies. The Court held that this refusal was a
breach of arts 49 and 54 TFEU. The core of the reasoning was as
follows. Hungarian law did have provisions which allowed
domestic businesses to convert from one form of incorporation
to another (without loss of legal personality), just as UK law
allows provides for conversion from a private to a public
company and vice versa, for example. It appears that in this case
Vale proposed to re-incorporate in Hungary as the same type of
company as it had been in Italy. Nevertheless, the Court held
that the exclusion of a cross-border re-incorporation from the
domestic conversion provisions was in principle discrimination
against foreign companies. This meant that the national
authorities would have to adapt the domestic procedural rules to
deal with the situation of re-incorporation by a foreign company.
In particular, the Hungarian authorities would have to take
account of the documentation issued by the Italian authorities in
the course of the Italian de-registration proceedings. On the other
hand, there appears in the judgment to be no infringement of the
principle of national control of incorporation requirements. If the
Italian company had proposed not to transfer its headquarters to
Hungary and this was a requirement for incorporation in
Hungary (for all companies), the Hungarian authorities would
have been entitled to refuse registration.
On the other hand, these decisions can be said to have
implications for domestic law. The fact that the Court in Vale
required domestic re-incorporation provisions to be adapted for
use by companies incorporated in another Member State suggest
the UK should introduce some simple transferring in procedure.
Since the UK is an incorporation rule state, there would be no
need for the transferring-in company to move its operations to
the UK at the same time as it moved its registered office. Some
Member States, for example, Spain148 do permit a transfer in of
the registered office, but many, including the UK, do not.
Equally, the dictum in Cartesio suggests the UK should have
some simple procedure for transferring out the registered office.
EU law: alternative transfer mechanisms
6–27
There are other mechanisms available to a company which
wishes to change its applicable law. The obvious alternative
technique—though it is rather more costly—is to form a
subsidiary in the new jurisdiction and merge the existing
company into it. Unlike for the transfer of a registered office, EU
law does now provide a mechanism for a cross-border merger.149
This is potentially significant. For example, in the US the
standard mechanism for transferring incorporation to the state of
Delaware is the merger of the existing company into a Delaware
corporation. However, the crucial point to be made here is that
the company resulting from the merger (whether a new company
or an existing one) must be validly incorporated in the new
jurisdiction and the Directive, following the policy of the CJEU,
leaves criteria for valid incorporation to be determined by the
member states.150 Consequently, a real seat state may continue to
insist that, for valid incorporation in that state, the headquarters
of the resulting company be located in that state. This reduces
the attraction of the merger mechanism if what the company
seeks to achieve is a simple change in the applicable law—
unless it is prepared to incur the potentially substantial additional
costs of moving the company’s headquarters to the jurisdiction
of the resulting company. By contrast, the cross-border merger
directive does facilitate the choice by a company of the law of an
incorporation rule state.
A further mechanism which EU law makes available is the
European Company (“SE”).151 The companies which found an
SE may choose any Member State in which to incorporate the
new entity, whether or not any of the founding companies
operated in that jurisdiction.152 Furthermore, the SE does benefit
from a EU mechanism for the simple transfer of its registered
office to another Member State after formation.153 However, the
SE is currently required to have its headquarters in the same
jurisdiction as its registered office,154 thus reducing its
attractiveness as a mechanism for changing the applicable
company law alone. If this ceases to be the case, the state of
registration must take steps to require the SE either to move its
head office back to the state of registration or to move its
registered office to the State where its head office now is; failing
either of these things, the state of registration must have the SE
wound up.155 The SE Regulation required the Commission to
report on the functioning of the SE statute after five years of
operation and in particular on the appropriateness of maintaining
this requirement,156 but no reform resulted from the report.157
Even if this restriction were removed, the costs of establishing a
SE simply for the purposes of changing the applicable law might
deter significant use of this mechanism.
Finally, and most obviously, the EU might act to require all
Member States to amend their laws so as to provide to all
companies a simple mechanism for the transfer of their
registered office. Thus, the law of the state of current
incorporation would have to permit the transfer of the registered
office to transferee state and the law of the transferee state would
have to permit re-incorporation, in both cases without the
company in question being wound up, but subject to appropriate
safeguards for minority shareholders, creditors and employees.
But the EU appears reluctant to grapple with this issue.158
Conclusion
6–28
The changes in the rules governing corporate freedom to move
the registered office have produced regulatory competition at the
level of company formation. Whether providing an equivalent
level of corporate freedom at the stage of re-incorporation would
generate the same level of regulatory competition among states
and regulatory arbitrage by companies is much less clear. Even
if a convenient legal mechanism for transfer were provided,
would states compete for re-incorporations and would
companies wish to transfer their registered offices? The
particular revenue gains from reincorporation which the state of
Delaware obtains in the US are simply not available in the EU,
though there may be other incentives for states to attract re-
incorporations.159 As for the companies themselves, the
incentives for mature companies to change jurisdictions will be
very different from those operating at the time of initial
incorporation of small companies. They may not wish to litigate
their corporate law matters in a jurisdiction with which they are
not otherwise connected or, alternatively, have the courts of their
headquarters jurisdiction apply a foreign law with which those
courts may be unfamiliar.
However, it is not clear that there is a strong argument against
permitting freedom to transfer the registered office by way of re-
incorporation. On the contrary, if Member States, when
reforming corporate law, are influenced mainly by a desire to
provide efficient company law to their “own” companies rather
than to attract re-incorporations of foreign companies, then this
suggests that no element of “corporate dumping” is involved
when a company does decide to move to the law of another
Member State. Equally, if companies weigh all the relevant
factors before deciding to re-incorporate, this suggests that the
choice which is ultimately made will be the appropriate one.
6–29
The contrary argument to those put forward in favour of
regulatory competition, and which constitutes the basis of the
real seat theory, is that to allow a company to choose a
jurisdiction for incorporation, even though it carries on no
substantial economic activities in that state or perhaps even no
economic activities at all, weakens the power of the state where
those activities are carried on to impose mandatory rules on
companies for the benefit of members, creditors or employees. If
a company does not like the rules of the state where it has based
its operations, it will simply choose the law of another Member
State for its incorporation.160 What will then ensue is a “race to
the bottom” among the Member States of the EU as they
compete to provide company laws which companies find
attractive.
Although these fears are not fanciful, they can be exaggerated
and may even be misplaced. First, as a result of the EU’s initial
company law harmonisation programme (discussed above in this
chapter), there are minimum standards in place below which no
Member State’s company law can go. Secondly, and most
importantly, competition does not necessarily result in a
reduction of protection. In the case of financial markets,
competition among stock exchanges for investors’ funds has led
to a raising of standards, especially in areas such as insider
dealing, market abuse and corporate governance. The crucial
question is who decides on the distribution of the good (in this
case, the incorporation decision) for which the competition
exists. In the US, where incorporations are a matter for each
state, where the incorporation theory prevails and where a high
proportion of public companies choose to incorporate in
Delaware, even though their businesses may have no connection
with Delaware, the argument that this situation has produced a
race to the bottom seems to be based on the proposition that re-
incorporations are in practice the result of a board decision, so
that Delaware has a strong incentive to produce a corporate law
which is too favourable to management and which provides too
little protection for shareholders and creditors.161 One way of
addressing this problem is not to make the re-incorporation
decision a purely managerial one. It is relatively easy to build
into the re-incorporation decision a substantial role for
shareholders, creditors and employees, as the cross-border
mergers Directive does. Moreover, in the case of listed
companies, it is probably the rules and mechanisms of the
exchange which are more important for the protection of
shareholders than the provisions of company law as such.
CONCLUSION
6–30
British company law has traditionally adopted a welcoming
stance towards companies incorporated elsewhere. This is shown
both by the limited extent to which it applies the provisions of
the British Act to such companies and its acceptance of
incorporation as the connecting factor in its private international
law rules. However, it is much less open to transfers by British
companies of the registered office to other jurisdictions or the
simple transfer in of the registered office by companies already
incorporated in other jurisdictions (as opposed to their conduct
of business in the UK). However, to a substantial extent, it has
preferred the goals of maximising freedom of movement and
promoting a degree of competition among jurisdictions as
against ensuring that those dealing with foreign companies do so
on the basis of a framework of law with which they are familiar.
Within the EU these two objectives have been reconciled to
some degree through the programme for the harmonisation of
company laws, though that initiative never achieved all its
promoters wished and expected of it. However, free movement
and jurisdictional competition cannot be achieved by one state
alone, since the migrating company is dependent also on the
laws of the country to which or from which it moves. For this
reason, corporate migration is undoubtedly a proper subject for
the attention of the EU legislator, or failing that, of the Court of
Justice of the European Union.
1See Ch.1 for a discussion of the various forms of incorporation available in Great
Britain.
2 [1933] A.C. 289 at 297 HL.
3
In particular industries a company operating in the UK may be required to do so
through a British subsidiary. Thus, banks from (non-EU) countries with a poor record of
banking supervision were reported to have been required by the FSA (predecessor to the
FCA) to withdraw from the business of taking retail deposits in the UK, unless they
incorporated their branches as subsidiaries, which would be required to have their own
capital: Financial Times, 25 June 2002, p.2. However, such national requirements must
not infringe EU law on freedom of establishment. See Case C-221/89, Factortame
[1991] E.C.R. I-3905.
4
For example, where the contract is concluded over the telephone or the internet by
someone in the UK with a company established in another country.
5
See Ch.8, below. In the future the multinational parent might put all its European
operations (perhaps of a particular type) into an SE—see above, para.1–40—and the SE
might or might not be registered in the UK.
6
Before 2006 the even more quaint term “oversea” company was used.
7
2006 Act s.1044. This means that Channel Island and Isle of Man companies are
“overseas” companies as well.
8
See above, Ch.4.
9
See below, Ch.21.
10
Directive 89/666/EEC [1989] O.J. L395/36.
11
The situation seems to have arisen because the then Government was unwilling to
allocate parliamentary time for primary legislation on overseas companies (which would
have allowed for the integration of the two regimes) but decided instead to implement
the Eleventh Directive by secondary legislation under the European Communities Act
1972.
12 In this connection it is important to note that the Eleventh Directive applies, not only
to EU companies setting up branches in the UK, but to all foreign companies so doing.
Thus, its scope was parallel to that of the traditional domestic law.
13
Oversea Companies (1999) and Final Report I, paras 11.21–11.33.
14 Modernising Company Law, 2002, Cm 5553–1, para.6.17. The havering around the
implementation of this policy in the Act itself was described in the 8th edn of this book
at pp.122–123.
15 Overseas Companies Regulations 2009 (SI 2009/1801), as amended.
16 SI 2009/1801 regs 2, 3, 30 and 68.
17However, the trading disclosures requirements apply on an even broader basis: see
para.6–6.
18
[1986] 1 W.L.R. 180 at 184. See also [1990] B.C.L.C. 546.
19 South India Shipping Corp v Export-Import Bank of Korea [1985] 1 W.L.R. 585 CA;
Actiesselskabat Dampskib “Hercules” v Grand Trunk Pacific Railway Co [1912] 1 K.B.
222 CA. Registration in the UK of an establishment in order to carry on business
involves the creation of a place of business, even if business has not yet commenced at
the establishment: Teekay Tankers Ltd v STX Offshore & Shipping Co [2015] 2 B.C.L.C.
210. However, the business must be the business of the company, not of its agent or
subsidiary: Rakusens Ltd v Baser Ambalaj Plastik Sanayi Ticaret AS [2002] 1 B.C.L.C.
104 CA; Matchnet Plc v William Blair & Co LLC [2003] 2 B.C.L.C. 195.
20 This EU legislation is not otherwise dealt with here.
21 See, for example, Directive 94/19/EC on deposit guarantee schemes, art.1(5).
22 Case 33/78 Etablissements Somafer v Saar-Ferngas [1978] E.C.R. 2183.
23
In principle, British law accepts such an arrangement, though not all European
countries do: see paras 6–17 et seq., below.
24
However, in the Centros case (Case C-212/97 [1999] E.C.R. I-1459) the CJEU seems
to have treated as a branch, for the purposes of art.49 TFEU, the British company’s place
of business in Denmark, even though it carried on no business anywhere else, including
the UK, which was simply its place of incorporation. Putting the matter the other way
around, this might suggest that the British head-office of a company incorporated
elsewhere would also be a “branch” for the purposes of the Eleventh Directive.
25
2006 Act s.1046 and the Overseas Companies Regulations 2009 Pt 2. The information
about the company must include a certified copy of its constitution (reg.8(1)). The
residential addresses of directors or permanent representatives are subject to the same
protective provisions as in the case of UK-incorporate companies: Pt 4. Although the
disclosure obligation applies in principle each time the overseas company opens an
establishment in the UK (reg.4(2)), the company need not repeat the company-specific
information each time, but simply cross-refer to it (reg.5). This applies even though the
establishments are in different UK jurisdictions.
26
2009 Regs Pt 3.
27 2009 Regs regs 11 and 17.
28 2009 Regs reg.6.
29
cf. arts 2 and 8 of the Eleventh Directive. The theory, presumably, is that the more
extensive information about the company is available from the national registries of EU
Member States, under the provisions of the First Directive.
30 2006 Act ss.1056 and 1139(2)(a). In Teekay Tankers Ltd v STX Offshore & Shipping
Co [2015] 2 B.C.L.C. 210 the judge confirmed the traditional view that, despite the
apparently narrower wording of reg.7(1)(e), the service did not have to concern the
business of the establishment (as opposed to the business of the company more
generally). If there is no such person or if the registered person refuses to accept service,
then service can be effected at any place of business in the UK (s.1139(2)(b)).
31 2009 Regs reg.6(1)(e).
322009 Regs reg.7(1)(f). Part 4 of the regs applies provisions equivalent to those
operating in relation to domestic companies for the protection of directors’ residential
addresses from public disclosure. See para.14–23.
33
See para.9–20.
34 2006 Act s.1051 and 2009 Regs Pt 7.
35 2009 Regs regs 60–61 (and at the service address of every person authorised to accept
service on behalf of the company in respect of the branch).
36
2009 Regs reg.62.
37 2009 Regs reg.63.
38 2009 Regs reg.67.
39
2009 Regs reg.66. For a discussion of those civil consequences, see para.9–20.
40 2006 Act s.1049 and 2009 Regs Pt 5. Unlimited overseas companies are exempted (as
domestic ones are) from this obligation, and special rules (not considered here) apply to
credit or financial institutions (Pt 6).
41If the overseas company is incorporated in an EEA state, it falls within this category
even if it is exempted by its parent law from the requirements to have its accounts
audited or to deliver them (reg.31(1)(b)). Such exemptions are controlled by the relevant
EU law, which is discussed in Ch.21.
42
The most recent accounting documents have to be included with the initial return to
the Registrar (reg.9(1),(2)). Thereafter, Pt 5 applies (reg.32(5)). The accounts delivered
to the Registrar must identify the legislation under which the accounts have been
prepared, which GAAP has been used, if any; and whether they have been audited and,
if so, according to which Generally Accepted Auditing Standards (reg.33).
43
2009 Regs reg.31(2). The auditors’ report is not required if the company is exempted
from audit.
44
2009 Regs reg.34.
45
2009 Regs Pt 5 Ch.3. See Ch.21 below. This is a considerable improvement on the
previous law which applied to overseas companies in such cases a modification of an
out-dated set of accounting rules based on the 1948 Act.
46
2006 Act s.395, as applied to overseas companies by reg.38. This assumes, of course,
that the parent law does not require preparation, audit and filing of the accounts of the
overseas company, in which case it will fall within the first category of companies.
47
2006 Act s.1058 and reg.77—transfer of an establishment from one jurisdiction of the
UK to another counts as the closure of one establishment and the opening of another.
48
2006 Act s.1053(2) and 2009 Regs Pt 8.
49 2006 Act s.1103(1).
502006 Act s.1105 and the Registrar of Companies and Applications for Striking Off
Regulations 2009 reg.7.
51
2006 Act s.1045 and the Overseas Companies (Execution of Documents and
Registration of Documents) Regulation 2009/1917 Pt 2
52 The rules on company charges created by overseas companies (s.1052) are also
regulatory and are considered in paras 32–28 et seq. They were reduced in scope in
2011.
532006 Act ss.1047(1),(2) and 1048—and it may alter its alternative name and toggle
between its corporate and alternative names.
54 See paras 4–13 et seq.
55 2006 Act s.1047(4),(5)—and to any alteration of the registered name.
56
2006 Act s.1047(3),(5). These controls are set out in s.57 and regulations made
thereunder.
57 Case C-167/01 Kamer van Koophandel en Fabrieken voor Amsterdam v Inspire Art
Ltd [2003] E.C.R. I-10155, where the ECJ struck down Dutch “pseudo-foreign
company” requirements applied to an overseas (in fact, British) company which went
beyond the Eleventh Directive. However, the Court recognised the possibility of
justification which, one would have thought, would have been applicable in principle to
the domestic name requirements, on the grounds of third-party protection, not involving
a disproportionate cost to the company. However, this conclusion cannot be firmly
arrived at without knowing the nature and extent of the name controls applied in the
Member State of incorporation. The approach of the Act simply side-steps these
difficulties.
58 See below, para.9–16.
59 IA 1986 ss.216(8) and 217(6).
60
IA 1986 s.220 (“any company”, except, of course, those incorporated under the
British companies legislation). See Re Paramount Airways Ltd [1993] Ch. 223 at 240
CA. Voluntary winding-up of an unregistered company, however, is not permitted:
s.221(4).
61
Stocznia Gdanska SA v Latreefers Inc (No.2) [2001] 2 B.C.L.C. 116 CA. However,
the company must have some connection with Great Britain and there must be some
good reason for winding it up here.
62
See previous note.
63
See Stocznia Gdanska SA v Latreefers Inc (No.2) [2001] 2 B.C.L.C. 116 CA; and IA
1986 ss.213 and 214. See also Ch.9, below. It seems likely that the application of ss.213
and 214 to EU companies does not infringe the Treaty provisions relating to freedom of
establishment. See Case C-594/14, Kornhaas v Dithmar [2016] B.C.C. 116 and below
fn.135.
64
In the case of insolvent companies with the centre of their main interests in another
EU Member State, Council Regulation (EU) 2015/848 on insolvency proceedings
([2015] O.J. L141/19) favours the opening of insolvency proceedings in that other
Member State.
65 See Ch.10.
66 IA 1986 s.22(2). See also Re Seagull Manufacturing Co Ltd (No.2) [1994] 1 B.C.L.C.
273—Act applicable to foreigners outside the jurisdiction and to conduct which occurred
outside the jurisdiction, though presumably only in relation to a company falling within
the Act. In the case of undischarged bankrupts the connecting factor is instead whether
the company has an established place of business in Great Britain.
67 See J. Wouters, “European Company Law: Quo Vadis?” (2000) 37 C.M.L.R. 257 at
269; and G. Wolff, “The Commission’s Programme for Company Law Harmonisation”
in M. Andenas and S. Kenyon-Slade (eds), EC Financial Market Regulation and
Company Law (London, 1993), p.22. This position was adopted in particular by France.
68 Under the “ordinary” legislative procedure of the EU: art.294 TFEU.
69 Directives are binding on the Member States as to the principles to be embodied in
national legislation but give the states some flexibility in the transposition of the
Directive into national law: art.288 TFEU. Article 50 does not provide for the adoption
of Regulations, which are directly applicable in the Member States.
70 This includes creditors and, probably, employees. Basing the Directive on employee
involvement in the SE (see above, para.1–40) on what is now art.50 was controversial
and it was eventually adopted on the basis of what is now art.352 TFEU, which requires
unanimity. However, the controversy was as much about whether the SE rules could be
regarded as a harmonising measure as about the subject-matter of the Directive.
71
Council Directive 68/151 [1968] O.J. 68.
72 Council Directive 77/91 [1977] O.J. L26/1.
73 Council Directive 78/855 [1978] O.J. L295/36.
74 Council Directive 78/660 [1978] O.J. L222/11.
75 Council Directive 82/891 [1982] O.J. L378/47.
76
Council Directive 83/349 [1983] O.J. L193/1.
77
Council Directive 84/253 [1984] O.J. L126/20.
78
Council Directive 89/666 [1989] O.J. L395/36.
79
Council Directive 89/667 [1989] O.J. L395/40.
80
For similar reasons, the overall significance of the EU company law directives has
been questioned: L. Enriques, “EC Company Law Directives and Regulations: How
Trivial Are They?” (2006) 27 University of Pennsylvania Journal of International
Economic Law 1.
81
See para.7–29, below.
82
See Chs 11–13, below.
83
See Ch.21, below. The Seventh on group accounts was less important since domestic
law already recognised the principle of group accounting.
84See Ch.22, below, but the Eighth was revised in 2006 (Directive 2006/43/EC [2006]
O.J. L157/87) and the second version was more significant.
85
See para.6–2, above.
86 See Ch.14, below.
87 See paras 14–67 and 29–20, below.
88Final Report of the High Level Group of Company Law Experts on a Modern
Regulatory Framework of Company Law in Europe, Brussels, 4 November 2002.
89
Final Report, Ch.II.1.
90Communication from the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament,
COM(2003) 284, 21 May 2003.
91
On harmonisation “from the bottom up” see below para.6–25.
92 Article 5 TFEU. Where both the EU and the Member States have competence, the EU
should take action “only if and insofar as the objectives of the proposed action cannot be
sufficiently achieved by the Member States and can therefore, by reason of the scale or
effects of the proposed action, be better achieved by the Community”.
93 See above, fn.90, Ch.II.1.
94 Directive 2005/56/EC [2005] O.J. L310/1. See Ch.29, below.
95 Directive 2007/36/EC [2007] O.J. L184/17. See Ch.21, below.
96Article 308, TFEU. In Case C-436/03 Parliament v Council of the European Union
[2006] E.C.R. I-3733 the CJEU confirmed that proposals for EU forms of incorporation
could not be brought forward under art.50 TFEU because they were not harmonisation
measures.
97Council Regulation (EC) No 2157/2001 on the Statute for a European Company
[2001] O.J. L294/1 and the accompanying Directive on employee involvement in the SE
(Council Directive 2001/86/EC [2001] O.J. L294/22). See para.1–40.
98H. Eidenmuller, A. Engert and L. Hornuf, “Incorporating under European Law: The
Societas Europaea as a Vehicle for Legal Arbitrage” (2009) 10 European Business
Organization Law Review 1.
99
As at the end of March 2015 there were 44 SEs registered in the UK, though that was
decline of about 20 over the end March 2014 and 2013 figures: Companies House,
Company Registration Activity in the United Kingdom 2014-2015, Table E3.
100
[2014] O.J. C154/03. See P. Davies, The European Private Company (SPE):
Uniformity, Flexibility, Competition and the Persistence of National Laws (Oxford
Legal Studies Research Paper No.11/2011; ECGI—Law Working Paper No.154/2010.
Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1622293 [Accessed 28 April 2016]).
101
See para.6–11, above.
102
At the time of writing the Directive had not been adopted.
103
Directive 2004/25/EC [2004] O.J. L142/12. See Ch.28, below.
104
Financial Services, Implementing the Framework for Financial Markets: Action
Plan, COM (1999) 232, 11 May 1999.
105 Directive 2003/71/EC [2003] O.J. L345/64.
106
Directive 2004/109/EC [2004] O.J. L390/38.
107
Directive 2003/6/EC [2003] O.J. L96/16.
108See the Final Report of the Committee of Wise Men on the Regulation of European
Securities Markets, Brussels, February 2001.
109
In EU jargon the subsequent procedure for law-making by the Commission is known
as “comitology”.
110 Articles 290 and 291 TFEU.
111
“Recommendations shall have no binding force”: art.288 TFEU.
112
See HLG, above, fn.88, Ch.II.2 and 3.
113 Commission Recommendation 2005/162/EC on the role of non-executive or
supervisory directors of listed companies and on committees of the (supervisory) board,
[2005] O.J. L52/51, supplemented by the recommendation of 2009 mentioned in the
following note.
114
Commission Recommendation 2004/913/EEC fostering an appropriate regime for
the remuneration of directors of listed companies [2004] O.J. L385/55, supplemented by
Commission Recommendation C(2009) 3177, 30 April 2009.
115
See art.46A of the Fourth Directive, inserted by Directive 2006/46/EC art.1(7).
116 Above fn.95.
117 See Directive 2003/58/EC [2003] O.J. L221/13 (amending the First Directive);
Directive 2006/68/EC [2006] O.J. L264/32 (amending the Second Directive); Directives
2007/63/EC [2007] O.J. L300/47 and Directive 2009/109/EC [2009] O.J. L259/14
(amending the Third and Sixth Directives); and Directive 2009/49/EC [2009] O.J.
L164/42 amending the Fourth and Seventh Directives. Others of the initial directives
have been substantially expanded over the years, notably the audit and accounts
directives, so that they now have a broader scope than when adopted.
118Proposal for a Directive relating to certain aspects of company law (codification)
(COM/2015/0616 final).
119 Completing, para.11.55.
120
For an extended analysis of the issues discussed in this paragraph see J. Armour,
“Who Should Make Corporate Law? EC Legislation versus Regulatory Competition”
(2005) 58 Current Legal Problems 369.
121
2006 Act s.9(2)(b).
122
The facility for companies whose registered office is in fact in Wales to alter the
statement so as to toggle between “Wales” and “England and Wales” does not involve a
change of legal jurisdiction. The change has an impact on the availability or otherwise
on the use of Welsh in the company’s official documents and in communications with
Companies House. See s.88.
123
Since British law adopts the incorporation theory, a UK company may freely move
its headquarters out of the UK without imperiling the validity of its incorporation in the
UK in the eyes of British law. This is useful for companies which wish to retain British
company law but does not address the issue of companies which wish to change the
applicable company law.
124 On schemes of arrangement see Ch.29.
125 Cross-border mergers are discussed below at para.6–27.
126
Completing, paras 11.54–11.70 and Final Report I, Ch.14.
127
Reg.2157/2001/EC art.8.
128 If the company, after emigration, maintained a place of business in the UK it would
become subject to the information provision rules for overseas companies (above); if
not, it would in any event have to file with Companies House contact details relating to
its new jurisdiction.
129 Immigration would also be permitted but there the regulatory burden would fall
mainly on the former state of registration. The British requirements would parallel those
for a domestic company which re-registers: Final Report I, para.14.12 and above, paras
4–20 et seq.
130
Modernising, pp.54–55.
131 The right of a company established in another Member State to set up an agency,
branch or subsidiary in Great Britain is normally referred to as the right of “secondary
establishment”. The right of a company to transfer its registered office to another
Member State is referred to as the right of “primary establishment” and is dealt with at
paras 6–22 et seq., below.
132The Commission has a long-standing proposal for a Fourteenth Directive in the
company law harmonisation series on the transfer of the registered office, on which
work has been intermittent. It ceased most recently in 2007 (Commission Staff Working
Document, Impact Assessment on the Directive on the cross-border transfer of
registered office, SEC (2007) 1707, 12 December 2007). However, in 2013 the
Commission again consulted on the topic.
133
See the quotation from Lord Wright, above para.6–2.
134 Case C-212/97 Centros Ltd v Erhverus-og Selkabsstyrelsen [1999] E.C.R. I-1459.
For an earlier and under-appreciated decision going in the same direction see Case 79/85
Segers v Bestuur Bedrijfsvereniging voor Bank-en Verzekeringswezen, Groothandel en
Vrije Beroepen [1986] E.C.R. 2375.
135
Kamer van Koophandel en Fabrieken voor Amsterdam v Inspire Art Ltd [2003]
E.C.R. I-10155. However, the state where the main centre of operations is located is free
to apply its insolvency law to a company registered elsewhere, since such provisions do
not infringe freedom of establishment: Case C-594/14, Kornhaas v Dithmar [2016]
B.C.C. 116.
136
See M. Becht, C. Mayer and H. Wagner, “Where Do Firms Incorporate?
Deregulation and the Costs of Entry” (2008) 14 Journal of Corporate Finance 241; W.
Bratton, J. McCahery and E. Vermeulen, “How Does Corporate Law Mobility Affect
Lawmaking? A Comparative Analysis” (2009) 57 American Journal of Comparative
Law 347.
137
Above, para.6–3.
138
Case C-55/94 Reinhard Gebhard v Consiglio dell’Ordine degli Avvocati e
Procuratori di Milano [1995] E.C.R. 1-4165.
139
Case C-208/00 Uberseering BV v Nordic Construction Company Baumanagement
GmbH [2002] E.C.R. I-9919.
140
“The requirement of reincorporation of the same company in Germany is tantamount
to outright negation of freedom of establishment” (at 81).
141 If the transferring state is a real seat state, then of course moving the headquarters to
another state does cast doubt on the validity of the company’s incorporation in the
transferring state and EU law does not seek to alter that result. See Cartesio, below.
142 Case C-81/87 Daily Mail and General Trust [1988] E.C.R. 5483.
143Case C-9/02 Hughes de Lasteyrie du Saillant v Ministère de l’Economie, des
Finances et de l’Industrie [2004] E.C.R. I-2409; Case C-196/04 Cadbury Schweppes Plc
v Commissioners of Inland Revenue [2006] E.C.R. I-4585.
144 Case C-210/06 Cartesio Oktató és Szolgáltató bt [2008] E.C.R. I-964.
145 “Thus a Member State has the power to define both the connecting factor required of
a company if it is to be regarded as incorporated under the law of that Member State and,
as such, capable of enjoying the right of establishment, and that required if the company
is to be able subsequently to maintain that status. That power includes the possibility for
that Member State not to permit a company governed by its law to retain that status if
the company intends to reorganise itself in another Member State by moving its seat to
the territory of the latter, thereby breaking the connecting factor required under the
national law of the Member State of incorporation” (at 110).
146 See at 111–112.
147 Case C-378/10 VALE Epitesi kft [2013] 1 W.L.R. 294.
148See art.94 of the Ley 3/2009 de Modificaciones estructurales de las sociedades
mercantiles (LME) and art.309 of the Reglamento del Registro Mercantil (RRM).
149 The UK transposing rules are discussed in Ch.29, below.
150
Directive 4.1(b) and Recital (3).
151 See para.6–13, above.
152 SE Reg art.7
153 SE Reg art.8. See para.6–19, above, for some of the details of this process.
154
SE Reg art.7.
155
SE Reg art.64, implemented by the Insolvency Act 1986 s.124B.
156
SE Reg art.69(a).
157
The Commission’s report might be said to favour the arguments for removing the
restriction, but the Commission did not positively recommend this course of action:
Report from the Commission … on the application of Council Regulation 2157/2001 on
the Statute for a European Company (SE), SEC(2010) 1391, 17 November 2010, 4.2.
158
See fn.132, above.
159
J. Armour, “Who Should Make Corporate Law? EC Legislation versus Regulatory
Competition” (2005) 58 Current Legal Problems 369. Whilst not disputing that the
revenue-raising incentives operating on the state of Delaware have no counterpart in the
case of the UK, he sees the incentive as located with the “magic circle” law firms based
in London, which would pressurise the government to provide laws which encourage re-
incorporations.
160 Of course, this is an existing risk for incorporation theory states whose company law
contains some feature which incorporators do not like and which some other available
jurisdiction does not insist on. See the Kamer van Koophandel en Fabrieken voor
Amsterdam v Inspire Art Ltd [2003] E.C.R. I-10155. Real seat theory states seek to
protect themselves against competitive pressures through a private international law rule,
whereas incorporation theory states will have to use some other technique to address the
threat, such as a “pseudo-foreign” company statute.
161It is much controverted whether the Delaware law maximises managerial freedom or
shareholder value. For a convenient short account of the, now very large, literature, see
R. Romano, The Foundations of Corporate Law (New York: Oxford University Press,
1993), pp.87–99.
PART 2
Introduction 7–1
Contractual Rights and Liabilities 7–4
Contracting through the board or the shareholders
collectively 7–5
Constructive notice and the rule in Turquand’s case 7–6
Statutory protection for third parties dealing with the
board 7–9
Contracting through agents 7–16
Agency principles 7–18
Establishing the ostensible authority of corporate
agents 7–20
Knowledge 7–24
Knowledge of the constitution as an aid to third
parties? 7–26
Ratification 7–27
Overall 7–28
The ultra vires doctrine and the objects clause 7–29
Tort and Crime 7–30
Tortious liability 7–31
Criminal liability 7–38
Litigation by the company 7–47
Conclusion 7–48
INTRODUCTION
7–1
One consequence of the abstract nature of a company as a legal
person is that inevitably decisions for, and actions by, it have to
be taken by natural persons. Decisions on its behalf may be
taken either (a) by its primary decision-making bodies (the board
of directors or the members collectively); or (b) by officers
(including individual directors), agents or employees of the
company. Acts done on its behalf will perforce be by (b). Similar
problems of attribution arise where the question is simply
whether the company “knew” about a certain fact or situation.
The question is whether the decision taken, act done or
knowledge held by the natural persons can properly be attributed
to the company. There clearly needs to be some linkage between
the natural persons in question and the company for the
company’s legal position to be regarded as having been altered.
Much of this chapter is about identifying the linkages that the
law has accepted and those it has rejected. Those connections are
clearly easier to identify where the board or shareholders as a
body have purported to act as the company, but corporate life
would be difficult or inappropriately regulated if the company’s
legal position could be affected only by actions of the board or
the shareholders collectively. On the one hand, a large company
would find contracting a cumbersome activity if all contracts,
even relatively minor ones, had to be approved by the board or
the shareholders collectively. On the other, it would be
surprising if a company could escape all tortious or criminal
liability where the wrongful act was authorised or committed by
a senior manager who was neither a director nor a shareholder.
In this chapter we are concerned with the answers to these
questions primarily in two contexts. The first is where the
company purports to enter into a contract with an outside third
party. If a company could not acquire and enforce contractual
rights and subject itself effectively to contractual duties, it would
find the carrying on of its business a very difficult matter. This is
obviously true of companies with a commercial purpose, but the
statement is true of all companies which need to deal with third
parties. The company would find it difficult to plan its future in
the absence of enforceable contractual rights, and, in the absence
of contractual duties enforceable against the company,
counterparties would be unwilling to contract with companies or
would routinely require guarantees from individuals of the
company’s obligations. What is required is a simple and
straightforward set of rules whereby the company can contract
through the actions of individuals, for the benefit of both
companies and third parties.1 The law has developed two
principal approaches to providing those rules. Where the
company contracts through the decision-making bodies
established in its articles of association (board of directors,
shareholders collectively), the solution is provided by
organisational law and is straightforward. The company is bound
because its constitutionally established decision-making bodies
have committed it to the contract. Where, however, the contract
is entered into on the company’s behalf other than by these
bodies, some further set of rules is required. There was no need
to develop a company-specific set of overall rules to achieve this
goal. The common law of agency, applying to non-corporate as
well as corporate principals and their agents, furnished the bed-
rock structure. However, as we shall also see, agency and
organisational rules have had to be tweaked in order to deal with
some particular features of corporate structure and doctrine.
7–2
The second situation is where the individual acting on behalf of
the company commits a wrongful act. Is the company liable in
this situation? This question arises principally in the criminal
law and in tort, though it exists in other areas, such as
wrongdoing in equity. The company may seem to have an
obvious interest in not being liable for the wrongdoing of those
connected with it. However, on a more sophisticated view it is
doubtful whether this is true. If companies, some of which are
powerful economic actors and all of which contribute to the
functioning of the economy, are seen to be free of liability for
the wrongful acts of those acting for them, then there is likely to
be increased political pressure for rules which reduce the
freedom of action of companies.2 From the point of view of the
efficient enforcement of the law, it can be argued, further, that
corporate liability gives those in control of the company a strong
incentive to constrain wrongful action on the part of those acting
on its behalf and so corporate liability contributes to law
enforcement—an argument that has appealed to the legislature in
recent years.
With wrongdoing it is again appropriate to hold the company
liable where the constitutional decision-making bodes of the
company have committed the wrong. Normally, this means the
company is liable because board or shareholders collectively
have authorised the wrongdoing, though in the case of a
company with only a single shareholder or director, that person
might actually commit the wrongful act. Beyond those bodies,
general doctrines of the common law again provided a second
basis for corporate liability, without the need to establish a
company-specific set of rules. In the law of tort, the doctrine of
vicarious liability is available to provide a framework of
corporate liability and proved to be capable of dealing with most
cases of corporate principals as it did with non-corporate ones.
In criminal law and some cases of non-criminal liability,
however, vicarious liability has proved controversial, at least in
relation to serious crimes, whether the person sought to be made
vicarious liable was a company or not. Here the law developed a
third layer of rules for those areas where vicarious liability did
not “work” in relation to companies.
This third layer of rules, like the first, is company-specific, in
the sense that they require consideration of how a particular
liability rule relates to the processes whereby decisions are taken
and implemented within companies. Sometimes, these rules
were made by the legislature, sometimes by the courts. Thus,
from the beginning of the twentieth century the courts developed
the notion of corporate “direct” liability, whereby the actions and
states of mind of the person connected with the company were
attributed to the company so as to make it a wrongdoer. Unlike
with vicarious liability, where only the liability of the connected
person was visited on the company and the company itself was
not a wrongdoer, with direct liability the company itself becomes
a wrongdoer.3 As we shall see below, the courts had difficulty in
establishing the boundaries of direct liability and it has only
recently begun to be developed in a satisfactory way. Legislative
interventions to create direct liability have been uncommon. The
principal example is the Corporate Manslaughter and Corporate
Homicide Act 2007, which imposes criminal liability for this
serious crime in circumstances where the notion of common law
direct liability proved inadequate.
7–3
Overall, therefore, the broad answer to this fundamental question
—how does a company decide, act or know?—is provided
through a tripartite hierarchy of rules. At the top are the rules
setting up the constitutional structure of the company and its
decision-making bodies, i.e. its articles of association; then
general doctrines of the common law such as agency and
vicarious liability; and at the bottom, where neither of these
approaches is available, statutory or common law rules
attributing liability specifically to companies in some cases. The
top and bottom layers in this tripartite division involve analysis
of issues peculiar to companies (or at least corporations). The
middle (and practically very important layer) consists of general
common law doctrines, which are not company-specific, though
their application to companies raises some difficulties which do
not arise where companies are not involved. Following the
terminology developed by Lord Hoffmann in Meridian Global
Funds Management Asia Ltd v Securities Commission4 the first
layer can be referred to as company law’s “primary rules of
attribution” because of their location in the constitution of the
company; the second as its “general rules of attribution”—
general because they apply also to principals who are not
companies but natural persons; and the third as its “special rules
of attribution” because their function is to provide for corporate
liability in situations where such liability is thought to be
appropriate but neither of the first two approaches to attribution
is capable of achieving that result. The residual and ill-defined
function of the third approach no doubt explains why definition
of its scope has proved so controversial, both in the courts and
the legislature.
CONTRACTUAL RIGHTS AND LIABILITIES
7–4
As noted above, decisions can be taken by or on behalf of a
company to enter into a contract or other transaction with a third
party in two ways, either by the decision-making bodies
established under the Companies Act by the company’s articles
of association (i.e. its board of directors or the shareholders
acting collectively) or by persons (who may include individual
directors) acting as its agents. Where the board or the
shareholders collectively act, they constitute the company, i.e.
they act as the company. They are not its agents. For the same
reason, they will not be personally liable on any resulting
contract, which will exist only between the third party and the
company. Where the company contracts through an agent, the
law of agency, as we shall see, produces a similar result in the
standard case, i.e. that the contract exists only between the third
party and the company. Despite the similarity of the results in
the two cases, we need to examine them separately because the
rules applicable in the two situations are not identical. We will
begin with corporate contracting through the directors or
shareholders collectively5 and then move on to contracting
through agents. Although there is a good deal of similarity in the
law applicable in the two situations, it is suggested that the
complexity of the applicable law can better be understood by
dividing the subject-matter up as proposed. It is also necessary to
set out the common law agency rules, partly because they
explain the form of the modern rules on contracting via the
board and partly because they still largely determine legal
outcomes where third parties contract other than through the
board or the shareholders collectively.
Contracting through the board or the shareholders
collectively
7–5
Where the articles confer management powers on the board or
the shareholders collectively and the board or shareholders, in
the exercise of those management powers, enter into contracts
with third parties, the conclusion that an effective contract
results is straightforward. If the law rejected this proposition,
corporate contracting would become an unwarrantably
complicated matter. Where the board or the shareholders
collectively contract, the question of how authority to contract
was conferred upon them is easily answered: it is to be found in
the company’s constitution, principally its articles. The difficulty
which has exercised both the courts and the legislature since the
early years of modern corporate law is how to deal with
situations where either board or shareholders go beyond the
powers conferred upon them by the articles. As we have seen in
Ch.3, it is rare for the board and the shareholders each to have
unrestricted and equivalent management powers—though it
seems that the constitutional arrangements of the company could
be set up in this way. Normally, the articles of association divide
up the management powers of the company between the
shareholders and the directors, giving the greater part to the
directors. Thus, it is possible that a third party will contract with
the company via the board in an area where the board cannot act
or where the board’s powers are restricted. The same issue may
also arise in relation to contracting through the shareholders
collectively. Third parties probably expect the shareholders’
powers under the articles to commit the company to contracts to
be limited, but, by contrast, they normally expect that the board
will have wide management powers. Consequently, they are
likely to be surprised if, after apparently contracting with the
company through the board, they are met with the argument that
the board did not have power to bind the company.6
In any event, an immediate question thus arises: is the contract
binding on the company if the board (or shareholders) act
outside the powers conferred upon them by the articles of
association? From the point of view of the shareholders as a
whole in the case of a board decision or the non-assenting
shareholders in the case of a shareholder decision to contract,
there is an argument that the constitutional arrangements of the
company should be paramount. Either the articles are followed
or the company should not be contractually committed (until
such time as the articles are altered). Overall, the development of
the law in recent times has been in the opposite direction, i.e.
towards preserving third parties’ reasonable expectations that the
body purporting to contract as the company had power to do so,
even if that power was restricted by the articles. Given the
primacy of the board in relation to the allocation of management
powers under the articles of most companies, this policy was
implemented in relation to board contracting, and it is upon
board contracting that we will concentrate below. The modern
view is thus away from the notion that restrictions in the
company’s articles on the contracting powers of the board are
something with which third parties are expected to familiarise
themselves.7 However, this is not the position from which
company law started out.
Constructive notice and the rule in Turquand’s case
7–6
As the law developed in the nineteenth century the answer to the
question whether the company was bound by a transaction
entered into by the board (or shareholders)8 outside their powers
as laid down in the articles was perceived to turn principally on
whether the third party knew (or ought to have known) that the
board were acting outside their authority. If the third party knew
the board had so acted, then the transaction was not binding on
the company unless the company chose to ratify it.9 Thus, the
security of the third party’s transaction depended on the will of
the company in such a case. The view was taken that the third
party, knowing of the board’s lack of authority, had no
legitimate claim to hold the company to the contract against the
company’s wishes.
This potentially defensible position was rendered completely
indefensible, however, by the doctrine of constructive notice,
which deprived the third party of the security of the transaction,
even though that party had no actual knowledge of the board’s
want of authority and no practical means of finding it out, other
than a detailed study of the company’s constitution. The rule
developed by the courts in the nineteenth century was that
anyone dealing with a company registered under the companies
legislation was deemed to have notice of its “public documents”,
a term which certainly included its articles, which are required to
be filed at Companies House.10 By developing this rule the
courts substantially enhanced the restrictive impact of provisions
in the articles limiting the board’s authority. By treating third
parties as knowing that which they would have known had they
read and understood the articles, the courts in many cases
deprived the third party of a plausible claim to a reliance interest
which the law should protect. The company might choose to
ratify the contract but was not bound to do so, so that the third
party’s contractual rights and duties rested on the company’s
decision.
7–7
However, the nineteenth century position was not quite as harsh
as the above paragraph suggests. It was modified by the so-
called “rule in Turquand’s case”11—sometimes referred to as the
“indoor management rule”. This rule had the effect that, in some
cases, the third party could assume that the directors had
authority to act, even if a fair reading of the articles might lead a
third party to make further enquiries. In Turquand12 itself
security for a loan had been given by a company through its
directors, but the articles provided that the directors could
borrow only such sums as were authorised by the shareholders in
general meeting and the requisite authority had not been given.
Jervis CJ said that a third party reading the company’s articles
would discover “not a prohibition on borrowing, but a
permission to do so under certain conditions. Finding that the
authority might have been made complete by a resolution, he
would have a right to infer the fact of a resolution authorising
that which on the face of the document appeared to be
legitimately done”. This was a benign interpretation of the
constructive notice doctrine, since the courts might have said
that the constructive notice of the articles put the third party on
notice to enquire whether the shareholders had in fact given the
requisite authority. It should be noted this benign removal of the
duty to make further enquiries must apply, a fortiori, to a third
party who has actually read the articles.
In Mohoney v East Holyford Mining Co,13 the Turquand
doctrine was approved and applied by the House of Lords in an
even more difficult case. Here, a bank had honoured the
company’s cheques, signed by two of three named directors,
after having received from the company’s secretary a copy of a
board resolution giving cheque-signing powers to the three
directors, to which their signatures had been appended.
Unfortunately, neither “secretary” nor “directors” had been
appointed but had simply acted as such. Nevertheless, the bank
successfully resisted an action for the repayment of the money.
Provided nothing appeared which was contrary to the articles,
the bank was entitled to assume that the apparent directors had
been properly appointed. This protection for third parties was
partially re-affirmed by statute which originally provided14 that
the acts of a director were valid “notwithstanding any defect that
may afterwards be discovered in his appointment or
qualification”. However, in Morris v Kanssen15 the House of
Lords held that the section applied only when there had been a
defective appointment and not where there has been “no
appointment” at all. In the light of this, s.161 of the 2006 Act
provides a somewhat expanded protection, applying not only in
the case of the subsequently discovered defect in the
appointment but also where the director is disqualified from
holding office, has ceased to hold office,16 is not entitled to vote
on the matter in question or (which was already part of the
statutory protection) the appointment was in breach of the
requirement that appointments of directors be voted on
individually.17 However, the section does not render valid the
acts of a person who acts as director without ever purportedly
having been appointed. In this situation the decision in Mahoney
continues to provide protection.18 The Kanssen case also
establishes that the protection of what is now s.161 does not
apply to a third party who actually knows of the facts giving rise
to the invalidity of the director’s appointment.19
7–8
Although immensely important in keeping the doctrine of
constructive notice within some sort of bounds, the indoor
management rule has significant limitations. First, it does not
protect the third party if the constitution simply provides that a
particular type of contract cannot be entered into by board at all.
To vary the facts of Turquand slightly, if the articles had
provided that loans above a certain amount could not be
contracted for by the directors at all (i.e. third parties must
contract with the shareholders in such cases), the rule would not
have protected a lender whose contract was approved by the
board alone, even if the restriction on the board’s powers was an
unusual one.20
Secondly, and perhaps more important, the Turquand rule
does not apply if the third party has been put on notice or on
enquiry as to the board’s lack of authority. Obviously, this
exception cannot arise simply out of the third party’s
constructive or even actual notice of the company’s constitution,
for that would be entirely to negate the indoor management rule.
Something else is required. In the leading case on this point, B.
Liggett (Liverpool) Ltd v Barclays Bank,21 where the third party
bank had actual knowledge of the articles, the question was
whether the bank was entitled to assume that the appointment of
a third director had been properly made. Such appointment
required the consent of both existing directors. The letter
informing the bank of the appointment was signed by only one
existing director (L). The other existing director (M) had for a
long time made it clear to the bank that it should not meet
cheques which were not signed by himself, in line with the
articles’ requirement for two signatory directors, because he
thought that L was improperly withdrawing money from the
company’s account. Nevertheless, after the “appointment” of the
third director by L, the bank met cheques which carried the
signatures of L and the purported third director. The prior
dealing between M and the bank as to the signing of company
cheques was the “something else” which put the bank on enquiry
to establish whether M had in fact consented to the appointment
of the third director; the bank was not entitled to assume such
consent.
Statutory protection for third parties dealing with
the board
7–9
Despite the qualifications to the constructive notice doctrine
which the indoor management rule had introduced, from the
point of view of third parties the resulting state of the law was
unattractive. No third party could safely refrain from reading and
analysing the company’s articles before contracting with it, for
fear of finding a ban or restriction on the board’s contracting
powers which could not be removed by some internal corporate
procedure. In modern times the policy view has been taken that
commerce will be promoted by relieving third parties from the
need to check the company’s constitutional documents before
engaging with the company’s board. The company is free to
limit the authority of the board, but the constitution is no longer
seen as an obviously appropriate way to communicate such
limitations to third parties. Other and more direct methods must
be employed. In line with this policy, the legislature moved to
enact statutory provisions which extended the protection
afforded to third parties by the indoor management rule. The
reforms were introduced in 1972,22 revised in 1989, and the
current version is s.40 of the 2006 Act.23
Subsection (1) of s.40 provides:
“(1) In favour of a person dealing with a company in good faith, the power of the
directors to bind the company, or authorise others to do so, shall be deemed to be
free of any limitations under the company’s constitution.”
9–1
From the beginnings of modern company law in the middle of
the nineteenth century, the legislature has been ready, in a small
number of cases, to remove the shield of limited liability and
impose responsibility for the company’s obligations on the
shareholders personally. More often it imposed the liability on
the directors of the company. Some of the examples which
survived into modern law were surprising, because the sanction
of personal liability seemed disproportionate to the importance
of the rules which the sanctions upheld. A good example was the
imposition of personal liability on the remaining shareholder
where the number of members was reduced below two, a
provision not repeated in the 2006 Act.1 This rule was the final
remnant of a legislative policy which attached significance to the
number of members of a company as a protection for those who
dealt with it. The Limited Liability Act 1855 applied only to
companies with at least 25 members, and as late as 1980 public
companies had to have at least seven members. But this policy
was effectively undermined by the decision in Salomon’s case2
in 1897, allowing nominee shareholders (e.g. those holding
shares as bare trustees for another person) to count towards the
required statutory number.
9–2
In fact, in modern law it is extremely difficult to find examples
of the companies legislation imposing personal liability on
shareholders in order to combat opportunistic behaviour
encouraged by the doctrine of limited liability. The target of the
anti-abuse legislation is rather those in charge of the company’s
central management, i.e. typically its directors. Directors,
responsive to shareholder interests, are much more likely to be in
a position to initiate such action on the company’s part than the
shareholders, because of the concentration of power and
authority in the board.3 Shareholders are not excluded from such
liability if they involve themselves in the central management of
the company (for example, as “shadow” directors) or in the
conduct which the law wishes to prohibit. But they are not liable
personally simply because they are shareholders.
PREMATURE TRADING
9–3
A public limited company, newly incorporated as such, must not
“do business or exercise any borrowing powers” until it has
obtained, from the Registrar of Companies, a certificate that it
has complied with the provisions of the Act relating to the
raising of the prescribed minimum share capital or until it has re-
registered as a private company.4 The link between this
provision and the doctrine of limited liability is that requiring a
company to hold assets to a certain value when it is formed is
arguably a protection for those whose claims are confined to the
assets of the company, though it is highly doubtful whether the
actual minimum capital rule found in the Companies Act
operates to confer any such protection.5 If the company enters
into any transaction in contravention of this provision, not only
are the company and its officers in default liable to fines,6 but if
the company fails to comply with its obligations in relation to
the transaction within 21 days of being called upon to do so, the
directors of the company are jointly and severally liable to
indemnify the counterparty in respect of any loss or damage
suffered by reason of the company’s failure to comply.7
Whether this is a true example of lifting the veil is
questionable; technically it does not make the directors liable for
the company’s debts but rather requires the directors to
indemnify creditors for any loss suffered as a result of the
company’s default in complying with the section. But the effect
is much the same. The section, however, is unlikely to be
invoked often since it is unusual for companies to be formed
initially as public ones. Usually, companies are formed as
private companies and later convert through re-registration to
public status. If this way of proceeding is adopted, however,
obtaining the required minimum share capital is made a pre-
condition to re-registration8 and so trading as a public company
without the authorised minimum is avoided in that way.
FRAUDULENT AND WRONGFUL TRADING
9–4
Of far greater practical importance are the provisions on
fraudulent trading. These provisions recognise that the separate
entity and limited liability doctrines generate an incentive for
company controllers to defraud creditors, knowing that the
creditors’ claims are limited to the company’s assets. The
fraudulent trading provisions aim to redress the balance. They
come in both a criminal9 and a civil liability form. Section 993
(constituting the single-section Pt 29 of the Act) creates a
specific, but widely defined, criminal offence of carrying on the
business of a company with intent to defraud the creditors10 of
the company or of any other person or for any other fraudulent
purpose. Every person knowingly party to the carrying on of the
business in this manner commits a criminal offence. So, here the
personal scope of the criminal liability is defined by reference to
being party to the fraud. Shareholders may be included in this
class but are not liable simply as shareholders. The civil liability
is imposed by ss.213 and 246ZA of the Insolvency Act 1986.11
These sections are analysed further below but, in essence, they
operate on the basis of the same test for liability as does the
criminal provision.
Abuse in the shape of hiding behind limited liability to effect
fraud is easy to identify as something the law should address, as
the long-standing provisions against fraudulent trading indicate.
More significant are the provisions on wrongful trading, added
initially in the 1980s. These seek to address the risk, when the
company is in the vicinity of insolvency, but has not yet entered
a formal insolvency procedure, that the directors will take
excessive risks with the business of the company, in the hope of
escaping from its financial troubles, but knowing that, if the
gamble is unsuccessful, limited liability will place most or all of
the additional losses on the creditors. If such action is taken
deliberately, it will probably fall within the fraudulent trading
provisions. The wrongful trading provisions of the Insolvency
Act give directors, contemplating this strategy—but without
fraud or at least provable fraud—an incentive to accord greater
consideration to the interests of the creditors. The creditors are
highly exposed to the downside risk of the strategy whilst the
benefits of it, if they occur, will accrue overwhelmingly to the
shareholders. This can been seen most clearly if, at the time the
strategy is adopted, the company’s assets are just enough to meet
its liabilities, but no more, so that, if the company then stopped
trading and were wound up, the creditors would be repaid but the
shareholders would receive nothing. If the directors continue
trading, the shareholders will be no worse off, but have a chance
(perhaps a small one) of being much better off, whilst the
creditors will be no better off but have a chance (perhaps a large
one) of being much worse off. Whilst continuing to trade is not
necessarily against the interests of the creditors, doing so in a
risky way in likely to be, whilst potentially benefitting
shareholders. The wrongful trading provisions attempt to re-set
the incentives of the directors by making them personally liable
for the increased liabilities of the company if the gamble fails
and the court adjudges the directors to have acted negligently.
Again, it is to be noted that the persons potentially made liable
are the controllers of the company (directors and shadow
directors) rather than its shareholders. The latter will fall within
the scope of the provisions only if they fall within the category
of a “shadow director” (see below). However, it is directors
responsive to the interests of the shareholders who are most
likely to fall foul of s.214.
The importance attached by the legislature to the provisions
on fraudulent and wrongful was demonstrated by their reform in
2015. Previously, they had applied only when the company was
in insolvent liquidation but they were extended to companies in
administration,12 a significant change since administration often
precedes, or even eliminates the need for, liquidation.13 The 2015
reforms also made it easier for liquidators and administrators to
obtain financing for litigation to enforce these liabilities, as is
discussed below.
Civil liability for fraudulent trading
9–5
The Insolvency Act mimics for the purposes of civil liability the
criteria laid down in s.993 of the Companies Act for criminal
liability, i.e. that the business of a company was carried on with
intent to defraud the creditors of the company or of any other
person or for any other fraudulent purpose. However, ss.213 and
246ZA require in addition that the company be in the course of
administration or winding up (which the criminal section does
not) before the liability can be enforced.14 Assuming this to be
the case, the court, on the application of the administrator or
liquidator, may declare the persons who were knowingly parties
to carrying on15 the business of the company in this way “liable
to make such contributions (if any) to the company’s assets as
the court thinks proper.”16 Since the company in winding up will
be in need of such a contribution only where its assets are
insufficient to meet its liabilities, this is in effect an indirect way
of making the persons in question liable for the company’s debts
(to at least some degree).17 As with criminal liability, the persons
liable are those party to carrying on the business of the company
in the fraudulent way; they need have no other connection with
the company, i.e. they do not need to be directors of or
shareholders in the company—though they often will be.18 It is
enough to establish liability that only one creditor was defrauded
and in a single transaction.19 However, in the case of a one-off
fraud there is a risk that the court will not be able to conclude
that the business of the company was carried on for fraudulent
purposes, in which case liability will not arise.20
Given the wide personal scope of the sections, banks and
parent companies (third parties) have at times felt inhibited from
providing finance to ailing companies, fearing that they may
thereby fall foul of these provisions as persons knowingly party
to the fraud. It is sometimes said that their fears are unfounded
so long as they play no active role in running the company with
fraudulent intent.21 However, the extent of the exposure of a
third party company to liability under the sections will depend in
part on what rule of attribution is used to determine the extent of
the knowledge the third party company possesses of the
activities within the fraudulently run company. In Re Bank of
Credit and Commerce International SA (No.15)22 the Court of
Appeal rejected the proposition that only the knowledge of the
board of the third party was to be attributed to it. Here, the court
attributed to the defendant company the knowledge of a senior
manager who had been given authority by the board to set the
terms of transactions with the company whose business was
being carried on fraudulently and to which fraud the manager
had turned a blind eye. Thus, as was already clear and as this
case illustrates, a third party can fall within the sections if it
participates, with knowledge,23 in the fraudulent activity of a
company, even though that party could not be said to have taken
a controlling role within the company.24 Overall, therefore, these
rules encourage third parties, whose dealings with a company
might assist the fraudulent running of that company’s business,
to have in place internal controls designed to identify at an early
stage and to deal with situations where relevant employees of the
third party have knowledge of the fraudulent activities. In this
way the third party may hope to avoid the risk that it will be
liable to contribute under the sections.25
As to whether those conducting business are doing so
fraudulently, it has been said that what has to be shown is
“actual dishonesty involving, according to current notions of fair
trading among commercial men, real moral blame”.26 That may
be inferred if “a company continues to carry on business and to
incur debts at a time when there is, to the knowledge of the
directors, no reasonable prospect of the creditors ever receiving
payment of those debts”,27 but it cannot be inferred merely
because they ought to have realised there was no prospect of
repayment. It was this need to prove subjective moral blame that
led the Jenkins Committee in 1962 vainly to recommend the
introduction of a remedy for “reckless trading”28 and the Cork
Committee, 20 years later,29 successfully to promote it under the
name of “wrongful trading”.
Wrongful trading
9–6
Sections 214 and 246ZB empower the court to make a
declaration similar to that under ss.213 and 246ZA where the
company has gone into insolvent administration or liquidation.
An insolvent is distinguished from a solvent procedure on a
balance-sheet test, i.e. were the assets of the company sufficient
to meet its liabilities and the costs of the procedure at the point
the company entered into it.30 The basis for imposing the
obligation to contribute is that the director (or shadow director)
knew, or ought to have concluded, at some point before the
administration or winding-up, that there was no reasonable
prospect that the company would avoid going into insolvent
administration or liquidation.31 A declaration will then be made
unless the court is satisfied that the person concerned thereafter
took every step with a view to minimising the potential loss to
the company’s creditors as he ought to have taken, on the
assumption that he knew there was no reasonable prospect of
avoiding insolvency.32 In judging what facts the director ought to
have known or ascertained, what conclusions the director should
have drawn and what steps should have been taken, the director
is to be assumed to be a reasonably diligent person having both
the general knowledge, skill and experience to be expected of a
person carrying out the director’s functions in relation to the
company33 and the general knowledge, skill and experience that
the director in fact has.34 This formulation heavily influenced the
general duty of care now imposed on directors by s.174 of the
Companies Act 200635. The wrongful trading provisions, s.174
of the 2006 Act and the director disqualification provisions
(discussed in the following chapter) constitute the three main
areas where sanctions are imposed on directors for negligent
discharge of their duties. In the case of ss.214/246ZB, however,
the beneficiaries of the duty to take care are the creditors rather
than the shareholders, whom s.174 of the 2006 Act protects.
Section 214 poses two questions which have to be answered,
both on an objective basis. Should the director have realised
there was no reasonable prospect of the company avoiding
insolvent liquidation and, once that stage has been reached, did
the director take all the steps he or she ought to have taken to
minimise the loss to the company’s creditors, especially, no
doubt, by seeking to have the company cease trading? Both these
judgments will depend heavily on the facts of particular cases:
what sort of company was involved, what were the functions
assigned to or discharged by the director in question, what
outside advice was taken and what was its content?36
Shadow directors
9–7
Section 214 applies to shadow directors as well as to directors,
i.e. a person, other than a professional adviser, in accordance
with whose directions or instructions the directors of a company
are accustomed to act.37 This considerably widens the class of
persons against whom a declaration can be made, though not as
widely as under s.213 which brings in any person who is party to
the fraudulent trading (see above). The shadow director
definition catches only the person who influences at least a
certain category of board decisions on a continuing basis.38 The
two potential defendants of greatest interest are, once again,
banks and parent companies. As far as the former are concerned,
the courts have so far taken a cautious line, initially on the
grounds that the definition of a shadow director required that the
board cede its management autonomy to the alleged shadow
director. This was not regarded as occurring as a result of the
bank taking steps to protect itself, provided the company
retained the power to decide whether to accept the restrictions
put forward by the bank, even though the company might be
thought to have no other practicable alternative.39
In relation to parent companies, such a degree of cession of
autonomy by the subsidiary may be more easily found, but much
will still depend upon how exactly intra-group relationships are
established. The degree of control exercised by parent
companies may vary from detailed day-to-day control to virtual
independence for the subsidiary’s board, with many variations in
between. It would seem that the establishment of business
guidelines within which the subsidiary has to operate would not
make the parent inevitably a shadow director of the subsidiary.40
However, the Court of Appeal has rejected the proposition that it
is necessary for the board to cast itself in a subservient role or
surrender its discretion in order for the alleged shadow director
to be found to be such, thus casting doubt on the “cessation of
autonomy” test and potentially broadening the scope of shadow
director liability.41 It is important to note that the shadow
director definition in s.251 of the Insolvency Act does not
exclude parent companies, in contrast to the exclusion in s.251
of the Companies Act which provides that a parent company is
not to be considered a shadow director “by reason only that the
directors of the subsidiary are accustomed to act in accordance
with [the parent’s] directions or instructions”. It would thus seem
that, so long as the subsidiary is a going concern, the parent
company may impose a common policy on the group companies
without being in danger of infringing their general duties in
relation to the subsidiary. Once insolvency threatens the
subsidiary, however, the interests of its creditors take priority
over the interests of the parent and the group policy.42 When
ss.214/246ZB are triggered, they will apply to the actions of the
boards of both the subsidiary and the parent company (provided
the latter falls within the definition of a shadow director).
The declaration
9–8
Section 215 contains certain procedural provisions common to
both fraudulent and wrongful trading. Those provisions are to
have effect notwithstanding that the person concerned may be
criminally liable.43 The court may direct that the liability of any
person against whom the declaration is made shall be a charge
on any debt due from the company to that person or on any
mortgage or charge in that person’s favour on assets of the
company. This enables the company to set off what it owes to
the director against what the director is declared liable to
contribute to the company, which may prove valuable in the
bankruptcy of the director.44 In addition, s.21545 provides that the
court may direct that the whole or any part of a debt, and interest
thereon, owed by the company to a person against whom a
declaration is made, shall be postponed to all other debts, and
interest thereon, owed by the company. Thus, even if, for
example, the court makes only a small contribution order, which
the director is able to meet, the director may suffer a further
financial loss by having his or her debts due from the company
subordinated to those of the company’s other creditors, a
potentially important provision since the company ex hypothesi
is insolvent.
The central question, however, is the amount of the
contribution, a matter with which s.215 does not deal. The
fraudulent and wrongful trading provisions simply say that the
amount of the contribution shall be “as the court thinks
proper”.46 It is now established that contribution orders in
relation to both wrongful and fraudulent trading are intended to
be compensatory in relation to the company.47 The outer
boundaries of the contribution are thus set by the amount by
which the company’s assets have been depleted by the director’s
conduct. Thus, the trading provisions will not replace the
Insolvency Act rules on preferences, which deal with the
situation where the company improperly pays one creditor ahead
of another. As far as the company is concerned, a preference is
balance-sheet neutral: assets are certainly paid out to the
preferred creditor but the company’s liabilities are reduced to the
same extent, so that overall the company is no worse off.
Preference rules are apt to deal with the improper distribution of
assets among creditors; trading rules with situations where the
creditors as a class are disadvantaged by the directors’ actions.
Within the parameter of the overall loss to the company, the
court has a discretion to fix the amount to be paid as it thinks
proper. The assessment is to be made against each defendant
individually rather than on some basis of collective
responsibility.48 Despite this method of calculating the upper
limit on the contribution, the contribution from the directors is to
the assets of the company generally and not for the particular
benefit of those who became creditors of the company during the
period of wrongful or fraudulent trading. Consequently, pre-
wrongful trading creditors may actually benefit from the
wrongful trading,49 a somewhat ironic result but one driven,
presumably, by a desire for simplicity.
Impact of the wrongful trading provisions
9–9
The wrongful trading provisions are capable of playing a central
role in re-orienting the duties of directors as the company’s
insolvency becomes overwhelmingly likely. However, the
drafters of the wrongful trading provisions were careful not to
specify the precise action directors are required to take to meet
its requirements. Instead, the provisions lay down a standard to
which the director must conform in order to avoid liability, i.e.
“to take every step with a view to minimising the potential loss
to the company’s creditors as (assuming him to have known that
there was no reasonable prospect that the company would avoid
going into insolvent liquidation or entering insolvent
administration) he ought to have taken”.50 A central question is
whether the section requires the directors, in all cases where
there is no reasonable prospect of avoiding insolvent liquidation,
to cause the company to cease trading and put the company into
an insolvency procedure. Certainly, one of the commonest forms
of wrongful trading is to keep the company’s business on foot
even after the accounts or other management information have
clearly revealed that the company is in a chronically loss-making
position.51 However, there are good reasons for not requiring this
response across the board. In the interests of both creditors
(higher recovery of their debts) and of shareholders and other
stakeholders (such as employees) it may well be better if the
company can be turned around or its business disposed of in
some other way, which an immediate cessation of trading might
jeopardise.
The courts can adjust the section to the needs of the “rescue
culture” either by postponing the point at which they conclude
the directors ought to have realised the company had no
reasonable prospect of avoiding insolvency or by taking a broad
view of the appropriate actions of the directors once that point is
reached. An example of the first approach can be seen in Re The
Rod Gunner Organisation Ltd,52 where the court refused to find
“no reasonable prospect” for a period of six months after the
company became unable to meet its debts as they fell due, on the
grounds that the directors reasonably thought an outside investor
was going to come in with substantial funding (though that
analysis no longer held once it became clear that the investor
would not live up to the directors’ expectations of him).
Similarly, in Re Continental Assurance Co of London Plc
(No.4),53 where a substantial insurance company had suffered
unexpected losses, the court refused to find “no reasonable
prospect” during a period of some six months in which the
directors commissioned a report as to the company’s solvency
and decided to continue trading on the basis of the report
received, until it later became clear that the company was in fact
insolvent. Park J was very aware of the dangers of judging the
directors’ conduct on the basis of hindsight, and he remarked
pithily in relation to the general issue that “ceasing to trade and
liquidating too soon can be stigmatised as the cowards’ way
out”. Once the point of “no reasonable prospect” is reached,
however, the section appears to shift the risk of continued
trading onto the directors. If the continued trading reduces the
company’s net deficiency, no contribution will be required of
them. But in the opposite case they will be exposed.54
9–10
However, any analysis of the impact of the wrongful trading
provisions also requires an assessment of the effectiveness of its
enforcement. In contrast to litigation under the disqualification
provisions discussed in the next chapter, where the public purse
pays for the cases and there has been a high level of activity,
litigation about wrongful trading seems to have been sparse and
certainly there are few reported cases. As we have seen, the Act
places the initiation of litigation in the hands of the liquidator or
administrator (“office holders”), who does not have access to
any public funds to support any litigation it is proposed to bring.
Assuming the insolvent company does have some realisable
assets, the office holder may contemplate using those to fund the
litigation in the hope of swelling the ultimate amount available
for distribution to the creditors. However, even if the office
holder can secure solicitors who will take the case on a
conditional fee basis—not always possible—the litigation is
likely to involve some costs (for example, for the insurance to
meet the other side’s costs if the litigation is unsuccessful), and
so the office holder is likely to be unwilling to risk the
company’s already inadequate assets on litigation unless there is
a very strong chance of success.55 The office holder might
conceivably seek funding for the litigation from a floating
charge holder, but there is little incentive for such a creditor to
provide funding, for the proceeds of fraudulent and wrongful
trading claims go to benefit the unsecured creditors, not the
holders of a floating charge.56
The obvious step for the office holder to take, faced with this
uncertainty, is either to sell the claim to a third party or to obtain
funding for the claim by assigning some part of the fruits of the
litigation to a third party. A third party whose business consists
of buying or funding such claims is in a position to take a more
adventurous view of which claims may be litigated, because it
spreads its risks across a number of such claims, unlike the
office holder who has only “one shot” on behalf of the unsecured
creditors of any particular company. However, until the reforms
of 2015 the office holder could not sell the wrongful trading
claim under the general power to dispose of the company’s
assets, because the right to claim under the section is vested in
the office holder personally, not in the company.57 The 2015
reforms sensibly cut through this difficulty by giving the office
holder an express statutory right to assign a wrongful or
fraudulent trading claim (or the proceeds of such an action).58
However, the rule that the proceeds of such an action are not the
property of the company is retained.59 This means that the
proceeds are not swept up by the holders of any floating charge
the company has issued, but rather remain available for the
benefit of the unsecured creditors.
COMMON LAW DUTIES IN RELATION TO CREDITORS
9–11
The wrongful trading reforms of the mid-1980s, discussed in the
previous section, create a statutory duty of care on the part of
directors towards creditors at the point when insolvency seems
unavoidable. Despite this statutory reform, the common law has
not entirely neglected the interests of creditors at this point in the
company’s life-cycle and we analyse that development in this
section. Although the statutory codification of the duties of
directors in s.172 of the Companies Act 200660 does not in terms
list creditors among those to whose interests the directors must
have regard when promoting the success of the company,
nevertheless it does recognise and preserve this common law
development. Section 172(3) provides that the duty the section
creates “has effect subject to any enactment or rule of law
requiring directors, in certain circumstances, to consider or act in
the interests of the creditors of the company”. This removes any
doubt that might otherwise have existed about whether the
wrongful trading rules had been in any way qualified or reduced
as a result of the enactment of s.172, but this provision also
preserves (“or rule of law”) the common law developments.61
9–12
Starting in Australia in the 1970s,62 the notion of a common law
duty upon directors to take account of the interests of creditors
as insolvency approaches has been widely accepted throughout
the common-law world. The principle was adopted by the Court
of Appeal in West Mercia Safetywear v Dodd.63 As with most
significant common-law developments in their relatively early
stages, there was and still remains considerable uncertainty
about the conceptual boundaries of this doctrine. There are still
uncertainties about when the duty bites, about its content, the
remedies available and, to a lesser extent, the mechanisms for
enforcing it. On the answer to these questions turns the broader
issue of what, if anything, the common law duty adds to the
statutory wrongful trading remedy.
9–13
Only the most imprecise indications have been given by the
courts as to when the duty is triggered, except that there appears
to be general acceptance that the duty can bite in advance of the
company being insolvent.64 In Brady v Brady, Nourse LJ said
that the interests of the company were really the interests of the
creditors when the company was “doubtfully solvent”,65 whilst
in Nicholson v Permakraft (NZ) Ltd66 the judge conceivably was
prepared to go a bit further by suggesting the duty was triggered
by “a course of action which would jeopardise solvency”. In any
event, while it is clear that the common law duty, like the
statutory one, may apply before the company is insolvent, it is
unclear whether the common law applies at a pre-insolvency
point which is earlier than under the statutory test of “no
reasonable prospect of avoiding insolvent liquidation or
administration”. This question is not made any easier to answer
by the fact that the statutory test itself carries a penumbra of
uncertainty (when does the reasonable prospect finally
disappear?).
9–14
Assuming the duty has been triggered, how does it require
directors to behave? There are some indications in the early
cases67 that the duty is akin to the duty of care under the statute.
It is a duty to protect the creditors from further harm rather than
a duty to promote the interests of the creditors in a more general
sense. For example, the directors of a financially troubled
company might adopt a course of action designed to advance the
interests of the shareholders, provided it did not increase the
riskiness of the creditors’ claims on the company.68 However,
the most recent cases treat the common law duty as a fiduciary
duty, by analogy with the core directors’ duty set out in
s.172(1).69 At first glance, this seems disadvantageous to
creditors since it is well established that this core duty is a
subjective one, i.e. the directors must act in what they consider
(not what a court would consider) to be the best way to further
creditor interests. By contrast, as we have seen, under the
statutory duty of care the minimum standard of care is set
objectively.70 Thus, the directors appear to have greater freedom
of action under the fiduciary approach. However, the contrast
may be more apparent than real, at least in the typical case.
These are cases where the court finds that the directors acted
without considering the creditors’ interests at all. The failure
itself may constitute a breach of duty or at least open the way for
the court to apply the objective test of whether a reasonable
director would have acted in the same way as the directors in the
instant case.71
Where directors do seek to fulfil their fiduciary duty to
creditors, there are uncertainties about what is required of them.
In some cases the interests of the creditors are described as
“paramount”, implying that creditor interests are to be the sole
concern of the directors, once the duty has been triggered.72
Other cases do not adopt this approach or even reject it,73
suggesting that directors may pursue the interests of the
shareholders as well as of the creditors once the duty is
triggered. Probably, the required action turns on the financial
condition of the company. Where the company is hopelessly
insolvent or the decision facing the directors, if taken a particular
way, will put the company into that position, only the creditors’
interests should be considered by the directors. If the company is
in financial difficulties of a less serious sort, there may be scope
for taking action to promote shareholder interests whilst still
protecting creditors.74 In this sense the creditors’ interests are
always “paramount” (they must always be protected) but,
depending on the company’s financial position, they may not
have to be the exclusive focus of directorial action.
This analysis may be particularly important when the duty is
triggered significantly in advance of insolvency, so that, whilst
the risk of future insolvency has increased substantially to the
detriment of the creditors, the shareholders still have some
equity in the business. Where the directors seek to keep the
company going rather than, as is typical in the decided cases,
extract assets from it, there is some scope for action which
advances both shareholder and creditor interests, provided the
duty is not one to maximise the welfare of the creditors. After
all, even from a purely creditor point of view, continued trading
is not necessarily contrary to their interests. As Scott VC
recognised in Facia Footwear Ltd v Hinchliffe75 “a continuation
of trading might mean a reduction in the dividend eventually
payable to creditors but it represented the creditors’ only chance
of full payment. It is, therefore, not in the least obvious that in
continuing to trade the directors were ignoring the interests of
the creditors”.
9–15
The remedies available for breach of fiduciary duty are superior
to those for breach of the duty of care. Both will provide
recompense for loss (equitable compensation, damages
respectively), but if assets extracted from the company have
ended up in the hands of the directors, as will often be the case,
the fiduciary claim may give the company a proprietary and not
just a personal claim for their return.76 As the previous sentence
implies, the creditor-regarding duty, like the other duties of
directors, is owed to the company and is therefore enforceable
by the company alone, not by individual creditors.77 As
Gummow J said in the Australian High Court, “the result is that
there is a duty of imperfect obligation owed to creditors, one
which the creditors cannot enforce save to the extent that the
company acts on its own motion or through a liquidator”.78
Typically, enforcement will be by the liquidator, as with
enforcement of the wrongful trading duty. However, in principle
the company or a shareholder suing derivatively could seek to
enforce breaches of the duty outside insolvency. This could
conceivably occur where the former creditors of the company
have taken control of it via a debt for equity swap as a means of
avoiding its liquidation. The main disadvantage of the common
law duty being owed to the company, not to individual creditors
—and it is a significant one—is that its proceeds would appear
not to go primarily to the unsecured creditors, but are typically
caught by any security interests the company has granted. As we
have seen, this result is avoided under the wrongful trading
provisions.79
However, breach of the creditor-facing duty may avail
litigants who bring personal actions against the company or its
directors, because the breach of duty displaces an answer to the
claim which the defendants would otherwise have. Thus, in
Colin Gwyer and Associates Ltd v London Wharf (Limehouse)
Ltd80 a shareholder challenge to the validity of a board resolution
succeeded because the breach of the creditor duty was held to
disqualify the director from being counted towards the quorum
required under the articles. Recognition of creditors’ interests in
advance of insolvency may also have an impact on litigation
brought against directors for breaches of their non-creditor
duties. Such breaches cannot be ratified by the shareholders in
the vicinity of insolvency because they are no longer the ones
primarily interested in the value of the company’s assets.81
PHOENIX COMPANIES AND THE ABUSE OF COMPANY NAMES
9–16
The Company Law Review described the “Phoenix company”
problem in the following terms:
“The ‘phoenix’ problem results from the continuance of a failed company by those
responsible for that failure, using the vehicle of a new company. The new company,
often trading under the same or similar name, uses the old company’s assets, often
acquired at an undervalue, and exploits its goodwill and business opportunities.
Meanwhile, the creditors of the old company are left to prove their debts against a
valueless shell and the management conceal their previous failure from the
public.”82
CONCLUSION
9–25
Since the Cork Committee134 reported in 1982, statutory
willingness to impose liability towards creditors on the directors
of companies which abuse the mechanism of limited liability has
significantly increased. Both the wrongful trading provisions and
those dealing with the re-use of corporate names were a response
to primarily small company problems. Together with the
provisions on the disqualification of directors,135 also aimed
primarily at small companies, they may be said to constitute the
legislature’s preferred alternative to compulsory minimum
capital requirements136 for dealing with the abuses of limited
liability in small companies. These provisions, however, are not
formally limited to small companies; and the wrongful trading
provisions, through the use of the idea of shadow directors, are
capable also of catching abuses outside small companies, in
particular within corporate groups. However, the issue of limited
liability within groups has not received the same degree of
legislative attention. Like the judges, whose decisions on lifting
the veil we examined in the previous chapter, the legislature has
touched on limited liability within groups only gingerly, whilst
showing itself perfectly able to recognise group structures in
other areas of company law.
1
Companies Act 1985 s.24—a provision applying initially to all companies but from
1992 only to public companies since private companies were then empowered to have a
single member. This is now the position for public companies as well: CA 2006 s.7.
2 Salomon v Salomon [1897] A.C. 22. See above, para.2–1.
3 See para.14–3, below.
4
See s.761 and para.11–8, below.
5
See below para.11–9.
6 2006 Act s.767(1),(2).
7 2006 Act s.767(3). The validity of the transaction, however, is not affected.
8
2006 Act ss.90 and 91.
9
Fraud is a general criminal offence, of course, but it has been regarded as less
confusing for juries to face them with a single charge of fraudulent trading rather than
with numerous charges of individual acts of fraud: see R. v Kemp [1988] Q.B. 645 CA.
(pet. dis. [1988] 1 W.L.R. 846 HL). The legislature thought so well of the offence that it
enacted in s.9 of the Fraud Act 2006 a similar offence in respect of those businesses
carried on by persons falling outside the scope of s.993, including sole traders. This
shows that the absence of limited liability is not a guarantee of the absence of fraud.
10
The section embraces fraud on future, as well as present, creditors: R. v Smith [1996]
2 B.C.L.C. 109 CA.
11 The shift of the civil liability provision out of the companies legislation and into the
insolvency legislation occurred as a result of the recommendations of the Cork
Committee on Insolvency Law (Cmnd. 8558 (1981), Ch.44).
12Insolvency Act 1986 ss.246ZA and ZB, inserted by s.117 of the Small Business and
Enterprise Act 2015.
13 For a discussion of the role of administration see paras 32–43 et seq, below.
14
The fraudulent trading will have occurred before the company went into
administration or liquidation. In fact, there is no limit in the section on the prior period
which may be scrutinised for evidence of fraudulent trading. The company being in
liquidation or administration is simply a condition for the claim being brought.
However, the longer-lived the fraudulent scheme, the less likely it is the early creditors
will have suffered a loss. So, older fraud is likely to be less relevant to the setting of the
amount of the contribution: see para.9–8, below.
15A business may be regarded as “carried on” notwithstanding that the company has
ceased active trading: Re Sarflax Ltd [1979] Ch. 592.
16
1986 Act ss.213(2)/246ZA(2).
17
Unlike the situation before 1985, it is no longer possible to impose liability under
ss.213 and 246ZA in respect of particular debts or in favour of particular creditors: cf.
Re Cyona Distributors Ltd [1967] Ch. 889 CA.
18
And it is no bar to inclusion within the section that the activities in question occurred
abroad: Jetivia SA v Bilta (UK) Ltd [2015] 1 B.C.L.C. 443 SC. This is on the basis that
the winding up of a company incorporated in the UK has effect, as far as domestic law is
concerned, in relation to all the assets of the company, no matter where situated. This
reasoning would seem equally applicable to liability for wrongful trading under
ss.214/246ZB of the Act.
19
Re Cooper Chemicals Ltd [1978] Ch. 262 (only one creditor defrauded). Indeed, for
criminal liability to arise it is not clear that it is necessary for any person actually to be
defrauded provided that the business of the company was carried on with intent to
defraud (R. v Kemp [1988] Q.B. 645 CA—only potential creditors defrauded).
20Morphitis v Bernasconi [2003] 2 B.C.L.C. 53 CA. The defrauded person will have
remedies under the general law of fraud.
21
In Re Maidstone Building Provisions Ltd [1971] 1 W.L.R. 1085 an attempt to obtain a
declaration against the company’s secretary, who was also a partner in its auditors’ firm,
failed because, although he had given financial advice and had not attempted to prevent
the company from trading, he had not taken “positive steps in the carrying on of the
company’s business in a fraudulent manner”. In Re Augustus Barnett & Son Ltd [1986]
B.C.L.C. 170 an attempt against its parent company (Rumasa) failed on the same
ground.
22
Re Bank of Credit and Commerce International SA (No.15) [2005] 2 B.C.L.C. 328
CA, following the lead given in Meridian Global Funds Management Asia Ltd v
Securities Commission [1995] 2 A.C. 500 PC (above, at para.7–41). This step was
facilitated by the separation of the criminal and civil liability for fraudulent trading, so
that there is no implication from this decision that the same attribution rule would be
applied if criminal liability were in question: at [107] and [129].
23
The required degree of knowledge is “blind eye” knowledge, i.e. “a decision to avoid
obtaining confirmation of facts in whose existence the individual has good reason to
believe” (Re Bank of Credit and Commerce International SA (No.15) [2005] 2 B.C.L.C.
328 CA at [14] quoting Lord Scott in Manifest Shipping Co Ltd v Uni-Polaris Shipping
Co Ltd [2003] 1 A.C. 469 at [116]). See also Re Bank of Credit and Commerce
International SA (No.14) [2004] 2 B.C.L.C. 236.
24 In Re Gerald Cooper Chemicals Ltd [1978] Ch. 262 it was held that a declaration
could be made against a creditor who refrained from pressing for repayment knowing
that the business was being carried on in fraud of creditors and who accepted part
payment out of money which he knew had been obtained by that fraud. Gerald Cooper
Chemicals was followed in Re Bank of Credit and Commerce International SA (No.14)
[2001] 1 B.C.L.C. 263.
25 In Re Bank of Credit and Commerce International SA (No.15) [2005] 2 B.C.L.C. 328
CA it was left open whether the third party’s liability could not be more simply and
widely established on the basis of the third party’s vicarious liability for breaches of
s.213 by its employees. See Dubai Aluminium Co Ltd v Salaam [2003] 2 A.C. 366 HL
and para.7–31. This approach would strength the incentives of third parties to control
participation by their employees in the fraudulent conduct of the company’s business.
26
Re Patrick Lyon Ltd [1933] Ch. 786 at 790, 791.
27
Re William C Leitch Ltd [1932] 2 Ch. 71 at 77, per Maugham J. See also R. v
Grantham [1984] Q.B. 675 CA, where the court upheld a direction to the jury that they
might convict of fraudulent trading a person who had taken an active part in running the
business if they were satisfied that he had helped to obtain credit knowing that there was
no good reason for thinking that funds would become available to pay the debts when
they became due or shortly thereafter. That dishonesty may be inferred in these cases
does not mean, of course, that it can never be established in other cases: Aktieselskabet
Dansk Skibsfinansiering v Brothers [2001] 2 B.C.L.C. 324 HKCFA.
28
Cmnd. 1749, para.503(b).
29
Above fn.11. For the argument that the Cork Committee overestimated the potential
role of the wrongful trading provisions, partly because existing Companies and
Insolvency Act provisions already cover much of the ground, partly because defendants
financially able to meet the liability are likely to be few, see R. Williams, “What can we
expect to gain from reforming the insolvent trading remedy?” (2015) 78 M.L.R. 55.
30
1986 Act ss.214(6)/246ZB(6). Section 213 formally applies in any winding up
(solvent or insolvent) but in practice it is needed only in insolvent winding up.
311986 Act ss.214(2)/246ZB(2). It appears it is sufficient that the directors should have
anticipated, for example, insolvent liquidation but the company ends up in insolvent
administration.
321986 Act ss.214(3)/246ZB(3). The burden of proof on knowledge is on the claimant,
on “every step” on the directors: Brook v Masters [2015] B.C.C. 661.
33
This includes functions entrusted to the director even if the director has not carried
them out: ss.214(5)/246ZB(5). If the director has failed the objective test he or she
cannot be excused by the court, under Companies Act 2006 s.1157, on the ground that
the director has acted honestly and reasonably: Re Produce Marketing Consortium Ltd
[1989] 1 W.L.R. 745.
34 1986 Act ss.214(4)/246ZB(4).
35 Below, para.16–15.
36 The directors are likely to be treated with a particular lack of sympathy by the court if
they have not abided by the statutory requirements for keeping themselves abreast of the
company’s financial position: Re Produce Marketing Consortium Ltd (No.2) [1989]
B.C.L.C. 520 at 550, which requirements Knox J referred to as the “minimum
standards”. See Oditah, [1990] L.M.C.L.O. 205; and Prentice, (1990) 10 O.J.L.S. 265.
37 Insolvency Act 1986 s.251.
38
Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Becker [2003] 1 B.C.L.C. 565; Secretary
of State for Trade and Industry v Deverell [2000] 2 B.C.L.C. 133 CA.
39 Re Hydrodan (Corby) Ltd [1994] 2 B.C.L.C. 180; Re PFTZM Ltd [1995] B.C.C. 280;
cf. Re A Company Ex p. Copp [1989] B.C.L.C. 13.
40 In Re Hydrodan (Corby) Ltd [1994] 2 B.C.L.C. 180 the judge was prepared to treat
the indirect parent as a shadow director of a company, but that was because the directors
of the company in question were corporate bodies and so must have received their
instructions from elsewhere. Even here, the directors of the indirect parent were held not
to be shadow directors.
41
Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Deverell [2000] 2 B.C.L.C. 133 CA,
where the precise definition of “shadow director” was determinative of the appeal. The
court also decided that the central question was whether the board in fact did what the
alleged shadow directors proposed and not whether those proposals were couched as
directors or instruction or mere “advice”; nor was it necessary to prove the subjective
expectations of the alleged shadow director and directors as to whether the advice would
be followed.
42
For the general duties see Ch.16, below.
43
1986 Act s.215(5), applied to administrations by s.246ZC.
44
Including any assignees from that person (other than a good faith assignee for value
without notice): IA 1986 s.215(2) and (3).
45
1986 Act s.215(4).
46
1986 Act ss.213(2)/246ZA(2) and 214(1)/246ZB(1).
47
See Re Produce Marketing Consortium Ltd [1989] 1 W.L.R. 745, for wrongful
trading and Morphitis v Bernasconi [2003] 2 B.C.L.C. 53 CA, for fraudulent trading, the
latter reversing the previous understanding in relation to fraudulent trading where a
penal element was thought appropriate in some cases.
48 See the dicta of Park J in Re Continental Assurance Co of London Plc (No.4) [2007] 2
B.C.L.C. 287 at [382]–[390] (s.214); and Re Overnight Ltd [2010] 2 B.C.L.C. 186
(s.213). The defendants’ liability may, but need not, be put on the basis of joint and
several liability.
49 Assume a pre-wrongful trading position of assets 50, liabilities 100, so creditors paid
50p in the pound. Assume wrongful trading which increases liabilities to 150 and a
contribution which raises assets to 100. Creditors now receive 66p in the pound
(assuming no transaction costs).
50 1986 Act s.214(3).
51
See Re Produce Marketing Consortium Ltd [1989] 1 W.L.R. 745; Re Brian D.
Pierson (Contractors) Ltd [2001] 1 B.C.L.C. 275.
52Re The Rod Gunner Organisation Ltd [2004] 1 B.C.L.C 110. Similarly, Roberts v
Frohlich [2011] 2 B.C.L.C. 501.
53 Re Continental Assurance Co of London Plc (No.4) [2007] 2 B.C.L.C. 287. See also
Re Sherborne Associates Ltd [1995] B.C.C. 40, in which the judge held that the
liquidator had to identify and then stick to a particular date by which it was argued the
directors should have realised the company had no reasonable prospect of avoiding
insolvent liquidation. Contrast Singla v Hedman [2010] 2 B.C.L.C. 61: causing a
company without any secure financing to begin contracting for production was a breach
of s.214.
54 Grant v Rails [2016] B.C.C. 293, where Snowden J held that continued trading in
favourable conditions did not afford the directors a defence under the “every step”
provision because new creditors would be worse off, i.e. “every step” was equated with
every creditor.
55
The issue that the costs of the s.214 litigation might not count as costs of the
liquidation was determined in favour of the liquidator by an amendment to r.4.218 of the
Insolvency Rules 1986/1925, made in 2002 and by s.176ZA of the IA 1986, inserted by
s.1282 of the Companies Act 2006, which gives liquidation expenses priority over both
preferential debts and assets secured by a floating charge (subject to exceptions to
prevent abuse), overruling the result of Buchler v Talbot [2004] 2 A.C. 298 HL. Thus,
the disincentive to liquidator litigation arising from the risk of the liquidator being left to
bear the litigation costs personally has been considerably reduced, if not eliminated.
56
Re Yagerphone Ltd [1935] 1 Ch. 395.
57
A liquidator or administer who sought to avoid this rule by assigning the fruits of the
litigation rather than the claim itself would find it difficult to give the funder sufficient
control of the litigation. See Grovewood Holdings Plc v James Capel & Co Ltd [1995]
Ch. 80; Re Oasis Merchandising Services Ltd (In Liquidation) [1998] Ch. 170 CA;
Ruttle Plant Ltd v Secretary of State for the Environment, Food and Rural Affairs (No.3)
[2009] 1 All E.R. 448; Rawnsley v Weatherall Green & Smith North Ltd [2010] 1
B.C.L.C. 658.
58
1986 Act s.246ZD.
59
1986 Act s.176ZD.
60 See para.16–16, below.
61 The CLR in fact proposed that the wrongful trading duty should be embodied in the
statutory statement of directors’ duties (CLR, Final 1, p.348 (Principle 9)), but the
Government rejected this proposal on the grounds that decoupling the substantive
provisions at present in s.214 from the remedies available under the 1986 Insolvency
Act would be “incongruous” (Modernising Company Law, Cm. 5533-I, July 2002,
para.3.12). Had this step been taken, the common law duties would have been wrapped
up into the statutory statement as well (CLR, Final I, para.3.17).
62
Walker v Wimborne (1976) 137 C.L.R. 1.
63
West Mercia Safetywear v Dodd [1988] B.C.L.C. 250 CA. In this case the payment by
the insolvent company to a particular creditor involved both a breach of fiduciary duty
by the director and also a fraudulent preference (being motivated by a desire to protect
the director from liability under a personal guarantee to the creditor).
64 Even then it is often unclear whether the court is using a balance sheet definition of
insolvency (liabilities exceed assets) or a cash-flow approach (company does not have
enough cash to pay its debts as they fall due).
65 Brady v Brady [1988] B.C.L.C. 20, 40 CA.
66 Nicholson v Permakraft (NZ) Ltd [1985] 1 N.Z.L.R. 242.
67
For example, Re Welfab Engineers Ltd [1990] B.C.L.C. 833.
68 Thus, the directors might continue the trading of an unprofitable but balance sheet
solvent company, in the hope of returning to profitability, without altering the risk
profile of the company’s business, even though the creditors’ interests would most
obviously be advanced by liquidating the company now and allowing them to crystallise
their claims against the company’s assets.
69
See para.16–37, below for a discussion of this duty.
70 See para.9–6.
71 Re HLC Environmental Projects Ltd [2014] B.C.C. 337 at [92]. The reasonable
director approach is based on Charterbridge Corp Ltd v Lloyds Bank Ltd [1970] Ch. 62
(see para.16–42, below).
72
Colin Gwyer and Associates Ltd v London Wharf (Limehouse) Ltd [2003] 2 B.C.L.C.
153 at [74]; Re HLC Environmental Projects Ltd [2014] B.C.C. 337.
73
Bell Group Ltd (In Liquidation) v Westpac Banking Corp (No.9) [2008] WASC 239 at
[4436]; Ultraframe (UK) Ltd v Fielding [2005] EWHC 1638 (Ch).
74
See fn.68.
75
Facia Footwear Ltd v Hinchliffe [1998] 1 B.C.L.C. 218 (an application for summary
judgment). For a similar approach to wrongful trading see above, para.9–9.
76
See para.16–112, below.
77
Yukong Line Ltd of Korea v Rendsburg Investments Corp of Liberia (The Rialto)
[1998] 1 W.L.R. 294; Kuwait Asia Bank EC v National Mutual Life Nominees Ltd
[1991] 1 A.C. 187, 217 (Lord Templeman); Spies v R [2000] HCA 43; [2000] 201
C.L.R. 603 Aust HC. In this respect the dictum of Lord Templeman in Winkworth v
Edward Baron Development Co Ltd [1986] 1 W.L.R. 1512 at 1517 goes too far. But in
the same vein see the decision of the Supreme Court of Canada, Peoples Department
Stores v Wise [2004] 3 S.C.R. 461, adopting the notion of direct duties to individual
creditors (criticised by Stéphane Rousseau, correctly it is submitted, on the basis that the
case involved a reversal of “a fundamental principle of corporate law”: “Directors’ Duty
of Care after Peoples: Would it be Wise to Start Worrying about Liability?” (2005) 41
Canadian Business Law Journal at 225).
78
Sycotex Pty Ltd v Baseler (1994) 122 A.L.R. 531, 550.
79 See para.9–10, above. Indeed, there is a broader question here of what the duty to the
creditors means when there are several classes of creditor. Junior creditors, who are “out
of the money” at the time of the relevant decision, may, like shareholders, have an
interest in taking on very risky projects, because only in that way have they any hope of
recovering anything. Senior creditors, by contrast, may be better off by stopping trading
at once.
80
Above fn.72.
81 Kinsela v Russell Kinsela Pty Ltd [1986] 4 N.S.W.L.R. 722.
82
Final Report I, para.15.55.
83 Final Report I, para.15.56. The facts giving rise to the application to use a similar
name in Re Lightning Electrical Contractors Ltd [1996] 2 B.C.L.C. 302 might be
thought to be an example of this: the administrative receivership of a medium-sized
company was brought about by the failure of two large client companies to pay the
money due from them; the successor company’s use of the similar name was supported
by the receivers since it enable them to maximise the value of the first company’s assets.
84
CLR, Final Report I, paras 15.65–15.72. The problem with the existing law is perhaps
demonstrated by the background facts of Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v
Becker [2003] 1 B.C.L.C. 565.
85
If misleading the creditors as to the creditworthiness of the second business is the
rationale of the section, it is perhaps understandable that the prohibition extends even to
the carrying on of the second business in non-corporate form (i.e. potentially without
limited liability): (s.216(3)(c)). However, no personal liability is imposed in this case,
presumably on the basis that it is unnecessary: s.217(1). In many cases the defendant
will be liable as partner or sole trader, but it is conceivable that a person could “directly
or indirectly be concerned or take part in the carrying-on” of a non-corporate business
without attracting personal liability as a partner or sole trader, so that the absence of
personal liability under s.217 is important.
86
R. v Cole [1998] 2 B.C.L.C. 234 CA.
87
1986 Act s.216(6)—an important extension, for otherwise the prohibition could be
easily avoided by the transferee company’s registered name being quite dissimilar from
the transferor company’s but by the transferee then carrying on business under a similar
name. See R. (Griffin) v Richmond Magistrates Court [2008] EWHC 84 (Admin). The
CLR found that this was a practice used effectively to avoid the impact of the provisions,
even though ostensibly caught by them.
88
First Independent Factors and Finance Ltd v Mountford [2008] 2 B.C.L.C. 297.
89
Ricketts v Ad Valorem Factors Ltd [2004] 1 B.C.L.C. 1 CA; Revenue and Customs
Commissioners v Walsh [2005] 2 B.C.L.C. 455, though in the former case there was a
disagreement among the judges as to whether the facts needed only to “suggest” an
association or give rise to a probability that members of the public would associate the
two companies.
90
Ricketts v Ad Valorem Factors Ltd [2004] 1 B.C.L.C. 1 CA.
91
1986 Act s.217. That the liability is restricted to debts incurred by the company in the
period during which the person was in breach of s.216 (and did not extend to all the
debts incurred whilst that person was a director of the company) was accepted by Arden
LJ in ESS Productions Ltd v Sully [2005] 2 B.C.L.C. 547 at [75]. See also Glasgow City
Council v Craig [2009] 1 B.C.L.C. 742: liability confined to the debts of that part of the
business which was carried on under the prohibited name.
92
Though such a person does not commit a criminal offence. For the purpose of both
ss.216 and 217, “company” includes any company which may be wound up under Pt V
of the Insolvency Act, i.e. virtually any company or association: s.220.
93 The CLR reported that the Official Receiver was aware of 134 cases of breaches of
s.216 in 1999/2000, which led to 118 warning letters and nine convictions, but these
figures apparently relate only to criminal liability under the section: Completing,
para.13.105.
94 First Independent Factors and Finance Ltd v Mountford [2008] 2 B.C.L.C. 297—
claim brought by debt factor which had acquired the claims from two trade creditors at a
discount. cf. fn.57 above.
95Insolvency Rules (SI 1986/1925), rr.4.228 to 4.230; and the Insolvency (Scotland)
Rules (SI 1986/1915), rr.4.78 to 4.82.
96
First Independent Factors and Finance Ltd v Churchill [2007] 1 B.C.L.C. 293 CA.
97 The Insolvency (Amendment) Rules 2007 (SI 2007/1974).
98 See Penrose v Secretary of State for Trade and Industry [1996] 1 W.L.R. 482. In the
Churchill case (fn.96, above) the Court of Appeal put the function of the notice rather
differently: it was to help creditors of the first company make an informed assessment of
the risks of extending credit to the successor company, i.e. the focus was on protection
of the creditors of the successor company. This approach seems more consistent with the
drafting of the section. On the other hand, it is not then clear why the notice has to be
given before the directors of the first company become involved with the successor
company: it should be enough if notice is given before creditors of the first company
extend credit to the successor company.
99
Final Report I, para.15.62.
100
The second case (r.4.229) is ancillary to the provision permitting a person to act in
breach of s.216 if the court gives permission. The second case permits a director, who
applies for leave within seven days of the first company going into liquidation, to
continue to act in breach of s.216 for a period of six weeks or until the court disposes of
the application for leave, whichever is the shorter.
101
Rule 4.230—and has not been a dormant company. Otherwise, a shelf company
could be formed purely for the purpose of triggering this exception.
102
Though cf. Morphitis v Bernasconi [2003] 2 B.C.L.C. 53 CA: scheme to avoid s.216
by the directors resigning from the company at least a year before it was liquidated.
103
ESS Production Ltd v Sully [2005] 2 B.C.L.C. 547 CA.
104See Atkins v Wardle (1889) 5 T.L.R. 734 CA; Scottish & Newcastle Breweries Ltd v
Blair, 1967 S.L.T. 72; Civil Service Co-operative Society v Chapman [1914] 30 T.L.R.
679; British Airways Board v Parish [1979] 2 Lloyd’s Rep. 361.
1052006 Act s.82(1) and the Company Limited Liability Partnership (Names and
Trading Disclosure) Regulations 2015 (SI 2015/17) Pt 6.
106
This is a more radical response than that recommended by the CLR which would
have kept personal liability but on a narrower basis: Final Report I, paras 11.55–11.57.
107 This is new: previously, other than as provided by s.349(4), the sanctions for breach
of the disclosure requirements were only criminal. However, the civil liability imposed
by s.83 is modelled on that imposed by s.5 of the Business Names Act 1985 which
already applied to companies trading other than under their corporate name. The
criminal sanctions are retained in s.84 of the 2006 Act.
108
2006 Act s.83(1),(2). The restriction does not apply if the company seeks to enforce
its contractual rights in proceedings brought by another person (for example, by way of
counter-claim): s.83(3).
109
Hence the importance of disclosure of the company’s name, not only in
correspondence, but on its website and at any place of business: Trading Regulations,
regs 4 and 6(2).
110 The rationales for limited liability are discussed at paras 8–1 et seq.
111This situation is not usual, but is certainly not unknown, in the UK: “Governance
concerns rise after London IPOs”, Financial Times, 16 June 2011.
112
At para.8–11, above.
113 This does not include all groups of companies: in conglomerate groups (i.e. groups
of diversified businesses) the advantages of common ownership may well reside in
something other than the imposition of a single business strategy (for example, access to
sources of finance or managerial expertise).
114 On “corporate opportunities” see para.16–86, below.
115 For an example of the use of the strategy of disqualifying directors (discussed in the
following chapter) see Re Genosyis Technology Management Ltd [2007] 1 B.C.L.C. 208
—directors disqualified for causing debts due to subsidiary to be paid to parent
company.
116 Aktiengesetz, Book Three.
117
For a discussion of German “Konzernrecht”, see K.J. Hopt, “Legal Elements and
Policy Decisions in Regulating Groups of Companies” in C.M. Schmitthoff and F.
Wooldridge (eds), Groups of Companies (London: Sweet & Maxwell, 1991), p.81; H.
Wiedemann, “The German Experience with the Law of Affiliated Enterprise”, in K.J.
Hopt (ed.), Groups of Companies in European Laws, Legal and Economic Analyses on
Multinational Enterprises, Vol. II (Walter de Gruyter, 1982) 21. For a comparative
perspective, see Forum Europaeum Corporate Group Law, “Corporate Group Law for
Europe” (2000) 1 European Business Organization Law Review 165; and V. Priskich,
“Corporate Groups: Current Proposals for Reform in Australia and the United Kingdom
and a Comparative Analysis of the Regime in Germany” in (2002) 4 I.C.C.L.J. 37; and
K.J. Hopt, “Groups of Companies” in J. Gordon and G. Ringe (eds), Oxford Handbook
of Corporate Law and Governance (OUP, online ed, 2015).
118
Completing, Ch.10. On parent and subsidiary company reporting requirements see
immediately below.
119Final Report I, paras 8.23–8.28. Nevertheless, a variant of the idea (exemption from
audit but not from producing accounts in exchange for a guarantee from the parent) has
been implemented in UK law: see para.22-7.
120 Aktiengesetz, s.317.
121
A possible partial solution, which the German courts have used for private
companies (GmbH), would be to use the contractual group model under which exercise
of influence to disadvantageous ends would make the parent liable for all the
subsidiary’s losses, whether they could be related to a particular disadvantageous
contract or not.
122Brussels, 4 November 2002, Ch.V. See above, para.6–12. For more detailed
consideration of the options, see Forum Europaeum, above fn.117. The proposal was
made again—this time for an EU Recommendation—in the Report of the Reflection
Group on the Future of EU Company Law, Brussels April 2011, Ch.4.
123This is often referred to as the Rozenblum doctrine, after the name of the French case
(Bulletin criminel 1985 No.54) in which the principle was articulated.
124
See further para.16–47, below. The potential liability of the parent company as a
shadow director of the subsidiary is largely excluded by s.251(3) of the CA 2006, unless
the subsidiary is in the vicinity of insolvency.
125 See para.28–25.
126 On New Zealand law and Australian proposals, see R.P. Austin, “Corporate Groups”
in R. Grantham and C. Rickett (eds), Corporate Personality in the Twentieth Century
(Oxford: Hart Publishing, 1998), especially at pp.84–87.
127 To take a simplified example: if a parent company A has two wholly-owned
subsidiaries, B and C, and in a financial year B makes a loss of £100,000 while C makes
a distributable profit of £10,000 all of which it pays to A by way of dividend, the
individual accounts of A (assuming it has broken even) will show a profit of £10,000
whereas in fact the group has made a loss of £90,000.
128 See para.16–70, below.
129 See para.13–47.
130“Parent company” is defined in s.1162 and Sch.7 (see para.21–10) and “holding
company” in s.1159 and Sch.6.
131
For purposes of consolidation a measure of uncertainty is acceptable because, when
in doubt, one can play safe and consolidate.
132
1948 Act s.154. Under the former s.154(10)(a)(ii) holding more than half in nominal
value of a company’s equity share capital (voting or non-voting) made it a subsidiary.
133
Unfortunately, this relatively simple definition requires additional refinement to
make it work (which is contained in Sch.6 to the Act) and, as Enviroco Ltd v Farstad
Supply A/S [2011] 2 B.C.L.C. 165, SC demonstrated, that refinement was not itself
sufficiently refined because it failed to take full account of the definition of a “member”
in s.112 of the Act.
134
See above fn.11.
135
Discussed in the next chapter.
136 See para.11–8, below.
CHAPTER 10
DISQUALIFICATION OF DIRECTORS
10–1
In the previous chapter we examined the provisions which, at the
instigation of those in charge of the insolvency of a company,
may lead to the imposition of a financial liability on directors
and shadow directors who, in the period preceding the
insolvency, engaged in conduct which exploited the
vulnerabilities of creditors and caused a diminution in the
company’s assets. The Cork Committee, which recommended
this reform in 1982, went further, however, and argued that
“proper safeguards for the public” required that wrongful trading
be supplemented by provisions which ensure that “those whose
conduct has shown them to be unfitted to manage the affairs of a
company with limited liability shall, for a specified period, be
prohibited from doing so”.1 In particular, they thought the law
should “severely penalise those who abuse the privilege of
limited liability by operating behind one-man, insufficiently
capitalised companies”.2 This recommendation is now embodied
in the Company Directors Disqualification Act 1986,3 as later
amended. Like the wrongful trading provisions, the central
provisions of the Act (disqualification on grounds of “unfitness”)
apply to shadow directors as well as directors.4 The law was here
to be used in general deterrence mode, for the protection of
future creditors of companies as a whole, rather than to seek
compensation for existing creditors. However, under the Small
Business and Enterprise Act 2015 a compensation power was
grafted onto the disqualification provisions, thus holding out
some prospect that the provisions will aid in addition the
creditors of the company whose directors have been disqualified.
A further significant feature of the Act is that initiation of
disqualification action lies exclusively in the hands of the public
authorities in the case of the most commonly used provisions,
i.e. where disqualification is based on “unfitness”.5 Initiation of
the disqualification process is assigned to the Secretary of State
(“SS”) (i.e. the relevant government minister), though the
minister may delegate that function, and normally does, to the
Insolvency Service, a government agency.6 The SS also has
exclusive control over the initiation of the new compensation
provisions.7 Outside the area of unfitness, the liquidator or any
past member or creditor may apply for a disqualification order,8
but it is unclear that they will have any great incentive to do so,
because the benefits of disqualification accrue to future
creditors. In other words, the forward looking disqualification
process and its initiation by the public authorities are linked
features of the legislation. When compensation was grafted onto
the legislation in 2015, the opportunity might have been taken to
open up the range of potential initiators, but it was not.
The introduction of a compensation mechanism was not the
only significant reform after 1986. In particular, reforms in the
Insolvency Act 2000 introduced the notion of an out-of-court
“disqualification undertaking” in cases of unfitness to
supplement the “disqualification order”, which only a court can
make.9 In addition, the 2015 Act10 made reforms aimed at taking
into account the cross-border environment in which many
companies now operate but which national prudential rules often
ignore. These changes make it possible for conduct of the
director in relation to overseas companies (i.e. companies
incorporated outside Great Britain)11 to be taken into account in
appropriate circumstances by the court or SS when considering
disqualification. However, powers already contained in Pt 40 of
the Companies Act 200612 have not been used to date. These
empower the SS to make regulations so that a person
disqualified in a foreign jurisdiction would or could be
prohibited from acting in relation to a company incorporated in
Great Britain. New s.5A (see para.10–12, below) gets close to
this principle, but is based on conviction abroad for a serious
offence, not disqualification abroad. The attraction of the more
general principle clearly depends upon the equivalence of the
foreign jurisdictions’ disqualification provisions to those in the
UK. It is an issue in which the EU is likely to show interest.
In addition to the general ground of unfitness, there are a
number of more specific cases in which disqualification can be
imposed on persons. Although these persons are typically
directors or shadow directors of companies, these
disqualification provision apply more broadly in some cases.
The specific instances can best be analysed as falling within the
following categories:
(a) commission of a serious offence, usually involving
dishonesty, in connection with the management of a
company;
(b) being found liable to make a contribution to the assets of the
company on grounds of fraudulent or wrongful trading;
(c) failure to comply with the provisions of the companies or
insolvency legislation relating to the filing of documents with
the Registrar.
Finally, there is a long-standing provision in the companies
legislation which disqualifies an undischarged bankrupt from
being involved in the management of companies, to which was
added in 2002 the notion of “bankruptcy restriction orders”.
DISQUALIFICATION ORDERS AND UNDERTAKINGS
10–2
The power to disqualify has generated a high level of activity. In
the years 1997–1998 to 2000–2001 between 1,250 and 1,500
directors were disqualified each year by court order and in 2001–
2002, when disqualification undertakings were introduced, the
total of orders and undertakings was nearly 2,000.13 Since then,
the total of orders and undertakings has fluctuated within a
slowly declining pattern. In 2014/15 there was a total of 1,227
(899 undertakings and 328 court orders)—about 4 per cent of the
total number of directors of failed companies in that year. Over
80 per cent of the orders and undertakings were on grounds of
unfitness.14 Thus, the Act has been the basis of a considerable
activity on the part of the public authorities. The rationale behind
the introduction of undertakings in unfitness cases by the
Insolvency Act 2000 was the fact that, under the previous
legislation, even where the public authorities and the director
could reach agreement on how the provisions of the Act should
apply in the particular case, it was necessary to go to court to
obtain an order and it was doubtful whether the court could
simply accept, and rubber-stamp, the agreement between them.15
The amended Act permits the SS and the director to reach an
agreement out-of-court on a disqualification undertaking, which
will restrict the director’s future activities in the same way as a
disqualification order, but without the need for a court hearing.16
The director can always trigger a court hearing by refusing to
agree terms for an undertaking, though he or she will normally
be liable for the SS’s costs, as well as his or her own costs, if the
court makes an order. Alternatively, a director who has accepted
an undertaking may subsequently apply to the court, apparently
at any time, for the period of the disqualification to be reduced
or for the undertaking to cease to apply.17 This is equivalent to
the power which the court has under the Insolvency Rules to
review, vary or rescind disqualification orders.18 Although the
power is broadly framed, the courts are likely to find it
appropriate to alter the undertaking for the future (the court has
no power to declare that it ought not to have been made) only in
limited circumstances. In particular, it would be likely to
undermine the undertaking procedure if directors, having entered
into an undertaking, were able freely to invoke the section.19
Scope of disqualification orders and undertakings
10–3
The scope of the disqualification order or undertaking is
obviously a crucial matter in the design of the legislation. It
would be too limited for such an order to prohibit a person from
acting only as director of a company, since there are many ways
of controlling a company’s management without being a director
of the company. A way forward might have been to extend the
prohibition to being a shadow director of a company but the Act
in fact avoids the difficulties of that definition and takes an even
broader approach. The prohibition imposed by a disqualification
order or undertaking extends to “in any way, directly or
indirectly, be[ing] concerned or tak[ing] part in the promotion,
formation or management of a company”.20 The courts have
taken a broad approach to what being concerned or taking part in
the management of a company may embrace.21 In addition, the
disqualified person is prohibited from acting as an insolvency
practitioner.22 Finally, the disqualified person is denied access to
limited liability through some corporate form other than a
registered company, such as a limited liability partnership, a
building society or an incorporated friendly society.23
Adherence to a disqualification order or undertaking is
secured by criminal penalties24 and, probably much more
important, by personal liability for the debts and other liabilities
of the company incurred during the time the disqualified person
was involved in its management in breach of the order or
undertaking.25 This demonstrates that it is misuse of the facility
of limited liability which lies at the heart of disqualification
orders. Personal liability is also extended to any other person
involved in the management of the company who knowingly
acts on the instructions of a disqualified person.26 Indeed,
entrusting the management of a company to someone known to
be disqualified might well be a basis for disqualifying the
entrusting director on grounds of unfitness.27
The temporal scope of the disqualification order is also
important in assessing its rigour. The approach of the Act is to
set maxima and then to leave the actual disqualification period to
be fixed in the order or undertaking. The maxima vary from one
disqualification ground to another, the longest being in the case
of disqualification on grounds of unfitness, where it is set at 15
years.28 There is also a minimum period of two years in the case
of unfitness in relation to insolvent companies.29 After some lack
of clarity in the cases the Court of Appeal has opted for setting
the actual period of disqualification on grounds of unfitness by
assessing how far below the conduct expected of a director the
respondent fell.30 In Re Sevenoaks Stationers (Retail) Ltd31 the
Court of Appeal divided the 2–15 year period for unfitness
disqualification into three brackets, reflecting different levels of
seriousness, though it cannot be said that it drew the dividing
line between them very clearly.32
The prohibition (except that part of it which relates to acting
as an insolvency practitioner) may be relaxed by the court,
which may give leave to the disqualified person to act in a
particular case. In the case of disqualification on grounds of
unfitness under s.6, it is the practice to consider such
applications at the same time as the disqualification order is
made (in those, now minority, cases in which the disqualification
is imposed by the court).33 The leave granted, which obviously
must not be so wide as to undermine the purposes of the Act,34
often relates to other companies of which the applicant is already
a director, which are trading successfully and whose future
success is thought to be dependent on the continued involvement
of the applicant. Often the leave is made conditional upon other
steps being taken to protect the public, such as the appointment
of an independent director to the board.35 Overall, what the court
has to do is to balance the need to protect the public, especially
future creditors, as demonstrated by the conduct which has
rendered the director unfit, with the interest of the director or
other persons dependent on the company in relation to which
leave is sought in the director having access to trading with
limited liability.36
Compensation
10–4
The compensation provisions introduced in 2015 mean that the
disqualification process may have significance for present as
well as future creditors. The provisions apply to all classes of
disqualification order or undertaking, provided that the company
has become insolvent, the conduct for which the person was
disqualified caused loss to one or more creditors and the
disqualified person was at any time a director of it.37 This
appears to mean that only present or former directors may be
subject to compensation orders (not shadow directors, for
example) but that the conduct leading to the disqualification
need not be conduct as a director (it might be conduct as a
shadow director provided that person was at some point a
director of the company). The initiation of the compensation
procedure lies in the hands of the SS, by way of application to
the court or acceptance of a compensation undertaking, who has
two years from the initial disqualification order or undertaking to
seek to add compensation to it—though both may be dealt with
at the same time.38 In effect, the company’s creditors piggy-back
on the efforts of the public authorities to enforce the
disqualification provisions. But the creditors have no
independent right of action. The utility of the new compensation
provisions thus depends on the SS’s willingness to use them.
Where there is clear loss to creditors and an available
mechanism for distributing the compensation, there is no reason
why the SS (or, rather, the Insolvency Service on his behalf)
should not use them.39 But a pre-condition of use of the
compensation power is the existence of a disqualification order
or undertaking. The Insolvency Service has power to seek these
on grounds of unfitness—the most widely deployed ground—
only where it regards this course of action as being “in the public
interest”.40 It is unclear whether the Service will regard simple
loss to creditors as a ground for seeking disqualification and then
compensation. The amount of the compensation is not specified
precisely, but is to be fixed (by the court or SS) having regard
“in particular” to the amount of the loss caused, the nature of the
conduct which led to the loss and any recompense already
made.41 This suggests that the loss suffered as a result of the
director’s conduct sets the outer boundary of the compensation
to be awarded and, within that, the seriousness of the conduct
will be crucial.
DISQUALIFICATION ON GROUNDS OF UNFITNESS
10–5
There are in fact two mechanisms in the 1986 Act for obtaining
disqualification on unfitness grounds, the initiative in both cases
lying with the SS. Under ss.6 and 7 the SS may apply to the
court to have a director42 or shadow director43 of an insolvent44
company disqualified where the SS thinks it is expedient in the
public interest to do so.45 Instead, the SS may accept a
disqualification undertaking from the director in such
circumstances.46 Secondly, under s.8 the SS may apply to the
court or accept an undertaking in relation to a similar range of
people, whether the company is insolvent or not, if he or she
decides it is in the public interest to do so.47 Under s.6
disqualification is mandatory for a minimum period of two
years, if unfitness is found; the maximum period is 15 years
under both sets of provisions.48 Thus, although in the wake of the
Cork Report business opposition fought off the idea of automatic
disqualification in the case of directors of insolvent companies,
the Government managed to avoid leaving the issue entirely to
the discretion of the courts.49
Once the company has become insolvent, the director is liable
to have the whole of his or her conduct as director of that
company scrutinised for evidence of unfitness. Unlike the
wrongful trading provisions considered in the previous chapter,
that scrutiny is not confined to the director’s conduct in the
period immediately before the insolvency. Moreover, ss.6(2) and
8(2) include within the scrutiny the director’s conduct of other
companies where that person was a director or shadow director.
These other companies may not have fallen into insolvency and
there need be no particular business or other link between the
“lead” company and the other companies in order for the
director’s conduct in relation to them to be taken into account.50
In short, once the unfitness provisions are triggered, the scrutiny
is capable of reaching out into the whole of the activities of the
directors of that company in their capacity as directors.51 In an
important extension made by the 2015 Act these additional
companies include companies incorporated outside Great
Britain, so that geography no longer confines the court’s
examination—though evidential difficulties may do so.52
10–6
Despite the fact that ss.6–8 apply to shadow directors, in 2015
the disqualification provisions were extended to other
“influencers” of directors’ “unfit” conduct. This means that a
disqualification order may be made against or a disqualification
undertaking accepted from a person in accordance with whose
directions or instructions the director has acted.53 These
additional provisions are ancillary in the sense that they may be
invoked, in the case of an order against the influencer,54 only if
there is a disqualification order or an undertaking on grounds of
unfitness in place against the director. In the case of an
undertaking given by the influencer, one or other of those two
situations must exist or the SS must be satisfied that an
undertaking could be accepted from the director.55 In many cases
the influencer will be a shadow director and so can be tackled
directly under ss.6–8. But the extension does not depend, as with
a shadow director, on the board as a whole being accustomed to
act in accordance with the non-director’s directions or
instruction. The focus is on the relationship between the
influencer and the person disqualified. Nor does the person
disqualified need to be accustomed to act as the influencer
wishes, provided the conduct forming the basis of the underlying
conduct was in fact influenced in the required way. The
extension seems to have been part of a general policy which was
being promoted in the run up to the 2015 Act of making
transparent where control of companies lies and bringing
responsibility home to the real controllers.56
The role of the Insolvency Service
10–7
When recommending what is now s.6, the Cork Committee57
said that its aim was to “replace by a far more rigorous system
the present ineffective provisions”. The effectiveness in practice
of s.6 can be said to depend upon two matters. The first is the
assiduity of the Insolvency Service, to which the SS normally
delegates disqualification powers, in enforcing the provisions of
the Act; and the second is the courts’ approach to s.6, especially
their interpretation of the central concept of unfitness and how
they set the period of disqualification.
In order to maximise the chances of applications being made,
the Cork Committee58 recommended that applications by
liquidators or, with leave, other creditors should be permitted,
and so confining applications to the SS was regarded at the time
of the passage of the Insolvency Act 1986 as a retrograde step.
There are two reasons why the Insolvency Service might not
prove effective. The first is lack of information about directors’
conduct, especially when the company is being wound up
voluntarily, so that the Official Receiver is not involved.59 This
is addressed by the imposition of a requirement on liquidators,
administrators and receivers to report to the SS on the conduct of
directors and shadow directors of companies for whose affairs
they are responsible though the quality of the information
provided is not always high.60 In 2015 the obligation was
strengthened to require a report of relevant information in all
cases and not only where the office holder believed there had
been a breach of s.6.61 Secondly, there was doubt about the
quantity and quality of the resources the government would
devote to the enforcement of the legislation. Although the early
efforts of the Insolvency Service were criticised,62 the
enforcement effort is now substantial, as we have noted, though
only a small percentage of the directors of failed companies are
disqualified. Nevertheless, it is clear that the Service still
experiences difficulties in commencing applications within the
two-year period originally permitted by the statute63 and in
prosecuting them with sufficient vigour to avoid striking out on
grounds of delay or infringement of the director’s human rights
(i.e. the right to have one’s civil rights and obligations
determined within a reasonable time, as required by art.6(1) of
the European Convention on Human Rights).64 The response of
the legislature in 2015 was to extend the period for commencing
proceedings to three years—though this does not help, but rather
exacerbates, the human rights issue.
There is an additional risk that the human rights of directors
will be threatened by the disparity between the state resources
available to the Insolvency Service and those available to the
director, who, in the case of a small company, may be virtually
bankrupt. In particular, there is a danger that the impoverished
director will give a disqualification undertaking because he or
she cannot afford the costs of a full-scale court examination of
the issues. So far, these issues have been addressed rather little
in litigation, though appreciation of the situation may lie behind
the courts’ unwillingness to impose too high a level of
competence on directors under the disqualification provisions.65
As far as the European Convention on Human Rights is
concerned, both the domestic courts and the European Court of
Human Rights seem agreed that disqualification proceedings are
civil in nature, not criminal, so that a lower, but not negligible,
standard of fairness is required in conducting them.66 In
particular, the domestic courts have concluded that the Human
Rights Convention does not require the automatic exclusion of
evidence against the director which was obtained from him or
her under statutory powers of compulsion.67 However, the
exclusion of such evidence has been achieved in fact, as a matter
of interpretation of the domestic law, in the case of the statutory
provisions most likely to be of use to the Insolvency Service.
Under ss.235 and 236 of the Insolvency Act 1986 the liquidator
of a company and the Official Receiver are empowered to
require answers to questions which they put to directors of
companies in insolvent liquidation and to require the production
of documents, but the Court of Appeal has held that these
provisions cannot be used for the purpose of supporting
disqualification applications.68
The role of the court
10–8
Turning to the role of the courts, some guidance is given in
Sch.1 on how the courts (and indeed the SS) should approach
disqualification determinations. The Schedule was revised in
2015 so as to set out the relevant matters at a higher level of
generality than previously, so as to emphasise the width of the
courts’ investigation. The applicability of the Schedule was also
widened since it now applies to all disqualification decisions, not
just to the determination of unfitness.69 In all cases the court
must take into account the extent to which the company was in
breach of legislative requirements (not necessarily just the
requirements of the companies legislation), the defendant’s
responsibility for the company70 becoming insolvent, the loss
actually or potentially caused by the defendant’s conduct and the
frequency with which a director has engaged in conduct caught
by the Schedule. Where the defendant is a director—the standard
case—the court must have regard to the director’s breach of
fiduciary duties or other duties applying specifically to directors.
Breach of commercial morality
10–9
It is possible to divide the cases in which the courts have found
unfitness into two rough categories: probity and competence.71
However, it must be remembered that the concept of unfitness is
open-ended, so that it cannot be claimed that all potential, or
even actual, disqualification applications can be forced into one
or other of these categories. Further, in the nature of things,
many disqualification cases display aspects from both categories.
Nevertheless, it is thought that identifying the two categories is a
useful starting point.
The first category, breach of commercial morality,72 has at its
centre the idea of conducting a business at the expense of its
creditors. A leading example, though only an example, of such
conduct is the Phoenix company described by the Cork
Committee in terms of a person who sets up an undercapitalised
company, allows it to become insolvent, forms a new company
(often with assets purchased at a discount from the liquidator of
the old company), carries on trading much as before, and repeats
the process perhaps several times, leaving behind him each time
a trail of unpaid creditors.73 More generally, the courts have been
alert to find unfitness where the directors have apparently
attempted to trade on the backs of the company’s creditors.74 It
was thought at one time that particular obloquy attached to
directors who attempted to trade out their difficulties by using as
working capital in the business monies owed to the Crown by
way of income tax, national insurance contributions or VAT, on
the grounds that the Crown was an involuntary creditor.
Although that view has been rejected by the Court of Appeal, the
same court has affirmed that, in relation to any creditor, paying
only those creditors who pressed for payment and taking
advantage of those creditors who did not, in order to provide the
working capital which the company needed, is a clear example
of unfitness.75 If the directors of the financially troubled
company are at the same time paying themselves salaries which
are out of proportion to the company’s trading success (or lack
of it) or making disguised distributions to themselves of
corporate assets, the likelihood of a disqualification order being
made is only increased.76
Recklessness and incompetence
10–10
In the previous section the cases considered highlighted
opportunistic behaviour by directors towards the creditors of the
company by failing to pay the creditors whilst continuing
trading. The cases considered in this section focus more
generally on the recklessness or incompetence of the directors’
conduct of the business. They may pay the creditors the money
due to them, as long as the company is able to do so, but the
directors may be regarded as responsible for bringing about the
situation where the company ultimately has to default on its
commitments because of the way they have chosen to run it. In
many cases, of course, both aspects of unfitness can be found.
The early cases put liability on the basis of recklessness,77 but
more recently it has been said that “incompetence or negligence
to a very marked degree”78 would be enough. The danger which
the courts have to avoid in this area is that of treating any
business venture which collapses as evidence of negligence. To
do so would be to discourage the taking of commercial risks,
which must be the life-blood of corporate activity. However,
creating a space for proper risk-taking is no longer thought to
require relieving directors of all objective standards of conduct.
In Re Barings Plc (No.5)79 the Court of Appeal gave guidance on
what constitutes a high degree of incompetence in the common
situation of the directors having properly delegated functions to
lower levels of management. Provided the articles of association
permit such delegation, as they inevitably will in large
organisations, delegation in itself is not evidence of unfitness.
However, the responsible director may be found to be unfit if
there is put in place no system for supervising the discharge of
the delegated function or if the director in question is not able to
understand the information produced by the supervisory system.
In other words, in large organisations directors must ensure there
are in place adequate internal systems for monitoring risk and
failure to do so may be grounds for disqualification.
However, the proposition that directors “have a continuing
duty to acquire and maintain a sufficient knowledge and
understanding of the company’s business to enable them
properly to discharge their duties as directors”80 applies not just
to duties delegated to sub-board level but also to reliance by
directors on their board colleagues to take responsibility for
particular functions and duties. Although such reliance is again
in principle acceptable, so that there can be a division of
functions on the board, most obviously between executive and
non-executive directors, all directors must maintain a minimum
level of knowledge and understanding about the business so that
important problems can be identified and dealt with before they
bring the company down. Thus, in Re Richborough Furniture
Ltd81 a director was disqualified for three years, on the basis of
“lack of experience, knowledge and understanding. She did not
have enough experience or knowledge to know what she should
do in the face of the problems of pressing creditors, escalating
Crown debts and lack of capital. It seems that she was not
sufficiently skilful as regards the accounts functions to see that
the records were inadequate.” Disqualification of incompetent
directors has thus become a crucial tool in the enforcement of
directors’ standards of competence, perhaps more so than actions
for breach of the director’s general duty of care,82 which must be
funded by private litigants. The two areas of law will no doubt
continue to influence each other.
10–11
In this area, particular importance is attached by the courts to
failure by directors to file annual returns or, in future,
confirmation statements, produce audited accounts and to keep
proper accounting records.83 These are the practical expressions
of a more general view that all directors must keep themselves
au fait with the financial position of their company and make
sure that it complies with the reporting requirements of the
companies legislation, for otherwise they cannot know what
corrective action, if any, needs to be taken.84 Although this duty
may fall with particular emphasis on those responsible for the
financial side of the company, all directors must keep themselves
informed about the company’s basic financial position.85 On the
other hand, seeking and acting on competent outside advice
when financial difficulties arise will be an indication of
competence, even if the plan recommended does not pay off and
the company eventually collapses.86 It should also be
remembered that, in the disqualification area, the courts have
required a “marked degree” of negligence87 before declaring a
director unfit. There is a contrast here with wrongful trading and
the standard of care under the directors’ general duties88 where
there is no suggestion that a low standard of care is to be applied
to directors.89 It is suggested that this contrast is explained by the
fact that a disqualification order can often have the effect of
depriving the director of his livelihood and that, once unfitness is
found, a two-year disqualification is mandatory.
DISQUALIFICATION ON GROUNDS OTHER THAN UNFITNESS
Serious offences
10–12
The remaining provisions of the 1986 Act permit, but do not
require, the court to disqualify a director, on various grounds.
With one exception, disqualification here is based on a court
order. Disqualification by means of undertaking is not generally
available. These other grounds of disqualification will be dealt
with briefly, partly because they have not generated as much
controversy as the unfitness ground. Disqualifications under s.2
(disqualification on conviction of an indictable offence)
apparently constitute the second most common source (after
unfitness) for disqualification orders.90
In relation to serious offences, there are two routes to a
disqualification order, depending upon whether the person
concerned has actually been convicted of an offence. If there has
been a conviction, a disqualification order may be made against
a person, whether a director or not, who has committed an
indictable offence in connection with the promotion, formation,
management, liquidation or striking off of a company or in
connection with the receivership or management of its
property.91 Usually, the disqualification will be ordered by the
court by which the person is convicted and at the time of his or
her conviction. However, if the convicting court does not
consider the issue, the SS or the liquidator or any past or present
creditor or member of the company in relation to which the
offence was committed may apply to any court having
jurisdiction to wind up the company to impose the
disqualification.92 Here, too, the courts have taken a wide view
of what “in connection with the management of the company”
means in this context.93 Where a person has been convicted of an
equivalent offence outside Great Britain the SS may seek a
disqualification order from the High Court or Court of Session or
accept an undertaking from that person.94
Where there has not been a conviction, but the company is
being wound up, then if it appears that a person has been guilty
of the offence of fraudulent trading95 or has been guilty as an
officer96 of the company of any fraud in relation to it or any
breach of duty as an officer, then the court having jurisdiction to
wind up the company may impose a disqualification order.97
Disqualification in connection with civil liability for
fraudulent or wrongful trading
10–13
In addition to the array of civil orders which the court may make
under ss.213 and 214 of the Insolvency Act 1986 when it finds
fraudulent or wrongful trading,98 s.10 of the Disqualification Act
adds the power to make a disqualification order. The court may
act here on its own motion, that is, whether or not an application
is made to it by anyone for an order to be made. Since there are
only low levels to litigation to recover contributions in cases of
fraudulent and wrongful trading, the number of disqualifications
is also low.99
Failure to comply with reporting requirements
10–14
Again, there are separate provisions according to whether the
person to be disqualified has been convicted or not. If he or she
has been convicted of a summary offence in connection with a
failure to file a document with or give notice of a fact to the
Registrar, then the convicting court may disqualify that person if
in the previous five years he has had at least three convictions
(including the current one) or default orders against him for non-
compliance with the reporting requirements of the Companies
and Insolvency Acts.100 If the current conviction is on
indictment, then the provisions of s.2 (above) apply, but, where
the current conviction is summary, the fact that the earlier
convictions were on indictment does not prevent the convicting
summary court from taking them into account.101
Where there has been no conviction, the SS and the others
mentioned in s.16(2)102 may apply to the court having
jurisdiction to wind up the companies in question for
disqualification orders to be made on the grounds that the
respondent has been “persistently in default” in complying with
the reporting requirements of the Companies and Insolvency
Acts.103 The “three convictions or defaults in five years” rule
applies here too, but without prejudice to proof of persistent
default in any other manner.104 Since the offences involved in
these sections may be only summary ones, the maximum period
of disqualification is limited to five, instead of the usual 15,
years. Nevertheless, the fact that these provisions are in the Act
at all is a testimony to the importance attached recently to timely
filing of accounts and other documents. However, the
improvement recorded in this area may be due more to the
introduction of late filing penalties than the disqualification
orders.
REGISTER OF DISQUALIFICATION ORDERS
10–15
Crucial to the effective operation of the disqualification
machinery is that publicity should be given the names of those
who have been disqualified. Thus, the Act requires the SS to
create such a register of orders and undertakings, which register
is open to public inspection.105 The register is also to contain
details of any leave given to a disqualified person to act despite
the disqualification. However, either because of doubts about the
accuracy of the register or to relieve the Registrar of the need to
check it, the 2006 Act contains a power for the SS to make
regulations about the returns which companies have to make to
the Registrar about the appointment of directors and secretaries.
The regulations may require the return to contain the statement
in relation to a disqualified person that the leave of the court to
act has been obtained.106
BANKRUPTS
10–16
The prohibition on undischarged bankrupts acting as directors or
being involved in the management of companies can be traced
back to the Companies Act 1928. Although bankruptcy does not
necessarily connote any wrongdoing, the policy against
permitting those who have been so spectacularly unsuccessful in
the management of their own finances taking charge of other
people’s money is so self-evident that it has not proved
controversial. The prohibition is now contained in s.11 of the
1986 Act, which makes so acting a criminal offence,107 and the
main point of interest about it for present purposes is that it is an
automatic disqualification, not dependent upon the making of a
disqualification order by the court. In 2002 the prohibition was
extended to include acting in breach of a bankruptcy restriction
order or undertaking, themselves creations of the legislative
reforms of that year.108 Bankruptcy restriction orders and
undertakings, clearly modelled to some extent on directors’
disqualification orders and undertakings, put restrictions on a
former bankrupt’s activities after discharge from bankruptcy, in
general an earlier event than had previously been the case.
However, the disqualification is not absolute, because the
bankrupt or previous bankrupt may apply to the court for leave
to act in the management of a company, other than as an
insolvency practitioner.109 In other words, the statute really
reverses the burden of taking action, by placing it upon the
bankrupt to show that he or she may be safely involved in the
management of companies rather than upon the state to
demonstrate to a court that the bankrupt ought not to be allowed
to act.
OTHER CASES
10–17
Disqualification has become a popular legislative technique in
recent years. The 1986 Act itself applies to those in charge of
other corporate bodies as if they were companies formed under
the Companies Acts, such as building societies, incorporated
friendly societies, NHS foundation trusts, registered societies
and charitable incorporated organisations.110 Another extension
is to apply disqualification to the directors of companies for
breaches of provisions other than company law rules. Thus,
ss.9A–9E make provision for disqualification orders and
undertakings in relation to directors (and shadow directors) of
companies which have broken competition law where a court or
regulator is of the opinion that the director is in consequence
unfit to be involved in the management of a company. Finally,
breaches of sector-specific rules, such as in the banking sector,
could form the basis for disqualification, for example, on
grounds of unfitness, but the Government stopped short of
giving sectoral regulators disqualification powers under the 1986
Act: instead, they have to operate through the Insolvency
Service. Of course, sector-specific legislation may give sectoral
regulators disqualification powers in relation to the areas of
economic activity they regulate, as is the case with financial
regulators—but such provisions are outside the scope of this
chapter.
CONCLUSION
10–18
For many years the disqualification provisions of the successive
Companies Acts seemed to make little impact. Important in
principle as a technique for dealing with corporate wrongdoing
of one sort or another, especially on the part of directors, the
practical consequences of the provisions were limited. The
combination of the substantive reforms recommended by the
Cork Committee and of acceptance by Government that the
promotion of small, and not-so-small, businesses needed to be
accompanied by action to raise the standards of directors’
behaviour and to protect the public from the scheming and the
incompetent, brought the disqualification provisions to the fore.
Further, as we have seen in Ch.7,111 controversy about whether
directors whose companies are convicted of the proposed new
corporate killing offence should be disqualified from acting in
connection with businesses delayed progress on that reform
proposal, though in the end the legislation did not make use of
the disqualification technique. As to disqualification orders in
company law, judged by the level of disqualification orders and
undertakings, the provisions now have a substantial impact. An
independent survey112 found a widespread consensus that the
provisions performed a useful role and should be retained,
although they were certainly capable of improvement, especially
at the level of securing compliance with the disqualification
orders made.113
However, it would be wrong to see disqualification as solely a
response to abuses of limited liability within small companies.
There is some evidence that the public authorities use
disqualification to inflict reputational harm on directors of
companies which have failed in circumstances giving rise to
public condemnation and where no other remedy is readily
available. We noted above the disqualification of directors of
Barings Bank which collapsed as a result of failure to identify
and prevent large foreign exchange bets being placed by a junior
trader.114 Another example is the disqualification undertakings,
offered by the four directors of MG Rover Group Ltd after its
well-publicised collapse, and accepted by the SS. The company
had gone into administration in April 2005, owing creditors
nearly £1.3 billion, causing many employees to lose their jobs
and ending large-scale, British-owned car manufacturing. In this
case, the ground work for the disqualification had been provided
through a lengthy and expensive public investigation into the
collapse of the company.115 The removal of the investigation pre-
condition to the use of s.8 by the SS may increase this use of the
provision in the future.
1Report of the Review Committee on Insolvency Law and Practice, Cmnd. 8558 (1982),
para.1808.
2
Cmnd. 8558, para.1815.
3 This is still the principal legislation and references in this chapter to sections will be to
that Act, as amended, unless otherwise indicated.
4 1986 Act ss.6(3C), 8(1).
5 1986 Act ss.6 and 8.
6 1986 Act s.7.
7
1986 Act s.15A(1).
8 1986 Act s.16.
9 1986 Act ss.1 and 1A. See further below, para.10–2.
10
For the policy behind the 2015 Act in the disqualification area see BIS, Transparency
& Trust: Enhancing the Transparency of UK Company Ownership and Increasing Trust
in UK Business: Government Response, April 2014 (BIS/14/672) Ch.5–9.
111986 Act s.22(2A). The reference is to “Great Britain” rather than the “United
Kingdom” because Northern Ireland has separate disqualification legislation—The
Company Directors Disqualification (Northern Ireland) Order 2002—though its scope is
similar.
12
2006 Act s.1184.
13
DTI, Companies in 2001–2002 (2002), Table D1.
14
Companies House, Statistical Tables on Companies Registration Activities 2014–
2015, Table D1.
15
Though the courts had developed a summary procedure for dealing with non-
contested cases: Re Carecraft Construction Co Ltd [1994] 1 W.L.R. 172; and Practice
Direction [1999] B.C.C. 717. The summary procedure has effectively been overtaken by
the out-of-court undertaking, though in principle it is still available.
16
1986 Act ss.1 and 1A.
17 1986 Act s.8A. This is separate from the director’s power to apply to the court for
leave to act notwithstanding the undertaking, a power which applies also to orders: s.17.
See below, para.10–3.
18 Insolvency Rule r.7.47(1).
19
Re INS Realisations Ltd [2006] 2 B.C.L.C. 239—director not normally able to use the
section to challenge the facts on which the undertaking was premised, but in the
particular circumstances of that case the power was used to cause the undertaking to
cease to operate. See also Re Morija Plc [2008] 2 B.C.L.C. 313.
20
1986 Act ss.1(1) and 1A(1). If a court makes a disqualification order, it must cover all
the activities set out in the statute, but the court could give the disqualified director
limited leave to act despite the order. See Re Gower Enterprises (No.2) [1995] 2
B.C.L.C. 201; and Re Seagull Manufacturing Co Ltd [1996] 1 B.C.L.C. 51 and below.
21 Management of a company is thought to require involvement in the general
management and policy of the company and not just the holding of any post labelled
managerial, though in small companies it may not be possible to distinguish between
policy-setting and day-to-day management: R. v Campbell (1983) 78 Cr. App. R. 95 CA
(acting as a management consultant); Drew v HM Advocate, 1996 S.L.T. 1062; Re
Market Wizard Systems (UK) Ltd [1998] 2 B.C.L.C. 282.
22
1986 Act ss.1(1)(b) and 1A(1)(b).
23 1986 Act ss.22A–C and E–F and the Limited Liability Partnership Regulations 2001
(SI 2001/1090), reg.4(2). The disqualified director is also prohibited from acting as the
trustee of a charitable trust, whether that trust is incorporated or not: Charities Act 2011
ss.178 et seq., though the charity commissioners may give leave to act.
24 1986 Act ss.13 and 14. The equivalent offence in relation to acting when bankrupt has
been held to be one of strict liability (R. v Brockley (1993) 92 Cr. App. R. 385 CA) and
the arguments used to support that conclusion would seem equally applicable to the
offence of acting when disqualified.
25 1986 Act s.15(1)(a).
26 1986 Act s.15(1)(b). The various people made personally liable by s.15 are jointly and
severally liable with each other and with the company and any others who are for any
reason personally liable: s.15(2).
27 See Re Moorgate Metals Ltd [1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 503.
28 1986 Act ss.6(4) and 8(4).
29 1986 Act s.1A(2) applies the minima to undertakings as well.
30
Re Grayan Building Services Ltd [1995] Ch. 241 CA. In this case the Court of Appeal
held that the respondent could not reduce the period of disqualification by showing that,
despite past shortcomings, he was unlikely to offend again. Such evidence, however,
could be taken into account on an application for leave. See also Re Westmid Packing
Services Ltd [1998] 2 All E.R. 124 at 131–132 CA.
31
Re Sevenoaks Stationers (Retail) Ltd [1991] Ch. 164 at 176 CA.
32
The court distinguished between a top bracket of over ten years for “particularly
serious” cases; a middle bracket of six to ten years for serious cases “which do not merit
the top bracket”; and a minimum bracket for “not very serious” cases. See also Re
Westmid Packing Services Ltd [1998] 2 All E.R. 124 CA: fixing of length of
disqualification to be done on the basis of “common sense”)—ibid. at 132.
33
Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Worth [1994] 2 B.C.L.C. 113 CA, which
indeed puts the applicant under some costs pressure to apply then, if his application is
based on circumstances existing at the time of the order. If disqualification is by
undertaking, a separate application for leave will, of course, be necessary. Leave cannot
be given by the Secretary of State, only by the court.
34
Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Barnett [1998] 2 B.C.L.C. 64; Re
Britannia Homes Centres Ltd [2001] 2 B.C.L.C. 63: leave refused where director with
history of insolvencies wished to incorporate a new and wholly-owned company to carry
on trading in same line of business.
35 Re Cargo Agency Ltd [1992] B.C.L.C. 686; Re Chartmore Ltd [1990] B.C.L.C. 673;
Re Clenaware Systems Ltd [2014] 1 B.C.L.C. 447. The practice has been followed in
Scotland despite doubts whether the power to give leave confers upon the courts the
power to specify conditions: Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Palfreman
[1995] 2 B.C.L.C. 301. If the conditions attached by the court are not strictly complied
with, the director is in breach of the disqualification order and so exposed to personal
liability: Re Brian Sheridan Cars Ltd [1996] 1 B.C.L.C. 327.
36 Re Barings Plc (No.3) [2000] 1 W.L.R. 634; Re Tech Textiles [1998] 1 B.C.L.C. 259.
37
1986 Act s.15A(3)(4), insolvency being defined so as to include insolvent liquidation,
administration and administrative receivership.
38 1986 Act s.15A(5).
39
1986 Act s.15B(2) provides that the compensation may be ordered in favour of the
Secretary of State for distribution among the specified creditors (whoever they may be)
or, as with wrongful trading awards, take the form of a contribution to the assets of the
company. It is implicit in the second case that the company is in the hands of an
insolvency practitioner. It is likely that the Insolvency Service will favour the latter
method of distribution, if only because it avoids the costs of undertaking this task.
40 1986 Act s.7(1)(2A).
41
1986 Act s.15B(3).
42 Including a de facto director (s.22(4)), i.e. a person who acts as a director even though
he has not been validly appointed as a director or even though there has been no attempt
at all to appoint him as director: Re Kaytech International Plc [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 351
CA.
431986 Act s.22(5). On the meaning of “shadow director” see the previous chapter at
para.9–7 and, below, Ch.16 at para.16–8.
44
A company is insolvent if it goes into liquidation with insufficient assets to meet its
liabilities, if an administration order has been made in relation to the company or if an
administrative receiver is appointed: s.6(2). Thus, the disqualification provisions, unlike
the wrongful trading provisions, are not confined to companies which go into insolvent
liquidation. The court is specifically given power to look at the director’s conduct post-
insolvency. Sections 21A–C apply the Act to the specialised mechanisms for bank
insolvencies and administrations.
45
1986 Act s.7(1).
46
1986 Act s.7(2A).
47
Until 2015 this power was exercisable only on the basis of information obtained via
official investigation into the company (under a variety of powers). The s.8 power was
previously rarely used; it remains to be seen whether the reform will change that.
48
1986 Act s.6(1)(4), 8(4) and 1A(2).
49See A. Hicks, “Disqualification of Directors—Forty Years On” [1988] J.B.L. 27 at 35
and 38–40.
50 Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Ivens [1997] 2 B.C.L.C. 334 CA.
However, it would seem that a director cannot be disqualified on the basis of his conduct
of the non-lead companies alone.
51 And, indeed, post-insolvency activities: s.6(2).
52
The court may look at the conduct in relation to “one or more other companies or
overseas companies”: ss.6(1)(b),(1A) and 8(2),(2B).
53 1986 Act ss.8ZA(2), 8ZD(3).
54 1986 Act ss.8ZA(1), 8ZD(1).
55
1986 Act ss.8ZC(1), 8ZE(1).
56
BIS Ch.4 (“Opaque corporate control through irresponsible ‘front’ directors”).
57
See above, fn.1 at para.1809.
58 See above, fn.1 at para.1818.
59In Scotland, where there are no Official Receivers, even compulsory liquidations are
handled by insolvency practitioners and the potential scope of the problem is
accordingly greater.
60
See S. Wheeler, “Directors’ Disqualification: Insolvency Practitioners and the
Decision-making Process” (1995) 15 L.S. 283. Moreover, the statutory scheme does not
bite if the company is simply struck off the register (see below, paras 33–35 et seq.)
without going through any of these procedures.
61 1986 Act s.7A and SI 2016/180. The obligation is to provide any information about
conduct which may help the Insolvency Service decide whether to implement
disqualification proceedings. Previously, this information was to be provided by the
insolvency practitioner only if the Service asked for it. The request power now exists in
relation to all persons other than the insolvency practitioners (s.7(4)).
62National Audit Office, The Insolvency Service Executive Agency: Company Director
Disqualification (1993) H.C. 907.
63
1986 Act s.7(2). The court may give leave to commence the application out of time,
though the Secretary of State must show a good reason for any extension: Re Copecrest
Ltd [1994] 2 B.C.L.C. 284 CA; Re Instant Access Properties Ltd [2012] 1 B.C.L.C. 710.
64
Re Manlon Trading Ltd [1996] Ch. 136; Davies v UK [2006] 2 B.C.L.C. 351 ECtHR
(a case decided in 2002); Eastaway v UK [2006] 2 B.C.L.C. 361 ECtHR. However, in
the last of these cases the Court of Appeal refused to set aside the disqualification
agreement entered into by the director under the Carecraft procedure (above, fn.15),
even though the ECtHR had held the proceedings to have taken too long: Eastaway v
Secretary of State for Trade and Industry [2007] B.C.C. 550. The National Audit Office,
above, fn.62 para.18; found that the Insolvency Service in most cases took nearly the full
two-year period permitted to bring an application and that up to a further four years
might elapse before a disqualification order was made, during which period the director
was free to carry on business with limited liability.
65See para.10–10, below and the extra-judicial remarks of Lord Hoffmann, Fourth
Annual Leonard Sainer Lecture in (1997) Company Lawyer 194.
66
R. v Secretary of State for Trade and Industry Ex p. McCormick [1998] B.C.C. 379
CA; DC v United Kingdom [2000] B.C.C. 710 ECtHR.
67Official Receiver v Stern [2000] 1 W.L.R. 2230 CA. Contrast the decision in Saunders
v United Kingdom [1998] 1 B.C.L.C. 362 ECtHR.
68
Re Pantmaenog Timber Co Ltd [2001] 4 All E.R. 588 CA.
69 1986 Act s.12C (replacing the former s.9).
70This includes not just the “lead” company but all other companies, including overseas
ones, brought in under s.6(1)(b).
71
“Those who trade under the regime of limited liability and who avail themselves of
the privileges of that regime must accept the standards of probity and competence to
which the law requires company directors to conform” (per Neill LJ in Re Grayan
Building Services Ltd [1995] Ch. 241 CA).
72 Of course, simple fraud will be a basis for disqualification. As a proposition of
substantive law this is straightforward; the complications are procedural. See Secretary
of State v Doffmann (No.2) [2011] 2 B.C.L.C. 541.
73Cork Committee, para.1813. For the operation of the rule forbidding re-use of
corporate names in this situation, see Ch.9, above. For examples in the disqualification
case law, see Re Travel Mondial (UK) Ltd [1991] B.C.L.C. 120; Re Linvale Ltd [1993]
B.C.L.C. 654; Re Swift 736 Ltd [1993] B.C.L.C. 1.
74 Re Keypak Homecare Ltd [1990] B.C.L.C. 440.
75
Re Sevenoaks Stationers (Retail) Ltd [1991] Ch. 164 CA; Secretary of State for Trade
and Industry v McTighe (No.2) [1996] 2 B.C.L.C. 477 CA.
76Re Synthetic Technology Ltd [1993] B.C.C. 549; Secretary of State v Van Hengel
[1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 545; Secretary of State for Business Innovation and Skills v Doffman
(No.2) [2011] 2 B.C.L.C. 541.
77 Re Stanford Services Ltd [1987] B.C.L.C. 607.
78 Re Sevenoaks Stationers (Retail) Ltd [1991] Ch. 164 CA at 184.
79
Re Barings Plc (No.5) [2000] 1 B.C.L.C. 523 CA. The case involved the insolvency
of an old and respected merchant bank brought about by the huge losses generated by
the unauthorised trading activities of a junior employee whose activities were neither
well understood nor effectively monitored by his superiors.
80
Re Barings Plc (No.5) [2000] 1 B.C.L.C. 523 at 536. See also Re Westmid Packing
Services Ltd [1998] 2 All E.R. 124; and Re Vintage Hallmark Plc [2007] 1 B.C.L.C.
788.
81
Re Richborough Furniture Ltd [1996] 1 B.C.L.C. 507.
82
See para.16–15.
83
These may be ingredients in a finding of unfitness, even though, as we see below,
para.10–14, non-compliance with the reporting requirements of the legislation is a
separate ground of disqualification, albeit only for up to five years. For further
discussion of what is required in this area see Ch.21.
84
Re Firedart Ltd [1994] 2 B.C.L.C. 340; Re New Generation Engineers Ltd [1993]
B.C.L.C. 435.
85 Re City Investment Centres Ltd [1992] B.C.L.C. 956; Secretary of State v Van Hengel
[1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 545; Re Majestic Recording Studios Ltd [1989] B.C.L.C. 1; Re
Continental Assurance Co of London Plc [1977] 1 B.C.L.C. 48; Re Kaytech
International Plc [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 351 CA.
86 Re Douglas Construction Services Ltd [1988] B.C.L.C. 397. Conversely, ignoring a
plan produced by outside accountants is likely to be characterised as “obstinately and
unjustifiably backing [the director’s] own assessment of the company’s business”: Re
GSAR Realisations Ltd [1993] B.C.L.C. 409.
87 See above, fn.78.
88
See para.9–6, above, and para.16–16, below.
89
Of course, keeping an insolvent company going can be grounds for disqualification
for being unfit but only in strong cases. See, for example, Re Living Images Ltd [1996] 1
B.C.L.C. 348, where the directors were aware of the company’s parlous condition and
keeping it going was described as “a gamble at long odds” and “the taking of
unwarranted risks with creditors’ money”, so that there was a lack of probity involved
and not just negligence. cf. the refusal to make a disqualification order in Re Dawson
Print Group Ltd [1987] B.C.L.C. 601; Re Bath Glass Ltd [1988] B.C.L.C. 329; Re CU
Fittings Ltd [1989] B.C.L.C. 556; and Secretary of State v Gash [1997] 1 B.C.L.C. 341.
90 A. Hicks, Disqualification of Directors: No Hiding Place for the Unfit? (ACCA
Research Report 59, 1998), p.35, found that in 1996 about one quarter of those at that
time disqualified were in that position as a result of a s.2 disqualification. The proportion
has probably fallen since then, with the rise of unfitness disqualifications, especially via
undertakings. The Companies House figures (above, fn.14) do not distinguish among
disqualifications on any of the grounds laid down in ss.2–5 of the Act, but indicate that
in 2014/15 217 out of 1227 disqualifications took place under ss.2–5.
91 1986 Act s.2.
92 1986 Act s.16(2). If the criminal court does consider the matter and decide not to
impose disqualification, it is an abuse of process to pursue the same issue before a civil
court: Secretary of State v Weston [2014] B.C.C. 581. However, the courts have
permitted disqualification orders to be pursued in such cases under other grounds for
disqualification contained in the Act: Secretary of State v Rayna [2001] 2 B.C.L.C. 48;
Re Denis Hilton Ltd [2002] 1 B.C.L.C. 302.
93
R. v Goodman [1994] 1 B.C.L.C. 349 CA (insider dealing by a director in the shares
of his company); R. v Georgiou (1988) 4 B.C.C. 625; R. v Ward, The Times, 10 April
1997 (conspiracy to defraud by creating a false market in shares during a takeover bid);
R. v Creggy [2008] 1 B.C.L.C. 625 CA (facilitating criminal activity by third parties).
94
1986 Act s.5A introduced in 2015.
95
See para.9–5.
96
Also included are the usual cast of liquidators, receivers and administrative receivers
and also shadow directors: s.4(1)(b) and (2).
97
1986 Act s.4, upon application by those listed in s.16(2). It is unclear whether the
breach of duty referred to must involve the commission of a criminal offence, but the use
of the word “guilty” suggests so.
98 See para.9–8.
99
No disqualification order was made under s.10 in the period 2010–2015 (Companies
House, above, fn.14) though it is possible that disqualification in relation to fraudulent
trading was imposed in a few cases under s.4.
100
1986 Act s.5.
101
Contrast the wording of subs.(1) and (2) of s.5.
102 See above, text attached to fn.92.
103 1986 Act s.3.
104
1986 Act s.3(2).
105
1986 Act s.18 and the Companies (Disqualification Orders) Regulations 2009 (SI
2009/2471).
106 CA 2006 s.1189. At the time of writing no regulations have been made.
107 Acting in breach of the prohibition also attracts personal liability for the company’s
debts (s.15—though this may not be of much utility in relation to bankrupts) and could,
apparently, give rise to the making of a disqualification order under s.2 (above, para.10–
9): R. v Young [1990] B.C.C. 549 CA).
108These changes were effected by Sch.20 to the Enterprise Act 2002, introducing a
new Sch.4A into the Insolvency Act 1986.
109
IA1986 ss.11(1) and 390(4)(a).
110 1986 Act ss.22A–C, E–F.
111 See above, para.7–45.
112By A. Hicks; see fn.90, above. The report makes a number of interesting and
thought-provoking suggestions for reform. For a more sceptical account see R. Williams,
“Disqualifying Directors: a Remedy Worse than the Disease?” (2007) 7 J.C.L.S. 213.
113 Companies in 2005–2006 (above, fn.13) reveals that some 90 prosecutions for
breach of disqualification orders or of the prohibition on bankrupts acting as directors
were launched in that year, producing 81 convictions. More recent statistics appear not
to be available. It is difficult to know whether this relatively modest total indicates a
high level of compliance with the disqualifications or a low level of detection of
breaches.
114
See above, fn.79.
115
Department of Business Innovation and Skills, Press Release, 9 May 2011.
CHAPTER 11
LEGAL CAPITAL, MINIMUM CAPITAL AND
VERIFICATION
MEANING OF CAPITAL
11–1
In the previous two chapters we saw how the law applies
sanctions to the controllers of companies who abuse the facility
of limited liability. In particular, personal liability for the
company’s obligations and disqualification from being involved
in the management of a company in the future are techniques
used by the law in these cases. Both are ex post techniques, i.e.
the sanctions are applied after the event, normally after the
company has fallen into insolvency. Sanctions are applied on the
basis, most often, that the court has concluded that the
controllers have infringed some broad and general standard laid
down for the assessment of their conduct, for example, engaging
in “wrongful” trading or displaying “unfit” conduct. In this
chapter and the next two, by contrast, we consider ex ante
approaches to controlling abuse of limited liability, i.e. the rules,
generally of a precise and detailed character, which apply before
the company is in insolvency or even in the region of insolvency.
Given that creditors’ claims are confined to the assets of the
company, the techniques now discussed seek to ensure that the
shareholders contribute to or maintain in the company an
appropriate level of assets for the benefit of creditors. A good
level of shareholder-contributed assets, it can be argued, will
both reduce the chances of the company falling into insolvency
and increase the likely size of the pay-out to creditors if
insolvency does occur. This idea can be given expression in a
number of ways, which will be explored in these chapters.
The traditional protective mechanism of company law in this
area, which is as old as limited liability itself, involves laying
down rules about the raising and maintenance of “capital”.
“Capital” is a word of many meanings,1 but in company law it is
used in a very restricted sense. It connotes the value of the assets
contributed to the company by those who subscribe for its
shares. By and large, the value of what the company receives
from investors in exchange for its shares constitutes its capital.2
One talks about the value of what is received, rather than the
assets themselves, because those assets will change form in the
course of the business activities of the company. If the company
receives cash in exchange for its shares, the directors will turn
that cash into other types of asset in order to promote its
business: indeed, if they did not, they would probably be in
breach of duty. So, the focus is on using the number in the
company’s accounts which indicates the value of what was
received by the company in the exchange for the shares to
constrain the actions of the company in various ways, in UK law
principally to constrain the company’s freedom to make
distributions to its shareholders.
The value of the assets which the company receives in
exchange for its shares (its legal capital) will normally be less
than the total value of the company’s assets. Even where the
company has not yet begun to trade, it may have raised money in
ways other than share issues. For example, it may have borrowed
money from a bank or a group of banks, which loan contributes
to the company’s cash assets. The value of such loans does not
count towards its legal capital, however. This is because the aim
of the capital rules is to protect creditors as a class and only
assets contributed by shareholders do this effectively.3 The cash
provided by the lender will be exactly counterbalanced by an
increase on the liabilities side of the company’s balance sheet, so
that the creditors as a whole are no better off. Once a company
has begun trading and if it has done so profitably, it will have
assets which represent the profits. These, too, do not count as
part of the company’s legal capital: they may have been earned,
at least in part, by deploying the shareholders’ contributions to
the business but the profits were not contributed by the
shareholders. Nevertheless, the totality of the surplus of assets
over the liabilities is a very important accounting concept and is
often referred to as “the shareholders’ equity” or the company’s
“net asset value”. The law distinguishes between the company’s
“net asset value” and the value of the assets contributed by the
shareholders (its legal capital). Broadly, the company is free to
distribute to the shareholders the difference between the net asset
value and the legal capital value—provided that is a positive
number! By contrast, therefore, if the company trades
unsuccessfully, it may run through any profits made in previous
years and begin to eat into the value of the assets contributed by
its shareholders. In this situation its net asset value may fall
below the value of its legal capital, and no distribution is
permitted to be made. In short, the value of the assets
contributed by the shareholders is not a measure of the
company’s net worth, which may be higher or lower than the
legal capital figure at any one time and only by chance will the
two figures be the same.
11–2
An alternative use of the legal capital figure is to use it to
identify the amount the shareholders must contribute to the
company’s assets before it is permitted to begin trading. Such
rules are called minimum or initial capital rules. British law has
never made much use of this concept. Minimum capital has been
required of public companies, since the implementation in the
UK of the Second European Company Law Directive of 1977,4
but private companies are not subject to the rule and,
historically, apart from a short period in the early years of
modern company law in the middle of the nineteenth century,
British law has not attached importance to minimum capital
requirements for any class of company.
However, and contrary to what is sometimes thought, British
law currently does make use of legal capital to constrain to a
significant extent distributions to shareholders. On this approach
the law leaves companies wholly or substantially free to decide
their own level of legal capital, but attaches legal consequences
to the amount of legal capital the company in fact chooses to
raise. This second policy has been central to British company
law since its origins and remains so. From the early days the
courts have laid down that, given limited liability, “it is clearly
against the intention of the legislature that any portion of the
capital should be returned to the shareholders without the
statutory conditions being complied with”.5 The rule against the
return of capital to shareholders is elaborated in a three main
ways. First, as noted, the value of the company’s legal capital is
used as a yardstick to measure the amount of a company’s assets
which may be returned to the shareholders by way of a dividend
or other form of distribution. We consider this aspect of the “no
return” policy in Ch.12. All modern jurisdictions place
constraints on distributions to shareholders but it is controversial
whether such rules should be based on the concept of legal
capital, as the British ones currently are. Secondly, the
repurchase or redemption of its shares by the company may
occur only through tightly controlled procedures which aim to
maintain the value of the company’s legal capital. Thirdly, the
company may reduce the value of its legal capital in its accounts
only through procedures which are designed to protect the
interests of the creditors. The second and third manifestations of
the “no return” policy are considered in Ch.13, together with the
rules prohibiting a company from giving financial assistance to a
person in connection with the acquisition by that person of its
shares. The second and third sets of rules are normally lumped
together under the heading of “capital maintenance”, though it is
debatable whether the financial assistance rules are linked to the
notion of legal capital.
In this chapter we elaborate some of the basic elements of the
concept of legal capital and consider in particular the role of the
minimum or initial legal capital rule.
NOMINAL VALUE AND SHARE PREMIUMS
Nominal value
11–3
We have talked so far about legal capital being the amount that
the company receives from those who subscribe for its shares.
Very broadly, this is true, but the law arrives at this result in a
surprisingly complex way. This is because the law distinguishes
between the “nominal” value of the share and any amount
received above the nominal or “par” value, which is referred to
as the “premium”. The Act stipulates that shares in a limited
company “must each have a fixed nominal value” and that an
allotment of shares not meeting this requirement is void.6 In
other words a monetary value needs to be attached to the
company’s shares. In consequence, one talks of the company
having issued a certain number of “£1 shares” or “10p shares”
and so on. The par value is a doubtfully useful concept because
it does not normally indicate the price at which the share is likely
to be issued to investors; still less the price at which the share is
likely to trade in the market after issue. The only linkage
between the nominal value of the share and the price the
subscriber pays for it is the rule that a share may not be issued at
less than its nominal value7—often referred to as the “no
discount” rule.8 However, the company, whilst being obliged to
attach a nominal value to the share, maintains full control over
its level. This freedom, coupled with the “no discount” rule,
gives the company an incentive to keep the nominal value of the
share low in relation to its issue price. The lower the nominal
value, the less likely the company is to find itself in the situation,
either now or in the future, where investors will be prepared to
buy its shares only at less than their nominal value.
If a further tranche of shares already in issue is offered to the
public, then the par value is likely to be even less related to the
purchase price. Suppose a company has initially issued shares at
par, has traded successfully, re-invested the profits and seeks
capital for further expansion. The second tranche of shares will
naturally be issued at a price higher than par; otherwise, the
second set of shareholders would obtain a disproportionately
large interest in the company. In effect, they would be obtaining
an interest in the profits earned in the past without having
contributed any of the capital which was used to earn them. The
situation can be rectified by setting the share price on the second
issue so that it reflects the total value of the shareholders’
interest in the company. In the case of publicly traded
companies, this will be what market price of the share reflects.
The CLR contemplated abolishing par value for private
companies,9 but eventually resiled from the proposal. The
Second Directive was thought to require the retention of par
value, or something very much like it,10 for public companies,
and the transitional difficulties likely to arise when a company
moved from private to public were thought to militate against
this reform.11 So, unless and until the Second Directive is
amended on this point, par values will remain part of the law.
No issue of shares at a discount
11–4
For investors the nominal value requirement is potentially
misleading because it tells them nothing about the market price
of the share or its value measured in any other way. Does the
rule, which was established by the courts in the nineteenth
century,12 that shares must not be issued at a discount to their
nominal par value act as a protection for creditors? The common
law rule is now stated in the Act,13 which specifically provides
that, if the shares should be so issued, the allottee is liable to pay
to the company the amount of the discount with interest.14 This
provision is of some value to creditors, but of only limited value,
given the company’s control over the setting of the nominal
value. The creditor is probably more interested in the actual
price at which the share was issued and in the total value of the
consideration received by the company from its share issue. In
fact, it could be argued that the rule against discounts to nominal
value harms creditors, at least where the company nears
insolvency. Suppose that, because of the unsuccessful trading of
the company, its shares are in fact trading on the market at less
than par. The company needs to raise new capital. No sensible
investor will pay more than the market price for the shares and
yet the Act seems to prevent the company from recognising the
economic reality of its situation in the pricing of any new issue,
which may help it back to solvency.15 Yet, in this situation
creditors will benefit if the legal capital of the company is
increased, no matter how little the company receives for any one
of its shares. Any contribution from shareholders increases the
amount available to satisfy the claims of the creditors.
In fact, there are a number of ways around this problem,
though it cannot be guaranteed that in every situation one will be
available. For example, a new class of share may be created with
a lower par value but otherwise with rights substantially the
same as the existing shares. This new class of share can be
issued without infringing the prohibition on issuing shares at a
discount.
Nevertheless, as noted, the risk that the par value rule will
hamper the company in the future gives companies some
incentive to fix low par values initially and to raise most of the
consideration for the shares by way of premium, so that the par
value displays an even more remote relationship to the issue
price than it might otherwise do.
11–5
It might be argued that the rule is better understood as a
protection for the shareholders. The rule, it might be said, was
intended to protect existing shareholders from directors who
proposed to devalue (or “dilute”) the existing shareholders’
interest in the company by issuing shares to new shareholders
too cheaply. However, dilution arises only if the shares are
issued to new investors at a price which is lower than the current
market price of the shares, so that the “no shares at a discount”
rule is not well adapted to shareholder protection either. It will
be under-protective of shareholders where the market price is
above nominal value and over-protective where it is below.
Indeed, what is surprising from a shareholders’ perspective is
that there is no precise statutory obligation laid on the company
to issue shares at a premium, where the market will bear one.16
This is probably because the company may have a number of
good reasons to contract on the basis that the share will be issued
at less than its full market price.17 However, the directors’ duty
to promote the success of the company for the benefit of its
members18 will normally require the directors to issue shares at
the best obtainable price; otherwise the company will be
overpaying for its capital, just as it would be if it bought raw
materials at above market price.19
The share premium
11–6
It is clear that the amount received by the company by way of
the nominal value of the shares issued constitutes part of its legal
capital. The amount (often much more significant) received by
way of premium is today treated in much the same way. Prior to
1948, when companies issued shares at a premium, the value of
the premium was treated differently from the par value. Legal
capital was regarded as determined by the nominal or par value
of the shares; if they had been issued at a price above par the
excess was not “capital” and, indeed, constituted part of the
distributable surplus which the company, if it wished, could
return to the shareholders by way of dividend.20 This was, of
course, a ridiculous rule, except on the basis that it might be an
indirect way of subverting the capital-based distribution rules. If
the price paid for the shares was £100,000, the amount received
by the company was also £100,000 (assuming no transaction
costs) and it should make no difference to the analysis whether
the £100,000 was obtained by issuing 100,000 £1 shares at par
or by issuing 100,000 1p shares at £1 (i.e. at a premium of 99p
per share). In either case, the issue price (£1 in both cases)
determined the amount raised by the company, whilst the par
value, set by the company, is a figure determined in order to give
the company maximum flexibility under the Act.21 This situation
was changed, however, by the 1948 Act. The rule, now stated in
s.610 of the 2006 Act, is that a sum equal to the aggregate
amount or value of the premiums shall be transferred to a “share
premium account” which, in general, has to be treated as if it
were part of the paid-up share capital. However, the Act does not
fully assimilate share capital and the share premium. It is still
necessary to refer expressly to both, and for the company, in its
annual accounts and reports, to distinguish between the share
capital account and the share premium account. What, if it were
not for arbitrary par values, would be a single item—capital—
has to be treated as two distinct items, albeit for most purposes
treated identically.
11–7
However, share capital and share premium are not treated as
wholly identical, though the 2006 Act has narrowed some of the
differences between them. Section 610 provides two
“exceptions” and two “reliefs” for the share premium account
which do not apply to the capital account. The first exception is
that a company may apply the share premium account in paying
up bonus shares.22 A bonus share is a share issued to the existing
shareholders, without requiring any payment from them, but is
paid for, in this case, by reducing the share premium account.23
Since the effect of this transaction is to reduce the share
premium account but to increase the share capital account by an
equivalent amount, it is wholly unobjectionable from the
creditors’ point of view,24 and it is hardly an exception to the
main rule laid down by s.610. It would, of course, be impossible
thus to apply share capital account but to apply share premium
account in this way is unobjectionable since the only effect is to
convert it, or a part of it, to share capital proper. The second
exception is that the share premium account may be applied in
writing off the expenses of or the commissions paid on the issue
of the shares which generated the premiums.25 This is a real
exception, but now is a relatively minor contrast with share
capital. Within limits, share capital may also be used to pay
commission.26 Although the rule in relation to the share premium
account is somewhat more broadly phrased than that relating to
the capital account, the share premium rule is now tighter than it
was previously.27
More important (and more interesting) are the “reliefs”.
Section 610 (as did its predecessors) expressly applies to issues
at a premium “whether for cash or otherwise”. The result of this
was held to be that if, say, on a merger one Company (A)
acquired the shares of another (B) in consideration of an issue of
A’s own shares and the value of B’s shares exceeded the
nominal value of those issued by A, a share premium account
had to be established in respect of the excess.28 The result of this
was that B’s undistributed profits formerly available for
distribution by way of dividend ceased to be distributable. This
caused something of a furore in commercial circles. However, in
1980 the question was again litigated and the earlier decision
fully upheld.29 In consequence, “merger relief” was introduced in
the Companies Act 1981. The general effect of the merger relief
provisions30 is that the premium does not have to be transferred
to the share premium account when, pursuant to a merger
arrangement, one company has acquired at least 90 per cent of
each31 class of equity shares32 of another in exchange for an
allotment of its equity shares at a premium.
The Act also modifies (rather than removes) the requirement
for a transfer to the share premium account in certain cases of
reconstruction within a group of companies.33 The relief applies
in the case of issues at a premium by a wholly-owned subsidiary
in consideration of a transfer to it of non-cash assets from
another company in the group comprising the holding company
and its wholly-owned subsidiaries. In this case the company
issuing the shares is permitted to value the assets received, not
by reference to their market value, but by reference to the cost of
their acquisition by the transferor company or their value in the
books of the transferor company. In this way, the value of the
assets received in exchange for the shares will often be
understated, but, to the extent that this understated value in fact
exceeds the nominal value of the shares issued, the excess must
still be transferred to the share premium account.34 If this relief is
available on the facts of a particular case, the more extensive
merger relief is not.35
Finally, the Secretary of State is empowered by s.614 to make
regulations providing further relief in relation to premiums other
than cash premiums or for modifying the reliefs in the Act (but
has not done so).
MINIMUM CAPITAL
11–8
With the above preliminaries, we can turn to an analysis of the
minimum capital rule. As we have noted, as a result of the
Second Directive,36 a minimum capital requirement was
introduced for public companies. Section 761 requires that the
nominal value of the company’s allotted share capital meet a
certain minimum level That was set at the derisory level (for a
public company) of £50,000 (or, currently, €57,100),37 though
that is double the amount required by the Directive.38 Moreover,
that £50,000 (or assets of equivalent value) does not have to be
handed over to the company at the time of issue of the shares. It
is enough, as with all share issues by public companies, that one
quarter of the nominal value of the shares be paid at the time of
issue.39 The rest may remain unpaid, though of course subject to
being called up by the company at a later date or in its
liquidation. Nevertheless, the minimum capital requirement puts
a little pressure on public companies not to issue shares at a
hefty premium (because the premium does not count towards the
required minimum). However, the Act retains its traditional
aversion to minimum capital requirements in respect of private
companies, where none is imposed. This is said to have been a
major factor behind the incorporation in England of companies
from other EU countries which applied minimum capital
requirements to their equivalents of private companies.40
In the relatively unusual case of a company being formed
directly as a public company, the minimum capital requirement
operates, not as a condition of its formation, but as a condition of
its commencing business.41 In order to commence business (or to
exercise any borrowing powers—an important addition) it must
apply to the Registrar for a “trading certificate”42 (in addition to
the formation certificate which it will already have obtained);
and the condition for the issuance of a trading certificate is that
the nominal value of the company’s allotted share capital must
be not less than the required or “authorised” minimum.43 The
company is under some pressure to obtain the trading certificate,
because if it does not do so within a year from incorporation, it
may be wound up by the Court and the Secretary of State may
petition for that to happen.44 A public company which trades or
borrows without a certificate is liable to a fine, as is any officer
of the company (including therefore its directors) who is in
default.45 However, the interests of third parties are properly
protected in this case. Transactions entered into by the company
in such a case are valid, and further, if the company fails to
comply with its obligations, the directors of the company are
jointly and severally liable to indemnify third parties in respect
of any loss or damage suffered.46 Thus, personal liability of the
directors, criminal and civil, operates to give them a strong
incentive not to trade without a trading certificate.
In the more usual case of a company becoming public upon
conversion from private status, the requirement that the
company’s allotted capital be not less than the authorised
minimum operates as a condition for the re-registration of the
private company as a public one.47
If the nominal value of the company’s allotted share capital
meets the authorised minimum, on either of the occasions
described above, it will normally remain at that level thereafter.
This is because the nominal value of the shares does not change,
no matter how much the value of the company may decline.
However, in relatively rare cases the nominal value of the
company’s allotted capital might subsequently fall below the
authorised minimum. There is no general provision in the Act
dealing with this eventuality. Rather, provision is made on an ad
hoc basis. Thus, if under the reduction of capital procedure48 the
company’s capital is reduced below the authorised minimum, the
normal requirement is that the company must re-register as a
private company before the reduction of capital order is
finalised.49 Further, the Secretary of State has power to alter the
authorised minimum by regulation (subject to affirmative
resolution).50 Were that alteration to be in an upward direction,
the Secretary of State also has the power to require existing
public companies to bring their nominal values into line with the
new authorised minimum or to re-register as a private
company.51
Objections to the minimum capital requirement
11–9
There are two objections which can be made to minimum capital
rules. First, company laws normally set only one (as in the UK)
or a small number of minimum capital rules (for example, one
for private and another for public companies), but in fact, to be
effective, the minimum capital requirement ought to be related to
the riskiness of the business which the company undertakes.
General minimum capital requirements tend either to be too low
effectively to protect creditors (as in the case of the current
British requirement) or too high, in which case they reduce
competition (by discouraging new entrants into the field) whilst
over-protecting creditors. However, adjusting capital
requirements to the riskiness of the company’s business would
be a complex and continuing activity, as is shown by the special
regulation necessary to implement such a principle in those
industries, for example banking and insurance, where capital
adequacy requirements are taken seriously (and also where
“capital” means net asset value, not “legal” capital). Thus, it is
not surprising that the approach of company laws to minimum
capital requirements is relatively crude; and in practice in
developed economies tends towards the “too low” end of the
spectrum, thus conferring no substantial protection on creditors
but conceivably discouraging the incorporation of companies.
If, therefore, the minimum capital requirement has no claim to
be a genuine assessment of the amount of risk capital the
company needs to survive the vicissitudes of its business, could
it nevertheless be justified as a “cushion” of assets provided by
the shareholders for the protection of the creditors? This is also a
difficult argument to sustain. The creditors need the protection of
an asset cushion when the company begins to trade unprofitably.
A minimum capital requirement imposed at the time the
company commences trading does not guarantee any particular
level of assets being available for the creditors at this later date
or when the company goes into an insolvency procedure. For
example, a minimum capital requirement of, say, £3,000 for a
private company, even if paid in cash, could soon be returned
quite legitimately to the incorporators by means of salary
payments for services rendered to the company52 or it could be
satisfied by the contribution to the company by the incorporators
of a depreciating asset, such as a second-hand car. Thus,
minimum capital rules are likely to be ineffective beyond a very
short initial period unless coupled with rules which require the
directors to take action if the net value of the company’s actual
assets declines below the value of its legal capital.
The Act does in fact contain a rule which requires action on
the part of the company if its net asset value falls below a certain
proportion of its legal capital. However, this rule is not linked to
the minimum capital requirement and would therefore survive
even if the authorised minimum were abolished. Nor does the
rule specify the substantive action the company should take in
this situation. Section 656 requires a public company to convene
an extraordinary meeting of the shareholders if the net value of
its assets falls below one half of its called-up share capital,
which may be, and typically will be, far in excess of the
authorised minimum.53 The section does not require the
shareholders or the directors to take any particular action in this
situation (for example, cause the company to cease trading or
raise further capital from the shareholders).54 This section seems
not to be very important in practice, probably because, before it
becomes operative, large lenders will have exercised rights
under their loan contracts to replace the failing management or
otherwise to redress the situation55 or the wrongful trading
provisions56 will have required the directors to take corrective
action. Consequently, it can be argued that, at the initial stage,
the minimum capital requirement is too low to confer substantial
protection on creditors and that subsequent adverse
developments in the company’s trading ability are dealt with
through mechanisms other than those which focus on the
minimum capital.57
DISCLOSURE AND VERIFICATION
11–10
Whether or not a legal system imposes a minimum capital
requirement, there are obvious arguments in favour of requiring
the company to disclose the amount it has raised by way of the
issuance of its shares and providing some assurance that the
amounts stated in the capital accounts are accurate. This
information will facilitate creditor self-help, i.e. making it easier
for creditors to decide whether to lend to the company and on
what terms. The extent of the facilitation should not be over-
estimated. It will perhaps be useful at the point of issuance of the
shares, but the creditor is really interested in the company’s
overall net asset position which, as the company trades, is likely
to be more and more divorced from its legal capital figure.58
Thus, the creditor is likely to pay more attention to the
verification of the company’s assets and liabilities as a whole,
not just the amounts raised through share issues; and that
assurance is provided, to the extent that it is, through the
company’s annual financial statements and their audit.59 In
addition, those who are shareholders at the time the shares are
issued will have an interest in knowing and verifying the
amounts raised through share issues, in order to be satisfied that
new shareholders are not being admitted to the company too
cheaply.60
UK company law has developed over time a number of rules
which address the above policies, and they were substantially
added to when the Second Directive was implemented in the
UK.
Initial statement and return of allotments
11–11
When a company is formed, assuming it is limited by shares, the
application for registration must contain a statement of capital
and initial shareholdings. This requires disclosure of information
relating to the totality of the shares to be taken by the subscribers
and to their individual subscriptions. In particular, the number of
shares, their aggregate nominal amount, the amounts, if any, to
be left unpaid and the prescribed rights attached to the shares
must be disclosed.61 In practice, the answer will often be one £1
share taken by each of two people, upon which nothing is paid
up, the two people being employees of a company formation
business, which has created a shelf private company. When more
serious amounts of shares are issued at a later date, similar
information has to be given to the Registrar of companies via a
“return of allotments”.62 Thus, data about those to whom shares
of various classes have been issued,63 the amounts paid for the
shares and the main rights and obligations attached to those
shares is public information, but this is a disclosure provision,
not a provision which regulates the amount or type of share the
company issues. Although it is a criminal offence knowingly or
recklessly to deliver a false statement to the Registrar,64 these
provisions do not otherwise provide verification of the
information delivered.
Abolition of authorised capital
11–12
The 2006 Act did away with the former concept of “authorised
capital”, as recommended by the CLR.65 This was a concept
which sounded important but which fulfilled no identifiable
creditor-protection role. Under the old law, a company with a
share capital (unless it was an unlimited company) was required
to state in its memorandum “the amount of the share capital with
which [it] proposes to be registered and the division of that share
capital into shares of a fixed amount”.66 Until the authorised
capital was allotted, i.e. an investor agreed to take some shares in
exchange for a consideration provided to the company, the
authorised capital in no way increased the company’s assets. The
company’s authorised capital might have been 10 million shares
of £1 each, but if only two of those shares had been issued, say
at par, then its legal capital was £2. If anything, authorised
capital served to confuse the potential investor.
In fact, the requirement for authorised capital had more to do
with relations between directors and shareholders than with
creditor relations. The directors could not issue more than the
amount of the company’s authorised capital without returning to
the shareholders for approval of an increase in the authorised
amount.67 However, if the authorised capital was set at a high
level, as it normally was, this was not a significant constraint on
the directors. Shareholder control of share issues is now effected
by other sections of the Act and shareholders, if they wish, can
put stronger controls in the company’s constitution, so that
authorised capital is not needed for the protection of
shareholders either.68
Consideration received upon issue
11–13
We next turn to the rules which focus on the quality and even the
reality of the consideration received by a company upon the
issuance of its shares, whether the shares are issued to satisfy the
minimum capital requirement or not and irrespective of whether
that consideration is referable to the nominal value of the share
or the premium payable. Before 1980 the domestic rules in this
area were exiguous, but they were strengthened as a result of the
Second Directive, which, however, was somewhat relaxed in
2006.69 As a result, there is a marked divergence between the
rules applying to all companies and to public companies only.
Rules applying to all companies
11–14
We should first note that the law does not require that the
consideration promised for the shares be immediately due to the
company. There is thus a distinction between paid-up capital and
uncalled capital, the former being, for example, the amount paid
on allotment and the latter the amount payable when the
company calls upon the shareholder for the payment in
accordance with the terms of the allotment.70 Long-term uncalled
capital could be a valuable indication of creditworthiness since,
in effect, it affords a personal guarantee by the members, but it is
doubtful whether it is extensively used in private companies.71
A potentially important creditor protection rule restricts the
use of capital to pay commissions etc. Payment by way of
commissions, brokerage or the like to any person in
consideration for subscribing or agreeing to subscribe is
prohibited,72 even if the shares are issued at a premium, except to
the limited extent to which they are explicitly permitted. Without
this rule, the amount actually received by the company from an
investor in exchange for its shares might be substantially less
than appears. However, the Act permits commission for
subscribing for shares (or procuring others to do so) to be paid
out of capital provided it is limited to 10 per cent of the issue
price and is authorised by the articles (which may set a lower
percentage).73 It would be logical if this restriction on the
payment of commission did not apply to payments out of
distributable profits, since creditors have no claim to limit what
the company does with such funds. This is what s.552 appears to
say, since it provides that a company “must not apply any of its
shares or capital money” in the payment of commissions etc.74
However, the section no longer attempts to do that which earlier
drafts of the statute attempted, i.e. to make clear the
consequences of infringing the prohibition. Those drafts
provided that, if there were an agreement to pay commission,
etc. in breach of the prohibition, the agreement was to be void; if
the payment had been made, the amount of the inducement was
to be recoverable, either from the person to whom it was paid or
any third party who knew of the circumstance constituting the
contravention and benefited from it.75 A court could deduce
these consequences from the prohibition contained in the current
section.
Payment does not have to be in cash; it can instead be made in
kind76 and very frequently is in private companies.77 But, except
in relation to public companies, it seems that the parties’
valuation of the non-cash consideration will be accepted as
conclusive78 unless its inadequacy appears on the face of the
transaction79 or there is evidence of bad faith.80 Hence on an
issue for a non-cash consideration it is possible to some degree
to “water” the shares by agreeing to accept payment in property
which is worth less than the value of the shares.
Public companies
11–15
Shares allotted by a public company must be paid up (in cash or
in kind) at least as to one quarter of their nominal value and the
whole of any premium due.81 If this does not occur, the share is
nevertheless to be treated as if this had happened and the allottee
is liable to pay the company that amount, with interest. This
provision reduces the company’s and creditors’ exposure to the
continuing solvency of its shareholders, although it is relatively
uncommon for companies not to require full payment upon
allotment. Where the company does want to stagger the
payments for the shares, this rule creates a disincentive to setting
the nominal value of the shares well below the issue price,82
because the whole of the premium must be paid up on allotment.
The remaining rules for public companies concern the
regulation of non-cash issues, but before turning to them it is
important to note the width of the definition of “cash
consideration” in s.583(3), for these rules do not apply where the
consideration is cash, as defined. The section includes within the
definition of “cash consideration” an undertaking to pay cash to
the company in the future, thus putting the company at risk of
the insolvency of the shareholder, but also the reducing the
disincentive mentioned at the end of the previous paragraph.83
Also treated as cash is the release of a liability of the company
for a liquidated sum.84 The latter is a useful provision in
facilitating equity for debt swaps whereby the creditors of an
insolvent company forgo their claims as debtors against the
company in exchange for the issue to them of equity shares. The
company is thereby released from an often crippling burden of
interest payments and the removal of the debt may even produce
by itself a surplus of assets over liabilities. This will be to the
immediate benefit of the shareholders and non-converting
creditors, though if the company prospers in the future, the
original shareholders will naturally find that their equity interest
has been extensively diluted. It seems that no infringement of the
rule forbidding issuing shares at a discount to par value occurs
where the face value of the debt is taken for the purposes of
paying up the new shares, even though the market value of the
debt at the time of the swap was less than its face value because
of the debtor’s insolvency.85
A public company may not accept, in payment for its shares or
any premium on them, an undertaking by any person that he or
another will do work or perform services for the company or any
other person.86 If it should do so, the holder of the shares87 at the
time they are treated as paid up (wholly or partly) by the services
is liable to pay the company an amount equal to the nominal
value of the shares plus the premium or such part of that amount
as has been treated as paid up by the undertaking.88 Nor may the
company allot shares as fully or partly paid-up if the
consideration is any sort of undertaking to provide a non-cash
consideration which need not be performed until after five years
from the date of the allotment.89 If the undertaking should have
been performed within five years but is not, payment in cash
then becomes due immediately.90 And (though this is of minimal
importance) shares taken by a subscriber to the memorandum of
association in pursuance of his undertaking in the memorandum
must be paid for in cash.91
Valuation of non-cash consideration
11–16
Finally, the possibility of “share-watering” by placing an inflated
value on the non-cash consideration is tackled in the case of
public companies by requiring that consideration to be
independently valued. Under Ch.6 of Pt 17 a public company
may not allot shares as fully or partly paid-up (as to their
nominal value or any premium) otherwise than in cash unless:—
(i) the consideration has been valued in accordance with the
provisions of the Part; (ii) a report is made to the company
during the six months immediately preceding the allotment; and
(iii) a copy is sent to the proposed allottee.92 To this there are
exceptions in relation to bonus issues93 and in relation to most
types of takeovers and mergers.94 But, in other cases, if the
allottee has not received the copy of the valuation report or there
is some other contravention of the Part, which he knew, or ought
to have known, amounted to a contravention, once again he or
she is liable to pay in cash with interest.95 These provisions
clearly protect existing shareholders as well as creditors.
However, if the correct valuation steps are taken, there is no
statutory prohibition on the company issuing shares in a
transaction which puts a higher valuation on the non-cash
consideration than has emerged in the valuation process. In that
situation the directors might well be in breach of their fiduciary
duties96 and the subscriber would be in a poor position to assert
that he or she was unaware of this.
The valuation has to be made by a person “qualified to be
appointed, or continue to be, an auditor of the company”97 and
that person must meet statutory tests of independence from the
company.98 The expert has a right, similar to that of an auditor,
to require from officers of the company the information and
explanations required to produce the valuation.99 The expert
may, however, arrange for and accept a valuation from another
person who appears to him to have the requisite experience and
knowledge and who is not an employee or officer of any
company in the group.100 In practice, therefore, the report will be
by the company’s auditor supported by another professional
valuation of any real property or other consideration which the
auditor does not feel competent to value on his own. The report
has to go into considerable detail101 and must support the
conclusion that the aggregate of the cash and non-cash
consideration is not less than the nominal value and the
premium.102
A private company proposing to convert to a public one
cannot evade these valuation requirements by allotting shares for
a non-cash consideration shortly before it re-registers as a public
one. In such a case, the Registrar cannot entertain the application
to re-register unless the consideration has been valued and
reported on in accordance with the above provisions.103
11–17
This relatively straightforward mandatory valuation procedure,
imposed where a public company issues shares for a non-cash
consideration, is extended by the Act to a category of cases
where the company acquires a non-cash asset in exchange for
something other than the issuance of shares.104 This extension
applies only during the period of two years after the company
has been issued with a trading certificate105; only to agreements
on the part of the company to acquire non-cash assets from
anyone who was a subscriber to the memorandum on the
company’s formation or a member of it on its conversion to a
public company106; and only where the consideration to be
provided by the company is at least equal to one tenth of its
issued share capital. This provision is aimed at a purchase by the
company of property from the promoters of the company at an
excessive price, though it seems relatively easy to avoid by
simply not becoming a member of the company until just after
either of the two dates which trigger the mandatory valuation
rule. Again, these controls protect both creditors and “outside”
shareholders, but a significant feature of the extended rule is that
it places greater emphasis on the protection of the shareholders
through the imposition of the additional requirement that the
shareholders approve of the proposed transaction.107
The valuation requirements, especially on a small issue of
shares, are potentially time-consuming and expensive. However,
they are required by the Second Directive.108 In 2006 the
Directive was amended so as to permit certain assets to be
valued without an independent expert’s report.109 Although the
Act contains a power for the Secretary of State to make
regulations to modify the independent valuation requirements,110
the Government did not propose to take up the options offered
by the amendment to the Directive, on the grounds it was not
clear the amendments did relax the provisions of the Directive
and, in any event, they would not simplify the legislation.111
Further provisions as to sanctions
11–18
The above provisions, both those relating to all companies and
those applying to public companies alone, impose civil liability
on the allottee (normally) towards the company, as we have
seen. However, by the time the company comes to enforce that
liability, it is not unlikely that the shares will be in the hands of
someone else. The general policy of the Act is to impose liability
jointly and severally with the allottee on the subsequent holder112
of the shares, but subject to a major defence.113 Following
normal equitable principles, that defence is that the holder is a
purchaser for value in good faith (i.e. without actual knowledge
of the contravention concerned) of the securities or someone
who derives title from such a purchaser.114 Consequently, if the
shares have been traded in the normal way on a public market,
the current holder will not be liable. On the other hand, a donee
of the shares would be jointly and severally liable.
The liability which the above provisions impose on the
allottee or the current holder of the shares is potentially
substantial, in respect of what might be only a technical breach
of the statute, for example, the allottee has not been sent a copy
of the valuer’s report, though the allottee is in fact aware of its
contents. Even where there has been a more than technical
breach, the liability imposed may be penal. For example, a
failure to have non-cash assets valued makes the allottee liable to
pay the whole of the consideration due for the shares in cash
with interest,115 without any account being taken of the actual
value of the non-cash assets transferred. Consequently, the court
has the power to grant relief against liability to make a payment
to the company in most cases,116 but that power to grant relief is
limited.117 In particular, the court must have regard to two
“overriding principles”, namely:
(a) that a company which has allotted shares should receive
money or money’s worth at least equal in value to the
aggregate of the nominal value of those shares and the value
of the premium or, if the case so requires, so much of that
aggregate as is treated as paid-up118; and
(b) that when the company would, if the court did not grant
exemption, have more than one remedy against a particular
person it should be for the company to decide which remedy
it should remain entitled to pursue.119
Share capital and choice of currency
11–19
The Act requires the minimum capital requirement for public
companies to be satisfied by shares denominated in either
pounds sterling or euros, presumably for some sort of
verification reason.120 However, apart from this, the company
has considerable freedom to denominate shares in such currency
as it wishes. It has never been doubted that this was possible in
relation to the share premium account (and other capital
reserves) but the issue was debated in relation to the share
capital account until it was decided in favour of giving the
company this freedom in Re Scandinavian Bank.121 The Act now
puts the point beyond doubt.122 Moreover, the Act adds to this
freedom by providing a simple procedure for re-denominating
share capital from one currency to another (into or out of sterling
or from one non-sterling currency to another), including the re-
denomination of the shares used to satisfy the minimum capital
requirement when trading began. Formerly, this could be
achieved only by the cumbersome and potentially expensive
procedure of a reduction of capital and an issue of new shares in
the desired currency.123 Now any limited124 company, subject to
contrary provision in its articles, may re-denominate its shares
by ordinary resolution of the members.125 Such re-denomination
does not affect the currency in which dividends are required to
be paid by the company or calls on shares smet by the
shareholder.126
Such re-denomination, which must be carried out at prevailing
rates of exchange,127 could produce new nominal values of a
rather awkward kind, for example, $2.24. The company may
respond in two ways: by capitalising distributable reserves so as
to increase the nominal values to a more acceptable level, for
which no special statutory permission is needed,128 or by
reducing the nominal values so as to achieve the same result,
which the statute permits without the need to follow the full
reduction of capital procedure. All that is required is a special
resolution of the members, provided the decision is taken within
three months of the re-denomination resolution and does not
reduce the company’s share capital by more than 10 per cent.129
Further, the amount of the reduction must be carried to a “re-
denomination reserve” which is a new undistributable reserve
created by the Act.130 It is also conceivable that the reduction
following re-denomination could produce the result that neither
the euro nor the sterling requirements for the authorised
minimum capital of a public company is met, in which case the
company will have to re-register as a private company.131
CAPITALISATION ISSUES
11–20
The net worth of a business will fluctuate from time to time
according to whether the company makes profits and ploughs
them back or suffers losses. But a company’s legal capital, i.e.
the issued share capital plus share premium account (if any) does
not automatically fluctuate to reflect this. It remains unaltered
until increased by a further issue of shares, which must be made
in conformity with the rules dealt with above, or reduced in
accordance with the rules dealt with in Ch.13. If, however, the
company has made profits and not distributed them as dividends,
a necessary consequence of the static nature of its capital
accounts is that its net asset value will exceed its legal capital.
This is not necessarily something either company or
shareholders need worry about—in fact, they should welcome
the profits—but an accounting device is needed to bring the
company’s books back into balance. This is to be found by
including a (notional) liability on the balance sheet in order to
balance the “assets” and “liabilities”. This is normally described
as a “reserve”, an expression which may confuse those
unaccustomed to accounting practice since it may suggest
(falsely) that the company has set aside an actual earmarked fund
to meet some potential or actual liability. The crucial point is
that this reserve is a distributable reserve, unlike the capital
accounts, i.e. the company can distribute assets to its
shareholders up to the value in the reserve, and keep its books in
balance by reducing the reserve accordingly.
Should a profit-rich company wish to bring its legal capital
more into line with its net worth, it can do so by making a
“bonus” or “capitalisation” issue132 to its shareholders. The
former expression is likely to be used by the company when
communicating with its shareholders (in the hope that they will
think that they are being treated generously by being given
something for nothing) and the latter when communicating with
the workforce (which might otherwise demand a bonus in the
form of increased wages). In fact, such an issue is merely a
means of capitalising reserves by using them to pay-up shares
newly issued to the shareholders.133 We have already noted one
form of bonus issue, where the shares are paid up out of the
share premium account, which is accordingly reduced to the
extent of the nominal value of the bonus shares, whilst the share
capital account is correspondingly increased. Here, however, the
bonus shares are paid up out of the distributable profits reserve.
For example, suppose that before the issue the net asset value
(taking book values) of the company was £2 million and the
issued capital one million shares of £1 each. The shares, on book
values, will be worth £2 each.134 The company then makes a one-
for-one bonus issue paid up out of the distributable profits
reserve. The immediate effect on a shareholder is that for each
former £1 share worth £2 he or she will now have two £1 shares
each worth £1.135 However, a more significant change has
occurred, which may have implications for the future. The
formerly distributable profit can no longer be distributed because
it has been converted into share capital. The company is thus
signalling a need to have greater permanent risk capital than
might previously have been understood to be the case. Further, it
is likely to stop short of capitalising undistributed reserves to an
extent which would impair its freedom to pursue an appropriate
dividend policy in the future. Thus, a bonus share paid up out of
distributable reserves is a potentially more significant event than
an issue of bonus shares paid up from the share premium
account, where the decrease in one undistributable account is
balanced by the increase in another.
CONCLUSION
11–21
The requirement that a public company have a minimum allotted
capital when it begins trading is of doubtful utility to creditors,
given the low level at which it is set. Protections of creditors
which take as their base the nominal value of the share (notably
the rule against issues at a discount to nominal value) are also of
doubtful utility, given the company’s freedom to set the nominal
value of the share, and may even be harmful to their interests in
certain circumstances. The rules designed to ensure that a
company receives assets of a value equal to the price at which it
has issued the shares are more useful to creditors and also
promote equal treatment of different groups of members holding
the same class of share. However, such rules do not depend for
their effectiveness on a concept of legal capital. Such rules could
equally well be formulated and enforced even if there were no
legal capital rules. The main claim that the legal capital rules
have to remain part of our company law must rest, therefore, on
their role in constraining the payment of distributions to the
members of the company to which we turn next.
1
cf. Capital punishment, capital letter, capital ship, capital city, capital of a pillar,
capital and labour, capital and income, and “capital!”.
2
In Kellar v Williams [2000] 2 B.C.L.C. 390, the Privy Council accepted that it was
possible for an investor to make a capital contribution to a company, other than in
exchange for the purchase of shares, in which case the contribution is to be treated in the
same way as a share premium (see below, para.11–8). Such a procedure is very unusual,
of course, since the contributor is left substantially in the dark as to what he or she is
getting in exchange for the contribution. However, one can see that an existing
shareholder in a company wholly controlled by him might act in this way. The difficulty
is to distinguish between such a capital contribution and a loan to the company.
3 Of course, a contribution made by a creditor may in fact benefit other creditors, for
example, a loan made to a company just before insolvency may mean the creditors as a
class obtain a larger percentage pay out than if the loan had not been made, but that
benefit to the earlier creditors is paid for by the later lender.
4 Council Directive 77/91/EC [1977] O.J. L26/1 (now replaced by Directive 2012/30/EU
[2012] O.J. L315/74, to which version the references in this chapter relate). See para.6–
11.
5 Re Exchange Banking Co, Flitcroft’s Case (1882) 21 Ch. D. 519, per Jessel MR.
6 2006 Act s.542(1),(2). This implements the requirements of the Second Directive,
although the requirement of a nominal value was not introduced into UK law by that
Directive.
7
2006 Act s.580.
8Note, however, the discount here is to the nominal value of the share, not to its market
value, which is the issue addressed by the pre-emption rules. See para.24–6.
9 Strategic, paras 5.4.26–5.4.33. The Gedge Committee, Cmd. 9112, had recommended
as long ago as 1954 that no-par equity shares should be introduced and the Jenkins
Committee (Cmnd. 1749, 1962, paras 32–34) recommended this reform in relation to all
classes of share. The reform has been widely introduced in common law jurisdictions
elsewhere, but now seems unlikely to be introduced here unless the Second Directive is
amended on this point. Introduction of no-par shares would require some matters to be
expressed differently or regulated differently in the contract of issue. For example, the
dividend on a preference share is normally expressed as a percentage of its nominal
value (but could as easily be expressed as so many pence per share) and surplus assets
are distributed on a winding in accordance with nominal values, so that a different
formula would have to be adopted. See Birch v Cropper (1889) 14 App. Cas. 525.
10
The Directive (art.8) refers to “accountable par” as a permitted alternative to “nominal
value” (but without defining it). The concept appears to be that one takes the total
consideration raised through the issue of shares and divides it by the number of shares in
issue at any time. Two consequences follow: the shares do not have a fixed nominal
value (because the accountable par would change on a new share issue at a different
price) but a par value does exist at all times; and the company has no freedom to set the
nominal value: it is simply the result of an arithmetical exercise. See Bank of England,
Practical Issues Arising From the Euro, Issue 8, June 1998, Ch.6 at paras 24–28.
11 Completing, para.7.3.
12
Finally in Ooregum Gold Mining Co v Roper [1892] A.C. 125 HL.
13
2006 Act s.580(1).
14
2006 Act s.580(2).
15
See the facts of Ooregum Gold Mining Co v Roper [1892] A.C. 125 HL where the
“no discount” rule enabled the existing shareholders to act in a wholly opportunistic way
towards an investor who was willing to inject new money into the company at market
value (but less than the nominal value) of the shares at a time when the existing
shareholders were unwilling to advance further capital.
16 Hilder v Dexter [1902] A.C. 474 HL. The argument was there rejected that failing to
obtain the premium amounted to the payment of a commission, contrary to what is now
s.552 (see below). The decision was undoubtedly right on its facts, since the right to
purchase further shares at par was an explicit part of the contract under which the
investor had originally become a shareholder in a corporate rescue.
17
See the previous note and directors’ share option schemes, the essence of which is
that the director has the right to subscribe in the future for shares in the company at
today’s share price.
18 See para.16–64.
19
“If the share stands at a premium, the directors prima facie owe a duty to the company
to obtain for it the full value which they are able to get. It is true that it is within their
powers under the Companies Acts to issue it at par, even in such a case, but their duty to
the company is not to do so unless for good reason.” (per Lord Wright in Lowry v
Consolidated African Selection Trust Ltd [1940] A.C. 648, 679.) See also Shearer v
Bercain Ltd [1980] 3 All E.R. 295: “Those who have practised in the field of company
law for any length of time will have spent many hours convincing directors that it is
wholly wrong for them to issue to themselves and their friends shares at par when they
command a premium, however great the company’s need for capital may be.” (per
Walton J). See also Re Sunrise Radio [2010] 1 B.C.L.C. 367.
20Drown v Gaumont British Corp [1937] Ch. 402. See C. Napier and C. Noke,
“Premiums and Pre-acquisition Profits” (1991) 54 M.L.R. 810.
21
In some cases, the nominal value of the share has a more substantial significance. The
dividend entitlement of a preference share is normally set as a percentage of the nominal
value of the share, so that choosing a low nominal value for a preference share might
imply a high percentage dividend. To produce the equivalent of a 10 per cent dividend
on a £1 share, the dividend entitlement on a 1p share would have to be 1000 per cent! In
general with preference shares, given their bond-like characteristics (see para.23–7), the
nominal value will be set much closer to the issue price, since the nominal value will
also determine what the preference shareholder receives in a reduction of capital or
liquidation, at least if the holder has no right to participate in surplus assets.
22
2006 Act s.610(3).
23
The bonus issue could also be funded by distributable profits. See below at para.11–
20.
24
The issuance of a bonus share has little impact on the shareholders either in the
normal case. The shareholder now has more shares, but since the value of the company
is not increased by this exercise, the market price of each share in the expanded class
will fall. Sometimes bonus shares are issued precisely to achieve this result because it is
thought that the market value of the share has become so large that it is an obstacle to
trading them. See EIC Services Ltd v Phipps [2004] 2 B.C.L.C. 589 CA, where the
(botched) bonus issue was aimed at reducing the trading price of the shares. A similar
result can be obtained by effecting a “stock split” under s.618, an exercise which is
possible no matter whether the company has a share premium account of any size.
25
2006 Act s.610(2).
26
2006 Act s.553 and see below, para.11–14.
27 Under the 1985 Act the share premiums account could be written off against a wider
range of share issue expenses which, in particular, did not necessarily have to have been
incurred in relation to the shares generating the premiums.
28 Head & Co Ltd v Ropner Holdings Ltd [1952] Ch. 124.
29 Shearer v Bercain Ltd [1980] 3 All E.R. 295.
30
2006 Act ss.612–613.
31
2006 Act s.613(3).
32 Which will include preference shares if they have a right to participate in either
dividends or surplus on a winding up beyond a fixed amount: ss.616(1) and 548.
33
2006 Act s.611.
34
2006 Act s.611(2)–(5), defining the “minimum premium value”.
35
2006 Act s.612(4).
36 See above, fn.4, art.6.
372006 Act s.763 and the Companies (Authorised Minimum) Regulations 2009 (SI
2009/2425) reg.2.
38
Second Directive art.6: €25,000.
39 2006 Act s.586.
40See M. Becht, C. Mayer and H.F. Wagner, “Where do Firms Incorporate?
Deregulation and the Cost of Entry” (2008) 14 Journal of Corporate Finance 241.
41
2006 Act s.761.
42 The form of the application, containing a statement of compliance on the part of the
company, is set out in s.762. It is not demanding and the Registrar may accept the
company’s statement of compliance as sufficient evidence of the matters stated in it, and
the Registrar must issue the certificate if satisfied the minimum capital requirements are
met: s.765(2). The trading certificate, once issued, is conclusive evidence that the
company is entitled to commence business: s.761(4). However, by analogy with the
decisions referred to in para.4–35 in relation to the certificate of incorporation, it appears
that, as this section is not expressed to bind the Crown, the Registrar’s decision could be
quashed on judicial review at the instance of the Attorney-General.
43
2006 Act s.761(2). A company’s capital may be stated in euros in which case s.763
deals with the fixing of the equivalent prescribed euro amount. Where a company has
some share capital denominated in pounds and some in euros, the company’s application
for a certificate must be made by reference to the sterling capital or to the euro capital
alone and not by reference to a mixture of the two types of capital: s.765.
44
Insolvency Act 1986 ss.122(1)(b) and 124(4)(a).
45
2006 Act s.767(1),(2).
46
2006 Act s.767(3),(4).
47
2006 Act ss.90(1)(b), (2)(b) and 91(1)(a).
48 See Ch.13.
49
2006 Act.650(2). The court may order otherwise. Section 651 provides an expedited
procedure for re-registering as a private company in such cases. See also s.662(2)(b),
dealing with the consequences of a forced cancellation by a public company of its own
shares.
50
2006 Act s.764(1),(4).
51
2006 Act s.764(3)—no doubt through an expedited procedure.
52As we shall see below at para.12–9, directors’ remuneration would not normally be
caught by the rules controlling distributions by companies.
53
2006 Act s.547 makes it clear that called up share capital includes capital payments to
be made in the future if those future payment dates are laid out in the company’s articles,
the terms of allotment of the shares or other arrangements for the payment of the shares.
This section implements domestically art.19 of the Second Directive. Article 19 refers to
the company’s “subscribed” capital, which probably means the nominal value of the
issued share capital, thus reducing the impact of the rule.
54
As is the case in some continental European jurisdictions.
55 See paras 31–26 et seq.
56 See paras 9–6 et seq.
57
See Chs 9 and 10, above.
58 Above, para.11–1.
59 See Chs 21 and 22.
60 Above, para.11–5.
61 2006 Act s.10. Prescribed are details of the right to vote, to receive a distribution
either by way of dividend or capital, and provisions about redemption: Companies
(Shares and Share Capital) Order 2009/388 art.2.
62 2006 Act s.555 and see para.23–6.
63
As we see in para.26–18, those who take the shares may be nominees for others who
have the financial interest in them, but this is perhaps of less moment to the creditors
whose main interest is in the amount of shares issued, rather than data about their
holders. Since the shareholders’ liability is limited, it does not matter to the creditors
whether the shareholders are rich or poor, at least once the shares are fully paid up.
64
2006 Act s.1112.
65
Modernising, para.6.5.
66
1985 Act s.2(5)(a).
67
1985 Act s.121.
68
See Ch.24.
69
A set of relaxations to the original version of the Second Directive was made by
Directive 2006/68/EC ([2006] O.J. L264/32). However, in relation to the issues
discussed below the Government took the view that the permitted relaxations were so
minor and so hedged about with qualifications that it was not worth taking them up:
DTI, Implementation of the Companies Act 2006: A Consultation Document, February
2007, para.6.23.
70
2006 Act s.547 defines called-up capital so as to include that amount represented by
calls which have been made, whether or not they have been met, and the amount payable
under the articles or the terms of allotment on a specified future date, even though that
date has not arrived.
71
Or, indeed, by public ones. As the CLR proposed, the Act no longer contains
provisions which permit a company to determine by special resolution that any part of its
capital which has not been called up shall be incapable of being called up except in a
winding up.
72 2006 Act s.552.
732006 Act s.553. Section 552(3) also permits the payment of “such brokerage as has
previously been lawful”—an obscure and potentially wide permission. On the use of the
share premium account to pay commissions, etc. see above, para.11–7.
74Of course, for a company to make such a payment, even out of distributable profits,
might infringe the prohibition on a company giving financial assistance towards the
purchase of its own shares, but the latter rule no longer applies to private companies: see
para.13–55, below.
75 Modernising Company Law—Draft Clauses, Cm 5553-II, July 2002, cl.28.
76 2006 Act s.582(1) restates the general rule that “shares allotted by a company may be
paid-up in money or money’s worth (including goodwill and know-how)” but this is
followed by exceptions and qualifications relating to public companies only. Again,
bonus shares are specifically allowed.
77For example, when the proprietor of a business incorporates it by transferring the
undertaking to a newly formed company in consideration of an allotment of its shares.
78
Re Wragg [1897] 1 Ch. 796 CA; Park Business Interiors Ltd v Park [1992] B.C.L.C.
1034.
79 Re White Star Line [1938] Ch. 458.
80 Tintin Exploration Syndicate v Sandys (1947) 177 L.T. 412.
81
2006 Act s.586.
82
See para.11–3, above.
83
2006 Act s.583(3)(d). There is no apparent limit on the future date which may be
fixed for the actual payment, for the five-year limit in s.587 (see below) applies only to
non-cash payments, but the undertaking must be one given to the company in
consideration of the allotment of the shares: System Controls Plc v Munro Corporation
Plc [1990] B.C.C. 386. And the “cash” must be given to the company, not a third
person: s.583(5).
84
2006 Act.583(3)(c). So, if the company owes the investor a sum of money, the release
by the investor of the company from that obligation in exchange for the shares amounts
to the provision of a cash consideration for them: EIC Services Ltd v Phipps [2004] 2
B.C.L.C. 589 at [36] to [52] (Neuberger J).
85
Re Mercantile Trading Co, Schroeder’s Case, Re (1871) L.R. 11 Eq. 13; Pro-Image
Studios v Commonwealth Bank of Australia (1990–1991) 4 A.C.S.R. 586, though it
should be noted that in this case both the debt and the consideration for the new shares
were immediately payable. Independent valuation of the debt is not required because its
release constitutes a cash consideration.
86
2006 Act s.585. But this section (nor s.587 below) does not prevent the company from
enforcing the undertaking: s.591. If a private company wishes to convert to a Plc such
undertakings must first be performed or discharged: s.91(1)(d).
87
Including the holder of the beneficial interest under a bare trust: s.585(3).
88 2006 Act s.585(2).
892006 Act s.587(1). If contravened the consequences are similar to those for
contravention of s.585, except that the liability falls on the allottee: s.587(2). If a
contract of allotment does not offend s.587(1) but is later varied so as to produce this
consequence, the variation is void: s.587(3).
902006 Act s.587(4). And see s.91(1)(d) regarding a private company converting to a
Plc.
91 s2006 Act s.584.
92
2006 Act s.593(1).
93 2006 Act s.593(2).
942006 Act ss.594–595. The rules of the Act, the Takeover Panel or the FCA will
normally ensure that there has been professional assessment of value in such cases.
95
2006 Act s.593(3). As is a subsequent holder unless he is or claims through a
purchaser for value without notice: s.605(1),(3). See Re Bradford Investments [1991]
B.C.L.C. 224.
96
See para.11–5.
97 2006 Act ss.596(1) and 1150. For these qualifications, see Ch.22, below.
98 2006 Act ss.1151–1152.
99 2006 Act s.1153. Knowingly or recklessly making a false statement under the section
is a criminal offence: s.1153(2)–(4). Unlike the auditor’s right, the independent expert’s
does not extend to employees of the company. See para.22–30.
100 2006 Act s.1150(2).
101
2006 Act s.596(3)–(5).
102
2006 Act s.586(3)(d).
103
2006 Act s.93.
104
2006 Act s.598.
105
2006 Act.598(2)—the “initial period”. For the requirement for a public company to
obtain a trading certificate see above, para.11–4.
106
2006 Act ss.598(1)(a) and 603.
107
2006 Act ss.599(1)(c) and 601.
108
Second Directive arts 10 et seq.
109 Now arts 11 and 12.
110
2006 Art s.657(1).
111
DTI, above, fn.69, para.6.23.
112“Holder” is defined to include not just the registered holder of the share but also a
person who has the unconditional right to be included in the company’s register of
members or to have a transfer of the share executed in his favour: ss.588(3) and 605(4).
See Ch.27, below.
113 2006 Act ss.588 and 605.
114
2006 Act ss.588(2) and 605(3). The requirement for “actual notice” is favourable to
the subsequent holder. On the possible meanings of “actual knowledge” see Eagle Trust
Plc v SBC Securities Ltd [1991] B.C.L.C. 438.
115 2006 Act s.593(3).
116
There is no relief power in relation to the allottee in the case of issuance of shares at
a discount or breach of the paying-up requirements: s.589(1).
117
2006 Act ss.589 and 606.
118The importance of which is demonstrated in Re Bradford Investments Plc (No.2)
[1991] B.C.L.C. 688; cf. Re Ossory Estates Plc (1988) 4 B.C.C. 461.
119 2006 Act ss.589(5) and 606(4). For other matters which the court should take into
account, see ss.589(3),(4) and 606(2),(3). When proceedings are brought by one person
(e.g. a holder of the shares) against another (e.g. the original allottee) for a contribution
in respect of liability the court may adjust the extent (if any) of the contribution having
regard to their respective culpability in relation to that liability: ss.589(6) and 606(5).
And see s.606(6) for exemption from liability under s.604(3)(b).
120 2006 Act s.765(1).
121Re Scandinavian Bank [1988] Ch. 87. Of course, until the rules on share capital were
brought into line with those on share premium, the company was not in a position to
exercise freedom of choice in relation to currency.
122 2006 Act s.542(3): shares “may be denominated in any currency and different classes
of shares may be denominated in different currencies” (subject, of course, to s.765,
above, fn.120).
123
As happened in Re Scandinavian Bank [1988] Ch. 87. For the reduction of capital
procedure see para.13–30.
124
Unlimited companies had the freedom already.
125
2006 Act s.622(1). The section requires the actual conversion to take place within 28
days of the adoption of the resolution (s.622(5),(6)).
126
2006 Act s.624(1). Other rights and obligations of members under the constitution or
the terms of issue of the shares are also expressly preserved.
127
2006 Act s.622(3).
128
On capitalisation issues see below, para.11–20.
129
2006 Act s.626. Thus, in the example in the text, the company would not be able to
use this procedure to reduce the nominal value to $2, but it would be able to if the
unreduced nominal value were $2.20. There must also be notification to the Registrar:
s.627.
130
2006 Act s.628. For the significance of this for the payment of dividends see
para.12–2.
131 2006 Act s.766 and the Companies (Authorised Minimum) Regulations 2008/729
reg.5. A speedy method of re-registration is provided.
132
The two expressions mean the same thing and, indeed, so does a third (“scrip” issue)
which is sometimes used.
133 Technically, there is a two-stage process. First, the undivided profits of the company
are capitalised and then there is the appropriation to each member who would have been
entitled to a distribution of the profits by way of dividend of the amount needed to pay
up as fully paid the shares to be issued. See Topham v Charles Topham Group Ltd
[2003] 1 B.C.L.C. 123, especially at 139–141, where the failure of a parent company to
carry out the first step (because its accounts in fact showed no distributable profits,
though its subsidiary did have such profits) meant that the issue of the bonus shares was
ineffective to create any right in the shareholders to receive the shares. cf. Re Cleveland
Trust [1991] B.C.L.C. 424, where the company’s accounts erroneously showed a
distributable profit (in fact the profit so shown was repayable to a subsidiary) and the
issue of the bonus shares was held to have been effective, as far as the statute was
concerned, but rendered void by the common law doctrine of common mistake.
134
This does not mean that listed shares will be quoted at that price: that will depend on
many other factors, including in particular the expected future profits and dividends.
And the book values, of fixed assets in particular, may not reflect their present values.
135The quoted price is not likely to fall by a half because it is to be expected that the
company will seek to maintain approximately the same level of dividend per share as
before the issue.
CHAPTER 12
DIVIDENDS AND DISTRIBUTIONS
This passage suggests that the common law rule is broader than
the statutory provisions on distributions, for it indicates that any
return of corporate assets to the shareholders, which is not
justified by a statutory provision or the pursuit of the company’s
objects, will be unlawful, even if the company has distributable
profits. However, if there are distributable profits the statutory
provisions discussed above provide a mechanism for making a
distribution which does not breach the common law rule.
Consequently, if there are no distributable profits, both the
statutory and common law rules will be broken, but the common
law rule will catch any improper return of assets to the
shareholders whether that return is classified as a distribution or
not.
12–10
The core element of a disguised contribution is that it is a
transaction between the company and a shareholder which does
not purport to be a distribution but which contains a transfer of
value to the shareholder47 because of a discrepancy between the
value provided to the company by the shareholder and the
greater value provided to the shareholder by the company. It is
not necessary that the transaction be a sham to be characterised
as a disguised distribution: it is the imbalance in the
considerations that is the focus of the courts’ concerns. The two
main issues arising are: (i) how rigorously will the courts
examine the discrepancy in the values provided to and by the
company; and (ii) what is the relevance of the good faith or
otherwise of the parties to the transaction? As we shall see, these
questions are to some degree interlinked.
In some cases the discrepancy is obvious, not necessarily
because the value transferred to the shareholder is large but
because the shareholder provides nothing or virtually nothing to
the company in exchange for the value transferred.48 These may
be thought of as virtually gratuitous transactions. Outside
gratuitous transactions, the courts are clearly reluctant to be put
in a position where they may have to scrutinise routinely the
exchange of values in commercial transactions between
shareholders and their companies. In Progress Property Co Ltd v
Moorgarth Group Ltd49 Lord Walker stated that the parties
should have a “margin of appreciation” in relation to the
assessment of the value of what was transferred under the
contract, at least where the transaction was entered into in good
faith. In other words, it would be necessary to show a very large
discrepancy between the values provided and received by the
company in such a case for the disguised contribution rule to be
triggered.
However, it is clear that good faith will not take the parties to
the transaction outside the scope of the disguised distribution
rule altogether. In Re Halt Garage (1964) Ltd50 the shareholder
and the company (in effect the same person, as is often the
situation in these cases) had acted entirely honestly, having been
misled by professional advice. However, the company had paid
for services which in effect had never been received and the
amount paid had to be accounted for to the company (now in
liquidation). This case might be distinguished as in effect a
gratuitous transaction. Certainly, in Aveling Barford Ltd v Perion
Ltd,51 which was not a gratuitous transaction but a case of a
transfer of corporate property to a controlling shareholder at a
considerable undervalue, Hoffmann J put some emphasis on the
fact that the parties (again in effect a single controlling
shareholder) knew and intended the sale to be at an undervalue.
In Progress Property Co Ltd v Moorgarth Group Ltd52 Lord
Walker thought that sometimes the parties’ subjective intentions
would be relevant and sometimes they would not, but he did
agree that an apparent distribution disguised as an arm’s length
commercial transaction was the “paradigm case” where
subjective intentions were relevant.
“If the conclusion is that it was a genuine arm’s length transaction then it will stand,
even if it may, with hindsight, appear to have been a bad bargain [for the company].
If it was an improper attempt to extract value by the pretence of an arm’s length
sale, it will be held unlawful. But either conclusion will depend on a realistic
assessment of all the relevant facts, not simply a retrospective valuation exercise in
isolation from all other inquiries.”53
13–1
In the previous chapter we analysed at some length the rules
limiting the maximum amount a company may make by way of
a distribution to its shareholders. There are two clear ways in
which a company might seek to circumvent this rule. First,
instead of making a distribution (for example, paying a dividend)
to its shareholders, it could offer to buy back some of the shares
held by them. In this way the company would be returning assets
to its shareholders (or some of them), as would occur in a
distribution, and so the interests of the creditors would be
engaged in such a move. However, the distribution rules would
not apply on the basis that this exercise was not a gratuitous
transaction (assuming shares repurchased at market price). In
addition, the company would be reducing the amount standing in
its share capital and, possibly, share premium accounts through
the repurchases. By returning assets to its shareholders in this
way a public company would be making it easier to carry out a
regular distribution to shareholders in the future. The reduction
of the amounts in the capital accounts would lessen the impact of
the distribution rule discussed in the previous chapter, i.e. that
after the distribution the company should have net assets at least
equal to its capital. Perhaps it is not surprising that, for both
these reasons, the nineteenth century view was that a company
could not acquire its own shares. However, a less draconian
approach—close to that eventually adopted in the modern
reforms—would have been to subject the acquisition, by
analogy, to the distribution rule.
Secondly, a public company could seek directly to reduce the
amounts standing in its share capital and other capital accounts,
thus facilitating distributions, either immediately after the
reduction or in the future. This might seem to be a
straightforward and unlawful manipulation by the company of its
accounts. Having insisted on the creation of capital accounts in
the first place and having imposed a distribution rule by
reference to the balance sheet, how could the law permit the
company to adjust downwards the amounts stated in those
accounts? The answer, of course, is that the company is
permitted no such general freedom. However, there are
circumstances in which it might be in the interests of all
involved—shareholders and creditors alike—to permit a
reduction of the amounts stated in the capital accounts. This
might be so even in the case of a private company, for example,
to avoid the rule about not issuing shares at a discount to
nominal value (see para.11–4, above). The law thus provided
from an early stage a procedure by which the capital figures
might be reduced, whilst protecting shareholder and creditor
interests, and in the 2006 reforms an additional and more
flexible procedure was added for use by private companies.
We look first at acquisitions by a company of its shares, then
at the capital reduction procedure and finally turn to the matter
of a company giving financial assistance for the purchase of its
own shares. This third issue seems only tangentially related to
the issue of legal capital, though it has traditionally been so
regarded, and so we take it last.
ACQUISITIONS OF OWN SHARES
The general prohibition
13–2
It was held by the House of Lords in the nineteenth century that
a company could not acquire its own shares, even though there
was an express power to do so in its memorandum, since this
would result in a reduction of capital.1 Assuming that on
acquisition by the company the shares were cancelled and
nothing put in their place this would necessarily reduce the
capital yardstick represented by issued share capital and it could
also be regarded as objectionable as a diversion of the
company’s assets to the shareholders whose shares were
acquired, possibly in circumstances in which an ordinary
dividend could not be paid because of the rules discussed in the
previous chapter. Today, however, acquisitions by companies of
shares held by their investors are common. Acquisitions may
occur because the company is able to meet its investment needs
from internally generated profit and so has less need of
externally provided equity finance, or because it wishes to give
investors who no longer rate the company an attractive
opportunity to exit it, whilst retaining those shareholders who
think the company’s prospects are good. Thus, the story of the
law’s development is from prohibition of acquisition to
specification of circumstances in which acquisition by a
company of its own shares is allowed. As we shall see, the Act
now legitimises two forms of acquisition: redemption and re-
purchase.
The 2006 Act begins by confirming the common law rule that
a limited company “shall not acquire its own shares whether by
purchase, subscription or otherwise”.2 If it purports to do so, the
company and every officer in default is liable to a fine and the
purported acquisition is void.3 In addition, a public company is
prohibited from taking a lien or charge over its own shares (that
is also treated as void), except to cover the unpaid liability on a
partly paid share.4 Moreover, this central prohibition is
buttressed by two further statutory restrictions.
Acquisition through a nominee
13–3
First, the prohibition could be avoided in certain cases if the
company acquired the shares through a nominee rather than
directly. Accordingly, in such a case the shares are treated as
held by the nominee on its own account and the company is
regarded as having no beneficial interest in them.5 Further, if the
nominee does not meet the financial obligations attached to the
shares, then that liability will fall on the other subscribers to the
memorandum (where the nominee is a subscriber) and in the
other cases it will fall on the directors of the company at the time
the shares were issued to or acquired by the nominee.6 In both
cases it is a joint and several liability.
However, this liability rule is applied only when the nominee
for the company acquires the shares as a subscriber to its
memorandum, where the shares are issued by the company to the
nominee, or when the nominee acquires the shares partly paid
from a third person.7 It does not apply if the nominee acquires
fully paid shares from a third party, even if the nominee does so
with funds provided by the company.8 This suggests that the
rationale of the nominee rules is to ensure that the company
receives the full price of the shares it issues, which price the
company will necessarily have received before the nominee’s
acquisition of the shares in the case of the acquisition of fully
paid shares by a nominee from an existing holder. Furthermore,
where shares are acquired by a nominee for the company rather
than by the company directly, the shares remain in the hands of
the nominee (i.e. are not cancelled) so that the company’s capital
accounts remain unaffected. This also helps to explain why the
general prohibition applies, by contrast, to direct acquisition by
the company of even fully paid shares in the company.
Company may not be a member of its holding company
13–4
Secondly, the prohibition on acquisition of own shares is
supplemented by s.136 which provides that a company cannot be
a member of its holding company, either directly or through a
nominee,9 and any allotment or transfer of shares in the holding
company from an existing shareholder in the parent to the
subsidiary or its nominee is void. Section 136 is aimed at
preventing the de facto reduction of capital which would result
from a subsidiary company acquiring shares in its holding
company. The holding company, through its subsidiary, would
be returning assets to the selling shareholder.10 Nevertheless,
s.136 does not apply where the subsidiary, at the time of
acquisition of the shares in the holding company, is not a
subsidiary of it, but later becomes so, for example, as a result of
a takeover.11 The upshot of the exception is that the resources of
the holding company may be expended in buying (in effect) its
own shares (i.e. when it completes the takeover), but it has been
held, nevertheless, that this result cannot be prevented by relying
on the general prohibition on a company acquiring its own
shares (s.658) rather than s.136.12 Presumably the desire to
permit a useful commercial transaction was thought, in this
instance, to outweigh the policy behind the prohibition on the
acquisition of own shares.
Specific exceptions to the general prohibition
13–5
This apparently comprehensive set of prohibitions is, however,
subject to a number of exceptions. Thus, a company may acquire
its own shares by way of gift13 or by way of forfeiture for non-
payment of calls.14 In the latter case, however, a public company
must cancel the shares and reduce its capital account accordingly
if the shares are not disposed of within three years of the
forfeiture.15 Both these exceptions are of long-standing. In 1983
there was added a further complex set of rules to deal with
possible problems faced by public companies in relation to
shares acquired by the trustees of a company’s employee share
scheme or pension scheme.16 These do not need to be further
analysed in a work of this kind. There are also scattered
throughout the Act provisions which permit the court to order
that a company acquire shares from a shareholder, as a remedy
for some wrong which has been done to that shareholder. The
best known example is a compulsory purchase order made by the
court under the unfair prejudice provisions, considered in
Ch.20.17 Finally, an acquisition of shares by the company under
a reduction of capital carried out under the provisions discussed
below is exempted from the prohibition.18
13–6
Where a public company is permitted to acquire its own shares,
whether directly or through a nominee, then so long as it holds
those shares (i.e. does not cancel or dispose of them) and decides
to show those shares as an asset in its balance sheet, an amount
equal to the value of the shares must be transferred out of profits
available for dividend to an undistributable reserve.19 In effect,
the amount available for distribution will be reduced by the
value of the purchase. Thus, suppose a public company acquires
through a nominee fully paid shares from a third party, providing
the nominee with the funds to effect the purchase. The
company’s net asset value will remain the same, the reduction in
cash being offset by the value of the shares acquired. However,
by virtue of the requirement to create an undistributable reserve,
the amount of the profit available for distribution will be
reduced, thus protecting creditors.20 To put the matter another
way, the purchase of the shares is treated as a distribution to the
shareholder whose shares the nominee acquired.
REDEMPTION AND RE-PURCHASE
Introduction
13–7
However, the developments in the modern law which most
directly qualify the “no acquisition” principle are those which
specify the conditions under which a company may redeem or
re-purchase its own shares. In these cases the legislature has
taken the view that the transactions could be structured in such a
way as not to endanger the interests of creditors and that the
nineteenth century prohibition was over-inclusive in its reach.
Redeemable shares are shares which are issued on the basis
that they are to be or may be redeemed (i.e. bought back) at a
later date by the company. The terms of issue may be that the
shares will be redeemed at a certain point or that they may be,
and in the latter case the option to redeem may be allocated to
the shareholder or the company or both. The process of
redemption is thus different from the process of re-purchase,
where the Act, under certain conditions, permits the company to
re-purchase shares, something which would otherwise be
unlawful. With re-purchase, however, there is no obligation
upon the company to make an offer to re-purchase or, if one is
made, upon the shareholder to accept it. The redemption
arrangement, by contrast, will always create some rights or
duties to redeem or be redeemed.
Redeemable shares thus involve an element of planning of its
financial structure by a company, because the terms of the
redemption have to be set at the time of issue. As compared with
non-redeemable shares, the holder of a right to have the shares
redeemed is not locked into the company and able to dispose of
the shares only to an investor who is prepared to buy them at the
prevailing market prices. An investor may welcome the right to
exit the company at a particular period in the future on terms set
out in advance. Such an arrangement makes the redeemable
share a hybrid between debt and equity, the debt holder also
being someone who normally has a repayment right at an
identifiable point in the future and on pre-set terms. Equally, the
company may wish to issue redeemable shares over which it has
a redemption right, perhaps as an alternative to standard
preference shares which can normally also be squeezed out
through a reduction of capital.21
However, the freedom of the company and the shareholder to
agree upon a re-purchase of shares is more useful than the
redemption procedure, precisely because it does not involve
commitment in advance. It is a mechanism which can be
resorted to as occasions arise, whilst the occasions when it is
desirable to redeem some of the company’s shares may be
difficult to identify in advance. It is true that the re-purchase
provisions do not create a mechanism whereby the shareholder
can be compelled to sell the shares back to the company or
whereby the company can be compelled to buy them, but there
are many instances where company and shareholder interests are
aligned so that the repurchase is likely to go ahead in those
cases, if the law permits it, as it now does. The company may
wish to return unwanted equity capital to the shareholders, either
because it has no need at all for the financing represented by the
shares repurchased or because it wishes to replace that financing
with an alternative, such as debt. More questionably, the
incumbent board may wish to buy out a group of shareholders
who are causing trouble for the incumbent management—a
process referred to in the US literature as “greenmail”,
presumably after the colour of the dollar bill. As we shall see,
there are features of the re-purchase mechanism aimed at
combating such opportunism. As for the shareholders, some may
welcome the chance to exit the company at an attractive price,
whilst those remaining may hope that the company’s earnings
per share will increase when some of the shareholders are paid
off, if indeed it was the case that the capital returned to them was
not earning a high reward or if it can be replaced by a cheaper
form of financing.
Some history
13–8
Redeemable shares have been permissible since the Companies
Act 1929. However, prior to the 1981 Companies Act, only
preference shares could be issued as redeemable.22 Now,
however, as s.684 provides, a company may issue shares of any
class which are to be redeemed or are liable to be redeemed,
whether at the option of the company or the shareholder.
However, the 1929 Act made the crucial breakthrough because it
introduced a method whereby redemption could take place
without prejudicing the interests of creditors and this method
was adopted again when, also in 1981, companies were
empowered to re-purchase their own shares, whether or not they
were issued as redeemable.23 This method has two crucial
creditor-protection features, which are discussed further below.
First, the shares may be redeemed or re-purchased only out of
distributable profits or (in most cases) out of the proceeds of a
fresh issue of shares made for the purposes of the redemption or
re-purchase. Insofar as distributable profits (as defined in the
previous chapter) are used to fund the redemptions or re-
purchases, the creditors have no cause to complain, since the
company could have used them to fund dividends instead.
Secondly, as far as the capital accounts are concerned, the capital
created by the fresh issue will replace the capital removed by the
redemption or re-purchase and so the level of protection afforded
to the creditors through the capital accounts will be the same. In
addition, provided it is disclosed that redemption or re-purchase
of existing shares is the reason for the fresh issue, creditors will
not be misled into thinking that the company is issuing shares in
order permanently to raise the amounts stated in its capital
accounts. However, the impact of a purchase on the company’s
capital accounts remains to be dealt with if the redemption or re-
purchase is funded out of distributable profits. Once the shares
are re-purchased the amount stated in the company’s capital
accounts will be reduced, thus lowering the level of creditor
protection. This problem was met by requiring the company to
establish an undistributable reserve of an amount equal to the
capital reduction when the redemption or re-purchase was
funded out of distributable profits. This is known as the “capital
redemption reserve” (“CRR”).
General restrictions on redeemable shares and on
repurchases
13–9
Redeemable shares may not be issued unless the company has
also issued shares which are not redeemable.24 This provision
eliminates the risk of the company ending up with no members if
and when all the redeemable shares are redeemed.25 However,
the Act makes no stipulation as to the number or value of the
non-redeemable shares which are required to have been issued,
and so the main form of equity financing for the company could
be via redeemable shares. Somewhat similarly, a re-purchase
cannot be made if the result would be that there were no longer
any members of the company holding non-redeemable shares or
only treasury shares remained.26
In the case of a public company redeemable shares may not be
issued unless the company is authorised in its articles to do so
and, in the case of a private company, the articles may exclude
or restrict the issue of redeemable shares.27 Thus, the default rule
is in favour of the private company having the power to issue
redeemable shares and against it in the case of public companies.
This requirement is additional to the provisions discussed in
Ch.24 which, in some cases, require the directors to seek the
authorisation of the shareholders before they take advantage of
the power to issue any type of share. The default rule addresses
the logically prior question of whether the company has power to
issue redeemable shares at all. Nevertheless, both sets of rules
create a requirement for shareholder consent. The main
difference between them appears to be that, in the case of a
public company, authority to issue shares can be given to the
directors by ordinary resolution.28 By contrast, a provision in the
articles conferring power on the company to issue redeemable
shares must either be there from the beginning, and thus be
consented to by all the subscribers to the memorandum, or be
introduced at a later date by special resolution of the members
altering the articles. This higher level of shareholder consent
might be thought to be justified by the drain on the company’s
cash resources that redemption is likely to entail, thus reducing
the cash available to pay dividends to the other shareholders or
to invest in projects for the benefit of the shareholders as a
whole.
A company may purchase its own shares (including
redeemable shares),29 subject to any restriction or prohibition in
the company’s articles.30 Thus, the default rule for both public
and private companies is that the company does have power to
re-purchase its shares. The contrast with the default rule for
public companies in relation to redeemable shares (no power to
do so) can be explained by the greater protection for
shareholders which exists in relation to the actual
implementation of the re-purchase, as we shall see below.31
13–10
Concern about the impact of the redemption on the non-
redeemable shareholders also lies behind a long-running debate
concerning the setting of the terms of the redemption. Under the
1985 Act, in order to protect the shareholders whose shares were
not to be redeemed (and indeed the offerees of the redeemable
shares), the terms and manner of the redemption were required
to be set out in the company’s articles, so that all would know
the position.32 However, this was thought to be an inflexible
requirement and the rule now embodied in the Act is somewhat
more flexible.33 Fixing the terms in the articles remains the
default rule,34 but, provided either the articles or an ordinary
resolution of the company permit it, the directors may fix the
terms and conditions of the redemption.35 Protection for the
shareholders is maintained by the requirement that the directors,
if they set the terms, must do so before the shares are allotted
and the company’s statement of capital provided to the Registrar
must include the terms of the redemption.36
The Act contains two further relevant provisions, one
restrictive, the other facultative. First, redeemable shares may
not be redeemed until they are fully paid37; and the same rule is
applied to re-purchases.38 This avoids the acquisition wiping out
the personal liability of the holders in respect of uncalled capital.
Secondly, the terms of redemption may provide that, by
agreement between company and shareholder, the amount due is
to be paid on a date later than the redemption date39; whereas the
requirement that the shares be paid for on re-purchase is
unqualified.40
Once the acquisition is effected, the Registrar must be
informed in the usual way and supplied with details of the
transaction.41
Creditor protection: all companies
13–11
The core of the nineteenth century objection to redemption and
re-purchase of shares was creditor protection. Therefore, the
crucial step in permitting these transactions was producing a
solution to the creditor protection issue. That solution, as now
embedded in the 2006 Act, consists of two sets of rules: one
applying to all companies and a set of relaxations which only
private companies can take advantage of. We will look first at
the rules applying to all companies and then at the private
company relaxations.
The general solution to the creditor protection issue consisted,
as noted, of providing that shares could be redeemed or re-
purchased only out of distributable profits or out of the proceeds
of a fresh issue of shares made for the purpose of the redemption
or re-purchase.42 Any premium payable on redemption or re-
purchase must be paid out of distributable profits alone, unless
the redeemed or re-purchased shares were issued initially at a
premium, in which case the redemption premium may be paid
out of the proceeds of a new issue, up to the amount of the
premium received on issue or the value of the company’s current
share premium account, whichever is the less.43 This rather
complicated rule ensures that the money received on the new
issue of shares is paid out only to the extent that it reflects the
reduction in the capital accounts arising out of the redemption or
re-purchase. If more is needed to redeem the shares, the excess
must be provided out of distributable profits.44
Once the shares have been redeemed, they are treated as
cancelled and the amount of the company’s issued share capital
is diminished by the nominal value of the shares redeemed.45
The company may also cancel its repurchased shares. In these
cases the company must create an (undistributable) CRR. The
amount of this reserve is equivalent to the amount by which the
company’s issued share capital is diminished by a purchase
wholly out of profits46 or, where the redemption is financed
partly by the proceeds of a new issue and partly by distributable
profits, the amount by which the proceeds of the new issue fall
short of the amount paid on redemption or re-purchase.47
However, since 2003 the company has had the option not to
cancel shares which have been re-purchased but instead to hold
them “in treasury”, usually for later re-issue. (Treasury shares
are considered further at paras 13–24 et seq., below.) This is a
significant difference between the redemption and re-purchase
procedures. Where shares are held in treasury, the creation of a
CRR is unnecessary, because the company’s capital accounts are
not altered.
Private companies: redemption or purchase out of
capital
13–12
In relation to both redemptions and re-purchases of shares,
special concessions are made to private companies. It is thought
often to be impossible for a private company to redeem or
purchase its own shares unless it could do so out of capital and
without having to incur the expense of a formal reduction of
capital with the court’s consent. There might not be sufficient
distributable profits, and there might be no available takers for a
fresh issue of shares. The whole concept of raising and
maintaining capital is, in relation to such companies, of
somewhat dubious value. Hence it was decided that, subject to
safeguards, they should be empowered to redeem or buy without
maintaining the former capital yardstick. In particular, the aim
was to permit entrepreneurs to withdraw assets from their
company to fund their retirement rather than by selling control to
a larger competitor.
There are in fact now two concessions. The first, introduced in
2013 and applying to repurchases only, simply allows a private
company to spend in any financial year up to (the lower of)
£15,000 or 5 per cent of the nominal value of its share capital on
re-purchases. There are no additional formalities to be met,
provided only that the company is authorised by its articles to
take this action.48 This provision is clearly crafted with small-
scale but potentially frequent re-purchases in mind, probably
linked to employee share schemes, rather than one-shot
retirement exercises.
13–13
The second set of provisions, which date back to 1981, are now
contained in Ch.5 of Pt 18 of the Act. They have been retained
even though there has now been provided to private companies a
non-court based method of reducing capital.49 These rules apply
to redemptions as well as repurchases, but, to shorten exposition,
the rules are stated here in relation to re-purchases.50
Section 709 provides that, subject to what follows, a private
company, unless restricted or prohibited by its articles from so
doing, may make a payment in respect of the purchase of its
shares otherwise than out of its distributable profits or the
proceeds of a fresh issue of shares. Such a payment is termed a
payment “out of capital”.51 This is a very wide definition and
may explain why it was thought there might be some cases
where re-purchase “out of capital” would be available, whereas a
reduction of capital would not. Suppose a company wishes to
acquire shares for a price above their nominal value but has no
share premium or capital redemption reserve. No matter how
much the share capital account is reduced, this will not free up a
sufficient amount of assets to be distributed so as to meet the
redemption premium. Assuming, however, that the company has
sufficient cash, it may be able to engage in re-purchase by
making a payment “out of capital” under s.709. This section
helpfully says that a payment other than out of distributable
profits or the proceeds of a fresh issue is a payment out of capital
(and so in principle permitted) “whether or not it would be
regarded apart from this section as a payment out of capital”.
Provided the company has the necessary cash and follows the
provisions of this part of the Act, that is all it needs to be
concerned with.52
The extent of any such payment out of capital is restricted,
however, to what is described as “the permissible capital
payment” (“PCP”).53 In brief, the rule is that any distributable
profits and any proceeds of fresh issue made for the purpose of
the re-purchase must first be used before resort may be had to a
payment out of capital. The rules for determining distributable
profits are those considered in the previous chapter in relation to
dividends, but there are certain amendments,54 perhaps the most
important of which is that the accounts by reference to which the
profits are calculated must be prepared within a period of three
months ending with the date of the statutory declaration which
the directors are required to make.55
The principal protective techniques used in the Chapter in
respect of the PCP are, in the case of creditors and shareholders,
the requirement for a solvency statement from the directors; in
the case of shareholders, the requirement for approval of the
proposed re-purchase by special resolution; and, in both cases,
the availability of a right of objection to the court.
Directors’ statement
13–14
As far as the solvency statement is concerned, the requirements
of the Act are similar to those applied in the case of a solvency
statement upon a reduction of capital out of court by a private
company, including the requirement for the directors to take into
account contingent and prospective liabilities.56 However, they
are not the same. In particular, the directors are apparently
unable to make the required forward-looking statement in the
case of a purchase out of capital, if they intend to wind the
company up within 12 months of the proposed payment.57 And
the forward-looking statement, applying to the immediately
following year, is required to be a little fuller. The form of the
required statement is that, having regard to the “the amount and
character of the financial resources” which will be available to
the company in the directors’ view, the directors have formed
the opinion that the company will be able to carry on business as
a going concern throughout that year (and accordingly will be
able to pay its debts as they fall due).58 The emphasis is thus on
an opinion which envisages a continuing business, not just the
ability of the company to pay its debts.59 Perhaps because of
these differences the statement required on a purchase is termed
a “directors’ statement” in the Act, whilst the term “solvency
statement” is reserved for the statement required of directors
under the out-of-court reduction procedure, though both
statements are, substantively, statements about the solvency of
the company.
The Act applies to the directors’ statement the same criminal
liability for negligence as is applied to the solvency statement.60
There is also a limited statutory civil liability in negligence to
the company if the company goes into winding up within one
year of the payment being made to the shareholder.61 However, a
major difference with the solvency statement is that the
directors’ statement needs to be accompanied by a report from
the company’s auditors stating their opinion that the amount of
the PCP has been properly calculated and that they are not aware
of any matters, after inquiry into the company’s affairs, which
renders the directors’ statement unreasonable in all the
circumstances.62
Shareholder resolution
13–15
The solvency statement can be said to protect both the creditors
of the company and the shareholders who will remain in the
company after the re-purchase. An additional protection for the
shareholders is the special resolution which is required to be
passed within a week of the directors’ statement and on the basis
of prior disclosure to the members of the directors’ statement
and auditors’ report.63 In this case it is explicitly provided that
the resolution is ineffective if these requirements are not
complied with.64 Further, the resolution will not be effective to
authorise the purchase out of capital if the shares to which the
resolution relates vote on the resolution and their votes were
necessary to secure its adoption.65
Appeal to the court
13–16
The final protective device (for both creditors and dissenting
members) is court scrutiny. The Act entitles any member of the
company, who has not consented to or voted for the resolution,
and any creditor of the company, to apply to the court for the
cancellation of the resolution, provided this action is taken
within five weeks of the passing of the resolution.66 The court is
given the widest powers. For example, it can cancel the
resolution, confirm it, or make such orders as it thinks expedient
for the purchase of dissentient members’ shares or for the
protection of creditors, and may make ancillary orders for the
reduction of the company’s capital.67
Legal capital consequences
13–17
If there is no court objection, the PCP must be made between
five and seven weeks after the adoption of the resolution.68 Upon
the re-purchase of the shares, the company’s share capital
account will be reduced accordingly, but, because this is a
permitted payment out of capital, there will be no need to
transfer a corresponding amount to the CRR, as would happen in
the case of a purchase out of distributable profits.69 A transfer to
CRR will be needed only to the extent that distributable profits
have been used in part to fund the purchase of the shares.70
Where the PCP is greater than the nominal value of the
purchased shares (i.e. they are being purchased at a premium),
the company is given permission to reduce its CRR, share
premium account and its revaluation reserve accordingly.71 In
other words, the company’s capital yardstick will in all
probability be reduced to the extent of the PCP.72 This is, after
all, the object of the exercise. Overall, indeed, the effect of the
foregoing provisions is that a private company may be able to
make a return to one or more of its members which will exhaust
its accumulated profits available for dividend and reduce both its
assets and its capital yardstick.
13–18
As far as the Companies Act is concerned, this is the end of the
procedure. However, the Insolvency Act contains a limited
mechanism for unscrambling the acquisition. If the company
goes into liquidation within one year of the payment being made
to the shareholder, that person is liable to return to the company
the amount of the payment out of capital, to the extent that this is
needed to meet any deficiency of the company’s assets in
relation to its liabilities.73
Protection for shareholders
13–19
We now turn to how the law handles intra-shareholder conflicts
arising in redemptions and re-purchases generally (i.e. beyond
the specific shareholder protection put in place for acquisitions
out of capital). This is particularly needed for re-purchases.
Redemptions, if not out of capital, tend not to raise issues for
shareholders because the terms of the redemption are set out at
the time of issue of the shares. By contrast, it is clear that re-
purchases have implications for the relations of shareholders
among themselves. Controlling shareholders—or shareholders
whom the management wish to see exit the company—may be
given the opportunity to sell their shares when other
shareholders are excluded, or may be given the opportunity to
sell on more favourable terms. The Act contains some provisions
aimed at controlling such abuses. These protections vary
according to whether the purchase is to be an “off-market” or a
“market” purchase. The essential distinction between the two
situations is whether the purchase takes place on a “recognised
investment exchange”, i.e. one authorised by the Financial
Conduct Authority.74 In broad terms this means that it is a
market purchase if it takes place on the main market of the
London Stock Exchange or on the Alternative Investment
Market.75 Market purchases create fewer risks of abuse since the
offer will be a public one and the purchases will be effected at an
objectively determined market price. If there is no market, the
opportunities for favouritism are much greater.
Off-market purchases
13–20
Under s.694 an off-market purchase can be made only in
pursuance of a contract the terms of which have been authorised
by a resolution of the shareholders before it is entered into.76
Until 2013 a special resolution was required, but now an
ordinary one will suffice.77 The contract so approved may take
the form of a “contingent purchase contract”, i.e. one where the
company’s obligation or entitlement to purchase shares is subject
to a contingency which may arise sometime in the future.78
Contingent purchase contracts may be particularly useful
because they enable the company to bind or entitle itself to
purchase the shares of a director or employee upon termination
of employment, or, as an alternative to the creation of a new
class of redeemable shares, to meet the requirements of a
potential investor in an unquoted company who wants assurance
that he or she will be able to find a purchaser if the investor
needs to realise his investment.79 The authorisation can
subsequently be varied, revoked or renewed by a like
resolution.80
In the case of a public company the authorising resolution
must specify a date on which it is to expire and that date must
not be later than five years after the passing of the resolution,81
so that directors may not subsequently act on a “stale” authority,
but no such rule applies to private companies.82 Moreover, on
any such resolution, whether of a public or private company, a
member, holding shares to which the resolution relates, may not
exercise the voting rights of those shares83 and if the resolution
would not have been passed but for those votes the resolution is
ineffective.84 This is an interesting example of the exclusion of
interested shareholders from voting on resolutions in which they
have a personal financial interest—a rule which normally does
not apply at common law.85 The resolution is also ineffective
unless a copy of the contract or a memorandum of its terms is
available for inspection by members, and in the case of a
resolution passed at a meeting it must be available at the
company’s registered office for not less than 15 days before it is
held.86 The same requirements apply on a resolution to approve
any variation of the contract87 or to an agreement whereby the
company releases its rights under the contract,88 since both
variation and release provide opportunities for favourable
treatment of insiders just as the initial off-market contract does.
Essentially, the shareholder protection technique deployed in
the case of an off-market purchase is the requirement for
approval by the shareholders in advance of the terms of the re-
purchase contract with the potential sellers excluded from
voting.
Market purchases
13–21
Under s.701 a company (necessarily a public one) cannot make a
market purchase of its own shares unless the making of such
purchases has first been authorised by ordinary resolution of the
company in general meeting.89 Those whose shares are to be
purchased are not excluded from voting, for the very good
reason that, with a market purchase, their identities will not be
known in advance. For the same reason, the shareholders are
asked to approve in this case, not a contract (even a contingent
one) for the purchase of the shares of specified members, but an
authorisation to the company (in practice, its directors) to go into
the market in the future and acquire its shares on certain terms.
The authorisation may be general or limited to shares of any
particular class or description and may be conditional or
unconditional90 but it must specify the maximum number of
shares to be acquired, the maximum and minimum prices,91 and
a date on which it is to expire, which must not be later than five
years after the passing of the resolution.92 Thus, the potential for
a re-purchase resolution to create uncertainty about the
appropriate market price of the share is reduced. Moreover, a
copy of the resolution required by the section has to be sent to
the Registrar within 15 days,93 so that the market is formally
aware of the company’s intentions or at least its powers. Thus,
the directors are given a re-purchase authority but one which is
exercisable only within the specified limits as to price, amount
and timing.
Companies with a premium listing
13–22
In the case of a re-purchase effected by a company with a
premium listing on the Main Market of the London Stock
Exchange, the Listing Rules add a further and significant set of
rules relating to the exercise by the company of the authority
conferred upon it under the statutory provisions, whether the re-
purchase is on- or off-market. In order to provide some degree of
equality of treatment of shareholders in relation to substantial
market re-purchases, which might affect the balance of power
within the company, the Listing Rules require re-purchases of
more than 15 per cent of a class of the company’s equity shares94
to be by way of a tender offer to all shareholders of the class (i.e.
to be on-market) or, alternatively, that the full terms of the re-
purchase have been “specifically” approved by the
shareholders.95 A standard tender offer is an offer open to all the
shareholders of the class on the same terms for a period of at
least seven days, capable of being accepted by the shareholders
pro rata with their existing holdings, and setting a fixed or
maximum price for the purchase.96 Thus, in a fixed price tender a
shareholder holding 2 per cent of the class may sell shares to the
company up to the amount of 2 per cent of the shares the
company acquires through the tender process. Where the tender
is at a maximum (but not a fixed) price, the shareholder has to
indicate the price at which it is prepared to sell its shares to the
company (a price not exceeding the maximum set by the
company) and the company will implement the tender by
accepting the lowest-priced offers first and continue up the price
curve until it has fulfilled its tender. Even where the purchase is
of less than 15 per cent, the company must either use the tender
offer procedure or limit the price it is offering to not more than 5
per cent above the market price of the shares over the five days
preceding the purchase.97 This limits the possibilities for
favoured shareholders to sell their shares to the company at an
above-market price.
Listing Rules also require the prior consent of any class of
listed securities convertible or exchangeable into equity shares of
the class to which the re-purchase proposal relates, unless the
terms of issue of the security provided that the company may re-
purchase the relevant equity shares.98 Thus, in principle, the
holders of convertible bonds will need to consent (by special
resolution in a separate meeting) to a re-purchase of the equity
shares into which the bonds are convertible. Further, where an
off-market transaction is contemplated, the Listing Rules apply
their rules concerning related-party transactions.99 These exclude
from voting on the resolution a wider range of persons than
would the statute, because the statute excludes only those whose
shares are to be re-purchased, whereas the Listing Rules also
exclude their associates.100 Finally, the FCA’s Rules not
surprisingly address market issues, such as the need for the
market to be informed immediately of all the stages of a share
re-purchase, from proposal to results101; and the need to avoid
insider trading by excluding, subject to exceptions, re-purchases
during prohibited trading periods.102 In addition, the Investment
Association guidelines103 propose that companies should always
act by special resolution even if the statute permits an ordinary
resolution, so that listed companies, or at least those with large
institutional shareholdings, will tend to follow this path, even if
the statute does not formally require it.
Payments otherwise than by way of the price
13–23
It is conceivable that a company might pay money to a
shareholder, not as the price for the shares purchased, but, for
example, by way of consideration for:
(a) acquiring any right (for example an option) to purchase under
a contingent purchase contract;
(b) the variation of any off-market contract; or
(c) the release of any of the company’s obligations under any
off-market or market contract.104
Although such payments are not strictly part of the purchase
price,105 none of them is normal expenditure in the course of the
company’s business but rather constitute a distribution to
members, and the payment would not have been made but for
the fact that the company was minded to agree to purchase its
shares. Such payments ought therefore to be treated, so far as
practicable, in the same way as the purchase price. It is highly
unlikely that a company would contemplate making a new issue
of shares for the purpose of financing any such payment.106
Hence, as a matter of creditor protection, the Act provides that
they must be paid for out of distributable profits only. If this is
contravened, in cases (a) and (b) above, purchases are not
lawful, and in case (c) the release is void.107
Treasury shares
13–24
The question of whether a company can itself hold the shares it
acquires is another issue that arises only in relation to re-
purchases of shares, since a cancellation rule is imposed in the
case of redemptions.108 Re-purchases of treasury shares were not
permitted under the original reforms of 1981, but the subsequent
history has been one of progressive liberalisation. In 1998, the
Government began consultation over the proposition that
companies should be able to retain re-purchased shares and re-
issue them, as required.109 The main argument in favour of this
reform was that it would permit companies to raise capital in
small lots but at a full market price by re-selling the re-
purchased shares as and when it was thought fit to do so. The
argument against was that the freedom to re-sell would give
boards of directors opportunities to engage in the manipulation
of the company’s share price, i.e. an argument based on investor
protection rather than creditor protection. In 2001, the
Government issued a further consultation document which
accepted the idea in principle, but only for companies whose
shares were traded on a public market, and consulted on further
issues related to its implementation.110 The manipulation danger
was thought to be addressed by the separate provisions,
contained in the FSMA 2000, dealing with market abuse,111 and
by the restriction on the amount of the treasury shares to 10 per
cent of any class (as then required by the Second Directive).
13–25
These proposals were implemented in 2003112 and Ch.6 of Pt 18
of the 2006 Act re-stated them without substantive change. In
2009, however, following amendments to the Second Directive,
the 10 per cent limit was removed.113 Under the 2003 reforms
only “qualifying shares”114 could be re-purchased. These were
publicly traded shares. In 2013, however, the restriction to
qualifying shares was removed from the legislation,115 so that all
shares subject to re-purchase may be held in treasury and all
companies may hold treasury shares (the previous approach
having necessarily excluded private companies from holding
shares in treasury).
The principal restriction today on holding treasury shares is
that their re-purchase must have been financed out of
distributable profits, even in the case of a private company.116
This limitation seems to have been imposed because it was
thought that there would be little demand for re-purchases out of
new issues. This approach also simplifies the legal capital issues.
Deployment of distributable profits has no impact on the
company’s capital accounts. Moreover, no balancing transfer to
the capital redemption reserve is required where the re-
purchased shares are not cancelled.
Sale of treasury shares
13–26
The underlying rationale of the treasury share scheme is
achieved by the provision that treasury shares may at any
subsequent time be sold by the company for cash.117 When this
happens, there is a sale by the company of existing shares, not an
allotment of new shares. Consequently, the rules requiring
shareholder authorisation of directors to allot shares do not
apply,118 thus facilitating speedy action by the directors. The
same argument could be advanced in relation to pre-emption
rights for shareholders on allotment, but the Act artificially
extends the statutory concept of allotment so as to make pre-
emption rights applicable on sales of ordinary shares held in
treasury.119 Although shareholders can waive pre-emption rights
in advance, the fact that treasury shares are in principle subject
to these rights is another example of the attachment of
institutional shareholders to pre-emption rights.120
Where the proceeds of the sale are equal to or less than the
purchase price paid by the company, the money received by the
company is to be treated as a realised profit and so potentially
distributable by the company.121 Since the shares will have been
acquired out of distributable profits, which were thereby
diminished, there can be no creditor-protection objection to the
proceeds of the sale being treated as a realised profit. Any excess
of the price received by the company over that paid by it,
however, must be transferred to the share premium account.122
This again seems correct. The increase in the price of the shares
presumably represents an increase in the value of the company
since the shares were purchased, so that the portion of the price
obtained on re-sale which represents that increase in value
should be treated as legal capital, just as the premium received
by the company on the initial issue of shares would be so
treated.123
Alternatively, the company may transfer treasury shares to
meet the requirements of an employees’ share scheme.124 Or it
may do what it could have done when it originally acquired the
shares, i.e. cancel them.125 In this latter case its share capital
account must be reduced by the amount of the nominal value of
the shares cancelled and an equivalent amount transferred to the
capital redemption reserve.126 In the usual way the company has
to inform the Registrar when it disposes of the shares (in either
of the permitted ways) or cancels them, giving the necessary
particulars.127
Whilst the shares are in treasury
13–27
Whilst the shares are still held by the company, it may not
exercise any of the rights attached to them (notably the right to
vote) and any such purported exercise is void,128 so that the
directors cannot strengthen their position in the general meeting
of the company through the use of the treasury shares. Nor may
a dividend be paid or any other distribution be made on the
treasury shares.129 However, the company may receive (fully
paid) bonus shares in respect of the treasury shares, for
otherwise the proportion of the equity represented by the
treasury shares would decline. The bonus shares so allotted are
to be treated as treasury shares purchased by the company at the
time they were allotted.130 On a subsequent sale of the bonus
shares their purchase price is to be treated as nil, so that the full
amount received for them must be transferred to the share
premium account.131 This seems correct, since the purpose of
issuing bonus shares is to capitalise profits and so the sale price
of the bonus shares needs to be added to the company’s capital
accounts and not be treated as a realised profit.132
Failure by the company to perform
13–28
So far, we have assumed that the company has discharged its
obligation to redeem shares under the terms of their issue or to
re-purchase shares as a result of a contract entered into with the
shareholder. Normally, this will be the case but it is conceivable
that the company will not fulfil its obligations. This may occur
because the company decides to break the contract or because it
cannot lawfully perform it since, for example, the new issue of
shares has not raised the proceeds expected and the company has
inadequate available profits.133 What are the remedies of a
shareholder if the company does not perform the contract to
redeem or purchase his shares? Section 735 provides that the
company is not liable in damages in respect of any failure on its
part to redeem or purchase.134 It was thought that damages were
not an appropriate remedy; it would result in the seller retaining
his shares in, and membership of, the company and yet
recovering damages (paid perhaps out of capital) from the
company.135 Any other right of the shareholder to sue the
company is expressly preserved, but, even then, it is provided
that the court shall not grant an order for specific performance
(perhaps a more appropriate discretionary remedy) “if the
company shows that it is unable to meet the costs of redeeming
or purchasing the shares in question out of distributable
profits”.136 Apart from this, the section gives no indication of
what “other rights” the shareholder might have. There is little
doubt that these would include the right to sue for an injunction
restraining the company from making a distribution of profits
which would have the effect of making it unlawful for the
company to perform its contract.
However, the ban on the recovery of damages can be
circumvented by using an indirect procedure to this end. In
British & Commonwealth Holdings Plc v Barclays Bank Plc137 a
consortium of banks had promised to take the shares from the
shareholder if the company could not redeem them and the
company had promised to indemnify the banks in respect of
actions by it which made it impossible for it to redeem. It was
held that the section did not prevent the banks suing the
company on its promises, even though the aim of the whole
scheme was to ensure that the shareholder would be able to
redeem even if the company had no distributable reserves. The
case strongly suggests, but does not finally decide, that s.735 is
concerned only with the range of remedies available to the
shareholder rather than with ensuring that a company never in
effect redeems shares out of capital.
A second issue which arises is the position if the company
goes into liquidation before the shares have been redeemed or re-
purchased. The Act provides that the terms of redemption or
purchase may be enforced against the company in winding up,138
but subject to the restriction on specific performance noted
above. However, the shareholder will gain little or nothing by
enforcing the contract if the winding up is an insolvent
liquidation since the member is a deferred creditor. Any claim in
respect of the purchase price is postponed to the claims of all
other creditors—and, indeed, to those of other shareholders
whose shares carry rights (whether as to capital or income)
which are preferred to the rights as to capital of the shares to be
redeemed or purchased.139 Moreover, even this limited right may
not be enforced in liquidation if the terms of redemption or
purchase provided for performance to take place at a date later
than that of the commencement of the winding-up; or if during
the period beginning with the date when redemption or purchase
was to take place and ending with the commencement of the
winding-up, the company did not have distributable profits equal
in value to the redemption or purchase price.140 In this case it
appears the member is treated in the winding-up as if there were
no obligation on the company to redeem or purchase the shares
and as if he or she were still a member of the company.
Conclusion
13–29
Even if one takes the view that legal capital is a central doctrine
of company law, the above discussion has shown that it is
relatively easy to reconcile it with the acquisition by a company
of its own shares, provided certain conditions are met. In
particular, acquisitions out of distributable profits, coupled with
an appropriate adjustment to the company’s capital accounts,
present no threat to the integrity of the doctrine of legal capital.
We should note, however, that the facility for a private company
to purchase shares out of capital, provided the decision is
supported by what is, in effect, a solvency statement, is a
legislative move towards the adoption of an alternative to legal
capital as the primary protection mechanism for creditors. In the
case of re-purchases, where the directors have a greater
discretion than in the case of redemptions, shareholder agency
problems emerge as an issue which has to be faced, but a
combination of the standard techniques of disclosure and
shareholder approval, plus in appropriate cases, reliance on the
functioning of a public market, ought to be sufficient to address
those problems as well.
REDUCTION OF CAPITAL
Why are reductions of capital allowed?
13–30
Acquisition by a company of its shares through redemption or
re-purchase is akin to a distribution to shareholders, discussed in
the previous chapter, to the extent that assets are returned by the
company to its shareholders. Unlike a distribution, which is a
gratuitous disposition by the company, in a redemption or re-
purchase the company receives shares in exchange for the assets.
However, if the shares are immediately cancelled, the acquisition
has a largely gratuitous character; and the cancellation generates
a reduction in the company’s legal capital yardstick. Only if the
re-purchased shares are held in treasury does the company obtain
value for the price paid, to the extent that the re-purchased shares
can be sold again to investors.
A reduction of capital, by contrast, does not necessarily
involve a return of assets to shareholders, though it may pave the
way for such action, either immediately or in the future. What is
reduced in a reduction of capital are the amounts stated in the
company’s capital accounts.141 The initial puzzle is why the
company should be permitted by the law to take this step at all.
Having built a creditor-protecting distribution rule, which turns
on the numbers in the company’s balance sheet, and especially
those in its capital accounts, why should the law allow the
company to reduce those numbers so as to facilitate a
distribution to shareholders, either immediately or in the future?
More generally, the creditors might conceivably rely on the
numbers stated in the capital accounts as an indication of its
creditworthiness, that is, as indicating the level of the
shareholders’ commitment to the company. In principle, the
company cannot reduce its capital, but the law has long
recognised that it is legitimate to do so in some circumstances,
subject to safeguards to protect creditors and to deal with intra-
shareholder conflicts, especially conflicts among different
classes of shareholder.
13–31
The following are examples of situations where a reduction of
the numbers in the capital accounts might be thought to be
legitimate. Suppose the company has traded unsuccessfully, so
that its net asset value (assets less liabilities) is less than its legal
capital. However, the company has found a new investor who is
prepared to inject funds into the company so that it can try an
alternative business plan. In return, however, the new investor
wants to make sure that any profits made in the future can be
paid out immediately and that he or she obtains the fair share of
those profits. Thus, the investor requires that, before the issue of
new shares is made, the value of the company’s legal capital
accounts is reduced to reflect the value of the existing
shareholders’ equity in the company. In short, the new investor
does not want his investment to fund the past losses of the
company nor that existing shareholders should participate in
future profits except to the extent that their investments have
survived the company’s previous trading misfortunes. Both these
aims can be achieved if the company’s legal capital is reduced to
the level of its current net asset value.142 For example, if the
company’s net asset value is half its legal capital, the shares
having all been issued at par, equilibrium could be achieved by
reducing the nominal value of the existing shares by half. The
new investor would then obtain twice the number of shares—
again assuming issuance at par—when the new money is
injected compared to the pre-reduction situation. This ensures
fairness as between old and new investors as well as allowing
future profits to be distributed immediately they are earned.
There is no particular reason for the creditors to object to this
procedure: any contribution by the new investor to the assets of
the company improves their position because their claims on the
company’s assets have priority over those of the shareholders
(old and new).
13–32
A situation at the opposite end of the spectrum is where the
company has more equity capital than it needs and wishes to
reduce its capital by repaying the holders of a particular class of
share. Here, the reduction of capital is indeed accompanied by a
return of assets to the shareholders. One might say that the return
of assets to the shareholders is the driving force behind the
transaction and the reduction of capital is the consequent
adjustment to the balance sheet which is necessary to reflect
what has been done. Here, reduction of capital appears as a
functional substitute for a redemption or re-purchase of shares,
as discussed in the previous section of this chapter. However,
there is one significant difference. The outcome of the reduction
procedure is a decision which is binding on all the shareholders
in question. This may also be the case in a redemption
(depending on how the terms of issue were drafted), but it is not
the case in a re-purchase where, as we have seen, the statutory
procedure simply makes it lawful for company and shareholder
to agree to the re-purchase.143 In this example, since assets are
being returned to shareholders, the interests of creditors can be
said to be engaged, whilst the decision as to which shareholders
are to be squeezed out of the company and on what terms may
provide fertile ground for intra-shareholder conflicts.
The statutory procedures
13–33
For many years successive Companies Acts have provided a
procedure through which the reduction can be effected and the
claims of shareholders and creditors that the proposed reduction
is adverse to their interests can be evaluated and protection
provided, if it is due.144 Before the passage of the 2006 Act there
was only one procedure. The general principle was that a
company might reduce its capital if the proposal was adopted by
a special resolution of the shareholders and confirmed by the
court. However, a private company rarely needed to resort to that
procedure. The main situation in which a private company may
wish to reduce capital is when it needs to buy out a retiring
member of the company or to return to the personal
representatives of a deceased member his share of the capital,
but has insufficient profits available for dividend to enable it to
do so except out of capital. As we have seen above,145 when
companies were empowered to purchase their own shares,
special concessions were made to private companies to enable
them to do so out of capital and without the need for a formal
reduction. This provided a substitute for capital reduction which
met the needs of private companies in many cases.146 However,
the 2006 Act introduced an alternative procedure for the
reduction of capital by private companies, for which court
confirmation is not needed, but it left in place the special rules
enabling private companies to re-purchase shares out of capital.
In the case of public companies, the 2006 Act left the previous
law unchanged.
Whichever procedure is used, the Act provides that a company
may reduce its share capital “in any way”147 but it then sets out
three typical situations, which are important because of their
different implications for creditor protection. The three situations
are: (a) by reducing or extinguishing the amount of any uncalled
liability on its shares148; (b) by cancelling any paid-up share
capital “which is lost or unrepresented by available assets”149; (c)
by paying off any paid-up share capital which is in excess of the
company’s wants.150 Situations (b) and (c) are exemplified by the
examples discussed in paras 13–31 and 13–32. In situation (a),
which arises only where the company has issued shares as not
fully paid up, a shareholder’s liability to the company is
terminated and so the interests of the creditors are engaged, as
are the interests of the shareholders whose commitments to the
company are fully paid up.151
Procedure applying to all companies
13–34
Under the procedure applying to all companies a reduction of
capital requires a special resolution of the members and
confirmation by the court.152 It is the requirement for court
approval which is supposed to provide the necessary protection
for creditors (as well as for minority shareholders insofar as the
supermajority vote requirement does not achieve that end). The
obtaining of shareholder consent is most likely to raise tricky
issues where there is more than one class of share and the
reduction does not affect all the classes rateably. If the rights of a
class of shareholders are affected by the reduction proposal, the
separate consent of that class will be required under the “class
rights” provisions discussed in paras 19–13 et seq.153 In
particular, companies have often wanted to cancel the shares
issued to preference shareholders, whose entitlement to a fixed
preference dividend has moved out of line with interest rates in
the market, so that the contribution of those shareholders can be
re-financed more cheaply. The courts have held that mere
cancellation of preference shares does not infringe their rights,
provided the preference shareholders are treated in accordance
with the rights they would have on a winding up of the
company.154 Thus, the question becomes whether the reduction
of the preference shares meets this test. Although the court
probably has discretion to approve a reduction of shares which
infringes class rights and which has not secured the consent of
that class, it is highly unlikely to do so.155 Where there is only
one class of share, the minority’s protections are less
extensive,156 though they do have the chance to oppose the
confirmation of the reduction by the court under the reduction
procedure.
Creditor objection
13–35
Creditor protection is provided solely through the mechanism of
court confirmation of the reduction proposal.157 The practical
pressure generated by the procedure used to be towards making
the company discharge or secure all the creditors’ claims
outstanding at the time of the reduction before application was
made to the court for confirmation. These were the remedies the
court could order in favour of an objecting creditor.158 In order to
avoid the difficulty of identifying every one of a fluctuating
body of trade creditors, companies often felt obliged to short-
circuit the objection procedure and arrange for a sufficient sum
to be deposited with or guaranteed by a bank or insurance
company to meet the claims of all the unsecured creditors before
applying for court confirmation. The Company Law Review
(“CLR”) thought that the interests of creditors were thus often
over-protected, because creditors obtained either payment of or
security for their previously unsecured debts, whether or not
their chances of repayment had been adversely affected by the
repayment of capital.159 However, its proposal for reform did not
make its way into the Act. Nevertheless, the story did not end
there. In 2006 the European Union amended the Second
Directive’s provisions on reduction of capital160 so as to make
them less protective of creditors. The Government’s initial
reaction was not to take advantage of this new flexibility,161 but
after consultation changed its mind.162 The reduction of capital
provisions of the 2006 Act were then amended by statutory
instrument163 so as to make the procedure less protective of
creditors, thus achieving, albeit by slightly different wording, the
policy recommended by the CLR.
The crucial change is that it is no longer the case that every
creditor is entitled to object to the reduction of capital who, at
the relevant date, has a debt or claim which would be admissible
in proof were the company being wound up.164 Under the prior
law this was the position where the reduction fell within cases
(a) or (c) above (para.13–33) or analogous cases.165 Now, in
order to obtain a right of objection the creditor, upon whom the
burden of proof lies, must demonstrate not only the existence of
situations (a) or (c) and an admissible debt or claim but, in
addition, “a real likelihood that the reduction would result in the
company being unable to discharge the debt or claim when it fell
due”.166 The list of objecting creditors will, in future, thus consist
of those who have demonstrated that their claim is subject to real
risk of non-payment if the reduction goes ahead, so that the
pressure on the company to settle the claims of all creditors
should be mitigated, if not eliminated.
Confirmation by the court
13–36
In principle, the court is required to settle a list of creditors and
to do so as far as possible without requiring an application from
a creditor to be included on the list.167 However, this rarely
happens.168 In the past this was because creditors were repaid or
secured before confirmation was sought, as indicated above. It
would be an unwanted side-wind of the introduction of the “real
likelihood” test if court consideration of the claims of objecting
creditors became routine. In fact, the court has power to order
that the creditor objection procedure shall not apply in a
particular case.169 Under the new test companies are likely to rely
on evidence about their business prospects over the next few
years as grounds for dispensing with the objection procedure.
This is a form of non-statutory solvency certification. To date
the courts have been disposed to accept such evidence as
grounds for disapplication, stressing in particular that the test is
whether the reduction of capital creates a “real risk” of non-
payment for the creditor, so that the creditor’s continued
exposure to the general risks of the company’s business is not as
such permissible ground for objection.170
Even if there are no objecting creditors or their objections
have been dealt with, it appears that the court must still have
regard to creditor interests when deciding whether to confirm the
reduction “on such terms and conditions as it thinks fit”. This is
shown by the case law concerning reductions of capital because
that capital was not represented by available assets (i.e. case (b)
above). Here, there is no right of objection for creditors, unless
the court so orders.171 Nevertheless, the courts might regard the
interests of creditors in such a case as requiring protection at the
confirmation stage. A standard situation falling within case (b) is
where a company is required to write down the value of an asset
in its accounts (for example, a loan which the company now
thinks is unlikely to be re-paid), thus extinguishing its
distributable profits. It then wishes to reduce its share capital
(and probably its share premium account) so as to permit the
distribution of future profits. However, a variation on this theme
is where, on the facts, it is possible (and foreseeable at the time
of the write-down) that the asset may recover in value. In that
case the court may impose a condition that any amount
recovered in the future should be put in an undistributable
reserve. However, it seems that this will be required only if
needed to protect the creditors existing at the time of the write-
down172 and that future creditors are regarded as sufficiently
protected by the publicity requirements for the reduction of
capital (below).
13–37
The court may make ad hoc publicity requirements part of its
order confirming the reduction, including the requirement that,
for a specified period, the company include the words “and
reduced” in its name.173 In addition, the company must deliver a
copy of the court order and a statement of its capital,174 as now
reduced, to the Registrar, who must register and certify them175;
the registration must be publicised; and the reduction takes effect
only upon registration.176 It is conceivable that the reduction in
capital would mean that the company no longer met the
minimum capital requirements for a public company, in which
case it must re-register as a private company before the Registrar
will register the reduction (unless the court orders otherwise).177
13–38
Minority shareholders as well may seek—or the court may
provide—protection at the confirmation stage, even if the
requirements for shareholder meetings have been met before
application to the court. The two main requirements for
shareholder protection which the court will insist on are that the
reduction treat the shareholders equitably and that the reduction
proposal be properly explained to the shareholders who
approved it. It is established that the court must be satisfied on
these matters, even if the petition for confirmation is unopposed,
as it often will be.178 However, before a conclusion of
inequitable treatment is reached, a significant risk to those
shareholders arising out of the reduction must be identified.
Thus, in Re Ransomes Plc179 a substantial reduction in share
premium account was permitted over the objections of
preference shareholders, in order to permit a distribution to the
ordinary shareholders, on the grounds that the preference
shareholders’ entitlements to dividend and return of capital (non-
participating in both cases) were not put at risk by the proposed
distribution. Even after the proposed distribution, the company
would have assets and projected profits well in excess of what
was required to meet the preference shareholders’ entitlements.
In other words, the protection for both creditors and shareholders
now revolves around the same general notion: their objections
will be plausible if the reduction is likely significantly to harm
their entitlements. The apparently strict procedural requirements
of proper explanation have been somewhat qualified by the
adoption of a “no difference” rider, i.e. the court may forgive
procedural inadequacies if convinced that following the correct
procedure would have led to the same result.180
Procedure available to private companies only
13–39
The provisions for reduction of capital without court
confirmation apply only to private companies. These were
introduced in 2006 to mitigate the delay and cost involved in
court confirmation. The CLR wished to make this procedure
available to public companies as well, but with the rider, needed
to meet the requirements of the Second Directive, that creditors
entitled to object to the reduction could invoke the court to veto
or modify the reduction.181 In place of court confirmation
reliance would be put on a solvency statement made by the
directors. For both types of company the procedure with court
confirmation (above) would be kept as an alternative, because it
allows directors to avoid the potential liabilities arising out of the
solvency statement.182 However, in the event the Act makes the
procedure of reduction without court approval available to
private companies only (which retain the option of using the
court-based procedure).183
Solvency statement
13–40
Under the procedure available to private companies only, a
special resolution of the shareholders is still required,184 as
discussed above, with the need to hold separate meetings of each
class of shares whose rights are varied by the proposed
reduction. However, the resolution of the members is to be
supported by a solvency statement from the directors rather than
confirmed by the court. The essence of the solvency statement is
that to some degree it transfers responsibility for the reduction
from the court to the directors of the company. This is a gain for
the company in terms of speed and cost, but a potential risk for
the directors, in so far as personal liability attaches to their
approval of the solvency statement.185 The solvency statement,
which must accompany the resolution, is not an entirely novel
device in British company law. It was required as part of the
(now repealed) “whitewash” procedure available to private
companies wishing to give financial assistance for the purchase
of their own shares.186 Something similar is also to be found in
the rules governing share re-purchases by private companies
from capital.187 However, unlike the re-purchase statement, the
solvency statement on a reduction of capital is not required to be
audited.
The solvency statement is a statement by each director of the
company, who must each sign it.188 Each director asserts in it
that he or she has formed an opinion on two matters. The first
relates to the company’s current financial position at the time the
statement is made and is to the effect that “there is no ground on
which the company could be found unable to pay (or otherwise
discharge) its debts”.189 The second relates to the future and
covers a period of one year after the date of the statement. The
second opinion comes in two alternative forms.190 If it is
intended to commence the winding up of the company within a
year,191 then the required opinion is that the company will be
able to pay or otherwise discharge its debts within 12 months of
the winding up. In any other case, it is that the company will
able to pay (or discharge) its debts as they fall due within the 12
months after the date of the statement. The required opinion
relates only to the payment or discharge of debts (i.e. claims on
the company to pay a liquidated sum). However, the directors
are required to take into account contingent and prospective
liabilities when forming their opinions.192 The obligation to take
into account prospective liabilities is hardly surprising, since
these are liabilities which will certainly become due in the future
(though it may not be clear precisely when). Contingent
liabilities are those which may arise in the future because of an
existing legal obligation or state of affairs. In other words,
directors have to take account of contingent and prospective
liabilities which may become debts payable by the company and
imperil its ability to pay its debts, either at the date of the
statement or, more likely, as they fall due over the 12-month
period required to be considered under the second opinion.193
13–41
The transfer of responsibility to the directors is most graphically
illustrated by the provision in the Act that it is a criminal offence
for a director to make a solvency statement without having
reasonable grounds for the opinions expressed in it—unless the
solvency statement is not delivered to the Registrar, so that the
reduction does not take effect.194 This criminalises purely
negligent conduct on the part of the director, an unusual step, for
the Act normally confines criminal sanctions to knowing or
reckless misstatements. The greater liability imposed by the Act
is an indication of the importance attached by the legislature to
the accuracy of the solvency statement. The Act is silent on the
civil liabilities of the directors for making an inaccurate solvency
statement. The CLR had recommended that there should be an
express civil liability on the directors to pay up the capital
reduced,195 but this suggestion is not taken up in the Act.
However, it seems clear, at least where the reduction involves a
return of assets to the shareholders, that the directors could be
liable to the company for the loss suffered on the grounds that
they are in breach of their general duties to the company; and
that those who receive the assets with knowledge of the breach,
whether directors or shareholders, would be liable to restore
them to the company, under the principles discussed in relation
to unlawful dividends.196 It is further arguable that the reduction
is ineffective where the directors have not made a solvency
statement in accordance with the requirements of the Act, in
particular where they do not have reasonable grounds for the
opinions expressed in it.197 In this case, the recipients could be
said to be liable to return the company’s assets, whether they
know of the breach or not, subject only to defences such as
change of position.198
13–42
A copy of the solvency statement must be provided to the
members voting on the reduction resolution (in different ways
according to whether the vote is at a meeting or by written
resolution),199 but it is expressly provided that failure to observe
these requirements does not affect the validity of the resolution
passed.200 The solvency statement must precede the date on
which the resolution is passed by no more than 15 days and, if
this is not the case, it appears the resolution cannot be said to be
supported by a solvency statement. Thus, if the date for passing
the resolution slips for one reason or another, the directors will
be required to review and re-issue their solvency statement.
After the passing of the resolution, the company has a further 15
days to file the copy of the resolution and the solvency statement
and a current statement of the company’s capital with the
Registrar.201 It is only with the registration of these documents
by the Registrar (thus making them publicly available) that the
reduction is effective.202 Failure to deliver the documents to the
Registrar on time does not affect the validity of the resolution
but it does constitute an offence on the part of every officer of
the company in default.203
Reduction, distributions and re-purchase
13–43
Provided a private company observes the requirements of the
Act, especially the requirement laid upon the directors to have
reasonable grounds for the beliefs stated in the solvency
statement, it is provided with an inexpensive and quick method
of reducing its capital. It is arguable that, in consequence, the
test for the legality of a distribution by such a company is a
solvency test. Although the cumulative profits test, discussed in
Ch.12, still applies to private companies, the impact of that rule
can be mitigated by reducing the company’s capital to write off
losses, provided the solvency test (and other requirements of the
private company procedure) are met. However, it may be that
this step does not generate profits for a distribution even after the
company’s capital has been reduced, even to near vanishing
point. Consequently, in this case the net accumulated profits rule
will still operate as a binding constraint on distributions,
especially if the private company was only thinly capitalised in
the first place.204
The simplified procedure for reduction of capital without
court approval also constitutes a functional substitute for a re-
purchase or redemption out of capital, as discussed above.205
Which will prove more popular where both mechanisms are
available? Re-purchase out of capital has the virtue of familiarity
and may continue to be used quite widely, at least initially, but
the procedure for reduction out of court seems simpler and
cheaper. No auditors’ report is required on the directors’
solvency statement, no special accounts have to be prepared206
and there is no right of objection to the court on the part of
creditors or non-approving members.
FINANCIAL ASSISTANCE
Rationale and history of the rule
13–44
Section 678 prohibits a public company (or its subsidiary) from
giving financial assistance to a person for the acquisition by that
person of the company’s shares, whether the assistance is given
in advance of or after the acquisition. The history of this rule
does not constitute one of the most glorious episodes in British
company law. The rationale for its introduction was under-
articulated; it has proved capable of rending unlawful what seem
from any perspective to be perfectly innocuous transactions; and
it has proved resistant to a reformulation which would avoid
these problems. The CLR eventually decided that, for private
companies, the only way forward was to take them out of the
scope of the rule altogether, which reform proposal was
implemented in the 2006 Act. The CLR also proposed a series of
amendments to the rule as it applies to public companies,207 but
most of these were not implemented in the 2006 Act. The
Government took the view that the Second Directive prevented
significant changes to the rule as it applies to public
companies.208 Since then, the Second Directive itself has been
amended,209 but the Government regarded the relaxations
introduced as not significant210 and pinned its hopes on a more
radical reform of the Directive in the future (which, however,
seems unlikely to occur).
The rule against financial assistance for acquisitions of the
company’s shares was not developed by the nineteenth century
judges as part of the capital maintenance regime. Rather, it was a
statutory reform introduced in the 1929 Act as a result of the
recommendations of the Greene Committee.211 Although
conventionally dealt with, as in this work, under the heading of
legal capital, it is clear that in formal terms financial assistance
may have no impact on the company’s legal capital. If a
company lends £100,000 to someone to purchase its shares from
another investor and that person does not act as a nominee for
the company but acquires the shares beneficially, the company’s
share capital, share premium account and capital redemption
reserve will not be in any way altered by that loan or the
subsequent purchase of the shares. The Greene Committee
seems to have thought that financial assistance offended against
the spirit, if not the letter, of the rule in Trevor v Whitworth
(company prohibited from acquiring its own shares),212 but the
Jenkins Committee commented that, had the ban “been designed
merely to extend that rule, we should have felt some doubt
whether it was worth retaining”.213
Nor does financial assistance necessarily reduce the
company’s net asset position. If in the above example the
borrower is fully able to repay the loan, the company is simply
replacing one asset (cash) with another (the rights under the
loan) and possibly the latter will earn the company a higher rate
of return. For obvious reasons, there is no general principle of
creditor protection in company law which prohibits the company
from altering the risk characteristics of its assets,214 and so it is
by no means clear that the rule against financial assistance be
justified on that ground.
13–45
In fact, the Greene Committee seems to have been heavily,
perhaps inappropriately, influenced by the use of financial
assistance in schemes which it disapproved of for more general
reasons. The Committee thought, in particular, that it was
abusive to finance a takeover by a loan and immediately repay it
by raiding the coffers of the cash-rich company which is taken
over or to use the assets of the new subsidiary as security for the
takeover loan.215 Now that highly leveraged takeovers are a
common event, this worry looks somewhat overdone. More to
the point, as it has operated in recent years, the financial
assistance rule has not proved a major hindrance to such
takeovers. In particular, the legislation has for some time
permitted a payment of cash from the new subsidiary to the
parent provided it is made by way of lawful dividend.216 This
suggests that, at least under the current law, the objection is not
to the use of the subsidiary’s cash balances to repay the loan but
rather that the aim is to allow repayment only in a way which
protects both creditors (by requiring the dividend to be paid in
accordance with the distribution rules)217 and minority
shareholders, since dividends are paid pro rata to the proportion
of the share capital held.218 In other words, the financial
assistance prohibition does not express a policy about desirable
and undesirable takeovers but more general concerns about
creditor and minority shareholder protection. However, the
financial assistance rule seems too broad to be supported on a
simple creditor or minority shareholder rationale, as the above
example of a loan to purchase shares suggests. For example, if
the loan were for some purpose other than the purchase of
shares, the rule would not bite, yet the borrower might be less
able to repay the loan than the borrower for the share purchase.
13–46
However, the Greene Committee’s recommendations were
enacted as s.45 of the 1929 Act, which was re-enacted with
amendments as s.54 of the 1948 Act. Section 45 immediately
revealed the difficulties involved in drafting a prohibition that
was properly targeted on the perceived abuses. That section,
despite its relative brevity, became notorious as unintelligible
and liable to penalise innocent transactions while failing to deter
guilty ones. The Jenkins Committee219 suggested an alternative
approach very similar to that eventually adopted in 1981 in
relation to private companies, but at the time no action was taken
on that suggestion and, when the Second Company Law
Directive was adopted, it became impracticable in relation to
public companies.220
However, in 1980 two reported cases221 caused considerable
alarm in commercial and legal circles, suggesting, as they did,
that the scope of the section was even wider, and the risk of
wholly unobjectionable transactions being shot down even
greater, than had formerly been thought. Hence it was decided
that something had to be done about it in the 1981 Act which
was then in preparation. Probably more midnight oil was burnt
on this subject than on all the rest of that Act, and the resulting
elaborate provisions were certainly some improvement on s.54.
However, they still did not produce the holy grail of a precisely
targeted prohibition and, after the controversy generated by the
House of Lords decision in Brady v Brady,222 the Government
made proposals for the further relaxation of the provisions.223
However, before these proposals could be implemented, the
CLR was established, with the results described above. In the
meantime, the difficulty of producing a targeted formula
continued to be demonstrated in litigation, for example, in the
decision of the Court of Appeal in Chaston v SWP Group Ltd224
in 2002.
The prohibition
13–47
Section 678 distinguishes between assistance given prior to the
acquisition and that given afterwards.225 Its subs.(1) says that,
subject to exceptions:
“where a person226 is acquiring or is proposing to acquire227 shares in a public
company, it is not lawful for that company, or a company that is a subsidiary of that
company,228 to give financial assistance directly or indirectly229 for the purpose of
that acquisition before or at the same time as the acquisition takes place.”
13–54
The trial judge, and O’Connor LJ in the Court of Appeal,257 had
thought that the larger purpose was to resolve the deadlock and
its inevitable consequences; and Croom-Johnson LJ258 had found
it in the need to reorganise the whole group. But if either could
be so regarded, it would follow that, if the board of a company
concluded in good faith that the only way that a company could
survive was for it to be taken over, it could lawfully provide
financial assistance to the bidder—the very “mischief” that the
legislation was designed to prevent. The logic is, of course,
impeccable. But the result seems to reduce the purpose
exceptions to very narrow limits indeed and to make one wonder
whether the midnight oil burnt on the drafting of the two
subsections had achieved anything worthwhile.
The transaction was in fact saved by application of the special
provisions then applying to private companies (now repealed).
However, the (eventually) successful outcome in that particular
case did not get rid of the awkward issues raised by it. The
DTI259 floated the ideas of substituting “predominant reason” for
“principal purpose” or relying solely on the test of good faith in
the interests of the company. The CLR supported the first of
these suggestions.260 However, these suggestions do nothing to
address the arguments put forward in the House of Lords in
favour of giving the purpose requirements a strict interpretation,
if the prohibition is to remain a meaningful restriction. In any
event, the 2006 Act retains the established wording.
Exemption for private companies
13–55
In the reforms of 1981 a more relaxed regime for private
companies was introduced, allowing assistance if this did not
involve a reduction of the company’s net assets or if the
financial assistance was given out of distributable profits.261 The
effect of this provision was to tie the financial assistance rule
more clearly to the creditor protection concerns of the rules
applying to distributions.262 The 2006 Act went further and
removed the financial assistance prohibition from private
companies, as the CLR recommended. Section 678 applies only
to financial assistance given to a person who is proposing to
acquire shares in a public company or, in relation to an
acquisition which has occurred, where the company whose
shares have been acquired is at the time of the assistance a public
company. Consequently, where a public company is taken over
and then re-registered as a private company, it may give
financial assistance by way of reducing or discharging the
liabilities of the (new) parent incurred for the purpose of the
acquisition.263 The limitation in s.678 thus focusses on the
private status of the company whose shares are subject to the
acquisition. Consequently, if a private subsidiary gives financial
assistance for the purchase of the shares of its public parent, as
in the Chaston case,264 that situation will still be caught by the
prohibition. Moreover, the prohibition is extended by s.679 to
catch financial assistance given by a public company towards the
acquisition of shares in its private holding company—an unusual
but not impossible situation.265 In this case the status of the
provider of the assistance as a public company subsidiary is
enough to trigger the rule.
Civil remedies for breach of the prohibition
13–56
The only sanctions prescribed by the Act for breaches of the
prohibition are fining the company266 and fining or imprisoning
(or both) its officers in default.267 More important are the
consequences in civil law resulting from the fact that the
transaction is unlawful. Unfortunately, precisely what these
consequences are has vexed the courts both of England and of
other countries which have adopted comparable provisions and it
is a pity that the current Act did not attempt to clarify the
position.268
What has caused the courts to make heavy weather of this is
the somewhat curious wording of the prohibition down the years.
Since the object of the section is to protect the company and its
members and creditors, one would have expected it to say that it
is not lawful for any person who has acquired or is proposing to
acquire shares of a company to receive financial assistance from
the company or any of its subsidiaries. That would have pointed
the courts in the right direction to work out the consequences.
But instead it declares that it is unlawful for the company to give
the assistance, and follows that by imposing criminal sanctions
on the company and (the one thing that makes good sense) on
the officers of the company who are in default. This could be
taken to imply (and was so taken by Roxburgh J in Victor
Battery Co Ltd v Curry’s Ltd)269 that the object of the prohibition
was not to protect the company but to punish it and its officers
by imposing fines. This calamitous decision continued to be
accepted in England, and was cited with apparent approval by
Cross J (subsequently a Law Lord) 20 years later,270 though
rejected by the Australian Courts whose decisions helped those
in England eventually to see the light. The decision has now
been disapproved or not followed in a series of cases271 and is
accepted to be heretical.
13–57
Freed from the fetters of that heresy the courts have since given
the section real teeth and it is submitted that the following
propositions can now be regarded as reasonably well established:
(a) An agreement to provide unlawful financial assistance, being
unlawful, is unenforceable by either party to it. This
proposition is undoubted and authority for it is the decision of
the House of Lords in Brady v Brady.272 However, if the
contract could be performed legally (i.e. without giving
unlawful financial assistance), but unlawful financial
assistance is in fact provided, then the legality of the contract
depends on whether the other party to it was party to a
common design to act unlawfully.273
(b) However, the illegality of the financial assistance given or
provided by the company normally does not taint other
connected transactions, such as the agreement by the person
assisted to acquire the shares. It would be absurd if, for
example, a takeover bidder which had been given financial
assistance by the target company, or by a subsidiary of the
company, could escape from the liability to perform purchase
contracts which it had entered into with the shareholders of
the target. Clearly, it cannot.
(c) This, however, is subject to a qualification if the obligation to
acquire the shares and the obligation to provide financial
assistance form part of a single composite transaction. The
obvious example of this would be an arrangement in which
someone agreed to subscribe for shares in a company (or its
holding company) in consideration of which the company
agreed to give him some form of financial assistance. In such
a case the position apparently depends on whether the terms
relating to the acquisition of shares can be severed from those
relating to the unlawful financial assistance. If they can, those
relating to the acquisition can be enforced. If they cannot, the
whole agreement is void. The authorities supporting this
proposition are the decisions of Cross J in South Western
Mineral Water Co Ltd v Ashmore274 and of the Privy Council
in Carney v Herbert.275 In essence, the facts of both were that
shares of a company were to be acquired and payment of the
purchase price was to be secured by a charge on the assets of,
in the former case, that company and, in the latter, its
subsidiary. The agreed security was, of course, unlawful
financial assistance. In the former case, the shares had not
been transferred or the charge executed; in the latter, they
had. In the former it was held that unless the sellers were
prepared to dispense with the charge (which they were not)
the whole agreement was void and that the parties must be
restored to their positions prior to the agreement. In the latter
it was held that the unlawful charge could be severed from
the sale of the shares and that the sellers were entitled to sue
the purchaser for the price. Despite the different results, the
Privy Council judgment, delivered by Lord Brightman, cited
with approval the decision of Cross J in the earlier case. In
both cases a fair result seems to have been arrived at and
certainly one preferable to that for which the assisted
purchaser contended in Carney, namely that he should be
entitled to retain the shares without having to pay for them.276
It is therefore to be hoped that even in a single composite
transaction the courts will permit severance or order restitutio
in integrum unless there are strong reasons of public policy277
why the whole transaction should be treated as unlawful so as
to preclude the court from offering any assistance to any
party to it.
(d) If the company has actually given the unlawful financial
assistance, that transaction will be void. The practical effect
of that depends on the nature of the financial assistance. If it
is a mortgage, guarantee or indemnity or the like, the party to
whom it was given cannot sue the company upon it.278 It is
that party who suffers,279 and the company, so long as it
realises in time that the transaction is void, need do nothing
but defend any hopeless action that may be brought against it.
If, however, the unlawful assistance was a completed gift or
loan, the company will need to take action if it is to recover
what it has lost. And a long line of cases has established that,
in most circumstances, this it will be able to do.280 Its claim
may be based on misfeasance, when recovery is sought from
the directors or other officers of the company, or on
restitution, conspiracy, or constructive trust, when the claim
is against them or those to whom the unlawful assistance has
passed or who have otherwise actively participated in the
unlawful transaction. The most popular basis seems to be
constructive trust, the argument being that the directors
committed the equivalent of a breach of trust when they
caused the company’s assets to be used for the unlawful
purpose and the recipients became constructive trustees
thereof. The constructive trust is discussed further in Ch.16,
below.
(e) In the light of propositions (a)–(d) it would also seem to
follow that if the unlawful assistance given by the company is
a loan secured by a mortgage or charge on the borrower’s
property281 then, so long as the company has rights of
recovery from the borrower under proposition (d), it should
be able to do so by realising its security. This would certainly
be so if the mortgage or charge could be severed from the
unlawful loan—which, however, might be regarded as
impossible since the consideration given for the mortgage or
charge was the unlawful loan. But, since the effect of the
recent case law is to recognise that the object of the
prohibition, despite its wording, is to protect the company,
the courts ought not to boggle at the conclusion that the
security given to the company can be realised to recover what
is due to it by the borrower.
(f) The above points all go to the validity of the financial
assistance transaction and transactions associated with it. In
addition, the directors who cause the company to give the
unlawful finance assistance may be found to have been in
breach of their duties to the company and the company is not
prevented from enforcing those duties against the directors
(normally to recover any loss suffered) by virtue of the fact
that the company’s act in providing the assistance was
unlawful.282
13–58
It will therefore be seen that we have come a long way from the
time when it was believed that the only likely sanctions were
derisory fines on the company and its officers in default. These
developments have caused the banking community some alarm,
for there is no doubt that banks could find themselves caught out
—as indeed they have been in the past.283 The fact that money
passing in the relevant transactions is likely to do so through
banking channels inevitably exposes banks to risks.284 The
government proposed, in consequence, that transactions in
breach of the prohibition should no longer be void for that
reason alone,285 but the Act did not take up this proposal.
CONCLUSION
13–59
The elaborate rules on preservation of legal capital, discussed in
this chapter, can be justified only if the role of legal capital in
controlling distributions by companies is regarded as a valuable
one. This was discussed in Ch.12. If the concept of legal capital
were removed from the distribution rules, the Act could be
simplified substantially by largely removing the rules on
reduction of capital—or at least by confining them to their
shareholder protection aspects—and simplifying those on the
redemption and re-purchase of shares. Creditor protection would
then turn on other concepts. The financial assistance rules, by
contrast, are a candidate for reform even if the concept of legal
capital is maintained, since they have no necessary connection
with that doctrine in their current form. Further, the other goals
which the financial assistance rules might be thought to promote
are, these days, probably better targeted by other provisions with
less potential for disruption of innocuous transactions. For
example, where a target company in a takeover lends money to,
or indemnifies against loss, known sympathisers who buy its
shares or where, on a share-for-share offer, either or both of the
target and predator companies do so to maintain or enhance the
quoted price of their own shares, such practices are now
regulated by the provisions on market abuse or by the rules of
the Takeover Panel.286 Again, in the case of abuses in the period
prior to insolvency the provisions on wrongful trading may be
better targeted.287 Progress on either front, however, requires
changes to EU law in the shape of the Second Directive, since
that Directive is still committed to legal capital as a required
element in the test for distributions by public companies and its
relaxation in 2006 of the financial assistance rules did not go far
enough to encourage significant domestic reform.
1Trevor v Whitworth (1887) 12 App. Cas. 409 HL. Since at this stage in the
development of UK company law, there was no distinction between public and private
companies, the rule necessarily applied to all companies incorporated under the Acts.
2 2006 Act s.658(1)—the exemption of unlimited companies from this prohibition shows
the connection between the rule and creditor protection.
3
2006 Act s.658(2).
4 2006 Act s.670. There are also exceptions for companies whose ordinary business
includes the lending of money and the charge is part of that business, and for charges
taken by a private company before it re-registered as public.
5 2006 Act s.660(2). In effect, the nominee arrangement is unwound by the law.
6
2006 Act.661(2), but the court has the power to relieve a director or subscriber who
has acted honestly and reasonably from the whole or part of the liability: s.661(3)–(4).
7 2006 Act s.660.
8
Though the financial assistance rules, below, para.13–44, may apply.
9
2006 Act s.144.
10
However, if such a transaction were permitted, the parent’s legal capital account
would not be reduced by the fact that one of its members is a subsidiary—any more than
in the case of shares held by a nominee—so that it would not become easier for the
parent to make distributions.
11
2006 Act s.137(1)(b), (c). The company may not exercise the voting rights attached to
the shares, once it becomes a subsidiary (s.137(4)), but this does little to help creditors.
12 Acatos & Hutchinson Plc v Watson [1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 218. Technically, the basis of
the decision was that the bidder was acquiring the shares of the its new subsidiary, not
its own shares.
13
2006 Act s.659(1)—“otherwise than for valuable consideration”. This was held to be
permissible at common law in Re Castiglione’s Will Trust [1958] Ch. 549, where the
acquisition was through a nominee, but the Act permits direct acquisition in such a case.
14
2006 Act s.659(2)(c).
15 2006 Act s.662(1)(a),(2),(3)(a).
16 These problems were originally tackled by the Companies (Beneficial Interests) Act
1983: see now the 2006 Act ss.671–676. The acquisition of such shares is likely to be
financed by the company and the company may have a residuary beneficial interest in
them which, under these provisions, may be disregarded.
17 2006 Act s.659(2)(b), which also lists three other situations where the court may order
the purchase of shares, i.e. under ss.98, 721(6) and 759.
18 2006 Act s.659(2)(a).
19
2006 Act s.669.
20This result will be achieved as a result of the requirement in s.831 that a public
company may make a distribution only to the extent that its net assets (unchanged in this
example) exceed its legal capital and undistributable reserves (increased in the example
by the value of the share purchase).
21 See para.19–35.
22 Perhaps because they were already capable of being squeezed out through the
reduction procedure (see para.19–35, below) and the redemption mechanism allowed the
parties to contract about the handling of this process.
23The crucial policy document was The Purchase by a Company of its own Shares
(DTI, 1980, Cmnd. 7944).
24
2006 Act s.684(4).
25 Moreover, after issue, the non-redeemable shares cannot be re-purchased so as to
produce the result that the company has only redeemable or treasury shares in issue:
s.690(2). Nor may a private company reduce its share capital through the solvency
statement regime so as to produce the result that it has only redeemable shares in issue:
s.641(2). In the case of the court-centred reduction, the court could permit such a
reduction but, presumably, would be unlikely to do so.
26
2006 Act s.690(2). On treasury shares, see below para.13–24.
27
2006 Act s.684.
28
2006 Act s.551 and see para.24–4.
29Thus enabling the company to “redeem” them prior to a date fixed in the terms and
conditions if it can reach agreement with the holder.
30
2006 Act s.690. A purported re-purchase in breach of the articles would be void,
because the company would no longer be protected from the operation of s.658(2)
(above, para.13–2); cf. Hague v Nam Tai Electronics Inc [2007] 2 B.C.L.C. 194 PC.
31 See paras 13–19 et seq.—though that protection was somewhat reduced in 2013.
32
1985 Act s.160(3).
33
Though not as flexible as the CLR’s recommendation, which would have given the
directors an unconditional power to set the terms of the redemption: Final Report I,
para.4.5.
34
2006 Act s.685(4).
35
2006 Act.685(1),(2).
36 2006 Act s.685(3).
37 2006 Act ss.686(1).
38
2006 Act s.691(1).
39
2006 Act s.686(2)—otherwise the shares must be paid for on redemption: s.686(3).
402006 Act s.691(2)—except in relation to a private company purchasing shares
pursuant to an employee share scheme. For the problems to which this lack of flexibility
can give rise see Peña v Dale [2004] 2 B.C.L.C. 508; Kinlan v Crimmin [2007] 2
B.C.L.C. 67 (though in the latter case the judge managed to avoid requiring the
shareholder to return to the company the money received by resort to the defence of a
good faith change of position).
41 2006 Act ss.689 (redemption) and 707 (re-purchase).
42
2006 Act ss.687(2) and 692(2).
43 2006 Act ss.687(3), (4) and 692(2)(b), (3).
44 To see this, let us suppose that, immediately before the re-purchase, a public company
has net assets exactly equivalent to its then legal capital. Thus, it has distributable profits
of zero. It raises money by issuing 100 new shares at par at £2 per share. Its share capital
account will increase by £200. It uses the money to re-purchase 100 £1 shares at a
premium of £1, the shares having been originally issued at par. After cancellation of the
re-purchased shares, the company’s share capital will be reduced by £100 (the nominal
value of the shares). However, by raising the finance for the re-purchase in the way
indicated, the company has brought about a net increase in its legal capital of £100 (the
increase arising out of the new issue (£200) less the nominal value of the shares re-
purchased and cancelled (£100)). It cannot distribute the amount needed to finance the
redemption premium without reducing its net assets below the (newly increased) capital
yardstick. It must thus finance the premium on re-purchase out of distributable profits or
not pay a redemption premium at all.
45
2006 Act s.688.
46
2006 Act s.733(2).
47
2006 Act s.733(3).
48 2006 Act s.692(1ZA).
49
See para.13–39, below.
50
2006 Act s.709(1).
51
2006 Act s.709(2).
52
HL Debs, Grand Committee, Tenth Day, 20 March 2006, cols.31–32.
53 2006 Act s.710.
54 2006 Act s.711.
55
2006 Act s.712(6),(7). The available profits so determined have then to be treated as
reduced by any lawful distributions made by the company since the date of the accounts
and before the date of the statutory declaration: s.712(3),(4).
56 2006 Act s.714(4). On the requirements for a capital reduction see para.13–40, below.
57
Presumably on the grounds that a re-purchase to enable the founding entrepreneur to
retire is in those circumstances unnecessary: the withdrawal can take place as part of the
winding up. Section 714(3)(b) requires the statement to say that the directors’ opinion is
that the company will be able to carry on business as a going concern in the following
year “having regard to their intentions with respect to the management of the company
during the year”, so that they could not honestly make the required statement if they
contemplated a winding up.
58
2006 Act s.714(3)(b).
59 As to the opinion about the current position, that relates to the position “immediately
following” the date on which the PCP is proposed to be made (s.714(3)(a)) rather than
the date of the statement (cf. s.643(1)(a)), so that it requires a small degree of foresight.
60 2006 Act s.715 cf. s.643(4) (see below, para.13–41).
61
Insolvency Act 1986 s.76. See fn.73, below.
622006 Act s.714(6). The less demanding “solvency statement” approach is used for
payments out of capital for purchases under an employee share scheme (s.720A).
632006 Act s.718(1),(2)—the method of disclosure varying according to whether a
written resolution or a resolution at a meeting is contemplated.
64
2006 Act s.718(3), cf. s.642(4) applying to solvency statements, where the validity of
the resolution is expressly preserved (see para.13–42, below) and reliance is placed
instead on criminal sanctions to produce compliance with the disclosure obligation:
s.644(7).
65 2006 Act s.717, cf. s.695.
66
2006 Act s.721(1),(2). The shareholder should know about the resolution but the
creditor may not. Consequently, s.719 requires publicity to be given to the resolution,
within one week of its adoption, giving the relevant details, including the amount of the
PCP and naming a place where the directors’ and auditors’ reports may be consulted.
67
2006 Act s.721(3)–(7).
68
2006 Act s.723.
69
See para.13–12 above. Since this is a private company procedure, there is no question
of the company holding the shares in treasury. See para.13–24.
70
2006 Act s.734(4).
712006 Act s.734(3). Section 734(4) deals with the complication where the purchase is
partly by way of PCP and partly by way of the proceeds of a fresh issue.
72But note the example given above in para.13–13 where the PCP is greater than the
company’s CRR and share premium account.
73
Insolvency Act 1986 s.76. The directors of the company who signed the statement are
jointly and severally liable with the shareholders unless the director can show reasonable
grounds for the opinion set out therein.
74
2006 Act s.693(2),(5). See para.25–8, below.
75
However, even if the trade takes place on a RIE it will not count as a market purchase
if the market authorities have given only restricted permission for trading in the shares:
s.693(3)(b).
76
The contract may be entered into before approval, but in that case no shares may be
purchased in pursuance of it before approval is obtained: s.694(2)(b). Under s.693A the
requirements discussed in this section are somewhat modified in connection with
purchases under an employee share scheme, but these variations are ignored here.
77The Government’s reasons for downgrading minority protection were not particularly
persuasive: below, fn.82 at para.25 (“sufficient other safeguards” but none as effective).
78 2006 Act s.694(3).
79There is the potential small disadvantage to the contingent purchase contract that the
consideration for the contract or any variation of it must be provided out of distributable
profits (s.705). However, the actual acquisition of the shares may be funded in
accordance with the rules discussed in para.13–11.
80 2006 Act s.694(4).
81
2006 Act s.694(5). Until 2009 the period was 18 months.
82 BIS, Implementation of Nuttall Review – Recommendation V: Government response
to consultation February 2013, para.22, interprets s.694 as meaning that a private
company cannot give advance approval at all but it is far from clear that this is what the
section says.
83 Or, on a written resolution, vote any shares held: s.695(2).
842006 Act s.695 which also provides (a) that it applies whether the vote is on a poll or
by a show of hands; (b) that, notwithstanding any provision in the company’s articles,
any member may demand a poll; and (c) that a vote and a demand for a poll by a
member’s proxy is treated as a vote and demand by the member.
85
See also s.239 for the exclusion of shareholders from voting on the ratification of their
own wrongdoing as directors (para.16–193).
86
2006 Act s.696. In the case of a written resolution the information is sent to the
members at or before the copy of the proposed resolution: s.696(2)(a). In either case the
names of members holding shares to which the contract relates must be disclosed. These
rights, being for the benefit of the shareholders, may be waived by their unanimous
agreement: Kinlan v Crummin [2007] 2 B.C.L.C. 67; and see para.15–8.
87
2006 Act ss.697–699.
88
2006 Act s.700.
89
As in the case of off-market purchases, the authority may be varied, revoked or
renewed by a like resolution: s.701(4).
90 2006 Act s.701(2).
91 2006 Act s.701(3). The resolution may specify a particular sum or a non-discretionary
formula for calculating the price (for example, by reference to the market price of the
shares): s.701(7).
92 2006 Act s.701(5). Again, 18 months until 2009. But the purchase may be completed
after the expiry date if the contract to buy was made before that date and the
authorisation permitted the company to make a contract which would or might be
executed after that date: s.701(6).
93
2006 Act s.701(8), applying Ch.3 of Pt 3 of the Act to this ordinary resolution.
94
This includes preference shares which are participating in either dividend or
distributions on a winding up: LR, Glossary Definition, “equity share capital”.
95 LR 12.4.2.
96
LR, Glossary Definition, “tender offer”.
97
LR 12.4.1. If a higher limit is permitted under the market stabilisation rules (see
para.30–37), that will replace the 5 per cent figure.
98 LR 12.4.7–8.
99LR 12.3.1. The rule will catch on-market transactions as well if there was an
understanding at the time of the resolution to repurchase that a particular related party
would be able to take up the offer.
100LR 11.1.7(4)(b). “Associate” is defined widely in LR, Glossary Definition,
“associate”.
101LR 12.4.4–6. In addition the legislation requires ex post disclosure of the shares
purchased in the directors’ annual report: SI 2008/410 Sch.7 Pt 2.
102LR 12.2.1. The specific protections against liability for market abuse in the course of
share buy-backs are dealt with in para.30–44, below.
103
Investment Association, Share Capital Management Guidelines, 2014, 1.3.1.
104 These difficulties do not arise in relation to redemptions. Nor does the issue of
payment for a variation arise in relation to a market contract since these cannot be
varied.
105 Though, in case (a), the division of the total price between that paid for the option
and that paid on its exercise may be arbitrary.
106
Which, in case (a) and perhaps (b), would be made some time before any actual
purchase and which in cases (a) and (c) might never be made at all.
107
2006 Act s.705.
108
2006 Act s.688(a).
109
See DTI, Share Buybacks, URN 98/713 (1998).
110
DTI, Treasury Shares, URN 01/500 (2001).
111
FSMA 2000 Pt VIII, especially s.118 and the Financial Services and Markets Act
2000 (Prescribed Markets and Qualifying Investments) Order 2001 (SI 2001/996). See
Ch.30. Note also that a company cannot assign its rights under a contract to re-purchase
shares (s.704), whether the shares are to be held in treasury or not, and this rule reduces
the company’s ability to trade in its own shares.
112
By the Companies (Acquisition of Own Shares) (Treasury Shares) Regulations 2003
(SI 2003/1116) and the No.2 Regulations (SI 2003/3031). See G. Morse, “The
Introduction of Treasury Shares into English Law and Practice” [2004] J.B.L. 303.
113 This was achieved through the repeal of s.725.
114
2006 Act s.724(1),(2), as originally enacted.
115
2006 Act s.741(1),(2), as amended.
116 2006 Act s.724(1)(b).
117 2006 Act s.727(1)(a). Cash is widely defined in s.727(2). There is one minor
restriction: where a company has been the subject of a successful takeover offer (which
included the treasury shares) and the bidder is using the statutory squeeze-out procedure,
the treasury shares can be sold only to the bidder: s.727(4) and see para.28–69, below.
118
See para.24–4, below.
119
2006 Act s.560(3).
120 See para.24–14, below.
121
2006 Act s.731(2).
122 2006 Act s.731(3). On the share premium account see para.11–6.
123Of course, what is transferred to the share premium account is the excess above the
nominal value of the share (see para.11–6), whereas what is being transferred here is the
excess above the purchase price.
124 2006 Act s.727(1)(b).
1252006 Act s.729. It may be obliged to cancel them if the shares cease to be
“qualifying shares”: s.729(2),(3).
1262006 Act ss.729(4) and 733(4). The directors may do this without following the
reduction of capital procedure: s.729(5).
127 2006 Act ss.728 and 730.
128
2006 Act s.726(1),(2).
129
2006 Act s.726(3)—including a distribution on a winding up.
130
2006 Act s.726(4)(a),(5). On capitalisation issues see para.11–20.
131
2006 Act.731(4)(b).
132
By the same token, the value treasury shares acquired by purchase will be reduced by
the bonus issue, thus reducing the amount of realised profit arising on their re-sale.
133
The company could, presumably, protect itself from being in breach by expressly
providing in the contract that the purchase is conditional upon its having the needed
proceeds or sufficient profits.
134
2006 Act s.735(2).
135
In any event, the section does not protect the company against paying damages in all
cases as a result of its failure to redeem. See British & Commonwealth Holdings Plc v
Barclays Bank Plc [1996] 1 W.L.R. 1 CA, below.
136
2006 Act s.735(2),(3). This ignores the possibility that it has adequate proceeds of a
fresh issue but has nevertheless decided to break the contract. Surely the seller should
then be entitled to specific performance?
137British & Commonwealth Holdings Plc v Barclays Bank Plc [1996] 1 W.L.R. 1 CA.
The case also raises issues about financial assistance which are discussed at para.13–49,
below.
138
2006 Act s.735(4). Hence in respect of these shares the seller will cease to be a
member or “contributory” and will become a creditor in respect of the price.
139
2006 Act s.735(6). In a solvent liquidation the shareholder may be worse off than if
shares had not been redeemed or purchased, if the share gave a right to participate in
surplus assets but the purchase or redemption price did not reflect the value of this right.
140
2006 Act s.735(5).
141
2006 Act s.641, introducing the reduction procedures, in terms applies only to the
share capital account, but the share premium account and capital redemption reserve are
treated as share capital for the purposes of the reduction procedure: ss.610(4) and
733(6).
142 There are other techniques which could be used to achieve the same result, such as
issuance at par of a new class of share to the new investor where the new class has a
lower par value than and priority as to dividends over the existing shares, but issuing
shares of the same class after a reduction may reduce the risk of intra-shareholder
disputes in the future.
143 See para.13–7, above.
144Reduction of capital is to be distinguished from the situation where the company
simply divides its share capital into shares of a smaller nominal value or consolidates
them into shares of a larger nominal value, but where the aggregate nominal value of the
shares (and thus the company’s share capital) remains the same, though there is a
smaller or a larger number of shares representing that aggregate. These steps present no
creditor protection issues and the matter is one for the shareholders alone (s.618).
However, there are potential issues of intra-shareholder conflict with divisions: see
Greenhalgh v Arderne Cinemas [1946] 1 All E.R. 512 CA; and para.19–18, below.
145
Above at para.13–13.
146
2006 Act s.617(5) makes it clear that a repurchase or redemption of shares in
accordance with the Act does not fall foul of the prohibition on altering share capital
contained in that section.
147
2006 Act s.641(3).
148
2006 Act s.641(4)(a)—in the unlikely event of its having uncalled capital.
149
2006 Act s.641(4)(b)(i). Technically share capital (a notional liability) cannot be
“lost” (see Ch.11, above) but may well be “unrepresented by available assets”. However,
this does not seem to have bothered the courts which have interpreted “lost” to mean that
the value of the company’s net assets has fallen below the amount of its capital (i.e. its
issued share capital, and, if any, its share premium account and capital redemption
reserve) and that this “loss” is likely to be permanent.
150
2006 Act s.641(4)(b)(ii).
151
Where there is a reduction of capital by means of extinguishing uncalled capital, it is
normal accounting practice to create a reserve to reflect the reduction. Section 654 says
the reserve is to be undistributable, but allows the Secretary of State to specify cases
where the prohibition does not apply. Making ample use of this power reg.3 of the
Companies (Reduction of Share Capital) Order 2008/1915 says the reserve is to be
treated as a realised profit under both procedures, unless the court order, the company’s
articles or a company resolution specify otherwise.
152
2006 Act s.641(1)(b). The previous requirement that the company have power under
its articles to reduce its capital has been removed.
153The issue of how to identify of the rights of preference shareholders is discussed in
Ch.23.
154
The proposition that the preference shareholders are treated in breach of their rights
by cancellation of their shares and deprivation of a favourable dividend entitlement was
decisively rejected by the Court of Appeal in Re Chatterly-Whitfield Collieries [1948] 2
All E.R.593, so that the issue has become whether the terms of the reduction are in
accordance with the rights which they would have on a winding up. The effect of the
decision was to make preference shares in effect redeemable by the company, even if not
formally issued as redeemable, provided the company could satisfy the requirements of
the reduction procedure. It is to be noted that a reduction in order to replace preference
shares with a cheaper form of financing does not clearly fall within any of the three
categories specified in s.641(4) but it does fall within s.641(3)—reduction “in any way”:
Re Hunting Plc [2005] 2 B.C.L.C. 211.
1552006 Act s.645 in terms requires only a resolution of the company, not of the class in
question.
156 These possibilities are also discussed in Ch.19.
157
2006 Act s.645(1).
158 2006 Act s.648(2).
159 Strategic, para.5.4.5.
160Directive 2006/68/EC amending art.32 of Directive 77/91/EEC (now art.36 of the
2012 version of that Directive).
161 DTI, Implementation of the Companies Act 2006, February 2007, Ch.6.
162
The Government response to the consultation on the implementation of amendments
to the 2nd Company Law Directive, 28 October 2007.
163
The Companies (Share Capital and Acquisition by Company of Own Shares)
Regulations 2009 (SI 2009/2022) reg.3. The Secretary of State has power under s.657 to
amend a number of the elements in Pt 17 of the Act, in addition to the usual powers
under s.2 of the European Communities Act 1972.
164
Not all claims a creditor might make in the future are provable: see Re Liberty
International Plc [2010] 2 B.C.L.C. 665 (debtor liable only if a third party exercises a
discretion so as to impose the liability).
165
See s.645(2). The court has a dispensing power under s.645(4), but this was rarely
used against creditors whose claims had not been secured. In case (b) there is no right of
objection, unless the court so orders: s.645(4).
166
2006 Act s.646(1)(b). That likelihood, “beyond the merely possible, but short of the
probable”, will be more difficult to demonstrate the further into the future the debt falls
due: Re Liberty International [2010] 2 B.C.L.C. 665 at [19]–[20].
167
2006 Act s.646(2)(3).
168
In Re Royal Scottish Assurance Plc, 2011 S.L.T. 264 Lord Glennie stated that this
had not been done, in either Scotland or England, since 1949.
169 2006 Act s.645(2)—this was the formal basis on which the prior practice avoided the
creditor objection procedure. Under s.645(3) the court may also order that the procedure
shall not apply to particular class or classes of creditor because of “the special
circumstances of the case”.
170Re Vodafone Group Plc [2014] 2 B.C.L.C. 422; Re Sportech Plc, 2012 S.L.T. 895;
Re Royal Scottish Assurance Plc, 2011 S.L.T. 264.
171 2006 Act s.645(4).
172Re Grosvenor Press Plc [1985] B.C.L.C. 286; cf. Re Jupiter House Investments
(Cambridge) Ltd [1985] B.C.L.C. 222.
173 2006 Act s.648(3)(4).
174
Equivalent to that required on an allotment of shares.
175 The certificate constitutes “conclusive evidence” that the statutory reduction
requirements have been complied with and that the company’s share capital is as stated
in the statement of capital: s.649(6).
176 2006 Act s.649. There is more flexibility about the effective date where the reduction
is part of a scheme of arrangement because that is normally upon delivery of the order to
the Registrar, a matter under the control of the company (see Ch.29 and CLR, Final
Report, para.13.11): s.649(3)(a).
177 2006 Act s.650. An expedited re-registration procedure, which dispenses with
shareholder authorisation, may be used if the court authorises it (s.651). The basis for
this provision is presumably the shareholder authorisation which was a necessary step in
the reduction procedure.
178 Re Ransomes Plc [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 591, 602 CA.
179 Re Ransomes Plc [1999] 1 B.C.L.C. 775 (affirmed on appeal; see previous note). See
also Re Ratners Group Plc [1988] B.C.L.C. 685; and Re Thorn EMI Plc (1988) 4 B.C.C.
698 (reduction of share premium account to write off goodwill arising out of the same
transaction as generated the premium).
180
See previous note—a hypothetical and sometimes difficult judgment, which the
courts should use sparingly.
181
Company Formation and Capital Maintenance, para.3.27. However, in the absence of
creditor objection, court involvement would not be necessary.
182
Completing, para.7.9.
183
DTI, Company Law Reform, Cm. 6456, para.4.8 rejected the application of the
alternative procedure to public companies. It was thought that the possibility of creditor
objection and thus court involvement would lead public companies to opt for the court-
confirmation route, though it is not clear that this is a strong argument against making
the option available to public companies.
184
2006 Act s.641(1)(a).
185
Under the court procedure, liability (for example, in negligence) could attach to the
directors for proposing the reduction, but they would be protected to a considerable
extent against such liability in practice by the subsequent examination of the scheme by
the court.
186Companies Act 1985 s.155. The financial assistance rules no longer apply to private
companies: see below, para.13–55.
187
See above, para.13–14.
188
2006 Act s.643(1),(3) and the Companies (Reduction of Share Capital) Order
2008/1915 reg.2. Although the section does not extend to shadow directors, the term
“director” does include de facto directors: see s.250. In Re In A Flap Envelope Co Ltd
[2004] 1 B.C.L.C. 64, a case arising under the financial assistance whitewash procedure,
a director who resigned for part of a day in order that the statement could be signed by
his replacement, was held to be a de facto director during this period and thus liable to
make the statement required under those provisions.
189 2006 Act s.643(1)(a).
190
2006 Act s.643(1)(b).
191So that the reduction of capital is a prelude to a winding up, as in Scottish Insurance
Corp Ltd v Wilsons and Clyde Coal Co Ltd [1949] A.C. 462 HL.
192 2006 Act s.643(2).
193
The language of s.643 reflects to some considerable degree the language to be found
in s.123(1)(e) of the Insolvency Act, on which see R. Goode, Principles of Corporate
Insolvency Law, Student Edn (London: Sweet & Maxwell, 2005) paras 4–15 to 4–23 and
4–28 to 4–29.
194
2006 Act s.643(4). The offence is punishable by imprisonment, whether tried
summarily or on indictment: s.643(5).
195 Company Formation and Capital Maintenance, para.3.35.
196 See para.12–12. However, the specific statutory rules on distributions will not be
relevant since a reduction of capital in cases (a) and (c) does not amount to a distribution
for the purposes of Pt 23 (s.829(2)(b)) and in case (b) no assets are returned to the
shareholders.
197
If a solvency statement is not made in accordance with s.643, the resolution for the
reduction of capital appears not to be “supported by a solvency statement” as s.642(1)
requires and no other provision of the Act explicitly saves the resolution from this
defect.
198
cf. MacPherson v European Strategic Bureau Ltd [2000] 2 B.C.L.C. 683 CA.
199
2006 Act s.642(2),(3). On these different methods of shareholder decision-making
see Ch.15.
200
2006 Act s.642(4). However, it is an offence on the part of every officer in default to
fail to comply with this requirement: s.644(7)–(8), but liability is restricted to a fine.
201
2006 Act s.644(1),(2) and the Shares Regulations reg.10.
202
2006 Act s.644(3),(4).
203 2006 Act s.644(6),(7).
204
For a discussion of the general test applying to distributions by private companies
see para.12–3.
205
See para.13–13.
206 Though the directors can hardly make the required statement unless they have at
least up-to-date management accounts.
207
Company Formation and Capital Maintenance, paras 3.42 and 3.43. These proposals
were derived in the main from proposals for reform made earlier by the DTI itself.
208 DTI, Company Law Reform, Cm. 6456, March 2005, paras 42–43.
209
Now arts 25 and 26 of the current version of the Second Directive (Directive
2012/30/EU).
210DTI, Implementation of Companies Act 2006: A Consultative Document, February
2007, para.6–26.
211
Cmnd. 2657 (1926).
212
See fn.1, above.
213 Cmnd. 1749 (1962), para.173. Of course, if the shares are held by the person to
whom the assistance is given, not beneficially, but as a nominee for the company, then
the provisions discussed above at para.13–3 will apply (so that the financial assistance
rules are not necessary to address the nominee situation).
214 Lenders may impose such constraints by contract, of course. See para.31–24.
215On variations on this theme see Selangor United Rubber Estates v Cradock (No.3)
[1968] 1 W.L.R. 1555; Karak Rubber Co v Burden (No.2) [1972] 1 W.L.R. 602; and
Wallersteiner v Moir [1974] 1 W.L.R. 991 CA (pet. dis.) [1975] 1 W.L.R. 1093 HL.
216 2006 Act s.681(2).
217 See paras 12–1 and 12–2.
218 See para.19–2.
219
Cmnd. 1749 (1962) paras 170–186.
220
See art.23 of Directive 77/91 [1977] O.J. L26/1.
221
Belmont Finance Corp v Williams Furniture Ltd (No.2) [1980] 1 All E.R. 393 CA;
Armour Hick Northern Ltd v Whitehouse [1980] 1 W.L.R. 1520.
222
Brady v Brady [1989] A.C. 755 HL.
223
DTI, Company Law Reform: Proposals for Reform of Sections 151–158 of the
Companies Act 1985 (1993); DTI, Consultation Paper on Financial Assistance
(November 1996).
224
Chaston v SWP Group Ltd [2003] 1 B.C.L.C. 675, helpfully considered by E. Ferran,
“Corporate Transactions and Financial Assistance: Shifting Policy Perceptions but Static
Law” (2004) 63 C.L.J. 225.
225
On the other hand, the drafters seem to have thought of financial assistance, whether
given before or after the event, as a one-off transaction. For the difficulties involved in
calculating the impact of the assistance on the company’s net assets where the assistance
is continuing, see Parlett v Guppys (Bridport) Ltd [1996] 2 B.C.L.C. 34 CA.
226The Government’s interpretation of the section is that the person must be someone
other than the company itself: HC Debs, Standing Committee D, 20 July 2006, cols.
856–857 (Vera Baird).
227 In contrast with s.54 of the 1948 Act, which used the expression “purchase or
subscription”, this section refers to “acquire” or “acquisition” thus extending the ambit
of the section to non-cash subscriptions and exchanges.
228
The sections do not apply to financial assistance by a holding company for the
acquisition of shares in its subsidiary; in such a case there is less likelihood of prejudice
to other shareholders or to creditors. The subsidiary must be a “company” within the
meaning of the Act (see s.1) so that foreign subsidiaries are not caught by the
prohibition. This was the view taken previously: see Arab Bank Plc v Merchantile
Holdings Ltd [1994] Ch. 755.
229
A charge given by a company to secure a loan to the company which both lender and
company knew was to be on-lent to the purchaser of a company’s shares to finance the
purchase constitutes indirect financial assistance: Re Hill and Tylor Ltd [2005] 1
B.C.L.C. 41; Central and Eastern Trust Co v Irving Oil Ltd (1980) 110 D.L.R. (3d) 257
Sup Ct. Can.
230 The words “or with any other person” are somewhat puzzling; one would have
expected “or that of any other person”. Can there be an agreement or arrangement which
is not made with some other person? And, if there can, would it not be covered by “or by
any other means”?
231 The difficulty of doing this after a takeover is mind-boggling.
2322006 Act s.677(1)(a)–(c)—other than an indemnity given in respect of the
indemnifier’s own neglect or default.
233
e.g. where a company which is a diamond merchant sells a diamond to a dealer for
£100,000, payment to be 12 months hence, the intention being that the dealer will sell
the diamond at a profit or borrow on its security thus putting him in funds to acquire
shares in the company.
234
In some cases (e.g. gifts) they will be; in others (e.g. loans or guarantees) they may
or may not.
235
Defined as “the aggregate of the company’s assets, less the aggregate of its
liabilities” and “liabilities” includes any provision for anticipated losses or charges:
s.677(2).
236
Above, fn.224.
237
If the assistance had been provided by the parent, as it could well have been, no
question of financial assistance would probably have arisen.
238
But reimbursement of the costs of digesting and assessing the information could be,
as in Chaston. Nor is assistance financial if it consists of the parent instructing its
subsidiary to pay money to the vendor of the shares, where no financial asset leaves the
parent and the assistance provided by the (foreign incorporated) subsidiary is lawful:
AMG Global Nominees (Private) Ltd v Africa Resources Ltd [2009] 1 B.C.L.C. 281 CA.
This is a surprising decision and the CA’s reliance on the Arab Bank case (above,
fn.228) seems misplaced, since the issue there was the legality of the assistance provided
by the subsidiary and not, as in AMG, the assistance provided by the parent.
239 cf. MT Realisations Ltd v Digital Equipment Co Ltd [2003] 2 B.C.L.C 117 CA—
enforcement of security rights was recovery of a legal entitlement rather than the receipt
of financial assistance.
240See Plaut v Steiner (1988) 5 B.C.C. 352, but note also the insistence by the Court of
Appeal in British & Commonwealth Holdings Plc v Burclays Bank Plc [1996] 1 W.L.R.
1 CA that the terms used in the definition must be given their technical meaning (in this
case in relation to the meaning of an “indemnity”).
241 Above, para.13–28.
242
Above, fn.224.
243
In Anglo Petroleum Ltd v TFB (Mortgages) Ltd [2007] B.C.C 407, a differently
constituted CA took a more commercially robust line, notably in rejecting the argument
that any payment by a company which “smoothed the path to the acquisition” of its
shares constituted financial assistance.
2442006 Act.681. There is no express exemption for the expenses of share issues (for
example, commissions—see para.11–14), but there clearly should be.
245 2006 Act s.682(2). There is also a conditional exception for financial assistance
given in connection with private company acquisitions, but this is of such importance
that it is treated separately in para.13–55 below.
246 2006 Act s.682(1). Distributable profits are defined in s.683(1), which essentially
tracks the rules governing distributions.
247 Directive 2012/30/EU [2012] O.J. L315/74
248 Above, fn.210, para.6.23. For trenchant criticism of the limited scope of the reforms
to art.23, see E. Ferran, “Simplification of European Company Law on Financial
Assistance” (2005) 6 E.B.O.L.R. 93.
249Belmont Finance Corp v Williams Furniture Ltd (No.2) [1980] 1 All E.R. 393 CA;
Armour Hick Northern Ltd v Whitehouse [1980] 1 W.L.R. 1520.
250 Dymont v Boyden [2005] 1 B.C.L.C. 163 CA.
251Brady v Brady [1989] A.C. 755 HL. This case is an illustration (of which
Charterhouse Investment Trust v Tempest Diesels Ltd ([1987] B.C.L.C. 1) is another) of
how, all too often, parties agree in principle to a simple arrangement which on the face
of it raises no question of unlawful financial assistance but then refer it to their
respective advisers who, in their anxiety to obtain the maximum fiscal and other
advantages for their respective clients, introduce complicated refinements which
arguably cause it to fall foul of the prohibition on financial assistance. In the
Charterhouse case, where the former s.54 applied, Hoffmann J, by exercising
commonsense in interpreting the meaning of “financial assistance”, was able to avoid
striking down an obviously unobjectionable arrangement. But the elaborate definition of
that expression in the present Act leaves less scope for commonsense.
252
Brady v Brady [1988] B.C.L.C. 20 CA.
253
Brady v Brady [1989] A.C. 755 at 778. Agreeing with O’Connor LJ in the Court of
Appeal ([1988] B.C.L.C. 20 at 25) he described the paragraph, with commendable
restraint, as “not altogether easy to construe”.
254The layout of ss.678(2) and (4) now reflects this analysis more clearly than did the
previous legislation.
255
A situation envisaged by Buckley LJ in his judgment in the Belmont Finance case
[1980] 1 All E.R. at 402, as giving rise to doubts under the former s.54 of the 1948 Act.
256 Brady v Brady [1989] A.C. 755 at 779.
257 Brady v Brady [1988] B.C.L.C. 20 at 26.
258
Brady v Brady [1988] B.C.L.C. 20 at 32.
259
Company Law Reform: Proposals for Reform of Sections 151–158 of the Companies
Act 1985 (1993).
260
Completing, para.7.14.
261
1985 Act s.155(2). As we have seen, the Directive now adopts this criterion as one of
the conditions under which financial assistance may be permitted (above, para.13–51).
262 See Ch.12.
263
Of course, the directors of the (new) subsidiary will need to continue to comply with
their fiduciary duties to their company.
264
Above, fn.224.
265 2006 Act s.679. An example might be where a target public company in a takeover is
re-registered as a private company (to avoid the ban on its giving financial assistance to
its new parent) but still has subsidiary companies which are public companies. Section
679 prevents the subsidiaries giving financial assistance to their immediate parent
(unless an exception applies). At least this is what s.679(3) appears to say.
266 Since the prohibition is intended to protect the company and its members and
creditors it is difficult to conceive of a more inappropriate sanction than to reduce the
company’s net assets (still further than the unlawful financial assistance may have done)
by fining the company. The CLR had proposed that the criminal sanction on the
company be removed: Formation, para.343(d).
267
2006 Act s.680.
268The remedies for an unlawful distribution are specifically excluded from the area of
unlawful financial assistance: s.847(4)(a).
269
Victor Battery Co Ltd v Curry’s Ltd [1946] Ch. 242.
270
Curtis’s Furnishing Stores Ltd v Freedman [1966] 1 W.L.R. 1219. But he ignored it
in South Western Mineral Water Co Ltd v Ashmore [1967] 1 W.L.R. 1110.
271
Selangor United Rubber Estate Ltd v Cradock (No.3) [1968] 1 W.L.R. 1555; Heald v
O’Connor [1971] 1 W.L.R. 497; and Lord Denning MR in Wallersteiner v Moir [1974]
1 W.L.R. at 1014H–1015A. The modern view helped Millett J to conclude in Arab Bank
Plc v Mercantile Holdings Ltd [1994] Ch. 71 that the legislation applies to assistance
provided by a subsidiary of an English company only where the subsidiary is not a
foreign company, on the grounds that the protection of the shareholders and creditors of
a company is a matter for the law of the place of incorporation. By the same token, the
giving of assistance by the English subsidiary of a foreign parent ought to be regulated
by the Act, though it is by no means clear that it is.
272
Brady v Brady [1989] A.C. 755. See also Re Hill and Tyler Ltd [2005] 1 B.C.L.C.
41.
273 Anglo Petroleum Ltd v TFB (Mortgages) Ltd [2007] B.C.C. 407 CA: a contract to
lend money to a company where the contract did not require the sum advanced to be
used to provide unlawful financial assistance but where the lender knew the money lent
was to be used to repay monies due to the company’s former parent from the purchaser
of the company’s shares from the former parent. The CA thought there was no public
policy in forcing the lender to investigate whether the proposed use of the loan would
constitute unlawful financial assistance and so held the contract of loan enforceable
(though this view was, strictly, obiter).
274
South Western Mineral Water Co Ltd v Ashmore [1967] 1 W.L.R. 1110.
275
Carney v Herbert [1985] A.C. 301 PC, on appeal from the Sup. Ct. of N.S.W.
276Yet Lord Brightman seemed to think that this would be the consequence if severance
was not possible: see [1985] A.C. at 309.
277
In support of this caveat, see [1985] A.C. at 313 and 317.
278 See the cases discussed under (c) and Heald v O’Connor [1971] 1 W.L.R. 497,
where the unlawful assistance was a mortgage on the property of the company whose
shares were being acquired, the purchaser guaranteeing the payment of sums due under
the mortgage. The mortgage was unlawful. Hence the purchaser escaped liability on the
guarantee (though that was lawful) since no payments were lawfully due under the
mortgage. It would have been different had the guarantee been an indemnity.
279Since the mortgage is illegal and void (not merely voidable) presumably a bona fide
purchaser of it without notice could not enforce it either.
280Steen v Law [1964] A.C. 287 PC; Selangor United Rubber Estates v Cradock (No.3)
[1968] 1 W.L.R. 1555; Karak Rubber Co v Burden (No.2) [1972] 1 W.L.R. 602;
Wallersteiner v Moir [1974] 1 W.L.R. 991 CA; Belmont Finance Corp v Williams
Furniture Ltd (No.2) [1980] 1 All E.R. 393 CA; Smith v Croft (No.2) [1988] Ch. 114;
Agip (Africa) Ltd v Jackson [1991] Ch. 547 CA.
281 Unless the company is a public company and the charge is on shares in it, for then
the charge may be void under s.670: see above, para.13–2.
282 Steen v Law [1964] A.C. 287; Selangor United Rubber Estates v Cradock (No.3)
[1968] 1 W.L.R. 1555; Chaston v SWP Group Plc [2003] 1 B.C.L.C. 675 CA. The same
principle is applied to actions the company may have against third parties who are
implicated in the provision of the financial assistance: Belmont Finance Corp Ltd v
Williams Furniture Ltd [1979] Ch. 250 CA.
283
See, for example, Selangor United Rubber Estates v Cradock (No.3) [1968] 1
W.L.R. 1555; Karak Rubber Co v Burden (No.2) [1972] 1 W.L.R. 602.
284
But they are afforded special protection since the prohibition does not invalidate a
loan “where the lending of money is part of the ordinary business of the company” and
the loan is “in the ordinary course of its business”: s.682(2)(a). This recognises that it
would be absurd if, on a public issue of shares by one of the major High Street banks, its
branches had to refuse to honour applicants’ cheques if they were customers who had
been granted overdrafts.
285
DTI, Consultation Paper on Financial Assistance (1996), para.14.
286
See Chs 28 and 30, below. This example is particularly pertinent since the Greene
Committee (above fn.211 at para.30) specifically mentioned the undesirability of a
company “trafficking in its own shares” are a justification for the prohibition on
financial assistance.
287
See Ch.9, above.
PART 3
Even after making allowances for the fact that the UK Corporate
Governance Code applies formally only to companies with a
Premium Listing of equity shares on the London Stock
Exchange,2 and that in small companies things may appear very
differently, this is a formidable specification for the board’s role.
14–2
However, it would be difficult to glean any similar
understanding of the importance of the board from a reading of
the Companies Act. Although s.154 requires all public
companies to have two directors and private companies one,3 it
leaves the determination of the role of the board very largely to
the company’s constitution, which is, of course, under the
control of the shareholders. Unlike in many, perhaps most, other
jurisdictions, the division of powers as between board and the
shareholders is a matter for private ordering by the members of
the company rather than something to be specified mandatorily
in the companies legislation. This may reflect the partnership
origins of British company law (under partnership law the
partners are given a very broad freedom to arrange the internal
affairs of the partnership as they wish) and it certainly facilitates
the use of a single Act to regulate all manner and sizes of
company. Jurisdictions which specify the role of the board for
large companies in legislation often have a separate statute for
smaller companies which gives the members in the latter class of
company a freedom nearer to that enjoyed by the members of a
British company.4 It is also a point of some theoretical (even
ideological) importance: the directors’ authority is derived from
the shareholders through a process of delegation via the articles
and not from a separate and free-standing grant of authority from
the State. This helps to underline the shareholder-centred nature
of British company law.
The default provision in the model articles
14–3
Since the division of powers between board and shareholders is a
matter for the articles (subject to a limited range of matters
where the statute requires the participation of the shareholders in
the decisions, discussed below), it is difficult to generalise about
the patterns of division found in practice. However, some limited
help can be gained from the model sets of articles which apply
unless excluded by the incorporators in a particular case.5 For
both public and private companies, the default provision is the
same, and it is one which gives substantial authority to the
board: “Subject to the articles, the directors are responsible for
the management of the company’s business, for which purpose
they may exercise all the powers of the company”.6 This follows
quite closely the provision found in earlier sets of model articles.
It is perhaps surprising that the model article for public
companies refers to “management” quite generally, since it is
clear that, in a large company, the totality of its management is
something quite beyond the grasp of even the most talented set
of directors. The provision of the UK Corporate Governance
Code, quoted above, is more realistic for large companies when
it gives the board the functions of setting the corporate strategy
and reviewing management performance, thus indicating that the
task of executive management is otherwise not for it but rather
for the full-time senior employees of the company. This
approach causes no formal difficulty for the model set of
articles, since the model gives the board a wide power of
delegation of the powers conferred upon them by the articles “to
such person to such an extent and on such terms and conditions
as they think fit”.7 Thus, delegation of powers by the board to
the senior management of the company is provided for in the
model articles. The point rather is that the strategy followed in
the model set of articles for public companies of a broad grant of
management power to the board which is then permitted a wide
power of delegation does not tell one what pattern of division of
function is in fact adopted in large companies between the board
and senior (and, indeed, other) management.8 On that, the UK
Corporate Governance Code may be a better guide.
14–4
Turning to private companies, here discharge of the full
management function by the board is often in fact possible, but it
is equally possible in small companies for the shareholders to
play a larger role in decision-making than in large companies.
Often in such companies important shareholders who are not
also directors will expect to have such a role. In quasi-
partnership companies in particular the incorporators may wish
to reproduce the rule which would apply if the entity were a
partnership rather than a company. This rule is that “any
differences arising as to ordinary matters connected with the
partnership business may be decided by a majority of the
partners, but no change may be made in the nature of the
partnership business without the consent of all existing
partners”.9 Such a desire again creates no formal problem for the
model articles, since the grant of management authority to the
board is “subject to the articles”. It is thus possible for the
articles to provide that certain types of decision shall either not
be given to the board at all or shall be subject to the
shareholders’ consent (even though such consent is not required
by the Act). Again, however, the model articles provide no hint
as to the ways in which or the extent to which this power is in
fact used in small companies to move away from the default
rule.
Thus, in both public and private companies (though for
different reasons) the model articles provide only a starting point
in determining the role of the board which may be modified
substantially through either board decisions to delegate authority
to management (in public companies) or modifications of the
articles in the case of private companies so as to confer decision-
making authority on the shareholders. One may wonder how
useful such a default provision is, but the truth is that the
variations from the default are so many and so varied (depending
on the circumstances of the particular company) that it is
impossible to identify a better default provision.
The power of the board—the legal effect of the
articles
The board and shareholders
14–5
It is not possible to make general statements about the typical
division of authority between shareholders and the board and
management, because that is, in the main, open to being tailored
to suit the individual company in question. But it is possible,
nevertheless, to analyse the legal effect of the articles. That has
changed over time, with an evolution in the answer being given
to the key question of whether the effect of the delegation of
authority in the articles to the directors was simply to confer
authority on the directors or also, at the same time, to restrict the
authority of the shareholders in general meeting to take decisions
in the delegated area. Was the relationship between company
and shareholders simply one of principal and agent10 or did the
articles effect something in the nature of a constitutional division
of powers as between the shareholders in general meeting and
the board? At one level, this was simply a matter of choosing the
appropriate default rule. A principal conferring authority on an
agent does not normally restrict its own authority to act, but
there is no reason why the principal should not contract on the
basis that the agent has authority to the exclusion of the
principal. Equally, a constitution normally divides up authority
among the various relevant bodies, but there is no legal reason
why a constitution should not confer concurrent competence on
two or more bodies. However, the choice between these two
legal analyses did affect very strongly the way in which the
courts approached the interpretation of provisions in the articles
of particular companies.
14–6
Until the end of the nineteenth century, it was generally assumed
that the general meeting was the supreme organ of the company
and the board of directors was merely an agent of the company
subject to the control of the company in general meeting. It
followed that the shareholders could at any time by ordinary
resolution give the directors binding instructions as to how they
were to exercise their management powers. Thus, in Isle of
Wight Railway v Tahourdin,11 the court refused the directors of a
statutory company an injunction to restrain the holding of a
general meeting, one purpose of which was to appoint a
committee to reorganise the management of the company.
In 1906, however, the Court of Appeal in Automatic Self-
Cleansing Filter Syndicate Co v Cuninghame,12 made it clear
that in registered companies the division of powers between the
board and the company in general meeting depended entirely on
the construction of the articles of association and that, where
powers had been vested in the board, the general meeting could
not interfere with their exercise. The articles were held to
constitute a contract by which the members had agreed that “the
directors and the directors alone shall manage”.13 Hence the
directors were entitled to refuse to carry out a sale agreement
adopted by ordinary resolution in general meeting where that
decision fell within the management powers conferred upon the
board. Tahourdin’s case was distinguished on the ground that the
wording of s.90 of the Companies Clauses Act 1845 was
different—though that section does not in fact seem to have been
relied on in the earlier case.
The new approach did not secure immediate acceptance,14 but
since Quin & Axtens v Salmon15 it has been generally accepted
that where the relevant articles are in the normal form, as
exemplified by successive model sets of articles, the general
meeting cannot interfere with a decision of the directors unless
they are acting contrary to the provisions of the Act or the
articles.16
In Shaw & Sons (Salford) Ltd v Shaw,17 in which a resolution
of the general meeting disapproving the commencement of an
action by the directors was held to be a nullity, the modern
doctrine was expressed by Greer LJ as follows18:
“A company is an entity distinct alike from its shareholders and its directors. Some
of its powers may, according to its articles, be exercised by directors, certain other
powers may be reserved for the shareholders in general meeting. If powers of
management are vested in the directors, they and they alone can exercise these
powers. The only way in which the general body of the shareholders can control the
exercise of the powers vested by the articles in the directors is by altering their
articles, or, if opportunity arises under the articles, by refusing to re-elect the
directors of whose actions they disapprove.19 They cannot themselves usurp the
powers which by the articles are vested in the directors any more than the directors
can usurp the powers vested by the articles in the general body of shareholders.”
Introduction 16–1
To Whom and by Whom are the Duties Owed? 16–4
To whom are the general duties owed and who can
sue for their breach? 16–4
By whom are the general duties owed? 16–8
Directors’ Duties of Skill, Care and Diligence 16–15
Historical development 16–15
The statutory standard 16–16
Remedies 16–20
Introduction to Directors’ Various Duties of Good Faith and
Loyalty 16–21
Historical background 16–21
Categories of duties 16–22
Duty to Act within Powers 16–23
Acting in accordance with the constitution 16–24
Improper purposes 16–26
Remedies 16–30
Duty to Exercise Independent Judgment 16–33
Taking advice and delegating authority 16–34
Exercise of future discretion 16–35
Nominee directors 16–36
Duty to Promote the Success of the Company 16–37
Settling the statutory formula 16–37
Interpreting the statutory formula 16–40
Overview of the No-Conflict Rules 16–52
Transactions with the Company (Self-Dealing) 16–54
The scope of the relevant provisions 16–54
Approval mechanisms 16–55
Duty to declare interests in relation to proposed
transactions or arrangements 16–57
Duty to declare interests in relation to existing
transactions or arrangements 16–64
Transactions between the Company and Directors
Requiring Special Approval of Members 16–67
Relationship with the general duties 16–68
Substantial property transactions 16–70
Loans, quasi-loans and credit transactions 16–78
Directors’ service contracts and gratuitous payments
to directors 16–84
Political donations and expenditure 16–85
Conflicts of Interest and the Use of Corporate Property,
Information and Opportunity 16–86
The scope and functioning of section 175 16–86
A strict approach to conflicts of interest 16–87
Identification of “corporate” opportunities 16–89
Competing and multiple directorships 16–99
Approval by the board 16–103
A conceptual issue 16–105
Remedies 16–106
Duty not to Accept Benefits from Third Parties 16–107
The scope of section 176 16–107
Remedies 16–108
Remedies for Breach of Duty 16–109
(a) Injunction or declaration 16–110
(b) Damages or compensation 16–111
(c) “Restoration” of property 16–112
(d) Avoidance of contracts 16–113
(e) Accounting for profits: disgorgement of disloyal
gains 16–114
(f) Summary dismissal 16–116
Shareholder Approval or “Whitewash” of Specific Breaches
of Duty 16–117
What is being decided? 16–118
Who can take the decision for the company? 16–119
Disenfranchising particular voters 16–121
Voting majorities 16–123
Non-ratifiable breaches 16–124
General Provisions Exempting Directors from Liability 16–125
Statutory constraints 16–125
Conflicts of interest 16–126
Provisions providing directors with an indemnity 16–128
Pension scheme indemnity 16–132
Relief Granted by the Court 16–133
Liability of Third Parties 16–134
Limitation of Actions 16–138
Conclusion 16–140
INTRODUCTION
16–1
In Ch.14 we saw that it is common for the articles of large
companies to confer extremely broad discretionary powers upon
the boards of such companies. The arguments in favour of giving
the centralised management a broad power to run the company
are essentially arguments of efficiency. At the same time, the
grant of a broad discretion creates a real risk that the powers will
be exercised by the directors other than for the purposes for
which they were conferred, and in particular will be exercised
more in the interests of the senior management themselves than
of anyone else. A central part of company law is thus concerned
with providing a framework of rules which, on the one hand,
constrains the potential abuse by directors of their powers, whilst
on the other hand does not so constrain the directors that the
efficiency gains from having a strong centralised management
are dissipated. This is an age-old problem for company law and
one that is constantly re-visited by successive generations of
rule-makers, for no one approach can be shown to have struck
the balance in an appropriate manner. It was a major issue in the
debates leading up to the passage of the Companies Act 2006.
On the part of the rule-makers a number of distinct responses
to this intractable problem can be identified. In Ch.14 we
examined the extent to which rules relating to the structure and
composition of the board itself and to the power of the
shareholders to remove members of the board are used to
constrain the exercise by the board of its powers and to produce
accountability to the members of the company. In the previous
chapter, we analysed the opportunities which the shareholders
have to intervene directly in the management of the company by
securing the passing at general meetings of resolutions binding
the company or by subjecting the performance of the
management to critical review. The taking of managerial
decisions by the shareholders themselves is necessarily an
activity of limited potential in large companies, since it flies in
the face of the efficiency arguments for centralised management
in the first place. Indeed, well-directed criticism of board
performance may be more effective, especially if accompanied
by an implicit or explicit threat of removal if performance is not
improved.
In addition to rules on board structure and the governance
rights of the members of the company, there is a third set of rules
of great longevity in our law which are intended to operate so as
to constrain the board’s exercise of its powers. These are the
duties which company law lays directly on the members of the
board as to limits within which they should exercise their
powers. These rules for directors were developed by the courts at
an early stage, often on the basis of analogy with the rules
applying to trustees. The substantial corpus of learning on the
nature and scope of these general fiduciary or equitable duties
and duties of skill and care has remained until very recently
largely within the common law. Both the Law Commission and
the Company Law Review (“CLR”),1 however, recommended a
“high level” statutory restatement of the common law principles.
This recommendation, controversial though it was, made its way
into the Companies Act 2006 Ch.2 of Pt 10 of which is headed:
“General Duties of Directors”.
16–2
The main aim behind the proposal for a “high level” statutory
statement of directors’ duties was to promote understanding of
the basic principles underlying this area of law, especially
among directors themselves. It was thought that this objective
would be furthered if there was a relatively brief statutory
statement of those principles in place of the previous situation
whereby those principles had to be deduced from an elaborate
body of case law. The behavioural premises upon which this
view was based were never extensively investigated. And indeed
the CLR and the Law Commission differed on whether the
statutory statement should be comprehensive, in the sense of
setting out at a high level all the duties to which directors were
subject (the CLR’s view) or only the principal duties, leaving the
courts to develop duties which had not yet been clearly
formulated in the cases (the Law Commissions’ view).2 In the
end, and despite the initial behavioural premises, the Act
probably comes closer to the Law Commissions’ view: s.170(3)
makes it clear that that only “certain” duties are set out in the
statute, and so, for example, the issue of directors’ duties to
consider the interests of creditors is not dealt with
comprehensively in Pt 10 of the 2006 Act and the courts remain
free to develop this aspect of the law, even at the level of general
principle.3 But the likelihood of significant common law
additions is small: the seven general duties set out in Ch.2 of Pt
10 have been long established at common law, and the courts
have been able to deal with new problems by development of
those general duties rather than by seeking to create new ones.
There were strong objections to codification. One, which was
strongly advocated in particular by the Law Society and some of
the leading commercial firms of solicitors in the City of London,
was that such a reform was in danger of “freezing” the law of
directors’ duties and impeding its further development as
circumstances changed. This contention could be refuted on two
fronts. First, the statutory statement was intended to be, and in
the Companies Act 2006 is, a “high level” statement, which
gives the courts plenty of interpretative scope when applying the
principles to the changing circumstances of commercial life. In
addition, s.170(4) adds two propositions: first, the statutory
general duties “shall be interpreted and applied in the same way
as the common law duties or equitable principles”, so that the
existing case law on the common law duties will remain, in most
cases, relevant to the interpretation of the statutory duties; and
secondly, “regard shall be had to the corresponding common law
rules and equitable principles in interpreting and applying the
general principles”. This second proposition is less obvious in its
purpose, which seems, however, to be as follows. The law
relating to directors was often developed by the courts by
analogy with the rules relating to the duties of trustees to their
beneficiaries and agents to their principals. Those rules continue
to be embodied largely in the common law. The second
proposition enables the courts, in developing the statutory duties
of directors, to take into account developments in the equivalent
common law duties applying to trustees and agents.4 Thus, there
was no desire on the part of the legislature to cut the law of
directors’ duties off from its historical roots in the duties
applying to other persons acting in a fiduciary character.
A second objection to codification was that a high-level
statutory statement would cause confusion or uncertainty about
the relationship between the statutory statement and existing or
future decisions of the courts at common law. These matters are
dealt with in subss.170(3) and (4). The first subsection
establishes the proposition that the general duties replace (“have
effect in place of”) the common law principles on which they are
based. Consequently, in future, any allegation of breach of duty
by the director to the company needs to be identified as a breach
of one or more of the general duties set out in the statute, except
insofar as the statutory statement preserves, as it does in relation
to creditors’ interests, the common law duties. And s.170(4)
indicates, as described earlier, how the common law cases are to
be used.
16–3
However, there is a difficulty underlying subss.170(3) and (4),
arising from the fact that, as we shall see, the statutory statement
is more than simply a restatement of the common law. In some
cases it clarifies areas of uncertainty in the common law, for
example, in relation to the standard of care expected of directors,
whilst in other cases it adopts a different approach from that of
the common law, for example, in relation to the authorisation by
independent directors of conflicts of duty. Where there is a
departure in the statutory statement from the previous common
law, it will obviously be inappropriate for the courts to refer to
that common law in the interpretation of the statutory duties.5
Since, however, the Act does not on its face reveal where it is
confirming and where it is departing from the common law, it
will be necessary to understand when the statute departs from the
common law in order to determine the relevance of common law
decisions to the interpretation of the statute.
The seven duties set out in Ch.2 of Pt 10 cover only the
substantive content of the directors’ duties. The CLR hoped to
be able to recommend codification of the remedies for breaches
of duty as well, but did not have enough time to produce a
workable schema. The Government initially continued with this
work after the CLR’s final report but eventually abandoned the
idea. However, the considerable work done in this direction has
not been entirely lost since the work of Professor Richard Nolan,
written for the CLR, has been published.6 The failure to carry
through this project is regrettable, since the remedies for breach
of duty constitute an area where the law is confused and
inconsistent and where practitioners as well as business people
would have benefited from reform and restatement. In the result,
the Act simply provides in s.178 that the civil consequences of
breaches of the statutory duties are to be those which would
apply at common law.
TO WHOM AND BY WHOM ARE THE DUTIES OWED?
To whom are the general duties owed and who can
sue for their breach?
The company
16–4
Before turning to the substance of directors’ duties, we need to
ask who are their beneficiaries, i.e. to whom are they owed? The
answer in British law is clear: the common law formulation was
that the duties of the directors were owed to “the company” and
that is repeated in s.170(1) in respect of the statutory duties. The
importance of this point arises mainly in relation to the
enforcement of those duties. First, it tells us that those duties are
not owed to persons other than the company, for example,
individual shareholders or employees. Secondly, it tells us that
only those who are able to act as or on behalf of the company
can enforce the duties. As we shall see in Ch.17, the issue of
who can act on behalf of the company to enforce its rights, and
in particular the question of whether an individual shareholder
can do so through the so-called “derivative action”, has caused
considerable controversy ever since the emergence of modern
company law in the nineteenth century. That is also an area
where the Companies Act 2006 has introduced a major reform.
But even the seemingly straightforward notion that the
company itself can enforce these duties has been subjected to
some recent perturbations. The straightforward alignment
between directors’ duties being owed to the company and the
company being able to sue for their breach is clearly crucial in
maintaining the incentive structures underpinning directors’
duties. This requires some careful thought about the rules of
attribution in company law. In particular, even though a
director’s wrongdoing is commonly attributed to the company to
make the company a wrongdoer and subject to claims brought by
third parties, those same attribution rules do not necessarily
apply when the company sues its directors. If they did, the
company’s action might be blocked on the grounds of consent or
illegality. It is now recognised, in both civil7 and criminal8 law,
that to block the company’s action against the director on the
grounds that the company was is some sense party to the
illegality, or knew of and consented to the wrong, would be to
undermine the duties owed by directors to their companies and
that, except for rare cases,9 this is not the law. Although the fact
that it is not the law seems so sensible as not to merit debate, the
reason why this is so is less clearly articulated than might be
hoped. When, if ever, is a director’s act, knowledge, or intention
to be attributed to a claimant company? In Bilta (UK) Ltd (In
Liquidation) v Nazir, Lord Neuberger put it this way10:
“the question is simply an open one: whether or not it is appropriate to attribute an
action by, or a state of mind of, a company director or agent to the company or the
agent’s principal in relation to a particular claim against the company or the
principal must depend on the nature and factual context of the claim in question.”
16–10
This view that the categories are mutually exclusive is
increasingly doubted,49 but nevertheless it remains important to
draw some distinction in a statutory context because certain
statutory provisions apply to both shadow directors and directors
whilst others apply only to directors, in which category the
courts have long included de facto directors. Nevertheless, the
modern view, especially given the statutory change in
terminology in s.170(5), is that the differences between the two
categories of directors should not be the main focus of attention
when deciding the applicability of the general statutory duties of
directors. As Robert Walker LJ pointed out in Re Kaytech
International Plc,50 “the two concepts do have at least this much
in common, that an individual who was not a de jure director is
alleged to have exercised real influence in the corporate
governance of a company”.51 In principle, the general duties
should apply to all these people with “real influence”. If there is
a difference, it is practical, and likely to be that the general rules
should be applied to shadow directors only to the extent that they
have exercised control over the board: it is not inherent in the
definition of a shadow director that he or she should have
controlled all the activities of the board52; by contrast, most de
facto directors assume general directorial responsibilities.
Finally, in the context of shadow directors, two statutory
exceptions are provided. First, it is recognised that boards are
very likely—indeed are well-advised—to act in accordance with
the directions, advice or guidance of their professional advisers
or of parties acting under statutory or Ministerial authority.
These advisers are not thereby to be regarded as shadow
directors (s.251(2)). Secondly, and perhaps more controversially,
a company is not to be regarded as the shadow director of its
subsidiary for the purpose of the general duties by reason only
that the directors of the subsidiary are accustomed to act on the
instructions of the parent (s.251(3)).53 And, although the Act is
silent on this, the parent is also unlikely to be classified as a de
facto director, rather than a shadow director, if it is not involved
in a direct way in the central management of the subsidiary. A
parent company can thus impose a common policy on the group
of companies which it controls without placing itself in breach of
duty to the subsidiary (for example, because the group policy is
not in the best interests of the subsidiary). Note, though, that
s.251(3) does not answer the separate question of whether the
directors of the subsidiary can agree to implement the group
policy without placing themselves in breach of duty to the
subsidiary, which is discussed in para.16–36, below.
Senior managers
16–11
The general statutory duties set out in Ch.2 of Pt 10 clearly do
not apply to managers who are not directors of the company.
However, it is important to note that, when applying the law
relating to directors’ duties, the courts do not distinguish
between the actions of the director as director and actions as
manager, where the director is an executive director of the
company. Those duties will apply to both aspects of the
director’s activities.54 In consequence, some actions by senior
managers of the company, provided they are also directors of the
company, will be subject to the controls of the general statutory
duties. Although management theory may posit that it is the role
of the board in large companies to set the company’s strategy
and to oversee its execution, rather than to execute it itself, the
law of directors’ duties does not make this distinction in the case
of a director who has both a board position and a non-board
executive function. This is consonant with the traditional
provision in companies’ articles that the management of the
company is a matter for the board of directors.
However, it can also be asked whether these general statutory
duties (or common law fiduciary duties) apply to the senior
managers of the company who are not formally appointed as
directors. In Canadian Aero Services Ltd v O’Malley the
Canadian Supreme Court approved a statement from an earlier
edition of this book that directors’ common law fiduciary duties
(as they then were) apply to those “officials of the company who
are authorised to act on its behalf and in particular to those
acting in a senior management capacity”.55 That view has not
been adopted expressly in any English court. Moreover, it is
clear that, in principle, the employment relationship is not a
fiduciary relationship, so that it would be inappropriate to apply
the full range of fiduciary or directors’ duties even to senior
employees. However, this proposition is subject to a number of
qualifications. First, a senior employee who does in fact
discharge the duties of a director may be classed as a de facto
director, under the principles discussed above. Secondly, the
courts have held that, as a result of the specific terms of an
employee’s contract and of the particular duties undertaken by
him or her, a common law fiduciary relationship may arise
between employee and employer, even in the case of employees
who are not part of senior management, though the fiduciary
duty may be restricted to some part of their overall duties.56 The
view of the Canadian Supreme Court is not inconsistent with
these developments, since it too was derived from an analysis of
the functions of the employees in question as senior management
employees, though there will be scope for argument on the facts
of each case about how extensive the fiduciary aspects of the
employee’s duties are. It goes without saying that, should a
senior manager place him- or herself in an agency relationship
with the company, then the normal fiduciary incidents of that
relationship would arise. Thirdly, the implied and mutual duty of
trust and confidence which is imported into all contracts of
employment can in some cases operate in substantially the same
way as certain directors’ general duties.57 This is particularly the
case in relation to competitive activities on the part of an
employee or the non-disclosure by senior managers of the
wrongdoing of fellow employees and in some cases their own
wrongdoing.58
16–12
The exclusion of senior managers as such from the statutory
general duties of directors probably depends upon the
continuation of the UK practice, as recommended in the UK
Corporate Governance Code,59 that the board should contain a
substantial number of executive directors. If British practice
were to move in the US direction of reducing the number of
executive directors on the board, sometimes to one (the CEO),
and there are indications of a move in that direction, then
confining the statutory duties to members of the board might
become a policy which needed to be re-considered.60
Finally, the above discussion has concerned the fiduciary
duties of employees and directors. In relation to the statutory
duty of care (see below), which equally applies only to directors,
the common law duty of care required of employees seems to
come very close to that now required of directors (taking account
of the fact that the application of the reasonable care standard
will produce different results in different circumstances).61
Former directors
16–13
At common law the general duties of directors attach from the
date when the director’s appointment takes effect62 but do not
necessarily cease when the appointment ends. The second part of
the common law position is explicitly confirmed by s.170(2)
which provides that a person who ceases to be a director
continues to be subject to two of the seven general duties,
namely those relating to corporate opportunities of which he had
become aware whilst still a director and the taking of a benefit
from a third party in respect of acts or omissions whilst still a
director. However, those two duties are to be applied by the
courts to former directors “subject to any necessary adaptations”,
for example, to take account of the fact that the former director
may no longer have up-to-date knowledge of the conduct of the
company’s affairs. In this way it can be said that liability is
imposed in respect of actions which straddle the time before and
after the director ceased to hold office.63
Particularly difficult issues can arise in relation to the analysis
of actions by directors, whilst still directors, but after they have
given notice of resignation. In such cases the director is not (yet)
a former director and the issue is discussed below at para.16–94.
Directors of insolvent companies
16–14
When a company enters into an insolvency procedure
(liquidation, administration or receivership), the situation under
British law, unlike that in the US, is that the powers of the
directors are substantially curtailed and the direction of the
business passes into the hands of the insolvency practitioner
appointed to act in one or other of these roles and who acts in the
interests of the creditors. This is likely to have a substantial
impact on what the law of directors’ duties requires of the
directors in practice, but does not in principle relieve the
directors of their obligations to the company.64
DIRECTORS’ DUTIES OF SKILL, CARE AND DILIGENCE
Historical development
16–15
We turn now to the substance of the duties which directors
assume when they take up office. It is common in comparative
analysis of company law systems to divide those duties into
duties of loyalty and duties of care. Although the line between
these two sets of duties is not absolutely clear, they broadly
correspond to the two main risks which shareholders run when
management of their company is delegated to the board. The
board may be active, but not in the direction of promoting the
shareholders’ interests; or the board may be slack or
incompetent. We shall adopt this division here, for it
corresponds also to the two basic common law sources of the
rules on directors’ duties in English law: duties of loyalty based
on equitable principles, developed initially by courts of equity,
and duties of skill and care which now rest, with some particular
twists, on the principles of the law of negligence. However, it
should be noted that the general duties laid out in Ch.2 of Pt 10
are not divided in this way. The duty of care appears as the
fourth of the seven duties. It is nevertheless with this duty that
we begin.
The issue in this area which has long been debated is that of
the appropriate standard of care to be required of directors.
Historically, the common law was based upon a very low
standard of care, because it was subjectively formulated. The
traditional view is to be found in a stream of largely nineteenth-
century cases which culminated in the decision in 1925 in Re
City Equitable Fire Insurance Co.65 Those cases seem to have
framed the directors’ duties of skill and care with non-executive
rather than executive directors in mind and, moreover, on the
basis of a view that the non-executive director had no serious
role to play within the company but was simply a piece of
window-dressing aimed at promoting the company’s image.66
The result was a conceptualisation of the duty in highly
subjective terms. The proposition was famously formulated by
Romer J in the City Equitable case that “a director need not
exhibit in the performance of his duties a greater degree of skill
than may reasonably be expected from a person of his
knowledge and experience”.67 The courts were also influenced
by a model of corporate decision-making which gave the
shareholders effective control over the choice of directors. If the
shareholders chose incompetent directors, that was their fault
and the remedy lay in their hands. As we have seen,68 that is no
longer an accurate picture of the degree of control exercised by
shareholders over boards of directors in most public companies.
Furthermore, the proposition formulated by Romer J was highly
inappropriate for executive directors, appointed to their positions
and paid large, sometimes very large, sums of money for the
expertise which they assert they can bring to the business. The
implicit view of the role of the non-executive director also
became anachronistic after the development of the corporate
governance codes in the 1990s, which allocated a major role to
the non-executive directors in the monitoring of the executive
directors.69
Even before the enactment of the Companies Act 2006 this
was an area of the law of directors’ duties which was beginning
to change. The courts were influenced by the development of
more demanding and objective statutory standards for directors
whose companies were facing insolvency70 and began to develop
the common law requirements by analogy with those specific
statutory provisions. The beginnings of the modern approach at
common law can be found in Dorchester Finance Co v
Stebbing,71 but it was a pair of first instance decisions by
Hoffmann J72 in the 1990s which marked a move towards a fully
objective approach. He explicitly adopted as an accurate
expression of the common law the test contained in s.214(4) of
the Insolvency Act in relation to wrongful trading.73 This
inchoate change in the common law was endorsed by both the
Law Commissions and the CLR and now finds expression in
s.174 of the 2006 Act. This section first requires that “a director
of a company must exercise reasonable care, skill and diligence”
and then goes on to define what is meant by reasonable care,
using a formulation which tracks very closely s.214 of the
Insolvency Act 1986:
“This means the care, skill and diligence that would be exercised by a reasonably
diligent person with (a) the general knowledge, skill and experience that may
reasonably be expected of a person carrying out the same functions carried out by
the director in relation to the company, and (b) the general knowledge, skill and
experience that the director has.”
The ESV approach can be said to embody the insight that the
success of the company or the interests of the shareholders are
not likely to be advanced if the management of the company
conducts its business so that its employees are unwilling to work
effectively, its suppliers and customers would rather not deal
with it, it is at odds with the community in which it operates and
its ethical and environmental standards are regarded as
lamentable. However, it is crucial to note that the interests of the
non-shareholder groups are to be given consideration by the
directors only to the extent that it is desirable to do so in order to
promote the success of the company for the benefit of its
members as a whole. The non-shareholder interests do not have
an independent value in the directors’ decision-making, as they
would have under a pluralist approach. For this reason, it seems
wrong in principle to regard the section as requiring the directors
to “balance” the interests of the members with those of the
stakeholders. The members’ interests are paramount, but the
interests of stakeholders are to be taken into account when
determining the best way of promoting the members’ interests.
16–39
It may be asked whether the ESV approach amounts to a
development or a repetition of the common law. The answer is
that it represents a development, but a modest one. What the Act
adds to the common law is a duty on the part of the directors to
take account of stakeholder interests when it is in the interests of
the success of the company for the benefit of members to do so
(but not a corresponding right in the stakeholders to enforce that
duty). However, the statutory restatement may nevertheless have
an impact, if only by disabusing those directors and their
advisers who might have been inclined to take an unduly narrow
interpretation of the duty previously held.
If the move from permission to well-described obligation is
what lies at the root of the ESV approach, it becomes of great
importance to know how the duty will be enforced. As argued
immediately below, s.172 imposes a mainly subjective test,177 so,
as with the predecessor common law duty, litigation is likely to
be relatively uncommon and probably even less often successful.
This is because it is very difficult to show that the directors have
breached this duty of good faith, except in egregious cases or
cases where the directors have, obligingly, left a clear record of
their thought processes leading up to the challenged decision.178
Instead, the major role in giving some degree of practical
substance to the ESV duty will lie in the extended reporting
requirements to shareholders by directors, as described in
Ch.21.179 This was as envisaged by the CLR, which saw the ESV
approach to directors’ duties and enhanced reporting
requirements as closely linked.180
Finally, and for the avoidance of doubt, the duty of the
directors to promote the success of the company for the benefit
of its members does not exempt the company from compliance
with its other legal obligations, for example, health and safety or
discrimination legislation, even if it could be shown that non-
compliance would promote the company’s overall success.
Interpreting the statutory formula
Defining the company’s success
16–40
Several important points arise on the interpretation of the
language contained in this section. First, it is to be noted that
corporate success for the benefit of the members is the word
used to identify the touchstone for the exercise of the directors’
discretion. Success is a more general word than, for example,
“value”, which it might have been thought was what the
shareholders are interested in. However, the more general word
is clearly the appropriate one, because not all companies formed
under the Act are aimed at maximising the financial interests of
their members. Companies may be charitable; they may have
non-profit-making objectives without being charities, as in the
case of a company formed by leaseholders to hold the freehold
of a block of flats; they may be companies set up within a
corporate group simply to hold a particular asset rather than to
exploit it, even though the overall purpose of the group is to
make profits; or they may be commercially-oriented but without
aiming to distribute profits, in which case the company may, but
is not obliged to, be incorporated as a CIC. In all these cases,
maximising the value of the company is not the primary
objective of its members and perhaps not even an objective at
all. Section 172(2) makes it clear that:
“where or to the extent that the purposes of the company consist of or include
purposes other than the benefit of its members, subsection (1) has effect as if the
reference to promoting the success of the company for the benefit of its members
were to achieving those purposes.”
Introduction 18–1
Informal Investigations: Disclosure of Documents and
Information 18–2
Formal Investigations by Inspectors 18–5
When inspectors can be appointed 18–5
Conduct of inspections 18–7
Power of Investigation of Company Ownership 18–11
Liability for Costs of Investigations 18–12
Follow-Up to Investigations 18–13
Conclusion 18–15
INTRODUCTION
18–1
A distinctive feature of British company regulation for many
years has been the conferment of powers of investigation on the
relevant Government Department, currently the Department of
Business Innovation and Skills (“BIS”).1 Those provisions are
still contained in Pt XIV of the Companies Act 1985 (rather than
the 2006 Act),2 as amended by the Companies Act 1989 and
strengthened by the Companies (Audit, Investigations and
Community Enterprise) Act 2004.3 The 1985 Act, as amended,
empowers the Department to launch inquisitorial raids on
corporate (and even unincorporated) bodies, and BIS now has a
sizeable Companies Investigation Branch (“CIB”), which in
2006 became part of the Insolvency Service Agency of the
Department. The departmental powers are draconian, despite the
acknowledged need to ensure that the investigatory and
inspection powers comply, in both design and use, with the
Human Rights Act 1998, and with the fairness standards of
domestic public law, and it is perhaps the Government’s desire
not to spend public money on matters which should be the
concern purely of the company’s members or creditors which
has tended to limit the scale of their use.4
Originally, appointment of outside inspectors (usually a QC
and a senior accountant) was the only form of investigation
power that the Secretary of State had. But an announced
appointment of inspectors is likely in itself to cause damage to
the company. Hence the Department was reluctant to appoint
unless a strong case for doing so could be made out, and it
normally made inquiries of the board of directors before doing
so. Though such inquiries might cause the board to take remedial
action, they might equally well provide an opportunity for
evidence to be destroyed or fabricated. Hence, on the
recommendation of the Jenkins Committee,5 power to require the
production of books and papers was added in 1967, a power
which can be exercised with less publicity6 and which may
suffice in itself or may lead to a formal appointment of
inspectors if the facts elicited show that that is needed. This
power, now conferred by s.447 of the 1985 Act, is by far the one
most commonly exercised.7 It is sometimes referred to as the
power of (informal or confidential) investigation, by way of
contrast with the far more formal and public powers of
inspection (by appointment of inspectors). It is undoubtedly the
primary form of intervention, and we consider it first.
INFORMAL INVESTIGATIONS: DISCLOSURE OF DOCUMENTS AND
INFORMATION
18–2
Under s.447, the Secretary of State may require or, more likely,
authorise an investigator from the CIB to require a company to
produce, at such time and place as are specified, such
documents8 and information as may be specified. Authorising an
investigator to impose the requirement avoids the risk of the
documents being destroyed or doctored; the officer will arrive
without warning9 at the company’s registered office (or
wherever else the documents are believed to be held).10 The
investigator may be authorised further to impose the same
requirements on “any person”,11 a power to be used where, for
example, the documents concerned are in the possession of some
person other than the company. The power of an investigator to
impose a requirement on “any person” in relation to the
production of “information” as well as documents means that,
for example, an officer or employee of the company may be
required to provide an explanation of a document or, if a
document is not produced by the person asked, to state to the
best of his or her knowledge where it is.12
Failure to comply with the requirements of s.447 on the part
of any person may be certified by the Secretary of State or the
investigator to the court and the court may treat that person as
guilty of contempt of court if, after a hearing, it concludes that
the defendant did not have a reasonable excuse13 for non-
compliance with the requirement.14 In addition, providing
information known to be false in a material particular, or doing
so recklessly, is a criminal offence, punishable by imprisonment
or a fine.15 Criminal sanctions are also imposed on any officer of
the company who is privy to the falsification or destruction of a
document relating to the company’s affairs, unless the officer
shows there was no intention to conceal the affairs of the
company or to defeat the law.16 In addition, fraudulently to part
with, alter or make an omission in such a document is a crime.17
These various provisions are all aimed at extracting
information from those who may be unwilling to provide it
without compulsion. It may happen, however, that a person
wishes to volunteer information to an investigator, but feels
constrained from so doing because the information has been
imparted to him or her in confidence and so disclosure might
trigger an action for breach of confidence on the part of the
person who provided the information to the informer. The Act
now gives a limited protection against such actions. The
information must be of a kind which the person making the
disclosure could be required to disclose under the Act, the
disclosure must be in good faith and in the reasonable belief that
it is capable of assisting the Secretary of State, must be no more
than is necessary for this purpose, and must not be a disclosure
prohibited by or under statute or by a banker or lawyer in breach
of an obligation of confidence owed in that capacity.18
18–3
An investigator appointed under s.447 is not confined to turning
up at premises to ask questions and demand documents, running
the risk that admittance will be denied. The Act provides for the
investigator to be given compulsory powers of entry and
search.19 These come in escalating tiers. A Justice of the Peace,
if satisfied on information given on oath by the Secretary of
State or by a person appointed or authorised to exercise powers
under Pt XIV, that there are on any premises documents,
production of which has been required under that Part and which
have not been produced, may issue a search warrant.20 Under
that provision a search warrant cannot be issued unless there has
first been a requirement to produce the documents sought. The
company, thus forewarned, could destroy the documents before
the search took place, even if such action might be a crime.21
Hence, the 1989 Act added a further provision under which a
warrant may be issued if a J.P. is satisfied: (a) that there are
reasonable grounds for believing that an indictable offence has
been committed and that there are on the premises documents
relating to whether the offence has been committed; (b) that the
applicant has power under Pt XIV to require the production of
the documents; and (c) that there are reasonable grounds for
believing that if production was required it would not be
forthcoming but the documents would be removed, hidden,
tampered with or destroyed.22 Though narrowly circumscribed
by the need to satisfy a J.P. of conditions (a)–(c), this enables the
search for the documents to be undertaken by the police rather
than by the (possibly self-interested) officers of the company.
Although the search warrant power introduced in 1989
undoubtedly increased the investigators’ powers, in many cases
it is not available, particularly given conditions (a) and (c)
above. Where it is not, the investigator might still be left
standing on the doorstep. Consequently, in the 2004 Act a right
of entry to premises was introduced which was not dependent on
a warrant issued by a J.P., nor subject to onerous conditions.
Whenever authorised by the Secretary of State to do so, and
provided the investigator23 thinks it will materially help in the
exercise of his or her functions, the investigator may require
entry to premises believed to be used wholly or partly for the
purpose of the company’s business and may remain there for
such time as is necessary to discharge those functions.24 The
power of entry extends to accompanying persons whom the
investigator thinks appropriate.25 The section does not give the
investigator powers of search but it does potentially give him or
her access to relevant persons from whom the production of
documents or information can be demanded. Intentional
obstruction of the exercise of this power of entry is an offence,
punishable with imprisonment or a fine,26 and non-compliance
with a requirement imposed under the section may be certified to
the court to be dealt with as a contempt of court.27 The power is
subject to some procedural safeguards, notably a requirement
that the investigator and accompanying persons identify
themselves,28 and the investigator must give a written statement
as soon as practicable after entry to the occupiers of the premises
about the investigator’s powers and the rights and obligations of
the persons on the premises.29
18–4
The powers discussed above are cumulatively very considerable,
but it is worth remembering that over three-quarters of the
investigations initiated are prompted by allegations of fraudulent
trading,30 so that attempts to side-step the investigation are
likely. Despite the width of the power to appoint investigators,
this fact also illustrates the reluctance of the Department to use it
unless wrongdoing and a strong public interest in taking action
are present.
Part XIV also contains further provisions common to both
departmental investigations and to inspections, but these are left
until after a description of the latter. What should be emphasised,
however, is that an investigation by the Department’s officials
under s.447 is very far from being merely a preliminary step
towards the appointment of inspectors if the documentary
evidence thus discovered justifies that. On the contrary, in most
cases it will be the only investigation undertaken and will lead
either to a decision that no further action is needed or that some
non-inspection follow-up action should be taken.31 The time
taken to decide may vary from a few days to several months and,
while the investigation continues, the officials will probe deeply
and in a way which from the viewpoint of the company is just as
traumatic as a formal inspection.
FORMAL INVESTIGATIONS BY INSPECTORS
When inspectors can be appointed
18–5
Sections 431 and 432 set out circumstances in which the
Secretary of State is empowered to appoint one or more
competent inspectors32 to investigate the affairs33 of a company
and to report the result of their investigations to him; and one
situation where the Secretary of State is obliged to do so. This
last is where the court by order declares that the affairs of the
company ought to be so investigated.34 The courts rarely make
use of this power. As to those situations in which the Secretary
of State has a discretion, s.431 deals with cases where the
company, formally, takes the initiative to suggest the
appointment (almost never used) and s.432 with cases where the
Secretary of State acts of his or her own motion (as it turns out,
rather rarely used).
Under s.431, the Secretary of State may appoint on the
application of: (a) in the case of a company with a share capital,
not less than 200 members or members holding not less than
one-tenth of the issued shares; (b) in the case of a company not
having a share capital, not less than one-fifth of the persons on
the company’s register of members; or (c) in any case, the
company itself.35 However, appointments under this section
hardly ever occur.36 This is due not only to the fact that, before
appointing under the section, the Secretary of State may require
applicants to give security to an amount not exceeding £5,000
for payment of the costs of the investigation,37 but also because
the application has to be supported by evidence that the
applicants have good reason for the application.38 If they have,
the Secretary of State will normally have power to appoint of his
own motion under s.432(2), below, and it is far better for those
who have good reasons to draw them quietly to the attention of
the Department, requesting that there should be an appointment
under that section. Proceeding thus avoids the danger, inherent
in s.431, that the malefactors in the company will tamper with
the evidence once they learn of possible action under that section
and thus frustrate effective intervention by the Department,
whether by the appointment of inspectors or the appointment of
an investigator under s.447 (see above).
Section 432(2) empowers the Secretary of State to appoint
inspectors39 if it appears that there are circumstances suggesting
one (or more) of four grounds, the first two of which are:
“(a) that the company’s affairs are being conducted or have been conducted with
intent to defraud creditors or the creditors of any other person or otherwise
for a fraudulent or unlawful purpose or in a manner which is unfairly
prejudicial to some part of its members;40 or
(b) that any actual or proposed act or omission of the company (including an act
or omission on its behalf) is or would be so prejudicial, or that the company
was formed for any fraudulent or unlawful purpose.”
18–6
Given the availability of the more attractive, cheaper and
speedier option of investigations (considered earlier),
appointments of formal inspectors under s.432(2) have become
far less common, except in major cases where there are
circumstances suggesting malpractice (such as companies
formed or used in unlawful, dishonest, fraudulent or improper
ways) and a strong public interest in having an inspection. Had
the reforms proposed in 2001 been implemented, this would
have become the sole basis for the s.432(2) discretion.43
Conduct of inspections
Extent of the inspectors’ powers
18–7
The Act itself contains a number of sections on the conduct of
inspections. Under s.433, if inspectors appointed to investigate
the affairs of a company think it also necessary for the purposes
of their investigation to investigate the affairs of another body
corporate in the same group, they may do so and report the
results of that so far as it is relevant to the affairs of the
company.44 Under s.434 inspectors have powers similar to those
of investigators under s.447 (above) entitling them to require the
production of documents and information. They may also
require any past or present officer or agent of the company to
attend before them and otherwise to give all assistance that he is
“reasonably” able to give.45 In addition, they may examine any
person on oath.46 If any person fails to comply with their
requirements or refuses to answer any question put by the
inspectors for the purposes of the investigation, the inspectors
may certify that fact in writing to the court which will thereupon
inquire into the case and, subject to the important defence of
reasonableness, may punish the offender in like manner as if he
had been guilty of contempt of court.47
Control of the inspectors’ powers
18–8
This topic can be looked at from two points of view: control over
the inspectors by the Secretary of State and control over the
inspectors in the interests of third parties. The former control
was considerably strengthened by Pt 32 of the Companies Act
2006, inserting new provisions in the 1985 Act, although to
some extent they reflect what was probably already
administrative practice. In any event, the inspectors are now
under a statutory obligation to comply with any direction given
to them by the Secretary of State as to the subject-matter of the
investigation, the steps to be taken in the investigation, and
whether to report or not report on a particular matter or in a
particular way.48 The Secretary of State may also terminate an
investigation.49
Perhaps anticipating that exercise of these powers may lead to
dissatisfaction among inspectors, they are given an express
statutory right to resign, and the Secretary of State a
corresponding power to revoke an appointment as inspector.50
However, former inspectors are under an obligation to produce
to the Secretary of State or a replacement inspector the
documents and information obtained or generated in the course
of the inspection.51 These provisions make it very clear that the
inspector is a creature of the Department.
As to control in the interests of the investigated, a number of
matters have been established by practice and case law. The
process of inspection is undoubtedly an inquisitorial one.
However, as noted, since the aim of the inspection is to establish
facts rather than to determine legal rights, in domestic law the
process has been characterised as administrative rather than
judicial, so that the inspectors are obliged to act fairly but are not
subject to the full requirements of natural justice. The European
Court of Human Rights has adopted a similar stance in relation
to the applicability of art.6 of the European Convention (right to
a fair trial) to inspections.52 Consequently, it would seem that the
use of compulsion in investigations and inspections to secure
information from those investigated, including compulsion to
answer questions put by inspectors, is not in principle unlawful,
as a matter of either domestic or European Convention law.
However, as we shall see below, European Convention law has
had a significant impact on what can be done subsequently, for
example by the prosecuting authorities, with compelled
testimony obtained by inspectors, and the Act was amended by
the Criminal Justice and Police Act 2001 to take account of the
jurisprudence of the European Court of Human Rights.
Although the full rules of “natural justice” do not apply, the
inspectors must act fairly. This involves letting witnesses know
of criticisms made against them (assuming that the inspectors
envisage relying on, or referring to, those criticisms in their
report) and giving them adequate opportunity of answering. But
the inspectors are not bound to show them a draft of the parts of
their report referring to them, so long as they have had a fair
opportunity of answering any criticisms of their conduct.
Inspectors are free to draw conclusions from the evidence about
the conduct of individuals, but should do so only with restraint.53
18–9
Inspectors sit in private (and probably do not have the power to
sit in public),54 but allow witnesses to be accompanied by their
lawyers—although the latter’s role is limited, since the
questioning is undertaken by the inspectors and neither the
witness nor his lawyers can cross-examine other witnesses.
Although the range of persons whom the inspectors may
question is very wide, the Act provides that such persons cannot
be compelled to disclose or produce any information or
document in breach of legal professional privilege, except that
lawyers must disclose the names and addresses of their clients.55
A banker’s duty of confidentiality is protected more narrowly.56
In particular, it may be overridden by the Secretary of State.57
Reports
18–10
The inspectors may, and if so directed by the Secretary of State
shall, make interim reports, and (subject to what is said below)
on the conclusion of the investigation must make a final report.58
If so directed by the Secretary of State, they must also inform the
Minister of matters coming to their knowledge during their
investigation.59 The Secretary of State may, if thought fit,
forward a copy of any report to the company’s registered office
and, on request and payment of a prescribed fee, to any member
of the company or other body corporate which is the subject of
the report, any person whose conduct is referred to in the report,
the auditors, the applicants for the investigation60 and any other
person whose financial interests appear to be affected by matters
dealt with in the report.61 And the Secretary of State may (and
generally will, though not until after any criminal proceedings
have been concluded62) cause the report to be printed and
published.63
There is one exception to this, however. Under s.432(2A),
inspectors may be appointed under s.432(2) on terms that any
report they make is not for publication, in which case s.437 does
not apply. Since, under that section, a report does not have to be
published unless the Secretary of State thinks fit, it might be
thought that subs.(2A) was unnecessary. But it has two
advantages: it protects the Secretary of State from pressure to
publish even though advised that that might prejudice possible
criminal prosecutions; and, since it is an ex ante rule, it makes it
clear to the proposed appointees that they will not be able to
bask in publicity resulting from their efforts.64
POWER OF INVESTIGATION OF COMPANY OWNERSHIP
18–11
The above provisions relate to the appointment of inspectors or
investigators to examine the affairs of the company in general
(even if in particular cases they may be given a more limited
remit). There is, however, one situation in which the Secretary of
State’s powers to appoint inspectors or investigators are limited
by the statute to a particular topic. This is the power of
investigation into company ownership.65 This may be a
controversial issue and the facts may not be clear, because,
although the name of the shareholder has to be entered on the
company’s share register, that shareholder may be a nominee
rather than the beneficial owner of the share. The circumstances
in which large beneficial shareholders are required to disclose
their positions or in which a company may require a person to
reveal the extent of a beneficial holding in the company are
discussed in Chs 2,66 2667 and 28.68 The Secretary of State’s
investigatory powers are essentially supplementary to these
provisions.
In the first instance, if the Secretary of State is persuaded that
there may be good reasons for intervening, he or she will
probably institute preliminary investigations under the powers
conferred by s.444. Under this provision, the Secretary of State
can require any person whom he or she has reasonable cause to
believe to has, or is able to obtain, information as to the present
and past interests in a company’s shares or debentures to
disclose this information.
If this fails to produce a satisfactory answer the Secretary of
State may then appoint inspectors under s.442.69 The Secretary
of State may do so at will and must do so if application is made
by members sufficient to instigate an appointment of inspectors
under the general powers.70 A fully-fledged investigation may
afford the best chance of getting at the truth, but it is expensive
and time-consuming.71 Hence, the amendments to the section
made by the 1989 Act provide that the Secretary of State shall
not be obliged to appoint inspectors if satisfied that the
members’ application is vexatious and, if an appointment is
made, may exclude any matter if satisfied that it is unreasonable
for it to be investigated72; and the applicants may be required to
give security for costs as in a general investigation initiated by
the members.73
The inspectors’ powers in this area are supported by the
sanctions mentioned above74 but what makes the foregoing
sections more effective than they would otherwise be is that, if
there is difficulty in finding out the relevant facts on an
investigation under ss.442 or 444, the Secretary of State may by
order direct that the securities concerned shall, until further
notice, be subject to restrictions on their transfer and the exercise
of rights attached to them. These restrictions are discussed
further in Ch.28.75
LIABILITY FOR COSTS OF INVESTIGATIONS
18–12
Under s.439, the expenses of any investigation under Pt XIV of
the Act76 are to be defrayed in the first instance by the
Department, but may be recoverable from persons specified in
that section. These expenses include such reasonable sums as the
Secretary of State may determine in respect of general staff costs
and overheads. The persons from whom costs are recoverable
include: anyone successfully prosecuted as a result of the
investigation; the applicants for the investigation where
inspectors were appointed under s.431, to the extent that the
Secretary of State directs77; any body corporate dealt with in an
inspectors’ report when the inspectors were not appointed on the
Secretary of State’s own motion, unless the body corporate was
the applicant, or except so far as the Secretary of State otherwise
directs.78 Thus, in the case of investigations under s.447, the only
persons at risk of costs are those subsequently prosecuted and,
even where inspectors are appointed, the same is true if the
Secretary of State takes the initiative to appoint the inspectors.
FOLLOW-UP TO INVESTIGATIONS
18–13
Following an investigation, whether by inspectors or otherwise,
the Secretary of State has a number of powers. Apart from the
obvious one of causing prosecutions to be mounted against those
whose crimes have come to light, which prosecutions may be
mounted by the Department itself or by others such as the
Serious Fraud Office, the Secretary of State may petition under
s.8 of the Company Directors Disqualification Act 1986 for the
disqualification of a director or shadow director on grounds of
unfitness.79 The Secretary of State may also petition the court for
an appropriate order if unfair prejudice to all or some of the
company’s members has been revealed.80 Alternatively, or in
addition, he or she may petition for the winding-up of the
company under s.124A of the Insolvency Act 1986. Under that
section, if it appears to the Secretary of State as a result of any
report or information obtained under Pt XIV of the Companies
Act that it is expedient in the public interest that a company
should be wound up, he or she may present a petition for it to be
wound up if the court thinks it just and equitable. In 2014–15,
102 companies were wound up on the Secretary of State’s
petition, and 58 disqualification orders obtained as a result of
investigations.81
What the Secretary of State can no longer do is initiate
proceedings in the name and on behalf of the body corporate,
indemnifying it against any costs or expenses incurred by it in
connection with the proceedings. This power was removed by
the 2006 Act,82 perhaps on the basis that remedies for the benefit
of the company should be a matter for its members.83 By
contrast, taking companies off the register and disqualifying
unfit persons from future involvement in the management of
companies may well be steps which no member has an interest
in taking.
Since the majority of investigations and inspections are driven
by allegations of potentially serious wrongdoing on the part of
those involved in companies, it is hardly surprising that the
Department does not simply receive the information produced by
the investigation machinery, but makes use of the possibilities
just described to take remedial steps of one sort or another. That
this is contemplated by the Act is revealed by s.449, which
contains a long list of exceptions to the starting proposition that
information obtained under the s.447 investigation powers is
confidential to the Department and cannot be disseminated more
widely without the consent of the company.84 These so-called
“gateways” permit the information to be provided to those who
are best placed to take the consequential action.
18–14
However, this possibility of subsequent action brings into sharp
focus the rules which permit investigators and inspectors to
secure information compulsorily. Although the domestic courts
had held to the contrary (before the enactment of the Human
Rights Act 1998), the European Court of Human Rights, in
litigation arising out of the Guinness affair, concluded that
evidence given to inspectors under threat of compulsion cannot
normally be used in subsequent criminal proceedings against
those investigated, on the grounds that this would infringe their
privilege against self-incrimination.85 The Act now provides that
compelled testimony (but not documents produced under
compulsion) may not be used in either primary evidence or
cross-examination in a subsequent criminal trial of the person
providing the testimony, unless the defendant him- or herself
brought the compelled testimony in, or unless the offence in
question is giving false evidence to the investigator or certain
offences under the general perjury legislation.86
However, this restriction does not apply to subsequent use of
the testimony in proceedings for disqualification under s.8 of the
Company Directors Disqualification Act. Indeed, s.441
specifically provides that an inspectors’ report can be evidence
as to the opinion of the inspectors in such an application, and the
courts have come to the same conclusion in respect of a report
by investigators under s.447.87 Both the domestic courts and the
ECHR seem to be in agreement that disqualification applications
are not criminal proceedings.88 However, disqualification
applications, if not criminal proceedings, clearly are proceedings
falling within art.6 of the European Convention, because they
determine the legal rights of the person to be disqualified. Unlike
the investigation process itself, which lies outside art.6,89
disqualification proceedings will have to comply with
Convention standards appropriate for civil proceedings. These
standards do not specifically include a privilege against self-
incrimination, but they do involve general standards of fairness.
Especially since disqualification has a penal element, the
presumption of innocence might be relevant.90 Presumably, the
same considerations will apply where it is proposed to use
compelled testimony in purely civil litigation91: there will be no
ban in principle, but the court conducting the civil trial will need
to have regard to general fairness issues. One such issue, already
identified by the English courts in the context of the Insolvency
Act powers of compulsory examination, is the undesirability of
allowing statutory powers to give one party a litigation
advantage over another in purely civil litigation, which it would
not have were the company not insolvent.92
CONCLUSION
18–15
Since the scheme of administrative remedies under the Act is
dominated by the power of investigation, and this power is
predominantly used in cases of suspected fraudulent trading or
breach of the disqualification provisions, it is far from clear that
these remedies constitute an important element in the British
system of corporate governance, if that is defined as the
accountability of the senior management to the shareholders as a
whole. These provisions might be better seen as seen as
supporting the provisions analysed in Part Two of this book,
dealing with the abuse of limited liability. It would seem that the
Department leaves allegations of breaches of the duties
discussed in Ch.16 to be pursued by companies or shareholders
themselves, perhaps now through the reformed derivative action
procedure,93 unless either there is a strong public interest in
favour of intervention by the Department or the misconduct of
the directors has been egregious. Nevertheless, administrative
remedies are an important part of corporate law, and
shareholders may benefit from them indirectly, as where
inspectors’ reports reveal matters which lead to the reform of
company law.94
1And in earlier guises the Department of Business Enterprise and Regulatory Reform
(BERR), the Department of Trade and Industry (DTI) and the Board of Trade (BoT).
2 Unless indicated otherwise, the references below are to the 1985 Act.
3Although not to the extent recommended by the Department’s own review: see DTI,
Company Investigations: Powers for the Twenty-First Century (2001).
4 DTI, Company Investigations: Powers for the Twenty-First Century (2001), gives
details of the costs and length of the then most recent formal s.432 inspections. For
example, the inspection into Mirror Group Newspapers Ltd took nearly nine years and
cost £9.5 million. However, nearly half that time was taken up with waiting for criminal
trials to be completed or with dealing with challenges in the courts to the inspectors by
those sought to be inspected. See fn.45, below.
5
Cmnd. 1749 (1962), paras 213–219.
6
The Department does not normally announce that it has mounted such an investigation
and all information about it is regarded as confidential. This has its disadvantages. If a
team of officials is going through the company’s books and papers, this cannot be
concealed from its employees and will soon become known to the Press, thus putting the
company under a cloud which may never be dispersed because the ending of the
inquiries will not normally be announced nor their results ever be published,
notwithstanding that the conclusion may be that all is well with the company.
7
The various powers to appoint inspectors are used only very infrequently. And the
number of informal investigations has remained relatively constant at about 150
investigations per year: see Insolvency Service Annual Report 2013–14, at p.18; and
Insolvency Service Annual Report 2014–15, at p.15.
8
1985 Act s.447(8). “Document” is defined as “information recorded in any form”. The
requirement to produce documents includes the power, if they are produced, to take
copies of them or extracts from them: s.447(7).
9
The investigation is an administrative act to which the full rules of natural justice do
not apply: Norwest Holst Ltd v Secretary of State [1978] Ch. 201 at 224 CA. But
“fairness” must be observed and directions to produce should be clear and not excessive:
R. v Trade Secretary Ex p. Perestrello [1981] 1 Q.B. 19 (a case which illustrates the
problems that may be met if the documents are not held in the UK). See also R. (on the
application of 1st Choice Engines Ltd) v Secretary of State for Business, Innovation and
Skills [2014] EWHC 1765.
10
The officer may be accompanied by a policeman with a search warrant: s.448.
11
1985 Act s.447(3). But this is without prejudice to any lien that the possessor may
have.
12
See Re Attorney-General’s Reference No.2 of 1998 [1999] B.C.C. 590 CA, decided
on an earlier version of s.447 where this power was stated explicitly. The current version
of the power is not confined to officers and employees.
13 1985 Act s.453C. cf. Re An Investigation under the Insider Dealing Act [1988] A.C.
660 HL, dealing with an analogous provision, where the court took a narrow view of
reasonable excuse in the case of a journalist refusing to answer questions in order to
protect his sources. This was because the information was needed for the prevention of
crime, which is likely to, but need not, be the case under s.447.
14 One effect of proceeding in this way is that the defendant is deprived of the automatic
protection of legal professional privilege, which applies if, as previously, failure to
comply is treated as an offence (s.1129 of the CA 2006), though the court might regard
legal professional privilege as reasonable grounds for non-compliance.
151985 Act s.451. Prosecution requires the consent of the Secretary of State or DPP in
England and Wales and Northern Ireland (CA 2006 s.1126(2),(3)).
161985 Act s.450(1). The same restriction on prosecution applies as under s.451: see
previous note.
17
1985 Act s.450(2).
18 1985 Act s.448A.
19 These powers apply also to inspectors, discussed below: s.448(1). Note also that there
is a power under CA 2006 s.1132 whereby (on application of the DPP, the Secretary of
State or the police) a High Court judge, if satisfied that there is reasonable cause to
believe that any person, while an officer of a company, has committed an offence in its
management and that evidence of the commission is to be found in any books or papers
of, or under the control of, the company, may make an order authorising any named
person to inspect the books and papers or require an officer of the company to produce
them: see Re A Company [1980] Ch. 138 CA (reversed by the House of Lords sub nom.
Re Racal Communications Ltd [1981] A.C. 374, because, under the express provisions
of subs.(5), there can be no appeal from the judge and it was held that this included cases
where he had erred on a point of law—and, having discovered that other judges had
taken a different view, had volunteered leave to appeal!).
20
1985 Act s.448(1).
21
See fn.6 above.
22
1985 Act s.448(2).
23
Or inspector (see below).
24 1985 Act.453A(1)–(3).
25 1985 Act s.453A(4).
26
1985 Act s.453A(5),(5A).
27
1985 Act s.453C(1); and see para.18–2, above.
28 1985 Act s.453B(3).
291985 Act s.453B(4)–(10); and the Companies Act 1985 (Power to Enter and Remain
on Premises: Procedural) Regulations 2005 (SI 2005/684), which, together, go into
considerably more detail than is indicated in the text.
30 The two other main grounds for appointing an investigator after fraudulent trading are
the involvement of a disqualified person or an undischarged bankrupt in the
management of the company and using the company to promote an unlawful pyramid
selling scheme.
31
See para.18–13, below.
32 As already mentioned, the usual appointees are a QC and a chartered accountant but
less expensive mortals may be appointed in the rarer case when the Department appoints
in relation to a private company.
33 i.e. its business, including its control over its subsidiaries, whether that is being
managed by the board of directors or an administrator, administrative receiver or a
liquidator in a voluntary liquidation: R. v Board of Trade Ex p. St Martin Preserving Co
[1965] 1 Q.B. 603.
34 1985 Act s.432(1). This seems to make the Secretary of State’s refusal to appoint
reviewable by the court if an application is made to it by anyone with locus standi, and
to enable a court, in proceedings before it (e.g. on an unfair prejudice petition), to make
an order declaring that the company’s affairs ought to be investigated by inspectors. A
copy of the inspectors’ report will be sent to the court: s.437(2).
35
1985 Act s.431(2)(c).
36 It is believed that there have been no appointments since 1990.
37 1985 Act s.431(4). The £5,000 can be altered by statutory instrument. In the 1948 Act
it was only £100 which, even then, would not have kept a competent QC and chartered
accountant happy for the time that most inspections take.
38
1985 Act s.431(3).
39
Even if the company is in the course of being voluntarily wound up: s.432(3).
40
“Member” includes a person to whom shares have been transmitted by operation of
law: s.432(4).
41 See Ch.20. Although s.432(2)(a) refers only to “some part of the members”, rather
than using the CA 2006 s.994 wording of “members generally or some part of the
members”, this is unlikely to have the absurd result that, strictly speaking, the Secretary
of State should not appoint inspectors if it is thought that all the members are unfairly
prejudiced. This is especially so since the precise grounds for action do not have to be
stated (see Norwest Holst v Trade Secretary [1978] Ch. 201 CA).
42
This wording implies that members may “reasonably expect” more information than
that to which the Act entitles them. But it seems that s.432(2) does not entitle the
Secretary of State to appoint merely because the directors or officers of the company
appear to have breached their duties of care, skill or diligence: see SBA Properties Ltd v
Cradock [1967] 1 W.L.R. 716 (which, however, was concerned with an action by the
Secretary of State under what is now s.438, below).
43 DTI, Company Investigations: Powers for the Twenty-First Century (2001), para.97.
44
Most major corporate scandals involve the use of a network of holding and subsidiary
companies, the extent of which may only become apparent during the course of the
investigation: s.433 avoids the need for a formal extension of the inspectors’
appointment each time they unearth another member of the group. The extended power
applies to bodies corporate (i.e. not just Companies Act companies) but does not extend
to unincorporated bodies, which, however, may be subjected to investigation on the
grounds that associated unincorporated bodies are part of the affairs of the corporate
body with which they are associated.
45 1985 Act s.434(1) and (2). On the use of the “reasonableness” defence to protect a
director against oppressive use by the inspectors of their powers, see Re Mirror Group
Newspapers Plc [1999] 1 B.C.L.C. 690. Agents include auditors, bankers and solicitor
(s.434(4)).
46 1985 Act s.434(3).
47 1985 Act s.436.
48 1985 Act s.446A.
49 1985 Act s.446B(1)—though in the case of inspectors appointed as a result of a court
order, only if matters have come to light suggesting the commission of a criminal
offence and those matters have been referred to the appropriate prosecuting authority:
s.446B(2).
50 1985 Act s.446C—and the Secretary of State can fill any vacancy: s.446D.
51
1985 Act s.446E. The inspector is under a duty to comply but no sanction is specified
—presumably in extremis the Department could obtain a court order.
52
Fayed v United Kingdom (1994) 18 E.H.R.R. 393.
53 Re Pergamon Press Ltd [1971] Ch. 388 CA; Maxwell v DTI [1974] Q.B. 523 CA; R.
(on the application of Clegg) v Secretary of State [2003] B.C.C. 128 CA.
54
Hearts of Oak Assurance Co Ltd v Attorney-General [1932] A.C. 392 HL.
55 1985 Act s.452(1),(5). This applies to Departmental investigations as well as to
inspections: s.452(2).
56
1985 Act s.452(1A),(1B).
57
1985 Act s.452(1A)(c). The bankers’ protection in relation to s.447 investigations is
differently worded. It can be overridden by the Secretary of State only when it is thought
necessary for the purpose of investigating the affairs of the person carrying on the
banking business, or the customer is a person upon whom a s.447 requirement has been
imposed: s.452(4).
58
1985 Act s.437(1).
59 1985 Act s.437(1A).
60
This is not relevant to inspections under s.432(2) when the Secretary of State appoints
of his or her own motion.
61
1985 Act s.437(3).
62For an unsuccessful attempt to force the Secretary of State to publish while criminal
proceedings were still being considered: see R. v Secretary of State Ex p. Lonrho [1989]
1 W.L.R. 525 HL.
63 1985 Act s.437(3)(c). Thus making the reports available for purchase from HMSO by
any member of the public so long as the reports remain in print. They often make
fascinating reading for anyone interested in “the unacceptable face of capitalism”.
64 It may also tend to make the officers of the company more co-operative.
65 There was also a power of investigation into share dealings (s.446), but this was
repealed by the Companies Act 2006 from October 2007, but the Financial Conduct
Authority has a like investigatory power and is now regarded as the more appropriate
body to exercise this type of power. See para.30–48.
66 At para.2–42.
67 At para.26–17.
68 At para.28–51.
69 This section is directed not merely to determining share and debenture ownership but
“the true persons who are or have been primarily interested in the success or failure (real
or apparent) of the company or able to control or materially to influence its policy”:
s.442(1).
701985 Act s.442(3) and see above, para.18–2, though under s.442(3) the appointment is
mandatory.
71 It is believed that no appointments have been made since 1992.
72
1985 Act s.442(3A).
73 See above, para.18–5.
74 1985 Act s.443.
75
At para.28–53.
76
Which in the case of inspections are likely to be heavy; the Atlantic Computers
investigation cost £6.5 million and the Consolidated Goldfields one nearly £4 million:
DTI, Company Investigations: Powers for the Twenty-First Century (2001), Annex A.
And the total costs to the companies and their officers were probably as great or greater.
77
Or the equivalent provisions relating to ownership investigations: s.439(5).
78
1985 Act s.439(4). Inspectors appointed otherwise than on the Secretary of State’s
own motion may, and shall if so directed, include in their report a recommendation
about costs: s.439(6). Note also the provisions regarding rights to indemnity or
contribution (s.439(8) and (9)).
79
See para.10–5.
80 See para.20–1.
81Insolvency Service Annual Report 2014–5, at pp.14 and 15. The winding-up
application cannot be made on the basis of information supplied under the voluntary
method (see para.18–2, above): Insolvency Act s.124A(1)(a).
82 1985 Act s.438 was repealed by s.1176 of the CA 2006 as from April 2007.
83
For the same reason the Department seems to make little or no use of its power to
bring unfair prejudice petitions.
84 The gateways are set out in Schs 15C and 15D of the Act. The same provisions apply
to information provided voluntarily: see para.18–2, above.
85
Saunders v United Kingdom [1998] 1 B.C.L.C. 362 ECtHR; IJL v United Kingdom
(2001) 33 E.H.R.R. 11 ECtHR. For a sceptical assessment, see P. Davies, “Self-
incrimination, Fair Trials and the Pursuit of Corporate and Financial Wrongdoing” in B.
Markesinis (ed.), The Impact of the Human Rights Bill on English Law (Oxford: OUP,
1998). The House of Lords refused to quash the convictions of those involved despite
the breach of the Convention: R. v Saunders, Times Law Reports, 15 November 2002.
86
1985 Act s.447A. Nor do the amendments specifically exclude evidence to which the
prosecuting authorities were drawn as a result of the compelled testimony, where the
answers themselves are not used in the criminal trial.
87
Re Rex Williams Leisure Plc [1994] Ch. 350 CA.
88R. v Secretary of State for Trade and Industry Ex p. McCormick [1998] B.C.C. 379
CA; DC v United Kingdom [2000] B.C.C. 710 ECHR.
89 Fayed v United Kingdom (1994) 18 E.H.R.R. 393.
90Albert and Le Compte v Belgium (1983) 5 E.H.R.R. 533 ECHR. The Court of Appeal
remains of the view that general fairness does not in principle require the exclusion of
compelled testimony: Re Westminster Property Management Ltd [2000] 2 B.C.L.C. 396
CA.
91 Where the inspectors’ report is also admissible: s.441.
92 Cloverbay Ltd v BCCI SA [1991] Ch. 90 CA.
93 See Ch.17.
94
Substantial elements in Pt X of the Act (see Ch.16) are the response to abuses
revealed in inspectors’ reports.
PART 4
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE—MAJORITY
AND MINORITY SHAREHOLDERS
Introduction 19–1
Review of Shareholders’ Decisions 19–4
The starting point 19–4
Resolutions where the company’s interests are
centre stage 19–6
Resolutions more generally 19–7
Resolutions to expropriate members’ shares 19–8
Other resolutions 19–10
The future 19–11
Voting at class meetings 19–12
Class Rights 19–13
The procedure for varying class rights 19–14
What constitutes a “variation” 19–16
The definition of class rights 19–18
Other cases 19–21
Self-help 19–22
Provisions in the constitution 19–23
Shareholder agreements 19–25
Conclusion 19–29
INTRODUCTION
19–1
In any company law system a number of techniques are in
principle available to control the unfair exercise of voting power
by the majority of shareholders. We have encountered several
such techniques already, and it is useful to draw them together
briefly, before going on to discuss in more detail some
techniques not previously dealt with.
Perhaps most obviously, the law could identify specific
decisions which the majority is simply not permitted to take.
There are one or two examples of this approach in the Act and at
common law. For example, s.251 provides that a member is not
bound by an alteration of the articles after the date upon which
he or she became a member if its effect is to require the member
to take more shares in the company or in any other way increases
the member’s liability to contribute to the company’s share
capital or otherwise pay money to the company. In other words,
the size of a shareholder’s investment in the company is a matter
for individual, not collective, decision. Another is the admittedly
controversial common law rule may be that certain majority
shareholders cannot ratify wrongdoing by a director which
involves the appropriation by the director of corporate property.2
However, it is impossible for the legislature or the judges to
identify in advance very many substantive decisions which
should be prohibited on the grounds that they will always be
unfair to the minority. Normally, fairness and unfairness are
fact-specific assessments and therefore not appropriate for ex
ante decision-making on the part of the rule-maker.
An obvious response of the rule-maker in this situation is to
move from substance to procedure, and in fact the legislature
does make much greater use of rules which determine how the
shareholders are to decide than it does of rules which determine
what they shall decide. Chapter 143 provides a list of decisions
which the Act requires to be taken by the shareholders. Often
those decisions must also be taken by a three-quarters majority
of those voting (a “supermajority”) rather than a simple majority
(an “ordinary majority”). The statutory categorisation of
decisions as requiring ordinary or supermajority voting is not
entirely consistent in policy terms, but decisions affecting the
rights of the shareholders under the constitution generally
require a supermajority. Of course, a three-quarters majority
requirement does not obviate all cases of unfair prejudice of the
minority, but it reduces the incidence of such problems because,
under a supermajority requirement, only a quarter of the votes is
needed to block the resolution.
19–2
An approach lying in between the substantive and the procedural
is to leave the shareholders largely free to take what substantive
decision they will, but to control those elements of the decision
which are most likely to cause prejudice to the minority. This
policy is often effected through an equal treatment or sharing
rule. Thus, when a company repurchases its shares and does so
through market purchases,4 the Listing Rules insist on equality
of treatment of the shareholders, either by controlling the price at
which the repurchase is made or by requiring the repurchase to
be made by way of a tender offer to all shareholders.5 This does
something to prevent insiders from taking undue advantage of
the repurchase exercise or the repurchase having an effect on the
balance of power within the company to the benefit of the
majority. In the same vein, the common law requires dividends
to be paid equally to shareholders according to their
shareholdings. The common law took as its test for equality the
nominal value of the shares, though the articles normally adjust
this so as to use the amount paid up on the shares where the
nominal value differs from the amount paid up.6 This makes it
difficult for the majority to use the mechanism of dividend
distribution to allocate a disproportionate share of the company’s
earnings to themselves.7
Three further minority protection techniques are worth
mentioning at this stage. The new statutory derivative action
procedure makes it more difficult for a controlling
shareholder/director to block access to the courts by the minority
to enforce the company’s rights against the controller acting as
director.8 The derivative action allows the minority to side-step
the majority’s control of the board or shareholder decision-
making and to seek court (rather than corporate) approval to
initiate litigation. Of course, the derivative action is not available
if the shareholders have ratified the wrongdoing. However, the
statute now prevents interested directors from voting on a
shareholder resolution to ratify the wrongdoing.9 Thus, two
techniques are used. One is the essentially procedural one of
structuring the vote at shareholder level by excluding the votes
of those interested in the decision. The other is novel, i.e.
shifting the litigation decision to an outside authority free of
majority influence.
Excluding the controllers, when interested, from voting on the
decision in question is a technique taken further by the Listing
Rules of the Financial Conduct Authority and applying to
companies listed on the Main Market of the London Stock
Exchange. More importantly, those Rules impose a requirement
for shareholder approval of transactions with significant
shareholders which is not to be found in general company law.
Under the rules for “related party” transactions, the Listing Rules
exclude the related party from voting on the decision in question
and require that party to take all reasonable efforts to ensure that
associates do not vote either. Crucially, the term “related party”
is widely defined so as to include a person who can control 10
per cent or more of the voting rights in the company or who can
exercise substantial control over the company. “Associate” is
widely defined, rather in the manner of a “connected person” in
s.252 of the Act. Finally, a “related party transaction” is widely
defined so as to include not only transactions between the
company and the related party but also transactions in which the
company and related party together finance a transaction or
project and any other similar transaction which benefits the
related party.10
19–3
The final technique to be mentioned is that of giving the
minority the right to exit the company at a fair price if certain
decisions with which they disagree are taken by the majority.
Such exit rights are usually referred to as “appraisal” rights.
Crucially, they are not simply rights to exit the company, which
in a listed company the shareholder hardly needs, but rights to
leave at a fair price. Although in some company law systems this
is a rather well-developed minority protection remedy,11 the
British legislation uses it only very sparingly. This is perhaps
because, whether the right is to be bought out by the company or
by the majority shareholder, the effect is to place a potentially
substantial financial hurdle in the way of the decision which
triggers the appraisal right. Nevertheless, an appraisal right can
be found in ss.110 and 111 of the IA 1986 (reflecting provisions
introduced in the nineteenth century) which deal with the
reorganisation of companies in liquidation.12 More important, it
is also to be found in both the Companies Act and the Takeover
Code where it provides an exit right at a fair price where there
has been an acquisition or transfer of a controlling block of
shares in the company. In this second situation, the exit right is
not tied to the taking of a business decision but rather to a shift
in the composition of the shareholder body, though the basis of
the exit right is, in part, that the shift in the identity of the
controller of the company may well have an adverse impact
upon the minority shareholders.13
In this chapter, however, we shall look at two further minority
protection techniques. The first consists of giving power to the
court to review the decision of the majority on the grounds that it
is in some sense unfair to the minority. In specific instances we
have seen that the Act gives such a right of appeal to the
minority. The question now is whether the common law gives
such a general right. The second is treating the shareholders
whose interests are at risk from the decision as a separate group
whose consent is needed for the decision to go ahead, whether or
not under the company’s constitution the separate consent of that
group would be required. The first of these two techniques
obviates the difficulty of having to predict in advance which
decisions are acceptable and which not, for the decision is
subject to ex post scrutiny on a case-by-case basis by the courts.
The second technique is an extension of the policy of excluding
interested parties from voting on a decision. Sometimes this
negative technique is enough by itself. In other cases, however,
the law may need to go further and specify those who are
entitled to vote as well as those who are not, rather than leaving
the determination of those entitled to vote to the rules contained
in the company’s articles.
REVIEW OF SHAREHOLDERS’DECISIONS
The starting point
19–4
Scattered throughout the reports are statements that members
must exercise their votes “bona fide for the benefit of the
company as a whole”,14 a statement which, read casually, might
suggest that shareholders are subject at common law to precisely
the same basic principle as directors. This would be highly
misleading, however, and the decisions do not support any such
parallel. Indeed, to the contrary, it has also been repeatedly laid
down that votes are proprietary rights, like other incidents of
shares, which the holder may exercise in his or her own selfish
interests even if these are opposed to those of the company.15 A
shareholder may even enter into a contract to vote or not vote in
a particular way, and that contract may be enforced by
injunction.16 Moreover, as we have seen, directors themselves,
even though personally interested, can vote in their capacity as
shareholders at that general meeting,17 unless the Act or the
Listing Rules specifically deprive them of the right to vote.18
And this is so also as regards the transactions which, under Chs
4 and 4A of Pt 10 of the Act, require the prior approval of the
company in general meeting.
Thus, it is wrong to see the voting powers of shareholders as
being of a fiduciary character. Unlike directors’ powers,
shareholders’ voting rights are not conferred upon them in order
that they shall be exercised in the way which prefers the interests
of others over the interests of the voting shareholder where the
two are in conflict (as the fiduciary rule requires), and this is so
whether those others are seen to be “the company” or the
minority shareholders or, indeed, any other group.
However, to deny the fiduciary character of shareholders’
voting rights and to assert their proprietary nature is not to say
that the exercise of shareholders’ voting powers is, or should be,
unconstrained by the law. The controlling shareholders may not
be required to exercise their powers in the best interests of the
non-controlling shareholders, but this does not mean they may
trample over the interests of the latter with impunity. There are
many situations in the modern law, and not just within company
law, where the exercise of property rights or personal powers is
subject to some sort of review by the courts. The issue which
arises, therefore, is not the one of principle, but whether it has
proved possible for the courts or the legislature to develop a set
of criteria for the effective review of majority shareholders’
decisions. As we shall see below, this task was addressed by the
courts at an early stage in the development of British company
law, but the results of that exercise have not been spectacularly
successful. The courts have hovered uncomfortably between an
unwillingness to determine how businesses should be run and an
equally deeply felt unease that simple majoritarianism would
leave the minority exposed to opportunistic treatment by the
majority.
19–5
The principle which the courts have found so difficult to develop
and apply to shareholder decisions was articulated as early as
1900 by the Court of Appeal in Allen v Gold Reefs of West
Africa Ltd19 in the context of a vote to alter the company’s
articles. The Court of Appeal held that because the power to alter
the articles was a power which enabled the majority to bind the
minority, it must therefore be exercised “not only in the manner
required by law, but also bona fide for the benefit of the
company as a whole, and it must not be exceeded. These
conditions are always implied, and are seldom, if ever,
expressed”. This explanation might be thought to embrace the
ideas of absence of power, good faith, and abuse of power.
Despite that, for much of the early development in this area, the
focus was almost exclusively on “bona fide for the benefit of the
company as a whole”, and the difficult task of deciding what this
required.
In examining the case law, it is useful to divide the cases into
those where the shareholders’ decision clearly concerns and
affects the company’s rights and those where it does not, but
merely affects the members’ rights as between themselves; and,
with the latter, subdividing those cases into alteration of the
articles involving an expropriation of the member’s shares, and
those not having that effect, although all these distinctions are
becoming less marked in light of recent cases.
Resolutions where the company’s interests are
centre stage
19–6
We have already seen the tension in reviewing voting decisions
brought to the fore in Ch.16. The company, like any legal
person, can forgive directors for the wrongs they do to the
company. This inevitably comes at a financial cost to the
company, since it gives up an otherwise valuable claim.
Nevertheless, the decision, typically taken by the general
meeting on behalf of the company, can be taken for perfectly
proper reasons. But we rightly doubt that the reasons are
“perfectly proper” when the decision is carried by the votes of
the wrongdoing directors themselves. This is true even if the
range of “perfectly proper” reasons is very much at large; there
is something unpalatable about forgiveness driven by the
wrongdoers themselves. In this context we have seen the
common law’s struggle between holding certain decisions “un-
ratifiable” (i.e. the general meeting simply does not have the
power to act) and, alternatively, disenfranchising the interested
shareholder directors (i.e. focusing on the propriety of their
decision-making).20 We have also seen the modern statutory
preference for the latter approach.21 The same approaches are
evident in other contexts: denying shareholders the right to
dispose of corporate assets when the company is insolvent has
parallels with “un-ratifiable” decisions22; occasionally
disenfranchising shareholders thought to be inevitably conflicted
is an example of the latter approach.23
Resolutions more generally
19–7
However intuitively compelling these approaches, they are rarely
defended on the basis of principle. That makes it difficult to
settle on the appropriate approach in the more difficult, and more
common, cases. These are the cases where the general meeting
has the undoubted power to take decision, but their objective is
not straightforwardly to advance the interests of the company
(although sometimes it can be framed that way), but merely to
determine relative rights as between the shareholders. In this
context, it is inevitable that the majority’s preferences will be
favoured, even in circumstances where there can be no rational
complaint that the decision was somehow inappropriate or
improper: consider decisions to sack directors, or change the
articles. When are these decisions reviewable? It is clear that
they are reviewable, but, as one judge put it with some
understatement, the current British law is “somewhat untidy”.24
Resolutions to expropriate members’ shares
19–8
In expropriation (or compulsory transfer) cases, the arguments
for judicial intervention might seem to be at their strongest, but
the law falls far short of prohibiting changes in the articles aimed
at introducing such clauses. On the contrary, it is clear that
compulsory transfer articles may be introduced into the
company’s articles, and the debate is about the level of judicial
scrutiny to which such amendments will be subject. The relevant
authorities start with Brown v British Abrasive Wheel Co,25 a
decision at first instance in which a public company was in
urgent need of further capital which shareholders, holding 98 per
cent of the shares, were willing to put up but only if they could
buy out the 2 per cent minority. Having failed to persuade the
minority to sell, they proposed a special resolution adding to the
articles a provision to the effect that any shareholder was bound
to transfer his shares upon a request in writing of the holders of
90 per cent of the shares. Although such a provision could have
been validly inserted in the original articles,26 and although the
good faith of the majority was not challenged, it was held that
the addition of a general provision enabling the majority to
expropriate the minority could not be for the benefit of the
company as a whole but was solely for the benefit of the
majority. Hence an injunction was granted restraining the
company from passing the resolution.
This decision, however, was almost immediately
“distinguished” by the Court of Appeal in Sidebottom v
Kershaw, Leese & Co Ltd.27 There, a directorcontrolled private
company had a minority shareholder who had an interest in a
competing business. Objecting to this, the company passed a
special resolution adding to the articles a provision empowering
the directors to require any shareholder who competed with the
company to sell his shares at a fair value to nominees of the
directors. This was upheld on the basis that it was obviously
beneficial to the company. In contrast, shortly thereafter in
Dafen Tinplate Co v Llanelly Steel Co,28 it was held at first
instance that a resolution inserting a new article empowering the
majority to buy out any shareholder as they thought proper, was
invalid as being self-evidently wider than could be necessary in
the interests of the company.
So far, all these decisions suggest that adding to the articles a
provision enabling the shares of a member to be compulsorily
transferred will be upheld only if passed bona fide in the
interests of the company, with that judged not just by the
members but also reviewable by the court, on a basis which in
some ill-defined way goes beyond the general meeting merely
showing good faith and rationality. However, in Shuttleworth v
Cox Bros Ltd,29 a case concerning not the expropriation of shares
but the removal of an unpopular life director, the Court of
Appeal, in upholding the validity of a resolution inserting in the
articles a provision that any director should vacate office if
called upon to do so by the board, held that it was for the
members, and not the court, to determine whether the resolution
is for the benefit of the company and that the court will intervene
only if satisfied that the members have acted in bad faith.30 If the
same applies to expropriation of shares, it is difficult to
understand why what is now s.979 of the Act was needed. That
section31 enables a takeover bidder who has acquired 90 per cent
or more of the target company’s shares to acquire compulsorily
the remainder. There would have been no need for that section if
a bidder, having acquired a controlling interest, could then cause
the target company to insert in its articles a similar power. That
might suggest that mere bona fides, directed to the benefit of the
company, does not quite capture the approach being applied by
the court. And yet going further has proved controversial.
19–9
An issue akin to the Brown facts was considered by the High
Court of Australia in Gambotto v WCP Ltd,32 where it was
proposed to alter the articles to allow a 90 per cent shareholder
to acquire the shares of minority shareholders at an objectively
fair price (the majority holder in fact holding 99.7 per cent of the
shares). The motivation for the change was to convert the
company into a wholly owned subsidiary, which would bring
enormous tax advantages for the company. Nevertheless, the
court refused to allow the change, holding explicitly that the
majority’s decision could only be upheld if it were taken in good
faith and for proper purposes. In the court’s view, the general
meeting’s power to expropriate shares could legitimately be used
to save the company from “significant detriment or harm” (as in
Sidebottom v Kershaw, Leese and Co Ltd) but not to advance the
commercial interests of the majority (as in this case, where the
tax advantages to the company would indirectly, but greatly,
benefit its controlling shareholders). “English authority”,
presumably Shuttleworth v Cox Bros Ltd, was disapproved on
the grounds that “it does not attach sufficient weight to the
proprietary nature of a share”.33 On one view, there is something
of this same approach implicit in Brown, in Astbury J’s
judgment, where he too could be seen as denying the majority
the right to use their power to expropriate the minority to their
own corresponding advantage.34 And yet English courts have on
occasion explicitly distanced themselves from the objective
“proper purposes” approach in Gambotto, even in the context of
expropriation decisions.35
However, the recent decision of Re Charterhouse Capital
Ltd36 perhaps puts suggestions of continuing adherence to a more
relaxed British test in doubt. The Court of Appeal approved an
amendment of the articles to permit expropriation of shares, and
affirmed the broadly subjective test in Shuttleworth, but, in
setting out the full detail of the appropriate test, the court
consistently referred to the test as embracing not only bona fides
but also the intended proper purpose of the power,37 here being a
tidying-up exercise designed to implement the agreed terms of a
shareholder agreement which was expressed to take priority over
the articles.
In such circumstances it would seem difficult for any minority
shareholder to argue that the amendment was either irrational or
for improper purposes, or in bad faith.
Other resolutions
19–10
If it is not clear what English law requires in cases of
compulsory transfer of shares, where the arguments can typically
be framed in terms of corporate benefit even if there are also
substantial benefits to the majority, then how much more
difficult is the issue likely to be where that claim cannot be
made, and it is simply a battle of wills between the majority and
minority as to how their relations should be regulated by the
articles? In these circumstances, many cases appear to adopt the
view that the only test can be good faith, as in Shuttleworth,
since the courts can have no objective standard of their own to
judge whether a decision is for the benefit of the company (other
than shareholder irrationality, perhaps, and even that requires
some conception of “the interests of the company”). In the
difficult case of Greenhalgh v Arderne Cinemas Ltd,38 where the
proposed amendment was to remove a pre-emption clause so as
to facilitate a sale of control to a third party, Sir Raymond
Evershed MR tried to preserve the application of the traditional
test by saying that in such cases “the company as a whole” did
not mean the company as a corporate entity but “the corporators
as a general body”, and that it was necessary to ask whether the
amendment was, in the honest opinion of those who voted in
favour, for the benefit of a hypothetical member. Since the case
was before the court precisely because of a division of opinion
on the issue, this test is hardly illuminating. As was pointed out
by the High Court of Australia in its famous inter-war decision,
Peter’s American Delicacy Co Ltd v Heath,39 it is “inappropriate,
if not meaningless” to ask whether the shareholders had
considered the amendment to be in the interests of the company
as a whole. Some other test of validity is required.
On what that might be, little progress has been made over the
intervening 75 years. Thus, in Citco Banking Corp NV v
Pusser’s Ltd40 the Privy Council upheld a change in the articles
which entrenched the existing controller of the company (who
before the change controlled 28 per cent of the company’s
shares) by permitting the conversion of his existing shares
(carrying one vote per share) into a new class of share carrying
50 votes per share. This was said by those who supported the
alteration to be a bona fide decision in the interests of the
company because it enabled the company to raise further finance
for expansion, the financiers requiring that the existing controller
remain in charge. The genuineness of this belief on the part of
the majority was not challenged by the other party to the
litigation and the court found that a reasonable shareholder could
have held this view about the proposed alteration. Applying the
Shuttleworth test and reiterating that the burden of proof is on
those who challenge the resolution, the court found the test of
bona fide in the interests of the company to have been met.
This may all seem unexceptional, yet working through the
potential ramifications must give some cause for concern. At
face value, it appears to suggest that a majority could use its
power to deliver differential benefits to itself to the exclusion of
the minority (here, conversion of a tranche of A shares carrying
one vote per share to a tranche of B shares carrying 50 votes per
share). If that can be done, would it not be equally permissible to
reclassify the majority’s tranche of ordinary shares to give
differential dividend rights, or rights to capital on winding up?
Even if it is thought that does not offend the rules on amending a
company’s articles—which is doubted—it must surely fail the
statutory requirements for protection of shareholders’ class
rights and pre-emptive rights. The minority would effectively be
reduced to advancing s.994 complaints of unfair prejudice. The
remedies there are typically that the minority is bought out, and
thus excluded completely from further participation in the
company. Looking back to the problem, notice that what is
intuitively objectionable is not that the minority is overpowered;
that is inevitable with majority rule. It is that the majority can
use its power for the purpose of delivering differential benefits to
itself to the exclusion of the minority. Lord Hoffmann, in Citco,
would not disenfranchise the interested shareholder (here one
Tobias), especially as there was no attack on his bona fides, but
he did note that, even without his votes, the resolution would
still have been carried by 78 per cent of the shareholders. In
these circumstances, there seems little cause for complaint by the
losing minority. But absent these circumstances, and despite the
prevailing analysis in the cases, surely there is a justifiable
concern?41
The future
19–11
But perhaps, finally, the future is looking a little more certain.
All the cases so far illustrate a set of common concerns in this
area. Of itself, this suggests a common approach is warranted:
there is little point in different tests for different sub-categories
of shareholder decision-making, although of course, whatever
the test, the particular power and the context for its exercise will
be a material consideration.42 In determining the appropriate
tests for judicial review, there seem to be three broad ways
forward in this area. The first is to demand little of shareholders
in their decision-making other than rationality and bona fides.
Many cases are illustrative,43 but so too their problems. The
second is to adopt a safe mid-way point, permitting an objective
element in the test applied by the court, and keeping that test
focused on “the interests of the company”, but not going so far
as to allow the court to substitute its own commercial view of
what might have been best in the circumstances. Brown v British
Abrasive Wheel Co,44 discussed earlier, might be illustrative.45
Whatever the merits, such an approach seems difficult to justify
in principle and impossible to administer with certainty. The
third, and certainly the most interventionist approach, is to
embrace the twin tests of subjective bona fides and objective
proper purposes, as in Gambotto. Despite the criticisms visited
on that case, this does increasingly appear to be the modern
approach, both with shareholder decision-making and more
generally.46 It has a respectable pedigree: it is evident in the
explicit language of the much-cited Allen v Gold Reefs of West
Africa Ltd,47 as well as in the more controversial Gambotto, and
is also evident in all the most recent considered English
decisions.48 Moreover, although it was not the language used, it
might be seen as a better explanation of some of the earlier
English cases.49
Its starting point is the perfectly general one that no grant of
power is absolute, at least when its exercise binds dissenting
parties. The minimum constraints are that the power must be
exercised rationally, in good faith, and for the purposes for
which the power is granted. It is this last feature which typically
provides the potential tripwire in authorisation and ratification
decisions, in expropriation decisions, and in governance
decisions such as Citco. But in different contexts the concerns
(or “purposes”) are different; for example, the relevant “proper
purposes” might give free rein to shareholders in their
appointment and dismissal of directors.50 This variability might
not make the relevant distinctions much easier to solve when
presented in terms of improper purposes (or fraud on the power),
rather than in terms of “bona fide in the interests of the
company”, but at least the principles being pursued are clearer.
As evidence of this trend, Sir Terence Etherton C in Re
Charterhouse Capital, indicated, obiter, that he preferred the
formulation in Peters’ American Delicacy Co Ltd v Heath,51 that
in the case of an amendment in which the company as an entity
has no interest, the test should be whether the amendment
amounts to oppression of the minority or is otherwise unjust or is
outside the scope of the power. This is the sort of test which also
applies more broadly, to decision-making by other power-
holders.52
Voting at class meetings
19–12
The rules discussed above apply not only to decisions by the
shareholders at large but also to votes at meetings of classes of
shareholders. These rules and their use are described in the next
section, but we might immediately note that here, too, the cases
adopt the same approach to decision-making as described
immediately above. Sometimes this is very clearly so. Re
Holders Investment Trust53 concerned a capital reduction scheme
requiring the confirmation of the court. Megarry J approached
the matter on the basis that he had to be satisfied, first, that the
resolution of the preference shareholders had been validly passed
bona fide in the interest of that class; and then that, in the court’s
view, the scheme was fair to all classes.54 The application failed
at the first step. By analogy with the cases considered earlier, the
law required members voting in class meetings to use their votes
for the purpose of—or in the interests of—the class. Here,
confirmation was refused because the resolution of the class
meeting of the preference shareholders had been passed as a
result of votes of trustees who held a large block of the
preference shares but a still larger block of ordinary shares. In
casting their votes, the trustees had deliberately voted in the way
best designed to favour the ordinary shareholders, since that was
what would best serve the interests of their beneficiaries (as of
course their trustee obligations required). The court held that use
of their power in this way was not permitted. We might now say
it was contrary to the protective purposes underpinning the
required class meetings.
CLASS RIGHTS
19–13
We have already noted that the principle discussed in the
previous section applies to class meetings as well as to general
meetings of the shareholders. Now we need to turn to the
question of when separate meetings of classes of shareholders
are required and how the class in question is defined. The
separate consent of shareholders particularly affected by a
proposed resolution may be required by statute or by the
company’s own constitution. For example, as we shall see, the
principle of separate consent is well-established in relation to
proposed alterations of the articles where these alterations affect
the “rights” of a class of members.
The procedure for varying class rights
19–14
Where a proposed alteration of the articles involves “the
variation of the rights attached to a class of shares”, the Act
supplements the general supermajority provisions of s.21 with
additional protective mechanisms for members of the affected
class. The technique deployed in ss.630 and 631 is to require the
separate consent of the class, usually by way of a 75 per cent
majority, to any proposal to alter the articles in such a way as
would vary the class rights. Without this important protective
technique, the class might be swamped by the votes of other
classes of shareholders. Indeed, the class in question might not
otherwise have any say in the matter at all, if, for example, it was
a class of non-voting shareholders. Preference shares are often
non-voting, at least if their dividends are being paid on time, and
classes of non-voting ordinary shares are not unknown. The
alteration of their rights would otherwise be a matter entirely for
the voting shareholders. The Act thus provides the class in
question with a veto over the proposed change, even if the
company’s constitution gave the class members no right to vote
on the issue. Of course, the alteration must also be approved in
the normal way under s.21 (approval by a three-quarters majority
of those shareholders entitled to vote under the company’s
articles), but that is not normally a problem in the cases
considered in this section.
The statutory provisions on variation in the 2006 Act are
considerably simpler than their predecessors. Section 630 in
effect lays down a single default rule,55 with equivalent provision
being made in s.631 for companies without shares. Variation of
the rights attached to a class of shares requires the consent of
three-quarters of the votes cast at a separate meeting of that class
or a written resolution having the support of holders of three-
quarters of the nominal value of the class (excluding treasury
shares) (s.630(4)). That default rule may be displaced by explicit
provisions in the company’s articles, which may set a higher or a
lower standard. This is very straightforward and is enough to
deal with most cases which will arise.
The complexity of the section, such as it is, derives from its
attempt to answer the question of what rules should govern any
attempt to amend the procedure in the articles for the variation of
class rights, if the articles contain such a procedure. If the
variation procedure in the articles could be freely amended in the
same way as any other article of the company, the protection
intended to be afforded by the articles to the class could easily be
undermined. The section begins by stating that any amendment
to the variation procedure contained in the articles itself attracts
the provisions protecting class rights (s.630(5)).56 Without this
provision, a variation procedure in the articles requiring a higher
level of consent could be reduced to, or even below, the level of
the statutory default by simply following the requirements of
s.21 for general alterations to the articles (for example, no class
meeting). This is now not possible as a result of s.630(5), unless,
presumably, the articles themselves expressly provide a less
demanding way of amending the variation procedure than the
default rule in the statute.
In the same vein, the subsection also treats as a variation of
class rights the introduction of a variation procedure into the
articles, for that might set a lower standard than the statutory
default rule previously applicable. Finally, the section is without
prejudice “to any other restrictions on the variation of rights”.57
This appears to mean that a company could use the entrenchment
mechanism of s.2258 to set an even higher requirement for
amendments to the variation procedure contained in the articles
than that otherwise required by s.630. For example, the articles
could provide that amendments to the variation procedure
require the consent of all the members of the class.
19–15
So far, we have observed that the statutory provisions on class
rights use two protective techniques, at least on a default basis: a
separate meeting of the class (the main protection) and the
supermajority protection of a three-quarters majority to obtain an
effective decision of the class meeting. However, s.633 also
makes use of a third technique analysed in the first part of this
chapter, namely, court review of the majority’s decision.59 This
acknowledges the fact that, even within a class meeting, it is
possible for the majority of the class to act opportunistically
towards the minority of the class. Section 633 may be
particularly useful where the articles adopt a variation procedure
considerably less demanding than the default statutory one. As
we have seen,60 those voting at class meetings are subject to the
general common law requirements as to proper decision-making,
but s.633 (with equivalent provisions in s.634 for companies
limited by guarantee) goes further. It affords a dissenting
minority of not less than 15 per cent of the issued shares of a
class,61 whose rights have been varied in manner permitted by
s.630, a right to apply to the court to have the variation
cancelled. Application must be made within 21 days after the
consent was given or the resolution passed, but can be made by
such one or more of the dissenting shareholders as they appoint
in writing. Once such an application is made, the variation has
no effect unless and until it is confirmed by the court. If, after
hearing the applicant “and any other persons who apply to be
heard and appear to the court to be interested”,62 the court is
satisfied that the variation would “unfairly prejudice”63 the
shareholders of the class represented by the applicant, it may
disallow the variation but otherwise must confirm it.64 It is
expressly provided that “the decision of the court is final”,65
which presumably means that it cannot be taken to appeal.66
The dearth of reported cases on s.633, and earlier versions of
it, suggests that applications under it are made rarely if at all.
Nevertheless, it probably serves a useful purpose in specifically
drawing the attention of boards of directors to the need to ensure
that variations of class rights treat classes fairly. But, should they
ignore that warning, they are more likely to face an application
under the unfair prejudice rules in Pt 30 rather than under s.633.
The sections analysed above provide a procedure whereby the
company can vary class rights. Sometimes, a variation of class
rights is effected by an order of the court. Section 632 makes it
clear that the courts’ powers under Pt 26 of the Act (dealing with
arrangements and reconstructions (see Ch.29)) and Pt 30 (unfair
prejudice—see the following chapter) and, less importantly, s.98
(cancellation of resolution of public company to re-register as
private) are not affected by ss.630 and 631.
What constitutes a “variation”
19–16
Although the Act deals at some length with the procedure for
varying class rights, it says very little, if anything, about what a
variation of class rights is or, indeed, what a class right is. Both
these matters are defined principally by the common law. As a
matter of logic, however, the statutory or constitutional
procedure is only relevant once it is clear that there is to be a
variation of a class right. We will look first at “variation” and
then at “class right”.
Prior to the enactment of statutory provisions in this area, it
was commonly assumed that rules specified in the articles
required class consent only of the class whose rights were being
altered in a manner adverse to that class. But the statutory
provisions on “variation” (even if coupled with the statement
that it includes “abrogation”) cannot reasonably be construed as
meaning only “adverse variation”, and, to avoid any subsequent
attack on the validity of the resolution, the formal consent of the
benefited class should be obtained, even though it might appear
a foregone conclusion.
However, the real problem lies where a class is adversely
affected by what is proposed, but the courts, by placing a narrow
technical construction on what constitutes a variation of rights,
have declined to hold that the proposal falls within the class
rights provisions of either the statute or the articles. Thus a
subdivision67 or increase68 of one class of shares has been held
not to vary the rights of another class notwithstanding that the
result was to alter profoundly the voting equilibrium of the
classes. Similarly, where preference shares were non-
participating as regards dividend but participating as regards
capital on a winding-up or reduction of capital, a capitalisation
of undistributed profits in the form of a bonus issue to the
ordinary shareholders was not a variation of the preference
shareholders’ rights notwithstanding that the effect was to deny
them their future participation in those profits on winding up or
reduction.69 In the contrary situation, where the shares were
participating as regards dividends but not in relation to return of
capital on a winding-up, a reduction of capital by repayment of
irredeemable preference shares in accordance with their rights on
a winding-up (i.e. at their nominal value) was not regarded as a
variation or abrogation of their rights, even though the
shareholders were deprived of valuable dividend rights.70 Even if
the dividend rights of the preference shareholders were fixed,
those rights might be valuable, if interest rates had fallen after
the issuance of the preference shares. The obvious unfairness of
this led to a contractual solution: the practice of providing, on
issues by public companies of preference shares which are non-
participating in a winding-up, that on redemption or any return
of capital the amount repaid should be tied to the average quoted
market price of the shares in the months before (the market price
reflecting the value of the dividend rights rather than the nominal
value of the shares). This, so-called “Spens formula”, named
after its inventor, affords reasonable protection in the case of
listed companies but preference shareholders in unquoted
companies still remain at risk.
Finally, an issue of further shares ranking pari passu with the
existing shares of a class was not regarded as a variation of
rights.71 And, where there were preference and ordinary shares,
an issue of preferred ordinary shares ranking ahead of the
ordinary but behind the preference was not a variation of the
rights of either existing class.72 The principle applied in all the
above cases was that the formal rights of the complaining
shareholders had not been varied, even if the change had
adversely affected the value of those rights.
19–17
However, just as it is possible for the articles to require a
variation procedure which is more demanding than the statutory
default procedure in terms, for example, of the level of approval
required, so it is possible for the articles to require a wider range
of variations to be subject to the procedure than the statute
requires. Thus, in the wake of the decisions on reduction of
capital referred to in the previous paragraph, it became common
to introduce special provisions into a company’s articles to
protect preference shareholders. In Re Northern Engineering
Industries Plc73 a clause in the articles deeming a reduction of
capital to be a variation of rights was upheld and enforced when
the company proposed to cancel its preference shares. But very
clear wording will have to be used if such a provision is to be
construed as affording any greater safeguards. In White v Bristol
Aeroplane Co74 and Re John Smith’s Tadcaster Brewery Co,75
the relevant clauses referred to class rights being “affected,
modified, dealt with or abrogated”. At first instance Danckwerts
J76 held that bonus issue to the ordinary shareholders could not
be made without the consent of the preference shareholders
because, although their rights would not be abrogated or varied,
they would be “affected” since their votes would be worth less in
view of the increased voting power of the ordinary shareholders.
But the Court of Appeal reversed his decision. They said that the
rights of the preference shareholders would not be affected; the
rights themselves—to one vote per share in certain
circumstances—remained precisely as before. All that would
occur was that their holders’ enjoyment of those rights would be
affected. If that eventuality was to be guarded against, more
explicit wording would have to be used, making it clear that the
clause was intended to protect economic interests as well as
rights.
It seems, therefore, that if s.630 is effectively to prevent class
rights from being “affected as a matter of business”,77 it is
necessary to find a formula for a variation of rights clause which
will expressly operate in relation to an alteration which affects
the enjoyment of their rights (as opposed to the rights
themselves). In the absence of such a clause in the model
articles, however, such rights are likely to be granted by
companies only if it is thought that the securities on offer would
not otherwise be acceptable to potential purchasers or, at least,
not acceptable at the price the company wishes to issue them at.
The definition of class rights
19–18
Before it is possible to decide whether a class right has been
varied, it is necessary to know what a class right is. This is a
matter upon which there is a surprising degree of doubt. Section
629 tells us that shares are to be regarded as of one class if the
rights attached to them “are in all respects uniform”, so that
merely attaching different names to groups of shares does not
turn them into different classes of share if the rights attached to
them are the same.78 This definition of a class of shares applies
to the Act generally, not just in relation to the variation of class
rights.
Beyond that, the statute gives no help. It does not even state
expressly, as s.127(1) of the 1985 Act did, that class rights can
arise only if there is more than one class of share. It seems likely
that no change was intended on this point, since, where there is
only one class of share, s.21 (alteration of the articles) and s.630
(variation of class rights) would overlap to an unacceptable
extent, if s.630 applied in this case as well. However, assuming
two or more classes of share, what then counts as a class right?
The choices range from only the rights attached to any one of the
classes which are unique to it (i.e. not held in common with any
of the other classes of share) to all the rights attached to any of
the classes. An intermediate position adds to the first group the
core rights of shareholders (relating to voting, dividends and
return of capital on a winding-up) whether or not those rights are
unique to the class in that particular case. There is little authority
on the choice to be made, although in Cumbrian Newspapers
Group Ltd v Cumberland and Westmoreland Newspaper and
Printing Co Ltd79 Scott J seemed to favour the first and
narrowest view. The second view might be thought to protect
more adequately the expectations of shareholders. On the first
and narrowest view a shareholder seeking protection of
dividend, voting and return of capital rights which were not
unique to the class would have to ensure that there was a
variation of rights clause in the articles and that that clause
defined class rights in an appropriately broad way. This seems
undesirable. The right to class consent at least for the variation
of core rights would be what companies and, for example,
preference shareholders would expect and the law should give
effect to that expectation.
19–19
Whilst this basic issue about the definition of a class right
continues unresolved, a more sophisticated aspect of the same
question has been considered judicially and has received a
surprisingly liberal response. The question is whether there are
class rights where nominally the shares are of the same class but
special rights are conferred on one or more members without
attaching those rights to any particular shares held by that
member or members. This was the question facing Scott J in the
Cumbrian Newspapers case.80 Two companies, publishing rival
provincial weekly newspapers in an area where it had become
apparent that only one was viable, entered into an arrangement
designed to ensure that one of the companies (Company A)
would publish that one newspaper but that it would issue 10 per
cent of its ordinary share capital81 to the other company
(Company B). Company B was anxious to ensure that the paper
should remain locally owned and controlled, and to this end the
articles of Company A were amended in such a way as to confer
on Company B pre-emptive rights in the event of any new issue
of shares by Company A or on a disposal by other shareholders
of their shares in Company A. These rights were not attached to
any particular shares but conferred on Company B by name.
Further, another new article provided that: “If and so long as
[company B] shall be the holder of not less than one-tenth in
nominal value of the issued ordinary share capital of” Company
A, Company B “shall be entitled from time to time to nominate
one person to be a director of” Company A. Company A’s
articles contained a variation of rights clause. Eighteen years
later, Company A’s directors proposed to convene a general
meeting to pass a special resolution deleting the relevant articles.
Company B thereupon applied to the court for a declaration that
Company B’s rights were class rights that could not be abrogated
without its consent.
Scott J pointed out that special rights contained in articles
could be divided into three categories.82 First, there are rights
annexed to particular shares. The classic example of this is
where particular shares carry particular rights not enjoyed by
others, e.g. in relation to “dividends and rights to participate in
surplus assets on a winding up”.83 These clearly were “rights
attached to [a] class of shares” within the meaning of what is
now s.630. He also held that this category would include cases
where rights were attached to particular shares issued to a named
individual but expressed to determine upon transfer by that
individual of his shares.
The second category was where the articles purported to
confer rights on individuals not in their capacity as members or
shareholders.84 Rights of this sort would not be class rights, for
they would not be attached to any class of shares.85 But
Company B’s rights did not fall within this class; the articles in
question were “inextricably connected with the issue to the
plaintiff86 and the acceptance by the plaintiff of the ordinary
shares in the defendant”.87
This left the third category: “rights that, although not attached
to any particular shares were nonetheless conferred upon the
beneficiary in the capacity of member or shareholder of the
company”.88 In his view, rights conferred on Company B fell
into this category.89 But did they come within the words in the
then equivalent of s.630(1) as “rights attached to any class of
shares”? After an analysis of the various legislative provisions
and of the anomalies which would result if they did not,90 he
concluded that the legislative intent must have been to deal
comprehensively with the variation or abrogation of
shareholders’ class rights and that he should therefore construe
what is now s.630 as applying to categories one and three. He
accordingly granted the declaration sought.91
19–20
This decision of Scott J might have been easier to reach under
the 2006 Act. In effect, the learned judge treated the expressions
“the rights of a class of members” and the “rights…attached to a
class of shares” as synonymous. The 2006 Act, by contrast, deals
explicitly with variations of the former type in s.631, and the
latter in s.630. In short, Scott J may have anticipated by a few
decades the position now provided for by statute.
Other cases
19–21
There are some statutory procedures for taking corporate
decisions which explicitly require the separate consent of each
class of shares, for example, Pt 26 dealing with schemes of
arrangement, but there the definition of a “class” of shares is
interpreted functionally rather than literally, in contrast with the
variation of rights cases.92
SELF-HELP
19–22
It is wrong to think that protection for minority shareholders is to
be found only in mandatory provisions of company law.
Provided the minority shareholder has sufficient bargaining
power, for example at the point a much-needed investment is
made in the company, that shareholder may be able to negotiate
for protections over and above those to be found in company
law. These contractual protections may then be reflected in the
company’s constitution or in an agreement existing separately
from and outside the constitution.
Indeed, across the board there is a considerable incentive for
shareholders themselves to provide, in advance of a dispute
arising, for a substantive or procedural rule which will govern
the case. Individuals reading the previous pages would be
justified in feeling somewhat gloomy about the extent to which
minority shareholder interests are truly protected by the rules
there analysed, and so might well feel that such contractual
protections would be essential. Where class rights are not
involved, the scope of the objective controls upon the voting
decisions of the majority is still very unclear. Even where class
rights are involved, the protection afforded still has its
weaknesses, notably the limited view taken by the courts of what
constitutes the variation of a class right. Indeed, the statutory
class-rights procedure encourages self-help because it sets out
only default rules and limited ones at that.93
As an added advantage, the techniques described below may
be used quite generally to exert control in the interests of
minority shareholders in any corporate decision, regardless of
whether that decision needs to be taken by the shareholders or
may be taken by the board of the company. As such, the
following discussion constitutes a bridge to the statutory unfair
prejudice provisions discussed in the following chapter.
Provisions in the constitution
19–23
The articles provide an obvious place in which to locate any
agreements reached for the protection of minority shareholders,
because the articles bind the company and its members as they
exist from time to time (s.33) so that future members are bound
by the provisions of the articles protecting the minority without
further ado.
Protective provisions in the articles will be an effective way of
safeguarding minorities only if they can be enforced. Often the
minority shareholder will want to assert that a decision taken in
breach of the protective provisions is not binding on the
company and that an injunction should be granted to enjoin the
company and its directors from acting on the invalid resolution.
In principle, such an action should be available since, as we saw
in Ch.3, the articles are enforceable as a contract, although the
discussion in Ch.3 also set out several important and probably
unexpected limits to the general principle.94
The weakness with protective provisions in the articles,
however, is that they are alterable by special resolution of those
entitled to vote on shareholder resolutions (s.21). This may
provide a way to defeat the expectations of non-voting
shareholders or even those of minority voting shareholders,
because a previous protection may simply be removed from the
articles, at least provided no class rights have been created.
The Act itself suggests one possible solution to the risk of
future amendment, namely, use of the entrenchment powers
contained in s.22. Under this section a provision in the articles
can be declared to be alterable only through a more restrictive
procedure than that required for a special resolution under s.21.
The entrenchment provision may go so far as to require
unanimity for a particular change, although it cannot render the
provision unalterable if all the members agree to the change
(s.22(3)). Thus, s.22 provides a mechanism whereby a provision
protective of the minority can be included in the company’s
articles and that protective provision can be declared to be
alterable only in the desired way, most obviously only if those it
is intended to protect agree to the change. However, the
entrenchment provision may have a powerful and adverse effect
on those it does not benefit and so s.22(2) provides that
entrenchment provisions may be included only in the company’s
articles on formation or, subsequently, with the consent of all the
members of the company. Entrenchment is, thus, essentially a
small company facility.
19–24
Consequently, it may be more attractive to provide the required
minority protection in a company already in existence by
creating a new class of shares carrying the relevant protection,
issuing those shares to the shareholder to be protected, and then
including a broad variation of rights clause in the articles, so
that, for example, the consent of the protected shareholder
becomes necessary for the alteration of the protection.
Alternatively, the shareholder may be given in effect control
over the taking of any resolutions by the shareholders through
provisions which in principle are alterable but in practice cannot
be. An example would be a rule that the quorum for a meeting of
the shareholders cannot be constituted unless the minority
shareholder is present, either in person or by proxy. Thus, the
shareholder would be given a veto over decisions of the
shareholders, exercisable by refusing to participate in the
meeting.95 This provision would be ineffective where the
shareholders decide by written resolution, but in that case it
might be possible to provide a solution by requiring the
particular shareholder’s consent for a written resolution or
through weighted voting rights.96
Shareholder agreements
19–25
Alternatively, the parties may prefer to proceed by way of an
agreement existing outside and separate from the articles. This
has the advantage of privacy because such an agreement, unlike
the company’s constitution, does not have to be filed at
Companies House. However, an issue immediately arises as to
whether the company can effectively be made party to such an
agreement, as it would be if the agreement were embodied in the
company’s articles. Here, there are two apparently conflicting
principles: first, that a company, like any other person, cannot
with impunity break its contracts and, secondly, that a company
cannot contract out of its statutory power under s.21 to alter its
articles by special resolution.
The second proposition was favoured by the House of Lords
in Russell v Northern Bank Development Corp Ltd.97 It was clear
to their lordships that “a provision in a company’s articles which
restricts its statutory power to alter those articles is invalid”98 and
they applied that principle to the agreement before them, existing
outside the articles among the shareholders and to which the
company purported to be a party. That agreement provided that
no further share capital should be created or issued in the
company without the written consent of all the parties to the
agreement. Consequently, it would seem that the company
cannot validly contract independently of the articles not to alter
those articles.99 However, that proposition is heavily qualified by
two further propositions which may render the initial proposition
ineffective in practice, at least for those who are well advised.
Prior contracts
19–26
The first qualification is that the principle of invalidity, laid
down in Russell, does not apply where the company has entered
into a previous contract on such terms that for the company to
act upon its subsequently altered article would involve it in a
breach of the prior contract. In this situation the term of the
earlier contract, which would be breached if the company acted
upon the altered article, is not invalid. The Russell principle is
not relevant here because the term in the earlier contract is not
broken when the company alters its articles, but only when it
acts upon the altered article. Although the case law has tended to
focus on directors’ service contracts, its implication for
shareholder agreements is that a company would be a party to
them and agree not to act in a particular way in the future,
provided it did not agree to refrain from amending its articles.
Thus, in Southern Foundries (1926) Ltd v Shirlaw100 the
company altered its articles so as to introduce a new method of
removing directors from office and then used the new method to
dismiss the managing director in breach of his 10-year service
contract. The managing director successfully obtained damages
for wrongful dismissal. The provision as to the term of the
service agreement was thus clearly held by the House of Lords
to be valid. Lord Porter said: “A company cannot be precluded
from altering its articles thereby giving itself power to act upon
the provisions of the altered articles—but so to act may
nevertheless be a breach of contract if it is contrary to a
stipulation in a contract validly made before the alteration”.101 In
this case the contract protected a manager but the principle is
equally applicable to a contract protecting a shareholder.
19–27
The unresolved issue in relation to this first qualification is
whether a claimant seeking to enforce his or her contractual
rights against the company is confined to the remedy of damages
or whether and, if so, how far, injunctive relief is available to
enforce the earlier contract. In Baily v British Equitable
Insurance Co,102 the Court of Appeal granted a declaration that
to act on the altered article would be a breach of the plaintiff’s
contractual rights. More surprisingly, in British Murac Syndicate
Ltd v Alperton Rubber Co Ltd103 Sargant J went so far as to grant
an injunction to restrain an alteration of the articles which would
have contravened the plaintiff’s contractual rights. Although
Sargant J’s decision is generally regarded as based upon a
misunderstanding of the previous authorities, some sympathy
with this approach was expressed by Scott J in the Cumbria
Newspapers case,104 where he said that he could “see no reason
why [the company] should not, in a suitable case, be injuncted
from initiating the calling of a general meeting with a view to the
alteration of the articles”. To the extent that injunctive relief is
made available in this way not simply to restrain acting upon the
altered article but to restrain the operation of the machinery for
effecting the alteration itself, the notion that the company cannot
validly make a direct contract not to alter its articles becomes
hollow. Such an extension of injunctive relief would also
contradict the dictum of Lord Porter in Shirlaw105: “Nor can an
injunction be granted to prevent the adoption of the new
articles”. However, injunctive relief merely to prevent the
company acting upon the new articles would not fall foul of this
principle.
Binding only the shareholders
19–28
The second qualification is that an agreement among the
shareholders alone as to how they will exercise the voting rights
attached to their shares is not caught by the principle that a
company cannot contract out of its statutory powers to alter its
articles. This rule was applied to save the agreement in Russell,
the House of Lords benignly severing the company from the
agreement in question. Lord Jauncy said that “shareholders may
lawfully agree inter se to exercise their voting rights in a manner
which, if it were dictated by the articles, and were thereby
binding on the company, would be unlawful”.106 The claimant
was granted a declaration as to the validity of the agreement, and
it seems that their lordships would have been happy to grant an
injunction had the claimant objected substantively to the course
of action proposed by the company, as against wishing to
establish the principle that his consent to the change was
required.107 This conclusion flows from the more general
proposition that the vote attached to a share is a property right
which the shareholder is prima facie entitled to exercise and deal
with as he or she thinks fit.108 Since the company can act only
through its members to alter the articles, an agreement binding
all the members is as effective as one to which the company is
party as well.
However, in one respect a members’ agreement is less secure
than one which binds the company as well. On a subsequent
transfer of a shareholding covered by the agreement the new
shareholder will not be bound without his or her express
adherence to the agreement among the other shareholders.109
Nevertheless, the shareholders’ agreement does play an
important role in establishing the requirement for minority
shareholder consent to important changes in the company’s
financial or constitutional arrangements in situations such as
management buy-outs, venture capital investments and joint
ventures.110
Finally, a device analogous to the voting agreement should be
noted. Closely associated with, but more sophisticated than, the
voting agreement is the voting trust, not uncommon in the US
but less common in the UK. Under this, in effect, voting rights
are separated from the financial interest in the shares, the former
being held and exercisable by trustees while the latter remains
with the shareholders. Voting policy then becomes a matter for
the trustees, who may use their powers to protect minority
shareholders, though the voting trust may be driven by other
considerations, such as a desire to make a takeover bid more
difficult and thus protect the incumbent management.111
CONCLUSION
19–29
The mandatory protections for minority shareholders identified
in this chapter are rather patchy. They apply only to voting at
general meetings and not to majority control exercised via the
board and, even then, only to certain types of shareholder
decision. In the case of the requirements for shareholder voting,
the protection provided manages to be, at once, both limited and
uncertain in scope. It is perhaps not surprising that shareholders
have resorted to private means, and that the legislature has
attempted make more far-reaching protections available. The
development and current status of these alternative means are
considered in the next chapter.
1
See above, para.3–31.
2 See above, para.16–124.
3 See above, at para.14–18.
4
See above, at para.13–19.
5
Listing Rules 12.4.1–2.
6 Birch v Cropper (1889) 14 App. Cas. 525 HL; cf. art.71 of Model Articles for Public
Companies. The Model Articles for Private Companies Limited by Shares needs no
equivalent since art.21 requires all shares (other than those initially subscribed) to be
fully paid as to nominal value and any premium.
7 This provides a possible rationale for the exemption of dividends from the rules on
financial assistance, especially as creditors are also protected by the rule that dividends
are payable only out of profits. See above at para.13–45.
8
See above, Ch.17.
9 See above, para.16–121.
10 See Listing Rules 11.1 et seq. The closest the general law comes to requiring
shareholders’ approval of transactions with significant shareholders is where that
shareholder falls within the category of “shadow director” and thus is subject to the
statutory rules on self-dealing contained in Ch.4 of Pt 10 (above, paras 16–54 et seq.).
11For example, the US (see R. Clark, Corporate Law (Little Brown, 1986) pp.444 et
seq.
12
See below, para.29–24.
13See paras 28–41 and 28–75. The statute recognises the exit right only if the new
controller holds 90% of the voting rights after a takeover bid; the Code gives an exit
opportunity at the 30% level, no matter how the 30% has been acquired and so goes
much further than the statute.
14
The original source of this oft-repeated (but potentially misleading) expression seems
to be Lindley MR in Allen v Gold Reefs of West Africa [1900] 1 Ch. 671–2, and merits
full citation: “The power thus conferred on companies to alter their articles is limited
only by the provisions contained in the statute and the conditions contained in the
company’s memorandum of association. Wide, however, as the language of [the Act] is,
the power conferred by it must, like all other powers, be exercised subject to those
general principles of law and equity which are applicable to all powers conferred on
majorities enabling them to bind minorities. It must be exercised, not only in the manner
required by law, but also bona fide for the benefit of the company as a whole, and it
must not be exceeded. These conditions are always implied, and are seldom, if ever,
expressed”.
15
North-West Transportation Co v Beatty (1887) 12 App. Cas. 589 PC; Burland v Earle
[1902] A.C. 83 PC; Goodfellow v Nelson Line [1912] 2 Ch. 324.
16 Greenwell v Porter [1902] 1 Ch. 530; Puddephatt v Leith [1916] 1 Ch. 200—in which
a mandatory injunction was granted. Contrast the rules on directors’ fettering their
discretion: above, para.16–35.
17 NW Transportation Co v Beatty (1887) 12 App. Cas. 589 PC; Burland v Earle [1902]
A.C. 83 at 93 PC; Harris v A Harris Ltd (1936) S.C. 183 (Sc); Baird v Baird & Co, 1949
S.L.T. 368 (Sc). And see the remarkable case of Northern Counties Securities Ltd v
Jackson & Steeple Ltd [1974] 1 W.L.R. 1133 where it was held that, although to comply
with an undertaking given by the company to the court the directors were bound to
recommend the shareholders to vote for a resolution, they, as shareholders, could vote
against it, if so minded.
18 See, for example, s.239 excluding the interested director from voting on a resolution
to ratify his or her wrongdoing (above, para.16–119) or the Listing Rules provisions on
related-party transactions, discussed above.
19 Allen v Gold Reefs of West Africa Ltd [1900] 1 Ch. 656 CA. See fn.14, above, for the
full quotation.
20
Prudential Assurance Co Ltd v Newman Industries Ltd (No.2) [1981] Ch. 257; Smith
v Croft (No.3) [1987] B.C.L.C. 365, neither adopted with great vigour in subsequent
cases, although clearly influential.
21 See paras 16–121 et seq.
22 See West Mercia Safetywear Ltd v Dodd [1988] B.C.L.C. 250 CA; Aveling Barford v
Perion Ltd [1989] B.C.L.C. 626; Re DKG Contractors Ltd [1990] B.C.C. 903; Official
Receiver v Stern [2002] 1 B.C.L.C. 119 at 129. Also see, more recently, Madoff
Securities International Ltd v Raven [2013] EWHC 3147 (Comm) at [272]–[288]
(Popplewell J); Goldtrail Travel Ltd (In Liquidation) v Aydin [2014] EWHC 1587 (Ch)
at [113]–[118] (Rose J).
23Bamford v Bamford [1970] Ch. 212 CA. The directors had issued shares for improper
purposes. In a ratification by shareholders of this decision, it was conceded that the
holders of the newly issued shares could not vote.
24
Constable v Executive Connections Ltd [2005] 2 B.C.L.C. 638, the judge refusing to
dispose of an expropriation claim summarily.
25
Brown v British Abrasive Wheel Co [1919] 1 Ch. 290. For a stimulating analysis of
these cases see Hannigan, “Altering the Articles for Compulsory Transfer” [2007] J.B.L.
471.
26
Phillips v Manufacturers Securities Ltd (1917) 116 L.T. 209; in Borland’s Trustees v
Steel Bros [1901] 1 Ch. 279 an even wider article was inserted with the agreement of all
the members. Presumably too a compulsory transfer article could be introduced by
majority vote which would affect only shares acquired in the future.
27
Sidebottom v Kershaw, Leese & Co Ltd [1920] 1 Ch. 154 CA.
28
Dafen Tinplate Co v Llanelly Steel Co [1920] 2 Ch. 124.
29
Shuttleworth v Cox Bros Ltd [1927] 2 K.B. 9 CA.
30
The court conceded that if the resolution was such that no reasonable man could
consider it for the benefit of the company as a whole that might be a ground for finding
bad faith, [1927] 2 K.B. 9 at 18, 19, 23, 26 and 27. This exception was affirmed in Re
Charterhouse Capital [2015] EWCA Civ 536. Another, it is submitted, would be if the
majority was trying to acquire the shares of the minority at an obvious undervalue.
31
Dealt with in Ch.28 at paras 28–68 et seq., below.
32
Gambotto v WCP Ltd (1995) 182 C.L.R. 432.
33 Gambotto v WCP Ltd (1995) 182 C.L.R. 432 at 444.
34 Brown v British Abrasive Wheel Co [1919] 1 Ch. 290, 296, per Astbury J: “The
defendants contend that it is for the benefit of the company as a whole because in default
of further capital the company might have to go into liquidation. The plaintiff is willing
to risk that. The proposed alteration is not directly concerned with the provision of
further capital, nor does it insure that it will be provided. It is merely for the benefit of
the majority. If passed, the majority may acquire all the shares and provide further
capital. That would be for the benefit of the company as then constituted. But the
proposed alteration is not for the present benefit of this company”. It may be that the
decision can be put on the basis, as found by the judge, that the majority did not think
about the benefit to the company’s business at all, but only their own benefit, for
example, because financing was available on equivalent terms from those who did not
require complete control.
35See Citco Banking Corp NV v Pusser’s Ltd [2007] UKPC 13; [2007] 2 B.C.L.C. 483
PC.
36Re Charterhouse Capital Ltd [2015] EWCA Civ 536, especially at [90], [92], [96]–
[108] (Etherton C for the court).
37
Re Charterhouse Capital Ltd [2015] EWCA Civ 536, see especially [90].
38Greenhalgh v Arderne Cinemas Ltd [1951] Ch. 286 CA; and [1950] 2 All E.R. 1120
where the judgment of Evershed MR is reported more fully.
39 Peter’s American Delicacy Co Ltd v Heath (1939) 61 C.L.R. 457, 512 (Dixon J). Here
the amendment provided that shareholders should thenceforth receive dividends rateably
according to the amounts paid up on their shares rather than, as previously, according to
the number of shares (fully or partly paid) which they held. A fortiori the test is not
useful if the group in question is made up of a number of distinct sub-groups: Redwood
Master Fund Ltd v TD Bank Europe Ltd [2006] 1 B.C.L.C. 149, not an expropriation
case and involving a “class” of creditors rather than of shareholders, but applying the
same principles.
40
Citco Banking Corp NV v Pusser’s Ltd [2007] UKPC 13; [2007] 2 B.C.L.C. 483 PC.
41 Note the different approach in Rights & Issues Investment Trust Ltd v Stylo Shoes Ltd
[1965] Ch. 250, cited in Citco, although not followed in its detail. In Stylo, along with a
substantial increase in the issued ordinary share capital, the articles were amended to
double the number of votes attached to special management shares so as to maintain the
control of the existing management. In upholding the shareholders’ resolution,
Pennycuick J noted, at 255–256, that the rules on class rights needed to be followed, and
that here the resolution was effective because the management shares had not voted, and
yet nevertheless 92 per cent of the ordinary shareholders, being those with no personal
interests to gain in the matter, had voted in favour.
42 See also Completing, para.5.98.
43
There is some indirect support for this approach in English law in Citco Banking Corp
NV v Pusser’s Ltd [2007] UKPC 13; [2007] 2 B.C.L.C. 483 at [20] PC, where a
subjective approach was endorsed even in what came close to an expropriation case.
44
Brown v British Abrasive Wheel Co [1919] 1 Ch. 290.
45
And was criticised on precisely that basis in Shuttleworth and (perhaps) Citco.
46 Any number of cases might be cited. The rule does not depend on the identity of the
power-holder, and in particular does not depend on the power-holder being a fiduciary.
See as illustrative Eclairs Group Ltd v JKX Oil & Gas Plc [2015] UKSC 71 SC
(directors); Assénagon Asset Management SA v Irish Bank Resolution Corp Ltd
(formerly Anglo Irish Bank Corp Ltd) [2012] EWHC 2090 (Ch) (creditors); Burry &
Knight Ltd v Knight [2014] EWCA Civ 604 (shareholders).
47 Allen v Gold Reefs of West Africa [1900] 1 Ch. 671.
48See especially the earlier discussion of Re Charterhouse Capital Ltd [2015] EWCA
Civ 536. See also fn.46, above.
49
In particular, the test applied by the courts is not to look at the controlling director-
shareholder’s actual bona fides, nor even to assert that no reasonable director-
shareholder could have thought the decision to be bona fide in the interests of the
company (i.e. either an irrationality test, or an indication that he court was simply not
persuaded that bona fides were proven). Rather, it is, it seems, to apply a more objective
test, and to assume an improper motivation, or a use of the power for improper ends.
50 Although even here there are some constraints: the potential pay-back for
appointment of a board of directors intended to serve as the appointer’s puppet is
classification of the appointer as a shadow director.
51 Peters’ American Delicacy Co Ltd v Heath (1939) 61 C.L.R. 457, 512 (Dixon J).
52See paras 16–26 et seq. (directors); and Redwood Master Fund Ltd v TD Bank Europe
Ltd [2006] 1 B.C.L.C. 149; and Assénagon Asset Management SA v Irish Bank
Resolution Corp Ltd [2012] EWHC 2090 (Ch) (bondholders).
53 Re Holders Investment Trust [1971] 1 W.L.R. 583.
54 See below, para.29–11.
55
The Model Articles for private and public companies contain no variation of rights
procedure, so, in effect, the statute is the default model.
56 Both in relation to variation of rights and amendments to variation procedures,
variation includes abrogation: s.630(6). Class rights and variation procedures contained
in the memorandums of existing companies are treated as being contained in the articles:
s.28.
57
2006 Act s.630(3).
58
Discussed below at para.19–23.
59
This court review applies to all variation procedures, whether specified in the Act or
in the company’s articles: s.633(1).
60
See above, para.19–12.
61
Provided that they have not consented to or voted in favour of the resolution—an
unfortunately worded restriction which effectively rules out nominees who have not
exercised all their votes in one way.
62
This clearly includes representatives of other classes affected and of the company.
63
This is the same expression as that used in Pt 30 (see Ch.20, below), which would
seem to provide a better alternative remedy not demanding 15 per cent support and strict
time limits and with a wider range of orders that the court can make.
64
2006 Act s.633(5). The company must within 15 days after the making of an order
forward a copy to the Registrar: s.635.
65
2006 Act s.633(5).
66 This was certainly the intention of the Greene Committee on whose recommendation
the section was based: Cmnd. 2657, para.23. But the need for speedy finality seems no
greater than on an application under the general unfair prejudice provisions where there
is no such provision and cases can be taken to the House of Lords. But if the application
under s.633 is struck out on the ground that the time-limit was not complied with, that
can be taken to appeal and was in Re Suburban Stores Ltd [1943] Ch. 156 CA. See also
Re Sound City (Films) Ltd [1947] Ch. 169 which seems to be the only officially reported
case on the predecessors to s.633. Cases in which it might have been invoked (e.g.
Rights & Issues Investment Trust v Stylo Shoes Ltd [1965] Ch. 250) have been taken
instead under the unfair prejudice sections or earlier versions of those sections.
67 Greenhalgh v Arderne Cinemas [1946] 1 All E.R. 512 CA, where the result of the
subdivision was to deprive the holder of one class of his power to block a special
resolution.
68White v Bristol Aeroplane Co [1953] Ch. 65 CA; Re John Smith’s Tadcaster Brewery
Co [1953] Ch. 308 CA.
69 Dimbula Valley (Ceylon) Tea Co v Laurie [1961] Ch. 353. On the meaning of
“participation” in this context see para.23–7 and on bonus shares see para.11–18. And
see the startling decision in Re Mackenzie & Co Ltd [1916] 2 Ch. 450 which implies that
a rateable reduction of the nominal values of preference and ordinary capital (which
participated pari passu on a winding up) did not modify the rights of the preference
shareholders notwithstanding that the effect was to reduce the amount payable to them
by way of preference dividend while making no difference at all to the ordinary
shareholders.
70
Scottish Insurance Corp v Wilson & Clyde Coal Co [1949] A.C. 462 HL; Prudential
Assurance Co v Chatterly Whitfield Collieries [1949] A.C. 512 HL; Re Saltdean Estate
Co Ltd [1968] 1 W.L.R. 1844; House of Fraser v AGCE Investments Ltd [1987] A.C.
387 HL (Sc.); Re Hunting Plc [2005] 2 B.C.L.C. 211. But contrast Re Old Silkstone
Collieries Ltd [1954] Ch. 169 CA, where confirmation of the repayment was refused
because it would have deprived the preference shareholders of a contingent right to
apply for an adjustment of capital under the coal nationalisation legislation.
71
See the cases cited above, but contrast Re Schweppes Ltd [1914] 1 Ch. 322 CA,
which, however, concerned s.45 of the 1908 Act, which forbade “interference” with the
“preference or special privileges” of a class.
72
Hodge v James Howell & Co [1958] C.L.Y. 446 CA; The Times, 13 December 1958.
73
Re Northern Engineering Industries Plc [1994] 2 B.C.L.C. 704 CA.
74
White v Bristol Aeroplane Co [1953] Ch. 65 CA.
75 Re John Smith’s Tadcaster Brewery Co [1953] Ch. 308 CA.
76
Only his judgment in the latter case is fully reported: see [1952] 2 All E.R. 751.
77
The words are those of Greene MR in Greenhalgh v Arderne Cinemas [1946] 1 All
E.R. 512 at 518.
78
This definition does not solve all the problematic cases. Suppose the only difference
between the classes is a difference in par values (thought by the Court of Appeal in
Greenhalgh v Arderne Cinemas Ltd [1946] 1 All E.R. 512 CA, to be enough to create
separate classes); or suppose the par values are the same but some shares are fully paid-
up and others only partly. The statute provides that its definition is satisfied even if the
rights to dividends of shares in the 12 months after allotment are different from those of
other shares with otherwise similar rights—as they might be if additional shares were
issued part-way through a financial year.
79Cumbrian Newspapers Group Ltd v Cumberland and Westmoreland Newspaper and
Printing Co Ltd [1987] Ch. 1 at 15. Earlier editions of this book have argued for the
second view. For a full discussion see E. Ferran and L.C. Ho, Principles of Corporate
Finance Law, 2nd edn (Oxford: OUP, 2014), Ch.6.
80
Cumbrian Newspapers Group Ltd v Cumberland and Westmoreland Newspaper and
Printing Co Ltd [1987] Ch. 1 at 15.
81
It also had preference shares but nothing turned on that. Clearly an attempt to vary
their class rights would have been subject to the equivalent of s.630.
82
Cumbrian Newspapers Group Ltd v Cumberland and Westmoreland Newspaper and
Printing Co Ltd [1987] Ch. 1 at 15A–18A.
83
Cumbrian Newspapers Group Ltd v Cumberland and Westmoreland Newspaper and
Printing Co Ltd [1987] Ch. 1 at 15.
84 He instanced Eley v Positive Life Assurance Co (1875) 1 Ex.D. 20, on which see paras
3–16 and 3–23, above. It seems clear that in such a case the individual will have no
enforceable rights in the absence of an express contract with the company additional to
the articles.
85Cumbrian Newspapers Group Ltd v Cumberland and Westmoreland Newspaper and
Printing Co Ltd [1987] Ch. 1 at 16A–E.
86 i.e. Company B.
87Cumbrian Newspapers Group Ltd v Cumberland and Westmoreland Newspaper and
Printing Co Ltd [1987] Ch. 1 at 16G.
88
Cumbrian Newspapers Group Ltd v Cumberland and Westmoreland Newspaper and
Printing Co Ltd [1987] Ch. 1 at 16A–17A.
89 Cumbrian Newspapers Group Ltd v Cumberland and Westmoreland Newspaper and
Printing Co Ltd [1987] Ch. 1 at 17. He instanced as other examples, Bushell v Faith
[1970] A.C. 1099 (above, para.14–51); and Rayfield v Hands [1960] Ch. 1 (above,
para.3–24).
90
Cumbrian Newspapers Group Ltd v Cumberland and Westmoreland Newspaper and
Printing Co Ltd [1987] Ch. 1 at 18A–22B.
91
Cumbrian Newspapers Group Ltd v Cumberland and Westmoreland Newspaper and
Printing Co Ltd [1987] Ch. 1 at 22F–G. But he refrained from granting an injunction on
the ground that this would “prevent the company from discharging its statutory duties in
respect of the convening of meetings” (instancing s.368—though there had not in fact
been any requisition by its members under this section). The result was therefore that
Company A could hold the meeting if it wished but, if the resolution was passed, it
would nevertheless be ineffective in the light of the declaration unless Company B
consented.
92 See below, Ch.29.
93 See above, para.19–16.
94
See especially para.3–27 on “mere internal irregularities”.
95
As we have seen at para.15–53, the courts have been unwilling to undermine such
arrangements through use of their powers under s.306 of the Act.
96 See Bushell v Faith (above, para.14–51).
97
Russell v Northern Bank Development Corp Ltd [1992] 1 W.L.R. 588 HL. See Sealy,
[1992] C.L.J. 437; Davenport, (1993) 109 L.Q.R. 553; Riley, (1993) 44 N.I.L.Q. 34;
Ferran, [1994] C.L.J. 343.
98
Russell v Northern Bank Development Corp Ltd [1992] 1 W.L.R. 588 at 593.
99
In this case what was proposed was an increase in the company’s authorised capital
laid down in the memorandum. Whether the quoted principle applies to all powers
conferred on the company by the statute is unclear.
100
Southern Foundries (1926) Ltd v Shirlaw [1940] A.C. 701 HL.
101 Southern Foundries (1926) Ltd v Shirlaw [1940] A.C. 701 at 740–741.
102
Baily v British Equitable Insurance Co [1904] 1 Ch. 373 CA.
103British Murac Syndicate Ltd v Alperton Rubber Co Ltd [1915] 2 Ch. 186. The case
concerned the right of the plaintiff, under both the articles and a separate contract, to
appoint two directors to the board so long as he held 5,000 shares in the company.
Today, after the Cumbria Newspaper decision (see para.19–18, above) the claimant
might be protected as the holder of a class right.
104Cumbrian Newspapers Group Ltd v Cumberland and Westmoreland Newspaper and
Printing Co Ltd [1987] Ch. 1 at 24.
105 Southern Foundries (1926) Ltd v Shirlaw [1940] A.C. 701 HL.
106 Russell v Northern Bank Development Corp Ltd [1992] 1 W.L.R. 588 at 593.
107 Russell v Northern Bank Development Corp Ltd [1992] 1 W.L.R. 588 at 595.
108On the enforcement of shareholder agreement see Greenwell v Porter [1902] 1 Ch.
530; and Puddephatt v Leith [1916] 1 Ch. 200, where a mandatory injunction was
granted to compel a shareholder to vote in accordance with his agreement. Some
shareholder agreements may make their adherents “concert parties”, thus triggering
provisions which impose obligations on a member of the shareholder group because of
the size of the group interest. See paras 26–19, 28–44 and 28–54, below.
109
cf. Greenhalgh v Mallard [1943] 2 All E.R. 234 CA. Of course, the selling
shareholder may be contractually bound to secure the adherence of the acquiring
shareholder, but even so it is difficult to make the arrangement completely water-tight by
purely contractual means, especially at the remedial level.
110
See, for example, Growth Management Ltd v Mutafchiev [2007] 1 B.C.L.C. 645;
and, generally, K. Reece Thomas and C. Ryan, The Law and Practice of Shareholders’
Agreements, 4th edn (London: LexisNexis, 2014). If the power which it is sought to
control is one which is exercisable by the board of directors, it may in addition be
necessary to alter the articles so as to shift the power in question to the general meeting
or to provide for its exercise by the board only with the consent of the general meeting
or to provide that the shareholders shall take all appropriate action to prevent the
company taking the steps to which a shareholder, exercising its rights under the
agreement, objects.
111 An offeror, where a trust is in operation, may acquire the majority of the shares but
still not be able to dismiss the incumbent management. Such trusts are common in the
Netherlands. See Ch.28, below.
CHAPTER 20
UNFAIR PREJUDICE
Introduction 20–1
Scope of the Provisions 20–4
Independent Illegality and Legitimate Expectations or
Equitable Considerations 20–6
Informal arrangements among the members 20–7
The balance between dividends and directors’
remuneration 20–10
Other categories of unfair prejudice 20–12
Prejudice and Unfairness 20–13
Unfair Prejudice and the Derivative Action 20–14
Reducing Litigation Costs 20–18
Remedies 20–19
Winding Up on the Just and Equitable Ground 20–21
Conclusion 20–23
INTRODUCTION
20–1
The statutory unfair prejudice provisions are surprisingly wide-
ranging, especially viewed against the patchy protections
considered in the previous chapter. Section 994(1),1 the first of
the six sections which constitute Pt 30 of the Act, provides that
any member may petition the court for relief on the ground:
“(a) that the company’s affairs are being or have been conducted in a manner which
is unfairly prejudicial to the interests of members generally or some part of its
members (including at least himself), or (b) that an actual or proposed act or
omission of the company (including any act or omission on its behalf) is or would
be so prejudicial.”
20–16
Given the breadth of the courts’ discretion as set out in s.996, the
answer to the first question is surely yes. Despite initial caution,
there have been a number of cases at appeal court level in which
corporate remedies have been granted in an unfair prejudice
petition. In Anderson v Hogg74 the Inner House of the Court of
Session (Lord Prosser dissenting) awarded relief to the company,
where the unfair prejudice was based on an unlawful payment by
the respondent director of remuneration to himself. Without
detailed consideration of the point, the director was ordered to
return the money to the company. More important, perhaps, the
court came close to rejecting Millett J’s proposition in Re
Charnley Davies that proof of illegality on the part of the
director as against the company is not by itself enough to
demonstrate unfair prejudice to the petitioning shareholder.
Since that case involved in essence a two-person company which
was in course of solvent liquidation, the distinction between
illegality to the company and unfairness to the shareholder was
in that instance very fine. Clark v Cutland75 was a somewhat
similar case involving a petition about a two-person company
where the controlling director had made large and unauthorised
payments to himself, this time by way of contributions to his
pension fund. Although the decision was principally about other
matters, the Court of Appeal did order the unauthorised
payments to be restored to the company and indeed was prepared
to contemplate that, as in a derivative action,76 the costs of the
litigation should be borne by the company. However, this
decision may not be as dramatic as it seems, since the litigation
began as separate derivative and unfair prejudice cases, which
were later consolidated into the unfair prejudice application.77
Thus, at an early stage in the derivative action the then
applicable standing rules were presumably satisfied, so that
granting corporate relief in the unfair prejudice petition would
not be objectionable on the ground identified above.
In the corporate opportunity case, Bhullar v Bhullar,78 which
we considered in Ch.16 and which again concerned a two-person
—or, at least, a two-family company—the litigation was always
in the form of an unfair prejudice petition and, indeed, the
petitioners sought the traditional personal relief in such a
petition, namely, the compulsory purchase of their shares at a
fair price by the respondents. However, the initial petition also
sought permission to bring a derivative action in the company’s
name. The trial judge refused the compulsory purchase order but
ordered direct corporate relief by declaring the property in
question to be held on trust for the company. The Court of
Appeal did not demur from this way of proceeding. It may be
that in this case the court took the view that the facts upon which
a derivative suit would be based and the petitioner’s standing to
sue derivatively had been clearly established in the petition and
that it would be simply a waste of time and money to have a
further action commenced by writ, and so corporate relief was
granted immediately. However, it is notable that the Court of
Appeal did not think it necessary to address this issue.
The most extensive discussion of the principles at issue in this
area is to be found a decision of only persuasive authority, Kung
v Kou, a decision of the Court of Final Appeal of Hong Kong.79
Although petition in the case was ill-conceived and there were
some differences of emphasis in the judgments of Bokhary PJ
and Lord Scott of Foscote NPJ, the issue of whether an unfair
prejudice petition could be used to avoid the standing rules of
Foss v Harbottle was addressed head-on and answered in the
negative. This answer did not mean that allegations of breaches
of duty by directors are irrelevant in unfair prejudice
proceedings, for example, as a basis for making out a claim for
relief to be granted to the member. Nor did it mean that the court
can never at the end of an unfair prejudice petition hearing grant
a remedy in the company’s favour. However, in order to do that
the court would have to hear both the company’s claim and the
member’s claim together. This would be appropriate only in
“rare and exceptional” circumstances (per Bokhary PJ) or where
at the pleading stage of the petition it was clear that “the
director’s liability at law to the company can conveniently be
dealt with in the hearing of the petition” (per Lord Scott of
Foscote). Otherwise, the petitioner should seek an order in the
petition to bring a derivative action on behalf of the company or,
under the new Act, make such an application directly to the court
rather than through the unfair prejudice petition.
20–17
It is submitted that the decision in Kung v Kou is based on the
correct principles and that the unfair prejudice petition is
normally confined to relief in respect of harm personal to the
minority shareholder.
As to the second question, and whether personal remedies in
favour of the petitioner are subject to the “no reflective loss”
principle, the answer is less clear. The most common remedy in
s.994 cases is an order for the compulsory purchase of the
petitioner’s shares. The purchase price may indeed contain an
element which would otherwise constitute reflective loss, but
that is by way of delivering a clean break to the petitioner in
circumstances where it is the proven unfairly prejudicial conduct
which has reduced the value of the petitioner’s shares. The cases
are considered below.80
REDUCING LITIGATION COSTS
20–18
A major issue which has emerged under the unfair prejudice
jurisdiction is the length and, therefore, the cost of trials of these
petitions. Although the decision of the House of Lords in O’Neill
v Phillips81 has done something to reduce the scope of the issues
to be explored, the court may still find itself trawling through a
great deal of the history of the relations between petitioner and
respondent, to establish, first, the existence of any informal
understandings and, secondly, whether they have subsequently
been breached. All this will typically occur in relation to small
companies, whose net value may not be large. Both the Law
Commission and the CLR investigated a number of ways of
reducing the costs of unfair prejudice litigation, but all were
ultimately rejected as ineffective, either by the Commission or
the Review,82 except for a suggestion that an arbitration scheme
be developed as an alternative to litigation before the High
Court,83 plus reliance on the newly introduced general system of
case management in the civil courts for those cases not going
down the arbitral route.
However, the courts themselves have developed a technique
for encouraging an agreed solution to unfair prejudice claims.
Where it is clear, as it will normally be, that the relationship
between the petitioner and the remainder of the members cannot
be reconstituted by the court and that the only effective remedy
available to the minority is to have their shares purchased at a
fair price, then if a suitable ad hoc offer is made to the petitioner
for the purchase of the shares or there is a suitable mechanism to
this effect in the company’s articles, but the petitioner decides to
proceed with the petition, rather than to accept the offer or use
the mechanism, that will be seen to be an abuse of the process of
the court and the petition will be struck out. In O’Neill v
Phillips84 Lord Hoffmann was as keen to endorse and encourage
this procedure as he was to set out the basis of the unfair
prejudice claim itself. His lordship thought that a petitioner
could not be said to have been unfairly prejudiced by the
respondent’s conduct if:
(a) the offer was to buy the shares at a fair price, which normally
would be without a discount for their minority status (see
below);
(b) there was a mechanism for determination of the price by a
competent expert in the absence of agreement;
(c) to encourage agreement the expert should not give reasons
for the valuation;
(d) both sides should have equal access to information about the
company and equal freedom to make submissions to the
expert; and
(e) the respondent should be given a reasonable time at the
beginning of the proceedings to make the offer and should
not be liable for the petitioner’s legal costs incurred during
that period.
Cases where an offer from the respondent has not blocked a
petition have usually involved offers which did not give the
petitioner all he or she would get if successful at trial85 or have
involved valuation by a non-independent expert.86 The offer
which the court has to evaluate may be an ad hoc one or may
result from the application of provisions in the company’s
articles laying down a mechanism to be used where a
shareholder wishes to dispose of his or her holding. Although the
courts once took a different view, it does not now appear that an
offer arising out of the mechanism contained in the articles is to
be treated differently from an ad hoc offer, in terms of its effect
in excluding an unfair prejudice provision.87
REMEDIES
20–19
Section 996 gives the court a wide remedial discretion to “make
such order as it thinks fit for giving relief in respect of the
matters complained of”. In addition to this general grant, five
specific powers are given to the court by s.996(2), of which
undoubtedly the most commonly used is an order that the
petitioners’ shares be purchased by the controllers or the
company.88 The reason for the popularity of this remedy, with
both petitioners and courts, is readily explained. Unfair prejudice
jurisprudence is most firmly established in relation to quasi-
partnership companies. When business and, often, personal
relations between quasi-partners have broken down and are
incapable of reconstitution by a court, the only effective remedy
is the minority’s exit. A share purchase order gives the petitioner
an opportunity to exit from the company with the fair value of
his or her investment, a result which is usually impossible in the
absence of a court order, since often no potential purchasers of
the shares are available or, even if they were, the purchase price
a third party would be willing to pay would reflect, rather than
remedy, the harm inflicted on the seller by the unfairly
prejudicial conduct.89
The crucial question in this buy-out process is how the court is
to assess the fairness of the price to be paid for the shares. Two
important issues have emerged in the valuation process. The first
is whether the petitioner’s shareholding should be valued pro
rata to the total value of the company or whether its value should
be discounted on the basis that it is ex hypothesi a minority
holding and so does not carry with it control of the company. In
this context the notion of a “quasi-partnership” company has
become important. Although many unfair prejudice proceedings
concern such companies, the statutory provisions are not
confined to them. However, in relation to whether a minority
shareholding should be discounted, the courts have developed a
presumption that it should not in a quasi-partnership company,
whereas no such presumption applies for other categories of
company.
In Re Bird Precision Bellows Ltd90 it was established that the
principle was pro rata valuation where the company could be
characterised as a quasi-partnership. This is because, in a true
partnership, upon dissolution of the partnership the court orders
a sale of the partnership business as a going concern and divides
the proceeds among the partners according to their interests in
the former partnership.91 However, the normal principle in
company law of discounting a minority shareholding applies if
the company is not a partnership carried on in corporate form or
if the petitioner had bought the shareholding at a price which
reflected its minority status or it had devolved upon him or her
by operation of law.92 The concept of a quasi-partnership
involves more than simply the company having a small number
of members. The members must have set up their association on
the basis of mutual trust and confidence, expect to be involved in
the management of the company (though the existence of clearly
defined “sleeping partners” would not defeat this requirement),
and there must be some degree of lock-in of the members to the
company,93 although these are cumulative preconditions and the
presence of one or more of these factors may suffice.94
20–20
The second question is whether the valuation should be on the
basis that the company will continue as a going concern, or on a
liquidation or break-up basis, which would normally yield a
lower value for the company. The going concern basis will
normally be appropriate, but this will depend to some degree on
the facts of the case, as will the precise method to be adopted for
valuing the going concern.95
A further issue concerns timing. The value put on shares,
whether on a pro rata or a discounted basis, will often depend
crucially on when the value of the company is assessed. The
courts have given themselves the widest discretion to choose the
most appropriate date. The competing dates are usually a date
close to when the shares are to be purchased or the date when the
petition was presented. In Profinance Trust SA v Gladstone,96 the
Court of Appeal thought that the former had become the
presumptive valuation date, but that there were many
circumstances when an earlier date might be chosen, for
example, where the unfairly prejudicial conduct had deprived the
company of its business, where the company had reconstructed
its business or even that there had been a general fall in the
market since the presentation of the petition. In Re KR Hardy
Estates Ltd,97 however, the court held that on the particular facts
of that case, the date of the order was the most appropriate date
since it had the advantage of certainty and seemed to be the most
fair.
Although a buy-out of the minority is the most common
remedy, it is not always the most appropriate one, and s.996
gives the courts a wide range of other possible remedies. These
include compensation, to which it is not yet clear whether the
“no reflective loss” principle applies.98
WINDING UP ON THE JUST AND EQUITABLE GROUND
20–21
Legal protection for minority shareholders is now dominated by
the unfair prejudice remedy, but, despite its remedial flexibility,
the court cannot thereby order the winding-up of the company in
question. The Law Commission recommended that this power
should be added to the range of remedies available to the court
for the redress of unfair prejudice,99 but the CLR rejected this on
the ground that it was open to abuse for the reasons discussed
below.100 There is, instead, a separate procedure by which a
minority shareholder may seek to have the company wound up.
A company may be wound up compulsorily by the court on a
petition presented to it by a contributory101 if the court is of the
opinion that it is “just and equitable” to do so. This provision,
now contained in s.122(1)(g) of the Insolvency Act 1986, has a
long pedigree in the law relating to companies, and the power
can be traced back to the Joint Stock Companies Winding-up
Act 1848. The provision was influenced by (then uncodified)
partnership law and was originally used mainly in cases where
the company was deadlocked. In the course of the twentieth
century it has been moulded by the courts into a means of
subjecting small private companies to equitable principles
derived from partnership law when they were in reality
incorporated partnerships. The apotheosis of this use of the
section, the decision of the House of Lords in Ebrahimi v
Westbourne Galleries Ltd,102 was also highly influential in the
courts’ development of their powers under the predecessors of
s.994.
Despite its remarkable substantive development, the winding
up provision always suffered from a weakness at the remedial
level: if the company was prospering, presenting a “just and
equitable” petition was tantamount to killing the goose that
might lay the golden egg (although the threat of liquidation
might induce the parties to negotiate an alternative solution to
their dispute). So long as the oppression remedy was hobbled by
the restrictive wording and interpretation associated with s.210
of the Companies Act 1948, the winding-up petition was better
than nothing. But, with the introduction of the unfair prejudice
remedy, one might argue that the role of the winding-up remedy
should now be restricted.
A winding-up petition triggers s.127 of the Insolvency Act
1986, which requires the court’s consent for any disposition of
the company’s property after the petition is presented. This
ability to paralyse, or at least disrupt, the normal running of the
company’s business adds to the negotiating strength of the
petitioner, but is hardly legitimate if an unfair prejudice petition
could give him or her all that is warranted. Consequently, a
Practice Direction103 seeks to discourage the routine joining of
winding-up petitions to unfair prejudice claims, unless a
winding-up remedy is what is genuinely sought. The force
behind the Practice Direction is provided by s.125(2) of the
Insolvency Act 1986, to the effect that the court need not grant a
winding-up order if it is of the opinion that some alternative
remedy is available to the petitioners and that they have acted
unreasonably in not pursuing it.104 It would seem an appropriate
use of this power for the courts to insist that, where a more
flexible s.996 remedy is available, the petitioner should be
confined to it. That would be a natural consequence of the fact
that the statutory alternative to a winding-up order has finally
come of age.
20–22
On the other hand, there are situations where a winding up order
is the only option. This observation is sometimes taken as proof
that the grounds of unfairness upon which a company can be
wound up under s.122(1)(g) of the 1986 Act are wider than those
which will found an unfair prejudice remedy under s.994 of the
2006 Act. Certainly the grounds do not overlap completely, but
this in itself does not determine which has greater width. The
cases, it is suggested, roundly accord that accolade to the unfair
prejudice petitions. But the important point here is that there are
reported cases in which the court has denied a petition based on
unfair prejudice, because the conduct of the petitioner did not
merit it, but has granted a winding-up order on the grounds that
mutual confidence among the quasi-partners had broken
down,105 or that the substratum had failed.106 In other words, in
these cases the mere fact of breakdown or deadlock is sufficient
to ground a winding-up order, whereas an unfair prejudice
petition is seen as requiring some assessment of the comparative
blame-worthiness of petitioners and controllers. This simply
reinforces the legislative sense in providing two distinct options,
expressed in different terms and designed to deliver remedies in
different circumstances.107
CONCLUSION
20–23
Part 30 of the Act does not provide, and on no conceivable
interpretation could provide, a unilateral exit right for minority
shareholders, i.e. a right for minority shareholders at any time to
withdraw their capital from the company. Indeed, it might be
thought that such a right would be inconsistent with the nature of
shareholding in companies. The shareholder is locked into the
investment in the company unless he or she is able to find
someone else to purchase the shares and thus stand in the
shareholder’s shoes in relation to the company.108 Compulsory
purchase appears under Pt 30, not as a right for the minority, but
as a remedy—and not even a remedy the minority can insist
upon, though it is the most common—in respect of unfair
prejudice committed by the company’s controllers. Thus in Re
Phoenix Office Supplies Ltd109 the Court of Appeal refused a
shareholder’s petition to have his shares acquired at a non-
discounted value, even though he had been removed from his
directorship by the other two incorporators in breach of their
common understanding. The reason for the decision was that the
conduct of the others had been a response to the petitioner’s
unilateral decision to sever his relations with the company,
which could be seen as a prior and more fundamental breach of
the original understandings among the three people involved. Of
course, members may bargain for rights of unilateral exit to be
incorporated in the articles of particular companies110; but they
are rare, since a general right for minority shareholders to
withdraw their capital when they will would seem likely wholly
to undermine the financing function of shares.
Finally, there is some evidence that the unfair prejudice
remedy, whatever its imperfections, has successfully “crowded
out” alternative techniques of controlling the exercise of
majority power through board decisions. Thus, the Law
Commissions’ draft statement of directors’ statutory duties111
included a requirement that directors act fairly as between
shareholders, a duty reflected at least at first instance in the
current case law.112 The CLR’s initial draft statement contained
the same duty,113 but fairness between shareholders was later
reduced to one of the factors to be taken into account by the
directors when discharging their duty to promote the success of
the company for the benefit of its members.114 The explanation
given for this development was a desire to “make it clear that
fairness is a factor in achieving success for the members as a
whole, rather than an independent requirement which could
override commercial success”.115 It is difficult to believe that this
argument would have been accepted in the absence of Pt 30 as
an overriding instrument of minority protection.
1
The procedure for petitions is governed mainly by the Companies (Unfair Prejudice
Applications) Proceedings Rules 2009 (SI 2009/2469), but also by the Civil Procedure
Rules and the practice of the High Court, where not inconsistent with the 2009 Rules.
Section 994(1A), somewhat bizarrely, specifically states that the removal of an auditor
in certain circumstances falls within (a). The reasons for this provision are dealt with at
para.22–18. Such claims should generally be heard in public open court: Global Torch
Ltd v Apex Global Management Ltd [2013] EWCA Civ 819 CA.
2 Re Legal Costs Negotiators Ltd [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 171 CA; cf. Parkinson v
Eurofinance Group Ltd [2001] 1 B.C.L.C. 720—majority shareholder, removed from the
board, not able to use his shareholding to obtain redress in respect of a sale of the
company’s assets by the directors to a company controlled wholly by them, and so able
to use the unfair prejudice provisions.
3 On conduct of the parent as conduct of the subsidiary see Nicholas v Soundcraft
Electronics Ltd [1993] B.C.L.C. 360 CA; expanding upon the approach taken in Scottish
Co-operative Wholesale Society Ltd v Meyer [1959] A.C. 324 HL, by not confining the
principle to companies engaged in the same type of business. See also Re Dominion
International Group (No.2) [1996] 1 B.C.L.C. 634. On conduct of the subsidiary as
conduct of the parent see Rackind v Gross [2005] 1 W.L.R. 3505.
4
And, accordingly, members can agree to waive or vary those rights, or, as in Fulham
Football Club (1987) Ltd v Richards [2011] EWCA Civ 855; [2012] Ch. 333, have
disputes determined by arbitration instead.
5
An agreement to transfer is not enough; a proper instrument of transfer must have been
executed and delivered to the transferee: Re a Company (No.003160 of 1986) [1986]
B.C.L.C. 391; Re Quickdome Ltd [1988] B.C.L.C. 370. However, the fact that the
directors have refused to register the transfer does not deny the transferee standing: Re
McCarthy Surfacing Ltd [2006] EWHC 832 (Ch).
6 See Re a Company (No.007828 of 1985) [1986] 2 B.C.C. 98,951 at 98,954 (Harman J):
“In my view, transmission by operation of law means some act in the law by which the
legal estate passes even though there be some further act (such as registration) to be
done; and in my view the mere allegation that there arises a constructive trust cannot
possibly amount to a transmission by operation of law”.
7Exceptionally, in Re I Fit Global Ltd [2013] EWHC 2090 (Ch), the court held that a
person whose name was not entered in the company’s register as required under s.112
was a shareholder and could bring a petition. This was because during the trading of the
company, there had been wholly inadequate formal corporate documentation and
records.
8
Atlasview Ltd v Brightview Ltd [2004] 2 B.C.L.C. 191. Also, the conduct of which a
petitioner may complain embraces conduct occurring before the petitioner became a
member, even if that conduct is not continuing (though it must prejudice the petitioner),
so that the beneficial holder will be able to petition if the shares are transferred to him by
the nominee: Lloyd v Casey [2002] 1 B.C.L.C. 454.
9
See Ch.18, above. A petition under s.995 may be instead of, or in addition to, a petition
by the Secretary of State to have the company wound up under s.124A of the Insolvency
Act (see para.18–13, above), but it is notable that the Companies Act power does not
require the Secretary of State to be of the opinion that the public interest would be
furthered by the bringing of an unfair prejudice petition. The Secretary of State’s power
of petition also applies to any company capable of being wound up under the Insolvency
Act (including in some cases companies not incorporated in the UK), whilst the general
right to petition under s.994 applies only to companies incorporated under the
Companies Acts and statutory water companies: s.994(3) and (4).
10 The Insolvency Act provision is not considered in any detail in this chapter. For
administration in general, see para.32–43. An unfair prejudice challenge may also be
made to proposals adopted by way of a company voluntary arrangement (see s.6 of the
Insolvency Act 1986) but the court’s powers here are confined to setting aside the
proposals adopted at the creditors’ meeting and ordering meetings to consider revised
proposals.
11
See the lament of the Lord President (Cooper) in Scottish Insurance Corp v Wilsons &
Clyde Coal Co, 1948 S.C. 376.
12 See above, paras 3–23 et seq.
13
Re A Company [1983] Ch. 178, decided under s.210 of the 1948 Act. Section 210
referred to “oppression” rather than “unfair prejudice”, and was generally interpreted
very narrowly, hence the statutory amendments delivering the form we now have, first in
s.459 of the 1985 Act, and now s.994 of the 2006 Act.
14Re Lundie Bros [1965] 1 W.L.R. 1051; Ebrahimi v Westbourne Galleries Ltd [1973]
A.C. 360 HL.
15
Re A Company [1986] B.C.L.C. 376; Re Haden Bill Electrical Ltd [1995] 2 B.C.L.C.
280.
16
Under s.210 of the 1948 Act, the House of Lords had defined “oppression” as conduct
which was “burdensome, harsh and wrongful” (emphasis added): Scottish Co-operative
Wholesale Society Ltd v Meyer [1959] A.C. 324. This was the point which gave rise to
the notion that the oppression section was aimed only at providing better remedies for
existing wrongs. The Jenkins Committee recommended that the restriction, if it existed,
should be removed (Report of the Company Law Committee, Cmnd. 1749 (1962), paras
203–206), and the courts, from an early stage, interpreted the substitution of the words
“unfairly prejudicial” for “oppressive” as intended to achieve that result: see Hoffmann J
in Re A Company (No.8699 of 1985) [1986] B.C.L.C. 382 at 387. The courts had already
arrived at this position some years previously in the case of petitions to wind up the
company. See Ebrahimi v Westbourne Galleries Ltd [1973] A.C. 360 HL; below,
para.20–21.
17 Analysed in Ch.17, above.
18 See, for example, the law relating to unfair dismissal of employees by employers,
introduced in 1971 and now contained in the Employment Rights Act 1996.
19
“Legitimate expectations” was the phrase endorsed by the Court of Appeal in Re Saul
D Harrison & Sons Plc [1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 14 at 19, per Hoffmann LJ; but in O’Neill v
Phillips [1999] 1 W.L.R. 1092; [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 1 HL, the same judge led the House
of Lords to adopt the phrase “equitable considerations” for fear that the former phrase
carried connotations which were too wide.
20
Re Saul D Harrison & Sons Plc [1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 14 at 19.
21
Though the legitimate expectation often arises when the company is formed, it may
arise at a later date, for example, when the petitioner becomes a member: Tay Bok
Choon v Tahanson Sdn Bhd [1987] 1 W.L.R. 413 PC; Strahan v Wilcock [2006] 2
B.C.L.C. 555 CA. Equally, a legitimate expectation based on informal agreement among
all the members is most often recognised in a quasi-partnership company, but may arise
in any small company, whether the company is to be operated as an incorporated
partnership or not: Re Elgindata Ltd [1991] B.C.L.C. 959.
22Re Saul D Harrison [1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 14 at 18. This aspect of unfair prejudice is, of
course, not peculiar to small companies but applies across the full range of companies.
Hence, it is suggested, the importance of the question, discussed above at para.20–14,
whether s.994 provides corporate or only personal relief to the petitioner.
23
So that s.994 may qualify not only the formal articles, but also the statutory powers of
the majority under s.168. In this respect the s.994 decisions reinforce the decision of the
House of Lords in Bushell v Faith, above, para.14–51.
24 Re Saul D Harrison [1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 14 at 18.
25
Ebrahimi v Westbourne Galleries Ltd [1973] A.C. 360 at 379 HL.
26
See Re Saul D Harrison [1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 14 itself; but also Re Posgate and Denby
(Agencies) Ltd [1987] B.C.L.C. 8; Re A Company [1987] B.C.L.C. 562; Re A Company
(1988) 4 B.C.L.C. 80; Re Ringtower Holdings Plc (1989) 5 B.C.C. 82; Currie v
Cowdenbeath Football Club Ltd [1992] B.C.L.C. 1029; Re JE Cade & Sons Ltd [1992]
B.C.L.C. 213; Murray’s Judicial Factor v Thomas Murray & Sons (Ice Merchants) Ltd
[1993] B.C.L.C. 1437 at 1455; Khoshkhou v Cooper [2014] EWHC 1087.
27Re Coroin Ltd [2012] EWHC 2343 (Ch) at [636] (the point not disturbed on appeal,
[2013] EWCA Civ 781; [2013] 2 B.C.L.C. 583).
28
In Ebrahimi v Westbourne Galleries Ltd [1973] A.C. 360 HL.
29 In O’Neill v Phillips [1999] 1 W.L.R. 1092; [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 1 HL.
30Re Blue Arrow Plc [1987] B.C.L.C. 585; Re Tottenham Hotspur Plc [1994] 1
B.C.L.C. 655; Re Astec (BSR) Plc [1998] 2 B.C.L.C. 556.
31
O’Neill v Phillips [1999] 1 W.L.R. 1092; [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 1 HL.
32 O’Neill v Phillips [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 1 at 7e HL.
33 O’Neill v Phillips [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 1 at 10–11 HL. In Re Guidezone Ltd [2000] 2
B.C.L.C. 321 at 356 Jonathan Parker J took the equitable analogy a stage further by
requiring that non-contractual understandings be relied upon by the minority before they
could form the basis of an unfair prejudice petition.
34 O’Neill v Phillips [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 1 at 11b–d HL.
35
O’Neill v Phillips [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 1 at 9a HL.
36
Shareholders’ Remedies, Cm. 3769 (1997), para.4.11. An example might be
mismanagement of the company not amounting to a breach of directors’ duties (see Re
Elgindata [1991] B.C.L.C. 959; but cf. Re Macro (Ipswich) Ltd [1994] 2 B.C.L.C. 354);
but with the rise in the standard of care required of directors (above, para.16–16) it may
be that this is a declining problem, because such cases will fall within the category of
“indirect” wrongs (below, para.20–14).
37
O’Neill v Phillips [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 1 at 8g–h HL.
38
Final Report I, para.7.41; Completing, paras 5.77–5.79.
39
Ebrahimi’s case [1973] A.C. 360 HL.
40
Ebrahimi’s case [1973] A.C. 360 at 379. This was a winding-up case, but, as we shall
see below at para.20–21, similar considerations apply there too and the winding-up case-
law has strongly influenced the development of this category of unfair prejudice.
41
Re Saul D Harrison [1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 14 at 18.
42
Re JE Cade and Son Ltd [1992] B.C.L.C. 213.
43 Irvine v Irvine (No.1) [2007] 1 B.C.L.C. 349, 421.
44 Re McCarthy Surfacing [2008] EWHC 2279 (Ch); [2009] B.C.L.C. 622; Re J&S
Insurance & Financial Consultants Ltd [2014] EWHC 2206 (Ch).
45
Irvine v Irvine (No.1) [2007] 1 B.C.L.C. 349, 421; Re McCarthy Surfacing [2008]
EWHC 2279 (Ch); [2009] B.C.L.C. 622; Sikorski v Sikorski [2012] EWHC 1613 (Ch).
46 Re Sam Weller & Sons Ltd [1990] B.C.L.C. 80.
47
Irvine v Irvine (No.1) [2007] 1 B.C.L.C. 349; Re Ravenhart Services (Holdings) Ltd
[2004] 2 B.C.L.C. 375.
48Irvine v Irvine (No.1) [2007] 1 B.C.L.C. 349, 420. Guidance can be taken from
guidelines on the remuneration of directors in listed companies: Re Tobian Properties
[2012] EWCA Civ 998 at [36].
49
This is not to deny that the degree of proof which the court requires of the informal
arrangement may vary according to whether the alleged arrangement is usual or unusual
in the type of company in question.
50Re A Company [1986] B.C.L.C. 382. See also Re St Piran Ltd [1981] 1 W.L.R. 1300;
but cf. Re Astec (BSR) Plc [1998] 2 B.C.L.C. 556 at 579. Also see Re Phoenix Contracts
(Leicester) Ltd [2010] EWHC 2375 (Ch).
51 See below, para.28–15. The Code was used only as a guide. In particular, the judge
borrowed from the Code the proposition that any advice given by the directors should be
given in the interests of the shareholders, but he did not borrow the further proposition
that the directors were obliged to give the shareholders their view on the bid.
52 McGuinness v Bremner Plc [1988] B.C.L.C. 673. See also Bermuda Cablevision Ltd v
Colica Trust Co Ltd [1998] A.C. 198 PC (analogy with the criminal law, though the
directors were acting, presumably, in breach of fiduciary duty). However, the courts
have not in general been prepared to use the unfair prejudice petition as a way of curing
defects in the statutory protections conferred upon minorities: see CAS (Nominees) Ltd v
Nottingham Forest FC Plc [2002] 1 B.C.L.C. 613 (avoidance of minority power to block
share issue—see below, para.24–4); and Rock Nominees Ltd v RCO (Holdings) Plc
[2004] 1 B.C.L.C. 439 CA (avoidance of minority’s power to reject a “squeeze out”
after a takeover—see below, para.28–69).
53
Re Sam Weller Ltd [1990] Ch. 682, where the judge refused to strike out the claim.
The case was largely concerned with the now irrelevant issue of whether the dividend
policy affected all the shareholders equally: cf. Re A Company Ex p. Glossop [1988] 1
W.L.R. 1068. Where the decisions on policy are in breach of the general law, see
para.20–10, above, and Re McCarthy Surfacing Ltd [2008] EWHC 2279 (Ch); [2009]
B.C.L.C. 622.
54
Re A Company (No.004415 of 1996) [1997] 1 B.C.L.C. 479.
55
Guinness Peat Group Plc v British Land Co Plc [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 243 CA—
exclusion of petitioner from an interest in a company where the shareholder’s equity was
negative. However, the case was mainly concerned with the inappropriateness of making
such a determination at the strike-out stage of litigation where the experts on each side
were in sharp disagreement as to the applicable valuation methodology.
56
Some guidance on the broad meaning of “prejudice”, and its possible financial and
non-financial aspects, is usefully discussed in the judgment of David Richards J in Re
Coroin Ltd [2012] EWHC 2343 (Ch) at [630]–[631] (affirmed on appeal, [2013] EWCA
Civ 781).
57 Re A Company [1983] Ch. 178; as explained in Re A Company [1986] B.C.L.C. 382
at 387; Re Guidezone Ltd [2002] 2 B.C.L.C. 321; Re J&S Insurance & Financial
Consultants [2014] EWHC 2206 (Ch).
58Grace v Biagioli [2006] 2 B.C.L.C. 70 CA; following Re London School of
Electronics [1986] Ch. 211. Also see Re Home & Office Fire Extinguishers Ltd [2012]
EWHC 917.
59Jesner v Jarrad Properties Ltd [1993] B.C.L.C. 1032 Inner House; but note the
qualifications in Re J&S Insurance & Financial Consultants [2014] EWHC 2206 (Ch).
60 Re RA Noble & Sons (Clothing) Ltd [1983] B.C.L.C. 273.
61
Bovey Hotel Ventures Ltd, Re unreported, but this view is set out and approved in
[1983] B.C.L.C. 290; Re Saul D. Harrison & Sons Plc [1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 14 at 17.
62 A point to which the courts have attached some importance. See above, para.20–6.
63The argument was accepted by Vinelott J in Re Carrington Viyella Plc (1983) 1
B.C.C. 98, 951, though the exact scope of the point was never finally settled.
64
“Direct wrongs”, i.e. where the harm is inflicted directly on the minority and not via a
diminution in the value of their stake in the company.
65 Report of the Company Law Committee, Cmnd. 1749 (1962), para.206.
66 Re Stewarts (Brixton) Ltd [1985] B.C.L.C. 4; Re London School of Electronics [1986]
Ch. 211; Re Cumana Ltd [1986] B.C.L.C. 430 (all involving various forms of diversion
of the company’s business to rival companies in which the majority were interested, i.e.
situations of the type found in Cook v Deeks [1916] 1 A.C. 553 PC, above, at para.16–
124); Re A Company Ex p. Glossop [1988] 1 W.L.R. 1068; and McCarthy Surfacing Ltd
[2009] B.C.L.C. 622 (both involving exercise of directors’ powers for an improper
purpose); Re Saul D. Harrison & Sons Plc [1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 14 (failure of directors to
act bona fide in the interests of the company). In not all these cases was the allegation in
question made out on the facts. Indeed, so long as the “independent illegality” theory
held sway, proving breaches of directors’ duties was a way of bringing the controllers’
conduct within the unfair prejudice provisions.
67
Re A Company (No.5287 of 1985) [1986] 1 W.L.R. 281; Re Stewarts (Brixton) Ltd
[1985] B.C.L.C. 4; Lowe v Fahey [1996] 1 B.C.L.C. 262.
68
Re Saul D Harrison & Sons Plc [1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 14 at 18.
69
Note that Pt 11 of the Act makes it clear that derivative actions can be brought only
under its provisions or “in pursuance of an order of the court in proceedings under
section 994”: s.260(2). The provision for Scotland is in s.265(6)(b).
70
Re Charnley Davies Ltd (No.2) [1990] B.C.L.C. 760.
71
This is, of course, a remedy very commonly sought by s.994 petitioners (see below,
para.20–19).
72 See above.
73
See Atlasview Ltd v Brightview Ltd [2004] 2 B.C.L.C. 191, para.20–20, below, and
the discussion of reflective loss at paras 17–34, above.
74
Anderson v Hogg, 2002 S.L.T. 354, Inner House.
75
Clark v Cutland [2004] 1 W.L.R. 783 CA (considered by Payne, (2004) 67 M.L.R.
500 and [2005] C.L.J. 647).
76 See above at para.17–13.
77 Clark v Cutland [2004] 1 W.L.R. 783 at [2] CA.
78
Bhullar v Bhullar [2004] 2 B.C.L.C. 241. The early stages of the litigation are
recounted at [3]–[4]. See above at paras 16–95 et seq.
79 Kung v Kou (2004) 7 HKCFAR 579. The decision was mentioned by the Privy
Council in the case of Gamlestaden Fastigheter AB v Baltic Partners Ltd [2007] B.C.C.
272 PC, where the judgment of the PC, delivered by Lord Scott of Foscote, makes no
reference to the restrictive conditions set out in the Hong Kong decision and seems to
treat it as a general permission to award damages to the company. Even stranger, the
company being hopelessly insolvent, the benefit to the petitioner from any payment by
the directors to the company would be obtained only as lender to the company, whose
loans would achieve a higher percentage recovery.
80See below, para.20–19, and the discussion of reflective loss, above, at paras 17–34 et
seq.
81
O’Neill v Phillips [1999] 1 W.L.R. 1092 HL.
82 These were (a) a new unfair prejudice remedy for those excluded from the
management of small companies (rejected by the Law Commission, Shareholders’
Remedies, Cm. 3769 (1997), at para.3.25, as likely to lead to “duplication and
complication of shareholder proceedings”; (b) a presumption of unfairness in certain
cases of exclusion from management (recommended by the Commission but rejected by
the CLR after the proposal received little support from consultees: Developing,
para.4.104); (c) the development of a model exit article (recommended by the Law
Commission, above, Pt V, but rejected by the CLR, Developing, para.4.103, on the
grounds that it was not likely to be used by the well-advised and would be a trap for the
ill-advised).
83 Final Report I, para.2.27 (this proposal was not confined to unfair prejudice petitions).
84See above, fn.81 at pp.16–17. This approach was applied to the winding-up remedy
(below, para.20–21) in CVC/Opportunity Equity Partners Ltd v Demarco Almeida
[2002] B.C.C. 684 PC.
85
North Holdings Ltd v Southern Tropics Ltd [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 624 CA; Harbourne
Road Nominees Ltd v Kafvaski [2011] EWHC 2214 (Ch).
86
Re Benfield Greig Group Plc [2002] 1 B.C.L.C. 65 CA, where, in fact, the non-
independence of the expert constituted the alleged unfair prejudice.
87
On the original approach see Re A Company Ex p. Kremer [1989] B.C.L.C. 365; and
on the later developments Virdi v Abbey Leisure Ltd [1990] B.C.L.C. 342; Re A
Company Ex p. Holden [1991] B.C.L.C. 597; Re A Company [1996] 2 B.C.L.C. 192.
88
2006 Act s.996(2)(e). In the latter case the company’s share capital must be reduced.
The statutory power is widely enough drawn to include an order that the minority
purchase the majority’s shares, which has occasionally been ordered: Re Brenfield
Squash Racquets Club Ltd [1996] 2 B.C.L.C. 184. The other specific powers are the
authorisation of proceedings to be brought in the company’s name (s.996(2)(c) and
above, para.20–14); requiring the company to do or refrain from doing an act (s.996(2)
(b)); requiring the company not to make alterations to its articles of association without
the leave of the court (s.996(2)(d)); and regulating the conduct of the company’s affairs
in the future (s.996(2)(a)). Whatever remedy is contemplated, the court must choose
what is appropriate at the time it is granted: Re A Company [1992] B.C.C. 542. Indeed,
the court is not limited to ordering the remedy requested by the petitioner: Hawkes v
Cuddy (No.2) [2009] EWCA Civ 291; [2009] 2 B.C.L.C. 427 (although in this case, and
as is specified now in the Companies (Unfair Prejudice Applications) Proceedings Rules
(SI 2009/2469), the petitioner specifically requested particular remedies or “that such
other order may be made as the court thinks fit”). Sections 757 and 758 give the court a
further specific power in the case where the unfair prejudice consists of a public offer of
shares by a private company: see para.24–2.
89
See Grace v Biagioli [2006] 2 B.C.L.C. 70 CA, for a good example of the court’s
preference for a “clean break” via a share purchase as against a compensation order,
which might have remedied the specific harm suffered by the petitioner but would have
left him exposed in the future.
90
Re Bird Precision Bellows Ltd [1984] Ch. 419, per Nourse J, approved on appeal
[1986] Ch. 658.
91 CVC/Opportunity Equity Partners Ltd v Demarco Almeida [2002] 2 B.C.L.C. 108 at
[41]–[42]; Strahan v Wilcock [2006] 2 B.C.L.C. 555. The court might instead work out
what the former partner’s interest would be worth upon the hypothesis of a sale, without
actually holding one.
92 Irvine v Irvine (No.2) [2007] 1 B.C.L.C. 445; Re Elgindata Ltd [1991] B.C.L.C. 959
at 1007. See also Re DR Chemicals (1989) 5 B.C.C. 37.
93 These criteria are taken from Ebrahimi v Westbourne Galleries Ltd [1973] A.C. 360,
371 (a winding-up case considered further below, para.20–21) and applied by the Court
of Appeal to unfair prejudice valuations in Strahan v Wilcock [2006] 2 B.C.L.C. 555.
What was initially a quasi-partnership may have ceased to be one by the time the facts
supporting the petition take place, thus changing the basis of valuation: Re McCarthy
Surfacing Ltd [2008] EWHC 2279 (Ch); [2009] B.C.L.C. 622.
94 Khoshkhou v Cooper [2014] EWHC 1087 (Ch) at [25], where a company with no
restriction on the transfer of shares was nevertheless held to be a quasi-partnership
company since it was closely dependent on the personal relationship between the
original members.
95
CVC/Opportunity Equity Partners Ltd v Demarco Almeida [2002] 2 B.C.L.C. 108;
Parkinson v Eurofinance Group Ltd [2001] 1 B.C.L.C. 720; Guinness Peat Group Plc v
British Land Co Plc [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 243 CA; Re Planet Organic Ltd [2000] 1
B.C.L.C. 366. See also Re Annacott Holdings Ltd [2013] EWCA Civ 119 CA, where it
was held that there is no rule that a going-concern valuation can only be adopted for
quasi-partnerships.
96
Profinance Trust SA v Gladstone [2002] 1 B.C.L.C. 141 CA, where the earlier
authorities are reviewed. Also see Re McCarthy Surfacing Ltd [2008] EWHC 2279 (Ch);
[2009] B.C.L.C. 622, for a valuation taking into account the depreciation due to the
wrongs complained of.
97
Re KR Hardy Estates Ltd [2014] EWHC 4001 (Ch) at [89]–[93].
98
Atlasview Ltd v Brightview Ltd [2004] 2 B.C.L.C. 191. This case, rightly it seems,
suggests that proper quantification of remedies would be alert to double recovery. If so,
the principle underpinning the rules on reflective loss would be upheld. This principle is
discussed above at para.17–34.
99
Shareholders’ Remedies, Cm. 3769 (1997), paras 4.24–4.49.
100
Developing, para.4.105.
101 2006 Act s.124(1). Petitions may also be brought by creditors, directors or the
company itself, though such applications are rare. The Secretary of State may petition
under s.124A in the public interest on the basis of information received as a result of an
investigation into the company’s affairs. See above, para.18–13. However, public
interest grounds for a winding-up are not available other than to the Secretary of State:
Re Millennium Advanced Technology Ltd [2004] 2 B.C.L.C. 77. The term “contributory”
includes even a fully paid-up shareholder provided he or she has a tangible interest in the
winding-up, which is usually demonstrated by showing that the company has a surplus
of assets over liabilities, though that will not be required if the petitioner’s complaint is
that the controllers failed to provide the financial information from which that
assessment could be made: see Re Rica Gold Washing Co (1879) 11 Ch. D. 36; Re
Bellador Silk Ltd [1965] 1 All E.R. 667; Re Othery Construction Ltd [1966] 1 W.L.R.
69; Re Expanded Plugs Ltd [1966] 1 W.L.R. 514; Re Chesterfield Catering Ltd [1977]
Ch. 373 at 380; Re Land and Property Trust Co Plc [1991] B.C.C. 446 at 448; Re
Newman & Howard Ltd [1962] Ch. 257; Re Wessex Computer Stationers Ltd [1992]
B.C.L.C. 366; Re A Company [1995] B.C.C. 705. The Jenkins Committee recommended
(para.503(h)) that any member should be entitled to petition, presumably on the grounds
that this remedy was aimed primarily at protecting minorities rather than at winding up
companies.
102
Ebrahimi v Westbourne Galleries Ltd [1973] A.C. 360 HL.
103 CPR Practice Direction, Applications under the Companies Act and Other
Legislation Relating to Companies, para.9(1). See Re A Company (No.004415 of 1996)
[1997] 1 B.C.L.C. 479 where the judge struck out the alternative petition for winding up
on the just and equitable ground on the basis that there was no reasonable prospect that
the trial judge would order a winding up as against a share purchase under what is now
s.996.
104
The alternative remedy need not be a legal one. For example, it may be an offer to
purchase the petitioner’s shares on the same basis as the court would order on an unfair
prejudice petition: Virdi v Abbey Leisure Ltd [1990] B.C.L.C. 342. See also Maresca v
Brookfield Development & Construction Ltd [2013] EWHC 3151 (Ch), where the
alternative remedy was for the shareholder to demand repayment of her interest from the
company.
105
Re RA Noble & Sons (Clothing) Ltd [1983] B.C.L.C. 273; and Jesner v Jarrad
Properties Ltd [1993] B.C.L.C. 1032 Inner House; Loch v John Blackwood Ltd [1924]
A.C. 783 PC; and Re Brand & Harding Ltd [2014] EWHC 247 (Ch). See also Re Full
Cup International Trading Ltd [1995] B.C.C. 682, where the judge found himself in the
presumably unusual position of being unable to fashion an appropriate remedy under
s.996 but of being prepared to wind up the company.
106
Re Kitson & Co Ltd [1946] 1 All E.R. 435 CA.
107
Hawkes v Cuddy (No.2) [2009] EWCA Civ 291; [2009] 2 B.C.L.C. 427 CA;
overruling on this point, Re Guidezone Ltd [2000] 2 B.C.L.C. 321 at 357.
108
Of course, if the company and the shareholder wish expressly to bargain for
“redeemable” shares, they are free to do so (above, para.13–2).
109
Re Phoenix Office Supplies Ltd [2003] 1 B.C.L.C. 76 CA.
110
See above, para.19–23.
111Company Directors: Regulating Conflicts of Interest and Formulating a Statement of
Duties, Cm. 4436 (1999), Appendix A.
112
See especially Mutual Life Insurance Co of New York v Rank Organisation Ltd
[1985] B.C.L.C. 11.
113 Developing, para.3.40.
114Final Report I, Annex C, Sch.2. On the nature of the general duty see para.16–37,
above.
115 Final Report I, Annex C, Explanatory Notes, para.18.
PART 5
Introduction 21–1
Scope and rationale of the annual reporting
requirement 21–1
The classification of companies for the purposes of
annual reporting 21–2
The Annual Accounts 21–7
Accounting records 21–7
The financial year 21–8
Individual accounts and group accounts 21–9
Parent and subsidiary undertakings 21–10
Form and content of annual accounts 21–13
Narrative Reporting 21–22
Directors’ report 21–23
The strategic report 21–24
Verification of narrative reports 21–26
Approval of the Accounts and Reports by the Directors 21–29
The Auditor’s Report 21–30
Revision of Defective Accounts and Reports 21–31
Filing Accounts and Reports with the Registrar 21–33
Speed of filing 21–34
Modifications of the full filing requirements 21–35
Other information available from the Registrar 21–37
Other forms of publicity for the accounts and reports 21–39
Consideration of the Accounts and Reports by the Members 21–40
Circulation to the members 21–40
Laying the accounts and reports before the members 21–42
Conclusion 21–43
INTRODUCTION
Scope and rationale of the annual reporting
requirement
21–1
On the basis that “forewarned is forearmed” the fundamental
principle underlying the Companies Acts has always been that of
disclosure. If the public and the members were enabled to find
out all relevant information about the company, this, thought the
founding fathers of our company law, would be a sure shield.
The shield may not have proved quite so strong as they had
expected and in more recent times it has been supported by
offensive weapons. However, disclosure still remains the basic
safeguard on which the Companies Acts pin their faith, and
every succeeding Act since 1862 has added to the extent of the
publicity required, although, not unreasonably, what is required
varies according to the type of company concerned. Not only
may disclosure by itself promote efficient conduct of the
company’s business, because the company’s controllers
(whether directors or large shareholders) may fear the
reputational losses associated with the revelation of
incompetence or self-dealing, but the more interventionist legal
strategies, going beyond disclosure, depend upon those who hold
the legal rights being well-informed about the company’s
position. For example, those in a position to enforce the
company’s rights against directors for breach of duty1 or to bring
claims of unfair prejudice2 or shareholders holding rights to
remove directors,3 if rational persons, will not turn their minds to
the exercise of those rights unless they think there are grounds
for so doing. Finally, self-help, such as taking contractual
protection or altering the pricing of credit, depends upon good
knowledge of risks embedded in the company’s operations.
Thus, disclosure is the bed-rock of company law.
This chapter is focused on what has always been the central
disclosure mechanism of the British companies legislation,
namely, the obligation laid on the directors to produce annual
accounts (referred to in EU law as annual financial statements)
relating to the financial position of the company and to
accompany those accounts with a report on the company’s
activities, including their own stewardship of the company.
Those accounts and reports are then typically considered by the
shareholders at an annual general meeting of the company,
though, as we have seen, only public companies are now
required to hold an AGM.4 Over the years, what is required of
large companies by way of accounts and reports has expanded.
By contrast, the recent tendency has been to reduce the reporting
requirements of small companies.
The production of the annual accounts has generated an
industry of professionals to help the company meet its statutory
obligations. Notably, the accounting profession has played a
major role in developing the standards which determine how the
raw financial data is to be analysed and presented in the
accounts, the law having rightly shied away from doing more
than setting the broad parameters for this task.5 That profession
then re-appears in the guise of auditors to verify that the
accounts do meet those standards and the applicable legal rules
and, in particular, present a “true and fair view” of the
company’s financial position.6
This is an area where the harmonisation programme of the EU
has had a significant impact. This is hardly surprising since the
utility of accounts is enhanced if they are comparable across
companies and increasingly investors (shareholders and
creditors) and others are interested in the financial position of
non-domestic companies. The first EU rules related to the
presentation of accounts,7 and were extended later to the use of
accounting standards8 and to the provision of non-financial
information.9 In 2013 the core provisions were modernised and
consolidated into Directive 2013/34/EU.10 References to the
“Directive” in this chapter are to the 2013 Directive as
amended11 (unless the context indicates otherwise). Since the
leading EU instrument in this area is a Directive (rather than a
Regulation), it needs to be transposed into domestic law. This is
done partly by amendments to the Companies Act 2006 and, to a
significant extent, by secondary legislation. Both the Act and the
secondary legislation were recently amended by the Companies,
Partnerships and Groups (Accounts and Reports) Regulations
2015/980, in order to implement the 2013 Directive.
The classification of companies for the purposes of
annual reporting
21–2
As we have hinted, the accounting rules have developed a
classification of companies which is more sophisticated than the
core division deployed in the Act between public and private
companies. That distinction turns on whether the company is
permitted to offer its shares to the public or not.12 The
accounting classification turns mainly on the economic size of
the company. However, the public/private distinction still plays a
role because public companies are excluded from the two
smallest categories of company (micro and small) for (most)
accounts purposes.13 Since the ramifications of the classification
run throughout the substantive rules on accounts, it is important
to set it out at the beginning. The criteria upon which the
classification is based are set out principally in the Directive and
the Member States have only limited freedom to amend them.
There are five categories of company for accounts purposes:
micro, small,14 medium-sized, large and “public interest entities”
(“PIE”). The criteria for identifying the first four categories are
quantitative indicators of the economic size of the company and
are designed to be capable of application in a fairly mechanistic
way. The PIE category is a cross-cutting category but, for the
general run of companies in the UK, it will form a sub-set of the
large company category. The criteria used refer to the company’s
“balance sheet total”, a perhaps not entirely clear phrase which
refers to amount of the company’s assets (without subtracting
liabilities)15; its net turnover16; and the number of persons
employed by it on average over the year.17 In order to classified
as micro, small or medium-size the company has to meet two of
the three applicable criteria; the “large” category is a residual
one into which companies otherwise fall; and the PIE
classification turns on a different approach.
Micro companies
21–3
Micro companies are private companies18 for which the balance
sheet maximum is £316,000; the maximum net turnover
£632,000 and the maximum number of employees is 10.19
However, a micro company will not have access to the reporting
relaxations if it is a member of a corporate group,20 presumably
because those relaxations might undermine the group accounts.
In short, the micro exemptions are available to stand alone
companies only, which reinforces their focus on very small
businesses.
Companies on the borderline of the criteria might find
themselves drifting in and out of qualification as micro
companies. This problem is addressed, as it is with the other
categories, by requiring that companies meet the criteria for two
years in order to qualify as micro and equally by providing that
micro status will not be lost unless the criteria are not met for
two consecutive years.21 As is to be expected, the micro
company benefits from the least demanding reporting regime.
The category was the result of an EU level initiative in 2012.22 It
operates by giving Member States the option to remove from
micro companies requirements that would otherwise apply to
them under the regime for small companies. The UK chose to
take up most of the options made available in the Directive.23 Of
course, the directors of micro companies may choose to report
more fully.
Small companies
21–4
The criteria for small companies are also set out in the Directive,
but, unlike with micro companies, Member States may increase
the monetary criteria by up to 50 per cent. The UK chose to take
advantage of this flexibility (i.e. to include more companies in
the small category). The resulting numbers are: £5.1 million for
balance sheet; £10.2 million for turnover; and 50 employees (this
last being a number fixed in the Directive).24 A company which
qualifies as small can normally benefit from the “small
companies regime” for the accounts and reports, which is less
stringent than that for larger companies. Moreover, having
qualified in a particular year, the company retains its status as
“small” unless it fails to meet the criteria for two successive
years.25 Some 3 million of the approximately 3.5 million
companies in the UK fall within either the “small” or “micro”
categories, so that in numerical terms the relaxations for small
companies are very important and the full accounting regime is
of concern only to the numerical minority of companies.26
A company which meets the numerical criteria nevertheless
cannot count as a small company if it is a public company or
carries on insurance, banking or fund management activities or is
a member of a group which contains an “ineligible” member.27
The thought here appears to be that such companies (or groups
of which they are members) are engaged in sufficiently sensitive
activities that full disclosure is required, especially for the
benefit of the relevant regulators, and, in the case of public
companies, the fact that they are free to offer their shares to the
public suggests that a full financial record should be available.
Medium-sized companies
21–5
Somewhat misleadingly placed some 80 sections away from the
provisions on small companies is to be found, in the
“supplementary provisions” to Pt 15, the definition of a medium-
sized company. The criteria here are: balance sheet total of not
more than £18 million, turnover not more than £36 million and
not more than 250 employees.28 There are similarly-motivated,
but not identical, exclusions from this category as we saw in the
small category, amongst which, crucially, are public
companies.29 In some ways, however, placing these definitions
in the “supplementary provisions” of the Part dealing with
accounts is appropriate, for medium-sized companies and groups
benefit from rather fewer relaxations from the full accounts
requirements, as compared with small companies. The CLR
recommended the removal of this category on the grounds that it
was neither much used nor valued, but this suggestion was not
taken up.30
Large companies and public interest entities
21–6
Large companies are simply those which not meet the
quantitative criteria needed to fall within the medium-sized
category.31 Public interest entities are companies whose
securities are admitted to trading on a regulated market in the
EU,32 which the Act terms a “traded company”.33 In addition, the
category includes any bank or insurance company (whether so
traded or not), plus any other category of company added to the
list for its jurisdiction by a Member State (the UK has not done
so). PIEs are already subject to special audit treatment, as we
shall see in the next chapter. As for core accounting, the
principal requirement is that PIEs should always report as large
companies even if otherwise qualified as medium-sized.34 It is
seriously open to doubt whether in the UK any PIE would
qualify as medium-sized even without this express exclusion.
The PIE category is, in fact, of most interest in the context of
non-financial reporting, as we shall see below.
There is a further dimension to financial reporting by
companies traded on public markets. Those who introduced the
annual reporting obligation in the nineteenth century probably
saw it as informing two groups of people: the shareholders of the
company, so that they could assess whether the company’s
management was doing an acceptable job; and the creditors of
the company, whose claims are confined to the company’s assets
(except in the rare case of an unlimited company). However, the
modern view includes a further group as having an interest in
this matter. At least with companies whose securities are traded
on a public market, disclosure of information about the company
is crucial for the accurate pricing of the companies’ securities
and hence for the efficient operation of the securities market.
This is true both of equity securities (shares) and debt securities
(bonds) which are traded on public markets.
So strong is the markets’ demand for information that it is not
satisfied by the annual reporting obligations discussed in this
chapter. As we shall see in Ch.26, publicly traded companies are
now subject to extensive disclosure requirements which operate
throughout the company’s financial year. Such rules include
more frequent periodic reporting than the annual requirements of
the Companies Act, as well as significant requirements for the
episodic or ad hoc reporting of particular events. Even in relation
to the annual reports, which remain a very significant reporting
occasion, it is the point at which the company makes a
preliminary announcement to the market of its financial results
for the previous year (the “prelims”)35 which moves the market.
Such announcements—and the later full accounts and reports,
though they are somewhat stale news by then—are pored over
by analysts, whose task it is to generate advice for investors.
THE ANNUAL ACCOUNTS
Accounting records
21–7
The statutory provisions relating to the annual accounts begin by
imposing on the company a continuing obligation to maintain
accounting records.36 This is logical enough, because, although
these records are not open to inspection by members or the
public, unless they are kept it will be impossible for the company
to produce verifiable annual accounts. Hence, s.386 provides
that every company—no matter how categorised for other
accounting purposes—shall keep records sufficient to show and
explain the company’s transactions, to disclose with reasonable
accuracy at any time its financial position and to enable its
directors to ensure that any balance sheet and profit and loss
account will comply with the relevant accounting standards.37
A company which has a subsidiary undertaking to which these
requirements do not apply38 must take all reasonable steps to
secure that the subsidiary keeps such records as will enable the
directors of the parent company to ensure that any accounts
required of the parent company comply with the relevant
requirements.39
Failure to comply with the section renders every officer of the
company (but not the company itself) who is in default guilty of
an offence40 unless he shows that he acted honestly and that, in
the circumstances in which the company’s business was carried
on, the default was excusable.41 More effective in practice is
probably the duty laid on the auditor to check whether adequate
accounting records have been kept and to reveal failure to do so
in the auditor’s report.42
Section 388 provides that accounting records are at all times
to be open for inspection by officers of the company.43 If any
such records are kept outside the UK,44 there must be sent to the
UK (and be available for inspection there by the officers) records
which will disclose with reasonable accuracy the position of the
business in question at intervals of not more than six months and
which will enable the directors to ensure that the company’s
balance sheet and profit and loss account comply with the
statutory requirements.45 All required records must be preserved
for three years if it is a private company or for six years if it is a
public one.46
The financial year
21–8
The first step in the production of the annual accounts is to fix
the company’s financial year. Sections 390–392 prescribe how
this is to be done. Despite its name the financial year is not a
calendar year nor, necessarily, a period of 12 months. What
period it is depends on its “accounting reference period”
(“ARP”), which in turn depends on its “accounting reference
date” (“ARD”), which is the date in each calendar year on which
the company’s ARP ends. For companies incorporated after 1
April 1996, the company’s ARD will be the anniversary of the
last day of the month in which it was incorporated.47 However,
the company may choose a new ARD for the current and future
ARPs and even for its immediately preceding one.48 This it may
well want to do for a variety of reasons; for instance, if the
company has been taken over and wishes to bring its ARD into
line with that of its new parent.49 The new ARD may operate
either to shorten or to lengthen the ARP within which the change
is made,50 but in the latter case the company may not normally
extend the ARP to more than 18 months51 and may not normally
engage in the process of extending the ARP more than once
every five years.52 These are necessary safeguards against
obvious abuses, for constantly changing ARPs make
comparisons across the years difficult. The company’s financial
year then corresponds to its ARP, as fixed according to the
above rules, except that the directors have a discretion to make
the financial year end at any point up to seven days before or
seven days after the end of the ARP.53
Individual accounts and group accounts
21–9
Subject to a very limited exception54 s.394 imposes on the
directors of every company the duty to prepare for each financial
year a set of accounts of the company (its “individual
accounts”). This duty applies even to the directors of small and
micro companies, though the requirements as to what the
accounts have to contain in those cases are less onerous. Section
399 imposes a duty on directors of a company which is a parent
company additionally to prepare a consolidated balance sheet
and profit and loss account (“group accounts”). Those group
accounts must deal with the state of affairs of the parent
company and its “subsidiary undertakings”—taken together.55
However, the obligation to produce group accounts is
qualified by one very significant exception: it does not apply to
parents of groups subject to the small companies regime. Many
businesses, even quite small ones, operate as groups. However,
that exemption could undermine the requirement for group
accounts, for example, where those in control of the business
ensured that the operations of the group were carried on and its
employees were employed principally in companies below the
parent which itself was a small company. Consequently, in order
to benefit from the small company group exemption, the test is
not whether the parent is small, but whether the group as a whole
meets the relevant criteria.56 The size tests for a small group are
the same as for a stand-alone company except that intra-group
transactions may be eliminated when calculating turnover and
balance sheet totals; alternatively, the parent company may
choose instead to benefit from higher levels (by one fifth)
without eliminating intra-group transactions.57 However, the
legislature recently expanded the group accounts exemption in
one significant way, by extending it to small public companies.
Provided the size criteria are met, it does not matter that the
parent or the subsidiaries are public companies, provided none of
them is a traded company.58
There is no special exemption for micro companies in relation
to group accounts. Indeed, if a micro company is part of a group,
the micro relaxations are not available for its individual
accounts.59 However, since, by definition, a micro company will
also be a small company, it will be able to benefit from the small
company regime when producing its individual accounts as a
member of a group and will benefit from the small company
exemption from the requirement to produce group accounts if it
is the parent company.
There is a similar approach to the definition of a medium-
sized group to that used for a small group—except, of course,
that a medium-sized group is not exempted from the obligation
to produce group accounts, but it may report less fully.60
Parent and subsidiary undertakings
21–10
The obligation to produce group accounts does not relieve the
directors of the parent company from the obligation to produce
individual accounts for the parent61 nor, subject to one exception,
the directors of the other companies in the group from that
obligation in relation to their company.62 The individual and
group accounts of companies within a group should be produced,
in principle, using the same financial reporting framework.63 The
exception relates to subsidiaries which have been dormant
throughout the relevant financial year (unless the subsidiary is a
traded company—a rare situation). They are not required to
produce individual accounts, subject to certain conditions, in
particular that all the members of the subsidiary agree (easy
enough if the subsidiary is wholly owned), that the parent is
incorporated in the EEA and that the parent guarantees the
liabilities of the subsidiary as they existed at the end of the year
in relation to which the exemption applied (and all this is
disclosed).64 The principle that the production of group accounts
should not normally remove the obligation to render individual
accounts is as it should be. Creditors, in particular, may well
have claims only against particular companies in the group,
unless they have contracted for guarantees from other group
members, and so the group picture alone might be misleading.
By contrast, the shareholders of the parent have an economic
interest in the performance of the group as a whole, since
subsidiary profits may eventually come to them as dividends
from the parent company, and so are interested primarily in the
group accounts.65
The obligation to produce group accounts gives rise to the
need to define a subsidiary undertaking. The situation may be
clear when Company A holds all the voting shares in Company
B, but suppose it holds only 30 per cent of them. What is then
the position? The answer is provided by ss.1161 and 1162 and
Sch.7. The term “undertaking” is used rather than “company”
because consolidation of the accounts is required even if the
subsidiary business does not take the form of a company or some
other body corporate, but is a partnership or other
unincorporated body.66 Thus, although group accounts are
required by the Act to be compiled only by entities which are
companies,67 the shareholders and creditors of and investors in
those companies are to be provided with financial information
relating to all the businesses the parent controls, no matter what
legal form they may take.
But what is control? The Act, building on art.22 of the
Directive, sets out five situations where control will be found to
exist. Briefly summarised, these situations are where the parent
company:
(a) holds a majority of voting rights in the undertaking68;
(b) is a member of the other undertaking and has the right to
appoint or remove a majority of its board of directors69;
(c) by virtue of provisions in the constitution of the other
undertaking or in a written “control contract”, permitted by
that constitution, has a right, recognised by the law under
which that undertaking is established, to exercise a “dominant
influence” over that undertaking (by giving directions to the
directors of the undertaking on its operating and financial
policies which those directors are obliged to comply with
whether or not the directions are for the benefit of the
undertaking)70;
(d) has the power to exercise or actually exercises dominant
influence or control over the undertaking or the parent and
alleged subsidiary are actually managed on a unified basis71;
(e) is a member of another undertaking and alone controls,
pursuant to an agreement with other members, a majority of
the voting rights in that undertaking72; and sub-subsidiaries
are to be treated as subsidiaries of the ultimate parent also.73
Despite the complexities of this definition, which arise partly
out of the need to address control structures across the EU, it is
clear that the most important case in the UK is (a). Thus, the
answer to our question is that a holding of 30 per cent by
Company A in Company B will not, by itself, make Company B
its subsidiary. However, companies are not permitted to remain
entirely silent about their significant relationships with
companies other than subsidiaries. Companies have to disclose
in their individual or group accounts certain information about
companies, not being subsidiaries, in which they have
nevertheless a significant holding.74 However, such affiliated
companies do not have to be consolidated into the group
accounts.
Parent companies which are part of a larger group
21–11
A parent/subsidiary relationship will exist even where the parent
(the “intermediate parent”) is itself the subsidiary of another
company. In groups of companies this situation often exists.
There may be a chain of companies in which all but the bottom
company meet the statutory definition for being a parent of the
company (or companies) below them in the chain. The resulting
proliferation of group accounts of varying scope is not likely to
be helpful. Consequently, there are exemptions which apply in
such cases. The terms of the exemption vary according to the
level of the parent’s shareholding in the intermediate parent,
since the “outside” shareholders in the intermediate parent have
an economic interest in that company’s subsidiaries and so may
wish to have intermediate group accounts.
Subject to certain further conditions, an intermediate parent
which is a wholly-owned subsidiary of another company is
relieved of the obligation to produce group accounts.75 Where
the parent of the intermediate parent holds 90 per cent or more of
the subsidiary’s shares, the exemption needs the approval of
(presumably a majority of) the remaining shareholders of the
intermediate parent.76 Where the parent of the intermediate
parent holds more than 50 per cent of the allotted shares77 (but
less than 90 per cent), exemption is the default rule. However, if
the holders of at least 5 per cent of the total allotted shares in the
intermediate parent serve a notice, within six months of the end
of the financial year in question, requiring the production of
group accounts by their company, then those group accounts
must be produced.78 The higher level of protection where the
“outside” shareholders constitute 10 per cent or less of the
shareholders is perhaps explicable by reference to the fact that
the governance rights of such shareholders are very limited. For
example, they are unable to block a special resolution. None of
the above exemptions is available, however, if the intermediate
parent is a traded company.79 This is particularly important in
relation to the default exemption. For such companies, there will
necessarily be a significant block of the company’s shares which
are not held by that company’s parent but are in the hands of
public investors. Their interests dictate that the traded company
should produce accounts which cover its position together with
the position of the undertakings it controls, for that is the
economic entity in which the public have invested.80
Even where the exemption is available in principle, certain
other conditions have to be met. First, the intermediate parent
must actually be included in the accounts of a larger group; those
accounts must be drawn up in accordance with the standards
contained in the Directive or equivalent standards, and must be
audited.81 Secondly, the individual accounts of the intermediate
parent must disclose that it is exempt from the obligation to
produce group accounts and give prescribed information in order
to identify the parent undertaking that draws up the group
accounts.82 Thirdly, the intermediate parent must deliver the
group accounts to the Registrar, translated into English, if
necessary.83
Companies excluded from consolidation
21–12
Even if a company is in principle subject to the obligation to
produce group accounts, nevertheless some subsidiary
companies may be omitted from the consolidation. Subsidiaries
may be omitted if (a) their inclusion is not material for giving a
true and fair view of the group (for example, if they are inactive
companies); (b) “severe long-term restrictions” substantially
hinder the exercise of the parent’s rights over the assets or
management of the company (a situation most likely to arise
from restrictions in foreign legal systems); (c) the necessary
information cannot be obtained “without disproportionate
expense or undue delay”; and (d) the parent’s interest is held
exclusively with a view to resale.84 If all the subsidiaries fall
within one or other of these categories, no group accounts need
be produced—no doubt a rare situation.85
Form and content of annual accounts
Possible approaches
21–13
Broadly, there are two model approaches for the legislature to
take to the rules governing the financial analysis of the
transactions the company has engaged in during the year and the
presentation of the results of that analysis in the company’s
individual or group accounts. It could lay down one or more very
general principles and leave it to the accounting profession to
develop more specific rules (usually referred to as “accounting
standards”), to which, however, legal force might or might not
be attached; or the legislature could try to set out a detailed set of
rules itself. The British tradition is closer to the former model.
However, the continental European tradition, which is closer to
the second model, had an impact on British law in the 1980s,
because that tradition influenced the Fourth and Seventh
Directives on companies’ accounts,86 though not to the extent by
any means of a complete shift to the latter approach. However,
in a later development, the EU moved towards giving standard
setters a bigger role in the setting of the detailed rules, through
the adoption of International Accounting Standards (“IAS”),
though with the rider that standard-setting should no longer be
purely a matter for the professions and the public interest should
be represented in the standard-setting exercise.
The result is that the current rules are a mixture of legislative
provision and accounting standards, to which different degrees
of legal recognition are accorded. Moreover, there are two sets
of rules, with different mixtures. Here lies the significance of the
term “accounting framework”. A company which is under an
obligation to produce individual accounts is free to do so either
by reference to the rules contained in the Companies Act and
regulations made thereunder or by reference to IAS.87 These
accounts are called, helpfully if unimaginatively, “Companies
Act individual accounts” and “IAS individual accounts”
respectively. The same choice is available to companies under an
obligation to produce group accounts, except that companies
which in domestic terminology are traded companies88 must use
IAS for their group accounts, as required by EU law.89 Thus,
there are also “Companies Act group accounts” and “IAS group
accounts”.
The IAS Regulation permits Member States to permit or
require domestic companies to use IAS more widely.90 The UK
adopted the permissive approach but made it widely available,
for even small companies may use IAS.91 Having switched to
IAS, a company may change back to Companies Act accounts
provided it has not changed to Companies Act accounts during
the five-year period leading up to the most recent year of IAS
accounts. This rule is clearly aimed at preventing chopping and
changing, which would reduce the comparability of the accounts.
If the company wishes to change back to Companies Act
accounts within that period, it must show that “there is a relevant
change of circumstance”.92 Similar rules apply on a reconversion
to IAS.93
We will now look at Companies Act accounts and IAS
accounts in turn, but first it is necessary to look at a two
provisions which applies to both Companies Act and IAS
accounts.
True and fair view
21–14
The traditional British approach to the accounts has long focused
around the general principle that the accounts must “give a true
and fair view of the assets, liabilities, financial position and
profit or loss”94 of the individual company or the companies
included in the consolidation in the case of group accounts. For
many years this was virtually all the companies legislation said
about the content of the accounts. It remains an overriding
principle, no matter which accounting framework is used for the
presentation of the accounts. The directors must not approve
accounts unless they provide a true and fair view.95 The
overriding nature of the requirement is reflected in art.4 of the
Directive.
If compliance with the Act or provisions made under it would
not be sufficient to give a true and fair view, the necessary
additional information must be given in the accounts or notes to
them.96 Further, if in “exceptional” or “special” circumstances
compliance with the statutory provisions would put the accounts
in breach of the “true and fair” requirement, the directors must
depart from the statute or subordinate legislation to the extent
necessary to give a true and fair view.97 What this qualification
seems not to permit, though standard-setters have sometimes
taken a different view, is the issuance of a standard which gives
a general dispensation to companies to depart from a provision
in or made under the Act, on the grounds that a true and fair
view requires this. These provisions of the Directive and of the
Act contemplate only ad hoc departures from the statutory
requirements in the case of particular companies in particular
circumstances.
The prohibition on signing accounts which do not give a true
and fair view applies equally to IAS accounts as to Companies
Act accounts. However, with IAS accounts, domestic law says
nothing about what must or may be done to produce that view if
the applicable standards by themselves do not achieve it.98
Nevertheless, the position is probably the same, since the
provisions of the Directive apply to all accounts, no matter what
accounting framework is employed. IAS 1 requires that the
accounts “present fairly” the company’s or group’s financial
position, which presumably may be equated with a “true and fair
view”.99 The application of IAS (or rather International Financial
Reporting Standards (“IFRS”), as they have now become) is
presumed to lead to fair presentation, but IAS 1 recognises that
further disclosure may be necessary to achieve this result.
Departure from IFRS in order to achieve fair presentation is
recognised as permissible but only “in extremely rare
circumstances”.
Going concern evaluation
21–15
Much less obvious in the domestic legislation than the true and
fair requirement, but often as important, is the requirement that
directors form a view, when they draw up the accounts, whether
the company is a going concern. Article 6 of the Directive lays
down as one of its “general financial reporting principles” that
“the undertaking shall be presumed to be carrying on its business
as a going concern”, so that, if the company is in danger of
ceasing to be a going concern, this fact must disclosed and
appropriate valuations made. This principle is important because
the numbers in the accounts are likely to look very different
where a company may have to sell assets off on a break-up basis.
Both the national and international accounting standards
(discussed below) require that the directors make this assessment
when preparing financial statements.100 In addition, the Listing
Rules require the directors of a company with a premium listing
on the Main Market101 of the London Stock Exchange to insert in
its annual financial report a statement that the company is a
going concern, together with any assumptions underlying that
statement and any qualifications to it.102 In the recent financial
crisis, and especially when liquidity was in short supply, the
issue came to the fore. The Financial Reporting Council (see
below) established a committee to examine the lessons to be
drawn from how this matter was handled in the crisis and later
issued revised guidance.103
Companies Act accounts
21–16
At the core of Companies Act accounts are a traditional balance
sheet and a profit and loss statement.104 The balance sheet
provides a statement of the company’s assets and liabilities, as at
a particular point in time, i.e. the last day of the financial year. If,
as is to be hoped, the former are greater than the latter, the
difference between the figures is sometimes referred to as the
shareholders’ equity. It is the theoretical amount which the
shareholders would receive if the company’s business were then
sold as a going concern.105 If the assets are less than the
liabilities, the shareholders have no equity in the company and
the people with the strongest interest in its economic
performance are its creditors.106 The profit and loss account
indicates the company’s performance over the financial year: has
it generated more value than it has consumed? Profit is different
from cash flow. A profitable company may have a negative cash
flow over a particular period, for example, where it has used a
previously large cash balance to buy a new (and profitable)
business. Although the new business may have generated cash
during the financial year in which it was bought, it is highly
unlikely that this cash income will come anywhere near the
amount expended to acquire the business. Conversely, a
company which has been unprofitable over the year but has
managed to dispose of a large fixed asset during that year may
end the year with more cash than at the beginning of it.
What does the Act say about the format of these two
accounts? With the enactment of the Fourth and Seventh
Directives, UK law also adopted the Continental practice of
dealing with matters of form and content to some extent in the
legislation itself, and so the domestic legal provisions dealing
with the accounts were expanded. Those provisions are now in
the Large and Medium-Sized Companies and Groups (Accounts
and Reports) Regulations 2008,107 and the Small Companies and
Groups (Accounts and Reports) Regulations 2008,108 both as
subsequently amended. This account of the Regulations is
necessarily brief and we shall omit entirely the special
provisions applying to banking and insurance companies.
Following the Directive, Pt 1 of Sch.1 to both sets of
Regulations109 provides two alternative formats in which the
balance sheet may be presented and four possible formats for the
profit and loss account. However, the directors cannot shift from
the formats adopted in the previous year “unless in their opinion
there are special reasons for a change”.110 The formats concern
simply the questions of how the accounting information is
grouped and the order in which the information, so grouped, is
presented to the reader. More important, therefore, are the
provisions of the Schedule which go into issues relating to the
proper accounting treatment of transactions carried out by the
company or contain rules about the valuation of assets and
liabilities. These are contained in Pt 2 of the Schedule under the
heading “Accounting Principles and Rules”. This is where the
“going concern” principle of the Directive is transposed into
domestic law. However, these rules are (strong) default rules, for
the directors may depart from them if there are “special reasons”
for so doing, provided the nature of the departure, the reasons for
it and its effect are stated.111 Furthermore, the Schedule explicitly
provides a choice to the directors as to the fundamental
accounting approach which will be adopted. No longer is a
historical cost approach mandatory (under which, for example,
assets are carried in the books at their original acquisition price,
less depreciation, even though their current market price is much
higher) but rather various forms of “marking to market” are
permitted.112
Finally, it is clear that the “Accounting Principles and Rules”
contained in the Schedule are not sufficient to produce a set of
accounts for any particular company, except perhaps one of the
simplest character. More detailed accounting standards need to
be deployed, which are not to be found in the Regulations
implementing the Directives but in standards developed by the
standard-setters, to which we now turn.
Accounting standards
21–17
In the UK the professional accountancy bodies had begun as
early as 1942113 to issue accounting standards. At that time and
for a long while thereafter they provided the only authoritative
guidance on what the “true and fair” requirement meant in
particular situations. Those standards covered ever more topics
and became ever more sophisticated over time; and, as we have
seen, their centrality to the accounts-producing exercise was not
ended by the transposition in the UK of the Fourth and Seventh
Directives. Two important developments have accompanied the
expansion of the role of accounting standards. These two
developments are probably not unconnected with one another,
their common feature being a recognition of the quasi-public
role played by accounting standards. First, accounting standards
have achieved legal backing; secondly, the professional bodies
have lost their previously complete control over the standard-
setting process.
Although the 1942 standards were termed
“Recommendations”, it became accepted in the accounting
profession that compliance with the legal obligation to present a
“true and fair” view of the company’s financial position required
in principle adherence to accounting standards – even if on rare
occasions that legal obligation had the contrary effect of
requiring directors to override the requirements of a particular
standard.114 A good example of this reasoning in action was
provided on the occasion of the introduction of a set of extensive
reporting relaxations for micro companies (see below). The
Directive provides that where advantage is taken of these
relaxations, the micro company’s annual financial statements
“shall be regarded as giving the true and fair view required by
Article 4(3)115 [which refers to the provision of additional
information to give a true and fair view]”. This was argued to
rule out the application of accounting standards to the relevant
items in the micro company’s accounts, because these typically
would require additional information. But, if accounting
standards could not be applied, directors and auditors would be
in danger of not meeting the “true and fair” obligation.
Consequently, the Act’s formulation of the directors’ true and
fair obligation was amended specifically to require directors of
micro companies to ignore accounting standards when making
that judgement if those standards would require the provision of
further information.116
This process described in the previous paragraph was
supported by the courts’ acceptance of the professional standards
as the best evidence of the standard of care required by the law
of negligence in relation to accountants performing their
professional duties, especially when acting as auditors, though
the courts are not bound by the professionally developed
standards.117 In the case of large companies the resulting position
was recognised legislatively in a provision added in 1989. This
provides that “it must be stated whether the accounts have been
prepared in accordance with applicable accounting standards and
particulars of any material departure from those standards and
the reasons for it must be given”.118 This in effect puts
accounting standards on a “comply or explain” basis, and it was
probably the first example of the use of this technique in
company law.119
The second development—the injection of a public element
into the standard-setting bodies—occurred when the Companies
Act 1989 conferred on the Secretary of State the power to
determine which body or bodies have authority to issue
accounting standards which have statutory recognition.120 Under
the current arrangements the Secretary of State has delegated
this power to the Financial Reporting Council Ltd (“FRC”). The
FRC is a private company (limited by guarantee), but the Chair
and Deputy Chair of the FRC are appointed by the Secretary of
State; the remaining directors, executive and non-executive, are
appointed and removed by the board itself. Those who have
practised in the accounting profession within the previous five
years are excluded, so that the board appears to be weighted
towards the users of accountants’ services. Some of the work of
the FRC in the accounting standards area is delegated to a Codes
and Standards Committee. The FRC is funded in its accounting,
audit and corporate governance activities by the accountancy
profession and the preparers of financial statements, though the
“preparers’ levy” paid by public traded and large private (i.e.
non publicly traded) companies.121 Overall, the public
authorities, despite no longer making any significant
contribution to the funding of the FRC, can be said to have
considerable potential control over its activities. On the other
hand, the governmental bodies do not interfere in the day-to-day
running of the FRC. Thus, the current structure can be said to
combine the technical competence and flexibility of setting rules
through expert bodies exercising delegated powers with the
safeguarding of the public interest through ultimate public
control.
IAS accounts
21–18
If the Directive represents the use by the EU of (partial)
legislative specification of the form of the accounts, the IAS
Regulation122 represents the EU’s adoption of the alternative
strategy of reliance on the standard-setters. Companies subject to
the IAS, whether mandatorily or by their own choice, are to
prepare their accounts in conformity with international
accounting standards as laid down by the International
Accounting Standards Board and as adopted by the
Commission.123 True it is that such companies remain subject to
the Directive, but the predecessors of the current Directive, the
Fourth and Seventh Directives, were amended so as to ensure
that they permitted companies to adopt the IAS approach. A
good example is the fact that IAS 1 does not require the
production of a profit and loss account but rather of income and
cash flow statements, which necessitated an adjustment of the
Fourth Directive.124 At domestic level, since the IAS Regulation
applies directly in the UK, the national provisions dealing with
the form and content of the accounts are applied only to
companies producing Companies Act accounts.125 For IAS
accounts, these matters are dealt with in the international
standards themselves.
The effect of the IAS Regulation is to give the standards
produced by the IASB (now called International Financial
Reporting Standards (“IFRS”)) an even more explicit legal
position than domestic standards. The appropriate IAS and IFRS
must be followed under the terms of the IAS Regulation.126 Not
surprisingly, and in line with the domestic developments, the
more prominent role afforded to the international standards was
accompanied by the loss of purely professional control over the
setting of those standards. The IASB became an independent
body in 2001, having been founded in 1973 by the professional
accountancy bodies of nine leading countries. However, close
ties with a particular government, on the model of the FRC, were
hardly feasible for the IASB, which adopted a different path
away from professional control. In brief, its members are
appointed by the trustees of a foundation,127 which trustees are a
self-perpetuating body (i.e. they appoint their own successors).
However, this arrangement was subject to criticism, notably
from the European Commission, and was modified by the
addition of a Monitoring Board consisting of representatives of
the public authorities (mainly regulators, including the European
Commission).128
21–19
The IASB is not a European but an international organisation, as
its name suggests. Given its wider scope, the obligation of
companies within the IAS Regulation to apply IAS and IFRS,
and the reluctance of the European Commission to lose all
control over this important area, it is perhaps not surprising that
there is a filter in place between the adoption of a standard by
the IASB and its becoming mandatory for European companies
subject to the IAS Regulation. The filter is that the standard
produced by the IASB must have been adopted by the
Commission of the European Union, which is advised by a
technical committee (European Financial Reporting Advisory
Group (“EFRAG”)) and a committee consisting of
representatives from the Member States (Accounting Regulatory
Committee (“ARC”)) before it endorses an international
standard.129 The nature of the filtration process is perhaps less
clear. Adoption is not permitted if the IASB standard is contrary
to the “true and fair view” principle,130 but if the “fair
presentation” principle of IAS 1 is the same as a true and fair
view,131 then that judgment will have been made already by the
IASB. Nor may the Commission adopt an IASB standard if it
fails to “meet the criteria of understandability, relevance,
reliability and comparability” required of such standards.
However, it is highly unlikely that the IASB would adopt a
standard which it considered infringed this principle either. In
effect, the filter operates as an opportunity for the same issues to
be debated again at EU level as were considered internationally
in the adoption of the initial IAS or IFRS. Such a re-hashing of
the arguments occurred in relation to the IAS standard on the
market valuation of financial instruments. After a long debate
IAS 39 was adopted but with two significant carve outs.132 The
other IAS and IFRS have been adopted straightforwardly,
though not always on time.133 It is clear that extensive use of the
blocking power by the Commission would be likely to lead to a
collapse of the IASB venture.
It may be wondered why the EU threw its weight behind the
IAS and the IASB rather than keeping closer control over
accounting standards itself. It seems to have recognised that
producing accounting standards for the largest companies is
necessarily a global rather than a regional activity.134
Globalisation has led multinational companies to acquire not
only cross-border business activities, but also cross-border
groups of investors. Both investors, seeking to compare
companies from different jurisdictions, and companies, seeking
to raise money in more than one country, have generated a
demand for international uniformity in accounting standards, so
that accounts do not have to be constantly restated according to
different countries’ “generally accepted accounting principles”
(“GAAP”). The only other contender for a global role is the US
national standards (US GAAP). The IASB provides a platform
from which convergence may be pursued with the US standards
rather than a simple adoption of them.135
Applying the requirements to different sizes of
company
21–20
We have seen that the form and content of the accounts result
from a complex interaction of rules set out in legislation (which
itself may be national or EU legislation and primary or
secondary legislation) and accounting standards (which may be
national or international). This is a far cry from the days when
there was only national legislation, when that legislation
confined itself to the requirement of a true and fair view, and the
rest was national accounting standards. It does not help that the
balance between legislation and standards varies somewhat
according to whether national or international standards are used
by the company. There is one further cross-cutting set of
divisions which we need to notice. This is the varying intensity
of the rules and standards across companies of different sizes.
We need to consider this point only briefly, since this is not a
textbook on accounting. The rules we consider here relate to the
different requirements for the production of accounts. As we
shall see later, differences in economic size are also relevant a
number of other accounting matters: what goes into the notes to
the accounts and into narrative reporting or the level of publicity
to be given to those accounts once produced (through their filing
in a public registry). The full force of the rules and standards
applies only to large companies and groups and PIEs which are
required to report as large companies, even though they are only
medium-sized.136 Medium-sized companies and groups benefit
from a modest set of derogations from the requirements for large
companies. In particular, the UK has not taken up the permission
in art.23 of the Directive to exempt the parent of medium-sized
groups from the obligation to draw up group accounts.
For small companies the derogations are more substantial. As
we have seen above, a small company is not required to produce
group accounts, though it may choose to do so. Further, the
Directive (art.14) permits Member States to allow small
companies to produce only “abridged” profit and loss accounts
and balance sheets. This means that some items normally
required to be shown separately may be combined in a single
heading. So, the accounts are less granular, but equally cheaper
to produce and less helpful to competitors. Until recently,
domestic law has permitted small companies to publish
abbreviated accounts.137 Drawing up abridged accounts raises
additional issues because the accounts are then less useful for
shareholders as well as outsiders (shareholders receive the
accounts as drawn up and are not reliant on the published ones).
The UK decided to take up the option to permit abridged
accounts to be drawn up only where all of the members of the
company consent to this course of action.138 This is designed to
allow the company to cut costs when all the shareholders are
insiders but to allow outside shareholders to protect themselves
by withholding consent. Finally, the accounting standards
applying to small companies have been simplified, both by the
FRC and the IASB.139
The largest set of derogations is reserved for the smallest
companies, i.e. micro companies. The permissible derogations
from the accounts preparation requirements are set out in art.36
of the Directive, and the UK has taken advantage of nearly all of
them140 for free-standing micro entities.141 Accounting standards
are further simplified for micro entities.142
Notes to the accounts
21–21
Although the British tradition has been for the legislature not to
specify the form and content of the accounts, but to leave that to
standard-setters, the legislature has long seen the accounts as a
useful place to require the disclosure of specific pieces of
information. These are not required to be part of the accounts
proper but are to be given in “notes” to the accounts.143 The
notes requirements apply whether the company has produced
Companies Act or IAS accounts.144 The information required to
be disclosed is often designed to make the information contained
in the accounts complete.145 We have seen above the example of
the requirement to give information in the notes about non-
subsidiary companies in which the reporting company has a
significant holding.146 Another example is the requirement for
companies (other than small ones) to disclose ‘off balance-sheet’
transactions, without knowledge of which the balance sheet may
be entirely misleading.147
Most of what is required by way of notes in arts 16–18 of the
Directive falls into the “completeness” category. However, in
this context there is again room for debate about whether the
notes requirements should apply uniformly across all sizes of
company. The Directive requires compliance with the art.16 list
by all companies, except that Member States may choose to
exempt micro companies from nearly all of them, as the UK
did.148 Small companies are in principle exempted from the more
advanced disclosures required by art.17. However, Member
States may choose to apply five of the more advanced
disclosures to small companies, but may not impose notes
requirements on small companies beyond this level.149 The UK
decided to apply all five additional disclosures to small
companies, on the grounds that they were not burdensome and
were needed to understand properly the financial position of the
company, e.g. material post-balance sheet events.150 Finally,
art.18 (disclosure of turnover by reference to different
geographical markets) applies only to large companies and
PIEs.151
However, the information provided in the notes may reinforce
the shareholders’ governance rights as well as supplying
potentially useful financial information. We have seen that the
issue of transactions between companies and those who are in a
position to influence the terms of those transactions or their
associates is a central regulatory problem in relation to both
directors and controlling shareholders. Transactions between
directors and their companies are subject to special rules about
disclosure to the board or even shareholder approval,152 whilst
similar transactions by controlling shareholders, though in
general less well policed by British company law, may give rise
to claims of unfair prejudice.153 Article 17(1)(r) requires
disclosure of information about material related party
transactions not concluded under normal market conditions, and
this is one of the provisions of art.17 which the UK has applied
to small companies.154 Shareholders reading the notes are thus in
a better position to decide whether to seek to invoke their
remedies in this area.
NARRATIVE REPORTING
21–22
The company’s financial statements, naturally, are dominated by
numbers. But the annual circulation by the directors to the
shareholders includes some predominantly non-numerical
documents. This is now conventionally referred to as “narrative
reporting”. Until about a quarter of a century ago, the only
statutorily required narrative report was the directors’ report, the
content of which was determined largely by the directors
themselves. Since then, the mandatory content of narrative
reporting has expanded enormously and, as part of that process,
further reports have been added to the directors’ report. Just as
important, the notion of the audience to whom the narrative
reports are addressed has expanded. Originally, directors thought
of their report as addressed to shareholders and, perhaps,
potential investors in the company. Today, it is common to say
that the narrative reports are addressed to all “stakeholders” in
the company—though the term “stakeholder” is usually
undefined and the action which stakeholders might take in
response to the information provided left unspecified.155
In consequence, the disclosures required are sometimes only
indirectly linked to the financial interests of the shareholders.156
Indeed, in some cases narrative reporting may be intended to
induce changes in corporate behaviour which the shareholders
might not wish to induce, if left to themselves. Thus, the recent
addition of “extractive industry” reporting requires the directors
of large companies and PIEs active in those industries to produce
an annual report which discloses payments made to foreign
governments. The purpose of this requirement is so that “we can
provide citizens [of foreign countries] with the detailed
information they need to hold their governments to account”.157
The implication is that such payments are often bribes to local
politicians or senior officials. The shareholders’ interests are not
placed centre-stage in this case, but rather those of the foreign
citizens. Indeed, if because of corruption or lack of democratic
process in those countries, no such accountability occurs, the
reporting companies will find themselves at a competitive
disadvantage as against companies from jurisdictions which do
not impose (or effectively enforce) this reporting requirement. If,
on the other hand, the foreign citizens are successful, the benefits
will accrue mainly to them rather than the company’s
shareholders.158 Perhaps for this reason, the Directive and the
domestic regulations, whilst requiring the payment report to be
made public (through filing at Companies House), do not require
it to be laid before the shareholders.159 Narrative disclosure can
thus be used to bolster policies whose drivers are located outside
company law, as conventionally conceived.
In this section we consider the various items that contribute to
narrative reporting, with the exception of the directors’
remuneration report, important though that is. This has been
dealt with in Ch.14160 and need not be further considered here.
Directors’ report
21–23
The directors’ report (“DR”), to accompany both the individual
and group accounts, has long been a statutory requirement in the
UK. However there is no longer a requirement for micro
companies to produce a directors’ report161 and small companies
benefit from a lower disclosure regime.162
The statute requires the report to contain some fairly
straightforward information, for example, a list of those who
were directors of the company at any time during the year.163 It
must also state the amount the directors recommend to be paid
by way of dividend to the shareholders.164 However, this latter
requirement does not apply to companies entitled to the “small
company exemption”. Presumably, this is because in small
companies public disclosure of dividend recommendations may
reveal the income of easily identifiable individuals, for example,
where the directors are the only shareholders. This exemption is
available not only to small companies falling within the small
companies regime for the accounts but also to small companies
which would so fall but for the fact that they are members of a
group of companies which contains an ineligible member.165
Thus, the relaxations for small companies in relation to the DR
go somewhat wider than in relation to the accounts. More
generally, the DR must state any important events which have
affected the company since the end of the financial year and
indicate the likely future development of its business.166
None of the above is very demanding. However, when one
turns from the Act to Sch.7 of the Large Companies Regulations,
one finds a number of disclosure requirements which are not
closely related to the financial interests of the shareholders.167
Thus Pt 3 requires information to be given about the
employment, training and promotion of disabled persons.168 Part
4 requires information about “employee involvement”, i.e. the
extent to which employees are systematically given information,
consulted, and encouraged to join employee share schemes. Part
7 requires traded companies169 to disclose their greenhouse gas
emissions. These provisions seek to co-opt large companies to
support (usually laudable) non-corporate policies which the
government is pursuing.
Even the requirement in Pt 1 for separate disclosure of the
amounts of political donations is not generally necessary to form
a view on the financial position of large companies in view of
the minimal amounts needed to trigger this requirement and the
modest amounts normally donated. However, this disclosure
clearly facilitates the operation of the controls over political
donations laid down in Pt 14 of the Act.170 One can say the same
of the buy-back disclosures required in Pt 2, which reinforce the
rules in Pt 18 of the Act. One might even take the same view of
Pt 6 of the Schedule, implementing for traded companies art.10
of the Takeover Directive on the disclosure of a company’s
control structures.171 Such disclosures facilitate takeover bids.
The strategic report
Rationale and history
21–24
Section 414A requires all companies, other than those benefiting
from the small companies regime,172 to produce an annual
strategic report (“SR”). The requirement for a SR reflects the
perception that shareholders and investors need more than
financial data to understand fully the prospects of the company.
They need also to be able to gauge the quality of the company’s
relationships with those upon whose contributions or
cooperation the success of the company depends (sometimes
called “stakeholders”). For stakeholders, as well, this
information may be useful, even if company law itself gives
them no particular platform from which to take action on the
basis of the information.173 As the CLR put it, “companies are
increasingly reliant on qualitative and intangible assets such as
the skills and knowledge of their employees, their business
relationships and their reputation. Information about future
plans, opportunities, risks and strategies is just as important as
the historical review of performance which forms the basis of
reporting at present”.174
The second argument for a broader review of the company by
the directors was the need to provide a check on the discharge by
directors of their “inclusive” duty175 to promote the success of
the company for the benefit of its members but on the basis of
taking into account the company’s need to foster its relationships
with stakeholders, its impact upon communities affected and
environmental and reputational concerns. This duty is
specifically referred to in s.414C(1). Thus, there was a close link
between the shareholder-centred statement of directors’ duties
recommended by the CLR and the desire to provide some
mechanism whereby its “enlightened” elements meant
something significant in practice and were not just self-serving.
Despite broad agreement on these principles, producing a
steady-state set of rules to implement them proved surprisingly
controversial. There have been three iterations of the rules,
which have come close to going around in a circle. The first set
of rules was recommended by the CLR under the name of an
Operating and Financial Review. At first, all seemed to be going
well with the OFR proposal. In fact, it was introduced by
regulation in 2005 under powers contained in the Companies Act
1985 in advance of the enactment of the 2006 Act,176 after
extensive consultation among those affected.177 Whilst the
companies affected were preparing their first OFRs, the then
Chancellor of the Exchequer, in a speech to the Confederation of
British Industry,178 and apparently after exiguous consultation
with the Department of Trade and Industry (the then name of the
governmental department responsible for company law),179
announced the repeal180 of the OFR on the grounds it was “a
gold-plated regulatory requirement”—but without showing any
appreciation of its place in the wider scheme of reforms
proposed by the CLR. The DTI, re-stating its commitment to
“strategic forward-looking narrative reporting”, then undertook
consultation on how far this commitment could be implemented
within what it called a Business Review requirement without
imposing on companies “unnecessary burdens”. However, the
coalition agreement of the government which took office in 2010
included a commitment to “reinstate” the OFR. The
implementation of that commitment gave us the current strategic
review. In the meantime, the EU legislature became more
involved in the area. The “management report” (in effect a DR)
required by arts 19 and 29 of the Directive (for individual and
group accounts respectively) contains some non-financial
requirements and in 2014 those requirements were strengthened
by an amending Directive, adding arts 19a and 29a to the 2013
Directive.181
Contents of the Strategic Review
21–25
Section 414C states that the purpose of the SR is to “inform
members of the company” and to help them assess whether the
directors have performed their duty under s.172 of the Act to
promote the success of the company for the benefit of its
members.182 Although placing the emphasis on the members ties
in well with the shareholder-centred focus of s.172, the CLR
proposed that the OFR should not be so narrowly targeted.183
Section 414C(2) requires the directors to produce a SR
containing a fair review of the company’s business and a
description of the principal risks and uncertainties facing it—or
them in the case of group accounts.184 The review required is “a
balanced and comprehensive” analysis of the development and
performance of the company’s business during the financial year
and of its position at the end of the year.185 To the extent that it is
necessary for an understanding of the business the review must
make use of “key performance indicators”, both financial and
non-financial.186 This is an attempt to inject some quantitative
analysis into what might otherwise be a set of generalities. These
parts of the section simply track art.19(1) the Directive, whose
requirements are indeed rather general.
For quoted companies187 the SR must deal with further
matters, largely as a matter of domestic law. At the most general
level, the company is required to describe its strategy and its
business model.188 Then the SR must address “to the extent
necessary for an understanding” of the company’s business189—
with KPIs where necessary—certain specific issues. The phrase
in quotes does not give the directors a discretion whether to deal
with a matter: it simply recognises that not all the additional
matters will be relevant to the businesses of all companies,
though few will not have to comment, for example, on the
employees. The list of additional matters potentially to be
commented on is:
(a) “the main trends and factors” likely to affect the future of the
company’s business;
(b) the impact of the company’s business on the environment;
(c) the employees;
(d) social, community and human rights issues.190
Finally, whether or not this is necessary to an understanding
of the company’s business, the SR must disclose the number of
persons of each sex who were (i) directors; (ii) senior managers;
and (iii) employees of the company. This is an example of
disclosure being used to promote the government’s diversity
policies, this time at senior levels in companies. The amending
Directive of 2014, operative from January 2017, requires some
expansion of the additional information to be provided by public
interest entities employing on average 500 employees over the
financial year, but it will not bring any novel departures from the
existing categories of additional disclosure. At the time of
writing the government is consulting on the potentially
significant move of confining all the additional elements of SR
reporting to companies with this number of employees.191
None of these provisions requires disclosure of impending
developments or matters in the course of negotiation if, in the
directors’ opinion, disclosure would be seriously prejudicial to
the interests of the company.192 Matters of strategic significance
which are required by regulation to be included in the DR may
be included instead, at the directors’ choice, in the SR, a move
likely to make discussion of strategic issues more coherent.193
Verification of narrative reports
21–26
There is a risk that narrative reporting requirements will produce
only self-serving and vacuous descriptions rather than analytical
material which is of genuine use to those who read the report.
There are two traditional ways of dealing with this issue in
relation to financial statements: audit and accounting standards.
The risk with applying audit to the DR and SR is that it will take
away from the desirability of those reports constituting the
directors’ view of the business rather than that of its auditors.
Consequently, the Act formerly restricted the audit requirement
for the DR and SR to certification that the reports were
consistent with the accounts (which are required to be audited).
Under the current version of the Act194 the auditor must state in
addition whether he has identified material misstatements in the
SR or DR (and describe their nature) in the light of the
knowledge of the company acquired in the course of the audit.
The auditor must also state whether the SR and DR have been
prepared in accordance with “applicable legal requirements”.
This phrase obviously covers statutory provisions but it also
raises the question whether there are professional standards for
these reports just as there are for the financial statements. The
OFR Regulations in fact contained the familiar requirement from
the accounts provisions that the Review must state whether it
had been prepared in accordance with the relevant reporting
standard and give reasons for any departure195; and a “reporting
standard” was defined, as with an accounting standard, as a
“statement of standard reporting practice” relating to OFRs and
issued by a body authorised by the Secretary of State, i.e. (then)
the Accounting Standards Board.196 The ASB duly produced its
reporting standard (RS 1) in May 2005. However, the Business
Review provisions contained no statutory underpinning for
reporting standards and so the ASB turned RS 1 into Reporting
Statement of best practice, changing its language so as to reflect
its new voluntary status, and that situation has continued with
the SR.197
Liability for misstatements in narrative reports
21–27
An alternative approach to verification is to impose liability ex
post for misstatements in narrative reports. There are two areas
of potential negligence liability to be considered. First, there is
liability on the part of the directors to the company under what is
now s.174 of the Act. Secondly, there is liability on the part of
the directors or the company (and conceivably others) to third
parties, including investors in the market, under the general law
on misstatements, whether negligent or fraudulent. However, the
extension of narrative reporting prompted reforms, now to be
found in s.463, whose aim is not to strengthen the ex post
liability regime but to circumscribe it. The case for providing a
“safe harbour” in relation to directors’ forward-looking
statements is that no one can predict the future with certainty and
if directors were to be exposed to litigation, or the threat of it,
whenever their forward-looking statements turned out to be
untrue, they would be very cautious in the statements they made
This caution might undermine the value of narrative reporting to
its users.198
Section 463, in fact, goes well beyond forward-looking
statements, apparently on the grounds that it would be difficult
to distinguish them from other types of statement. The section
applies to the entire content of the three narrative reports: DR,
SR and the directors’ remuneration report.199 The effect of s.463
is to exclude directors’ liability in negligence to the company
entirely. The director is so liable in respect of untrue or
misleading statements in the reports or omissions from them
only if the director has been fraudulent.200 Fraud is defined in the
way it is in the common law of deceit: the maker of the
statement must know it is untrue or misleading or be reckless as
to whether this is the case.201 Thus, a genuine belief in the truth
of the statement, no matter how unreasonable, will save the
director from liability.
21–28
If the directors’ liability to the company is preserved in the case
of fraud, their liability to other persons is excluded entirely, even
in the case of fraud.202 Moreover, the liability which is excluded
is the liability of “any person”, not just of the directors, provided
it is not a liability to the company. Thus, investors (including
existing shareholders) cannot impose liability on the company in
respect of unsuccessful investment decisions which are based on
inaccurate information in the narrative reports. It is in fact very
unclear whether, even without the section, liability in negligence
towards investors on the part of the company or the directors
would exist under the general law. The issue has been tested at
the highest levels only in respect of auditors, where, as we shall
see, the starting point of the courts is one of non-liability.203 The
exclusion of liability towards third parties in the case of fraud in
narrative reports is more questionable, since the common law
does impose liability in principle for fraud and it is unclear why
fraud should be condoned. In fact, however, the exclusion of
liability to third parties is qualified by the provisions of s.90A of
and Sch.10A to FSMA 2000, applying to companies with
securities traded on a regulated market, which imposes liability
in fraud on the company in relation to certain statements made to
the market (which might include the narrative reports).204
Section 463 excludes the third-party liability of “any person”,
but it is not clear who might be liable beyond the directors and
the company in respect of errors in the narrative reports. A
number of professionals may be consulted and have a hand in
the compilation of the reports but they are not normally
identified in those reports as responsible for particular parts of it
and thus as having particular statements attributed to them, since
the reports are the reports of the directors. However, if this did
occur, s.463 would protect these persons (other than in respect of
their liability to the company). The auditors are required to
report on the narrative reports to some extent, as we have seen,
but the auditor’s report is a separate document and so would not
be covered by s.463.
APPROVAL OF THE ACCOUNTS AND REPORTS BY THE DIRECTORS
21–29
That the narrative reports are the reports of the directors is
clear.205 The accounts as well are the product of the directors: the
directors must draw them up,206 although in this case, because of
the role played by the auditors in verifying the accounts and, in
practice, in drawing them up, they are often misconceived as the
auditors’ accounts. With the collapse of the Enron Company and
other companies renewed emphasis was placed on the directors’
responsibility for the accounts. At EU level the Fourth and
Seventh Directives were amended so as to impose on directors a
“collective duty” to ensure that the annual financial statements
and management report are drawn up in accordance with the
Directive or the IAS Regulation.207 The Government took the
view that this requirement was met by the existing domestic
provision that the annual accounts and narrative reports must be
approved by the directors and signed on behalf of the board by a
director or the secretary.208 If the directors approve accounts or
reports that do not comply with the Act, every director who
knows that they do not comply or is reckless as to whether or not
they comply and who fails to take reasonable steps to secure
compliance or to prevent the accounts being approved is guilty
of an offence.209
The Member States are also required to ensure that their
“laws, regulations and administrative provisions on liability” to
the company apply to the directors who breach their collective
duty.210 This provision does not require the Member States to
have any particular liability regime in place. In the case of the
UK this requirement is met presumably through the general law
on directors’ duties and, in the case of the narrative reports, by
the preservation of the directors’ liability in fraud to the
company.211
THE AUDITOR’S REPORT
21–30
The final document that has to accompany the annual accounts is
the auditor’s report thereon—assuming the company is one
which is required to have its accounts audited or has chosen to
do so. This has to be addressed to the company’s members212 and
to state whether in the auditors’ opinion on a number of matters,
notably whether the annual accounts have been properly
prepared in accordance with the Act or the IAS Regulation, as
appropriate and whether they give a true and fair view of the
company’s financial position.213 The rights and duties of the
auditor in the preparation of the audit report are considered more
fully in the following chapter. The auditors’ report must state the
names of the auditors and be signed by them.214 However, those
names need not appear on the published copies of the report or
on the copy filed with the Registrar (see below) if the company
has resolved that the names should not be stated on basis that
there are reasonable grounds for thinking that publication would
create a serious risk of violence to or intimidation of the auditor
or any other person, and has provided that information instead to
the Secretary of State.215
REVISION OF DEFECTIVE ACCOUNTS AND REPORTS
21–31
Despite the requirements for director and auditor approval, noted
above, it is not inconceivable that accounts and reports will be
produced by the company which are later discovered to be
incorrect. Until the passing of the Companies Act 1989 there
were no statutory provisions for revising incorrect accounts and
reports. However, it has never been doubted that, if directors
discover such defects, they can, and should, correct them.
Section 454 makes it clear that the directors may revise the
accounts and narrative reports on a voluntary basis. Where the
accounts have not yet been sent to the Registrar or the members
(see below), the directors have a pretty free hand as to revisions,
but if either of those events has occurred, as is likely, the
corrections must be confined to what is necessary to bring the
accounts and reports into line with the requirements of the Act or
the IAS Regulation.216 Regulations made under the section
provide that the revised accounts or reports become, as nearly as
possible, the reports and accounts of the company for the
relevant financial year, to which the other provisions of the Act
apply. For example, they will be subject to audit.217
More significant are the statutory powers to compel revision
of defective accounts. The Secretary of State has power to apply
to the court for a declaration that the accounts or the DR or SR
(but not, it seems, the remuneration report) do not comply with
the Act or the IAS Regulation and for an order that they be
brought into line, with consequential directions.218 The court
may order the costs of the application and of the production of
the revised accounts to be borne by the directors in place at the
time of the approval of the accounts or report, unless a director
can show that he or she took all reasonable steps to prevent
approval, though the court also has power to exclude from
liability a director who did not know and ought not to have
known of the defects.219 Notice of the application and of its
result must be given to the Registrar.220
However, in practice this is not an activity the Secretary of
State undertakes. There is power under s.457 for authorisation to
make applications to the court to be conferred upon persons
appearing to the Secretary of State “to have an interest in, and to
have satisfactory procedures directed to securing, compliance by
companies” with the Act and the IAS Regulation and “to have
satisfactory procedures for receiving and investigating
complaints” about annual accounts and the DR and SR and
otherwise to be “fit and proper”. Such authorisation is now
conferred on the Conduct Committee of the Financial Reporting
Council (“FRC”).221 In practice, the task of dealing with
defective reports is discharged by the Conduct Committee, rather
than by the Department, except in relation to small companies.222
The Committee has statutory authority to require the production
of documents, information and explanations if it thinks there is a
question-mark over the compliance of a company’s accounts or
reports with the Act or IAS Regulation.223 It must keep the
information received confidential, except for disclosure to a list
of approved recipients (relevant Government Departments and
Regulators).224
21–32
The FRRP, predecessor of the Conduct Committee, was
criticised for being reactive, i.e. acting only on complaints or
media revelations that a particular set of accounts was defective
rather than checking or investigating of its own motion. Partly
because of EU pressure to produce equivalent mechanisms in the
Member States for the enforcement of international accounting
standards, the FRRP agreed in 2002 to adopt a proactive review
policy,225 though it did not have to resort to a court order to
secure the necessary changes, a threat of an application being
enough. In 2014/15 the Conduct Committee reviewed the reports
of some 252 companies, sent letters raising queries to 76, and in
nine cases there was a restatement of the numbers in the
accounts or a significant change in disclosure policy.226
With regard to companies with securities traded on a regulated
market, the obligation to secure compliance with the periodic
reporting requirements of such companies (which include but
extend beyond the annual reports and accounts)227 is allocated by
EU law to the Financial Conduct Authority (“FCA”), but the
relevant Directive permits the FCA to delegate the tasks
conferred upon it.228 Accordingly, the Conduct Committee has
been authorised229 by the Secretary of State to keep under review
not only the accounts and reports required by the Act but also
those required under the provisions of the Transparency
Directive to be produced by companies whose securities are
traded on regulated markets. In this case, there is an obvious
need for close liaison with the FCA.230 The Conduct Committee
is under a duty to report its findings to the FCA in appropriate
cases and the FCA may expand the Conduct Committee’s
remit.231
FILING ACCOUNTS AND REPORTS WITH THE REGISTRAR
21–33
The statutory requirement to produce accounts and reports would
be of little use if there were no provisions for the information so
generated to reach the hands of those who might make use of it.
This is done in two ways under the Act: circulation to the
members (discussed below) and delivery of the accounts to the
Registrar.232 By delivery to the Registrar, the accounts and
reports become public documents.
Speed of filing
21–34
A source of complaint in the past has been the length of the gap
between the end of the financial year and the date laid down for
filing the accounts and reports with the Registrar. The CLR
thought that modern technology permitted speedier filing than
had been required in the past and recommended that the period
be reduced from seven to six months for public companies and
ten to seven for private companies.233 Section 442 implements
the former reform but only marginally reduces the private
company period (to nine months), which is a pity.234 For public
companies whose securities are traded on a regulated market235
the period for publication of the annual accounts and reports is
four months from the end of the financial year,236 though the
core elements in the accounts may have been made available
earlier through a preliminary public announcement of the results.
A linked source of complaint has been non-compliance with
the filing time-limits, though the UK’s record in this area is
superior to that of some Member States of the EU. The formal
sanctions are criminal liabilities on the directors and civil
penalties on the company. If the filing requirements are not
complied with on time, any person who was a director
immediately before the end of the time allowed is liable to a fine
and, for continued contravention, to a daily default fine, unless
the director can prove that he took all reasonable steps for
securing that the accounts were delivered in time.237
Furthermore, if the directors fail to make good the default within
14 days after the service of a notice requiring compliance, the
court, on the application of the Registrar or any member or
creditor of the company, may make an order directing the
directors or any of them to make good the default within such
time as may be specified and may order them to pay the costs of
and incidental to the application.238
To these criminal sanctions against directors, the Act adds
civil penalties against the company.239 The amount of the
penalty, recoverable by the Registrar, varies according to
whether the company is private or public and to the length of
time that the default continues; the minimum being £150 for a
private company and £750 for a public company when the
default is for not more than one month, and the maximum
£1,500 for a private and £7,500 for a public company when the
default exceeds six months.240 There are obvious attractions in
affording the Registrar an additional weapon in the form of a
penalty recoverable by civil suit to which there is no defence
once it is shown that accounts have not been delivered on time.
Presumably, the thought is that civil sanctions on the company
will put pressure on shareholders to intervene and secure
compliance on the part of the directors, but it is not clear how
effective this mechanism is. It may be that the shareholders
simply lose dividends as well as suffer from a failure on the part
of the directors to perform a duty intended to protect them.241 In
2014/15 the compliance rate was nearly 99 per cent across the
UK but nevertheless some 2,100 convictions for failure to file
accounts were obtained and late filing penalty worth over £81
million were issued (mainly in relation to private companies),
but it is not clear how much was collected.242
Modifications of the full filing requirements
21–35
Filing with the Registrar is such a sensitive issue precisely
because the information in the accounts and reports thus
becomes publicly available. The Act itself makes some
concessions to the fear of publicity in the case of small, medium-
sized and unlimited companies, by way of derogations from the
full filing regime. The full regime requires filing of the annual
accounts, the directors’ report, the strategic report and (in the
case of a quoted company) the directors’ remuneration report
and conceivably a corporate governance statement, and the
auditor’s report on those accounts and reports (assuming the
company is subject to audit).243 If the company has been required
to produce group accounts, then the full regime applies to both
the group and individual accounts.244 The balance sheet must
contain the name of the person who signed it on behalf of the
board.245 As we have noted along the way, some categories of
company are not required to produce the full range of these
accounts and reports, especially small and micro companies.
Naturally, they are not required to file a document they are not
required to produce. The issue here is whether directors are
required to give publicity to, i.e. file or file in full, a document
they are required to produce for their shareholders.
21–36
Unlimited companies are in principle exempt from filing any
accounts and reports, provided the unlimited company is not part
of a group containing limited companies and is not a banking or
insurance company.246 This is a good example of the link
between limited liability and public financial disclosure, i.e. the
latter is dispensed with if the former is not present.247 Of course,
the unlimited liability company still has to produce and circulate
accounts to the members, who have perhaps an even bigger
interest in the proper running of the company if their liability is
unlimited.
Small companies (and thus also micro companies) subject to
the small company regime are required to produce only
individual accounts and, in addition, they may choose to file
only a balance sheet and not the profit and loss account and
directors’ report though they may make more publicly available,
if they wish.248 Until recently, there was a further relaxation for
small companies in that the filed copy of the balance sheet (and
the filed copy of the profit and loss account, if one was filed at
all) were permitted to be less detailed than the accounts made
available to the members, at least where the company produces
Companies Act accounts. These were the so-called
“abbreviated” accounts.249 However, in 2015 changes were made
which withdrew this facility.250 The CLR would have required
small companies to file both balance sheet and profit and loss
account as prepared for the members. It took the view that the
filed accounts of small companies were “not meaningful”.251 The
general conclusion that little insight into the financial position of
a company subject to the small company regime will normally
be obtained from consulting its filed accounts probably remains
true, given that the option not to file a profit and loss account is
still available.
Other information available from the Registrar
21–37
The annual accounts and reports are probably the most important
documents filed with the Registrar252 and thus made public,
because they give reasonably current (though by no means
completely up-to-date) information about the company’s
financial position.253 However, the accounts and reports do not
constitute the whole of the information about the company
which is publicly available from the Registrar, as we see at
various points in this work. The next most important document
thus made available is probably the company’s constitution,
mainly its articles of association.254 After that is the list of the
company’s directors, which must be updated as changes occur.255
Amongst the other information available through the Registrar
are the list of those with significant economic interests in the
company,256 the address of its registered office,257 the amount of
its issued share capital258 and details of charges on its property.259
“Any person” has the right to inspect the register maintained
by the Registrar, subject to certain limited limitations imposed in
the interests of privacy.260 There is also a right to obtain a copy
of material on the register, subject to a fee,261 and a copy duly
certified by the Registrar is evidence in legal proceedings of
equal validity to the original.262 The applicant has the choice in
relation to the most central items of information to make the
request for inspection or copy electronically or in hard copy, and
to receive the information in either way.263
Confirmation statement
21–38
This document used to be called the “annual return” until the
current term was substituted by the Small Business, Enterprise
and Employment Act 2015. As the former name suggested, the
confirmation statement is produced each year by the company. It
is delivered to the Registrar by the company,264 but, unlike the
accounts and reports considered above, it is not a document sent
to the members. The Registrar is the principal addressee of the
annual return265 (though, of course, any member may access it
under the provisions discussed in the previous paragraph).
Nevertheless it is convenient to consider it here. Moreover, it is a
document required to be submitted by every company, whatever
its obligations as to accounts and reports.
The 2015 Act reduced the significance of the previous annual
return, which was already a rather historical document. The
annual return collated much information that should have been,
and probably had been, delivered to the Registrar when the
relevant transactions occurred, so that an enquirer might find it
unnecessary to search back beyond the latest annual return on
the file. Since the annual return was often reduplicative of
information already provided, the advantage to the company of
the confirmation statement is that it simply requires the company
to confirm to the Registrar that the information which the
company is under a duty to supply to the Registrar has already
been provided or is being provided along with the confirmation
statement. In the first case, the statement will be a bare
confirmation statement. Since we have noted at the appropriate
points in the book when information must be supplied by the
company to the Registrar, such as the statement of capital or the
statement of persons with significant control, we need not
rehearse those matters again here. With the 2015 reform, the
confirmation statement ceases to be a significant piece of
disclosure by the company and its main function is to jog the
corporate memory about its filing obligations. Despite the
criminal sanctions266 for non-compliance with the obligation to
provide a confirmation statement and provision by the Registrar
of electronic means for submitting it, companies are not always
prompt in complying with this obligation. In fact, failure to file
the annual return (or, in future, the confirmation statement) often
alerts the Registrar to more fundamental issues with the
company and may lead to the taking of steps which culminate in
the company’s removal from the register.
Other forms of publicity for the accounts and
reports
21–39
Although filing with the Registrar is the only form of publicity
for the annual accounts and reports mandated for all companies
by the Act, in fact large companies often, and other companies
sometimes, make their annual statements available more
generally; and quoted companies are now required to provide
website publication.267 Where a company chooses to make its
annual statements available in a way which is calculated to invite
members of the public generally, or a class of them, to read it,
then the Act requires the name of the person who signed the
balance sheet or the narrative reports on behalf of the company
to be stated.268 If a company publishes its accounts in this way,
they must be accompanied by the auditor’s report (if there is
one) and a company preparing group accounts cannot publish
only its individual accounts.269 In short, a non-quoted company is
not required to publish its annual accounts other than via the
Registrar, but if it does so, it must do so in full.
The accounts described above are known as the company’s
“statutory accounts”. A company is not prohibited from
publishing other accounts dealing with the relevant financial
year, thought this is in fact rare. If the company does so, it must
include with them a statement that these accounts are not the
statutory accounts and disclose whether the statutory accounts
have been filed and whether the auditors have reported on them
and, if so, whether the auditors’ report was qualified. Nor may
an auditors’ report on the statutory accounts be published with
the non-statutory accounts.270 If the company is listed on a
regulated market in the EU, it will be required by the
Transparency Directive271 to produce a set of (less elaborate)
accounts and a management report six months into the financial
year, as well as annual ones, though such accounts do not fall
into the category of “non-statutory accounts” because they do
not cover an entire financial year.
CONSIDERATION OF THE ACCOUNTS AND REPORTS BY THE
MEMBERS
Circulation to the members
21–40
Since the accounts and reports are communications from the
directors to the members, it is not surprising that the Act requires
their circulation to the members.272 However, not only the
members but also the company’s debenture-holders (i.e. its long-
term lenders holding the company’s debt securities)273 must
receive copies, since their chances of being repaid depend upon
the financial health of the company. Thirdly, so must anyone
who is entitled to receive notice of general meetings of the
company be sent the accounts and reports, a category which
includes the directors themselves (hardly a necessary
requirement) and anyone else entitled to notice under the
particular company’s articles.274 This obligation arises only if the
company has a current address for the person in question.275
Finally, those nominated to enjoy information rights will receive
copies of the accounts and reports.276 Just to make sure, the Act
also provides that shareholders and debenture-holders can at any
time demand copies of the most recent annual accounts and
reports and the company must comply with the request within
seven days.277
Circulation of the Strategic Report only
21–41
There are two linked problems with the circulation requirements.
First, the full accounts and reports may be grist to the mills of
the analysts, but lots of individual shareholders find the full set
more daunting than useful. Secondly, the circulation requirement
is an expensive one for the company to meet.278 Both these
concerns are addressed by the provisions which allow companies
to circulate something less than the full accounts and reports.
Initially, that something less was a “summary financial
statement”, but with the introduction of the strategic report,279
that document became the substitute.
This facility was previously available only to companies
whose securities were traded on certain public markets, but now
it is in principle open to all companies.280 Moreover, the burden
is on the recipient to ask to continue to receive the full accounts
and report. If, after being sent an appropriate notice from the
company, the recipient does not respond with a contrary
statement within 28 days, he or she will be deemed to have opted
for the summary, though that “choice” can be reversed at any
time.281 The provisions are, however, default rules, in the sense
that the company in its constitution or the instrument creating the
debentures may deprive itself of this facility. The right to make
use of the summary is also dependent on the company observing
the relevant provisions of the Act relating to the audit, filing and
approval of the full accounts and reports.282 The SR must be
accompanied by a warning that it is only part of the annual
accounts and reports; informing the reader how to obtain full
copies; stating whether any of the required auditor certifications
was qualified; and containing one (clearly important) figure from
outside the strategic report, i.e. the “single total remuneration”
figure from the directors’ remuneration report in the case of
quoted companies.283
An alternative, or additional, way, of addressing circulation
costs is to encourage members to receive communications
(whether full accounts and reports or only the SR) from the
company in electronic form or via the company’s website. This
has been discussed in Ch.15.284 A quoted company is in any
event required to put its current annual accounts and reports on
its website and to maintain it there throughout the following
financial year.285
Laying the accounts and reports before the
members
21–42
Circulating the accounts and reports to the members and others
allows them to consider them on an individual basis, but such
consideration is not likely to lead to significant action in the case
of companies with larger bodies of shareholders, unless there is
some facility for collective consideration of the accounts and
reports. As far as private companies are concerned, there is no
longer any statutory requirement for such collective
consideration, no matter how large a shareholding body that
company may have. A private company is required by the statute
to circulate its annual accounts and reports at the time it delivers
them to the Registrar,286 and any further action is a matter for the
shareholders or the company’s articles. The shareholders might
seek to convene a meeting287 or the articles might require annual
consideration of the accounts and reports at a meeting, which the
directors would be obliged to convene.
As far as public companies are concerned, the traditional
obligation “to lay the accounts and reports before a general
meeting” still applies.288 This formulation implies that the
shareholders are not required to consider a resolution to approve
the accounts and reports (as is the case in many countries), but
they must be afforded an opportunity to discuss them. Indeed,
this item on the agenda is normally used to allow a wide-ranging
discussion of the company’s business.289 The meeting at which
the accounts and reports are considered is termed the “accounts
meeting”290 and it is in fact normally the company’s annual
general meeting. The accounts and reports must be circulated at
least 21 days before the accounts meeting and the accounts
meeting itself must be held not later than the end of the period
for the filing of the accounts and reports with the Registrar, i.e.
six months after the end of the financial year in the case of a
public company. As we noted in Ch.15,291 the Government
backed away from the CLR’s proposal that, after circulation,
there should be a pause of two weeks, during which shareholders
could formulate, if they wished, resolutions on the accounts and
reports to be considered at the meeting.
CONCLUSION
21–43
Part 15 of the Act, dealing with the annual accounts and reports,
constitutes a substantial part of the Companies Act 2006, long
though that Act is. Part 15 contains nearly 100 sections, and this
is an indication of the central role played by annual reporting in
the structure of the companies legislation. Excessive though the
detail of the Act, subordinate legislation and accounting
standards is to anyone not an accountant, an understanding of the
central principles of the annual reporting process is central to
understanding the philosophy of company law.
The developments in this part of company law reflect very
well a broader trend in the subject towards greater refinement of
the applicable rules according to the economic importance of
different types of company. This classification proceeds broadly
by reference to direct indicators of economic size (turnover,
balance sheet total and number of employees) or by reference to
the divorce between ownership and control (i.e. whether the
shares are publicly traded) though this indicator is also
correlated with economic size. For the largest publicly traded
companies,292 not only is financial reporting increasingly
demanding, as International Financial Reporting Standards
expand their scope, but so are the demands of narrative
reporting. This expansion of reporting requirements is driven
substantially by investor demand but also in part by a
governmental desire to encourage investors (and in some cases
pressure-groups) to engage with the management of their
investee companies, even beyond what they might themselves
do, if left to their own devices. At the other end of the scale,
micro companies have obtained a further relaxation of the
relaxed rules which apply to small companies. In between,
medium-sized companies benefit from some relaxations whilst
large, but not publicly traded, companies are subject to broadly
the same reporting regime as publicly traded companies, but
have to cover less in their strategic report.
1 See Chs 16 and 17, above.
2
See Ch.20, above.
3 See Ch.14, above.
4 See para.15–8.
5 See below, para.21–14.
6 See Ch.22.
7
Notably the Fourth Council Directive on the Annual Accounts of Certain Types of
Companies, Directive 78/660/EEC ([1978] O.J. L222/110), as amended (hereafter
“Fourth Directive”) and the Seventh Council Directive on Consolidated Accounts,
Directive 83/349/EEC ([1983] OJ L193/1), as amended (hereafter “Seventh Directive”)
—both repealed by the 2013 Directive.
8
Regulation (EC) No.1606/2002 on the Application of International Accounting
Standards ([2002] O.J. L243/1) (hereafter “IAS Regulation”).
9
Directive 2003/51/EC ([2003] O.J. L178/16) (hereafter the “accounts modernisation
directive”), which amended the Fourth and Seventh Directives.
10
Directive 2013/34/EU [2013] O.J. L182/19.
11
As it was by Directive 2014/95/EU ([2014] O.J. L330/1) on the disclosure of non-
financial information.
12
See para.1–8.
13
2006 Act ss.384(1)(a) and 384B(1)(a).
14 Small Business Enterprise and Employment Act 2015 ss.33 and 34 envisage the use
of the micro and small business definitions in subordinate legislation to relieve these
categories of regulatory duties beyond the accounting area. If and when such regulations
are made, the domestic definitions might shift from the Act to these regulations, but the
controlling definitions would still be in the Directive.
15
2006 Act s.306(5) of the Act: “The balance sheet total means the aggregate of the
amounts shown as assets in the company’s balance sheet”, implementing art.3(11) of the
Directive.
16
“‘net turnover’ means the amounts derived from the sale of products and the provision
of services after deducting sales rebates and value added tax and other taxes directly
linked to turnover” (Directive art.2; Act s.474(1)). The Directive (art.3(12)) allows
Member States to add other items of income to the net turnover but the UK has chosen
not to do so.
17
Employed means only those employed under a contract of service (s.306(6)).
18 Other than charities and financial companies which are excluded from the micro
regime: s.384B.
19 2006 Act s.384A. The slightly odd amounts result from the translation into pounds of
the more rounded figures set out in art.3 of the Directive, i.e. €350,000 and €700,000
respectively. The Member State not using the euro can adjust the figure upwards or
downwards by 5 per cent when translating into their own currencies. The UK
government chose to increase the number resulting from a strict application of the
exchange rate, i.e. so as to increase the number of companies covered.
20 2006 Act s.384B(2). On group accounts see below para.21–9.
21 2006 Act s.384A(3). By way of qualification to this, in its first year of operation the
company’s status is determined by whether it meets the criteria at the end of that year
(s.384A(2)), so that a small start-up does not have to wait for a second year to benefit.
22 Directive 2012/6/EU [2012] O.J. L81/3, whose provisions are now incorporated into
the 2013 Directive.
23
BIS, Simpler Financial Reporting For Micro-Entities: The UK’s Proposal To
Implement The “Micros Directive”: Government Response, September 2013
(BIS/13/1124).
24
2006 Act s.382.
25
2006 Act s.382(2).
26
BIS, UK implementation of the EU Accounting Directive: Chapters 1-9: Impact
Assessment, 2014 (BIS/14/1055).
272006 Act s.384(1). The definition of ineligibility for groups includes a somewhat
wider range of financial companies (s.384(2)).
28
2006 Act s.465(3).
29
2006 Act s.467(1).
30
Developing, para.8.35.
31 Directive art.3.
32 Directive 2013/34/EU art.2. For the meaning of a “regulated” market see para.25–8.
In the UK the principal such market is the Main Market of the London Stock Exchange,
but a company will be a PIE if it is traded on such a market anywhere in the EU.
33 2006 Act s.474(1).
34 This is achieved by excluding “traded companies” from medium-sized status
(s.467(2)(a)). Since public companies may not be small or micro companies (above,
para.21–2) and private companies may not offer their securities to the public, explicit
exclusion from only medium-sized status is necessary.
35
Such a preliminary statement used to be obligatory for listed companies, but ceased to
be so in January 2007, in the light of the implementation of the Transparency Directive,
though companies continue to make such announcements and the Listing Rules regulate
the form they must take, if made. See LR 9.7A.1 and Ch.26, below.
36
2006 Act ss.386–389.
372006 Act s.386(3) adds certain specific requirements the records must meet, but,
except for unsophisticated businesses, the general standards are likely to be more
important.
38 e.g. because it is a foreign subsidiary or a partnership.
39 2006 Act s.386(5).
40
Punishable by fine or imprisonment or both: s.387(3).
41 2006 Act s.387(2).
422006 Act s.498(2). Failure to keep adequate accounting records could also form the
basis of a disqualification of a director under the general heading of unfitness (Re
Galeforce Pleating Co Ltd [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 705).
43 For this reason, accountants may not exercise a lien for unpaid fees over such
documents: DTC (CNC) Ltd v Gary Sargeant & Co [1996] 1 B.C.L.C. 529. Of course,
other persons may also have the right of access to the records, for example, the
company’s auditors: s.499.
44 e.g. because the company has a branch outside Great Britain.
45
2006 Act s.388(2),(3). The six-monthly requirement seems remarkably lax in the light
of both modern management practice and modern electronic technology.
46
2006 Act s.388(4). An officer of the company is liable to imprisonment or a fine or
both if he fails to take all reasonable steps to secure compliance with the preservation
requirement or intentionally causes any default: s.389(4). If there has been villainy,
destroying all record of it is all too likely.
47
2006 Act s.391(4). For companies in Northern Ireland the relevant date is 22 August
1997. For methods of determining the ARD for earlier incorporations see s.391(2),(3).
48
2006 Act s.292. This section applies no matter when the company was incorporated.
49
Indeed, in this particular situation, in order to promote the production of group
accounts, the directors of the parent company are under a presumptive duty to ensure
that the financial years of subsidiaries coincide with that of the parent: s.390(5).
50
2006 Act s.392(2).
51
2006 Act s.392(5), unless an administration order is in force in relation to the
company, presumably because the administrator, who is responsible to the court, can be
trusted in a way the directors cannot.
52
2006 Act s.392(3), unless an administration order is in force (see previous note) or the
step is taken to make the ARD coincide with that of an EEA undertaking which is the
company’s parent or subsidiary company, or the Secretary of State permits it.
53
2006 Act s.390(2),(3).
54
The exception for dormant subsidiaries is discussed in para.21–10.
55 2006 Act s.404(1).
56 2006 Act s.383(1).
57 2006 Act s.383(4)–(7). The choice is available separately in relation to each of the
turnover and balance sheet tests: s.383(6).
58
2006 Act ss.399(2A) and 384(2)(a). For the meaning of a “traded company” see
para.21–6, above. The other accounting advantages of being a “small” company
continue to be unavailable to “small” public companies.
59 2006 Act s.384B(2).
60 2006 Act s.466.
61
2006 Act s.399(2)—“as well as producing individual accounts”. Section 408 permits
certain relaxations for the individual accounts of a company which produces group
accounts, notably that the company’s individual profit and loss account need not be
circulated to the shareholders or filed with the Registrar, if notes to the group accounts
show the profit and loss of the company for the financial year.
62 2006 Act s.394—“the directors of every company”.
63
2006 Act s.407. However, this section does not apply if the parent uses IAS for both
the consolidated and its individual accounts. For the meaning of “financial reporting
framework” see para.21–13.
64
2006 Act ss.394A–C. Even so, the usual financial companies cannot take advantage
of the exemption nor may a dormant subsidiary which at any time in the relevant
financial year has been a traded company (see para.21–6, above). All this may seem
rather elaborate for exempting a company from producing individual accounts when, by
definition (see s.1169), it has engaged in no significant accounting transactions during
the financial year. At times the authorities have considered a wider policy of exempting
subsidiaries generally from producing individual accounts in exchange for a parent
company guarantee. However, the policy has always failed on the basis that it would
reduce the amount of information available about the activities of potentially
economically important subsidiaries.
65 Nevertheless, it is crucial to remember that dividends are paid on the basis of only
individual accounts alone. If the profits of a subsidiary are paid directly to the
shareholders of the parent, all sorts of legal problems arise. See Ch.12, fn.24.
66
2006 Act s.1161(1).
67
2006 Act s.399(2).
68
2006 Act s.1162(2)(a).
692006 Act s.1162(2)(b). Membership includes “indirect” membership, i.e. where a
subsidiary of the parent is a member of the undertaking in question: s.1162(3).
70
2006 Act s.1162(2)(c) and Sch.7 para.4. This situation of “contractual subordination”
is probably never found in the UK, though it is provided for in Germany, where,
however, it is rarely found in practice. See paras 9–21 et seq. There would be great
difficulties with the legality of such a contract under the law of the UK.
712006 Act s.1162(4). This is a reference to actual domination and the qualifications
needed to establish contractual domination do not apply here: Sch.7 para.4(3).
72 This brings in shareholder agreements which are an established way of exercising
control over companies in some continental European jurisdictions, but note that the
effect of the agreement must be to give the alleged parent sole control.
732006 Act s.1162(5). For this reason it is important that the section refers to parent
undertakings, since the immediate parent of the indirect subsidiary might not itself be a
company.
74 See, for example, paras 4–6 of Sch.4 to the Large and Medium-Sized Companies and
Groups (Accounts and Reports) Regulations 2008 (SI 2008/410, as amended) requiring a
company’s individual accounts to give certain information about companies in which the
reporting company has a “significant holding”—defined as 20 per cent or more of any
class of shares in the other company. Similar rules apply to group accounts (para.20–22)
with more detail being required in the cases where the “significant holding” makes the
other company an “associated” undertaking or a joint venture with the reporting
company (paras 18–19).
75 2006 Act ss.400(1)(a) and 401(1)(a).
76 2006 Act ss.400(1)(b) and 401(1)(b).
77 It does not matter whether the allotted shares carry voting rights or not, but unless the
“parent” undertaking controls 50 per cent of the voting rights, it will not be under an
obligation to produce consolidated accounts in any event. See below. In effect, the
requirement to hold 50 per cent of the allotted share capital means that the parent
company, which passes the 50 per cent figure by holding weighted voting rights in the
subsidiary, will have access to the exemption only if the parent also holds non-voting
shares in sufficient quantities.
78
2006 Act ss.400(1)(c) and 401(1)(c).
79
See para.21–6, above.
80
Of course, those investors may also be strongly interested in the traded company’s
relations with its parent, for fear that the parent may seek to take a disproportionate share
of the company’s earnings. But that is a different issue.
81
2006 Act ss.400(2)(a)–(b), 401(2)(a)–(c). The requirement for audit is stated
expressly in relation only to non-EEA parent companies, but in the case of EEA
companies this requirement follows from the provisions of the Audit Directive (see
Ch.22, below).
82
2006 Act ss.400(2)(c)–(d), 401(2)(d)–(e).This is not necessarily its immediate holding
company, since that company, by operation of the same rules, might be exempt from the
need to produce consolidated accounts. Thus, where there is a chain of three wholly-
owned subsidiaries, only the top company will normally have to produce consolidated
accounts.
83 2006 Act ss.400(2)(e)–(f), 401(2)(f)–(g).
84 2006 Act s.405.
85
2006 Act s.402.
86
See fn.7, above.
87 2006 Act s.395. A company which is a charity must provide Companies Act
individual and group accounts: ss.395(2) and 403(3).
88
See para.21–6. By virtue of s.407 (above, fn.63) there is some pressure to use IAS for
the individual accounts of group companies as well.
89 IAS Regulation art.4. Since the Regulation is directly applicable in the Member
States, the provisions of art.4 are not reproduced in the Act, though s.403(1) refers to the
EU obligation. In fact, IAS accounts are mandatory on a wider basis than the Regulation
suggests because the London Stock Exchange requires EEA-incorporated companies
traded on the Alternative Investment Market to use them as well: LSE, Aim Rules for
Companies, 2014, r.19.
90
IAS Regulation art.5.
91 2006 Act s.403.
92 2006 Act ss.395(3)–(4B) and 403(4)–(5B). The changes identified in the Act, and
they are apparently exclusive, are becoming a subsidiary of a company which does not
prepare IAS accounts and the company or its parent ceasing to have securities traded on
a regulated market: ss.395(4) and 403(5). Until 2012 the company always had to show a
relevant change of circumstance in order to revert to Company Act accounts.
93 2006 Act ss.395(5) and 403(6).
94
2006 Act s.393(1).
95 2006 Act s.393(1). The strength of UK commitment to this principle is demonstrated
by the modifications to it which were thought necessary when micro companies were
relieved of compliance with many standards. See para.21–17.
96 2013 Directive art.4(3) and, for Companies Act accounts, ss.396(4) and 404(4) (for
individual and group accounts respectively).
97
2013 Directive art.4(4) and ss.396(5) and 404(5).
98
2006 Act s.393(1) applies but not ss.396 and 405.
99
If this is not the case, then there is a flat contradiction between the requirements of
s.393 and art.4 of the Directive, on the one hand, and the obligations of companies under
the IAS accounting framework. Furthermore, the Commission is to endorse an IAS for
use in the EU only if it considers it will result in a true and fair view (Regulation, Recital
9). The FRC strongly argues that “true and fair” remains fully applicable to IAS
accounts: FRC, True and Fair, June 2014.
100
See International Accounting Standard 1 and Financial Reporting Standard 18.
101
For the definition of these terms see para.25–6 and 25–9.
102
LR 9.8.6(3).
103FRC, Guidance on Risk Management, Internal Control and Related Financial and
Business Reporting, September 2014.
104
2006 Act s.396. See the similar s.404(1) for group accounts.
105
Theoretical because what the shareholders will actually receive is what a buyer of the
business is willing to pay for it.
106
We saw at para.9–6 that this situation may induce directors responsive to shareholder
interests to embark on projects with a low chance of a high return and high chance of
making a loss.
107SI 2008/409 (hereafter the “Large Accounts Regulations”). They were previously in
Schedules to the 1985 Act.
108 SI 2008/410 (hereafter the “Small Accounts Regulations”).
109 Schedule 6 makes some additional provisions in relation to group accounts.
110
Regulations Sch.1 para.2.
111
Regulations Sch.1 para.10.
112
See Sch.1 Pt 2 ss.C and D. The introduction of “fair value accounting” into the
Fourth and Seventh Directives was effected by Directive 2003/53/EC ([2003] O.J. L178)
as a direct result of the adoption by the EU of the IAS for companies on regulated
markets, where this approach was required. See now art.8 of the 2013 Directive. In this
way, IAS have expanded as well the scope of action of purely domestic standard-setters.
113
In that year the Institute of Chartered Accountants in England and Wales began to
issue Recommendations on Accounting Principles.
114
See para.21–14, above.
115 Ibid. The implementing domestic provision is s.396(2A).
116 2006 Act s.393(1A).
117 Lloyd Cheyham & Co v Littlejohn & Co [1987] B.C.L.C. 303; but cf. Bolitho v City
and Hackney Health Authority [1998] A.C. 232 HL (court not bound by professional
standards where “in a rare case” it is convinced they are not reasonable or responsible).
118Large Accounts Regulations Sch.1 para.45. Medium-sized companies are exempt
from this obligation (see reg.4(2A)) and the Small Accounts Regulations 2008 do not
contain a impose a similar rule.
119
For its use in relation to the Corporate Governance Code, which was developed only
in the 1990s, see above at para.14–69.
120
Now s.464 of the 2006 Act. The current arrangements are set out in the Statutory
Auditors (Amendment of Companies Act 2006 and Delegation of Functions etc) Order
2012/1741. Previously, the delegation was directly to an Accounting Standards Board
which was a subsidiary of the FRC.
121
See FRC, Plan and Budget and Levies 2015/16, March 2015. Section 17 of the
Companies (Audit, Investigation and Community Enterprise) Act 2004 gives the
Secretary of State the power to make the levy binding, but currently the levy is paid on a
“voluntary” basis.
122
Above, fn.8.
123
IAS Regulation art.2.
124
Thus, in the current Directive art.13(2) permits the use of a “statement of
performance”, as required by IAS, rather than a profit and loss account, whilst art.8(6)
permits derogations from the Directive’s fair value rules in order to facilitate compliance
with IAS.
125 Both Large (regs 3 and 9) and Small (regs 3 and 8) Accounts Regulations exempt
companies from the operation of their Schs 1 (individual accounts) and 6 (group
accounts) if they use IAS. Of course, a small company need not produce group accounts
at all (see para.21–9) but may choose to do so.
126 Companies using IAS shall produce their accounts “in conformity with the
international accounting standards”: Regulation arts 4 and 5.
127
Currently termed the IFRS Foundation.
128
The role of the Monitoring Board is described at:
http://www.iasplus.com/en/resources/ifrsf/governance/monitoring-board [Accessed 27
April 2016].
129 IAS Regulation arts 3 and 6.
130 IAS Regulation art.3(2).
131
See para.21–14, above.
132 Commission Regulation (EC) No.2086/2004. The IASB later amended IAS 39 and
one of the carve outs was dropped (Commission Regulation (EC) No.1864/2005), the
hedge fund carve out remaining. The economic crisis has continued to keep this issue at
the forefront of regulators’ attention.
133 The current state of play on endorsement is given by EFRAG, The EU endorsement
status report, April 2012.
134Among the countries, outside the EU, which allow or require their companies to use
IFRS are Australia, India, Japan and South Korea.
135 The FRC also has a policy of producing convergence with IAS, so that in the end
there may be relatively little difference between Companies Act and IAS accounts,
though the IASB would be in the lead.
136 See above, para.21–6
137
See below, para.21–36.
138
Small Accounts Regulations Sch.1 Pt 1 para.1A.
139
The FRC’s had previously operated a separate Financial Reporting Standard for
Smaller Entities (“FRSSE”). The Directive required a change of approach but not of
principle. See FRC, Accounting Standards for Small Enterprises: Consultation
Document, September 2014 and Consultation Overview, February 2015. For the IASB,
see IFRS for SMEs (“International Financial Reporting Standards for Small and
Medium-sized Enterprises”).
140
See BIS, Simpler Financial Reporting For Micro-Entities: The UK’s Proposal To
Implement The “Micros Directive”: Government Response, September 2013. The
exception was the decision not to take up the option to relieve micro companies from the
obligation to use accrual accounting. Cash accounting was thought to be potentially
misleading: for example, pre-payments received in year 1 would show up without off-
setting costs where the supply of the good or service was not due until year 2 (when the
costs would show up without the associated income). The Directive itself prohibits
micro companies benefitting from the derogations from using fair value accounting:
art.36(3).
141 2006 Act s.394B(2)(b); see para.21–3, above.
142
For the FRC see Draft FRS 105 The Financial Reporting Standard applicable to the
Micro-entities Regime, discussed in the documents cited in fn.139, above.
143Unless it is a micro company, the company may, but is not required to, put them in a
separate document annexed to the accounts: s.472.
144
The Directive makes no derogation for IAS accounts, but in that case the notes
requirements may be found in the international standards themselves rather than in
domestic law transposing the Directive.
145Much of the information required to be disclosed in notes under Pt 3 of Sch.1 to the
Large and Small Accounts Regulations 2008 is of this character.
146Above, fn.74. This part of the Regulations is made under ss.409 and 410 of the Act
and extends to information about subsidiaries as well as about affiliates.
1472006 Act s.410A, introduced in 2008, in the wake of the Enron collapse in the US
which was in part brought about by the acquisition of liabilities by Special Purpose
Vehicles (“SPVs”) connected with Enron but not counting as its subsidiaries.
148The option is provided by art.36(1)(b). It is implemented in the UK in the Small
Regulations reg.5A. The matters still required to be disclosed in the notes to micro
companies’ accounts relate to contingent liabilities and capital commitments: Sch.3
para.57.
149 2013 Directive art.16(2) and (3).
150BIS, UK Implementation of the EU Accounting Directive, August 2014
(BIS/14/1025).
151For smaller companies such disclosure might give competitors valuable information
which could be used to undermine the company’s business.
152 Above, paras 16–54 et seq.
153
Above, Ch.20.
154
Small Companies Regulations Sch.1 para.66; Large Companies Regulations Sch.1
para.72. The requirements are applied more stringently to large than medium or small
companies. These provisions apply formally only to companies preparing Companies
Act accounts, but those preparing IAS accounts are under a similar obligation because of
the provisions in IAS 24 (Related Party Disclosures). The two are further tied together
by the adoption in paras 66 and 72 of the same definition of “related party” as in the IAS
—though unhelpfully it does not reproduce it. IAS 24.9 defines a related party widely so
as to include controlling shareholders as well as directors.
155 A typical statement (in this case from BIS, The Future of Narrative Reporting:
Consultation, September 2011 (BIS/11/945)) is: “Narrative reporting provides an
important link between companies and their investors and wider stakeholders. It is a key
element in the framework that allows investors to hold companies to account, both in
terms of achieving sustainable long term returns and on the impact of the business to
society and the environment.” So, reporting is presented as addressed to stakeholders as
well as investors, but only investors are mentioned in relation to accountability.
156
See below, para.21–24.
157
BIS, UK Implementation of the EU Accounting Directive, Chapter 10: Consultation,
March 2014, p.4 (BIS/14/622).
158
On the assumption that bribes do not increase the overall costs of the company but
rather are recovered by a lower formal contractual payment to the foreign government.
There may be some marginal gains to the company from operating in countries which
have less corruption.
159
See the Reports on Payments to Government Regulations 2014/3209, implementing
Ch.10 of the Directive.
160 At paras 14–44 et seq.
161
2006 Act s.415(1A).
162
2006 Act s.415A and contrast Sch.5 to the Small Companies Regulations with Sch.7
to the Large Companies Regulations.
163 2006 Act s.416(1).
164 2006 Act s.416(3).
165 2006 Act s.415A. For the meaning of “ineligible” companies see above, para.21–4.
166 Large Companies Regulations Sch.7 para.7.
167
This information may be laid out in the strategic report (below) instead.
168This disclosure and disclosure of political donations are required also of small
companies: Small Companies Regulations Sch.5.
169 See para.21–6, above.
170
See para.17–29, above. Until recently the amount of charitable donations had to be
stated as well.
171 See para.28–25, below.
172 The requirements are relaxed for medium-sized companies, but not excluded
entirely. A small company excluded from the small company regime because a member
of an ineligible group may also take advantage of this exemption: s.414B.
173
Trade unions might use the information in collective bargaining with the company or
they and other stakeholders might use it in making representations to government or
taking other sorts of political action.
174
Final Report I, para.3.33.
175
See above at paras 16–37 et seq.
176
Companies Act 1985 (Operating and Financial Review and Directors’ Report etc.)
Regulations 2005 (SI 2005/1011).
177
DTI, The Operating and Financial Review and Directors’ Report: A Consultative
Document, May 2004 (URN 04/1003).
178
Speech by the Rt. Hon. Gordon Brown MP, Chancellor of the Exchequer, at the CBI
Annual Conference in London, 28 November 2005.
179Somewhat more is known about the internal workings of government on this issue
than might be expected as a result of documents produced in judicial review proceedings
brought by Friends of the Earth over the abolition decision. See Financial Times, UK
Edition, 8 March 2006.
180Effected by the Companies Act 1985 (Operating and Financial Review) (Repeal)
Regulations 2005 (SI 2005/3442).
181
Directive 2014/95/EU [2014] O.J. L330/1.
182 Above at para.16–37.
183Completing, para.3.33. Thus, non-shareholders would have been included among the
addresses of the OFR.
184 2006 Act s.414C(13).
185 2006 Act s.414C(3).
186
2006 Act s.414C(4)(5), unless the company qualifies as medium-sized, or would do
were it not for the fact that it is a member of an ineligible group, in which case it need
not use KPIs in relation to non-financial matters: ss.414C(6) and 467(4).
187 2006 Act s.385. This definition includes not only companies included on the “official
list” in an EU state (see para.25–9) but also those UK-incorporated companies traded on
the New York Stock Exchange or Nasdaq. Nevertheless, this is a narrower set than
proposed by the CLR which wished to apply the OFR requirement to most public and
some large private companies as well.
188 2006 Act s.414C(8)(a)(b).
189 2006 Act s.414C(7).
190
The BR required information about supply chains and out-sourcing arrangements
(s.417(5)(c)). This was highly controversial because it was introduced only at a very late
stage in Parliament, though it had been part of the OFR. It has not made its way into the
SR.
191
BIS, The Non-Financial Reporting Directive, BIS/16/35, February 2016. Since
companies traded on a regulated market fall within the definitions of both “quoted
company” and “public interest entity”, the main impact of the change would be to
remove the higher level reporting requirement from quoted companies with fewer than
500 employees. The consultation document also floats the proposal to allow some of the
non-financial reporting to be released on a more relaxed time-table than that for the
annual accounts.
192
2006 Act s.414C(14).
193
2006 Act s.414C(11).
194
2006 Act s.496. This tracks art.35 of the Directive. The expanded audit requirement
is more in line with what the CLR proposed: Final Report I, para.8.63.
195 OFR Regulations reg.8.
196
OFR Regulations reg.11.
197
FRC, Guidance on the Strategic Report, June 2014. The question of developing
reporting standards for the DR seems never to have been actively pursued.
198
CLR, Final Report I, para.8.38.
199 2006 Act s.463(1). The inclusion of the remuneration report is particularly bizarre,
since it requires statements of policies but very little in the way of forward-looking
statements. See paras 14–44 et seq.
2002006 Act s.463(2),(3). The liability excluded is only the liability to compensate the
company, though it will be rare for any other liability to be in issue.
201Recklessness means making the statement not caring whether it is true or untrue,
accurate or misleading: Derry v Peek (1889) L.R. 14 App. Cas. 337 HL. In the case of
omissions there must be “a dishonest concealment of a material fact”.
2022006 Act s.463(4),(5). The liability here excluded is not confined to liability to
compensate but embraces any civil remedy, including self-help remedies.
203
See para.22–44.
204 See below at para.26–25.
205 See ss.414A, 415 and 420: directors’ duties to prepare narrative reports.
206 2006 Act ss.394 and 399.
207 Now art.33 of the Directive.
208 2006 Act ss.414(1), 414D(1) and 419(1). Section 419A imposes the same duty in
relation to the corporate governance report, if it is a separate document, but lays down
no specific penalties for non-compliance.
2092006 Act s.414(4),(5), 414D(2)(3) and 419(3)(4). This re-states the previous law
somewhat more simply by dropping the requirement that the director be a party to the
approval and presuming the existing directors to be parties.
210 2013 Directive art.33(2).
211 See above, para.21–27.
212 2006 Act s.495(1).
213
See para.22–3 for more detail.
214 2006 Act s.503.
215 2006 Act s.506. The reasons for this measure or secrecy in relation to the auditors are
the same as those which led to the suppression of public information about directors’
residential addresses: see above at para.14–23.
216
2006 Act s.454(2).
217
Companies (Revision of Defective Accounts and Reports) Regulations 2008/373 (as
amended).
218
2006 Act s.456(1)–(3).
219 2006 Act s.456(5)–(6).
220
2006 Act s.456(2)–(7).
221
Supervision of Accounts and Reports (Prescribed Body) and Companies (Defective
Accounts and Directors’ Reports)(Authorised Person) Order 2012/1439 reg.4.
Previously, the task was delegated to the Financial Reporting Review Panel.
222 Where Companies House takes the lead: CLR, Completing, para.12.48.
223 2006 Act s.459.
224
2006 Act ss.460–462.
225
DTI, Final Report of the Co-ordinating Group on Audit and Accounting Issues, URN
03/567, paras 4.11 et seq. Such a policy, including the identification of “priority sectors”
for review, has been developed and since 2006 the FRRP included the directors’ report,
and so the business review, in its activities.
226 FRC Corporate Reporting Review 2014, pp.7–9. The restatement occurs in the
following year’s accounts.
227
These requirements are discussed in Ch.26, below.
228
Directive 2004/109/EC art.24 (the Transparency Directive).
229 See fn.221, made in part under s.14 of the Companies (Audit, Investigations and
Community Enterprise) Act 2004. The tests laid down in s.14 of the 2004 Act are similar
to those contained in s.457 of the 2006 Act.
230The FRRP concluded a “memorandum of understanding” with the FSA in 2005
about their joint working, which is available on the FRRP website. Indeed, there was
some debate at the time as to whether these powers should not be retained by the FCA.
231 2006 Act s.14(2),(7). The Conduct Committee’s power to apply for a court order
appears to be limited to annual accounts and reports only (s.456(1)), so that it would fall
to the FCA to take action in respect of the semi-annual reports required of companies on
regulated markets.
232 2004 Act s.441.
233
CLR, Final Report I, paras 4.49–4.32 and 8.80 et seq.
234 2006 Act s.442 deals with some exceptional cases as well.
235See para.25–8, essentially those traded on the Main Market of the London Stock
Exchange.
236
See FCA, Disclosure and Transparency Rule 4.1.3, implementing art.4 of the
Transparency Directive 2004/109/EC. See Ch.26, below.
237
2006 Act s.451. But, to spike the guns of barrack-room lawyers, it is expressly stated
that it is not a defence to prove that the documents required were not in fact prepared in
accordance with the Act!
238
2006 Act s.452. If they fail to do so, they will be in contempt of court and liable to
imprisonment. The subsection does not say who may serve such a notice so presumably
anyone can: but in practice it is likely to be the Registrar who does so—though the
subsection makes it pretty clear that a member or creditor could.
239
2006 Act s.453 and the Companies (Late Filing Penalties) and Limited Liability
Partnerships (Filing Periods and Late Filing Penalties) Regulations 2008/497.
240
The Scheme withstood judicial review in R. (Pow Trust) v Registrar of Companies
[2003] 2 B.C.L.C. 295.
241
The company could, presumably, sue the directors to recover its loss resulting from
their default. But unless the company goes into liquidation, administration or
receivership this is unlikely to happen.
242Companies House, Statistical Tables on Companies Registration Activities 2014/15,
Tables A7, A8 and D2. Curiously, late filing does not appear to be prosecuted in
Scotland.
243 2006 Act ss.446 and 447.
244 2006 Act s.471.
245
See above, para.21–30.
246
2006 Act s.448. There are certain other disqualifications set out in the section.
247The same distinction can be found between partnerships (accounts need not be made
public) and limited liability partnerships (public disclosure required).
248
2006 Act s.444(1). On the exemption from group accounts see para.21–9. Small
companies excluded from the small companies regime because a member of an
ineligible group may choose not to file a directors’ report, but must file a profit and loss
account: s.444A.
249 2006 Act s.444(3)—as originally enacted.
250 Companies, Partnerships and Groups (Accounts and Reports) Regulations 2015/980
reg.8. This step was less radical than it might seem at first sight, since a small company
may prepare (and therefore publish) abbreviated accounts if all shareholders agree (see
para.21–20) and, even if they do not, the disclosure requirements of the Small
Regulations are much less demanding than those of the Large Regulations. These
regulations also removed the facility for medium-sized companies to file an abbreviated
profit and loss account (previously in s.445(3)(4)).
251
CLR, Developing, paras 8.32–8.34. Although using the term “abbreviated accounts”,
the CLR appears to include in it the option not to file a profit and loss account at all. The
CLR would have dealt with small company sensitivities through the simplified format
rules for the accounts prepared for the members.
252
Actually, there are three Registrars—one for each of the UK jurisdictions—though
their functions are similar: s.1060.
253 Hence with companies whose securities are traded on a regulated market the
obligation on the company (a) to produce reports more often than annually and (b) to
report material changes as they occur. See Ch.26, below.
254
See para.3–13.
255 See para.14–23. Also to be disclosed is the identity of the company’s secretary, if
there is one: s.276.
256
See para.2–42.
257
See ss.9(5)(a) and 86–87. This is important because it is there that legal process can
be served on it.
258
See para.11–11. The returns of allotments will show to whom the shares were
initially issued but not who now owns them.
259
See Ch.32. This is likely to be more up-to-date than the filed accounts and so a better
indicator of creditworthiness.
260 See ss.1085 and 1087, the latter excluding access, for example, to directors’
residential addresses (see para.14–23).
261
2006 Act s.1086.
262 2006 Act s.1091(3).
263 2006 Act ss.1089 and 1090. The information in relation to which this right exists is
set out in s.1078, which implements art.3 of the First Company Law Directive
(68/151/EEC) as amended by Directive 2003/58/EC art.1.
2642006 Act s.853A. The return date is normally the anniversary of the company’s
incorporation.
265
Hence the provisions about the confirmation statement are set out in a separate Part
of the Act (Pt 24).
266 2006 Act s.853L: offence by company, every director, shadow director and secretary,
and every other officer who is in default. Compliance with the annual return requirement
was about one percentage point less than for the accounts filing requirement. Some
1,200 directors were convicted of this offence in 2014/15 in England and Wales: above
fn.242, Tables A7 and D2.
267 2006 Act s.430 and para.21–40.
268 2006 Act ss.433 and 436.
269 2006 Act s.434.
270
2006 Act s.435.
271See Ch.26, below. This aspect of the Directive is implemented in the UK by
Disclosure and Transparency Rule 4.2, made by the Financial Conduct Authority.
272 2006 Act s.423(1). The content of the “annual accounts and reports” is specified in
s.471(2) separately for unquoted and quoted companies.
273 See Ch.31, below.
274 2006 Act s.307. In the case of companies without share capital only this third
category need be circulated: s.423(4).
275 2006 Act s.423(2),(3).
276
2006 Act s.146. See para.15–40.
277
2006 Act ss.431 (unquoted companies) and 432 (quoted companies). This right is
also extended to those nominated to enjoy information rights: s.146(3)(b).
278
It is reported that in 2006 postmen in the UK were restricted as to the number of sets
of the annual accounts and reports of HSBC bank they were permitted to carry at any
one time, because of the weight of the document.
279
Above, para.21–24.
280
2006 Act s.426.
281
2006 Act s.426(2)(3) and Companies (Receipt of Accounts and Reports) Regulations
2013/1973. The consultation may take place as part of the circulation of the annual
accounts and reports (and relate to future years) or be a free-standing consultation.
Requesting to continue with the full set must be made easy, depending simply on ticking
a box on a form, postage on which has been pre-paid by the company, at least if the
recipient has an address in the EEA. Those who enjoy information rights are within this
procedure as well: s.426(5).
282 Receipt Regulations reg.5.
283
2006 Act s.426A. On the “single total remuneration” figure see para.14–45.
284
At para.15–85.
285 2006 Act s.430.
286 2006 Act s.424(2). For delivery to the Registrar, see above, para.21–33. Of course,
the company cannot evade this obligation simply by not filing the accounts and report
with the Registrar: s.424(2)(a).
287 See para.15–48.
288 2006 Act ss.437–438.
289
See para.15–43.
290 2006 Act s.437(3).
291
At para.15–58.
292A particular feature of the rules applying to these companies is the differences in the
range of publicly traded companies caught by different rules. In descending order of
breadth, sometimes the rules apply on to companies traded on “regulated” markets,
sometimes to “quoted” companies and sometimes to companies on “prescribed”
markets.
CHAPTER 22
AUDITS AND AUDITORS
Introduction 22–1
Sources of audit law 22–2
The duties of the auditor 22–3
Overarching issues 22–4
Audit Exemption 22–5
Small companies 22–5
Subsidiaries 22–7
Dormant companies 22–8
Non-profit public sector companies 22–9
Auditor Independence and Competence 22–10
Regulatory structure 22–11
Direct Regulation of Auditor Independence 22–12
Non-independent persons 22–12
Non-audit remuneration of auditors 22–13
Auditors becoming non-independent 22–14
Auditors becoming prospectively non-independent 22–15
The Role of Shareholders and the Audit Authorities 22–16
Appointment and remuneration of auditors 22–17
Removal and resignation of auditors 22–18
Failure to re-appoint an auditor 22–20
Whistle blowing 22–21
Shareholders and the audit report 22–22
The Role of the Audit Committee of the Board 22–23
Introduction 22–23
Composition of the audit committee 22–24
Functions of the audit committee 22–25
Auditor Competence 22–26
Qualifications 22–27
Auditing standards 22–28
Quality assurance, investigation and discipline 22–29
Empowering auditors 22–30
Liability for Negligent Audit 22–31
The nature of the issue 22–31
Providing audit services through bodies with limited
liability 22–34
Claims by the Audit Client 22–36
Establishing liability 22–36
Limiting liability 22–38
Criminal liability 22–43
Claims by Third Parties 22–44
The duty of care in principle 22–44
Assumption of responsibility 22–47
Other issues 22–52
Conclusion 22–53
INTRODUCTION
22–1
The statutory accounts and reports discussed in the previous
chapter are the responsibility of the directors. However, all
modern company law systems have long accepted the principle
that the reliability of the accounts and reports will be increased if
there is in place a system of independent third-party verification
of them. The temptation to present the accounts in a light which
is unduly favourable to the management is one likely to afflict
all boards of directors at one time or another—and the
temptation is likely to be at its strongest when the financial
condition of the company is at its weakest and shareholders,
creditors and investors are most in need of access to the truth. To
provide such third-party verification is the traditional role of the
audit.
Sources of audit law
22–2
We saw in the last chapter that the global nature of modern large
businesses creates a strong pressure for global accounting
standards (though a single set of such standards is still some way
off) and for regulation of accounts within the EU to be
something which takes place to a significant extent at EU level.
Equally this is the case with auditing, as an essential
complement to accounts. Global auditing standards are being
developed, as we shall see below, and auditing is a matter which
has been regulated to an increasing degree at EU level. The
process began with Directive 84/253 on auditors’ qualifications,
but in the wake of various corporate scandals at the beginning of
the century (in the US as much as in Europe) that Directive was
replaced by one which regulated in addition the process of
auditing. Directive 2006/43/EC was in turn amended after the
financial crisis in 2013 by Directive 2013/34/EU and, again, by
Directive 2014/56/EU.1 However, in 2014 an additional crucial
step was taken. In respect of the largest companies, i.e.
companies whose securities are traded on regulated markets,
termed “public interest entities” (“PIEs”),2 an extended
supplementary set of rules was introduced. As important, that
supplementary set of rules was laid down in a Regulation,3
whose provisions are, therefore, directly applicable in the UK
(though domestic rules are needed to exercise any choices which
the Regulation specifically gives to Member States). Domestic
rules are still needed to transpose the amended Directive and to
deal with matters not dealt with by either the Regulation or the
Directive.4 Domestic rules on auditing are contained in the
Companies Act 2006, as amended, and the Statutory Auditors
Regulations but also in rules (“standards”) made by the Financial
Reporting Council or by the relevant professional bodies.5 The
structure of the domestic institutional arrangement was changed
(and simplified) in the light of the requirements of the
Regulation and, to a lesser extent, the Directives, so that the
2014 EU level reforms were significant for structural as well as
substantive reasons.
The duties of the auditor
22–3
To summarise briefly the role of the auditor, the core element of
it is the production of a report to the members of the company
which gives the auditor’s opinion on a number of issues. The
core opinion is whether:
(a) the annual accounts give a true and fair view of the financial
position of the company (or the group in the case of group
accounts)6; have been properly prepared in accordance with
the relevant financial reporting framework7; and have been
prepared in accordance with the requirements of the Act or
the IAS Regulation8;
(b) the directors’ report is consistent with the accounts, has been
prepared in accordance with the applicable legal requirements
and whether any material misstatements have been identified9
(the same or similar duties arise in relation to the strategic
report and the separate corporate governance statement, if the
company has produce either)10; and
(c) the auditable part of the directors’ remuneration report
(DRR) has been properly prepared in accordance with the
Act.11
The auditor’s report must be either “qualified” or
“unqualified”.12 An unqualified report is one where the auditor is
able to give the opinions mentioned above; a qualified report
(which is a serious thing for the company and its members) is
one where one or more of the opinions mentioned above cannot
be given.13 The auditor’s report to the members must contain
opinions on matters (a)–(c) above. In addition:
(d) In relation to PIEs the Regulation requires discussion in the
report of the risks of fraud or misstatement in the company’s
accounts.14 This falls short of requiring an opinion on
whether there has been fraud or misstatement, but the report
must “explain to what extent the statutory audit was
considered capable of detecting irregularities, including
fraud”.
Under domestic law and according to the circumstances, the
auditor’s report may also have to deal with further items. The
most important potential matters that may need discussion are:
(e) those “which cast significant doubt about the company’s
ability to continue as a going concern”.15
In addition, certain matters may need to be mentioned arising
out of the auditor’s duty, in preparing the report, to carry out
investigations so as to be able to form a view as to whether:
(f) adequate accounting records have been kept by the company;
(g) the company’s individual accounts are in agreement with the
accounting records; and
(h) the auditable part of the DRR is in agreement with the
accounting records.16
If all is well in relation to the above three issues, the auditor
need say nothing in the report. If it is not, the auditor must state
this fact.
(i) in addition, if the auditor has failed to obtain all the
information and explanations which he or she believes to be
necessary for the purposes of the audit, that fact must be
stated in the report.17
Finally, there are two specific provisions relating to the small
company accounts and the DRR:
(j) Where the directors have taken advantage of the relaxations
for small companies when preparing the company’s accounts
or the directors’ report, the auditor must state in the report his
opinion that they were not entitled to do so, if he forms such
an opinion.18
(k) If the auditor finds that the statutory provisions on the
disclosure of directors’ remuneration have not been complied
with, there is a duty upon the auditor, so far as he or she is
reasonably able, to provide the particulars which should have
been given in the directors’ report or the DRR.19 Apart from
this, however, the auditor is not under an obligation the revise
the accounts and reports so as to bring them into line with the
applicable requirements: that is the task of their authors, the
directors.
In the not uncommon case where more than one person is
appointed auditor, it must be disclosed whether they all agree on
the matters contained in the report and the reasons for any
disagreement must be given.
Undoubtedly, the most important and time-consuming of the
auditor’s tasks is that listed at (a) above, because it amounts to a
general endorsement of the accuracy of the accounts, though (d)
is likely to add considerably to the auditor’s burdens (and the
company’s costs) in the case of a PIE. In some cases, the auditor
may also be required to report facts uncovered to third parties,
especially regulators, though this development has been
controversial, as we shall see.20
Overarching issues
22–4
There are three main issues of principle about audits and
auditors. First, is the benefit of the audit greater than its costs for
all companies? If not, is there a case for exempting some classes
of company from the requirement21 to have an audit? Secondly,
once an audit is required, the temptation on management to
present the accounts in an unduly favourable light can be given
effect only if they can persuade the auditors to accept such an
unduly favourable presentation. What steps, then, can and should
be taken to ensure the independence of the auditors from the
management of the company? Thirdly, even if the auditor is
independent, what steps should be taken to ensure that a good
job will be done, in particular what role should be played by
civil liability in damages on the part of the auditor towards those
who relied on the reports? We shall look at these issues in the
remainder of this chapter.
The auditor today, at least in large firms, is not an individual
practitioner but a member of a firm, often of international scale,
and the audit is carried out by a team of auditors under the
leadership of one or more partners in the firm. Where necessary,
the text below will refer to these realities. Otherwise, the word
“auditor” is used, but to cover both firms and sole practitioners,
individuals and teams of auditors.
AUDIT EXEMPTION
Small companies
22–5
Over a little more than a decade a very substantial set of audit
exemptions has been introduced, to the point where some 88 per
cent of non-dormant companies are exempt from audit of their
annual accounts (both individual and group).22 Of course, one
must not exaggerate the economic significance of the companies
so exempt, because the exemption is applied to small companies.
Nevertheless, the definition of what counts as “small” for this
purpose has been progressively enlarged over this relatively
short period of time. This was a significant change of policy on
the part of Government, for previously it had been committed to
a universal audit requirement.23 What triggered the reversal
seems to have been the additional costs generated by the
implementation in the Companies Act 1989 of Directive 84/253
on auditors’ qualifications,24 which was alleged to have a
disproportionate impact on the audit costs of very small firms.
Once begun, the exemption process seems to have acquired a life
of its own. Despite the opposition from some users of accounts,
notably the HM Revenue and Customs and some banks, the
deregulatory pressure was successful.
An indication of the spread of the small company exemption
from audit can be gained from looking at how the upper turnover
figure for exemption has increased over the years. In 1994, this
was set at £90,00025; it was raised to £300,000 in 199726; and in
2000 to £1 million.27 The CLR recommended a further increase,
namely, to the level of the requirement for being a small
company for accounts purposes, and that at the same time the
UK’s definition of a “small” company should be revised
upwards to the level permitted by EU law.28 This raised the
turnover figure to £4.8 million. With a further raising of the EU
limit, we reach the current number of £10.2 million.29 Thus,
there has been a move from a very cautious approach to audit
exemption, where the domestic rules remained well within the
upper limit set by EU law, to one of taking full advantage of the
exemption permitted at EU level.30 In consequence, over a short
period a very substantial process of removal of third party
assurance in relation to the accounts of small companies has
taken place.31
22–6
After a period in which access for small companies to the audit
exemption was somewhat more restricted than access to the
small company accounting regime, the government decided in
2012 to adopt the simple rule that companies which are small for
accounts purposes are also entitled to the audit exemption.32
Even if the company meets this condition, it may be excluded
from the audit exemption, on grounds which parallel the loss of
small company status for accounts purposes.33 In particular, the
company must not be a public company.34 In addition, if the
company is a member of a group, it will qualify for the
exemption only if the group qualifies as small and is not an
ineligible group.35
Further, even if a company is exempt from audit on the
ground of its size (or the ground of dormancy, discussed below)
members representing at least 10 per cent of the nominal value
of the company’s issued share capital (or any class of it)36 may
demand an audit for a particular financial year, provided the
notice is given after the financial year commences and within
one year of its end.37 Thus, notice must be given on a year-by-
year basis and the members cannot make a demand relating to
future financial years (when they might not meet the size
threshold).
Where the exemption applies and is used, the directors must
confirm in a statement attached to the balance sheet that the
company was entitled to the exemption, that no effective notice
has been delivered requiring an audit and that the directors
acknowledge their responsibilities for ensuring that the company
keeps accounting records and for preparing accounts which give
a true and fair view of the state of the company’s affairs.38
However, none of this means that small companies will not
have their accounts audited in fact. If a company sees value in
providing such assurance to members, creditors or investors, it
may choose to have an audit. More likely, banks or other large
creditors may insist on an audit as part of the process of
considering whether to make a loan to the company. Where the
company which chooses to have an audit is a “micro” company,
however, the audit will not cause the company to reveal more
information where it has chosen to stick to the minimum
standards for such companies.39
Subsidiaries
22–7
Subsidiary companies, of any size, are exempt from the audit
requirement, under reforms introduced in 2012, subject to certain
conditions.40 The central requirement is that the parent company
guarantees all the liabilities of the subsidiary as they stand at the
end of the financial year, until they are satisfied, and that the
guarantee is enforceable against the parent.41 Apart from
extensive publicity requirements, this exemption is confined in
various ways. It is available only where the parent is
incorporated in the EEA; it is not available to subsidiaries whose
securities are traded on a regulated market—a rare, but not
unknown, situation in the UK; all the members of the company
must agree to forego the audit; and the subsidiary’s accounts
must be included in the consolidated accounts of the parent.42 It
is thus most easily available to wholly-owned subsidiaries of
EEA parents. The underlying policy argument is that the audit of
the subsidiary’s accounts in such case adds little by way of value
to the audit of the consolidated accounts—though, equally, given
the requirement for audit at group level, the savings from
omitting the subsidiary audit are probably not enormous.
Dormant companies
22–8
A further and less controversial type of company which is
exempt from audit is the so-called “dormant” company.43 A
company is dormant during a period when there is “no
significant accounting transaction” in relation to it, an
accounting transaction being one which needs to be recorded in
the company’s accounting records.44 Where the company has
been dormant since its formation, no other conditions need be
met before the exemption is granted.45 The most obvious and
common example of such a company is a “shelf company”46
while it remains on the shelf (though there may be legitimate
reasons for incorporating a company which is intended to remain
dormant indefinitely). If the company becomes dormant after a
period of activity, then its audit exemption is more
circumscribed. It depends on the company not being a parent
company required to produce group accounts and its being
entitled to produce its individual accounts under the small
companies regime47 or being entitled to do so but for the fact that
it is a public company or a member of an ineligible group.48 In
practice, the most important extension which the dormant
company exemption makes to that already provided for small
companies is that it extends to small public companies.49
Non-profit public sector companies
22–9
This exemption does not need detailed consideration because the
companies entitled to it, although incorporated under the
Companies Acts, are part of the public sector and are subject to
public sector audit.50 A company is non-profit making if it is so
for the purpose of art.54 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the
European Union—though that article in fact contains no
definition of “non-profit making”. Such companies are excluded
from audit because they are outside the scope of art.50(1) TFEU,
under which the audit Directives were made.
AUDITOR INDEPENDENCE AND COMPETENCE
22–10
Although the issue of small company exemption from audit has
been important over the past two decades, the most important
policy issue relating to auditors concerns their independence.
This was an issue brought to the fore by the collapse of the
Enron Company and others in the US in the early years of this
century, which collapses were thought to reveal weaknesses in
the provisions on auditor independence.51 At least in the eyes of
the EU, the same issue arose out of the experience of the
financial crisis 2007–9.52 The essence of the independence issue
is that the auditor is appointed and remunerated by the company
whose accounts and reports are to be audited. Although
companies are required to have their accounts audited (unless
exempted), they are not required to employ any particular
auditor or to pay that auditor any particular level of
remuneration. There thus develops the possibility that auditors
will compete for mandates on the basis that they will engage in
only a cursory scrutiny of the company’s accounts or that they
will act in this way in return for excessive remuneration (which
might be disguised as remuneration for the provision of non-
audit services to the company). The traditional response to this
argument is that in the long- or even the medium-term such a
business model is self-destructive. The auditor will obtain a
reputation for laxness, which will, perversely, destroy its
business. Whilst the company’s management may want a lax
audit, it is crucial that those who rely on the audit believe that
the appropriate checks have been carried out. A lax audit by an
auditor known to be lax is no good, even for evasive
management, because the management will not obtain the
benefit it desires from the audit opinion. Whilst the reputation
argument may have much force, recent experience suggests that
it does not operate at all times and in all circumstances so as to
guarantee an appropriate level of audit scrutiny. Individuals
within the audit firm may have perverse short-term incentives
which outweigh the firm’s longer term incentive to do a good
job or the investors may move away from attaching much
importance to the audited accounts in periods of market
exuberance.
Consequently, there is a case for regulation to reinforce the
market incentives supporting auditor independence. Much the
same arguments can be made in relation to auditor competence.
An audit firm has reputational reasons for providing a good
service in general but in particular cases there may be incentives
on individuals to operate inefficiently. Nor should the
independence and competence issues be viewed as completely
separate: a non-independent auditor displays dependence on
management precisely by carrying out an inadequate audit.
However, the fact the market cannot guarantee independence
and competence does not mean that regulation can (some aspects
of the problem might be insoluble) nor that all types of
regulation are equally appropriate.
There are eight strategies which have been deployed by the
law to address these problems.
(1) Laying down specific rules disqualifying persons from
acting as auditor of a particular company on grounds of
conflict of interest.
(2) Constraining the provision of non-audit services to audit
clients.
(3) Requiring the mandatory rotation of auditors.
(4) On the basis that the board is the body within the company
which has the greatest interest in a lax audit, increasing the
role of the shareholders in relation to audit decisions.
(5) On the basis that, within the board, it is the executive
directors who have the greatest interest in a lax audit and
that shareholders have serious collective action problems,
increasing the role of the non-executive directors in relation
to auditor decisions, notably via an audit committee
consisting wholly of independent non-executive directors.
(6) Attacking the problem not from the side of the company but
from the side of the auditor by subjecting auditors to greater
regulatory control and more effective disciplinary
mechanisms.
(7) Increasing the powers of the auditors as against the
company.
(8) Imposing civil liability on auditors to those who rely on the
audited accounts and reports where the auditors have been
negligent and imposing criminal liability for false statements
in audit reports.
Each has been deployed with greater vigour in recent years,
except civil liability, where indeed the tendency has been to
restrict liability.
Regulatory structure
22–11
Before we do so, however, a short word is necessary about the
structure of the regulation. The Directive requires Member
States to appoint a “competent authority” with the function of
approving auditors and putting in place a system of “public
oversight” of the work of those auditors who have been
approved.53 In the UK that competent authority is the Financial
Reporting Council.54 Whilst the competent authority has ultimate
responsibility for the tasks assigned to it, the Directive permits
delegation of its tasks to other bodies “authorised by law” to
carry out the delegated tasks—though in the case of PIEs the
Regulation forbids the delegation of many tasks beyond the
FRC.55 This delegation is subject to the condition that the
competent authority may reclaim the delegated power on a case-
by-case basis. Under the Statutory Auditors Regulations, the
FRC must itself oversee the creation of the standards which
auditors are required to meet and the manner of their application
in practice, but “must consider whether and how” other aspects
of the public oversight function (for example, quality assurance
and discipline) can be delegated to “recognised supervisory
bodies” (“RSBs”).56 The RSBs are, in brief, the professional
accounting bodies which meet the standards set in the Act for
recognition.57 An elaborate system of regulation of auditors and
auditing is thus envisaged. Some matters are determined in the
Act or the Statutory Auditors Regulations (or in the EU
Regulation in the case of PIEs), some in standards developed by
the FRC and some matters by the RSBs. However, the division
of powers between the FRC and the RSBs is not a novel feature
of EU Regulation. It was in place before the recent elaboration
of the EU requirements and, in fact, the impact of those
requirements has been somewhat to simplify the domestic
relationships. However, it is still the case that the obligation to
comply with the FRC’s standards flows from the requirements
that a statutory auditor be a member of a RSB58 and that the
RSB’s rules require compliance with standards laid down by the
FRC.59
DIRECT REGULATION OF AUDITOR INDEPENDENCE
Non-independent persons
22–12
A person may not act as an auditor if he is an officer or
employee of the company to be audited or a partner or employee
of such an officer or employee or, in the case of the appointment
of a partnership, if any member of the partnership is ineligible on
these grounds.60 Nor may a person act if any of these grounds
apply in relation to any associated undertaking61 of the company.
An auditor who comes within these provisions must immediately
resign and give notice to the company of the reason for the
resignation.62 Failure to do so is a criminal offence. Further, the
appointment or continuation in office of an auditor who is not
independent within the statutory section triggers a power in the
Secretary of State to require the company to appoint a proper
person to conduct a second audit or to review the first audit, and
the company may recover the costs of the additional audit work
from the first auditor, provided that person knew he or she was
not independent.63
Clearly, however, an employer-employee relationship with the
company being audited is far from being the only type of
relationship which might impair the independence of the auditor,
e.g. a debtor-creditor relationship or a substantial shareholding64
in the company might do so. The prohibition is clearly not a
sufficient compliance with the requirements of art.22 of the
Directive which imposes a general requirement upon Member
States to ensure the independence of auditors and to exclude a
person from acting as auditor if there is any relationship between
the auditor and audited company “from which an objective,
reasonable and informed third party would conclude that the
statutory auditor’s independence is compromised”. To meet this
requirement, the Statutory Auditors Regulations65 require the
FRC to make standards aimed at ensuring auditor independence
on appointment and during the audit. This mandate is discharged
by the FRC through its ethical standards.66
Non-audit remuneration of auditors
22–13
Apart from remuneration for the audit itself, the most common
conflicted relationship which an auditor may have with the audit
client arises from the fact that the auditor is normally a member
of a firm of accountants which is capable of providing a wide
range of services—well beyond audit or even accountancy
services—to clients. These non-audit revenues from audit clients
of accountancy firms have increased substantially in recent
years.67 Disclosure of the amount of these payments is provided
for under regulations requiring companies to disclose on a
disaggregated basis in notes to the accounts the non-audit
remuneration received by their auditors. The Regulations68
divide the auditor’s potential sources of remuneration into eight
categories (including remuneration from the audit itself), require
separate disclosure of remuneration earned from the company
(and its subsidiaries) and from associated pension schemes,69 and
require disclosure of amounts paid to the auditor’s “associates”
as well as to the auditor.70 The disclosure obligation imposed on
small or medium-sized71 companies extends only to the audit fee.
However, regulation of this issue extends beyond disclosure.
For PIEs a long list of non-audit services is simply prohibited
from the beginning of the period subject to audit to the
completion of the audit. These are non-audit services where the
risk of conflict of interest is thought to be high. They may not be
provided by the auditor or any member of its network72 or to a
PIE or any member of its group, if incorporated in the EU.73
Even permitted non-audit services are subject to controls. Their
provision must be approved by the company’s audit committee
(see below).74 In addition, the amount that is permitted to be paid
for the non-audit services is capped at 70 per cent of the average
audit fees paid over the previous three years.75
For non-PIEs the Directive applies its general principle that
auditors must assess and handle appropriately threats to their
independence, into which category non-audit remuneration falls.
In the UK this requirement is implemented via ethical standards
made by the FRC. However, these standards go beyond the
essentially procedural requirements of the Directive and make
the provision of certain high-risk non-audit services inconsistent
with an audit engagement.76 This approach on the part of the
FRC, which was in place before the most recent EU reforms,
essentially follows, but makes binding, the recommendations
contained in Commission Recommendation 2002/590/EC on
statutory auditors’ independence in the EU.77
Auditors becoming non-independent
22–14
It may be that, although the auditor may have no other
relationship with the company, over a period of time the auditor
relationship itself becomes a threat to independence. The auditor
may build up personal relationships with the management of the
audited company which make him or her reluctant to challenge
the management’s picture of events. The watchdog may have
become a lap dog. This argument is accepted at EU level in
relation to PIEs. The “key audit partners” are required to rotate
every seven years and not to take up appointment again for three
years.78 The notion of a “key audit partner” is one derived from
the Directive and it means the auditor designated by the audit
firm as primarily responsible for carrying out the audit (normally
referred to in the UK as the “engagement auditor”) but also the
auditor who signs the report, if different.79 In fact, the FRC’s
rules take up the option to make the rotation rules more
demanding and impose a five-year rotation and a five-year gap.80
In addition, the Regulation requires the phased rotation of all the
senior personnel in the audit team.
Rotation of the key audit partner has been required since 2006
Directive,81 but the Regulation introduces in addition a
requirement for the rotation of the audit firm of a PIE. The
argument against mandatory rotation of firms is that it means the
loss of the expertise of the whole of the existing audit team,
which occurrence would be likely to reduce the quality of the
audits immediately following a change of firm (unless, of
course, the audit team simply changed firms, thus defeating the
object of the exercise). In its 2011 proposals for an Audit
Regulation the Commission put forward, nevertheless, a rule
requiring for PIEs rotation of the audit firm every six years (or a
little longer in some cases).82 As enacted, the firm rotation
proposal survived but with considerably longer intervals. The
provisions are complex, reflecting their heavy negotiation in the
EU’s legislative process. In principle, rotation of the firm is
required every ten years, but Member States may opt for a 20-
year rule, as the UK has done, provided a public re-tendering
process is carried out after ten years.83
Firm rotation can be looked at as a competition issues as well
as an independence issue. Since a mere four firms dominate the
global accounting market, choice for large companies is
necessarily limited. In an attempt to address this issue, the
Competition and Markets Authority made an order in 2014
requiring mandatory re-tendering of audit engagements at least
every ten years for the largest 350 companies on the Main
Market of the London Stock Exchange.84 The aim was to give
second-tier audit firms an opportunity to break into the market
for the provision of audit services to this class of company and to
make it worthwhile for those firms to gear up to provide the
audit services. The Regulation now goes further than the order in
that it requires a change of auditor after 20 years, not just a re-
tendering process, and matches the order’s requirement of re-
tendering within the first ten years.
Both independence and competition goals might be hindered
if there were contractual restrictions in place on the choice of
auditor. The Regulation renders such clauses “null and void”;85
the Statutory Auditors Regulations treats them as of “no
effect”.86
Auditors becoming prospectively non-independent
22–15
An auditor may have no current relationship with the company
which creates a conflict of interest (nor may he or she have a
long association with the company as auditor) but there may be
an understanding, falling short of a contract, that the auditor will
resign in due course and take up a role in the management of the
company. Since accountancy skills are much prized in some
areas of management, movement from professional practice to
management is quite common. Article 22a of the Directive,
however, imposes a two-year “cooling off” period between
ceasing to be the statutory auditor or key audit partner and the
taking up of a “key” management position in a PIE and a one-
year period in any other case. The same periods are applied if the
new post is as a non-executive director of the client company or
a member of its audit committee (without being either a key
manager or a non-executive director—a rare situation). This rule
too is implemented via ethical standards in the UK.87
THE ROLE OF SHAREHOLDERS AND THE AUDIT AUTHORITIES
22–16
The traditional regulatory strategy deployed by the domestic
legislation to reinforce auditor independence has been to
enhance the role of the shareholders. In many ways this is an
obvious strategy. The accounts and reports are statements from
the directors to the members and so putting control over those
who verify those statements in the hands of the recipients rather
than the originators of the statements appears to be an
appropriate strategy. The auditor’s relationship with the
shareholders is underlined by the provision which gives him or
her a right to be sent all notices and other communications
relating to general meetings, to attend them and to be heard on
any part of the business which affects or concerns the auditor.88
In the case of a private company which takes its decision by
written resolution, the right transmogrifies into a simple right to
receive the communications relating to the written resolution,
but there is no general right to make representations to the
shareholders before they decide.89 This is a pretty ineffective
provision—though it needs to be recognised that many private
companies will be exempt from audit on grounds of being
“small”. However, the shareholders have limited opportunities to
exercise control, since they meet infrequently, and in addition
may face co-ordination problems in large companies over the
exercise of the powers which are conferred on them. Perhaps for
this reason, the auditor’s information obligations to the
shareholders are often extended to the audit authorities.
Appointment and remuneration of auditors
22–17
The normal rule is that the appointment of the auditors must be
done at each accounts meeting, normally the annual general
meeting,90 and the appointment is from the conclusion of that
meeting until the conclusion of the next such meeting.91 There
are only exceptional circumstances in which the directors may
appoint auditors.92 However, the proposal to appoint the
auditors, to re-appoint them or to appoint others in their place
comes normally from the board (though it need not) and the
meeting, almost invariably, will agree with the board’s proposal.
This is an example of a situation where the shareholders’ co-
ordination problems make it difficult, though not impossible, for
them to generate a proposal of their own. They might do so if
they had reason to believe that the auditor was in the board’s
pocket, but they rarely have grounds for so thinking, in which
case accepting the board’s proposal seems the rational course of
action. In the case of PIEs the audit committee (see below) is
required to put forward recommendations to the shareholders.93
This both recognises shareholders’ potential co-ordination
problems and attempts to shift the de facto nomination role out
of the hands of the executive directors of the company.
Where the auditors are appointed by the members in general
meeting, their remuneration shall be fixed by the company in
general meeting or in such manner as the general meeting shall
determine.94 This, too, is intended to emphasise that the auditors
are the members’ watchdogs rather than the directors’ lapdogs.
But in practice it serves little purpose since the members
normally adopt a resolution proposed by the directors to the
effect that the remuneration shall be agreed by the directors—as
the provision permits them to do. Even if the shareholders
actually fixed the auditor’s remuneration, rather than fixing the
method for fixing it, they would invariably act on a
recommendation from the board. A more effective protection,
perhaps, is that the amount of the remuneration, which includes
expenses and benefits in kind (the monetary value of which has
to be estimated) has to be shown in a note to the annual
accounts, thus enabling the members to criticise the directors if
the amount seems to be out of line.95
For private companies shareholder meetings are not required
to be held, but, assuming the company is subject to audit, the
principle of shareholder appointment and determination of
remuneration still applies, except that the shareholders may act
by written resolution and the rules are re-drafted so as to apply
with reference to, not the accounts meeting, which will probably
not be held, but the period of 28 days beginning with the day on
which the accounts and reports were circulated to the members
or, if later, the last day for circulating them.96 Suppose, however,
that no resolution with regard to the auditors is circulated to the
shareholders, a not inconceivable situation in a private company.
The Act provides that, unless the auditor was appointed by the
directors under their exceptional powers,97 failure to re-appoint
or to appoint someone else at the end of the year will mean the
auditors in place are deemed to be re-appointed.98 This process
of deemed re-appointment in private companies, which may
otherwise continue indefinitely, can be excluded by the
company’s articles.99 More important in practice, the auditor in
post may be required to undergo re-election as a result of a
resolution adopted by the members100 or a notice received from
members holding at least five per cent of the voting rights
entitled to be cast on a resolution that the auditor should not be
re-appointed.101 The last of these is the least demanding method
of preventing deemed re-appointment.
Removal and resignation of auditors
Requirement for shareholder resolution
22–18
As in the case of directors,102 a company may by ordinary
resolution passed at a meeting at any time remove an auditor
from office.103 However, the auditor, unlike a director, may not
be removed prior to the expiration of the term of office other
than by resolution of the shareholders.104 In this way the auditor
is given some protection against management pressure. If
management wish to remove the auditor prematurely, they must
do so by means of a proposal to the shareholders. If management
goes down that route, further provisions of the Act come into
play designed to permit or even require the auditor to put the
contrary case to the shareholders. Hence, not only has special
notice (28 days)105 to be given to the company of a resolution to
remove an auditor, but notice of the proposed resolution has to
be given to the auditor.106 The auditor is entitled to make written
representations which, if received in time, have to be sent to the
members with the notice of the meeting, and which, if not
received in time, have to be read out at the meeting.107 If the
resolution is passed, the auditor still retains the right to attend the
general meeting at which the term of office would otherwise
have expired or at which the vacancy created by the removal is
to be filled.108 Nor does removal deprive the auditor of any right
to compensation or damages, arising, for example, under the
contract between auditor and company, in respect of the
termination of the appointment as auditor or any appointment
terminating with that as auditor.109
A feature of the above rules is that, whilst protecting the
auditor to some degree against management pressure, they give
the shareholders a free hand over the removal of the auditor. If,
for example, the shareholders of their own motion wish to
remove an auditor they regard as too friendly with management,
they are free to do so, provided the special notice and auditor
statement provisions are complied with. However, art.38 of the
Audit Directive requires Member States to ensure that auditors
may be removed only on “proper grounds”. It provides that
“divergence of opinion on accounting treatments or audit
procedures shall not be proper grounds for dismissal”. The aim
is clearly to give the auditor further protection against
management pressure where the auditor has fallen out with the
management, but the provision appears to be general and makes
it less easy for the shareholders to act where they think the
auditor has become too cosy with the management.
In countries with controlling shareholders as the predominant
form of shareholding even in large companies (common in
continental Europe), it may have been thought unrealistic to
regard the directors and the (majority of the) shareholders as two
separate groups. However, it is not unrealistic in dispersed
shareholding jurisdictions such as the UK, and the Government
was clearly reluctant to implement the Directive in the obvious
way, i.e. by building a “proper grounds” qualification into the
shareholders’ removal power in s.510.110 Instead the Government
opted to amend s.994 dealing with unfair prejudice.111 Removal
of an auditor on ground of divergence of opinion or any other
improper ground is deemed to be conduct unfairly prejudicial to
the interests of some part of the members.112 This approach has
the merit of addressing the policy issue probably underlying the
Directive, i.e. unfair treatment of minority shareholders.
However, it is difficult to see that it transposes the Directive’s
formal requirement that the auditor “may be dismissed” only on
proper grounds. The dismissal, even if challengeable under the
unfair prejudice provisions by a shareholder, still seems to be
effective as far as the auditor is concerned nor, whether the
dismissal is effective or not, does the new provision give the
auditor any rights as against the company. Further, there is no
requirement that the court exercise its remedial powers under
s.996 to secure the reinstatement of the auditor. Whether this
way of proceeding meets the Directive’s requirements must be
open to doubt.
In the case of PIEs the Directive113 requires that 5 per cent of
the shareholders or the competent authority should be able to
bring proceedings before a court for the dismissal of the auditor
on proper grounds. Unlike the provision just discussed, this
expands the powers of (minority) shareholders though in a rather
cumbersome way.
A breakdown in relations between auditor and management is
more likely to reveal itself in the resignation of the auditor rather
than an attempt by the management to persuade the shareholders
to remove the auditor. Few auditors will want to retain office if
relations with the management of the company have become
seriously strained. At first glance the Act makes resignation an
easy matter: the auditor resigns by sending a notice to that effect
to the company.114 In this case what is needed are provisions
which make it difficult for the auditor to “go quietly”, i.e. to
resign office without ensuring that any matters which have
caused concern will be ventilated. The Act contains two sets of
notice provisions designed to achieve this objective, requiring
notice to be given to the company, on the one hand, and the
regulatory authorities on the other. The information may put
these bodies on the alert about possible mismanagement of the
company. However, the Act also imposes notification
requirements in the case of dismissal. We therefore discuss the
notification requirements together in the following sub-section.
Notifications
22–19
An auditor of a PIE who leaves office at any time and for any
reason must send the company a statement of reasons for this
occurrence.115 In the case of a non-PIE such a statement may be
required. It will not be required where the departure from office
occurs in circumstance which the legislature has determined in
advance raise no concerns.116 Nor will it be required of an
auditor who leaves office at the end of an accounts meeting,117
i.e. the rule here is aimed a departures during a financial year.
For both PIEs and non-PIEs the statement must include
reference to matters connected with the departure from office
which the auditor thinks should be brought to the attention of the
company’s members or creditors.118 This is the “section 519
statement”.
Having produced the statement, an auditor resigning from a
PIE can seek to replicate the situation in relation to a dismissal
by requiring the directors to convene a meeting of the
shareholders to consider it,119 though if “going quietly” was the
motivation behind the resignation, the auditor is pretty unlikely
to take this step.120 Whether or not the resigning auditor triggers
this right, the company must send circulate any s.519 statement
received from a departing auditor to those entitled to receive
copies of the company’s accounts.121 This too is unlikely to
generate action on the part of dispersed shareholders, unless the
statement reveals egregious conduct.
Of greater significance is the obligation to inform a regulator
of the s.519 statement. The auditor must send the statement to
the Registrar,122 so that it gets onto the company’s public file at
Companies House, and to the appropriate audit authority,123 both
obligations being sanctioned by criminal sanctions. The
appropriate audit authority for a PIE is the FRC and for a non-
PIE a RSB. Where the s.519 statement is made by an auditor
who is ceasing office other than at the end of an accounts
meeting (or its private company equivalent), the company must
forward to the appropriate audit authority a statement of its
reasons for the occurrence of this event, though the company
may simply say that it agrees with the reasons given by the
departing auditor. Thus the regulator is informed of both sides of
the dispute, if there is one, and is perhaps more likely to take
action than dispersed shareholders, at least where the dispute
reveals a public interest element. Overall, the management
cannot remove an auditor prematurely, whether by dismissal or
forced resignation, without facing a serious risk of a row at the
general meeting (and, in the case of a listed company, adverse
press publicity) and with the auditing and accounting authorities.
Failure to re-appoint an auditor
22–20
Finally, a management which has fallen out with its auditors
may simply wait until the end of the term of office and replace
them. As we have seen, in the case of a public company this is
an annual opportunity, since the term of office of the auditor
runs, normally, from one accounts meeting to the next, and in the
case of a private company the deemed re-appointment
mechanism can be brought to an end by appointing substitute
auditors during the annual period for appointing them.124
Moreover, since a change of auditors, for good reasons, is not an
uncommon event and is now encouraged by the authorities,
failure to re-appoint may not be suspicious. Alternatively,
auditors who have fallen out with the management may simply
not seek re-appointment. However, the Act does take steps to
flush out information about failures to re-appoint which are
questionable. First, a resolution to appoint someone other than
the existing auditors must be a resolution of which special notice
(at least 28 days)125 has been given to the company, and the
company must make use of the advance notice to inform the
outgoing auditor and the proposed replacement of the
resolution.126 The outgoing auditor then has the right to have
representations circulated in advance of the meeting or read out
at the meeting, similar to the rights arising on a resolution to
dismiss.127 If, in the case of a private company, the decision is to
be taken by written resolution, the right is to have the
representations circulated to the members of the company.128
More important, because obligatory, the rules applying to
PIEs concerning the auditor’s duty to deposit a statement of
circumstances with the company apply to the outgoing auditor.129
Following on from that, the auditor must supply a copy of the
statement to the Registrar and the FRC130 and the company must
circulate the statement to those entitled to receive the
accounts,131 but the company is not required to supply a
statement of its reasons to the FRC.132
Whistle blowing
22–21
The auditor’s relationship with the authorities is strengthened,
possibility to the detriment of the quality of its relationship with
the company, by whistle-blowing provisions, meaning a duty
laid on the auditor to report certain categories of facts discovered
in the course of the audit to the relevant authorities. In the case
of PIEs the Regulation not surprisingly requires auditors to
report suspected fraud or other irregularities to the company, but
if the company does not investigate the suspicions, the auditor
must report them to the relevant authorities.133 This is
supplemented by an obligation to report directly to the
authorities evidence discovered in the course of the audit about
“material” breaches of the law or regulation or which throws
doubt on the continuous functioning of the PIE or which lead the
auditor to form the intention not to issue an opinion on the
financial statements or to issue a qualified opinion.134 In the
latter two cases the auditor is not necessarily reporting any
wrongdoing to the authorities, but is giving them advanced
notice of something which will necessarily become public in due
course. Disclosure under the above provisions does not make the
auditor liable under any contractual or legal restriction on the
disclosure of information.135 The relevant authority in the UK
will often be the FRC but might be different body in some cases,
such as the Serious Fraud Office.
Although general whistle-blowing provisions of this kind
were previously not part of UK law, UK auditing standards have
for some time required auditors to consider whether the public
interest requires such action,136 and on the basis of this
professional guidance it has been held that the auditor’s legal
duties to the company could embrace, as a last resort, a duty to
inform relevant third parties of suspected wrongdoing.137
Shareholders and the audit report
22–22
The focus on the shareholder role in relation to the appointment
and removal of auditors rather obscures the fact that the audit
report is a report to the shareholders, to which they might be
expected to react. Until recently, the Act provided no specific
channels for these reactions. It was assumed that the
shareholders would use their general governance powers (for
example, to remove directors) or impose market pressure on the
company by selling their shares. We have seen above138 that the
Government did not take up the CLR’s general proposal for a
“pause” between the delivery of the annual accounts and reports
to the members and the holding of the annual general meeting,
during which period shareholders would have an opportunity, at
no cost to themselves, to require the company to circulate
resolutions for consideration at the AGM in relation to those
documents. However, a weak form of that proposal is to be
found in ss.527–531 of the Act. Shareholders of a quoted
company139 may require the company to post on its website a
shareholder statement about the audit of the company’s accounts
or about the circumstances in which an auditor has ceased to
hold office, for consideration at the company’s accounts meeting
(normally its AGM). The tests for defining the members entitled
to require website publication are the same as those for requiring
circulation of a resolution to be considered at an AGM,140 that is,
members representing at least 5 per cent of the total voting rights
of those entitled to vote at the accounts meeting or 100 voting
members holding shares upon which an average of at least £100
has been paid up.141 The company is required to post the
statement on its website within three working days of its receipt
and to keep it there until after the accounts meeting,142 unless the
company persuades a court that the shareholders are abusing
their rights.143 A copy of it must be sent to the auditor at the
same time as it is posted.144 The company may not charge the
shareholders for the costs of website publication, which will
normally be negligible.145 Finally, when it gives notice of the
accounts meeting, the company must draw attention to the
existence of this facility and that it is without cost to the
members, which may encourage them to take it up.
THE ROLE OF THE AUDIT COMMITTEE OF THE BOARD
Introduction
22–23
The argument in favour of conferring a greater role on directors
in relation to the audit is that the board is able to give more
continuous attention to the audit than are the shareholders,
whose contribution is naturally episodic, normally at the annual
general meeting when the auditors’ report is considered and the
auditors appointed or re-appointed. The conflict of interest
which the board may have on audit matters can be dealt with, it
is argued, by entrusting this supervisory role not to the board as
a whole but to an appropriate committee of the board. Audit
committees are now common among UK companies traded on
public securities markets. This is partly because successive
versions of the UK Corporate Governance Code (“CGC”) have
recommended, on a comply or explain basis, that companies
with a premium listing146 on the Main Market of the London
Stock Exchange establish such committees of the board, along
with remuneration and appointment committees.147 However, in
relation to public interest entities there is now a mandatory
requirement for audit committees contained in the Directive. The
provisions of the Directive in relation to audit committees are
transposed into domestic law via rules made by the Financial
Conduct Authority (“FCA”), notably its Disclosure and
Transparency Rule (“DTR”) 7.148 Present practice is thus an
amalgam of these two streams of rules, though their coverage is
not exactly the same. Premium listing is a voluntary choice on
the part of the listed company, whereas the definition of ‘public
interest entities’ embraces all companies with securities traded
on a regulated market.
Composition of the audit committee
22–24
Article 39 the Directive is headed “audit committee” and
art.39(1) appears to require most PIEs149 to establish an audit
committee, so that this is no longer a “comply or explain”
obligation for companies with securities listed on the Main
Market of the London Stock Exchange. In fact, art.39(4) allows
Member States to dispense with the audit committee if there is
some other body within the company performing equivalent
functions. Consequently, DTR 7.1.1 is drafted in terms of
requiring a listed company to have a “body” which discharges
the functions assigned to the audit committee by the Directive.
However, since the UK Corporate Governance Code (C.3.1)
recommends the establishment of an audit committee of the
board, we assume in this account that the “body” will take the
form of such a committee.150 It is possible, however, that in
small companies the task could be discharged by the board as
whole, since the drafting of DTR 7 permits this and the company
could explain its non-compliance under the CGC.151 Under the
Directive the committee is to be composed of non-executive
members of the board or of appointees of the shareholders, of
whom the majority (including the chair) are to be independent of
the company. The UK CGC does not envisage members of the
audit committee being directly appointed by the shareholders but
rather that the members should all be members of the board.
Shareholder appointments directly to board committees is not
part of UK practice and it is unlikely that the Directive will
encourage the adoption of this approach.152 However, the CGC
recommends that all members of the audit committee be
independent, and this is likely to continue to be UK practice.
Both sets of rules agree that at least one member of the
committee “shall have competence in accounting and/or
auditing” (Directive) or “recent and relevant financial
experience” (CGC).
Functions of the audit committee
22–25
The Regulation indicates the importance it attaches to the audit
committee by conferring on it a list of functions which, together,
make the audit committee the central focus for dealings between
the auditor and the PIE:
(a) The appointment of the auditor is a process run by the audit
committee.153 That committee makes a recommendation for
the appointment of the auditor and, except for the renewal of
an existing engagement, that recommendation must contain at
least two choices, with a reasoned statement of the
committee’s preference among them. The choices must have
resulted from an open and transparent tendering process
organised by the committee.154 Although the detail of the
procedure are left up to the committee to determine, the
selection is required to be made according to publicised
selection criteria and to be capable of justification according
to those criteria. The aim appears to be to avoid “sweet heart”
deals between auditor and the company. Although the
committee’s recommendations go to the full board and the
full board makes the final recommendations to the
shareholders, it is likely that the board will simply follow
what the committee recommends. If the full board makes a
different proposal, it must justify its departure from the
committee’s proposals and, in any event, the board’s list may
not include an auditor who has not participated in the
selection process.155
(b) Whilst the appointed auditor reports to the members of the
company,156 the audit committee must receive at the same
time or earlier a more detailed report which delves into some
sensitive matters.157 These include the methodology
underlying the audit, the quantitative criteria used to
determine materiality,158 the valuation methods used in the
financial statements and the judgements underlying the
auditor’s ‘going concern’ conclusions. The report to the audit
committee must also give details of any significant
deficiencies in the financial statements and of any areas of
non-compliance (actual or suspected) with the applicable
legal rules or the articles of association, explain the grounds
on which companies were included in or excluded from the
consolidated accounts, report any significant difficulties
arising during the conduct of the audit and, finally, describe
the extent of the auditor’s interaction with the management of
the company. It is clear that this list adds considerably to the
auditor’s standard reporting duties but also that the audit
committee will require a significant level of expertise to
understand and evaluate the report it receives.
(c) The approval of the audit committee is required for the
provision to the PIE of permitted non-audit services.159
(d) Where the audit fee received from the PIE exceeds 15 per
cent of the auditor’s total fee income over a period of three
years, the audit committee must decide whether the audit
engagement should continue (in any case it may not continue
for more than two years) and whether the audit report should
be subject to review by another statutory auditor.160 The
danger here is perceived to be that the auditor has become too
dependent on a single client and so is less likely to be
rigorous in its scrutiny. Given the adverse consequences for
the auditor of exceeding the 15 per cent threshold over the
three year period, it is likely that auditors will not allow this
situation to arise. Ironically, the risk of exceeding the
threshold is greater for small auditors trying to break into the
PIE market than it is for the established “big four” global
auditing networks.
(e) In addition to the Directive’s general independence
requirements for auditors,161 the Regulation requires a PIE
auditor annually to confirm its independence in writing to the
audit committee and to discuss with the committee any
threats to its independence and potential safeguards.162
(f) Finally, audit committees are themselves subject to periodic
review of their effectiveness by the FRC.163
In addition to these specific duties the Directive adds a group of
more general duties to the list of the audit committee’s tasks.
These are to monitor the financial reporting process, the
company’s internal quality assurance and risk management
systems and the conduct of the statutory audit and to report to
the board as a whole on the outcomes of the statutory audit.164
The inclusion of internal risk management review is a significant
addition to the committee’s tasks, since it gives the committee a
very important internal governance role.
Despite this formidable list of tasks, it is doubtful whether the
Regulation and the Directive substantially upgrade what has
been expected from audit committees in the UK for some years.
The UK CGC covers a lot of the same ground.165 In addition the
Code recommends that a separate section of the annual report to
the shareholders should explain how the audit committee has
discharged its obligations during the year and that the chair of
the audit committee should be available at the AGM to answer
shareholders’ questions.166 In 2002, as a result of the efforts of a
committee chaired by Sir Robert Smith, extensive extra-Code
guidance for audit committees was produced, which, whilst
having no formal status, even on a “comply or explain” basis,
strongly indicates the enhanced importance of the audit
committee.167 The FRC has also produced guidance on risk
management which stresses the potential role of the audit
committee.168 Nevertheless, the embodiment of these
requirements in hard law may lead to greater regulatory, and
potentially litigation, focus on these matters.
AUDITOR COMPETENCE
22–26
So far in this chapter we have focused on the issue of auditor
independence. But competence is important as well.
Shareholders, investors and creditors may suffer if the auditor,
whilst not beholden to management, just does not do a good job
and produces accounts which are not reliable. Moreover, as
noted, one sign of lack of independence may be a lax audit
which does not meet professional standards, so that tackling
competence is an indirect way of tackling lack of independence.
Rules aimed at increasing competence may be aimed at
controlling those permitted to carry out audits, at controlling
how audits are carried out or at sanctioning those who have
carried out incompetent audits. The sanctions may be criminal,
administrative or civil. Competence may also by enhanced by
extending the auditor’s powers.
Qualifications
22–27
An early concern of the EU law on auditors was to require that
they be appropriately trained and qualified and continue to be
so.169 We do not need to go into the details in this book. It is
enough to note that the rules of the recognised supervisory
bodies (i.e. normally the professional institutes)170 must provide
for appointment as statutory auditor to be confined to those who
hold appropriate qualifications (or in the case of appointment of
a firm that each individual responsible on behalf of the firm is so
qualified and that the firm is controlled by such persons).171
Schedule 11 then lays out in some detail the terms on which
bodies may award professional qualifications. The discharge by
the RSBs of this function is overseen by the FRC.172 Since a
person who acts as an auditor without the appropriate
qualifications is ineligible to do so,173 the POB has the power to
require a second audit in such cases and the ineligible auditor
may be liable for its costs.174 An auditor may also be
appropriately qualified by virtue of a qualification granted in
another EEA State and of having passed an aptitude test and
spent an adaptation period in the UK.175 The FRC also has power
to recognise qualifications obtained outside the EEA where it is
thought that they are equivalent and where the country in
question would provide reciprocal treatment of persons qualified
in the UK.176 The names of statutory auditors must be entered
into a public register, which must include an indication of the
other Member States (if any) in which the auditor is registered. It
must also contain the names of third country auditors who sign
the audit reports of third country companies whose securities are
traded on a regulated market in the EU.177
Auditing standards
22–28
Auditing standards play a similar role in relation to the function
of auditing as accounting standards play in relation to drawing
up the accounts. An auditor is necessarily concerned with both
sets of standards: the auditor must establish that the accounts
have been drawn up properly (including in accordance with the
relevant accounting standards) and he or she must carry out the
job of checking the financial statements in a proper manner (in
accordance with auditing standards). In the case of a negligence
claim against the auditor, compliance with both accounting and
auditing standards is likely to be a matter to which the courts
attach great weight.178 As with accounting standards, auditing
standards are becoming internationalised. Article 26 of the
Directive requires Member States to secure compliance on the
part of statutory auditors (in all cases, not just the audits of PIEs)
with international standards issued by the International Auditing
and Assurance Standards Board (“IAASB”), based in New York,
once these have been adopted by the Commission. In default of
adoption of international standards, Member States apply
national standards though only “to the extent necessary to add to
the credibility and quality of financial statements”. However, the
process of adoption of auditing standards for the EU lags behind
that of adopting accounting standards, and, at the time of
writing, none has been adopted. In the UK, this delay is of little
consequence since the approach of the FRC to auditing standards
has been to adopt those laid down by the IAASB, but with
additional explanatory material.
Quality assurance, investigation and discipline
22–29
A central function of the FRC is to oversee the monitoring of
audit quality in general and to carry out investigations into
particular cases of suspected inadequate audit and to secure
(subject to appeal) disciplinary sanctions.179 This has been so
since the substantial domestic reform of auditor regulation
initiated by the Companies (Audit, Investigation and Community
Enterprise) Act 2004, which effectively did away with
professional self-regulation in these areas. In respect of PIEs the
Regulation requires these functions to be carried out by the FRC
itself.180 In other cases, the task may be delegated by the FRC to
or shared with the RSBs. Quality assurance means the periodic
inspection of audits carried out in particular companies
accompanied by possible recommendations for improvement—a
process now familiar in many walks of life. Both the Directive181
and the Regulation182 require quality assurance arrangements to
be put in place but the latter, applying to PIEs, is more
prescriptive about the nature of the process, requires quality
assurance reviews more frequently (every three years rather than
every six) and makes the “recommendations” of the inspectors
binding. In order to facilitate this work of the FRC the
Regulation requires an “annual transparency report”183 by the
auditor to the authority, setting out information such as the PIEs
for whom it acts, the firm’s governance and remuneration
structure and its practices designed to ensure independence.
In the case of suspected inadequate audits the Directive
contains a series of provisions requiring effective investigation
powers and a range of potential sanctions to be available, and
lays down criteria for determining the severity of the sanction in
particular cases.184 The Regulation adds information and access
rights in the case of PIEs.185 The disciplinary sanctions range
from private censure, through public censure to a prohibition on
acting as an auditor and imposing a financial penalty.186 In
important cases the disciplinary proceedings are commenced in
the UK by the FRC, which initiates proceedings before
Disciplinary Tribunal, established by but independent of the
FRC. The Tribunal is chaired by an experienced lawyer, and
appeal lies to an Appeal Tribunal.
Empowering auditors
22–30
Even if the statutory and professional rules produce loyal and
competent auditors, auditors may fail to detect impropriety in the
company if they are not given the co-operation of those who
work for it. If an auditor does not receive the co-operation
needed to assess the company’s accounts, that fact can be
reflected in the ultimate report to the shareholders,187 but it is
obviously more desirable that the auditor should be able obtain
the necessary information. The issue of the auditor’s powers as
against the audited company and its management is one to which
the legislature has given increasing attention in recent years.
Auditors have a right of access at all times to the company’s
books, accounts and vouchers.188 They are entitled to require
such information and explanations as they think necessary for
the performance of their duties. Those under the obligation to
provide the information and explanations now go beyond the
company’s officers and embrace (present or past): employees of
the company; persons holding or accountable for the company’s
accounts (for example, where the company has outsourced this
function); subsidiary companies incorporated in the UK; and
persons falling within the above categories in relation to the
subsidiary and the subsidiary’s auditor (if different).189 More
problematic, though of great importance, is the position of
subsidiaries incorporated outside the UK and the relevant
persons connected with them. Here the problem of comity of
legal systems is dealt with by putting an obligation on the parent,
if required by its auditors to do so, to take such steps as are
reasonably open to it to obtain such information and
explanations from the subsidiary and the relevant persons.190 A
failure to respond “without delay” to a request for information is
a criminal offence, unless compliance was not reasonably
practicable. Also criminal is knowingly or recklessly making to
the auditors a statement which conveys or purports to convey
any information or explanation which is misleading, false or
deceptive in any material particular.191
The above rights for the auditor depend upon the auditor
knowing which questions to ask. Since the auditor is by
profession an investigator, it is reasonable to suppose that he or
she will often be in a position to ask the right questions.
However, the CLR192 thought there was a good argument for
requiring directors to “volunteer” information rather than leaving
the auditor to find everything out. This reform was implemented
via an addition to the matters required to be disclosed in the
directors’ report.193 That report must contain a statement on the
part of each director to the effect that (a) so far as the director is
aware, there is no information needed by the auditor of which
the auditor is unaware; and (b) the director has taken all steps he
ought to have taken to make him- or herself aware of such
information and to establish that the auditor is aware of it.194
This may require the director to reveal his or her wrongdoing or
that of fellow directors to the auditor.195 The full extent of what
is required of the director is to be assessed by reference to the
director’s objective duty of care,196 but the Act specifically
recognises that making enquiries of fellow directors and the
auditor might be enough to discharge the duty (i.e. that the
director can rely on satisfactory answers from such sources to
appropriate questions).197 A director is criminally liable if the
statement is false but only if the director knew of the falsity or
was reckless as to whether the statement was true or false and if
he or she failed to take reasonable steps to prevent the
(inaccurate) directors’ report from being approved.198 However,
as we shall see below, failure to comply with this provision may
also limit the auditor’s civil liability towards the company by
virtue of the doctrine of contributory negligence.
LIABILITY FOR NEGLIGENT AUDIT
The nature of the issue
22–31
Imposing civil liability on an auditor towards the company in the
case of a negligent audit is an obvious way of encouraging
diligence on the part of auditors. It is also a liability which arises
naturally out of the law of tort, once negligence liability was
extended to misstatements. If an auditor produces an audit report
which is misleading and the inaccuracy can be traced to a lack of
care, skill or diligence on the part of the auditor, then those to
whom the auditor owed a duty to take care will be in a position
to sue the auditor for damages, if they can show that the
inaccurate report caused them loss. In the case of a single
auditor, the liability will lie with that person; in the more
common case of a firm being appointed auditor, then the
individuals who were negligent will be liable but so also will the
firm, either because the negligence of the individuals is regarded
as the negligence of the firm or because the firm is vicariously
liable for the negligence of the individuals. Nevertheless, as we
shall see below, the question of how wide that liability should be
(both in terms of the range of potential claimants and the
quantum of liability) raises difficult policy issues.
The rules for determining the underlying liability of the
auditor rests, even after the 2006 Act, with the common law,199
though statute has played a role in fashioning the way that
common law liability applies to auditors. It is important to
distinguish among the potential claimants against the auditor
between the audit client and everyone else. That the audit client
in principle has a claim against the negligent auditor is well-
established, that claim being based either on the contract
between the auditor and the company or on the tort of
negligence.200 In relation to claims by persons other than the
audit client, however, the question of how widely the duty of
care in tort is owed has been, as we shall see, fiercely debated in
the courts and the upshot of the litigation is a rather restricted
duty of care. Of course, the matter might be decided by contract
even in relation to non-clients, but there is less likely to be an
explicit contract between the auditor and the non-client upon
which the claimant can rely. However, as we shall see, the thrust
of the court decisions on the tortious liability of auditors is that
liability exists in relation to non-clients only where a relationship
akin to a contract has arisen.
The formulation of the duty of care owed by auditors to non-
client claimants is but one example of a generally cautious
attitude on the part of legislators towards auditors’ civil liability.
One might have thought that increasing the civil liability of the
auditor would be an effective way of providing incentives to
auditors to be both independent and competent. However, unlike
all the legal strategies discussed above, which in one way or
another have seen some expansion in recent years, judicial
decisions and legislative rules have ensured that there has been
no such expansion in relation to civil liability; in fact, the
tendency in recent years has been to rein in civil liability.
22–32
As regards liability to non-clients, there is a particular problem
that liability arises out of the fact that the accounts and reports
and the auditor’s report thereon are placed in the public
domain.201 It is therefore possible that a very large number of
people will rely on them in order to carry out a wide range of
transactions. Unrestricted liability on the part of auditors to third
parties who rely on the accounts thus raises the prospect, as it
was once famously described, of “liability in an indeterminate
amount for an indeterminate time to an indeterminate class”.202
We discuss this problem further below in relation to the decision
of the House of Lords in Caparo Industries Plc v Dickman,203
but, at its worst, the liability rules might cause the audit market
to unravel through the withdrawal of financially sound auditors.
22–33
Even in relation to actions by audit clients, there are difficult
issues about the proper scope of the liability rules. Thus, the
general tort doctrine of joint and several liability may
significantly increase the tort exposure of auditors. Under this
doctrine, if two or more tortfeasors are liable in respect of the
same loss, the injured party may recover from any one of them
for the whole of the loss, leaving the defendant to seek
contributions from the other tortfeasors. In the classic case,
where the misstatements in the company’s accounts result from
the fraud or negligence of someone within the company and the
failure of the auditors to discover the wrongdoing, the
claimant204 may recover the whole of the loss from the auditor,
leaving the auditor to bear the risk that the original wrongdoers
(usually directors or employees of the company) are judgment
proof. Thus, claimants are encouraged to sue the defendants with
“deep pockets” for the recovery of the whole of their loss, even
though the auditor may be only the minor party at fault. Again,
there is a risk the audit market will unravel in these
circumstances.
The above problems are only partially addressed (and may
even be exacerbated) by the professional indemnity insurance (or
equivalent arrangements) which audit firms are obliged to
carry.205 That insurance may be very expensive and so increase
the cost of audits and it may not be available for the full extent
of the claim, so that the liability risk is only partially
collectivised through the insurance mechanism. More
problematically, the presence of insurance may actually
encourage litigation against auditors, since claimants will know
that auditors are worth suing and auditors will have an incentive
to settle quietly rather than fight the issue in court provided they
keep the liability within the insurance limits. There has been
some movement in the common law world towards the
substitution of “proportionate” liability for joint and several
liability for auditors (i.e. the auditor is liable only for the share of
the loss which is fairly attributable to the auditor’s
negligence).206 However, in the UK, despite pressure from the
accounting profession, there has been resistance to such a move
on the grounds that it simply shifts the risk of insolvency from
the auditor to the wholly innocent claimant.207 Nevertheless, a
British solution has emerged in the 2006 reforms permitting a
“liability limitation agreement” between auditor and audit client,
as discussed below. A restriction of liability to the auditor’s
proportionate share of the loss is a permissible type of
agreement. This reform, of course, does not address third party
claims against auditors.
Providing audit services through bodies with
limited liability
22–34
Where the auditor is an audit firm taking the form of a traditional
partnership, further issues are raised. The assets of the firm as a
whole become available to satisfy the claimant in the case of loss
caused by a partner (or employee) acting in the ordinary course
of the business of the firm.208 In addition, given the absence of
limited liability in the traditional partnership, the personal assets
of both the negligent partner and fellow partners may be called
on to meet the claim.209 The prospect of personal liability
(uncovered by insurance) might induce such defensive action on
the part of auditors that utility of the audit is reduced, because,
for example, auditors began to give qualified audit opinions
based on trivial grounds. Something has been done to address
the issue of personal liability. Audit services may now be
provided to a company by an accounting firm which is not a
partnership. The Act provides that both individuals and firms are
eligible to be appointed as auditors210 and then defines a “firm”
as “any entity, whether or not a legal person, that is not an
individual”.211 Thus, the old idea that it was the hallmark of a
professional that he or she provided services on the basis of
personal liability for their quality has gone. Some accounting
firms have set up their auditing arms as limited companies, but,
by and large, the company form of internal organisation is not
attractive to professional partnerships. The accounting firms
therefore pressed for, and ultimately obtained in 2000, a new
corporate vehicle, the limited liability partnership,212 which has
the internal structure of a partnership but benefits from limited
liability in its external dealings. The origins of this new vehicle
are demonstrated by the fact that, when originally proposed, it
was to be confined to professional businesses, but in the end it
was made generally available.213
Conducting the audit through a vehicle with limited liability
certainly protects the personal assets of the non-negligent
partners. Whether the personal assets of the negligent partner are
so protected depends on whether the negligent misstatement in
the audit report is analysed as having been made by the member,
for whose tort the corporate body is vicariously liable (personal
assets of the negligent member not protected), or whether the
negligent misstatement is analysed as having been made by the
corporate body through the auditor, in which case the personal
assets of the negligent member are not at risk. The decision of
the House of Lords in Williams v Natural Life Health Foods214
suggests the latter analysis (personal assets not at risk) but it is
unclear whether the Williams rationale extends to statements by
professionals.215
22–35
Even if Williams does apply, the benefits of corporate
personality and limited liability are restricted to the personal
assets of the members: the business of the corporate body itself
could still be destroyed by a large claim which exceeded the
insurance cover and pushed the body into insolvency. This is,
indeed, the public policy crux. If there were many competing
firms of auditors, the occasional insolvency of one of them
might not matter in public policy terms. However, there are now
only four international networks of firms capable of carrying out
the audits of the largest multinational firms, and the collapse of
Arthur Andersen in the aftermath of the Enron scandal in the US
is a reminder of how quickly such international firms can
disintegrate.216 The disappearance of another such firm would
further reduce competition in the market for the audit of
multinational companies from its already low level. However,
this fear should not push legislators into hasty acceptance of
arguments for the reduction of auditors’ liability without
rigorous scrutiny of the likely impact. For example, it was
argued that a cap on auditors’ liability would increase
competition in the audit market, especially for large firm audits,
on the grounds that a cap would encourage medium-sized audit
firms to move up into the “big league”. However, an analysis by
the Office of Fair Trading concluded that such a result was not a
likely impact of the reform.217 A more robust approach might be
to seek to open up the audit market, especially the market for the
audit of the largest companies, to a wider range of firms. As we
have seen above, rules relating to mandatory re-tendering of
audit contracts were driven as much by competition concerns as
by concerns for auditor independence.218
We now turn to the ways in which the current liability rules
reflect the above concerns, looking separately at claims by the
audit client and by others.
CLAIMS BY THE AUDIT CLIENT
Establishing liability
22–36
As we have already noted, the audit client’s cause of action in
negligence is easily established in principle. Thus, the litigation
is likely to focus on the question of whether the auditor has in
fact been negligent and, if so, whether and how much loss has
been caused to the claimant. As far as the standard of care is
concerned, it is clear in law, though often not accepted in the
commercial world, that the auditor is not a guarantor of the
accuracy of the directors’ accounts and reports. Indeed, in an old
case the auditor was given a broad discretion to rely on
information provided by management, so long as no suspicious
circumstances had arisen which should have put the auditor on
inquiry.219 However, the modern law is different. As Lord
Denning once put it, the auditor, in order to perform his task
properly, “must come to it with an inquiring mind—not
suspicious of dishonesty, I agree—but suspecting that someone
may have made a mistake somewhere and that a check must be
made to ensure that there has been none”.220 Auditor scepticism
is now firmly established in audit regulation. The Directive
requires Member States to ensure that the auditor “maintains
professional scepticism throughout the audit”.221 As to what
“scepticism” will require, the existence of accounting and
auditing standards helps the courts to concretise the duty of care
in any particular situation, even though they are not formally
binding on the courts.222 A court which relies on these standards
can be sure that it is not imposing unexpected standards of care
on auditors and that there has been some ‘public interest’ input
into the formulation of the standards.
As to the quantum of liability, the auditor’s failure to detect
error in the company’s financial statements deprives the
directors (or shareholders) of knowledge which could have
afforded them an opportunity to take remedial action or to
prevent the company from proceeding with some action on a
false basis (for example, by declaring a dividend or making
representations and warranties in a contract for the sale of the
company’s business). That remedial action might take a number
of forms, ranging from preventing a continuance of
mismanagement or fraud to deciding to sell a company whose
business model a proper audit would have shown to be under
serious threat from changing economic circumstances. However,
the auditor is not liable on a simple “but for” test for the
company’s failure through ignorance to take such action. For
liability to arise, the action which the company might have taken
or avoided must be one that was within the scope of the auditor’s
duty of care. This principle will embrace liability in respect of
decisions that companies normally take on the basis of the
accounts, such as declaring dividends or paying bonuses,
whether to staff or policy-holders.223 Thus, the auditor’s liability
will embrace losses caused to the company where the directors
would have acted differently in these areas if they had known the
full facts, even if the decision actually taken was perfectly
lawful. Beyond such decisions, the auditor’s duty of care will
depend in large part on the scope of the audit engagement. The
auditor’s liability may extend to wider classes of decision,
including strategic corporate decisions, if it is clear that the audit
engagement contemplated that the company needed the audit
information to make such decisions.224
22–37
In many cases, for example where the remedial action was the
possible sale of the company’s undertaking, what the company
will have lost is really the chance to take a particular step, i.e. to
find a purchaser at an acceptable price—who might or might not
have been forthcoming. The pecuniary value to be placed on that
lost opportunity depends upon the degree of likelihood that
action would have been taken and that it would have led to the
outcome the company alleges would have been reached. The
court will have to assess the value of that chance, awarding the
chance no value if it thinks it purely speculative.225 Even where
there was a course of action the directors could have taken which
was wholly within their own control, liability will depend on its
being shown that the step would have been taken. Often this will
be difficult to do, especially in the case of fraud or
mismanagement, when those involved included the directors.
Then, it would seem, to establish any loss the claimant would
have to show on the balance of probabilities that, had the
auditors’ report been properly qualified, action would have been
taken by the shareholders which would have led to the removal
of the directors. To recover any substantial damages, the
claimant would have to establish, further, a probability that the
ill-consequences of the former directors’ negligent or fraudulent
reign would have been effectively remedied by the steps which
would have been taken. The difficulties of establishing all this
are obvious.
Limiting liability
22–38
Even if the claimant can establish liability and substantial loss,
there are two types of argument available to the auditors to
reduce their liability for the whole of that loss, one based on
general defences (full or partial) to tortious liability and the other
on contract.
General defences
22–39
The most obviously available defence is contributory negligence,
whereby a claimant, who suffers loss as a result partly of his or
her own fault and partly of the defendant’s fault, will have the
damages payable by the latter reduced by such amount as the
court thinks just and equitable, having regard to the claimant’s
share of the responsibility for the damage.226 Thus, where harm
has been inflicted on the company through fraud committed by
its employees which the directors failed to discover because they
had inadequate internal controls in place and which the auditors
failed to discover because they did not realise the internal
controls were inadequate, the failures of the directors are the
failures of the company which the auditors can pray in aid to
reduce the damages payable. The disclosure statement now
required of directors in the directors’ report is likely to increase
the incidence of this defence being run by the auditors.227
In fact, a somewhat similar result seems to have been obtained
before this reform through the use by auditors of “representation
letters”, which auditors require companies to sign before the
auditors will certify the accounts. In these letters the company
typically promises “to the best of its knowledge and belief” that
certain important matters concerning the company’s financial
situation are in a particular state.228 If such a representation letter
is signed negligently on behalf of the company, the auditors will
have the partial defence of contributory negligence if
subsequently sued by the company and it can be shown that the
auditors would not have certified the accounts, or not certified
them without further investigation, had they known the true
facts. If the representation letter is signed fraudulently, the
auditors have a complete defence, because any damages due
from the auditors to the company can be wholly set off in the
claim the auditors have against the company for deceit
committed by the company against the auditors.229
In the above cases the situation is one where the both the
auditors and the directors or senior management of the company
failed to discover the fraud or negligence of a subordinate
employee and where both are at fault in failing to do so.
Reducing the company’s recovery seems acceptable in this
context for otherwise the existence of auditor liability would
provide an incentive for companies not to manage their internal
risk systems effectively. What is much less clear is whether the
auditors should be permitted to build a defence of contributory
negligence directly on the actions of the subordinate employee,
i.e. in a situation where the only failure to discover the fraud or
negligence is that of the auditors. The argument against allowing
contributory negligence on this basis is that it reduces the
incentive of the auditors to discover wrongdoing within the
company—sometimes put as the argument that contributory
negligence should not be based on conduct within the company
which was “the very thing” (or one of those things) the auditors
were under a duty to discover.
22–40
In Barings Plc (In Liquidation) v Coopers & Lybrand230 the
judge took account of both management failings and the
undiscovered fraud of the employee (which was attributed to the
company) in assessing the level of the company’s contributory
negligence. Applying this approach the judge assessed the
company’s contributory negligence at a high level, varying over
the time of the fraud, beginning at a 50 per cent contribution and
ending at 95 per cent. However, the judge did recognise some
force in “the very thing” argument,231 for it appears that he
would otherwise have attributed the employee’s fraud to the
company so as to allow the auditors to avoid all liability. We
need thus to consider again the rules on attribution, which we
looked at in Ch.7, but here in a different context. In Ch.7 we
considered attribution in the context of litigation by third parties
against the company; here we consider litigation by the company
against third parties. It is not obvious that the attribution rules
should be the same, at least where the third party is the auditor,
precisely because of the protective function of the auditors as
against the company, which a broad set of rules on attribution
might undermine.
22–41
The issue arose in an extreme form in Stone & Rolls Ltd v Moore
Stephens232 where the defendant auditors sought to raise the
defence of illegality as a complete defence to liability. In this
case a person who was the sole beneficial shareholder and
controlling shadow director of a company established it for the
purpose of committing large-scale fraud on banks. The company,
in liquidation, sought compensation through its liquidator (acting
in the economic interests of the creditors) for the allegedly
negligent failure the defendant auditor to discover the fraud. The
defendant sought to strike out the claim on the basis of an
illegality defence usually referred to by its Latin name: ex turpi
causa non oritur actio (roughly translated as “disgraceful conduct
does not give rise to a cause of action”). This is a rule of public
policy that the court will not allow its processes to be used by a
claimant to benefit from its own illegal conduct. In this case, the
majority by three to two allowed the defence, because of the
controller’s fraud, though on rather different grounds. As the
Supreme Court itself said in a later case, Jetivia SA v Bilta (UK)
Ltd,233 “it is very hard to derive much in the way of reliable
principle from the decision” in the earlier case.
In the later case, however, all the judges seemed to agree on
one proposition, namely, that the ex turpi defence is available
only if there are no “innocent” (i.e. uninvolved in the fraud)
shareholders or directors in the company. The decision thus
affects only a limited number of claims by companies against
their auditors. There was disagreement, however, on whether the
defence was always available in the absence of innocent
shareholders (and, perhaps, directors).234 This was the most
significant dividing line among the judges in Stone & Rolls
itself. Since the company was in liquidation at the time of the
litigation, the persons with an economic interest in the success of
the claim were its creditors (i.e. the defrauded banks), who were
“innocent”. If the presence of innocent shareholders would have
been enough to prevent use of the ex turpi defence by the
auditors, presumably on the grounds that a public policy defence
should not be deployed to deprive non-involved persons of the
value of their interest in the company, it can be argued that the
presence of innocent creditors of a company in liquidation
should have the same negative impact on the availability of the
defence. This argument does not involve acceptance of the
proposition that auditors’ duties are owed to the company’s
creditors (an argument which, as we see in the next section, the
courts have accepted only in limited situations). The duty here is
still one owed by the auditors to the company; the litigation is
brought by the body which has the management of the company
—the liquidator in this case; and the basis of the auditor’s
liability remains restoration of the company’s assets to the level
they would have enjoyed had the auditors not been negligent.
The point rather is that, so long as the company is a going
concern, the residual economic interest in the company’s assets
lies with the shareholders, so that excluding liability where all
the shareholders are involved in the fraud is understandable.
However, once the company is in the vicinity of insolvency, the
residual economic interest shifts to the creditors, as the law now
clearly recognises.235 If the interests of non-involved
shareholders trump the ex turpi defence when the company is a
going concern, it would be consonant with recent developments
in company law that the interests of non-involved creditors
should be taken into account in the same way.236
Limitation by contract
22–42
It was formerly impossible for auditors to limit their liability to
the company by means of a contract with it or by provision in
the company’s articles, or to obtain an enforceable promise of an
indemnity from the company in respect of such liability,237 but
one of the main changes in the 2006 Act was to permit such
contracts, subject to safeguards.238 The indemnity prohibition did
and does not apply if it relates to an agreement or provision to
indemnify the auditor against a liability incurred in defending
proceedings, criminal or civil, in which the auditor is successful
or in making a successful application for relief under s.1157 of
the Act.239 This is a limited qualification to the prohibition which
does no more than track the provisions relating to directors.240
The innovation is the permission for the auditor and company
to contract to limit the amount of a liability the auditor owes to
the company arising out of a breach of duty in the conduct of the
audit. The section is widely enough drafted to permit the parties
to introduce proportionate liability by agreement. This reform
was recommended by the CLR but it is subject to reasonably
strict safeguards. The principal ones are as follows:
(a) The agreement is effective to limit the auditor’s liability only
to the amount that is fair and reasonable in the circumstances,
having regard, amongst other things, to the auditor’s
responsibilities under the Act and the professional standards
expected of the auditor.241 If the agreement goes further than
is permitted by this provision, then it operates so as to limit
liability to the permitted level, i.e. the agreement does not fail
altogether.242 The agreement is exempted from the control
provisions of the Unfair Contract Terms Act 1977,243 which
applies a reasonableness standard to similar limitations of
negligence liability in many contracts. In short, the auditor
limitation clause is subject to ex post court control by
reference to a broad standard, as under UCTA, but the
significance of the exclusion from UCTA 1977 is that a
clause which fails the test under the 2006 Act still operates,
but at a lower level of substantive protection.
(b) The agreement may relate to only a single financial year, i.e.
a new agreement is needed for each set of annual reports and
accounts.244
(c) The agreement must be approved by the members, though in
the case of a private company the members, before the
company enters into the agreement, may pass a resolution
waiving the need for approval.245
To provide a check that these requirements have been met, a
note to the companies accounts must set out the principal terms
of the liability limitation agreement and the date on which it was
approved by the members (or approval was waived).246
The FRC produced guidance on the operation of these
provisions,247 which contemplates three main types of
agreement: proportionate liability, a “fair and reasonable” test
and a cap on liability, which could be expressed in a number of
ways, but most obviously as a multiple of the audit fee.
However, institutional shareholders have indicated that they will
normally vote in favour only of proportionate liability
agreements and, in particular, will be opposed to caps on
liability.248 Further, they will expect an improvement in audit
quality in exchange for the agreement, in particular, less
defensive auditing.
Criminal liability
22–43
The 2006 Act reform, permitting auditor liability limitation
agreements, was accompanied by an increase of criminal
liability for an auditor who knowingly or recklessly makes a
statement in the audit report which is misleading, false or
deceptive.249 In other words, the deterrent effect of unlimited
liability in damages for negligence was to some extent replaced
by a narrower criminal liability for intentional or reckless
misstatements.250 The liability applies to the statement that the
accounts give a true and fair view251 and to statements in the
audit report about the compliance of the company’s accounts
with its accounting records, about whether the necessary
information and explanations were forthcoming from
management and others, and about whether the company was
entitled to prepare accounts under the small companies
regime.252 Curiously, however, the liability applies only to that
part of the auditor’s report which deals strictly with the accounts.
Thus, it does not apply to the auditor’s report on the directors’ or
strategic report, the separate corporate governance statement or
the auditable part of the directors’ remuneration report. In this
respect, the criminal liability of auditors is narrower than that of
directors, which extends to knowing or reckless authorisation of
publication of non-compliant directors’ reports as well as of
accounts.253 There was much pressure in Parliament from the
auditing profession to remove the liability for recklessness, but
the Government stoutly resisted it.254
CLAIMS BY THIRD PARTIES
The duty of care in principle
22–44
The issues discussed above relating to breach of duty and loss
arise in relation to third-party claims (i.e. claims by anyone other
than the audit client) as well, but the prior and most controversial
issue has been to define the circumstances in which a duty of
care will be owed at all by the auditors to third parties. Here the
courts have applied in the auditing context the general common
law rules governing the duty of care in relation to economic loss
caused by negligent misstatement. Until less than 50 years ago,
this was not a live issue, because until the decision in Hedley
Byrne & Co Ltd v Heller & Partners Ltd255 the law of negligence
did not recognise a general duty to take care to avoid
misstatements causing economic loss. Liability in damages
could, and still can, be based on the tort of deceit, as had been
recognised in the nineteenth century, but that liability is subject
to two major restrictions. First, liability arises only if the maker
of the statement knows that it is false or makes it not caring
whether it is true of false, so that an honest, even if
unreasonable, belief in the truth of the statement protects its
maker from liability in deceit (or fraud).256 Secondly, the maker
of the statement must intend the claimant (or a class of persons
of whom the claimant is one) to rely on the statement.257 The
effect of the first limitation is to restrict the circumstances in
which liability in deceit will arise and the effect of the second is
to restrict the range of potential claimants if it does arise. The
impact of the decision in Hedley Byrne was to side-step both
these limitations, which are not part of the tort of negligence.
However, it was not at all clear from Hedley Byrne (which was
not a case concerning the audit) when the new duty of care to
avoid misstatements258 causing economic loss would be imposed
on auditors.
22–45
The answer to these questions, at least in broad outline, was
provided by what is undoubtedly the leading case on the
application of these rules to auditors, the decision of the House
of Lords in Caparo Industries Plc v Dickman,259 and was
provided in a way which gave greater comfort to auditors than to
investors. The facts of the case are worth recounting briefly.
Like many of the cases decided around this period, the factual
background of Caparo involved the purchase of a company
whose economic prospects were discovered after the purchase to
be less promising than the purchaser had thought beforehand.
The purchaser then looked around for someone to sue in respect
of what was alleged to be the misleading information about the
company which had been made available. In Caparo the
purchase was of a target company listed on the London Stock
Exchange by another such company through a takeover offer
preceded by share purchases in the market. The target company
had issued a profit-warning in March 1984, which caused its
share price to halve. In May 1984 the directors of the target
made a preliminary announcement of its annual results for the
year to March 1984, which confirmed that profits were well
short of expectations. This caused a further, though less
dramatic, fall in the share price. In June the annual accounts
were issued to the shareholders. Shortly before the June date,
Caparo, which had previously owned no shares in the target,
began acquiring shares in tranches until it reached a
shareholding of 29.9 per cent, at which point (after the accounts
had been circulated) it made a general offer for the remaining
shares, as the Takeover Code required it to do if it was to acquire
any more of the target’s shares.260 Caparo asserted that the 1984
accounts, although gloomy, in fact overvalued the company and
that the auditors had been negligent in not detecting the
irregularities or fraud which had led to the overstatements in the
accounts and in certifying the accounts as representing a true and
fair view of the company’s financial position.
The House of Lords’ examination of the statutory framework
for company accounts and audits led them to the following
conclusions. The statutory provisions establish a relationship
between those responsible for the accounts (the directors) or for
the audit report (the auditors), on the one hand, and some other
class or classes of persons, on the other, and this relationship
imposes a duty of care owed by the directors or auditors to those
persons. Among these “persons” is the company itself, to which,
apart altogether from the statutory provisions, the directors are in
a fiduciary relationship and the auditors in a contractual
relationship by virtue of their employment by the company as its
auditors. However, the statutory provisions do not establish such
a relationship with everybody who has a right to be furnished
with copies of the accounts or report or, a fortiori, with
everybody who has a right to inspect or obtain copies of them
from the Registrar of companies (i.e. the world at large).261 If a
relationship other than with the company is to be established so
as to give rise to a duty of care, it can be only with the members
of the company (and perhaps debenture-holders) and, even in
their case, the scope of the resulting duty of care extends only to
the protection of what may be described as the members’
corporate governance powers to safeguard their interests in the
company. Not within the scope of the duty are shareholders’
decisions to buy further shares in the company even if it is a
perusal of the annual accounts and reports that led them to do
so.262
22–46
To establish a duty of care to members which is greater in scope
than this, or to establish any duty of care to other persons, there
must be an additional “special” relationship with the person who
suffered loss as a result of relying on the accounts or report. To
succeed in establishing that additional relationship, the claimant
must show that the auditors (or directors) contemplated that the
accounts and report:
“would be communicated to the plaintiff either as an individual or as a member of
an identifiable class, specifically in connection with a particular transaction or
transactions of a particular kind (e.g. in a prospectus inviting investment)263 and
that the plaintiff would be very likely to rely on it for the purpose of deciding
whether or not to enter upon that transaction or upon a transaction of that kind.”264
EQUITY FINANCE
23–2
The definition of a share which is, perhaps, the most widely
quoted is that of Farwell J in Borland’s Trustee v Steel9:
“A share is the interest of a shareholder in the company measured by a sum of
money, for the purpose of liability in the first place, and of interest in the second,
but also consisting of a series of mutual covenants entered into by all the
shareholders inter se in accordance with [s.33]. The contract contained in the
articles of association is one of the original incidents of the share. A share is not a
sum of money …but is an interest measured by a sum of money and made up of
various rights contained in the contract, including the right to a sum of money of a
more or less amount.”
24–1
In the previous chapter we examined how the company attaches
rights to shares. We now need to look at the process by which a
company issues shares to those who wish to invest in it. The
crucial regulatory divide is between offers to the public to
acquire the company’s shares and offers which are non-public.
The regulatory regime is much more elaborate in the former
case. In addition, since a public offer is often combined with the
provision of a trading facility for the shares on a stock exchange
or other trading platform (though it need not be), the rules
governing that process become of crucial importance as well.
Where there is no public offer, the relevant rules are still to be
found mainly in the Companies Act and the common law of
companies, rather than in the Financial Services and Markets Act
2000 and in rules made by the FCA. In this chapter we deal with
the rules that apply to offers of securities, whether the offer is a
public one or not. The additional requirements applying only to
public offers are treated in the following chapter. However,
some of the rules discussed in this chapter, for example, the pre-
emption rules, have their greatest impact when the offer is a
public one. The domestic law considered in this chapter has been
substantially influenced by the Second Company Law Directive
of the Community,1 but, in contrast with its provisions on legal
capital, its rules on share issuance have generally been
welcomed by shareholders as strengthening their position,
though, often, not as strongly as they would wish.
PUBLIC AND NON-PUBLIC OFFERS
24–2
A public company has a choice whether to make a public offer
of its shares. It is not obliged to do so and if it refrains from
making a public offer, it will escape the regulation analysed in
the following chapter, although it will find that its fund-raising
possibilities are much constrained. Hence arises an ambiguity in
the meaning of the term “public company”. By those concerned
with capital markets the term is used to refer to companies which
have indeed made a public offering of their securities and
introduced those shares to trading on a public market. However,
under the Companies Act a public company is simply one that
may lawfully make a public offering of its securities, whether it
has actually done so or not. In this book, the term “public
company” means one that is public in the Companies Act sense
of the term, whilst one which has actually made a public offer of
its securities is referred to as a “publicly traded”2 company or
one which has “gone public”. Under the Companies Act the
contrast between a “public” and a “private” company is that a
private company is prohibited from offering securities3 to the
public, either directly or through an offer for sale via an
intermediary.4 Thus, a private company may make only a non-
public offer of its shares, and, indeed, this is the defining
characteristic of a private company; but a public company (under
the Companies Act) may or may not have made a public offer.
If a private company does make a public offer, the validity of
any agreement to sell or allot securities or of any sale or
allotment is not affected by breach of the prohibition, thus
protecting innocent third parties who wish to enforce their rights
under the contract of issuance of the shares,5 and the criminal
sanctions which previously underlay the prohibition have been
removed. Nevertheless, the court has a wide range of powers to
deal with the consequences of a breach or potential breach, on
application of any member or creditor of the company or the
Secretary of State or on its own motion in an unfair prejudice
application. The court may enjoin the proposed issue6; require
the company to re-register as a public company (the statute’s
preferred ex post remedy)7; and, if it decides against re-
registration, it may wind the company up or make a remedial
order.8 The purpose of the remedial order is to put the person in
whose favour it is made (who may be a subsequent holder of the
share) in the position they would have been in had the breach of
the prohibition not occurred.9 The court has a wide discretion as
to the contents of the remedial order, including the power to
order the company and any others “knowingly concerned” in
contravention of the prohibition to offer to purchase the
securities at a price determined by the court.10 For a private
company to contemplate breaching the prohibition is, thus, a
highly risky business, both for it and its officers and advisers. On
the other hand, the requirements for becoming a public company
are not onerous and the company can even leave conversion until
after the issue has succeeded, provided conversion is part of the
terms of issue.11
24–3
The definition of what is a public offer for the purpose of the Act
is in s.756. This section makes it clear that “public” includes a
section of the public (“however selected”).12 On the other hand,
the definition excludes an offer which “can properly be regarded,
in all the circumstances, as not being calculated to result, directly
or indirectly, in the shares or debentures becoming available for
subscription or purchase by persons other than those receiving
the offer or invitation”.13 Also excluded are offers which are of
“domestic concern” to the company, into which category fall,
presumptively, offers to the company’s existing members or
employees, their families, debenture-holders of the company or a
trustee for any of the above.14
The main issue with this definition is that it does not
correspond exactly to the definition of a “public offer” used for
the purposes of determining the applicability of the additional
regulation discussed in the next chapter. In particular, it does not
replicate the definition of a public offer in the Prospectus
Directive,15 which determines whether a prospectus is required
(and regulates its contents, if it is). On the one hand, some offers
regarded as private under the Act might be public under the
Directive. This is because the “offerees only” exemption of the
Act appears to set no limit on the number of people who receive
the offer nor to impose any qualification as to their experience or
qualifications as investors, whilst the central exemptions in the
Directive are based on one or other of these limitations.16 In
other words, a private company might make what is a public
offer for the purposes of the Directive without contravening the
prohibition in the Act. In such a case, of course, the private
company will have to comply with the requirements of the
Directive, as transposed into domestic law, and so no real
conflict arises, provided those concerned realise that private
companies may fall within the prospectus rules in some cases.
On the other hand, a private company may be prevented by
the Act from making an offer in respect of which, if it were a
public company, it would not need to produce a prospectus,
because the offer would fall within one of the exemptions
contained in the Directive. The Company Law Review, whilst
recommending that some alignment of the definition of “public
offer” in the Act with that in the Directive, did not think that the
lack of fit was in principle objectionable, because different
policies were being pursued by the two sets of rules. There might
be good reasons for preventing a private company from making
a public offer, even if such an offer would not attract the
requirement for a prospectus under EU law. The CLR’s view
was that some of these exemptions from the prospectus
requirement were “wholly inappropriate” for a private company,
because they might allow the private company to reach “very
large economic scale”. This should be permitted only if the
company were prepared to undertake the burdens of a public
company.17 Of course, most share issues by private companies
come nowhere near being classified as public for the purposes of
either the Act or the Directive.
DIRECTORS’AUTHORITY TO ALLOT SHARES
24–4
Issuance of shares by a company involves essentially three steps.
First, the company must decide to make an offer of shares,
public or non-public, and set the terms of the offer. Secondly,
some person or persons must agree with the company to take the
shares (at which point the shares are said to have been
“allotted”). Thirdly, in implementation of that contract, those
persons must take the shares and be made members of the
company, thus completing the process of issuance. We shall look
at each stage in turn.
The first question is whether the decision to allot shares18 is
one for the board alone or whether the shareholders’ concurrence
is required. We have seen that the company’s decision to allot
shares ranking along with or even ahead of the company’s
existing shares does not normally amount to a variation of the
rights of the existing shareholders, so that their consent will not
be required under the variation of class-rights procedure,19 even
though the practical value of those rights may well be affected
by such an issue. Even if the new shares are to rank behind the
existing shares, the shareholders may still have doubts about the
directors’ plans for the use of the finance which will be raised.
Thus, it is a matter of some importance whether the Act requires
the shareholders’ consent to a share issue or whether the matter
is left entirely to the company’s articles of association. If the Act
does not intervene, the situation is likely to be that the board has
power to issue shares as part of its general management powers,
and the articles may or may not give the shareholders a role in
the decision-making process. Thus, the question becomes
whether the Act should make shareholder consent mandatory or
leave this issue to be determined by the company’s articles.
The Second Company Law Directive20 contains the principle
that consent of the shareholders is required. The Directive
applies only to public companies, although the Government,
when transposing it into domestic law in 1980, chose to apply
the principle to private companies as well, albeit in a more
flexible way. However, the CLR proposed21 to remove the
requirement of shareholder authorisation for the issuance of
shares by private companies, except where the company already
had or the directors’ proposal would create more than one class
of shares. This would be a default rule, for private companies’
articles might restore the requirement of shareholder approval.
This reform was implemented in the 2006 Act.22 The
requirement for shareholder consent was thought to be an
unnecessary formality in private companies, with their greater
overlap of directors and members. However, such overlap would
not necessarily obtain, and there would be the risk of greater
opportunism, if the company had, or was about to create, more
than one class of share.
24–5
Except in relation to the private company with only one class of
share, however, shareholder consent, in one form or another, is
still required for the allotment of shares. Not to obtain it is a
criminal offence on the part of the directors knowingly
involved,23 although such failure does not affect the validity of
the allotment.24 The requirement is applied not only to the
allotment of shares but also to the grant of rights to subscribe for
or to convert a security into shares in the company in the future,
for example, a convertible bond.25 Otherwise, the requirement of
shareholder consent could be avoided easily, for example, by
issuing a debt security convertible at a later stage into shares. In
this case, the requirement for shareholder approval is imposed at
the stage of issuance but is not repeated at the conversion stage.26
However, if, unusually, a convertible bond is convertible into
existing, rather than new, shares of the company, then
shareholder consent would not be needed at the allotment stage
either.27
Shareholder authorisation may take the form of the directors
putting before the shareholders a proposal for the issuance of a
particular amount of shares to fund a specific project, with full
details of how the finance raised will be used. This is
authorisation for “a particular use of the power”.28 However,
authorisation can be given generally, either in the articles or by
(ordinary) resolution, for (renewable) periods of up to five
years.29 With general authorisation, where no specific use of the
power may be under contemplation at the time, information
about how the funds raised will be used will necessarily be very
general and will be phrased so as to give management maximum
freedom of action. However, the authority, whether general or
particular, must state the maximum number of securities which
can be allotted under it and the date at which the authority will
expire.30 Moreover, the authorisation may be made conditional,31
and it may be revoked or varied at any time by resolution of the
company, even if the original authority was contained in the
articles.32 Institutional shareholders do attach importance to the
general requirement for shareholder authorisation of share issues
by the board. Guidance from the Association of British Insurers
indicates that its members will not vote in favour of resolutions
giving authority above a certain size. That size used to be one
third of the company’s existing issued share capital. In 2008 the
limit was increased, under the pressures discussed in the next
section, to two thirds, provided that the second third could be
issued only on a pre-emptive basis and the authorisation for the
second third was renewed yearly.33
PRE-EMPTIVE RIGHTS
Policy issues
24–6
Whether or not collective shareholder consent is required for
allotment of shares, there is a further issue whether the existing
shareholders individually should have a “right of first refusal”
over the new shares or, in company law terms, whether the
shares should be issued on a pre-emptive basis. The basic
principle underlying the pre-emption rules is that a shareholder
should be able to protect his or her proportion of the total equity
by having the opportunity to subscribe, in proportion to the
existing holding, for any new issue for cash of equity capital or
securities having an equity element.34 There are two main
reasons why a shareholder might wish to exercise this right and
thus to prevent the “dilution” of his or her holding of equity
shares. First, if new voting shares are issued and a shareholder
does not acquire that amount of the new issue which is
proportionate to the existing holding, that person’s influence in
the company may be reduced because he or she now has control
over a smaller percentage of the votes. In listed companies this is
likely to be of concern only to large, often institutional,
shareholders, but in small companies the issuance of new shares
may well have a significant impact upon the balance of power
within the company, and perhaps be motived by a desire to bring
this change about. Here, pre-emptive rights operate as a potential
limit on the freedom of the directors to affect a shift in the
balance of control in the company by issuing new equity shares
carrying voting rights to new investors.35
Secondly, large issues of new shares by a publicly traded
company are likely to be priced at a discount to the existing
market price, in order to encourage their sale. Once the new
shares are allocated, all the shares of the relevant class, new and
old, will inevitably trade on the market at the same price. This
new price will be somewhere between the issue price of the new
shares and the previous market price of the existing shares,
depending upon the size of the discount and the size of the new
issue. In the absence of protective regulation, if an existing
shareholder does not acquire the relevant proportion of the new
shares, the loss of market value of the existing holding will be
uncompensated. The new shareholders, in effect, will have been
let into the company too cheaply, and the existing shareholders
will have paid the price for that decision.36
The protection against voting dilution afforded by a bare pre-
emptive right is only partial. The shareholder must also be in a
position financially to take up the shares on offer.37 A financially
constrained existing shareholder is thus not protected against
voting dilution by pre-emption. The same might seem to be true
of financial dilution. However, here the addition of a further
feature to the basic pre-emption model can help. If the
shareholder is able to sell his or her pre-emptive rights in the
market, that will provide compensation for the loss suffered. The
rights will have a value equal to the difference between the issue
price of the new shares and the (higher) price at which the whole
class will trade after the issue, which will compensate the
shareholder for loss caused by the difference between the pre-
issue value of that person’s holding and the (lower) value it will
have after the new issue.38 However, for the rights to be
marketable they must be transferable to third parties. There is an
established way of providing this facility. The company issues a
“renounceable” letter of allotment, which gives the shareholder
the option to subscribe for the new shares or to transfer the right
to subscribe to a third party, the overall process being known as
a “rights issue”.39 Provided the shareholder transfers the right to
acquire the new shares before the time for exercising it expires
(i.e. “renounces” it) the third party will pay the company for the
new shares, having paid the shareholder for the acquisition of the
right to subscribe.40
The scope of the statutory right
24–7
The Act creates a pre-emptive right in favour of existing
shareholders, but it does not require companies to add the
additional feature of a rights issue.41 The company may simply
make what is usually termed an “open” offer to its existing
shareholders: the shareholder either takes the shares at the price
asked or passes up the offer altogether. It is, however, common
practice in listed companies for pre-emptive offers to be made on
a renounceable basis.42 We will first examine the shareholder’s
legal entitlements and then see how institutional pressure has
moved practice beyond the statute in many cases.
The ambit of the statutory pre-emptive provisions extends
only to issues for cash of “equity securities”. These are defined
as ordinary shares (and rights to subscribe for or convert
securities into ordinary shares); and an ordinary share is any
share other than one where the holder’s right to participate in a
distribution (whether by way of dividend or return of capital) is
limited by reference to a fixed amount.43 It does not matter
whether the existing shares carry votes or not, and in fact it can
be argued that pre-emptive rights are particularly important for
the holders of non-voting shares, who will obtain no protection
from the rules on shareholder authorisation discussed in the
previous section. Certain types of share issue are excluded from
the pre-emption rules, even if they arguably involve the issue of
equity shares for cash: bonus shares (where the pre-emption
problem does not arise)44 or shares to be held under an
employees’ share scheme.45 Nor do the rules apply to shares
taken by subscribers on the formation of a company.46
Moreover, pre-emptive rights will be triggered only if the
proposed issue is exclusively for cash.47 For example, if a
company wishing to acquire a business proposed to allot
ordinary shares as consideration to the vendor, it would be
impracticable to make a pre-emptive offer to the existing
shareholders on the same terms. Nevertheless, the restriction of
the statutory pre-emptive provisions to cash issues, even if
compelled by necessity, does make a severe hole in the principle
of protecting shareholders against dilution, especially dilution of
their voting position. In relation to financial dilution some
alternative protection is provided by Ch.6 of Pt 17 of the Act,
requiring an independent valuation report in the case of share
issues by public companies for a non-cash consideration,48 but,
even so, that section does not confer individual rights upon
shareholders in the way that the pre-emption rules do.
24–8
Futhermore, the exclusion of share issues which are wholly or
partly other than for cash gives rise to possibilities of
manipulation so as to avoid the pre-emption rules. For example,
if any part of the consideration, even a minor part, is not cash,
then it appears that the pre-emption rules are excluded. This may
be of particular interest to private companies. In other cases it
may well be possible to restructure the transaction so that the
cash is provided otherwise than to the issuer in exchange for its
shares. Thus, where Company A wishes to acquire part of the
business of Company B, the latter wishing to receive cash,
Company A might issue new shares to raise the necessary
money, if it does not have sufficient available cash, thus
attracting the pre-emption provisions in relation to its
shareholders. Instead, however, Company A might issue its
shares to Company B, in exchange for the latter’s assets and thus
without attracting the pre-emption provisions, Company A
having previously arranged for an investment bank to offer to
buy the shares from Company B at a fixed price and to place
them with interested investors. Such a “vendor placing” gives
Company B the cash it wanted, whilst relieving Company A of
the need to abide by the pre-emption rules.49
24–9
Assuming none of the above limitations apply, the pre-emption
obligation requires the company not to allot equity securities to
any person unless it has first offered, on the same or more
favourable terms, to each person who holds shares covered by
the right a proportion of those equity securities which is as
nearly as practicable equal to the shareholder’s existing
proportion in nominal value of the existing shares.50 Only if the
period for the existing shareholders to accept the offer has
expired (now at least 14 days)51 without the offer being accepted
(or if it was positively rejected within this period) may an offer
be made to outsiders. If the pre-emptive offer is not accepted in
full, shares not taken up may be allotted to anyone; accepting
existing shareholders do not have further pre-emptive rights in
respect of those unaccepted shares.
Waiver
24–10
The shareholders collectively can forego their statutory pre-
emption rights: they can be excluded or disapplied. Exclusion
means the statutory provisions do not operate at all;
disapplication may mean that but it also embraces the situation
where the statutory provisions apply “with such modifications as
the directors may determine”52 or such modifications as are
specified in the disapplication resolution.53 Not surprisingly,
both exclusion and disapplication are easier for private than for
public companies. A private company may exclude the
obligation to offer pre-emptive rights (or a provision relating to
the method of offering, most likely the time during which the
offer must be open) through a provision in its articles—either
generally or in relation to allotments of a particular description.54
As for disapplication, if the private company has only one class
of shares, so that the directors do not need shareholder authority
to issue new shares, its articles or a special resolution of the
shareholders may remove the pre-emptive obligation or give the
directors power to modify the statutory scheme.55
In relation to public companies exclusion is available only
where the articles provide a pre-emptive alternative to the
statutory scheme. This provision is designed to deal with
situations where the company has more than one class of
ordinary share.56 The statutory pre-emptive obligation57 is
drafted in such a way as not to differentiate among different
classes of ordinary shares, so that an offer of ordinary shares of
one class would have to be made pre-emptively to all classes of
ordinary shareholder. Section 568 permits a company to
substitute an alternative pre-emption scheme in its articles which
operates on a class basis. Non-compliance with the procedure in
the articles carries the same consequences as non-compliance
with the statutory procedure.58
As for disapplication, the provisions applicable to public
companies (and private companies with more than one class of
share) are built onto the rules on directors’ authority to issue
shares, discussed above. Where such authorisation is needed and
has been given “generally”,59 the articles or a special resolution
may disapply the pre-emption rights entirely or give the directors
a discretion to apply them with such modifications as they may
determine.60 The disapplication lasts only so long as the general
authority and, if the authority is renewed, the disapplication will
need renewal as well. In other words, the disapplication can be
for a maximum period of five years.
Alternatively, where authorisation is required, and it has been
given either generally or specifically, a special resolution may
disapply the statutory provisions in relation to a particular
issuance of shares or determine that they shall apply only with
such modifications as are specified in the resolution.61 Again, the
disapplication lasts only so long as the authorisation to which it
relates, though this is a less important provision in relation to
specified allotments. Unusually for British company law, a
special resolution in relation to a specified allotment may not be
proposed unless it has been recommended by the directors, and
there is circulated a written statement by the directors of their
reasons for making the recommendation, the amount to be paid
to the company in respect of the proposed issue, and the
directors’ justification of that amount.62 A person, director or
otherwise, who knowingly or recklessly authorises or permits the
inclusion in the statement of information which is misleading,
false or deceptive commits a criminal offence.63
24–11
It is relatively common for public companies to make use of the
disapplication provisions, even where the directors have every
intention of respecting the principle of pre-emption, because
greater flexibility can be built into the arrangements. A common
desire is to exclude from the offer shareholders in foreign
jurisdictions whose securities laws are regarded as excessively
burdensome in relation to the number of the company’s investors
located there.64 Even if the statutory rules have been disapplied,
however, a publicly traded company is likely to be subject to the
Listing Rules,65 but these specifically permit pre-emptive offers
to exclude holders whom the company considers “necessary or
expedient to exclude from the offer on account of the laws or
regulatory requirements of” another country.66 Finally, there may
be disapplication in relation to treasury shares, whether held by a
public or a private company.67 The directors do not require
shareholder consent to sell treasury shares (since they are
already in issue) but such sales are caught in principle by the
statutory pre-emption right.68 However, the directors may be
given power to allot free of that right, either generally (by the
articles or by special resolution) or in relation to a specified
allotment (by special resolution).69 One of the arguments for
permitting treasury shares was that it gave companies freedom to
raise relatively small amounts of capital quickly, which a pre-
emption right would hinder, so that it seems correct policy to
facilitate the disapplication of the pre-emption right to treasury
shares.70
Sanctions
24–12
A civil (but not a criminal) sanction is provided by the Act.
When there has been a contravention of the pre-emption right
(either by not providing it all or by not providing it in the way
required by the Act), the company and every officer of it who
knowingly authorised or permitted the contravention are jointly
and severally liable to compensate any person to whom an offer
should have been made for any loss, damage, costs or
expenses.71 Where under the provisions discussed immediately
above, the statutory provisions are applied in a modified way,
these sanctions will equally apply to a contravention of the
modified provisions.72 The Act does not invalidate an allotment
of shares made in breach of the pre-emptive provisions, no doubt
in order to protect the legitimate interests of third parties.
However, in Re Thundercrest Ltd73 the judge was prepared to
rectify the register74 as against the directors of a small company,
with only three shareholders, where the directors responsible for
the breach of the pre-emptive provisions had allotted the shares
in dispute to themselves.
Listed companies
24–13
Institutional shareholders (pension funds and insurance
companies in particular) have traditionally held a very
significant proportion of the shares of publicly traded
companies.75 For a long time they have placed a high value on
pre-emptive rights. Consequently, market practice, influenced by
the institutional shareholders, goes beyond the statutory rights
embodied in the Act. Indeed, pre-emptive rights were a feature
of market practice in London before the statutory pre-emption
right was introduced into legislation in 1980. There are two
channels through which the institutional shareholders have been
able to advance their views. First, they have been able to
influence effectively the rules made by the FCA relating to the
listing76 of companies and the rules made by the London Stock
Exchange relating to the admission of securities to trading
(though the former are the more important source of rules).
Secondly, they have taken collective action to draw up rules to
govern what action they will or will not support as shareholders
in the pre-emption area. We will look first at the Listing Rules.
The most important Listing Rule in this area is probably the
one which limits the discount at which a company may issue
shares, other than by way of a rights issue, to 10 per cent of the
prevailing market price, unless the shareholders approve a higher
discount.77 This means that, if the company sticks to the bare
pre-emptive entitlement set out in the statute, those shareholders
who cannot afford to take up their rights face only a limited
financial loss, as a result of the cap on the discount. To put the
matter from the company’s point of view, if the success of the
pre-emption offer is thought to require a greater discount than 10
per cent, the directors will need the shareholders’ consent to
proceed with the issue other than as a rights issue.78 The rule is
thus an important restraint on the directors’ powers to proceed
with an open offer and pushes them instead in the direction of a
rights issue, where the shareholders’ financial interests are
protected.
Pre-emption guidelines
24–14
The overall picture which emerges of the above analysis is that
existing shareholders’ right to pre-emption, which the Act
creates, and to pre-emption on a rights basis, which the Listing
Rules indirectly create, may be removed by collective decision
of the shareholders. So the impact in practice of both the statute
and the Listing Rules turns on shareholders’ willingness (or
otherwise) to forego their rights. Since institutional shareholders
are strongly opposed to dilution of their positions, they have
sought to agree guidelines determining the circumstances in
which consent to disapplication will be given. Originally, the
institutions acted alone in drawing up the guidelines but, given
their importance for the financing of companies and the
operation of the capital markets, an element of public interest
has been injected by conducting the discussions under the
auspices of, first, the Bank of England, then the London Stock
Exchange and, now, the Financial Reporting Council.79
Institutionally, this development has resulted in the creation a
Pre-emption Group,80 which issues the guidelines which
determine institutional shareholders’ attitudes to disapplication
resolutions, whether under the statute or the Listing Rules. The
guidelines have no legal status but they articulate a strongly held
and practically significant attitude on the part of the institutions
about the value of pre-emptive rights. This policy of the
institutional investors has turned pre-emption on a rights basis
into an example of a “strong” default rule whose alteration
creates a significant hurdle for the management of the company.
Thus, the statutory provisions and the Listing Rules have much
more bite because of the difficulty of securing shareholder
consent to their disapplication other than in accordance with the
guidelines. On the other hand, if there were no default rules in
the statute and Listing Rules, the institutional shareholders
would face the more demanding task of securing an amendment
to a company’s articles of association, introducing a pre-emption
right.81
The guidelines, currently in the form of a Statement of
Principles,82 distinguish between general and specific
disapplication resolutions. The institutional investors will vote in
favour of general disapplication resolutions where the authority
is limited to no more 5 per cent of the ordinary share capital of
the company in any one year (plus a further 5 per cent for an
acquisition or capital investment which is identified at the time
the resolution is put forward). When acting under the general
disapplication resolutions, the company should raise no more
than 7.5 per cent in any rolling period of three years (excluding
the capital investment addition), without consulting with its
shareholders. Authority should not be sought for more than 15
months or until the next AGM, whichever is the sooner.83 In
consequence, disapplication resolutions have become a common
feature of the AGM agenda.
Controversy has raged over the rules relating to specific, non-
routine (often large-scale) disapplication resolutions, where the
institutions need to be persuaded to vote in favour of the
disapplication resolution and so need to be presented with the
business case for proceeding on a non-rights basis. It used to be
thought in some corporate circles that institutions would
normally vote against specific disapplication resolutions, but
after criticism from a government review,84 the rules were re-
drafted to make it clear this was not the case. What is abundantly
clear from the Principles, however, is that, where the
institutional shareholders hold sway, the company will have no
chance of securing a general, large-scale disapplication of the
pre-emption requirement. The Principles envisage specific
resolutions being supported only in the context of a specific
project, where the need for non-pre-emptive finance can be
demonstrated and justified.85
Criticism and further market developments
24–15
The pre-emptive right, and the rights issue in particular, have
always been unpopular amongst management, just as it has been
popular amongst shareholders. Two main criticisms are
advanced. First, that it reduces the pool of investors to whom a
company may turn for additional equity finance and so it pushes
up the cost of equity finance. Secondly, a rights issue takes
longer to carry out than either an open offer or a placing (i.e.
raising finance from a small number of investors without making
a public offer) and so exposes the company to market risk during
the offer period. The arguments in principle for and against the
rights issue were examined in the Myners Review of 2005.86
Paul Myners came out in favour of rights issues. He was
particularly impressed by the corporate governance argument in
favour of pre-emption. This is that this doctrine makes it difficult
for a management, which has failed its existing shareholders, to
obtain finance from a new group of investors, letting them into
the company cheaply (and at the expense of the existing
investors) as part of an implicit bargain to back the existing
management against the complaints of the first group of
investors. By contrast, pre-emption makes management seeking
further equity finance sensitive to the views of the existing
investors from whom it must be raised.
In 2008, the first full year of the financial crisis, the issue
came to fore again as a number of banks had to raise large sums
of fresh capital. All succeeded in doing so, but often only after
great difficulties. The Rights Issue Review Group87 was
appointed to see if the principle of rights issues could be
maintained whilst mitigating the associated fund-raising
difficulties. The main issue was perceived to be one of timing. If
the length of the rights issue process could be reduced, the
issuer’s exposure to market risk (possibly even to market
manipulation)88 would also be reduced, an important
development in turbulent markets.89
24–16
An obvious first step, already implemented, was to reduce the
period for shareholders to decide whether to take up their rights
from 21 to 14 days, the minimum specified in the Second
Directive.90 However, the main timing problem was seen to flow
from the need to both secure shareholders’ consent and to
provide the (now) 14-day period for shareholders to decide
whether to take up their rights, and the inability to have those
two activities running concurrently. It may not be clear why
shareholder consent should be needed if what is proposed is a
rights issue. There are three possible answers. First, the directors
may not have in place a large enough authority to issue shares
(in any way) without shareholder consent, though the changes
recently made to the Investment Association Guidance91 make
that now less likely. Second, the directors may wish to make a
non-statutory pre-emption offer and so need shareholder consent
to disapply the statutory pre-emption provisions.92 Thirdly, the
Pre-emption Group’s Principles suggest, though not clearly, that
institutional shareholders expect shareholder approval for deeply
discounted rights issues (above 5 per cent), even though the
statute does not specify any cap on the level of discount nor does
the Listing Rules cap apply if a rights issue is proposed.
Assuming shareholder approval is required, the difficulty
about making the offer to the shareholders before that approval
is obtained is that trading in the rights (so-called “trading in nil
paid form”) necessarily begins as soon as the offer is made
(since the trading must be completed within 14 days). If,
however, shareholder approval for the issue is not ultimately
obtained, unscrambling the trading may prove very difficult.
Consequently, practice is to obtain approval before making the
offer. An open offer does not suffer from this difficulty and so
the offer can be launched and shareholder approval sought at the
same time, the offer being conditional upon shareholder
approval being obtained. However, the open offer gives no
protection against dilution to the shareholder who cannot take up
the offer. Consequently, market practice has developed recently
the “compensatory open offer”, under which any shares not take
up by the shareholder are sold by the company (or its
underwriters) into the market and any premium obtained over
the offer price is paid to the shareholder who did not take up the
offer.93 In effect, the burden of trading the rights to the new
shares passes from the shareholder under a rights issue to the
company under the compensatory open offer, but the economic
impact on the shareholder should be very similar.94 This may be
a burden the company is happy to accept in order to speed up the
fund raising process.95
THE TERMS OF ISSUE
24–17
As noted in the previous chapter,96 the rights attached to the
shares to be issued are likely to be set out in the company’s
articles. What will not be set out there is the price or other
consideration to be asked in exchange for the shares. Here the
directors have a free hand, subject to the rules on capital raising
discussed in Ch.11.97 As far as private companies are concerned,
these rules are not demanding, consisting mainly of the rules on
commissions and requiring shares not to be issued at a discount
to their nominal value (not to be confused with a discount to the
market price, against which the pre-emption right, as we have
just seen, aims to provide protection). With regard to public
companies, the rules, implementing the Second Directive, are
more constraining, though they have recently been relaxed
somewhat.
ALLOTMENT
24–18
The process by which the company finds someone who is
willing to become a shareholder of the company is not
something about which the law says very much if there is no
offer to the public of the company’s shares98—although, as we
shall see in the next chapter, this is in fact now a very heavily
regulated area, if there is a public offer. What the Act does
assume is that the process of becoming a shareholder is a two-
step one, involving first a contract of allotment and then
registration of the member. As Lord Templeman said in 1995:
“The Act of 1985 preserves the distinction in English law between an enforceable
contract for the issue of shares (which contract is constituted by an allotment) and
the issue of shares which is completed by registration. Allotment confers a right to
be registered. Registration confers [legal] title.”99
This is consistent with the 2006 Act which defines the point at
which shares are allotted as the time when a person acquires the
unconditional right to be included in the register of members, but
does not require actual entry in the register.100
Renounceable allotments
24–19
In the case of a private company the processes of agreement and
registration will be achieved with little formality and without the
issue of allotment letters. If someone wants to become a
shareholder and the company wants him to, he will be entered on
the register and issued with a share certificate without more ado.
However, the advantage of constituting the agreement to become
a member in a formal letter of allotment is that it facilitates the
process described above in relation to rights issues101 of
“renouncing” the entitlement to be registered as a member in
favour of someone else, though the technique is not confined to
rights issues. Printed on the back of the letter there will be forms
enabling, for a short specified period, the allottee to renounce the
right to be registered as a member and the person to whom they
are ultimately renounced to confirm that he or she accepts the
renunciation and agrees to be entered on the register. Normally
the original allottee will not insert the name of the person to
whom they are to be renounced and the effect is then to produce
something similar to a short-term share-warrant to bearer.102 It is
not a negotiable instrument but once the renunciation is signed
by the original allottee, the rights can be assigned by manual
delivery of the allotment letter without a formal transfer. Before
the stated period ends, however, it will be necessary for the
name of the ultimate holder to be inserted, a signature obtained,
and the allotment letter lodged with the company or its
registrars.
Failure of the offer
24–20
Implementing art.32 of the Second Directive, the Act lays down
a default rule for public companies that no allotment of shares
shall be made pursuant to an offer to subscribe103 for shares
(whether the offer is to the public or not) unless the shares on
offer are taken up in full.104 This rule is designed to prevent an
investor ending up holding shares in a company which is less
fully capitalised than was expected when the offer was accepted.
If a full take-up of the shares is not achieved within 40 days of
making the offer, the money105 received from the offerees
becomes repayable in full, though without interest,106 and must
actually be repaid within a further eight days. The sanction for
this latter requirement is that the directors then become jointly
and severally liable to repay the money, with interest.107 If the
company actually proceeds with an allotment in breach of the
Act then the allotment is voidable by the offeree within one
month of the allotment (even if the company is in course of
winding up),108 and any director who knowingly contravenes or
permits the contravention of the prohibition on allotment
becomes liable to compensate the allottee and the company for
any loss, damages, costs or expenses.109 Despite these fearsome
sanctions, the rule is not enormously important in practice, for
two reasons. First, if the offer in terms says that the allotment
will proceed, even if not fully subscribed, or will proceed if
conditions falling short of full subscription are met, the
prohibition on allotment does not apply.110 So, the rule is really
one which requires only that the investors be told what risk they
run in relation to the take-up of the offer. Secondly, in relation to
offers to the public, failure to achieve a full take-up of the offer
is a serious matter, not only for the investors, but also for the
issuer, so that companies will arrange for the offer to be
“underwritten” in some way (i.e. normally an investment bank
agrees to take up the shares which are not bought by the
public).111
Once the shares have been allotted, the company must make a
return of allotment to the Registrar of companies, as discussed in
the previous chapter.112
REGISTRATION
24–21
As Lord Templeman indicated, allotment does not make a
person a member of the company. Entry in the register of
members is also needed to give the allottee legal title to the
shares. Section 112(2) says explicitly that a person “who agrees
to become a member of the company and whose name is entered
on the register of members is a member of the company”.113 The
Act now requires registration “as soon as practicable” and in any
event within two months of the date of allotment.114 Even when
registered, the shareholder will find difficulty in selling the
shares, if they are to be held in certificated form, until a share
certificate is received from the company. If the shares are to be
held in uncertificated form,115 then by definition no share
certificate will be issued. Instead, the company, by computer
instruction, will inform the operator of the electronic transfer
system of the identity of those to whom the shares have been
allotted and of the number of shares issued to each person.116
The lapse of time between allotment and registration in the share
register by informing the operator of the electronic transfer
system of what the company has done should be very much
shorter than the gap between allotment and the issue of share
certificates, where the Act gives the company up to two months
to complete the process.117
Bearer shares
24–22
A major exception in principle, though much less so in practice,
to the requirement of entry on the register in order to become a
member of the company was created by share-warrants to bearer.
Section 779 provided that a company, if so authorised by its
articles, could issue with respect to any fully paid shares a
warrant stating that the bearer of the warrant is entitled to the
shares specified in it. If similarly authorised, it could provide, by
coupons attached to the warrant or otherwise, for the payment of
future dividends.118 Title to the shares specified then passes by
manual delivery of the warrant,119 which is a negotiable
instrument.120 On their issue, the company removed from its
register of members the name of the former registered holder and
merely states the fact and date of the issue of the warrant and the
number of shares to which it relates.121 The bearer of the warrant
from time to time was unquestionably a shareholder but to what
extent, if at all, he was a member of the company depended on a
provision to that effect in the articles.122 Hence shareholding and
membership are not necessarily coterminous if share warrants
are issued. However, again subject to the articles, the bearer of
the warrant was entitled, on surrendering it for cancellation, to
have his name and shareholding re-entered on the register.123 In
practice this exception was unimportant because bearer
securities have never been popular with British investors or
British companies and are rarely issued and hardly ever in
respect of shares, as opposed to bearer bonds (i.e. debt securities
which are sometimes issued to attract continental investors who
have a traditional liking for securities in bearer form). It is
fortunate that bearer shares were such a rarity for, if they became
common, it would play havoc with many provisions of the Act.
In the end, amendments made by the Small Business, Enterprise
and Employment Act 2015 prohibited companies from issuing
share warrants in the future and made provision for the
mandatory conversion of existing warrants back into shares,
precisely because they were thought likely to undermine that
Act’s enhanced provisions on disclosure of share ownership.124
CONCLUSION
24–23
Where a company makes a non-public offer of shares, a situation
which will necessarily include most share offers by private
companies, the rules discussed above are all that the company
will need to concern itself with. Where, however, a public offer
of shares is to be made, the extensive regulation considered in
the next chapter will come into play. Even then, the relevant
regulation is additional to the rules considered in this chapter
and, though it may supplement, does not replace them. In fact,
rules discussed in this chapter, for example those relating to pre-
emptive rights, can be very important in public offers, but the
point is that such rules are not confined to public offers but apply
to share issues of a non-public type as well. Protection of the
position of existing shareholders through pre-emption is as
important in a private as in a public company, indeed arguably
more so in the absence of a market upon which the shares of a
disgruntled shareholder can be disposed of.
1 Directive 77/91/EEC ([1997] O.J. L26/1), subsequently amended and re-stated as
Directive 2012/30/EU ([2012] O.J. L315/74). The references in this chapter are to the re-
stated Directive.
2 Even this term is not fully precise, since a company may make public offer of its
shares without securing their admission to a trading facility.
32006 Act s.755. The prohibition applies to both shares and debentures: s.755(5). Nor
may a private company secure admission of existing securities to the official list without
making a public offer: FSMA 2000 s.74 and the Financial Services and Markets Act
2000 (Official Listing of Securities) Regulations 2001 (SI 2001/2956) reg.3. On the
“official list” see the following chapter at para.25–9.
4 See para.25–12 for a discussion of direct and indirect share offerings.
5
2006 Act ss.755(1) and 760.
6 2006 Act s.757.
7 2006 Act s.758(2)—but not if it is “impracticable or undesirable” to do so.
8 s2006 Act s.758(3). The remedial order may be make whether or not the company is
ordered to be wound up.
9
s2006 Act s.759(1).
102006 Act s.759(3) and (5). Those involved could include advisers, such as investment
banks. Where the company is ordered to re-purchase, the court may reduce its capital.
11
2006 Act s.755(3)(b)(4). On the requirements of converting to a public company see
para.4–40.
12 2006 Act s.756(2).
13
2006 Act s.756(3)(a). If the securities do in fact end up in public hands within six
months of their initial allotment or before the company has received the whole of the
consideration for the shares, the company is presumed to have allotted them with a view
to their being offered to the public: s.755(3).
142006 Act s.756(3)(b)–(6). Such offers may be renounceable in favour of other
persons, provided such persons also fall within the “domestic” category.
15
Discussed at paras 25–18 et seq.
16
See para.25–19.
17Completing, paras 2.77–2.82; Final Report I, paras 4.57–4.58. Examples of
exemptions under the Directive which might be thought inappropriate for private
companies were offers to professional investors, as part of takeovers, and of large
denomination shares.
18 The rules discussed in this section, unlike those relating to public offers, do not apply
to debt securities which have no equity element.
19 See para.19–16.
20 Directive art.29. Even then, only the consent of shareholders with voting rights under
the company’s articles.
21
Developing, paras 7.28–7.33.
22 2006 Act s.550.
23 2006 Act s.549(3)–(4).
24
2006 Act s.549(6).
25 2006 Act s.549(1). This may help to explain in part why the “shareholder rights plan”
or “poison pill” against takeovers is uncommon in the UK, for the effectiveness of the
plan depends heavily upon the directors being able to issue warrants to subscribe for
shares without shareholder approval.
26 2006 Act s.549(3).
27When the section talks about rights to “convert any security into shares in the
company” it means newly created shares, not shares already in existence.
28 2006 Act s.551(2). The section does not in terms require details of the use to which
the funds will be put to be given to the shareholders. However, if the directors are also
seeking authority in relation to a specific allotment to remove pre-emption rights, they
are obliged to put forward a justification: see s.571(6) and fn.62, below. Moreover, the
general rules on resolutions at meetings of shareholders may require it. See para.15–47.
The resolution need only be an ordinary resolution, even if it amends the company’s
articles (s.551(8)), but the resolutions must be notified to the Registrar (s.551(9)).
Authorisation can be given in the articles, but this is unlikely in the case of “particular”
authorisation.
29
2006 Act s.551(2), (3), (4). Renewals of authority are to be given by resolution, even
if the original authority was contained in the articles: s.551(4)(a). As s.551(7) makes
clear, the time limit relates to the directors’ authorisation of the share offer, not to the
allotment of the shares (which might occur after the time limit had expired). A time limit
is required even for particular exercises of the power.
30
2006 Act s.551(3). In relation to allotments of rights to subscribe or to convert, what
has to be stated is the maximum number of shares that can be allotted pursuant to the
rights: s.551(6).
31
2006 Act s.551(2).
32
2006 Act s.551(4)(b). This will be a case of an ordinary resolution amending the
articles. See fn.28, above.
33 See now Investment Association, Share Capital Management Guidelines, 2014, 1.1
(available at https://www.ivis.co.uk/media/11164/Rebranded-Share-Capital-
Management-Guidelines-3-June-2015-.pdf [Accessed 26 January 2016].
34 This principle is also to be found in the Second Directive (art.33) but has again been
applied in the UK to private as well as public companies. Pre-emption in relation to new
shares issued by the company should be sharply distinguished from pre-emption on the
transfer of shares by a shareholder, common in private companies, but entirely a matter
for private contracting through the articles. See para.27–7.
35
See also para.16–26 on the collateral purposes doctrine which has a similar effect but
operates only when the directors’ predominant purpose is an improper one, and Ch.20 on
the unfair prejudice remedy.
36See the distinction drawn between the loss suffered by the company and that by the
shareholders when shares are issued for an inadequate consideration in Pilmer v Duke
Group Ltd [2001] 2 B.C.L.C. 773 Aus. HC.
37
In the case of small companies, the shareholder may be able to challenge the decision
to issue new shares under the unfair prejudice procedure. See Re A Company [1986]
B.C.L.C. 362; and Re Sam Weller Ltd [1990] Ch. 682.
38
For a worked example of this analysis see Bank of England, Guidance on Share
Issuing, 1999, Technical Annex, showing that the total value of the rights will always
match the loss of value on the holding, no matter the size of the discount or the
proportion of the existing shares to be issued on a discounted basis. At the time of the
trading of the rights the actual post-issue price is unknown but a “theoretical ex rights
price” can be easily calculated.
39 See para.25–14.
40
A third course of action is for the shareholder to sell part of the rights and to exercise
the other part, so as to maintain the value of his or her shareholding in the company (but
not the proportion of the shares held), rather than simply to receive compensation for
that drop in value by selling all the rights. This action is called, obscurely, “tail-
swallowing”. The “discount” referred to in this discussion is, of course, a discount to the
prevailing market price of the shares, not to their par value, which is not permitted (see
para.11–4, above).
41
It recognises, of course, that a rights issue is a permissible way of providing the pre-
emptive right. See the reference to renouncement of rights to allotment in s.561(2).
42
For further discussion see E. Ferran, “Legal Capital Rules and Modern Securities
Markets” in K.J. Hopt and E. Wymeersch (eds), Capital Markets and Company Law
(Oxford: OUP, 2003).
43
2006 Act s.560(1). There is no upper limit to this amount (and it would be
impracticable to set one) with the result that it is possible to fix a dividend limitation so
high that the holders would in fact be entitled to the whole or the lion’s share of profits
without affording existing shareholders pre-emptive rights.
44
2006 Act s.564. See para.11–20. Since issuance of a bonus share involves the
capitalisation of the company’s reserves, no payment by shareholders is involved and the
shares must be allotted pro-rata to those entitled to the reserve, were it distributed, or, in
the case of an undistributable reserve, whose contributions constituted the reserve (as in
the case of the share premium account).
45 2006 Act s.566. Even if those scheme members may be entitled to renounce or assign
their rights so that, if they do, the shares when allotted will not be “held in pursuance of
the scheme”. Employees’ share schemes would be unworkable if every time a further
allotment was to be made pursuant to them all equity shareholders had to be offered pre-
emptive rights. If, however, equity shares have been allotted under the scheme, the
employee holders should have the same rights to protect their proportion of equity as
any other shareholder.
46
2006 Act s.577. Indeed, it is difficult to see how the rules could be so applied.
47
2006 Act s.565.
48See above, para.11–16. But the chapter does not apply to private companies or to
share issues even by public companies in connection with takeover offers or mergers,
where there is in fact a considerable risk of financial dilution. Listed company
shareholders are better protected, for the rule restricting discounts to 10 per cent (see
para.24–13) applies also to a “vendor consideration placing”.
49 It is difficult to regard this scheme with great disapprobation, since, if Company B
had been prepared to take the shares of Company A in exchange for its assets, and then
immediately sold them, no question of pre-emption would have arisen. A legitimate
concern of the existing shareholders in such a case arises if the shares are placed with
their new holders at a discount to the market price. For listed companies, the Listing
Rules restrict the discount to 10 per cent, unless the shareholders have approved
something larger: LR 9.5.10.
50 2006 Act s.561. Treasury shares are excluded from the calculations required by this
section: s.561(4). The details of how communication is to be made with the shareholders
are set out in s.562.
51 2006 Act s.562(5). Nor can the offer be withdrawn, once made: s.562(4).
52 2006 Act ss.569(1), 570(1).
53 2006 Act s.571(1).
54 2006 Act s.567. A provision in the memorandum or articles which is inconsistent with
ss.561 or 562 has effect as an exclusion of that subsection: s.567(3).
552006 Act s.569. On shareholder authority to issue in private companies see para.24–4,
above.
56
2006 Act s.568. The problem does not arise if the other classes of share are not
ordinary but preference shares, because they will not benefit from a pre-emption right.
57
2006 Act s.561.
58
2006 Act ss.568(4),(5), on which see below.
59
See para.24–5, above, for the meaning of “general” authorisation.
60
2006 Act s.570.
61
2006 Act ss.571.
62
2006 Act ss.571(5)–(7). These provisions track art.33.4 of the Directive, but the
common law would produce a similar disclosure requirement.
63
2006 Act s.572.
64
A Report to the Chancellor of the Exchequer by the Rights Issue Review Group,
November 2008, 6.5.
65 See para.24–13.
66 LR 9.3.12. This is primarily designed to deal with the situation where a company has
shareholders resident in the USA. Under the Federal securities legislation it may have to
register with the SEC if it extends the offer to such shareholders. Hence the present
practice is to exclude such shareholders and to preclude those to whom the offer is made
from renouncing in favour of a US resident. This practice was upheld in Mutual Life
Insurance of N.Y. v Rank Organisation [1985] B.C.L.C. 11, but a fairer arrangement
would surely be for the rights of the American shareholders to be sold for their benefit?
67
On which see para.13–26, above.
68
2006 Act s.560(2)(b).
69 2006 Act s.573.
70 However, existing shareholders in listed companies are protected against dilution by
the imposition of a limit of 10 per cent to any discount applied on the sale of the treasury
shares: LR 9.5.10.
71
2006 Act s.562. Proceedings must be commenced within two years of the filing of the
relevant return of allotments or, where rights to subscribe or convert are granted, within
two years from the grant: s.563(3). As noted, the same applies to contraventions of the
substitute right in the company’s articles relating to classes of ordinary shares: s.568(4),
(5).
72 2006 Act ss.569(2), 570(2), 571(2), 573(3),(5).
73
Re Thundercrest Ltd [1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 117.
74 See para.27–19.
75 See para.15–25.
76 On listing see para.25–9.
77LR 9.5.10. This rule applies only to companies with a premium listing, on which see
para.25–6.
78
Since the requirement is that “the terms of the offer or placing at that discount have
been specifically approved by the issuer’s shareholders”, the shareholder approval
cannot be given in practice in advance of the decision to issue.
79
On which see para.21–17.
80
http://www.pre-emptiongroup.org.uk [Accessed 26 January 2016]. The first
guidelines were adopted in 1987. The Principles are supported by the National
Association of Pension Funds and the Investment Association.
81
Hence the reported opposition of the institutional investors to the removal of the pre-
emption requirement from the Second Directive: Financial Times, UK edn, 22 October
2007, p.18 and ibid. 23 October 2007, p.23. Of course, the removal of the right from the
Second Directive would not prevent the UK from maintaining the statutory default.
82
The latest version dates from 2015 and is available on website identified in fn.80. The
Principles are said to apply formally only to companies listed on the Premium Listing
segment of the Main Market of the London Stock Exchange, but standard listing
companies and those on the Alternative Investment Market are “encouraged” to apply
them.
83
Principles, Pts 2A and 2B.
84
DTI, Pre-Emption Rights: Final Report, February 2005 (URN 05/679). It was in this
re-drafting process that the “Guidelines” became “Principles”, perhaps to emphasis this
point.
85
Principles, Pt 3.
86
See fn.84.
87 Above, fn.64.
88 On which see para.30–39.
89
The discussion below focuses on speeding up the formal offer process.
90
2006 Act s.562(5). The change was made in 2009. Similar changes were made to LR
9.5.6 to cater for non-statutory rights issues and to the AIM Rules for Companies (notes
to rr.24 and 25).
91 Above para.24–5.
92 See para.24–11.
93
See above para.24–6 as to why the market price can be expected to be higher than
offer price. LR 9.5.4 already imposed this rule in favour of offerees in a rights issue who
did not take up the offer, so that those unfamiliar with the rights issue procedure were
not disadvantaged.
94
However, a shareholder cannot engage in tail swallowing (above fn.40) under the
compensatory open offer.
95 Because of these market developments the FSA recommended against some of the
more radical suggestions from the RIRG which would allow offer and approval periods
to run simultaneously. See FSA, Report to HM Treasury on the implementation of the
recommendations of the Rights Issue Review Group, April 2010.
96
See above, para.23–6.
97 See above, paras 11–13 et seq.
98
The general common law rules on fraud, misrepresentation and negligence will
provide some protection to investors: see paras 25–31 et seq., below.
99
National Westminster Bank Plc v IRC [1995] 1 A.C. 111 at 126 HL. From this, Lord
Templeman reasoned that shares were not “issued” (the Companies Act does not define
the term) for the purposes of a taxing statute until the applicants for the shares were
registered as members of the company.
100
2006 Act s.558.
101
See above, para.24–7. Of course, a private company may not want to grant this
facility, which might be inconsistent with its articles (see para.27–7, below). The
statutory scheme of pre-emption rights does not require renouncing to be made
available.
102
See below, para.24–22.
103
The section thus does not apply to offers for sale of shares (see para.25–12) and does
not need to because the issue has been in effect underwritten.
104 2006 Act s.578(1). In fact, however, the rule has a much longer pedigree: CA 1948
s.47.
105
The rule applies, mutatis mutandis, where the consideration for the offer is wholly or
partly otherwise than in cash: s.578(4),(5).
106 2006 Act s.578(2).
107
2006 Act s.578(3). A director can escape liability if it can be shown that the failure
was not due to misconduct or negligence on the director’s part. If the company promises
to keep the monies advanced by a subscriber in a separate bank account and does so, it
seems that the monies will be held on trust by the company in favour of the investors: Re
Nan wa Gold Mines Ltd [1955] 1 W.L.R. 1080.
108
2006 Act s.579(1),(2). This means the assets contributed by the allottee are taken out
of the insolvent company’s estate, but only if the allotee acts within the one-month
period.
109 2006 Act s.579(3), subject to a two-year limitation period: s.579(4).
110
2006 Act s.578(1)(b)—or if the offer is stated to be subject only to certain conditions
(such as a 75 per cent acceptance) and those conditions are met.
111 See para.25–11.
112 At para.23–6.
113
On which, see Re Nuneaton Football Club [1989] B.C.L.C. 454 CA, holding that
“agreement” requires only assent to become a member. The subscribers to the
memorandum of association (above, para.4–5) are the first members of the company and
should be entered on its register of members, but in their case it appears that they
become members, whether this is done or not: Evans’ Case (1867) L.R. 2 Ch. App. 247;
Baytrust Holdings Ltd v IRC [1971] 1 W.L.R. 1333 at 1355–1356.
1142006 Act s.554. Failure to register is a criminal offence on the part of the company
and every officer in default.
115 See Ch.27.
116 Uncertificated Securities Regulations 2001 (SI 2001/3755) reg.34.
117
2006 Act s.769.
118
2006 Act s.779(3). Share-warrants to bearer must be distinguished from what is
perhaps the more common type of warrant, which gives the holder the right to subscribe
for shares in the company at a specific price on a particular date or within a particular
period. Such warrants are a form of long-term call option over the company’s shares.
They may be traded, but their transfer simply gives the transferee the option and does
not make him or her a member until the option is exercised.
119
2006 Act s.779(2).
120
Webb, Hale & Co v Alexandria Water Co (1905) 21 T.L.R. 572.
121
2006 Act s.122(1).
122
2006 Act s.122(3).
123 2006 Act s.122(4)—now repealed.
124
2006 Act s.779(4), as added; 2015 Act s.84 and Sch.4. The prohibition operated from
May 2015; the period for mandatory reconversion ended a year later.
CHAPTER 25
PUBLIC OFFERS OF SHARES
Introduction 25–1
Public offers and introductions to public markets 25–2
Regulatory goals 25–3
Listing 25–5
Types of public market 25–7
The regulatory structure 25–10
Types of public offer 25–11
Admission to Listing and to Trading on a Public Market 25–15
Eligibility criteria for the official list 25–15
Exchange admission standards 25–16
The Prospectus 25–17
The public offer trigger 25–18
Exemptions from the prospectus requirement on a
public offer 25–19
The admission to trading trigger 25–20
The form and content of prospectuses 25–22
Verifying the prospectuses 25–26
Publication of prospectuses and other material 25–30
Sanctions 25–31
Compensation under the Act 25–32
Civil remedies available elsewhere 25–36
Criminal and regulatory sanctions 25–41
Cross-Border Offers and Admissions 25–44
De-listing 25–45
INTRODUCTION
25–1
This chapter is concerned with a subject that takes us into the
area of securities regulation or capital markets law. Nevertheless,
it is not a subject which books on company law can ignore; how
public companies go about raising their capital from the
investing public and the legal regulations that have to be
complied with when they do are central to the operations of large
companies. An elaborate discussion of this specialised branch of
legal practice is inappropriate in a book of this sort but an outline
is essential. The rules considered in this chapter generally apply
to “securities”, i.e. both to shares and debt instruments (for
example, bonds). The focus of this chapter will be on share
issues but we will notice the major divergences when debt
securities are issued, as and when is relevant. Debt securities are
the lesser subject in this chapter, because they are less often
offered to the public even by companies which issue shares to
the public and because bonds are less frequently traded on public
markets (as opposed to “over the counter”). Nevertheless, to an
extent, this chapter crosses the divide between Pts 6 and 7 of the
book.
Public offers and introductions to public markets
25–2
There are two distinct, though usually combined, operations
which may take place when a large company seeks to raise
finance from the investing public. In the first place, it needs to
make its case to those people who may be interested in investing
in it by purchasing its securities. As we shall see below, the
company may choose among a number of different ways of
putting itself before investors. The most heavily regulated of
these methods is the public offer of securities, simply because
the company addresses its publicity to a wide range of persons
who may include the ill-informed and the gullible as well as the
experienced and well-informed. When a company makes a
public offer of its shares for the first time, that is usually termed
an “initial public offering” (“IPO”), and this is often a major
event in the life of the company. But it may well make further
public offerings at a later stage (“secondary” offers). The
document (the “prospectus”) through which public offers are
made is regulated heavily by the law. From this perspective, the
law relating to prospectuses can be viewed as a branch of
consumer protection legislation, but concerning a product which
is very difficult to evaluate. The value of shares depends heavily
upon the future performance of the company and cannot be
ascertained, as with a motor car, for example, by visual
inspection and a test drive.
It will normally be the case that a company seeking to raise
substantial funds from investors will also secure that the
securities to be issued will be admitted to trading on a public
securities market, such as one of the markets operated by the
London Stock Exchange. The reason the company will normally
take this extra step is that the willingness of investors to buy its
securities will be increased if there is a liquid market upon which
those securities can be traded after they have been issued. As we
have seen, a shareholder is normally “locked into” the company
after the shares have been purchased, in the sense that the
investor, short of winding up, cannot require the company to buy
back the shares, even at the later prevailing market price, except
in the case of some types of redeemable share. Equally, bonds
are not normally redeemable at the request of the investor until
after some specified period has elapsed and perhaps not before
they reach their maturity date. Therefore, a person who wishes to
withdraw from an investment will normally be constrained to
find another investor willing to purchase the securities. A liquid
securities market will facilitate this operation, to the benefit of
both investors and the company, which is likely to be able to sell
its securities at a higher price if they have access to the liquidity
afforded by a public market.
However, the mere admission of securities to trading on an
public market also involves putting those securities before the
investing public, even if there is no concomitant public offer,
since it is now open to the public to acquire the company’s
securities, this time not directly from the company but from
those who already hold them. Hence, there is a strong argument
for having the same information disclosure upon admission of
securities to a public market as when the company offers its
securities directly to the public. The argument is even stronger if,
as is usual, both events occur at the same time. However, there is
no legal requirement that this should be so. A company may
offer its securities to the public without securing their admission
to public market (for example, where it does not expect or want
the securities to be traded to any significant degree and so is
content to rely on sellers seeking out potential purchasers
privately). Or the driving force1 behind the admission of the
securities to the market may be an existing large shareholder (for
example, the Government in a de-nationalisation issue) which
wishes to liquidate or reduce its holding, but the company does
not intend at that time to raise additional finance.
Our main concern in this chapter is with the financing of the
company and the public offer of securities as a form of corporate
finance. Consequently, the core transaction which we examine is
one in which the company both makes a public offer of its shares
and, at the same time, secures the admission of the shares to
trading on a public market.
Regulatory goals
25–3
We have referred above to the law relating to public offers as
consumer law and that is a very strong strand in the thinking of
those responsible for the rules in this area. However, it would be
wrong to see the regulation as nothing but a form of consumer
protection. In fact, scholarship today stresses the function of
regulation in this area as a way of promoting “allocative
efficiency”, that is, of promoting investment on the basis of an
accurate understanding of the risk and reward profile of
particular projects which the issuance of the shares will finance.
This objective furthers the interests not only of investors but of
companies and of the economy generally, for effective
regulation promotes the allocation of scarce investment
resources to the projects with the highest returns. But what sort
of regulation will best facilitate the accurate assessment of
different projects?
It is conventional in this branch of law to make a distinction
between “merit” regulation and disclosure of information. Under
the former approach, a regulator permits an offer to be made to
the public only if the securities on offer or the company issuing
them (“the issuer”) pass certain quality tests, whereas the latter
simply puts information in the hands of investors and leaves it
up to them to make up their own minds about investing.
Although the early regulation of public offers (at state level in
the US) adopted the merit regulation approach,2 the disclosure
approach has been the predominant one in all jurisdictions since
its adoption by federal US law in the great reforms of 1933 and
1934.3 However, disclosure has never driven out all elements of
merit regulation. Although what is required varies from market
to market, disclosure is never all that is required. As a Canadian
committee once remarked, with heavy irony, “it would be
improbable that a securities commission in a disclosure regime
would approve a prospectus that said, truthfully, that the
promoters of the company intended to abscond with the proceeds
of the public offering, or that the company’s business enterprise
had no hope of success”.4 Thus, elements of merit regulation,
referred to in the UK as “eligibility requirements”, survive in
even the most disclosure-oriented regime.
The triumph of disclosure as the predominant regulatory
philosophy in this area is probably a reflection of the decision
the investor has to make. Prospective subscribers to the ordinary
shares to be issued by a company normally obtain no legal
entitlement to a return on their investment and so they are
essentially making a judgment about the company’s business
prospects in the future and the appropriate price to pay in the
light of those prospects. If the company makes good profits, the
ordinary shareholders will benefit; if it makes heavy losses,
those will fall first on the same people. The prospective
purchaser of shares has to take a view about how the industry in
which the company is active will evolve and about the qualities
of the company’s management.5 Nobody can be sure about the
future. Using merit regulation to exclude certain public offers
risks excluding a company whose track record is not good but
which has a perfectly decent story to tell about its future.
Further, heavy merit regulation may carry the implication that
those offers that are permitted to proceed benefit from some sort
of public guarantee of the company’s future success, something
the public authorities are unlikely to wish to provide. Merit
regulation thus tends to play a limited role. Even disclosure of
information does not make the investor’s task easy, because the
one piece of hard information the investor requires—what will
be the issuer’s financial results in the future?—is by definition
not available. However, information about the company’s
present and recent activities, its proposals for the future and the
terms of the securities on offer can help to guide the investment
decision, even if it cannot take all risk out of the process. Indeed,
if all risk could be eliminated, there would be no need for equity
finance in the first place.
25–4
A further question about the disclosure regime, which has been
hotly debated, is whether production of the requisite level of
information requires mandatory disclosure rules. It can be
argued that, a prospectus being a selling document, those
companies with good stories to tell would make full disclosure
of information and use private “bonding” mechanisms (such as
certification by independent third parties) to convince investors
of the truth of what they say. Companies with less good stories
would follow suit, for fear that investors would deduce from
inadequate disclosure that the prospects for the company were
dire. Only companies with truly dire prospects would make
inadequate disclosure and investors would draw the correct
conclusions from such inadequate prospectuses. Whether this
theory works in practice seems never to have been tested
satisfactorily, but even if self-interest would generate extensive
disclosure, mandatory disclosure rules have certain advantages
over leaving it to the issuers to decide for themselves the extent
of the disclosure. First, the state sanctions available for breaches
of the mandatory rules (criminal, civil and regulatory sanctions)
may be more credible to investors than the private bonding
mechanisms companies themselves could produce. Secondly,
mandatory rules may produce more uniformity in disclosure than
disclosure decisions taken by issuers on an individual basis (thus
helping investors to compare different public offerings). Thirdly,
mandatory rules may overcome forces acting against full
disclosure even when, from one point of view, disclosure is in
the company’s interest. An example is the disclosure of
information which, whilst it would make the company attractive
to investors, would also help the company’s competitors.6
In any event, the detail required by the disclosure rules
applicable on public offerings is now staggering. Since, as we
have noted, the information available is only indirectly relevant
to the future-oriented decision the investor has to make, there
comes a point where the marginal gain from more information
may outweigh the costs of providing it. This issue has been
debated especially in relation to small and medium-sized entities
(“SMEs”) since the financial crisis. SMEs traditionally relied on
bank funding, which became difficult to obtain post the crisis.
Many advocated greater use by SMEs of the financial markets to
raise capital. However, the largely fixed costs of capital raising
from the public markets absorb a relatively high proportion of
the funds raised in the case of small offerings. So, the question
of a relaxed disclosure regime for SMEs moved centre stage, as
we discuss below.
Turning to the admission of securities to trading on public
markets, a regulatory goal has been to ensure that those who
control the operation of public markets exercise their admission
and expulsion powers fairly. This might be thought necessary to
protect the interests of both issuers which wish to make public
offerings and investors who have bought the securities on the
basis that they would continue to be publicly traded. In practice,
this has turned out to be a less important regulatory objective,
since competition among public markets for offerings has itself
constrained any impulse to act unfairly.
Listing
25–5
The meanings of a public offer and admission to trading on an
exchange are easy enough to grasp. Somewhat less obvious is
the concept of “listing”. This is partly because of the varying
ways in which the term is used. Sometimes it is used to refer to
any security which is traded on a public market (i.e. it is on the
“list” of securities traded on that market), in which case it adds
nothing to what we have already said. In this book, however, we
use the term in a narrower sense: a listed security is one which
has been admitted to the “official list”. The first point to note is
that inclusion in the official list is not a pre-requisite for
admission to trading on all public markets. For example, it is
possible to make a public offer of “unlisted” securities and to
secure the admission of those securities to trading on the
Alternative Investment Market (“AIM”) of the London Stock
Exchange (“LSE”). On the other hand, the Main Market of the
LSE is a market for listed securities only. So, the question arises
as to why a company should wish its securities to be included in
the official list. The answer to that is that admission to the
official list constitutes a quality mark, which companies may be
anxious to have in order to encourage investors to acquire their
securities.7 For this reason, admission to the official list is an
important element in the public offer and admission to trading
process.
Inherent in the concept of an official list is the idea that
somebody controls admission to it in order to ensure that the
standards for admission are met. That task used to be discharged
by the LSE itself, but, with the demutualisation of the LSE, the
Exchange no longer wished to carry out this regulatory function,
which was transferred,8 in consequence, to what is now the
Financial Conduct Authority (“FCA”),9 established under the
Financial Services and Markets Act 2000,10 as amended. Section
74 of FSMA requires the FCA to maintain the “official list” and
to include securities in it only in accordance with the provisions
of the Act and it gives the FCA the power to make listing rules
(“LR”) for the purpose of governing admission to the official list
and the subsequent conduct of listed companies.11 However, as is
generally true in the area of public offers of securities, much of
the controlling legislation is now made at EU level. Under art.5
of the Consolidated Admissions Requirements Directive12 (or
“CARD”) Member States are required to “ensure [that] securities
may not be admitted to official listing” on a stock exchange
operating in their territory “unless the conditions laid down by
this Directive are satisfied” and it is from this Directive that
certain “merit” or “eligibility” requirements flow, as we shall see
below. Article 105 requires that Member States appoint a
“competent authority” for the purposes of the Directive, and in
the UK that authority is the FCA, acting as the UK Listing
Authority (“UKLA”).
Premium and standard listing
25–6
However, it would be wrong to think that the FCA’s Listing
Rules exist only for the purpose of implementing the CARD
Directive in the UK. The Listing Rules are of some antiquity and
deal with many matters falling outside the scope of CARD or
any other EU Directive or add to the requirements of those
Directives.13 For example, the LR contain corporate governance
rules and rules on related-party transactions which, as we have
seen, add significantly to the Companies Act requirements.14
These additional requirements substantially contribute to the
“quality mark” impact of admission to the official list. On the
other hand, the additional requirements add to the regulatory
burdens on a company and may discourage it from listing in
London—as opposed to New York or Hong Kong.
Consequently, in 2010 the FCA’s predecessor introduced two
classes of listing. Companies may choose between “standard”
and “premium” listing for equity shares, standard listing
requiring compliance only with the minimum EU standards and
not with the additional domestic rules.15 Those additional rules
concern predominantly corporate governance requirements to be
observed after listing, but to a lesser extent they relate to the
process of listing itself. Companies may choose a premium share
listing for reputational reasons or under investor pressure.
Types of public market
25–7
Most people, if asked, would probably say that there is one stock
market in the UK and that is the LSE. However, this is not the
case. The LSE itself runs two separate markets for shares,
namely the “Main Market” and the “Alternative Investment
Market” (“AIM”)16 for well-established and less well-established
companies respectively; and two separate markets for bonds (the
Gilt-edged and Fixed-Interest Market (“GEFIM”) and the
Professional Securities Market (“PSM”)).17 However, the LSE
has no monopoly on the operation of public markets in
securities, even in the UK, and there exist a number of smaller
share markets, of which the best known are probably those
operated by ICAP Securities & Derivatives Exchange (“ISDX”),
which operates partly in competition with those run by the LSE
and partly to provide a market for companies needing to raise
smaller sums of money than is usual on AIM. However, there is
no legal reason why a British registered company should not
have its securities traded on a public market in another country.
A number of large British companies have primary listings in
London and secondary listings elsewhere, usually in continental
Europe or the US, and some non-British companies equally have
secondary listings in London. More interestingly, a small
number of British companies have their primary listings outside
the UK and a somewhat larger number of foreign companies
have their primary listings in London. Indeed, there has been a
certain international competition in recent years among the
exchanges to secure such listings, notably from Chinese and
Russian companies. Bonds issued by UK-incorporated
companies are often listed in Luxembourg.
Regulated markets and multi-lateral trading facilities
25–8
Carrying on the business of operating a stock market is, not
surprisingly, one of the activities regulated under the FSMA.
Those who operate the exchange must either be persons
authorised to carry on financial business in the UK or the
investment exchange must be a “recognised” investment
exchange (“RIE”).18 Applications for recognition can be made
under Pt XVIII of FSMA to the FCA, which is the primary
regulator in the area covered by this chapter. The requirements19
which have to be met relate to both the initial setting up of the
exchange and its continued operation. Thus, any public market
in securities operating in the UK will be subject to the regulation
of the FCA.
The purpose of the above regulation of investment exchanges
is to ensure the security of their operation. Thus, the recognition
requirements deal with matters such as the suitability of the
persons running the exchange and the level of financial
resources available to them. As with the minimum requirements
for listing, the underlying rules for exchange regulation are set
out in EU law, in this case the Directive on Markets in Financial
Instruments (“MIFID”).20 This Directive distinguishes a
regulatory point of view between “regulated” markets and
“multilateral trading facilities” (“MTF”). The Community
requirements for a regulated market are now set out in Title III
of MIFID. Article 44 states that “Member States shall reserve
authorisation as a regulated market to those systems which
comply with the provisions of this Title”. The Title then sets out
a number of requirements for acquiring the status of a regulated
market, many of which cover the same ground as is to be found
in the domestic rules governing the award of recognised
investment exchange status.
It might therefore be thought that all RIEs would seek to have
all the markets they run characterised as regulated markets.21
However, there is no obligation on an RIE to apply for regulated
status for all or any of its markets and not having regulated status
does not prevent that market from continuing to operate in the
UK, provided it continues to meet the domestic law
requirements. In the language of MIFID a market which is not a
regulated market is a MTF.22 On the other hand, a market which
does not obtain regulated status under MIFID loses the benefits
and the burdens placed by EU law on regulated markets, those
benefits and burdens being found across the EU law governing
securities. For RIEs, therefore, the question is whether the
benefits EU law attaches to a regulated market outweigh the
burdens. The LSE decided not to seek regulated status for
AIM,23 but the Main Market of the LSE is a regulated market.
For bonds, GEFIM is a regulated market and PSM is not.24
Listing and regulated markets
25–9
Although official listing is a concept which refers to the quality
of the securities and the issuer, whilst regulated markets are
markets of a particular quality, there is a close link between
them, at least in the case of shares. The Listing Rules provide
that “equity shares must be admitted to trading on a regulated
market for listed securities operated by a RIE”.25 Thus, the
listing process is not complete unless the shares have been
admitted to trading on a regulated market. On the other side, it is
only companies whose shares are in the official list which will
be admitted by the LSE to its Main Market.26 Thus, listed shares
must be traded on a regulated market and the Main Market of the
LSE will admit only listed securities. The FCA (or the
competent authority in some other EEA State in the case of
companies incorporated there) controls inclusion in the official
list and the LSE controls admission of the securities to trading
on the Main Market.27 The company has to satisfy both sets of
requirements in order to give its securities the status of being on
the official list and its shareholders the facility to trade in those
securities.
By contrast, listed debt securities must be admitted to trading
on a market for listed securities operated by a RIE, but that
market need not be a regulated market. On the LSE, GEFIM is a
regulated market and the PSM is exchange-regulated, but
nevertheless trades listed debt securities.
The regulatory structure
25–10
The document containing the information which must be put
before potential investors in a public offering is termed a
prospectus. Domestic statutory law regulating prospectuses has a
long history: the Directors’ Liability Act 1890,28 imposing
liability for negligent misstatements in prospectuses, was an
advanced piece of legislation for its time and significantly
influenced the US Securities Act 1933. However, over the past
30 years EU law has gradually occupied the legislative space in
relation to public offers, admission of securities to public
markets and listing, as part of a broader strategy to create a
single European financial market29—though remedies for
breaches of the rules still remain substantially in the hands of the
Member States. The result of EU occupation of the field,
together with the additional rules adopted at national level, has
been a multi-layered regulatory structure, where six distinct
layers can be identified: primary community law; secondary
community law; primary domestic legislation; secondary
domestic legislation; FCA rules; and rules generated by stock
exchanges.
The modern EU legislative instruments aimed at regulating
this area were proposed in the Financial Services Action Plan
(“FSAP”),30 adopted in 1999 for the period up to 2005 and
substantially achieved in that period. We shall look at some of
the FSAP instruments in this and the following chapter. As far as
disclosure of information in prospectuses is concerned the
central piece of EU law is currently Directive 2003/71/EC on
prospectuses (the “Prospectus Directive” or “PD”) as amended
in 2010,31 whilst admission to listing is regulated by CARD.32
As far as the PD is concerned, it has two features which need
to be noted. First, it is what is inelegantly referred to as a
“maximum harmonisation” Directive. This means that it sets out
not only standards below which the Member States may not fall
but also standards above which they may not rise. Since it is also
a very detailed Directive, especially when taken with the
subordinate EU legislation—see below—the Member States
have rather little discretion over its implementation in domestic
law and it functions more like a Regulation than a Directive.33
The reason for this approach was the EU’s desire to produce a
prospectus which, without changes other than translation, could
be used simultaneously in more than one Member State in a
cross-border offer. We shall look at this “EU passport” concept
in more detail below.34
The second notable feature of the PD results from an
adaptation of the EU legislative process introduced for FSAP
instruments and known as the “Lamfalussy process”, after the
name of the chairman of the committee which put forward this
proposal. An important part of this process is that the European
Commission obtained the power to make what we would call
subordinate legislation (through Commission Directives or
Regulations), without going through the full EU legislative
process but after consulting the Member States,35 where the
parent Directive provides for such “second-tier” legislation. In
fact, in the case of disclosure of information in public offers the
detailed information required is to be found in Commission
Regulation (EC) No.809/2004,36 as amended, a document of
some 100 pages and being, as a Regulation, directly applicable37
in the Member States and so not requiring transposition by them.
The purpose of this shift of legislative power to the Commission
was said to be to enable the details of the FSAP legislation to be
adapted more quickly to changing market practices than would
be the case if the full EU legislative process had to be used.
Law-making by the Commission thus constitutes the second
layer of rules in this area, after the adoption of the parent legal
instrument by the EU legislature.
However, the PD, the parent EU instrument in our area, and
Commission instruments taking the form of a Directive do
require transposition into national law. This gives rise to the
third level of law-making, i.e. by the British legislature (which
itself may take the form of primary or secondary legislation).
The most obvious expression of the domestic law-making
process is FSMA 2000, as subsequently amended, especially its
Pt VI. FSMA 2000 contains three broad types of rules: those
simply transposing the EU law, those both transposing and
adding to the EU requirements (where EU law permits this) and
those dealing with matters not subject to EU regulation.
However, from the outset of domestic financial services
regulation, the policy of embodying all the relevant rules in a
statute or even in statutory instruments was rejected in favour of
conferring broad rule-making and enforcement powers on a
regulator, now the FCA. This is a statutory body38 but funded by
market participants and designed to be more attuned to the needs
of the markets than would be a governmental department. It has
a very wide remit in the financial services area but for the
purposes of this chapter we concentrate on its role in public
offerings. Rules made by the FCA or its predecessor thus
constitute the fifth level of rule-making. For the purposes of this
chapter particularly important are its Prospectus Rules (“PR”),
though on some matters its Listing Rules (“LR”) are relevant as
well.
The sixth layer of regulation is that done by the exchanges
themselves, as a matter of private contract with the issuers which
seek to have their securities traded on a securities market.
It is likely that the balance within the above structure will
change in the future. In November 2015 the European
Commission proposed to replace the PD with a Prospectus
Regulation, as well as making some changes to the substantive
rules, which we note as appropriate below.39 This proposal was
part of a more general scheme to create a “capital markets
union” within the EU. To the extent that this proposal is
successful, EU rules would become relatively more important
and domestic rules relatively less so, since a Regulation does not
need transposition into domestic law.
Types of public offer
25–11
The EU and domestic rules discussed in this chapter are
concerned with public offers of transferable securities. The
whole of this body of regulation can be avoided by offering non-
transferable securities to the public.40 However, the illiquidity
embodied in non-transferable securities is likely to make them
unattractive to investors. Assuming an issue of transferable
securities, the company’s choices appear to be as follows. On an
initial public offering of shares, a company’s choice of method
will be severely restricted. If the issue is large it will have to
proceed by way of an offer for sale or subscription coupled with
admission to listing (or admission to AIM), whilst smaller
amounts may be raised via a placing plus an introduction to a
public market. (A placing is an offer to a selected group of
investors and so is not a general offer.) In the case of bonds,
even large amounts are normally raised by means of a placing,
because bonds are traditionally bought by institutional, not retail,
investors. In the case of shares, a third way of proceeding may
be available. Where the company’s shares have somehow
become sufficiently widely held (which is unlikely without a
public offer but conceivable) it may be possible to raise the new
money needed by a rights or open offer to its existing
shareholders, but this course of action is normally available only
on subsequent offers, not on an IPO. We shall look briefly at
each type of offer.
Offers for sale or subscription
25–12
A full-blown public offer will prove to be an expensive and
time-consuming operation. The company’s finance director (and
probably other executives) and representatives of the advising
investment bank and their respective solicitors will for weeks or
months devote most of their time to working as a planning team.
At a later stage the services of a specialist share registrar will
generally be needed to handle applications and the preparation
and dispatch of allotment letters. The offer will have to be made
through a lengthy prospectus which will have to be published.
To ensure that the issue is fully subscribed, arrangements will
have to be made for it to be underwritten. Today this is normally
achieved by the sponsoring investment bank agreeing to
subscribe for the whole issue and for it, rather than the company,
to make the offer. Thus, large public offers are normally in the
form of offers for sale not offers for subscription, the investment
bank having already subscribed for all the shares on offer.41 In
major offerings, such as the privatisation issues,42 a syndicate of
investment banks may be employed. The banks will endeavour
to persuade other financial institutions to sub-underwrite.
Ultimately the cost of all this, including the commissions
payable to underwriters and sub-underwriters,43 will have to be
borne by the company.
The most ticklish decision that will have to be made is the
price at which the securities should be issued and, for obvious
reasons, this is normally left to the last possible moment. If it
proves to have been set too low, so that the issue is heavily over-
subscribed, the company will be unhappy, while, if it is set too
high so that much of the issue is left with the underwriters, it is
they who will be unhappy since their commission rates will have
assumed that they will end up with a handsome profit and not be
left with securities that, initially, they cannot sell except at a loss.
Nor, probably, will the company be best pleased since it is
generally believed that an under-subscribed issue will reduce the
company’s prospects of raising further capital in the future. The
nightmare of all concerned is that there will be an unforeseen
stock market collapse between the date of publication of the
prospectus and the opening of the subscription list.44 The sweet
dream is that the issue will be modestly over-subscribed and that
trading will open at a small premium.
If the issue is over-subscribed it will obviously be impossible
for all applications to be accepted45 in full. The issuer decides
how to deal with this situation and the prospectus will need to
say how it intends to do so. Normally this will be by accepting in
full offers for small numbers of shares and scaling down large
applications, balloting sometimes being resorted to. The
company will probably wish to achieve a balance between
private and institutional investors. To succeed in that aim
multiple applications by the same person will probably be
expressly prohibited.46 An abuse which also needs to be guarded
against is that “stags” will apply but seek to withdraw and stop
their cheques if it seems likely that dealings will not open at a
worthwhile premium to the offer price. However, offer
documents will require applications to be accompanied by
cheques for the full amount of the securities applied for, the
cheques being cleared immediately on receipt and any refund
sent later. This means that an applicant may not only fail to get
all or any of the shares he hoped for but may, for a period, lose
the interest that he was earning on his money.47
The offer price is normally stated as a fixed and pre-
determined amount per share. It can however, be determined
under a formula stated in the offer, though this is uncommon
except in offers addressed to professional investors.
Alternatively applicants can be invited to tender on the basis that
the shares will be allocated to the highest bidders. This,
however, is rarely used in relation to issues of company
securities.
Placings
25–13
Obviously, the expense of an offer for sale plus introduction to
listing is prohibitive unless a very large sum of money is to be
raised. For lesser amounts the placing may be more attractive
(and may be used for large amounts in the case of bonds). Under
this method the investment bank or other adviser to the issuer
obtains firm commitments, mainly from its institutional investor
clients (instead of advertising an offer to the general public),
coupling this with an introduction to trading. The absence of the
need for newspaper advertisements, “road-shows” and the like
makes this a much less expensive procedure. On the other hand,
it prevents the general public from acquiring shares at the issue
price. Another way of proceeding is the “intermediaries offer”,
whereby financial intermediaries take up the offer for the
purpose of allocating the securities to their own clients. This way
of proceeding should be only marginally more expensive than a
straightforward placing, but has the advantage that it is more
likely to result in a wide spread of shareholders and a more
active and competitive subsequent market. Although these are
not “public” offers as far as the financial community is
concerned, unless carefully controlled they may end up being
public offers under the prospectus rules (as we see below).
Rights offers
25–14
Once a company has made an initial public offering of shares it
will have additional methods whereby it can raise further capital
and, even if it proceeds by an offer for sale, this will be less
expensive if the securities issued are of the same class as those
already admitted to listing or to the AIM. More often, however,
it will make what is called a “rights issue” and, if it is an offering
of equity shares for cash, it will generally have to do this, or
make an open offer, unless the company in general meeting
otherwise agrees. This is because of the pre-emptive provisions
discussed in the previous chapter.48 In one sense a rights issue is
considerably less expensive than an offer for sale: circulating the
shareholders is cheap in comparison with publishing a lengthy
prospectus in national newspapers and mounting a sales pitch to
attract the public. But in another sense it may be dearer: if the
issue price is deeply discounted the company will have to issue
far more shares (on which it will be expected to pay dividends)
in order to raise the same amount of money as on an offer. In
any event, as we shall see, a rights issue will normally be a
public offer for the purposes of the prospectus rules.
Other methods of issue, which can be used in appropriate
circumstances, include exchanges or conversions of one class of
securities into another, issues resulting from the exercise of
options or warrants, and issues under employee share-ownership
schemes—though these will not necessarily raise new money for
the company. Nor, of course, will capitalisation issues, dealt
with in Ch.13, above. We do not discuss them further in this
chapter.
ADMISSION TO LISTING AND TO TRADING ON A PUBLIC MARKET
Eligibility criteria for the official list
25–15
We have already noted that admission to trading on a public
market is a normally a concomitant feature of a public offer.
Although it might seem logical to look at the rules on disclosure
of information in relation to offers before looking at the rules
governing admission to trading, there are good reasons for the
opposite approach. First, the admission rules are generally less
elaborate. Secondly, the admission rules contain merit
requirements, i.e. rules permitting securities resulting from only
certain types of public offer to be publicly traded. The admission
requirements therefore feed back into decisions about the types
of public offers than can considered and the public markets
available for the resulting securities to be traded.
The principal source of admissibility requirements are the
Listing Rules made by the FCA, partly transposing into domestic
law the EU rules from CARD on admission to the official list
and partly adding to those minimum requirements. Chapter II of
Title III of CARD lays down certain conditions for the
admissibility of shares to the official list, and Ch.III lays down a
lesser set of requirements for debt securities.49 Since securities
admitted to the official list must also be admitted to trading on a
regulated market,50 the rules on admission to the official list in
effect control admission to trading as well. However, the
operators of any market may lay down conditions for the
admission of securities to trading on that market, though
competition considerations constrain operators from going very
far in controlling admissions. We look first at the rules on
admission to the official list.
The admissibility conditions may be divided into those related
to the issuer and those related to the securities on offer. In
relation to both equity and debt securities one of two major
policy concerns of CARD and the LR is to ensure that there
should be a liquid market in the securities in question after
listing, so that subsequent trading in the securities is not
unacceptably volatile.51 The following requirements promote this
goal.
(i) The expected market value of the securities to be admitted
must be at least £700,000 for shares and £200,000 for debt
securities.52
(ii) All the securities of the class in question must be admitted to
listing.53
(iii) The securities must be freely transferable.54 Without this
requirement the development of a market in the securities
would clearly be inhibited.
(iv) In the case of shares a “sufficient number” of the class of
shares in question must be distributed to the public (as
opposed to being held in non-trading blocks by insiders),
which is translated as a rule of thumb into 25 per cent of the
shares for which admission is sought.55
The other main driver of the CARD rules is that the issuer
should have a certain quality. These requirements apply to
the issue of shares only.
(v) The company must produce audited accounts for a period of
three years, ending not earlier than six months before the
application for admission.56
(vi) Going beyond CARD, for premium listing the company
must show that “at least 75% of the applicant’s business is
supported by a historic revenue earning record” for the three
years in question and that it will be carrying on an
independent business as its main activity.57 The aim of these
requirements is not that the applicant show that it has been
profitable over the three years (though it may not find takers
for its shares if it has not been) but that its current business
has a three-year track record and is not contingent on some
other person’s consent.58 As a result of opportunistic
behaviour on the part of controllers of certain listed
companies, the LR were modified in 2015 so as to require
controlling shareholders (30 per cent of more of the voting
rights) to enter into a written and legally binding agreement
with the company, designed to safeguard its independence,
especially in relation to related-party transactions and the
election of independent directors, in the absence of which the
LR’s standard related-party transactions are applied to the
issuer with particular rigour.59
(vii) Again going beyond CARD and for premium listing, the
applicant must show, subject to exceptions, that it will have
sufficient working capital to meet its requirements for the
12 months after listing.60 This is some protection against the
company suffering a “cash crunch” in the short-term after
listing. Of course, where the admission is coupled with a
public offer, the working capital is likely to be raised in that
offer. The purpose of this requirement is that the applicant
shows it has made a realistic forecast of what needs in the
near term.
In addition to these specific requirements in relation to the
company and its securities, there is a general power in art.11 of
CARD for Member States to reject an application for listing “if,
in their opinion, the issuer’s situation is such that admission
would be detrimental to investors’ interests”. This is transposed
into domestic law by FSMA 2000 s.75(5), which gives the
power of rejection to the FCA as the competent authority. It is
unclear in what circumstances this power might be used, though
no doubt it is a useful back-stop to deal with the unexpected.
Exchange admission standards
25–16
Since admission to listing requires admission to a market for
listed securities, the admission standards of the exchange are
also relevant to the listing process. Taking the admission
standards of the LSE for its Main Market as an example, these
largely track the eligibility requirements of the LR but add to
them in some ways. Thus, the shares sought to be traded “must
be capable of being traded in a fair, orderly and efficient
manner” and the Exchange may refuse an application for listing
if the applicant’s situation is such that admission “may be
detrimental to the orderly operation of the Exchange’s markets
or to the integrity of such markets”.61
In the case of unlisted securities, the eligibility rules of the
exchange to which admission is sought are naturally central,
since the LR have no application. For the AIM, run by the LSE,
the exchange in fact lays down no general eligibility
requirements for admission other than the appointment of a
“nominated adviser”.62 This is because the responsibility for
assessing the suitability of the applicant for AIM is placed by the
Exchange on the adviser (usually referred to as the “nomad”).63
However, eligibility requirements are laid down in certain
specific cases. For example, r.7 of the AIM Rules for Companies
stipulates:
“Where an applicant’s or quoted applicant’s main activity is a business which has
not been independent and earning revenue for at least two years, it must ensure that
all related parties and applicable employees as at the date of admission agree not to
dispose of any interest in its securities for one year from the admission of its
securities.”
Introduction 26–1
Periodic Reporting Obligations 26–3
Episodic or Ad Hoc Reporting Requirements 26–5
Disclosure of Directors’ Interests 26–9
Who has to disclose? 26–11
What has to be disclosed, to whom and when? 26–12
Disclosure of Major Voting Shareholdings 26–14
Rationale and history 26–14
The scope of the disclosure obligation 26–16
Sanctions 26–24
Compensation for misleading statements to the
market 26–25
Compensation via FCA action 26–28
Administrative penalties for breaches 26–29
Criminal sanctions 26–32
Conclusion 26–33
INTRODUCTION
26–1
Even after a company has been admitted to a public market, in
accordance with the rules discussed in the previous chapter, the
law imposes “continuing obligations” in relation to disclosure by
publicly traded companies. These obligations are discussed in
the first half of this chapter. In addition, however, the law
requires those associated with the company, as directors or major
shareholders, to make certain disclosures to the company and,
through the company, to the market. We turn to them in the
second half.
26–2
The continuing obligations laid on the company largely reflect
the disclosure philosophy which dominates the rules on public
offerings and admission to trading,1 but that theory is applied
now to the post-admission period so as to inform trading among
investors in the securities of the company. Investor protection
and allocative efficiency are most obviously advanced by
continuing disclosure when a traded company returns to the
market to raise further capital, especially in cases where it may
do so without issuing a new prospectus.2 More generally,
investors’ willingness to purchase securities in publicly traded
companies (whether on a public offering or from existing
shareholders) is likely to be enhanced if they think that market
prices reflect the true state of the company’s business.3 In
addition, the prompt disclosure of significant information by the
company will reduce the opportunities for insiders to trade in the
securities before the market is aware of new developments.
Further, disclosure rules may benefit shareholders, whether or
not they contemplate trading in the company’s securities. The
market price of the stock may indicate to shareholders (or
independent directors acting on their behalf) whether all is well
with the company’s business and whether the exercise of their
governance rights would be appropriate—though it would be
unwise for shareholders to react to short-term movements in
share prices. Continuing disclosure by the company thus has
both market and corporate governance implications, which we
will explore in this chapter.4
Insider trading may also be discouraged by requiring those
closely associated with the company’s central management
(notably its directors) to make disclosures to the company and to
the market about their trading in the company’s securities, since
directors are structurally well placed to acquire inside
information. Finally, within the shareholder body disclosure of
beneficial ownership of shares may also reveal who is really in a
position to influence decisions in shareholder meetings and so to
determine the future course of the company (for example,
through the selection of directors). So, the rules about disclosure
to the company and the market have market “cleanliness” and
corporate governance objectives as well as the rules on
disclosure by the company.
As with the disclosure rules operating at the time of admission
to the market, the structure of domestic law is now heavily
influence by EU law, notably the Transparency Directive
(“TD”)5 and the Market Abuse Regulation (“MAR”).6 The TD
has generated the same multi-layered rule-making structure
which we identified in relation to the Prospectus Directive.7 At
the bottom of the structure, but very important in practice, are
the Transparency Rules (“TR”) made by the FCA. Under the TD
the domestic rules are somewhat more important than under the
PD because, unlike the PD, the TD is not a maximum
harmonisation instrument. In principle Member States can add to
its provisions, which the UK, because of its long history of
regulating continuing obligations, has often done. Market abuse
was previously dealt with at EU level through directives,
generating the same multi-layered structure. However, in the
post-crisis reforms the EU moved to a Market Abuse Regulation8
which, as a regulation, does not require transposition into
domestic law but operates directly as part of UK law. However,
it too provides largely minimum standards to which domestic
law may add.
PERIODIC REPORTING OBLIGATIONS
26–3
We saw in Ch.21 that all companies must report on an annual
basis to their shareholders and that such reporting is now
extensive, especially for “quoted” companies.9 However, for a
long time companies with securities10 traded on public markets
have been subject to more frequent reporting requirements, for
the market’s appetite is not satisfied by yearly reporting. Such
companies may be required to report half-yearly and even
quarterly. In the case of regulated markets11 these obligations
currently stem from the TD.
Article 4 of the TD requires the publication of audited annual
accounts and reports. By and large, the requirements of this
article are met by the rules contained in the Companies Act 2006
and considered in Chs 21 and 22.12 However, the Directive’s
requirement for speedier publication of accounts than the 2006
Act requires (four, rather than six, months from the end of the
financial year) is implemented domestically in the DTR.13
Further, TD art.4 requires a more explicit “responsibility
statement” than is to be found in the case of accounts approved
by the directors and signed by a director on behalf of the board
under the Act.14 The TD requires the names of all those
responsible within the issuer for the accounts and reports to be
stated and the responsibility statement must certify that, to the
best of their knowledge, the accounts have been prepared in
accordance with the relevant standards and give a true and fair
view of the company’s financial position, and the management
report includes a fair review of the company’s business.15
More significant is the TD’s requirement for half-yearly
reports, to which there is no Companies Act equivalent, to be
published within two months of the end of the half year. The
half-yearly reports are required to be less detailed than the
annual ones and are not required to be audited (though if they are
audited or reviewed, the audit report or review must be
published).16 The accounts required to be produced are a
condensed set of financial statements, the directors’ report is an
“interim review” and the responsibility statement is adjusted
accordingly.17
26–4
The issue of quarterly reporting has been contentious. Some
argue that it adds to the efficiency of securities markets; others
than it encourages management to focus on the short-term. The
original TD required, not a set of quarterly accounts but only a
quarterly “interim management statement”, giving an
explanation of material events and transactions which had taken
place and their impact on the issuer and a general description of
the company’s financial position and performance.18 However,
in the 2013 amendments the short-termism argument won out
and the quarterly reporting requirement was removed.19
As we have noted in Ch.21, the power to review the accounts
and reports of companies for compliance with the relevant
requirements is one which has been delegated by the
Government to the Financial Reporting Council; and that body’s
powers extend to all the periodic reports required to be produced
by listed companies, whether annual or otherwise.20
EPISODIC OR AD HOC REPORTING REQUIREMENTS
26–5
In addition to the requirement to make reports every six months,
publicly quoted companies are required to report events as they
occur. There are two main arguments behind this requirement.
First, it can be seen as a way of keeping shareholders and
investors up-to-date about developments in the business of the
company or about other factors which affect its business. The
information should be disclosed because it is relevant to
investors and shareholders. The second argument, reflected in
the fact that at EU level this disclosure obligation is located in
MAR rather the TD, is that the information should be disclosed
publicly in order that it shall no longer be known only to a small
group of persons who may be tempted to trade on the basis of
the information to their profit precisely because it is not known
to the market in general. On this rationale disclosure is a way of
reducing opportunities of “insider trading”, i.e. trading in
securities on the basis of price-sensitive information which is not
generally available. On both arguments, the purpose of the rules
is to have the information disclosed to the market, but, in the
first argument because market participants and shareholders
need the information to inform action they might take and, on
the second argument, because disclosure is the way of depriving
the information of its “inside” character.
26–6
The current version of these disclosure requirements is to be
found in art.17 of MAR, applying to companies whose securities
are traded on a multi-lateral trading facility as well as on a
regulated market.21 The emphasis in MAR is on disclosure by
the company of inside information “as soon as possible”. The
essence of inside information is that it is information which is
not known to the market but, if it were known, would have a
significant effect on the price of the company’s securities.22 This
is discussed further in Ch.30.
In the design of any rules relating to the disclosure of events
“as soon as possible”, there are two problems which have to be
faced. One is to define the point at which the event has
crystallised and so triggers the disclosure obligation. If
impending developments or matters under negotiation are
disclosed too soon, their completion may be jeopardised and the
market possibly be given information whose value is difficult to
assess because it relates to inchoate matters. The injunction to
act “as soon as possible” gives the issuer some leeway, for
example, where it receives unexpected information whose ambit
is not clear and which it needs to clarify. Beyond that, MAR
permits issuers “on their own responsibility” (i.e. they cannot
require the national regulatory authority to give advance
clearance of non-disclosure, though the regulator must be
informed of the decision not to disclose)23 to delay disclosure to
protect their “legitimate interests”, but subject to the riders that
the non-disclosure must not be likely to mislead the public and
that the company can ensure the confidentiality of the
information on the part of those to whom it will have to be
disclosed.24 This permission is particularly important since
art.7(2) states that, in principle, “an intermediate step in a
protracted process shall be deemed to be inside information if,
by itself, it satisfies the criteria of inside information as referred
to in this Article”.25
MAR provides for the European Securities Markets Authority
(“ESMA”) to produce guidelines on the tricky issues of what
constitutes a legitimate interest and action likely to mislead,
though some examples of legitimate interest are given in Recital
50 to the Regulation. The indicative list of such legitimate
interests produced in the draft guidance from ESMA26 focuses
on the negotiation or implementation of transactions which are
likely to be prejudiced if they are revealed, for example,
negotiations for a major contract or negotiations to sell a major
holding in the company. However, even where the issuer has a
legitimate interest in non-disclosure, it may refrain from
disclosing only if non-disclosure is not likely to be misleading to
the market. Here the indicative list suggests non-disclosure will
be misleading if (i) the information is inconsistent with some
prior public statement by the issuer to the market; (ii) casts doubt
on the issuer’s prospects of meeting its financial objectives
where these have been the subject of prior public guidance from
the company; or (iii) the information goes against the market’s
current expectations where these have been set by signals from
the issuer. As is to be expected, investors’ interests appear to
receive more weight than issuers’ concerns.27
26–7
The second problem is that public disclosure of adverse
developments may make it more difficult for the issuer to handle
them. In principle, this situation is also handled under the above
rules, but in one case the balance is re-weighted in favour of the
issuer. Where the issuer is a financial institution and disclosure
of the information would threaten the financial viability of the
issuer and of the financial system, disclosure can be delayed,
subject to the confidentiality test and a public interest test and
the consent of the competent financial regulator.28 The reason for
downgrading investors’ interests in this case is that instability in
the financial system is likely to be more costly to society as a
whole than the costs to investors of non-disclosure. This
provision reflects experience in the financial crisis where, at
least in the UK, the regulators interpreted the prior EU law
strictly so as to require immediate disclosure of the existence of
banks’ liquidity problems whilst permitting non-disclosure only
of the state of the negotiations to solve them—arguably the
worst of both worlds.29
26–8
Where information is required to be disclosed the Regulation
requires that to be done in a way which “enables fast access and
complete, correct and timely assessment of the information by
the public”.30 It also requires it to be displayed on the company’s
website for an appropriate period, but this is not in fact a very
good way of disclosing information simultaneously to all market
participants. In practice, Dissemination will occur in the UK via
a “Primary Information Provider” (“PIP”), i.e. one approved by
the FCA, which carries news about all companies in the market
and so does not favour those who happened to be logged onto a
particular company’s website at the time the information was
posted. Further, information required to be disclosed under
art.17 of MAR constitutes “regulated information” which, by
virtue of art.21 of TD, is subject to additional requirements,
notably that it be disseminated to the public simultaneously, as
nearly as possible, in all EEA Member States.31
Somewhat bureaucratically, art.18 of MAR32 requires issuers
to draw up and keep updated, lists of those working for them
(whether as employees or self-employed persons) who have
access to inside information; and to send the lists to the relevant
national regulator, if so requested. Each list must be kept for five
years. Those acting on behalf of the issuer (for example, an
investment bank or law firm) must also draw up such a list.33
The list must give the reason why a particular person is on the
list. All those on the list must be acknowledge in writing their
duties under the insider dealing rules and of their awareness of
the sanctions for breaking them.
DISCLOSURE OF DIRECTORS’ INTERESTS
26–9
In the previous sections we have examined the disclosure
obligations imposed on publicly traded companies. We now turn
to the obligations imposed on those associated with the company
as either directors or major shareholders.
Since shortly after the Second World War the Companies Acts
required directors to disclose to their companies their interests in
the securities of the companies of which they are directors, an
obligation which was later extended so as to impose upon the
director the duty to disclose the interests of spouses, civil
partners and children. In the case of a company with securities
listed on a recognised investment exchange34 the company was
then under an obligation to notify the exchange, which was
permitted to publish the information to the market. Following the
implementation of the Market Abuse Directive35 in the UK, these
disclosure obligations were transferred wholly to rules made by
the FCA36 and confined to companies whose securities were
admitted to trading on a regulated market (or where an
application for admission has been made). With the adoption of
MAR37 to replace the Directive the controlling obligation is now
to be found in art.19 of that instrument and, as we have noted,
MAR applies to multi-lateral trading facilities as well as to
regulated markets.38 However, the substantive provisions of the
Regulation are not enormously different from the prior
combination of EU and domestic law.
29–10
The principal, though not the exclusive, rationale behind this
disclosure requirement is to combat insider trading. Although
directors are not the only people under a temptation to engage in
insider dealing, they are particularly at risk because their
relationship with the company will routinely generate inside
information, i.e. information which, at least for a short while, is
known to them but not outside the company. The original
provisions requiring disclosure of directors’ securities dealings
were introduced following a recommendation from the Cohen
Committee (1945), which identified the insider dealing rationale
for requiring the disclosure:
“The best safeguard against improper transactions by directors and against
unfounded suspicions of such transactions is to ensure that disclosure is made of all
their transactions in the shares or debentures of their companies.”39
27–1
Once shares have been issued by the company, it is only
infrequently that the company will buy them back. Moreover,
this cannot happen without the company’s consent, either at the
time the shares were issued (as with shares which are issued as
redeemable at the option of the shareholder)1 or at the time of re-
acquisition (as in the case of shares redeemable at the option of
the company or a re-purchase of shares).2 In any event, the re-
acquisition cannot occur unless the rules on capital maintenance,
imposed for the benefit of creditors, are observed.3 Although
companies occasionally use surplus cash to re-purchase shares
rather than to pay a dividend, a shareholder who wishes to
realise his or her investment in the company will normally have
to find, or wait for, another investor who will purchase the
shares and take the shareholder’s place in the company. This is
precisely the reason why a company which secures the
admission of its shares to a public market is likely to find it
easier to persuade investors to buy the shares in the first place.
Although the above principle is true of all types of company,
there is a major difference between companies with large and
fluctuating bodies of shareholders whose shares are traded on a
public exchange (“listed” companies) and companies with small
bodies of shareholders whose composition is expected to be
stable and where the allocation of shares is as much about the
allocation of control in the company as it is about its financing
(“non-listed” companies). In the former case, the law or the rules
of the exchange will require the shares to be freely tradable as
far as the issuer is concerned,4 so that except in a few cases the
transfer of the shares will be simply a matter between the
existing shareholder and the potential investor. Free
transferability tends to be taken for granted in listed companies,
but it does become controversial when what is proposed is the
wholesale transfer of the shares to a single person, in the shape
of a takeover bidder, because in that situation, even in an open
company, the transfer of the shares has clear implications for the
control of the company. We shall examine takeovers in the
following chapter.
In non-listed companies, by contrast, even the transfer of
shares by a single shareholder may have implications for the
control of the company and often also for its management, since
a shareholding in such a company may be perceived as giving
rise to a formal or informal entitlement to membership of the
board of directors and participation in the management of the
company.5 In those companies, therefore, it is common for the
articles of association to contain some restrictions on the
transferability of the shares, perhaps by making transfers subject
to the permission of the board or requiring the shares to be
offered initially to the other shareholders before they can be sold
outside the existing shareholder body. The latter obligation is
normally referred to as giving the other shareholders pre-
emption rights, but these are pre-emption rights arising on
transfer and are to be distinguished from pre-emption rights
arising on issuance, which are discussed in Ch.24. The latter
bind the company; the former the selling shareholder.
27–2
Share transfers involve a two-step process. In the first step the
buyer and the seller conclude a sales contract where they agree
on the price which the shares are sold for and on other terms of
the transaction. Bankers sometimes refer to this first step as
“trading”. In the second step the transfer is carried out. At the
end of the second step the buyer becomes the owner of the
shares that formed part of the sales transaction. This second step
is sometimes referred to as “settlement”. Settlement is a process
which in itself consists of two or more stages depending on
whether certificated or uncertificated shares are sold.
When shares in private companies and non-listed public
companies are sold the buyer and the seller frequently know
each other’s identity and are often personally involved in
negotiating the terms of the transaction. Sales transactions are
completed by way of delivery of certain transfer documents from
the seller to the buyer and by way of registering the buyer’s
name on the shareholder register.
When listed shares are sold, the transaction is frequently more
standardised. In most cases, the seller does not go out to find a
buyer him- or herself, but enlists the services of a broker who
sells the shares for him or her. The broker does this either
through the electronic trading system operated by a stock
exchange or by making a contract with another financial services
provider directly. In both cases buyer and seller rarely know
each other’s identity. After the contract has been concluded, the
buyer’s name is also entered on the shareholder register, but this
settlement process is carried out electronically through a
settlement system known as CREST.
In this chapter we will focus on the second step of the transfer
process, the completion of the sales transaction. We shall
examine the difference between certificated and uncertificated
shares, transfers of certificated and transfers of uncertificated
shares as well as the rules governing the shareholder register and
transmission of shares by operation of law. We shall first address
the difference between uncertificated and certificated shares.
CERTIFICATED AND UNCERTIFICATED SHARES
27–3
In the UK, shares are predominantly issued in registered form.
Companies issuing registered shares keep a register of the names
of their shareholders. Until 1996 all registered shares were
issued in what is now called the “certificated form”. This means
that, in addition to having his or her name noted on the
shareholder register, every shareholder receives a paper
certificate evidencing his or her shareholding. When shares are
transferred the seller completes and signs a transfer form and
delivers this together with the share certificate to the buyer. The
buyer then lodges the certificate with the company to have his or
her name entered on its shareholder register.
This paper-based transfer process still applies to non-listed
shares. These are shares in private companies and shares in
public companies which are not listed on the London Stock
Exchange (“LSE”).
Until 1996 listed shares were also transferred by means of
paper documents. The LSE operated a transfer system entitled
TALISMAN. Under the TALISMAN regime, the LSE received
transfer forms and share certificates from buyers and ensured
that the sellers’ names would be registered on the shareholder
register. There was a gap of two to three weeks between trading
and settlement. If shares were sold in the meantime,
TALISMAN would keep track of that transaction and arrange
for the name of the ultimate buyer to be registered.
In the years leading up to the introduction of CREST in 1996,
the UK privatised a large number of previously state-owned
enterprises. The number of listed shares and with that the
number of share transactions increased significantly. When share
prices fell sharply on 19 October 1987, trading volumes soared
and substantial delays in settlement occurred. Delays in
settlement pose a significant risk to a share market. The longer
the delay between trading and settlement the greater the risk that
parties suffer loss by transactions not completing successfully. In
many cases, the law will provide remedies if the transaction
comes to a halt part way through, but the enforcement of those
rights will be expensive and in some cases, for example, in the
insolvency of an involved party, the rights may not have any
value.
27–4
In the discussion following the 1987 market crash, it became
apparent that the paper-based transfer process was unable to
cope with large volumes of share transactions. It was decided
that paper transfers should be phased out for listed shares and
that a new electronic share transfer system should be introduced.
This process of replacing paper with electronic shares transfers
is referred to as dematerialisation. Listed shares were
dematerialised in the UK in 1996 when the CREST system went
live. Since then, all UK shares listed on the LSE must be
compatible with electronic settlement.6 CREST operates on the
basis of ss.784–790 of the 2006 Act and of the Uncertificated
Securities Regulations 2001 (USR 2001).7 These Regulations
have termed electronic shares as uncertificated shares and paper
shares as certificated shares.8
The introduction of uncertificated shares requires the consent
of a number of parties. CRESTCo, as the operator of the
electronic system, must agree to admit the securities of the
company in question to the system, though it clearly has a strong
commercial incentive to do so, if the shares are heavily traded.
Moreover, since an operator of an electronic system of share
holding and transfer requires the approval of the Treasury and
that approval requires the operator’s rules not to distort
competition,9 it will not be in a position to set rules which
discriminate improperly among companies.
In addition, the company itself must agree to permit its
securities to be held in uncertificated form. Shares or individual
classes of shares are in principle admissible to the electronic
system only where the holding of shares in uncertificated form
and their transfer electronically is permitted by the company’s
constitution.10 The standard constitution requires the company to
issue shareholders with a certificate of their holding.11 To
facilitate the change-over to uncertificated shares, USR 2001
reg.16 permits such provisions in the articles to be disapplied by
resolution of the directors, rather than by the normal route for
altering the articles by resolution of the shareholders,12 provided
the shareholders are given prior or subsequent notice of the
directors’ resolution. The Regulations then provide that the
shareholders by ordinary resolution may vote to overturn the
directors’ resolution, but, unless they do so, the articles will be
modified pro tanto without the shareholders’ positive approval.
Thus, the Regulations encourage uncertificated shares by putting
the burden of objection on the shareholders.
For the time being shareholders can opt to have uncertificated
shares converted into certificated shares. If a shareholders
exercises this option conversion is recorded on the central
CREST register, the company is notified, updates the register
and issues the shareholders with a share certificate.13 On July
2014 the EU adopted a Regulation requiring all securities that
are transferable on a regulated market to be issued in book entry
form.14 The Regulation will come into force on 1 January 2023
by which point the UK will have to abolish the option to convert
shares into certificated form for those shares who are
transferable on regulated markets.15
Having briefly looked at the characteristics of certificated and
uncertificated shares in this section, we shall examine transfers
of certificated shares in the following section. After that transfers
of uncertificated shares will be addressed.
TRANSFERS OF CERTIFICATED SHARES
Legal ownership
27–5
To transfer certificated shares, the seller needs to complete a
transfer form and deliver that form together with the share
certificate to the buyer. The transfer form needs to comply either
with the requirements contained in the company’s constitution or
with the simplified requirements put in place by the Stock
Transfer Act.16
This, however, is not enough to make the transferee a member
of the company. Neither the agreement to transfer nor the
delivery of the signed transfer form and share certificate will
pass legal title to the transferee (though it may pass an equitable
interest in the shares to the transferee).17 The normal rule is that
a person becomes a member of a company and the legal owner
of the shares when they have agreed to this and their name has
been entered into the company’s register of members. The
company enters the transferee’s name on the register of members
in place of the transferor’s name.18 It is precisely this
requirement which gives a closed company the opportunity to
control the process of transfer of shares to new holders.
It also follows from this analysis that a share certificate is not
a negotiable instrument. Legal title does not pass by mere
delivery of the certificate to the transferee but upon registration
of the transferee by the company. In fact, even registration is not
conclusive of the transferee’s legal title. Section 127 provides
that the register of members is only “prima facie evidence” of
matters directed or authorised to be inserted in it and s.768
correspondingly says that a share certificate issued by the
company (for example, to the transferee) is “prima facie
evidence” of the transferee’s title to the shares.19 Where there is
a conflict between the register and the certificate, the former is
stronger prima facie evidence than the latter but neither is
decisive. Ownership of the shares depends on who is entitled to
be registered. Suppose, say, that A, who is registered and is
entitled to be registered, loses his certificate, obtains a duplicate
from the company20 and transfers to B who is registered by the
company. Subsequently A finds the original certificate and,
either because he has forgotten about the sale to B or because he
is a rogue, then purports to sell the shares to C. The company
will rightly refuse to register C whose only remedy will be
against A (who may by this time be a man-of-straw).
More importantly, suppose D loses the certificate to E, a
rogue, who forges D’s signature and secures entry on the register
in place of D. D will nevertheless be entitled to have the register
rectified21 so as to restore D’s name, because D is still the holder
of the legal title to the shares and so is entitled to be entered on
the register. This appears to be so, even if D’s conduct has been
such as to provide the opportunity for E to commit the fraud, for
example because D had deposited the certificate with E.22
Furthermore, D will be entitled to insist on rectification if, as is
all too likely, E has made a further transfer of the shares to a
wholly innocent third party, F, who is registered before D learns
of the fraud. D may still rectify the register against F. This
system of rules provides a high level of protection of D’s legal
rights, but is hardly conducive to the free circulation of shares.
Estoppel
27–6
However, the position of people such as F is ameliorated by the
doctrine of estoppel by share certificate, which may give F a
right to an indemnity against the company, if D insists on
rectification of the register. In other words, the risk of fraud (or
other unauthorised transfer) falls on the company, which is
perhaps defensible on the grounds that it is the company which
benefits from legal rules which encourage the free circulation of
shares.23 The doctrine of estoppel by share certificate produces
what has been termed “quasi-negotiability”.24
A share certificate contains two statements on which the
company knows that reliance may be placed. The first is the
extent to which the shares to which it relates are paid up. The
second is that the person named in it was registered as the holder
of the stated number of shares. The company may be estopped
from denying either statement if someone in reliance upon it has
changed his position to his detriment. This may afford a
transferee who, in reliance on the transferor’s share certificate,
has bought what he believed, wrongly, to be fully paid shares a
defence if the company makes a call upon him.25 The company
will also be estopped if the transferee has relied on a false
statement in his transferor’s certificate that the transferor was the
registered holder of the shares on the date stated in the
certificate.26 Thus, F, the transferee from the rogue, will be
entitled to an indemnity from the company if the company
rectifies the register in favour of D, the legal owner, because F
will have relied upon the certificate issued by the company to the
rogue.
However, this argument will rarely27 benefit an original
recipient of the incorrect certificate because receipt of the
certificate normally marks the conclusion of the transaction and
is not something which was relied on in deciding to enter into it.
In the example above, E, the rogue, is the original recipient of
the incorrect certificate and we need have no regrets about the
weakness of E’s legal position. However, suppose E, instead of
transferring the shares fraudulently into his own name and then
disposing of them to F, in fact, as is all too likely, short-circuited
this procedure by transferring them directly to F, and the
company then issued a new certificate to F. F could not claim to
have relied on the new certificate when entering into the
transaction which pre-dated its issue. F did rely on the certificate
issued to D but E’s fraud did not turn on a denial of D’s
ownership of the shares but rather upon E pretending to be D. In
this situation, only a transferee from F would be able to rely on
the doctrine of estoppel by share certificate. Perhaps this result
may be justified on the basis that D is in a better position to
detect E’s fraud than is the company.
Restrictions on transferability
27–7
The directors of non-listed companies are frequently empowered
by the articles to refuse to register transfers or there will be
provisions affording the other members or the company28 rights
of pre-emption, first refusal or even compulsory acquisition.
This does not apply to listed shares because the Listing Rules
require there to be no restrictions of the transfer of shares.29
Provisions restricting share transfers require the most careful
drafting if they are to achieve their purpose; and have not always
received it, thereby facing the courts with difficult questions of
interpretation. The following propositions can, it is thought, be
extracted from the voluminous case law:
(a) The extent of the restriction is solely a matter of construction
of the company’s constitution. But, since shareholders have a
prima facie right to transfer to whomsoever they please, this
right is not to be cut down by uncertain language or doubtful
implications.30 If, therefore, it is not clear whether a
restriction applies to any transfer or only to a transfer to, say,
a non-member,31 or to any type of disposition or only to a
sale32 the narrower construction will be adopted.
(b) However, this does not help the courts much when faced with
a common provision in the articles that a shareholder
“desirous” or “intending” or “proposing” to transfer his or her
shares to another must give notice to the company to trigger
pre-emption procedures. On the one hand, the provision
would be unworkable if the courts had held that as soon as a
shareholder formed the relevant intention, the provision in the
articles was triggered, especially as the shareholder is
normally permitted to withdraw the notice, if he or she does
not wish to sell to the person who comes forward to buy the
shares. There must be something in addition to the required
intention. On the other hand, a shareholder who enters into an
agreement with an outsider to sell the shares to that person or
to give that person an option to buy them will fall within the
provision in the articles, even if the outsider has not
completed the agreement (and so has only an equitable
interest in the shares) or has not taken up the option to
purchase.33 Drafters have spent much ingenuity on producing
agreements which do not fall within the second category and
have been rewarded. The courts have held that agreements do
not trigger the notice provision if they transfer only the
beneficial interest in the shares and entitle the transferee to be
registered as the legal owner of the shares only once the pre-
emption right has been removed from the articles.34 The
execution of a transfer form and its deposit with the
company’s auditor, however, can amount to a transfer which
triggers pre-emption rights contained in the company’s
constitution.35
(c) Where the regulations confer a discretion on directors with
regard to the acceptance of transfers, this discretion, like all
the directors’ powers, is a fiduciary one36 to be exercised
bona fide in what they consider—not what the court
considers—to be in the interest of the company, and not for
any collateral purpose. But the court will presume that they
have acted bona fide, and the onus of proof of the contrary is
on those alleging it and is not easily discharged.37
(d) Prior to the Companies Act 2006 it was possible for the
articles of association to stipulate that the directors shall not
be bound to state their reasons for not registering a transfer.38
The Companies Act 2006 now states in s.771 that the
company must provide the transferee with such further
information about the reasons for the refusal as the transferee
may reasonable request. This, however, does not include
minutes of the meetings of directors. The CLR hopes that this
will make it possible to apply the fiduciary tests and s.994 on
unfair prejudice in a transparent way to such refusals.39
(e) If, on the true construction of the articles, the directors are
entitled to reject only on certain prescribed grounds and it is
proven that they have rejected on others, the court will
intervene.40 If the directors state their reasons (as they are
now obliged to do) the court will investigate them to the
extent of seeing whether they have acted on the right
principles and would overrule their decision if they have
acted on considerations which should not have weighed with
them, but not merely because the court would have come to a
different conclusion.41 If the regulations are so framed as to
give the directors an unfettered discretion the court will
interfere with it only on proof of bad faith.42
(f) If, as is normal, the regulations merely give the directors
power to refuse to register, as opposed to making their
passing of transfers a condition precedent to registration,43 the
transferee is entitled to be registered unless the directors
resolve as a board to reject. Hence in Moodie v Shepherd
(Bookbinders) Ltd44 where the two directors disagreed and
neither had a casting vote, the House of Lords held that
registration must proceed. The directors have a reasonable
time in which to come to a decision,45 but since s.771(1)
imposes an obligation on them to give to the transferee notice
of rejection within two months of the lodging of the transfer,
the maximum reasonable period is two months.46
The positions of transferor and transferee prior to
registration
27–8
It may be of importance to determine the precise legal position
of the transferor and transferee pending registration of the
transfer which, if there are restrictions on transferability, may
never occur. As we have seen, only if and when the transfer is
registered will the transferor cease to be a member and
shareholder and the transferee will become a member and
shareholder. However, notwithstanding that registration has not
occurred, the beneficial interest in the shares may have passed
from the transferor to the transferee. In the case of a sale of
certificated shares the transaction will normally go through three
stages: (1) an agreement (which, particularly if a block of shares
conferring de facto or de jure control is being sold, may be a
complicated one); (2) delivery of the signed transfer form and
the certificate by the seller and payment of the price by the buyer
and; (3) registration of the buyer’s name on the shareholder
register.
Notwithstanding that the transfer is not lodged for registration
or registration is refused, the beneficial interest in the shares
will, it seems, pass from the seller to the buyer at the latest at
stage (2) and, indeed will do so at stage (1) if the agreement is
one which the courts would order to be specifically enforced.47
The seller then becomes a trustee for the buyer and must account
to him for any dividends he receives and vote in accordance with
his instructions (or appoint him as his proxy).48 This, however,
begs several questions. The first arises because at stage (2)
delivery of the documents may not necessarily be matched by
payment of the full price; the agreement may have provided for
payment by instalments49 and the seller will then retain a lien on
the shares as an unpaid seller. This will not prevent an equitable
interest passing to the buyer but the court will not grant specific
performance unless the seller’s lien can be fully protected,50 and
until paid in full he is entitled to vote the shares as he thinks will
best protect his interest.51 Instead of being a bare trustee his
position is analogous to that of a trustee of a settlement of which
he is one of the beneficiaries.
The second begged question is whether the foregoing can
apply when the articles provide for rights of pre-emption or first
refusal when a shareholder wishes to dispose of his shares. In
such a case the transferor (perhaps with the full knowledge of
the transferee52) has breached the deemed contract under s.33
between him and the company and his fellow shareholders.
There are observations of the House of Lords in Hunter v
Hunter53 to the effect that accordingly the transfer is wholly
void, even as between the transferor and transferee.
However, in later cases54 courts have refused to follow this
and, it must surely be right (at any rate if the price has been paid)
that the buyer obtains such rights as the transferor had. This will
not benefit the buyer if all the shares are taken up when the
transferor is compelled to make a pre-emptive offer, but it does
not follow that all of them will be taken up and, if not, the
transferee has a better claim to those shares not taken up than has
the transferor.
27–9
When the transaction is not a sale but a gift, there need be no
agreement. Even if there is, it will not be legally enforceable
under English law because there will be no valuable
consideration and because, under the so-called rule in Milroy v
Lord,55 “there is no equity to perfect an imperfect gift”. One
might have supposed, therefore, that if the donor has chosen to
make the gift by handing to the donee a signed transfer and the
share certificate, rather than by a formal declaration of trust in
favour of the donee, the gift would not be effective unless and
until the transfer was registered. In modern cases,56 however, it
has been held that so long as the donor has done all he needs to
do, or there has been detrimental reliance by the donee, the
beneficial interest passes from him to the donee.57
Priorities between competing transferees
27–10
Questions may also arise in determining the priority of purported
transfers of the same shares to different people. In answering
these questions the courts58 have relied on two traditional
principles of English property law: i.e. (1) that as between two
competing holders of equitable interests, if their equities are
equal the first in time prevails; and (2) that a bona fide purchaser
for value of a legal interest takes free of earlier equitable
interests of which he has no notice at the time of purchase.
In applying these principles to competing share transfers, a
transferee prior to registration is treated as having an equitable
interest only but registration converts his interest into a legal
one.59 Hence if a registered shareholder, A, first executes a
transfer to a purchaser, B, and later to another, C, while both
remain unregistered B will have priority over C. If, however, C
succeeds in obtaining registration before B, he will have priority
over B so long as he had no notice, at the time of purchase, of
the transfer to B. If C did have notice, although he has been
registered, his prima facie title will not prevail over that of B,
who will be entitled to have the register rectified (assuming that
there are no grounds on which the company could refuse to
register B) and in the meantime C’s legal interest will be subject
to the equitable interest of B.60 If both transfers were gifts, the
position would presumably be different; the gift to B61 would
leave A without any beneficial interest that he could give to C
and, not being a “purchaser”, C could not obtain priority by
registration; his legal interest, on his becoming the registered
holder, would be subject to the prior equity of B.
It should perhaps be pointed out once again that even
registration affords only prima facie evidence of title. If the
registered transferor, A, was not entitled to the shares, what will
pass when he transfers to B or C is not, strictly speaking, either a
legal or equitable interest but only his imperfect title to it, which
will not prevail against the true owner. If, for example, the
transfer to A was a forgery the true owner will be entitled to be
restored to the register.62 Hence a transferee can never be certain
of obtaining an absolute title in the case of an off-market
transaction. But his risk is slight so long as he promptly obtains
registration of the transfer. And this he can do unless there are
restrictions on the transferability of the shares or unless there are
good reasons for failing to apply for registration.
The principal example for the latter occurs when the
shareholder wants to borrow on the security of his shares. This
can be done by a legal mortgage, under which the shareholder
transfers the shares to the lender (who registers the transfer)
subject to an agreement to retransfer them when the loan is
repaid. Generally, however, this suits neither party; the lender
normally has no wish to become a member and shareholder of
the company and the borrower does not want to cease to be one.
Hence a more usual arrangement is one whereby the shareholder
deposits with the lender his share certificate and, often, a signed
blank transfer, this usually being accompanied by a written
memorandum setting out the terms of the loan. The result is to
confer an equitable charge which the lender can enforce by
selling the shares if he needs to realise his security. Custody of
the share certificate is regarded as the essential protection of the
lender.63 In the case of shares, dealt with through CREST,64 its
rules provided for uncertificated shares to be held in “escrow”
balances, which provision appears to give the bank an equivalent
security.65
The company’s lien
27–11
As we have seen,66 a public company is not permitted to have a
charge or lien on its shares except (a) when the shares are not
fully paid and the charge or lien is for the amount payable on the
shares; or (b) the ordinary business of the company includes the
lending of money or consists of the provision of hire-purchase
finance and the charge arises in the course of a transaction in the
ordinary course of its business.67 Neither exception is of much
importance in the present context.
Hence it is only in respect of private companies that problems
are still likely to arise when their articles provide, as they
frequently do, that “the company shall have a first and
paramount lien on shares, whether or not fully-paid, registered in
the name of a person indebted or under any liability to the
company”. Since the decision of the House of Lords in Bradford
Banking Co v Briggs, Son and Co68 it appears to be accepted that
the effect of such a provision is that:
(a) once a shareholder has incurred a debt or liability to the
company, it has an equitable charge on the shares of that
shareholder to secure payment which ranks in priority to later
equitable interests and, it seems, to earlier ones of which the
company had no notice when its lien became effective; and
(b) in determining whether the company had notice,69 s.126 has
no application; if the company knows of the earlier equitable
interest (because, for example, a transfer of the shares has
been lodged for registration even if that is refused) it cannot
improve its own position to the detriment of the holder of that
known equitable interest.
An interesting modern illustration is afforded by Champagne
Perrier-Jouet v Finch & Co.70 There the company’s articles
provided for a lien in the above terms. One of its shareholders71
had been allowed to run up substantial debts to the company
resulting from trading between him and the company and it had
been agreed that he could repay by instalments. Another creditor
of the shareholder subsequently obtained judgment against him
and a charging order on the shares by way of equitable
execution. It was held that the company’s lien had become
effective when the debts to it were incurred (even though they
were not then due for repayment) and as this occurred before the
company had notice of the charging order,72 the company’s lien
had priority.73
As this case shows, an equitable charge on shares in a private
company with articles conferring a lien on the company is likely
to be an even more undesirable form of security than shares in
private companies always are. It may, however, be the only
security obtainable, for an attempt to obtain a legal charge will
almost certainly be frustrated by the refusal of the directors to
register the transfer. If, faute de mieux, it has to be accepted,
notice should immediately be given to the company, making it
clear that this is a notice which it cannot disregard in relation to
any lien it may claim, and an attempt should be made to obtain
information about the amount, if any, then owed to the company.
TRANSFERS OF UNCERTIFICATED SHARES
27–12
We have seen in the previous section that certificated shares are
transferred by way of delivery of certain transfer documents to
the company. The company being so notified of a transfer then
registers the transferee’s name on the shareholder register. When
uncertificated shares are sold, the register is updated through
electronic instructions.
For a transfer of uncertificated shares to be possible, both the
seller and the buyer need to have access to the CREST system.
There are three ways in which investors can access CREST.
They can either hold an account with CREST themselves and
acquire the hard- and software necessary to establish a safe
connection with CREST. The cost involved in doing this makes
this option unappealing to small scale private investors. An
investor can also have his or her account with CREST operated
by a broker who accesses the system or his or her behalf. This
option is referred to as personal membership in the CREST
documentation. With both options, the account is operated in the
name of the investor who holds legal title to the shares. The third
option for an investor is not to hold an account with CREST but
to instruct a broker to act as a nominee on his or her behalf. In
that case, the investor’s name does not appear on the company’s
register. The nominee rather than the investor has an account
with CREST and holds legal title to the shares. This form of
holding shares has recently come under scrutiny (BIS Research
Paper 261, Exploring the Intermediated Shareholding Model,
January 2016).
When uncertificated shares are transferred, both the selling
and the buying account holder need to instruct the system to
carry out the transfer. When shares are sold through the Stock
Exchange’s electronic trading system, the sales information is
transferred into the CREST system automatically and the selling
and the buying account holder have an opportunity to verify the
data before the transfer is effected.
Upon receiving transfer instructions, CREST verifies them,
matches them and carries them out on the day specified by the
parties. On that day CREST transfers the shares from the seller
to the buyer and causes the purchase price to be paid over to the
seller. The buyer becomes the legal owner of the shares when
they are credited to his or her account. This is because, since
2001, CREST not only operates an electronic transfer system,
but also keeps the shareholder register for all UK uncertificated
shares.74 Having updated the register, CREST needs to
immediately inform the issuing company which keeps a record
of all transfers relating to uncertificated shares.
27–13
In order to preserve the integrity of the shareholder register, the
USR 2001 stipulates that the Operator must not amend the
shareholder register, except on completion of a trade in
uncertificated units, unless ordered to do so by a court75 or unless
shares have been transferred by operation of law.76 Equally,
there are only limited circumstances in which the Operator may
or must refuse to alter the operator register if it has received
appropriate instructions from system members. Of course, the
Regulations recognise that, in rare cases, events outside the
system may impinge on the Operator’s freedom of action in
relation to the Operator register, just as they do on the issuer
register kept by the company (for the uncertificated shares) or
the share register, also kept by the company, for companies
which have not entered the electronic transfer system. Thus,
unless it is impracticable to stop it, CREST must not make a
change in the Operator register which it actually knows is
prohibited by an order of a court or by or under an enactment or
involves a transfer to a deceased person.77 There are further
cases where CREST may refuse to make a change, for example,
where the transfer is not to a legal or natural person or is to a
minor.78 Section 771(1)79 applies in cases where CREST refuses
to register a transfer,80 but a two-month limit for notifying
transferees of a failure to register hardly seems an appropriate
one for an electronic system.
Title to uncertificated shares and the protection of
transferees
27–14
The CREST system has reduced the time that lapses between
trade and settlement. It has also caused transfers of uncertificated
shares to be carried out almost simultaneously with payment of
the purchase price. This has significantly reduced the
transactional risk investors in shares are exposed to. The risk
involved in shares transaction has, however, not been eliminated
completely. In particular, the Regulations do not introduce a rule
to the effect that entry on the Operator register confers title to the
shares on the person registered. On the contrary, reg.24(1)
provides, in the same way as the Act,81 that “a register of
members” is simply prima facie evidence of the matters directed
or authorised to be stated in it, and “register of members” is
defined to include both the issuer and Operator register of
members.82 In principle, therefore, a legal owner of shares may
seek rectification of the Operator register if CREST removes his
or her name from it without cause, and a court order restoring
the legal owner to the register would be, as we have seen,
something to which the Operator is obliged to respond.83 In fact,
it is doubtful whether the statutory provision under which the
Regulations were made is wide enough to effect a general
change in the rules as to the status of the register.
This is not to say, however, that the protection of transferees
is provided in the same way or to the same extent under the
Regulations in relation to uncertificated shares as it is in relation
to certificated shares. As we have seen, that protection in relation
to the latter class of shares depends heavily upon the doctrine of
estoppel by share certificate. Since, by definition, there is no
share certificate in relation to uncertificated shares, the
immediate position seems to be that the third party cannot be
protected by this doctrine. Is this in principle a problem for the
transferee of shares? The answer is that, if the matter were not
dealt with in the Regulations, it would be. There are obvious
risks that either an unauthorised person obtains access to the
system or a person with authorised access uses the system in an
unauthorised way, in both cases sending an instruction to
transfer shares not belonging to him or her to an innocent third
party. Can the former holder of the shares secure the restoration
of his or her name to the Operator register to the detriment of the
third party?
One technique for protecting the third party might be to
transfer the doctrine of estoppel by share certificate to the entry
on the register, but it is no accident that, in relation to
certificated shares, the doctrine is based on the certificate, not on
the register entry, even though both are available. This is
because it is rare for a transferee to rely on the register entry
before committing him- or herself to the transaction. This is true
of both the Operator register and the issuer register, and so
estoppel does not seem an effective protective device as against
either the company or CREST.
27–15
In fact, the Regulations take an entirely different approach to the
protection of transferees. If the unauthorised instruction in the
situations above is sent in accordance with the rules of the
Operator, the recipient of the instruction is entitled, subject to
very few exceptions, to act on it and the person by whom or on
whose behalf it was purportedly sent may not deny that it was
sent with proper authority and contained accurate information.84
Unlike at common law, where even careless conduct does not
prevent the legal owner from asserting his or her title to the
shares,85 even a legal owner who was in no way to blame for the
fraud may find that title to the shares has been lost. The
transferor may have a remedy in such a case against the system
participant whose equipment was used to send the unauthorised
instructions.86 There may also be a liability of the Operator in
such a case, but only if the instruction was not sent from a
system computer or the system computer it purported to be sent
from. Thus, purely unauthorised activity by a broker’s employee
is not caught.87 In any event, the liability is capped at £50,000 in
respect of each instruction88 and falls away entirely if the
Operator identifies the person responsible, even if the transferor
is not able to recover any compensation from that person.89
Thus, it seems right to conclude that transferees are somewhat
better protected under the Regulations than under the common
law doctrine of estoppel, since even first transferees from the
rogue are protected. However, that protection is provided at the
expense of the transferor, rather than of the company, as at
common law, and it is certainly arguable that company liability
is the better principle because of the benefit companies obtain
from effective markets.90
Because the transfer of legal ownership is so closely linked to
payment, the rules on beneficial ownership have less practical
relevance in relation to transfers of uncertificated shares.91 When
uncertificated securities are used as collateral, however, equity
continues to play an important role. Moreover, the Financial
Collerateral Directive,92 which aims at reducing the formalities
required to create a security interest over securities, has had
significant impact on English law.93
THE REGISTER
27–16
We have already seen that companies issuing registered shares
must keep a register containing the names of their members.94
We shall now examine the rules governing the shareholder
register more closely. The register of companies which issue
only certificated shares is subject to the 2006 Act. Companies
which issue only uncertificated shares or both certificated and
uncertificated shares are subject to the Uncertificated Securities
Regulation 2001 (USR 2001).95
Under both regimes, the register contains the name and
address of each member and the date on which each person was
registered as a member and the date on which any person ceased
to be a member.96 It also states the number and class97 of shares
held by each member and the amount paid up on each share.98 In
the case of a private company there must also be noted on the
register the fact and the date of the company becoming, or
ceasing to be a single member company.99
The register of members of both certificated and uncertificated
shares constitutes prima facie evidence of any matters which are
by the respective regulatory regime directed or authorised to be
inserted in it.100
In order to become a member or shareholder of a company an
investor has to have his or her name entered on that shareholder
register. A buyer normally acquires legal title to shares at the
point in time at which his or her name is entered on the
shareholder register.101 This rule applies irrespective of whether
shares are held in the certificated or in the uncertificated form.
27–17
Certificated and uncertificated shares differ in terms of who
maintains the shareholder register. The register for certificated
shares is maintained by the company itself or by a registrar on
behalf of the company. The register for uncertificated shares is
maintained by the Operator of the uncertificated transfer system,
CREST. The register of companies which issue certificated
shares and uncertificated shares consists of two parts. Entries
relating to certificated shares are maintained by the company.
They are referred to as the “issuer register of members”. Entries
relating to uncertificated shares are maintained by the Operator
of the uncertificated transfer system, and are referred to as
“Operator register of members”. The company maintains a
“record” relating to uncertificated shares. This record does not
constitute a shareholder register. It must be regularly reconciled
with the Operator register of members.102 In relation to
uncertificated shares, the Operator register prevails over the
record kept by the company.103 The record does not provide for
prima facie evidence. It enables the company to inform those
inspecting the register about entries that have been made on the
register maintained by CREST.
The issuer register may be kept at the company’s registered
office or at a place specified in regulations under s.1136.104 If
kept otherwise than at the company’s registered office, notice
must be given to Companies House (and thus to the public) of
the place where it is kept and of any change of that place.105
If a company has more than 50 members then, unless the
register is kept in such a form as to constitute an index of names
of members, such an index must be kept at the same place as the
register.106
27–18
The shareholder register and the index are available for public
inspection. Any member of the company may inspect the register
free of charge.107 Any other person may inspect the register on
payment of such fee as may be prescribed.108 In the case of
uncertificated shares, the inspection right is granted against the
record held by the company rather than against the Operator
register itself.109 This exposes the searcher to the risk that the
company’s record will not accurately reflect the Operator
register. Provided the company regularly reconciles its record
with the Operator register, except insofar as matters outside its
control prevent such reconciliation, the company is not liable for
discrepancies between the record and the register.110
The right to inspect the register is a legitimate help to a
takeover bidder and makes it possible for members to
communicate with each other. It also has, in the past, been
abused by traders who advertised their wares by unsolicited mail
or telephone calls and who were able to obtain more cheaply
than in any other way a list of potential victims by buying a copy
of the shareholder register of, say, British Telecom or British
Gas. With a view to putting an end to this illegitimate use of the
shareholder register, the 2006 Act revised the right to inspect the
register. The right to inspect the register may now be denied by
the Court if it is satisfied that the request was not sought for a
proper purpose.111
Under s.358 of the 1985 Act a company had the power to
close the shareholder register for any time or times not
exceeding in total 30 days in any year. The provision enabled
companies to draw up a list of those who are entitled to attend
the annual general meeting or to receive dividends. The 2006
Act does not contain a power to that effect.
Under the USR 2001, companies participating in CREST are
entitled to specify a time not more than 48 hours before a general
meeting by which a person must have been entered on the
register in order to have the right to attend and vote at the
meeting and may similarly choose a day not more than 21 days
before notices of a meeting are sent out for the purposes of
determining who is entitled to receive the notice.112 This way of
proceeding enables transfers to continue in the period before the
meeting (thus reducing the risk to transferees) without landing
the company in the position of having to deal with a constantly
changing body of shareholders.
Rectification
27–19
The register is “prima facie evidence of any matters which are
by this Act directed or authorised to be inserted in it”.113 It is not,
however, conclusive evidence for, as we have seen, membership
is dependent both on agreement to become a member and entry
in the register, and it may be that other requirements in the
company’s articles have to be met. If they are not, it seems that
the registered person does not become a member.114 In any
event, if the entry does not truly reflect the agreement or other
requirements, the register ought to be rectified. Hence s.125
provides a summary remedy whereby:
“(a) the name of any person is without sufficient cause entered in or omitted from a
company’s register of members, or
(b) default is made or unnecessary delay takes place in entering on the register the
fact of any person having ceased to be a member, the person aggrieved or any
member of the company, or the company may apply to the court for
rectification of the register.”115
Introduction 28–1
The Takeover Code and Panel 28–3
The Panel and its methods of operation 28–4
The Scope of the City Code 28–13
Transactions in scope 28–14
Companies in scope 28–15
The Structure of the Code 28–18
The Allocation of the
Acceptance Decision 28–19
Post-bid defensive measures 28–20
Defensive measures in advance of the bid 28–21
Target Management Promotion of an Offer 28–26
Disclosure and independent advice 28–27
Compensation for loss of office 28–28
Competing bids 28–33
Equality of Treatment of Target Shareholders 28–37
Partial bids 28–38
Level and type of consideration 28–39
Mandatory offers 28–41
To whom must an offer be made? 28–47
Wait and see 28–48
The Procedure for Making a Bid 28–49
Before the approach to the target board 28–50
Before a formal offer is made to the target
shareholders 28–55
The formal offer 28–58
The post-offer period 28–68
Conclusion 28–77
INTRODUCTION
28–1
A takeover bid consists of an offer from A (an acquirer—usually
another company) made generally to the shareholders of T Co
(the “target” company) to acquire their shares for a consideration
which may be cash or securities of the offeror or a mixture of
both. The legal mechanism at the heart of the bid is thus a
contractual transfer of shares, but the rules on transfers of shares,
discussed in the previous chapter, although relevant, do not
capture the significance of the takeover bid. A takeover offer has
the aim not simply of a transfer of shares but a shift in the
control of the T Co—or at least a consolidation of control.
Previously, T Co may have been under the control of its board
(for example, where its shareholdings were widely dispersed) or
of one or a few shareholders with a controlling block of shares.
After a successful bid (i.e. one where all or most of the T Co’s
shareholders accept A’s offer) T Co will be controlled by A.
Depending upon who previously had control of the company,
that change of control will therefore be a matter of some moment
to the board of T Co (who will have lost control) or the minority
shareholders1 of T Co (who will be faced with a new controller,
unless they themselves have accepted a cash offer). The change
of control may also affect other stakeholders in the company (for
example, employees) because bidders do not normally expend
large resources to obtain control of companies simply to run
them in the same way as previously. The change of control of T
Co may thus have wide ramifications for those who have
interests in the businesses run by T Co.
This little description reveals the two main issues which
takeover regulation has to address. First, should it seek to
prevent the management of the target company from taking any
steps to discourage a potential bidder from putting an offer to its
shareholders or from discouraging those shareholders from
accepting it? In other words, is the takeover bid to be analysed as
a transaction purely between bidder and target company
shareholders or as one in the outcome of which the management
of the target company also has a legitimate self-interest which it
may take steps to defend? As we shall see, the rules in the UK
have traditionally been based on the former view (no frustration
of the bid by the target management). This rule is expressed in a
strong form once a bid is imminent, and somewhat less strongly
and more diffusely in relation to defensive action taken by target
management in advance of any specific offer. This policy gives
the acquirer or offeror a free run at the target shareholders and
prevents the board from using its management powers so as to
frustrate the bid. It is a policy which can be justified on the
grounds that it supports the principle of free transferability of the
shares of listed companies and, more importantly, on the
grounds that it is a significant element in the British system for
disciplining management and reducing the agency costs of
dispersed shareholders. A board, it is argued, which is at risk of
an unwelcome takeover bid will be sure to promote the interests
of its shareholders, in order to decrease the chances of a bid
being made (because the share price will be high) and increase
the chances that those shareholders will reject an offer if one is
made (because they think they will be at least as well off with
the current management). In this way, the accountability of the
board to the shareholders is promoted by the threat of takeovers,
especially “hostile” ones, i.e. offers not recommended by the
target board to its shareholders but rather made over the heads of
the incumbent management to the shareholders.2
The second major issue for takeover regulation concerns the
steps to be taken to protect non-controlling shareholders if a bid
is launched. Obviously, the transfer of shares could be left, like
any other commercial transaction, to be regulated by the
ordinary law of contract. In the case of controlling shareholders,
who are well-placed to take care of themselves, this is probably
sensible policy. However, in the typical case in the UK, where
the shareholdings in the target are dispersed, the shareholders
may lack information needed to evaluate the offer which has
been made to them (especially information about the likely
benefits of the takeover to the acquirer). Moreover, if left to its
own devices, the offeror may be able to put pressure in various
ways on the shareholders of the target company to accept the
bid, often by proposing to treat some groups of target
shareholders more favourably than others. To counter these risks
we shall see that takeover regulation puts considerable emphasis
on two policies: disclosure of information (by both bidder and
target) to the shareholders of the target, and equality of treatment
of the target shareholders. Equality means that some
shareholders of the target cannot be offered a better deal than is
available generally. As we shall see below,3 this second policy is
taken even to the point of requiring a bid to be launched where
an offeror company has acquired in the market or by private
treaty a sufficient shareholding in the target to give it control.
The “mandatory bid” permits non-controlling shareholders to
exit the company at a fair price upon a change of control, even
though the bidder would prefer not to acquire any further shares.
28–2
Thus, the two central tenets of the British regulation of takeovers
are that the shareholders alone decide on the fate of the offer and
equality of treatment of shareholders. The regulation is both
orthodox and rigorous in putting the target shareholders centre
stage, and in this respect it differs from takeover regulation in
both the US and some, though not all, continental European
countries (for example, Germany). However, these are not the
only objectives of takeover regulation. A takeover offer is
disruptive of the normal running of the target company’s
business and it is therefore politic that this period of disruption
should be minimised by the setting of a firm timetable for the
bid. Thus, a bidder which has indicated it might make a bid is
required to do so or to withdraw within a relatively short period
(“put up or shut up”); the offer, if made, remains open only for
fixed period; and a bidder whose offer fails is not permitted
immediately to come back with another bid. Thus, the bid is a
relatively quick and self-contained event and is not capable of
infinite repetition.
We shall look at these and other aspects of the substantive
rules for the regulation of takeover bids below, but we begin by
examining the rather special machinery which exists in the UK
for the creation and application of those rules.
THE TAKEOVER CODE AND PANEL
28–3
Since the takeover does not require a corporate decision on the
part of the target company,4 there is no obvious act of the target
upon which company law can fasten for the purposes of
regulating the transaction.5 For this reason, most European
countries treat takeover regulation as part of their securities laws,
i.e. they rightly take the transfer of the shares as the central act.
The UK follows this pattern, but it developed takeover
regulation long before statutory regulation of the securities
markets was established, and so the regulation of takeovers took
initially a quasi self-regulatory approach. In the 1950s and
1960s, bidders took full advantage of the absence of regulation.6
Alarmed by what was happening,7 a City working party
published in 1959 a modest set of “Queensberry Rules” entitled
Notes on Amalgamation of British Businesses, which was
followed in 1968 by a more elaborate City Code on Takeovers
and Mergers and the establishment of a Panel on Takeovers and
Mergers to administer and enforce it. It is this Code, in its
various editions, which has since constituted the main body of
rules relating to takeovers, with the Companies Act and the
Financial Services and Markets Act, and rules and regulations
made thereunder, performing an accessory role. However, the
element of self-regulation in this arrangement could easily be
overestimated. Although the Panel had no statutory authority, its
success as a regulator depended largely on the recognition on the
part of those routinely involved in advising on takeovers (mainly
investment banks and large law firms) that to flout its authority
would probably induce Parliament to replace the Code and Panel
with something they liked even less.
The Panel and its methods of operation
The status and composition of the Panel
28–4
In any event, discussion of the self-regulatory status of the Panel
is now rather beside the point. The regulation of takeovers is a
further area where EU Law has come to be a significant source
of the relevant rules. After a very long gestation period the EU
eventually adopted Directive 2004/25/EC on takeover bids
(hereafter the “takeover directive”).8 One of the requirements of
the Directive is that Member States should “designate the
authority or authorities competent to supervise bids” (art.4(1)),
so that the UK was required to place the takeover rules on some
sort of a statutory footing. In fact, the proposed change in the
legal status of the Panel was the basis for the UK Government’s
initial opposition to the Directive, despite the fact that the
Directive’s substantive content was heavily influenced by the
City Code.9 During the EU legislative process changes were
made in the draft Directive so as to allay, as far as possible, the
Government’s fears that the Panel’s flexible way of working
would be undermined by the statutory basis required by the
Directive. The Government’s goal when implementing the
Directive was to produce a situation in which the Panel could
carry on in practice much as before, even though now with its
powers derived from statute. Article 4 of the Directive makes it
clear, which might otherwise be in doubt, that the designated
authorities may be “private bodies recognised by national law”.10
Thus, s.942 of the Companies Act 2006 simply confers certain
statutory powers upon the Panel but does not seek to regulate the
constitution of the Panel, in contrast to the way in which, for
example, the constitution of the FCA is regulated by FSMA
2000. The composition of the Panel is to be found, not in
legislation, but in the Code itself.11 It consists of a Chairman and
up to three Deputy Chairmen appointed by the Panel itself, up to
a further 20 members appointed by the Panel, and individuals
appointed by representative bodies of those involved in
takeovers, such as the Association of British Insurers, the
National Association of Pension Funds, the Association of
Investment Companies and other investor groups, the British
Bankers’ Association, the Institute of Chartered Accountants and
the Confederation of British Industry. The Panel appointees
come from similar backgrounds as those of the representative
appointees, though they include a former general secretary of a
large trade union.
Internal appeals
28–5
However, the Panel’s and the Government’s central concern,
when implementing the Directive, was not with the formal status
of the Panel but with preserving in the statutory framework its
way of working, in particular its freedom to give flexible and
speedy binding rulings in the course of the bid, which could not
be easily challenged in litigation before the ordinary courts. A
particular concern was to discourage “tactical litigation”, i.e.
litigation designed to disrupt the bid timetable or to delay the
operation of a decision of the Panel which is against the interests
of a particular party, but at the same time providing a method of
appeal for those with a genuine grievance. Before the
implementation of the Directive, this result was achieved
through a system of speedy appeal within the Panel itself,
coupled with the courts’ adoption of a limited and after-the-
event approach to judicial review of the Panel’s decisions.
Article 4(6) of the Directive does its best to preserve the viability
of this system by providing that:
“this Directive shall not affect the power of the Member States to designate judicial
or other authorities responsible for dealing with disputes and for deciding on
irregularities committed in the course of bids or the power of Member States to
regulate whether and under which circumstances parties to a bid are entitled to
bring administrative or judicial proceedings. In particular, this Directive shall not
affect the power which courts may have in a Member State to decline to hear legal
proceedings and to decide whether or not such proceedings affect the outcome of a
bid.”
The first of these duties involves not only ensuring that the
meeting was given the information the statute requires and that
the requisite majority was obtained, but also that the class was
fairly represented at the meeting. Thus, the sanction of the court
can be refused if the meeting was unrepresentative of the class as
a whole or if those whose votes were necessary to secure the
required level of approval did so in order to promote some
special interest which they did not share with the ordinary
members of the class.51 This seems to involve something akin to
the “bona fides” test applied to majority decisions to change the
articles.52 The second part of the test is relatively weak, since it
is a rationality rather than a reasonableness test. The court
should not differ from the majority view “unless something is
brought to the attention of the Court to show that there has been
some material oversight or miscarriage”.53
The scheme becomes binding on the company and all
members (or all members of the class concerned) and, if the
company is in liquidation, on the liquidator, once it is sanctioned
by the court and a copy of the court’s order is delivered to the
Registrar (so that knowledge of the scheme is publicly
available).54 Indeed, the binding effect of schemes on minorities
is one of its attractions over a takeover bid.55 In addition,
implementation of an approved scheme will not lead to liability
for any unlawful act contained in the scheme, for example,
unlawful financial assistance for the purchase of shares.56
Additional requirements for mergers and divisions
of public companies
29–12
Under British practice, amalgamations of domestic companies
are rarely carried out by means of transfers of undertakings (as
opposed to shares) using a scheme of arrangement. For this,
there are said to be two reasons. First, there are limitations on
what s.900 can achieve. It was held in Nokes v Doncaster
Amalgamated Collieries57 that the section does not operate to
transfer contracts of employment and that principle has been
applied to any rights which as a matter of general law are not
transferable. Even if the contract is in principle transferable, the
counterparty may have negotiated a right to terminate the
contract or to insist on different terms of business if the
transferor is replaced by the transferee as the contracting party.
Any court order under s.900 (transferring property) will not
override these third-party rights and so transferor and transferee
will have to negotiate an acceptable set of arrangements with the
third party. However, it should be noted that contractual
restrictions can easily be drafted so as to apply where control of
the company changes without there being any transfer of assets
(as in a takeover, whether effected by a scheme or not), so that in
this respect a merger may put the company in no worse a
position. Whether or not the third party has negotiated
contractual protection, s.900(2)(e) gives the court power to
require protection for any creditor (or, indeed, member) who
dissents from the transfer. This issue will not arise in the case of
a takeover, since the court is not involved in approving it.
A second part of the explanation may be that a merger
effected by a scheme is very likely to trigger Pt 27 of the Act,
which imposes extra requirements and costs on the
implementation of schemes for reconstruction58 or amalgamation
involving a public company, in order to meet the requirements of
the Third Company Law Directive on mergers of public
companies.59 Part 27 does not apply where a scheme is used to
effect a takeover, because bidder and target remain separate
companies after the scheme has been effected. There are three
major additional requirements,60 of which the most important is
the third, which deploys the protective device, not otherwise
found in the domestic rules on schemes of arrangement, of an
independent expert’s report. However, although no formal
independent expert’s report may be required of the bidder in the
case of a proposed takeover by means of a scheme, the Takeover
Code lays down extensive rules on the provision of information
to the “target” shareholders, including an independent expert’s
opinion on the fairness of the offer and the Code’s rules will
apply to takeovers by way of a scheme.61 Thus, Pt 27 may not
add much in substance to the bidder’s costs. Perhaps the truth is
that tax rules make amalgamations through schemes unattractive
or that British practitioners have become so familiar with the
takeover that alternative means of amalgamation are not
seriously explored. In any event, the scheme-based domestic
merger seems to be rare.
29–13
The additional requirements of Pt 27 are:
1. Normally, a draft scheme has to be drawn up by the boards of
all62 the companies concerned and publicised via the Gazette
or, more likely, the company’s website. All this must be done
at least one month before the meetings are held.63
2. What has to be stated in the board’s circulars is considerably
amplified as compared with the rules for a standard scheme,
but perhaps not as compared with the Takeover Code rules.64
3. In addition, generally65 separate written reports on the scheme
have to be provided to the members of each company by an
independent expert appointed by that company or, if the court
approves, a single joint report to all companies by an
independent expert appointed by all of them.66
However, the Directive, although widely framed, does not apply
to all forms of merger, and Pt 27 goes no wider. Hence, there is
some considerable scope for framing a merger scheme which
avoids the additional requirements. In particular, Pt 27 applies
only where the consideration for the transfer is or includes shares
in the transferee, so that a merger for a purely cash consideration
is excluded.67 Secondly, in the case of a merger “by absorption”
(see below), where the transferee company already holds all, or
in some cases 90 per cent, of the securities carrying voting rights
in the transferor, the requirements mentioned above are
substantially reduced.68 This facilitates mergers within corporate
groups and, in particular, a merger of parent and new subsidiary
following a successful takeover bid. Thirdly, Pt 27 does not
apply if the transferor company is being wound up,69 rather than
being dissolved without winding-up after the merger. Thus, the
requirements of Pt 27 can be avoided by incurring the expense of
putting the transferor into liquidation—probably not an attractive
course of action.
29–14
Finally, the merger must fall within one of two “Cases” specified
in the Directive. The two “Cases” are:
1. Where the undertaking, property and liabilities of the public
company are to be transferred to another public company,
other than one formed for the purpose of, or in connection
with, the scheme (“merger by absorption”).70
2. Where the undertakings, property and liabilities of each of two
or more public companies, including the one in respect of
which the arrangement is proposed, are to be transferred to a
new company, whether or not a public company, formed for
the purpose of, or in connection with, the scheme (“merger by
formation of new company”).71 Thus, a transfer to a new
company, public or private, by a single public company
escapes from both 1 and 2, and equally a reconstruction of a
single company can be carried out purely under Pt 26.72
3. There is a third Case, which applies to divisions. Where,
under the scheme, the undertaking, property and liabilities of
the public company are to be divided among, or transferred to,
two or more companies each of which is either a public
company or a company formed for the purposes of, or in
connection with, the scheme (“division by acquisition” or
“division by formation of new company”).73
29–15
Despite the discouraging history of the use of schemes to effect
true mergers, the CLR consulted on the issue of whether there
should be introduced into the Act a statutory merger procedure,
as in many other jurisdictions.74 For the CLR the crucial element
of a statutory merger procedure was that the merger should not
require approval by the court, though in appropriate cases those
adversely affected by the proposal should have a right of appeal
to the court. Its goal of providing a “court free” merger
procedure was thus in line with what it recommended in the case
of reductions of capital.75 However, it also took the view that,
where the Third Directive applied, it would be impractical to
implement a proposal except under the supervision of the court.76
The result of the restrictions in effect imposed by the Directives
was that the statutory merger procedure seemed to the CLR to be
feasible only in two cases. The first was the merger of wholly-
owned subsidiaries of a parent company. The CLR thought this a
useful reform, and it was supported on consultation, because
“many groups of companies include subsidiaries which are kept
alive for no good reason other than to avoid the expense and
problems associated with getting rid of them”.77 The second and
somewhat more general area for the operation of a statutory
merger procedure was where a company formed a new wholly-
owned subsidiary, into which the assets and liabilities of an
existing company were transferred, the transferor being
dissolved. On consultation a majority thought the new procedure
should be made available in this situation as well.78 However,
neither of these proposals was taken up in the Act.
CROSS-BORDER MERGERS
29–16
Despite the limited utilisation of the scheme of arrangement to
produce true mergers between domestic companies, the merger
procedure has begun to be used by UK companies involved in
cross-border mergers since the adoption by the EU of the Cross-
Border Mergers Directive.79 The objective is often to simplify
the structure of a multi-national corporate group, The Directive
is implemented in the UK by the Companies (Cross-Border
Merger) Regulations 2007.80 Thus, for cross-border mergers UK
law does now have a customised merger procedure, i.e. one not
tied to the scheme of arrangement. Given their EU origin, the
Directive and Regulations reflect the approach of the Third
Directive, but subject to the important extension that they cover
mergers involving private as well as public companies. They
provide a mechanism to effect both mergers by absorption and
mergers by formation of a new company. Within the absorption
category a distinction is made between standard absorptions and
absorption of a wholly-owned subsidiary.81
Even before the adoption of the Directive, the CJEU had held
that the blanket exclusion of a company incorporated in another
EU state from the domestic merger procedure of a Member State
was an infringement of a company’s freedom of establishment
under the Treaty.82 However, an effective cross-border merger
procedure requires the coordination of the laws of different
Member States, which is difficult to achieve via decisions of the
CJEU, but which EU legislation is uniquely well-placed to bring
about. The Regulations apply only to mergers involving both a
UK and a non-UK company incorporated in the EEA, so that
purely domestic mergers are excluded.83 Equally, the
Regulations are not available for cross-border mergers involving
a non-EEA company.84
29–17
Subject to the always thorny issue of employee representation on
the board of the resulting company (see below), the scheme of
the Directive and the Regulations is simple and relatively
elegant. Each company in the cross-border merger is subject to
its national merger procedure, on the basis of a common merger
plan, drawn up by the directors.85 That merger plan must be
accompanied by a report from the directors, setting out, amongst
other things, the rationale for the merger and its likely impact on
members, creditors and employees.86 As under the Third
Directive, a report by an independent expert is normally also
required.87 An expert is one who is eligible to be appointed as a
statutory auditor and is independent if he meets the statutory
tests for independence as an auditor.88 This report is concerned
principally with the exchange ratio proposed as between the
shares in the transferor company (or companies) and in the
transferee company involved in the merger.89 The consideration
for the merger will often be shares in the transferee company but
the UK regulations take up the option to make cash available as
consideration without restriction.90 In the case of merger by
absorption of a wholly owned subsidiary, the Regulations
anticipate that no consideration at all will be provided91 (since
consideration has no function in this situation). In the other types
of merger it has been held that, within a wholly-owned group
structure, the members of the transferor company can waive their
right to shares in the transferee, so that here, as well,
consideration is dispensed with.92
29–18
Publicity is to be given to these documents in various ways, for
the benefit of members, creditors and employees, but normally
in practice by their publication on the company’s website.93
Publicity is a necessary part of the process whereby consent is
sought from these groups for the merger proposal. As far as
members are concerned, in principle consent is required from
each of the UK companies involved in the merger. The approval
level, as under a scheme, is 75 per cent in value and a majority in
number of each class of members.94 Again, as under a scheme,
the court has power to order meetings of the members or classes
of them, and the same issues are likely to arise in relation to the
definition of classes as under schemes.95 Creditor approval does
not appear to be mandatory, but any creditor of a UK merging
company may apply to the court to summon a meeting of
creditors or classes of creditors, and the transferor company
itself will normally do so, if the rights of creditors are affected
(for example, because their claims will lie in future against a
foreign company).96 The level of creditor approval required at a
meeting is again 75 per cent in value and a majority in number.97
Employee consultation is considered below.
29–19
After the relevant procedure has been followed (including the
employee aspects—below), the UK court performs one of two
roles, depending on whether the transferee company is a UK
company or not. If it is not, the UK transferor company or
companies may apply to the court for a certificate (a “pre-merger
certificate”) that the UK procedure has been followed.98 The UK
company may use that certificate before the competent authority
in the jurisdiction where the transferee company is incorporated
in order to complete the merger in that jurisdiction. If the
transferee company is a UK company, the UK court may order
the completion of the cross-border merger on the basis of the
pre-merger certificates provided by the UK court and by the
competent authority of the jurisdictions in which the non-UK
merging companies are incorporated.99 The core function of the
court at this stage is to ensure that the merging companies have
all approved the same draft merger terms and that the employee
participation arrangements have been determined, where this is
necessary. However, it has been said that the court also has a
more general power to review the merger substantively to see
whether it will adversely affect any member, creditor or
employee in a material way and whether there is any other good
reason not to approve it.100 Upon approval and notification to the
registrar of companies, all the assets and liabilities of the
transferor companies go across to the transferee company,101 the
members of the transferor companies receiving securities
become members of the transferee company and the merging
companies cease to exist.102
Employee participation
29–20
The Directive and domestic Regulations become complicated
over the issue of whether the transferee company is required to
have in place a system of worker participation in relation to its
board. Participation includes not only the right to elect or
appoint members of the board but also rights to recommend or
oppose board members.103 No more than a sketch of the
provisions can be offered here, but in general the rules follow
those for the SE (European Company).104 However, there is one
very important difference from the scheme contained in the SE
Regulations: the default system of representation which applies
in the absence of agreement between company and employee
representatives may be capped by the transferee company at one
third of the seats for the employees, even if a more extensive
system applied to one of the constituent companies.105 There is
no such cap in the SE rules and so there may be some incentive
for cross-border mergers to take place via the Directive rather
than under the SE Regulation.
29–21
The following additional points can be made about the employee
participation rules, looking at the matter from the point of view
of a UK-incorporated transferee company:
(1) The general rule (though it has significant exceptions) is that
the transferee is subject to the participation rules applying in
its State of registration.106 On this basis a resulting company
registered in the UK would not be subject to participation
rules.
(2) However, participation is the default rule even in UK
transferee companies in three situations,107 of which the
most important is probably that where any merging
company in the six months prior to the publication of the
draft terms of the merger had an average number of
employees exceeding 500 and operated a system of
employee participation. The default rule covers any merging
company (not just a UK one) and any system of employee
participation, whether based on board level representation or
some other form of influence over the composition of the
board. In this way, a UK transferee company may
exceptionally become subject to mandatory employee
participation rules.
(3) Where participation rules apply to the UK transferee, the
merging companies (unanimously) may choose unilaterally
to apply to the transferee company the “standard rules” (set
out in the Regulations) on participation, i.e. without any
negotiation with the employee representatives and without
the loss of time such negotiation entails.108 In that case, the
employees of the transferee company obtain participation
rights in relation to that number of board members which is
equal to the highest proportion to be found in any of the
merging companies in which participation rights existed.
Thus, the strongest system applying in any of the merging
companies will apply to the transferee company, where
“strength” is measured by the number of board seats subject
to employee influence, not the form of that influence. The
right to oppose the appointment of three members trumps
the right to elect two.
(4) Alternatively, the merging companies may choose to
negotiate with representatives of the employees of the
merging companies with the aim of agreeing on some
alternative to the standard rules. This involves the creation
of a “Special Negotiating Body” (“SNB”) of employee
representatives to negotiate on behalf of the employees of all
the merging companies.109 The parties have six months
(extendable by agreement once to 12 months) to reach a
participation agreement, which agreement will then
determine the participation arrangements in the company.110
That agreement may increase or reduce the participation
rights of the employees.111 The SNB can even decide not to
negotiate participation arrangements, in which case the
employees of the transferee company are subject to the rules
on participation of the Member State in which that company
is incorporated.112 In the case of a UK transferee this would
mean no mandatory participation rights.
(5) If the parties either do not reach agreement within the
specified period or agree that the standard rules shall apply,
then the resulting company will be subject to those rules.113
In this case, however, the transferee company may impose
the cap mentioned above.
(6) The employee participation system applied by the Directive
to the first transferee company must be applied to a
subsequent domestic merger by that company for a period of
three years, so that the second transferee company cannot
escape the participation rules imposed on the first transferee
company.114 However, after three years it would appear to
be open to the first transferee company, in a jurisdiction
which does not require employee participation, to merge
with a domestic company under the domestic merger
procedure and thus escape from the Directive’s participation
requirements.
Further uses of cross-border mergers
29–22
In addition to the simplification of the structure of cross-border
groups, the Regulations could be used to effect an amalgamation
between two or more separately owned companies, in place of a
cross-border takeover bid. For the reasons given in relation to
schemes of arrangement,115 the cross-border merger is unlikely
to replace the cross-border hostile bid, especially as the directors
of the merging companies are even more strongly entrenched in
the case of cross-border merger than a scheme.116 However, the
cross-border merger could perform a role in relation to agreed
takeovers, where a competing offer is unlikely to emerge,
especially where the bidder is from a culture less committed to
the takeover form of amalgamation. On the other hand, the
takeover avoids the creation of novel employee participation
rights: the bidder and target remain subject to whatever, if
anything, their national laws provide in this regard.117
29–23
A rather different potential use of the cross-border merger is to
change a company’s jurisdiction of incorporation. The cross-
border merger Directive and Regulations appear to give the
merging companies a free choice as to the Member State
jurisdiction in which the transferee company is incorporated. If a
jurisdiction is desired which is not one in which any of the
merging companies is currently incorporated, then a new
transferee company can be incorporated in the desired
jurisdiction and the existing companies merged into it. However,
if the desired jurisdiction is a “real seat” state, then the Directive
appears to permit the authorities of that state not to register the
resulting entity, if the company’s “central administration” is not
also in that state.118 This is a significant obstacle to a merger
based solely on choice of law considerations.
Finally, it is worth noting that it is possible to produce a cross-
border merger through a “dual-listed structure”. In this
arrangement the companies remain formally independent (i.e.
they do not merge) nor does the one become a subsidiary of the
other, as in a takeover. Instead, by contract, including provisions
in their respective constitutions, the companies produce a unified
management (i.e. the same people sitting on the boards of
directors of the two companies or, normally, top companies of
the two groups of companies which are coming together). The
shareholder bodies remain separate but each body is given
voting rights in the meetings of the other, so as to produce a
single decision from the two votes; and the profits of the two
companies are equalised. Such structures are complex to create
(and to understand) but may have advantages over a merger, for
example, where national susceptibilities are involved. There are
not many such companies but a number of well-known
multinational companies take this form (Unilever, BHP Billiton,
Reed Elsevier) and others did so for a substantial period of time
before moving to a more conventional single company (or
group) structure (Shell, ABB).
REORGANISATION UNDER SECTIONS 110 AND 111 OF THE
INSOLVENCY ACT 1986
29–24
Under this type of reorganisation the company concerned
resolves first to go into voluntary liquidation119 and secondly to
authorise by a special resolution the liquidator to transfer the
whole or any part of the company’s business or property to
another company120 or a limited liability partnership (“LLP”) in
consideration of shares or like interests in that company (or
membership in the LLP) for distribution among the members of
the liquidating company. This procedure affords a relatively
simple method of reconstructing a single company or of
effecting a merger of its undertaking into that of another. It is
often used as a tax-efficient way of effecting a demerger or
division of a business.
Use of this method has the advantage, over a scheme, that
confirmation by the court is not required,121 and the advantage
over a takeover that all the shareholders of the company are
bound by the decision. But what it can achieve is somewhat
limited. Creditors of the transferor will be entitled to prove in its
liquidation and the liquidator must ensure that their proved
claims are met and cannot rely upon an indemnity given by the
acquiring company.122A high level of member agreement on the
use of the sections is also desirable. This is because s.111
provides that, in the case of a members’ voluntary winding-up,
any member of the company who did not vote in favour of the
special resolution may, within seven days of its passing, serve a
notice on the liquidator requiring the liquidator either to refrain
from carrying the resolution into effect or to purchase the
member’s shares at a price to be determined either by agreement
or by arbitration.123 It is normally essential if advantage is to be
taken of stamp duty concessions that the membership of the old
company and the new should be very largely the same. If a
number of the members elect to be bought out, there is a grave
risk that the reorganisation will have to be abandoned as
prohibitively expensive.
29–25
The CLR found the Insolvency Act procedure to be a popular
method for reconstructing private or family-controlled
companies or groups and also for reconstructing investment trust
companies.124 It therefore recommended its retention with,
however, the modernisation of the arbitration procedure which
operates when a member exercises the appraisal right and a
valuation of the member’s interest cannot be agreed. The
procedure under the current law is antiquated, invoking as it
does the arbitration provisions of the Companies Clauses
Consolidation Act 1845 or its Scottish equivalent,125 doubtfully
in compliance with the Human Rights Act and unclear about the
basis upon which the member’s interest should be valued. The
CLR proposed that the valuation should be based on the
dissentient’s proportionate share of the consideration offered by
the transferee for the transferor’s business.126 However, these
provisions being in the Insolvency Act 1986, they were not
touched by the Companies Act 2006.
CONCLUSION
29–26
We remarked at the beginning of this chapter that the Companies
Act does not contain a statutory merger procedure of the type
typically found in other jurisdictions. Whilst this statement is
true, somewhat oddly a true merger procedure is now provided
for cross-border mergers within the EU as a result of the Cross-
Border Merger Directive and implementing Regulations. For
purely domestic mergers, however, the scheme of arrangement is
available for this purpose, but that procedure is available also to
achieve a number of other objectives which have nothing to do
with mergers of two or more companies. Indeed, since the
scheme procedure, although available, is rarely used to achieve a
true merger, it would be odd to use the term statutory merger
procedure to refer to the scheme of arrangement. Just to confuse
things further, the alternative to the merger—the takeover bid—
can be, and increasingly is, affected by means of a scheme. The
scheme of arrangement is thus an immensely flexible instrument.
However, because it is as much an instrument of insolvency law
as of corporate law and because it elides what is regarded in
other jurisdictions as the fundamental difference between a
takeover bid and a merger, the scheme of arrangement has a
rather uncertain image. There can be almost as many types of
schemes of arrangement as there are inventive corporate and
insolvency lawyers, which indicates both the significance of the
scheme procedure and the impossibility of identifying such a
thing as a typical scheme of arrangement.
1
Delaware General Corporation Law s.251.
22006 Act s.900(1). The section also applies to the “reconstruction” of a company by
way of the transfer of its undertaking or property to another company.
3 2006 Act s.900(2)(a),(d).
4 That a de-merger is a valid scheme is clear, but the courts’ powers under s.900 apply
only to de-mergers which count as “reconstructions”. From this the courts have reasoned
that a reconstruction requires that the shareholding structure of the transferee company
must substantially reflect that of the transferor company (but liabilities may be left with
the transferor): Re South African Supply and Cold Storage Co [1904] 2 Ch. 268, 281–
282; Re MyTravel Group Plc [2005] 2 B.C.L.C. 123 (Mann J).
5 See para.29–12, below.
6
See para.29–24, below.
7 See para.29–12, below.
8This way of proceeding under what is now Pt 26 was sanctioned a century ago: Re
Guardian Assurance Co Ltd [1917] 1 Ch. 431, despite the fact that the element of
“arrangement” between the target company and its shareholders is vanishingly small,
consisting of no more than the company facilitating the transfer of their shares to the
bidder. See also Re Jelf Group Plc [2016] B.C.C. 289.
9
Popular in the past, because it avoided the payment of stamp duty on the transfer of the
shares from target shareholders to the “bidder”, was the “reduction” scheme, under
which the shareholders of the target agreed to the cancellation of their shares in the
target company; the reserve so created in the target was used by the target to pay up new
shares which were issued to the offeror; and the shareholders of the target received in
exchange for their cancelled shares cash or shares in the offeror company. The
company’s role in a reduction scheme is thus more significant. However, the Treasury
removed the stamp duty advantage in 2015 by prohibiting the first step (cancellation of
the shares) when this is part of scheme to allow the bidder to obtain all the shares in the
target company. However, the reduction scheme is still available for the equivalent of
share exchange bid. See the Companies Act 2006 (Amendment of Part 17) Regulations
2015/472, inserting new s.641(2A) and (2B).
10Above, at para.28–14. On the complications which can arise when competing bids are
put through the scheme mechanism see Re Allied Domecq Plc [2000] 1 B.C.L.C. 134;
and Re Expro International Group Plc [2010] 2 B.C.L.C. 514. For this reason acquirers
proceeding by way of a scheme often reserve the right to revert to a contractual offer if a
competing bidder emerges.
11
2006 Act s.899(1).
12
See above at paras 28–69 et seq.
13 Re National Bank [1966] 1 W.L.R. 819; Re BTR Plc [2000] 1 B.C.L.C. 740 CA.
14 See above, at para.28–67.
15
See para.28–35 at fn.128—though those accepting may contract for this right.
16
See para.6–18.
17In this case the problems mentioned in fn.4, relating to the use of courts’ ancillary
powers, are unlikely to arise.
18
Re National Bank Ltd [1966] 1 W.L.R. 819 at 829; Re Calgary and Edmonton Land
Co [1975] 1 W.L.R. 355 at 363; Re Savoy Hotel Ltd [1981] Ch. 351 at 359D–F; Re T&N
Ltd (No.3) [2007] 1 B.C.L.C. 563 at [46]–[50].
19 Re NFU Development Trust Ltd [1972] 1 W.L.R. 1548: held that the court had no
jurisdiction to sanction a scheme whereby all the members were required to relinquish
their financial rights without any quid pro quo. However, the decision in Re MyTravel
Group Plc [2005] 2 B.C.L.C. 123, makes it less easy for companies to use the scheme to
effect a debt-for-equity swap. The lack of congruence between the transferor and
transferee companies’ shareholding structures was brought about in that case by the fact
that, under the scheme, the existing shareholders were to be heavily diluted and most of
the shares in the transferee were to be held by the former creditors of the transferor.
However, the scheme did in fact proceed in that case but without the exercise of the
court’s ancillary powers (see the decision of the CA in that case). It is unclear why the
ancillary powers are not made available for all schemes which get through the statutory
procedure.
20 See the debt-for-equity swap discussed in the previous note.
21 For a modern example see Re T&N Ltd (No.3) [2007] 1 B.C.L.C. 563.
22Re Drax Holdings Ltd [2004] 1 B.C.L.C. 10, where Lawrence Collins J (as he then
was) said obiter at [29]: “It is almost impossible to envisage circumstances in which the
English court could properly exercise jurisdiction in relation to a scheme of arrangement
between a foreign company and its members, which would essentially be a matter for the
courts of the place of incorporation”.
23
2006 Act s.895(1).
24
2006 Act ss.896–899(1).
25
2006 Act s.896.
26The possibility of shareholder proposal was recognised in Re Savoy Hotel Ltd [1981]
Ch. 351.
27
See previous note.
28
See para.15–4 at fn.9.
29
See para.28–58.
30 The required level of approval of a scheme. See below.
31 2006 Act s.896(2) contemplates applications under step (b) by a creditor or member
as well as by the company or its liquidator or administrator.
32
THF would not be able to get around this problem by seeking to convene a general
meeting to propose the scheme, because at a general meeting both A and B shareholders
would vote together and the reasons given in the text why a bid would fail would apply
also to a shareholder resolution to adopt a scheme.
33 2006 Act s.896(1). Sensibly, the courts will recognise that a meeting can occur even if
the company has only one shareholder, for otherwise schemes would be less freely
available within groups (Re RMCA Reinsurance Ltd [1994] B.C.C. 378), but no meeting
can be said to have occurred when in a multi-member class only one member in fact
attends: Re Altitude Scaffolding Ltd [2006] B.C.C. 904.
34 Sovereign Life Assurance Co v Dodd [1892] 2 Q.B. 573 at 583, per Bowen LJ.
35
Re Equitable Life Assurance Society [2002] 2 B.C.L.C. 510.
36Re BTR Plc [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 675. The decision and reasoning were upheld on
appeal: [2000] 1 B.C.L.C. 740 CA. See also Re Industrial Equity (Pacific) Ltd [1991] 2
H.K.L.R. 614.
37 Re Hellenic and General Trust [1976] 1 W.L.R. 123. On the view of this case adopted
in BTR it was not fatal to the scheme that the subsidiary’s shares were voted at the class
meeting, but they were to be discounted at the third stage when deciding whether to
approve the scheme.
38 Re Hawk Insurance Co Ltd [2001] 2 B.C.L.C. 480. He thought it particularly
unfortunate that the court should feel obliged to raise the issue of its own motion at stage
(c), even though no member or creditor sought to argue that class meetings should have
been held.
39
Practice Direction [2002] 1 W.L.R. 1345. For an account of modern practice, see Re
T&N Ltd (No.3) [2007] 1 B.C.L.C. 563 at [18]–[20].
40The court does already decide at stage (b) issues relating to the jurisdiction of the
court to sanction a scheme at stage (c), though not issues going to the fairness of the
scheme: Re Savoy Hotel [1981] Ch. 351; Re Telewest Communications Plc (No.1)
[2005] 1 B.C.L.C. 752 at [14]–[15]; Re My Travel Group Plc [2005] 2 B.C.L.C. 123.
41
Final Report I, paras 13.6–13.7. This would not otherwise affect the tasks to be
performed by the court at the sanctioning stage, on which see below.
42
2006 Act s.897(1),(2).
43
2006 Act s.897(3). If the interests of the directors or the trustees change before the
meetings are held, the court will not sanction the scheme unless satisfied that no
reasonable shareholder or debenture-holder would have altered his decision on how to
vote if the changed position had been disclosed: Re Jessel Trust Ltd [1985] B.C.L.C.
119; Re Minster Assets [1985] B.C.L.C. 200.
44
Which will be the only way of notifying holders of bearer bonds. It may also be
necessary to advertise in this way to creditors.
45
2006 Act s.897(1)(b),(4). A default in complying with any requirement of the section
renders the company and every officer, liquidator, administrator, or trustee for
debenture-holders liable to a fine unless he shows that the default was due to the refusal
of another director or trustee for debenture-holders to supply the necessary particulars of
his interest: s.897(5)–(8). In that case the criminal offence is committed by that director
or trustee: s.898.
46
The CLR recommended the removal of the number requirement, which does indeed
appear anomalous in the context of the Companies Act approach to shareholder
approval: Final Report I, para.13.10. However, the “number” requirement does
constitute an additional element of minority protection where 75 per cent of the shares
are concentrated in one or a few persons.
47 In relation to creditors further difficulties may arise in valuing their claims and thus
determining whether the majority does represent three-fourths in value. This is a
problem met whenever this formula is employed in respect of creditors—as it is
throughout the Insolvency Act.
48
2006 Act s.899(1).
49
Re MyTravel Group Plc [2005] 2 B.C.L.C. 123 CA; Re Bluebrook Ltd [2010] 1
B.C.L.C. 338.
50In Re Dorman Long & Co [1934] Ch. 635, 655 and 657. See also Re National Bank
Ltd [1966] 1 W.L.R. 819, 829.
51Re BTR Plc [2000] 1 B.C.L.C. 740 at 747. For an extreme case, see Re PCCW Ltd
[2009] 3 HKC 292 Hong Kong Court of Final Appeal.
52Above, at para.19–7. At this point the first and second parts of the test began to
overlap.
53per Lindley LJ in Re English, Scottish, and Australian Chartered Bank [1893] 3 Ch.
385. See also Re Alabama, New Orleans, Texas and Pacific Junction Railway Co [1891]
1 Ch. 213, per Fry LJ; Re Telewest Communications Plc (No.2) [2005] 1 B.C.L.C. 772;
Re Apcoa Parking Holdings GmbH [2014] EWHC 3849 (Ch). These were all creditors’
cases but the same principle applies to members’ schemes.
54 2006 Act s.899.
55 The courts have rejected arguments that a scheme which satisfies the requirements of
the Act might nevertheless amount to deprivation of possessions contrary to art.1 of the
First Protocol of the European Convention on Human Rights: Re Equitable Life
Assurance Society [2002] 2 B.C.L.C. 510; Re Waste Recycling Group Plc [2004] 1
B.C.L.C. 352.
56
British and Commonwealth Holdings Plc v Barclays Bank Plc [1996] 1 W.L.R. 1 CA;
Re Uniq Ltd [2012] 1 B.C.L.C. 783—though it is unlikely that the judges will give
wholesale exemptions from the financial assistance rules just because the assistance is
embodied in a scheme.
57
Nokes v Doncaster Amalgamated Collieries [1940] A.C. 1014 HL; Re TSB Nuclear
Energy Investment UK Ltd [2014] B.C.C. 531—though the Transfer of Undertakings
(Protection of Employment) Regulations 2006/246 largely solve the employment issue.
58
See fn.4, above.
59
Directive 78/855/EEC (now Directive 2011/35/EU ([2011] O.J. L110/1)). The
requirements of this Directive were somewhat reduced by two subsequent amending
directives: Directives 2007/63/EC and 2009/109/EC, both of which have been
implemented in the UK. Directive 82/891/EEC (the “Sixth” Directive) deals with the
division of public limited companies.
60
The details differ somewhat according to the “Case” (see below) within which the
scheme falls, the main differences being between those within Case 1 or 2 (mergers) and
Case 3 (divisions).
61
See para.28–14.
62 This includes the transferee company, whose consent is not required under a scheme
governed purely by Pt 26, unless the rights of the shareholders or creditors of the
transferee are proposed to be changed. However, it is enough that the members of the
transferee are given the option to call a meeting (on the basis of a five per cent threshold:
ss.918 and 932) so that the burden of action falls on the shareholders rather than the
company in such a case. Of course, if the transferee is a UK listed company, the large
transaction provisions of the Listing Rules might require it to obtain shareholder
approval. See para.14–20.
63
2006 Act ss.905–6A, 920–921A.
64
2006 Act ss.908, 910, 923, 925.
65 As a result of amendments to the Directives introduced by Directive 2007/63/EC the
requirement for an independent report can be dispensed with if all the shareholders
agree. See s.918A.
66 2006 Act ss.909, 924 and 935–937. The matters to be dealt with in the report are
specified in some detail. In some respects it resembles the report required (also as a
result of an EU Directive) when a public company makes an issue of shares paid-up
otherwise than in cash: see paras 11–16 et seq., above.
67 2006 Act s.902(1)(c).
68
2006 Act ss.915 and 915A. In these cases, as well, the requirement for a meeting of
members is relaxed: ss.916–917 and 931.
69 2006 Act s.902(3).
70 2006 Act ss.904(1)(a) and 902(2)(b).
71
2006 Act ss.904(1)(b) and 902(2)(a).
72 See the scheme proposed in Re MyTravel Group Plc [2005] 2 B.C.L.C. 123.
732006 Act ss.919 and 902(2). The Sixth Directive applies to divisions. See fn.59,
above.
74
Completing, paras 11.40–11.53.
75
See paras 13–39 et seq.
76
Completing, para.11.46.
77
Completing, para.11.50. A potential use for the SE (above, para.1–40) is to achieve a
similar result within multinational groups.
78
Final Report I, paras 13.14–13.15.
79
Directive 2005/56/EC on cross-border mergers of limited liability companies ([2005]
O.J. L310/10).
80
SI 2007/2974, as amended, a self-standing set of regulations made under the European
Communities Act 1972 and constituting a major piece of corporate law which is not
located in the 2006 Act at all.
81 SI 2007/2974 reg.2.
82TFEU art.49. See Case C-411/03 SEVIC [2005] E.C.R. I-10805, concerning German
merger procedure.
83 SI 2007/2974 reg.2. In the case of merger by formation of a new company the
diversity requirement is applied to the transferor companies (reg.2(4)(a)).
84 See art.1 of the Directive.
85
SI 2007/2974 reg.7. It thus appears that the merger cannot proceed unless the
directors of all the companies involved approve the idea.
86 SI 2007/2974 reg.8.
87
SI 2007/2974 reg.9. An expert’s report is not required where the merger is between a
wholly-owned subsidiary and its parent and where the transferee holds 90 per cent of the
securities of the transferor carrying voting rights and an exit right on fair terms is
afforded to the minority: regs 9 and 9A.
88
Reg.9(7)–(8), invoking ss.1212 and 1214 of the Act, on which see para.22–12.
89
The transferor company or companies will have their assets and liabilities transferred
if the merger goes through and the transferee company is the company which will
receive those assets and may be an existing company or one formed for the purposes of
the merger.
90
SI 2007/2974 reg.2.
91 SI 2007/2974 reg.2(3).
92 Re Olympus UK Ltd [2014] EWHC 1350 (Ch)—an interesting example of the
interpretation of the English version of the Directive so as to maximize its harmonising
effect, despite an ill-advised use of words in that version.
93 SI 2007/2974 regs 10, 12–12A.
94 SI 2007/2974 reg.13. Transferor member approval is not required in the case of
merger by absorption of a wholly owned subsidiary and, where the transferee company
is an existing company, approval of its members is required only if the holders of 5 per
cent or more of the voting rights call a meeting to consider the merger.
95 SI 2007/2974 reg.11, and see para.29–8, above.
96
SI 2007/2974 reg.11. The transferor company may pay off or secure the creditors’
claims in advance of the merger.
97
SI 2007/2974 reg.13.
98
SI 2007/2974 reg.6. The court’s role here is presumably similar to that under a
scheme.
99
SI 2007/2974 reg.16. The court may order completion even where the merger
agreement is conditional, provided the court has a high degree of confidence that the
conditions will be met, that the conditions are aimed at facilitating the merger which the
shareholders approved and that they do not amount to giving a party other than the court
a discretion whether the merger goes ahead: Re International Game Technology Plc
[2015] 2 B.C.L.C. 45; Nielsen Holdings Plc [2015] EWHC 2966 (Ch); Re Livanona Plc
and Sorin SpA [2015] B.C.C. 914. This reflects practice under domestic schemes
(Lombard Medical Technologies Plc [2015] 1 B.C.L.C. 656).
100
Re Diamond Resorts (Europe) Ltd [2013] B.C.C. 275. The judge also held that the
rigor of that enquiry would also depend on the extent of the investigations undertaken by
the competent authority (which may not be a court) in the other EEA jurisdictions
involved.
101Including the rights and obligations of the merging companies under contracts of
employment: reg.17(1). It seems likely that reg.17 will be interpreted as transferring all
contractual rights and liabilities, no matter whether they are transferable under general
law. See fn.57, above.
102
SI 2007/2974 reg.17, widely construed in Re Lanber Properties LLP and Lanber II
GmbH [2014] EWHC 4713.
103 SI 2007/2974 reg.3(1).
104 See para.14–67.
105SI 2007/2974 reg.39. This follows art.16(4)(c) of the Directive, which permits, but
does not require, Member States to adopt a cap and confines that cap to one-tier boards.
106
Directive art.16(1) and reg.22.
107 Directive art.16(2) and reg.22.
108
Directive art.16(3)(h), (4)(a) and regs 36 and 38. However, the one third cap can be
imposed only if there have been negotiations with the employee representatives.
Completion of the employee participation arrangements is a condition for the
registration of the resulting company: reg.39.
109 Regulations Ch.2 of Pt 4.
110 SI 2007/2974 regs 28 and 29.
111 But if at least one-quarter of the employees of the merging companies had
participation rights, any decision by the SNB on an agreement which reduces
participation rights below the highest proportion previously operating requires a two-
thirds majority of the members of the SNB: reg.30.
112 SI 2007/2974 reg.31. This requires not only a two-thirds vote of the SNB, but also
that those voting in favour should represent two-thirds of the employees of the merging
companies.
113 SI 2007/2974 reg.36. However, failure to agree will trigger the standard rules where
fewer than one-third of the employees of merging companies were subject to
participation only where the SNB has positively opted (by a majority of its members) for
them. Thus, a majority of representatives, perhaps from countries not having a
participation system, could block its imposition on the resulting company, perhaps in
exchange for some different type of concession from the companies.
114
SI 2007/2974 reg.40.
115
Above, para.29–3.
116
Above, fn.85. Re International Game Technology Plc [2015] 2 B.C.L.C. 45
concerned a genuine cross-border merger, not just an intra-group restructuring.
117
This is in fact highly unsatisfactory in one respect. Where a German company,
subject to co-determination, takes over a British company, the British workers will have
no right to participate in board level representation arrangements of the German parent,
even though the strategy of both companies is probably determined at that level, unless,
as sometimes happens, voluntary arrangements are made to accommodate the interests
of the non-German workers.
118
Directive art.4(1)(b). For discussion of this issue, and a number of other pertinent
observations on the Directive, see J. Rickford, “The Proposed Tenth Company Law
Directive on Cross Border Mergers and its Impact in the UK” [2005] E.B.L.R. 1393.
119 Under former versions of these provisions it had to be a members’ voluntary
liquidation, i.e. one in which the directors have made a “declaration of solvency”
declaring that all the company’s debts will be paid in full within 12 months. It can now
be employed also in a creditors’ voluntary liquidation so long as it is sanctioned by the
court or the liquidation committee (Insolvency Act s.110(3)) but that sanction is unlikely
to be given unless all creditors are paid in full.
120 Whether or not the latter is a company within the meaning of the Companies Act
(Insolvency Act s.110(1)) so that it could be a company registered in another
jurisdiction.
121Though the court’s sanction may be needed if the company is to be wound up in a
creditors’ winding-up.
122 Pulsford v Devenish [1903] 2 Ch. 625. But the sale of the undertaking will be
binding on the creditors who will not be able to follow the assets transferred to the
transferee company: Re City & County Investment Co (1879) 13 Ch. D. 475 CA.
123 This is an example, rare under UK law (but more widely used in some other common
law jurisdictions) of protecting dissenting members by granting them “appraisal rights”.
The courts will not permit the company to deprive members of their appraisal rights
under the section by purporting to act under powers in its articles to sell its undertaking
in exchange for securities of another company to be distributed in specie: Bisgood v
Henderson’s Transvaal Estates [1908] 1 Ch. 743 CA.
124 Completing, para.11.13.
125 Clauses Consolidation Act 1845 s.111(4).
126 Final Report I, para.13.13.
CHAPTER 30
MARKET ABUSE
Introduction 30–1
Approaches to Regulating Insider Dealing 30–5
Disclosure 30–5
Prohibiting trading 30–6
Relying on the general law 30–7
Prohibiting insider dealing 30–11
The Criminal Justice Act 1993 Part V 30–12
Regulating markets 30–13
Regulating individuals 30–15
Inside information 30–16
Insiders 30–22
Mental element 30–24
Prohibited acts 30–25
Defences 30–26
Criminal Prohibitions on Market Manipulation 30–29
Regulatory Control of Market Abuse 30–30
Background 30–30
Insider dealing 30–31
Market manipulation 30–39
Safe harbours 30–43
Enforcement and Sanctions 30–47
Investigation into market abuse 30–48
Sanctions for market abuse 30–51
Sanctions for breach of the criminal law 30–54
Conclusion 30–57
INTRODUCTION
30–1
With these topics we reach the margins of company law. Market
abuse can occur in all markets and the relevant rules apply
equally widely. We are concerned in this book, however, only
with abuse in the markets for company securities (shares and
bonds) and their derivatives. Our analysis will accordingly be so
confined.
Market abuse is conventionally regarded, at least within the
EU, as covering two rather different activities: insider dealing
and market manipulation. Insider dealing (or trading)1 occurs
when a person in possession of price-sensitive information about
a company buys or sells securities in that company and so
obtains better terms in the transaction than would have been the
case had the counterparty been aware of the information in
question. In that way, the insider can either make a profit or
avoid a loss, depending on whether the information, once public,
will drive the price of the security up or down.2 The issue is at
the margins of company law because the insider dealer does not
have to be an insider of the company, for example a director,
though he or she very often is. A governmental official may
know that the agency for which he or she works is about to issue
an adverse report on a particular company which will affect the
price of its shares and then trade in the company’s shares before
the report is published.
Market manipulation involves conduct which moves the price
of the securities to a position which is different from that which
the market would have set in the absence of the conduct.
Penalising such behaviour thus involves drawing a distinction
between legitimate and illegitimate behaviour within markets. If
a company announces a bid for another company at a price
above the prevailing market price for the shares, that
announcement will move the price in an upward direction, but
such behaviour is not only regarded as legitimate, it may also be
required by takeover rules (as we saw in Ch.28). On the other
hand, if I move the market price by making statements which I
know to be false, that will be regarded as illegitimate behaviour.
In a very early example of market manipulation, from the
beginning of the nineteenth century, the fraudsters pretended to
be soldiers returning from France with news of the defeat of
Napoleon (before this event actually came to pass some time
later). The false rumours which they spread caused the price of
British government bonds to rise, thus enabling the accused to
dispose of their holdings of those bonds at a profit.3 However, as
we shall see below, distinguishing legitimate from illegitimate
behaviour in more marginal cases is not easy.
In the case of manipulation it is clear that market participants
may suffer loss as a result of the behaviour. They will have
acquired or disposed of shares on the basis of an artificial price
and may suffer loss when the truth emerges.4 Equally, the
allocative efficiency of the market may suffer. Investors use
market prices to determine how to target their resources and so
manipulated prices may produce a misallocation of those
resources. In the case of insider dealing the harm to the market
and its participants is less clear. The insider dealing may not
move the share price very much, if at all, and, in so far is it does,
it moves the price towards, not away from, its “true” value (i.e.
towards the value it will have when the full information is
eventually publicly disclosed). Since insider dealing can be
avoided by not trading and in public markets many of the other
market participants would have traded, whether or not the insider
traded, the harm to them is difficult to identify.5 It is easier to see
the harm if there are rules, as is now the case, requiring inside
information to be disclosed.6 If the information had been in the
market, the prices would have been different and this can be
used as a starting point for calculating loss.7 On this basis, the
harm-causing event is not the insider dealing as such but the
non-disclosure of the inside information, but non-disclosure is an
inherent part of the insider dealer’s strategy.8
30–2
In insider dealing rules a crucial task is distinguishing between
information which the insider cannot use privately and
information which can be used privately. This is not an easy
task. It cannot be said, though it often is, that the aim of the
insider dealing rules is to put all market participants in
possession of the same information, because then there would be
no incentive for analysts (and others) to seek out information
about companies which is not known to the market in general.
Analysts fulfil an important function in keeping the market
informationally efficient because they provide information to the
market after, or often as, they trade on the information for their
profit.9 If they had to disclose the information before trading,
their incentive to acquire it in the first place would disappear. As
with market manipulation, it can be argued that the key objective
is to distinguish legitimate from illegitimate means of acquiring
information which is not generally known to the market. Only
information acquired by illegitimate means should count as
“inside” information. So, for example, an analyst who carefully
pieces together public but not easily accessible information to
arrive at new facts about the company should not be classified as
a holder of inside information. On the other hand, a director,
who routinely acquires information about the company before
the market does because of his or her position in the company,
has no socially valuable claim to be allowed to trade on the basis
of that information.
30–3
The above arguments provide reasons why securities market
authorities would wish to control market abuse. But they do not
tie the regulation very closely to the objectives of corporate law.
It is possible to make this connection by focusing on the interests
of the company (the issuer) in having effective regulation in
place. If insider dealing is rife in the market, the non-insider will
know that the market prices will systematically fail to reflect all
the available information about the company and will do so in a
way which is unfavourable to the outsiders. In the absence of
regulation, this will be an inherent risk of holding shares in
companies and outsiders will build this risk into their investment
decisions, by lowering the price they are prepared to pay for
companies’ shares. This in turn will increase companies’ cost of
capital because they will be able to issues shares on less
favourable terms than if investors could be assured that there
was no or little insider trading in the market. Thus, companies
have an interest in effective insider dealing legislation or
regulation.10
The same general argument can be made in relation to market
manipulation.11 If extensive, such behaviour may systematically
produce prices which are unfavourable to outsiders, thus again
causing them to re-assess the riskiness of corporate securities as
a class.
30–4
The law on market abuse has developed rapidly over the past 40
years. The first sanctions against insider dealing were criminal
and were introduced by the Companies Act 1980. Those
sanctions are now in Pt V of the Criminal Justice Act 1993.
Market manipulation was criminalised (beyond the common
law) a little later in the Financial Services Act 1986. The present
provisions are in Pt 7 of the Financial Services Act 2012. The
Financial Services and Markets Act 2000 added administrative
sanctions against market abuse (of both types) and widened the
definitions of the behaviour which was open to sanction.
Enforcement of both the administrative penalties and the
criminal law lies in the hands of the Financial Conduct Authority
(“FCA”), previously the Financial Services Authority (“FSA”).
Market manipulation is an area where EU law has played an
important role. Initially, the EU operated via Directives which
required transposition into domestic law by the domestic
legislator. After the financial crisis, in the name of greater
uniformity, the EU adopted a Market Abuse Regulation
(“MAR”),12 most of whose provisions do not require
transposition.13 However, in the case of the UK, the EU rules
tended to lag behind the reforms made at domestic level, so that
their impact on the rules applicable to the UK markets was also
limited. Even the extensions contained in the new Regulation
relate primarily to markets other than the markets in corporate
securities. Consequently, for the matters considered in this
chapter, the impact of the Regulation has been more on the
structure of the law and less on its substantive content. Its impact
on the structure or sources of the law is profound. EU rules, in
the shape of the Regulation and “secondary legislation” made by
the Commission under the Regulation, become the important
first-line sources of law in relation to market abuse in securities
markets and domestic sources, whereas rules made by
Parliament or the FCA, become less important than in the past.
This is the position in relation to administrative sanctions
against market abuse. In relation to criminal law, the position is
different. There is a new Market Abuse Directive on criminal
sanctions,14 but this is a Directive out of which the UK may opt
and it has chosen to do so. In the criminal law, therefore, the
domestic rules remain in the front line.
We analyse first the rules on insider dealing and then those on
market manipulation.
APPROACHES TO REGULATING INSIDER DEALING
Disclosure
30–5
A number of approaches to the regulation of insider dealing are
to be found in the current law. Mandatory disclosure has long
been used, but disclosure may be used to control insider dealing
in a number of different ways. For example, as we saw in Ch.26,
directors, as potential insider dealers, may be required to
disclose dealings in their company’s securities on the theory that,
if they know that their dealings will be public knowledge, they
will be less likely to trade on the basis of inside information.15
Indeed, this is the oldest anti-insider dealing technique, having
been introduced upon the recommendation of the Cohen
Committee of 1945.16
Alternatively, or in addition, the disclosure rules may aim at
those who have the inside information and require them to
disclose it, whether or not they are likely to trade on the basis of
it. The point here is that putting the information into the public
domain reduces the opportunities of others to engage in insider
dealing. This, too, we have discussed above in the shape of the
obligation laid upon issuers to disclose inside information
promptly to the market.17 Even the obligation to disclose the
beneficial ownership of shares at the 3 per cent level and above18
may constitute a disclosure obligation of this type, for it shows
who is accumulating a stake in a company, perhaps preparatory
to a bid.19
Prohibiting trading
30–6
At the other end of the spectrum, the law could ban trading by
potential insiders, irrespective of whether they are in possession
of inside information or not. This is a blunt instrument, since it
deprives those without inside information of trading
opportunities. However, this approach is used in a targeted way
in relation to particular “high risk” groups. The clearest example
of this strategy was the requirement of the Model Code that
directors, subject to exceptions, should not deal in securities of
the company within a period of two months preceding the
preliminary announcement of the company’s annual results and
similar limitations were imposed in relation to the announcement
of the half-yearly and quarterly20 reports. In addition, clearance
to deal at any time had to be obtained in advance from the
chairman of the board, the CEO or the company secretary, as
appropriate.21 Compliance with the Code was not required by
legislation but was one of the continuing obligations imposed
upon companies with a premium listing by the Listing Rules.22
Such companies were required to ensure that those discharging
managerial responsibilities complied with the Code or such
stronger requirements as the company might impose. Thus, the
Code was not directly binding on directors but was a model
which premium listed companies were required to adopt with
such refinements as were thought desirable. In practice it was
normally adopted virtually verbatim. The company was required
to take “all proper and reasonable” steps to secure compliance
with the Code by those discharging managerial responsibilities
within it.23
The notion of a prohibition on trading during a closed period
preceding the company’s required regular reports was taken up
in MAR, though with a lesser closed period of 30 days.24 The
prohibition now applies to all companies traded on the Main
Market, whether with a premium listing or not, and companies
traded on AIM. MAR covers “persons discharging managerial
responsibilities” as well as directors (but not “closely associated”
persons25); extends to trading on the account of a third party as
well as to own account trading; and brings in trading in
derivatives and other financial instruments as well as directly in
the company’s securities. As under the Model Code, the issuer
may allow trading in this period in “exceptional circumstances,
such as severe financial difficulty”, as further elaborated in
Commission delegated acts.26 Since the MAR provisions overlap
with the Model Code, the FCA proposes to remove it from the
Listing Rules.27 However, this leaves two areas where the Model
Code applied more widely than MAR. First, it applied to
preliminary announcements of annual results, which are not
required, and so fall outside MAR, but are market practice in the
UK and are in effect the market moving event rather than the
later full publication. Secondly, MAR has no equivalent to the
clearance rules which applied whenever a director proposes to
deal (not just during the closed period). On the second issue the
FCA proposed to provide guidance for issuers in place of the
present obligation to have clearance rules.28 Its policy on the first
issue is unclear: it may take the view that the provisions of MAR
cannot be added to.29
Relying on the general law
30–7
A third approach is to not to legislate specifically for insider
dealing but to rely instead on established doctrines of the
common law to deal with it. Company law offers its fiduciary
duties for this purpose, and more general doctrines of the
common law may also have a role. For one reason or another,
however, these doctrines fail to capture the problem of insider
dealing comprehensively. Yet they need to be borne in mind
because they offer civil remedies under the control of private
parties, whereas, as we shall see, the specific insider dealing
rules rely wholly on criminal or regulatory sanctions which are,
in effect, under the control of the FCA.
Directors’ fiduciary duties
30–8
As pointed out in Ch.16,30 if directors make use of information
acquired as director for their personal advantage they may
breach their fiduciary duties to the company and be liable to
account to it for any profits they have made. A great advantage
of the civil suit brought by the company for breach of fiduciary
duty is that it does not have to show that it has suffered loss as a
result of the insider dealing, simply that the insider fiduciaries
have made a profit in breach of the rules on conflicts of
interest.31 In practice, however, it is unlikely that the company
will call them to account unless and until there is a change of
control. If only one director has committed the breach, the others
may cause the company to take action against him but most
public companies are likely to avoid damaging publicity by
persuading the errant director to resign “for personal reasons”
and to go quietly.
It is also possible that, for example, in relation to a takeover of
a small company,32 the directors may place themselves in the
position of acting as agents negotiating on behalf of the
individual shareholders and thereby, despite Percival v Wright,33
owe fiduciary duties to the shareholders. If so, they would
breach those duties if they persuaded any shareholder to sell at a
price which they knew (and the shareholders did not) was
materially lower than their likely value on the basis of full
disclosure of the information the directors hold about the
company. It is, however, highly unlikely that the directors of a
listed company would create such a relationship. If they did
engage in insider dealing, it would be by dealing impersonally
on a stock exchange so that no fiduciary relationship was
created.
Hence, the general equitable principle is, on its own, rarely an
effective deterrent. Moreover, the law relating to directors’
fiduciary duties is simply incapable of applying to the full range
of insiders and, except in the rare case where the decision in
Percival v Wright can be overcome, it has the demerit of
concentrating on the relationship between the director and the
company rather than on the relationship between the director and
other traders in the market.
Breach of confidence
30–9
Somewhat similar criticisms can be made of the second source
of equitable obligation which is relevant here, namely that
imposed by the receipt of information from another person
where the recipient knows or ought to have known that the
information was imparted in confidence. However, the range of
persons potentially covered by this obligation is much wider that
those covered by the fiduciary duties applying to directors of
companies. It will extend to the professional advisers of
companies who, say, are involved in preparing a takeover bid
which the company is contemplating, and to the employees of
such advisers, since no contractual link between the confider and
the confidant is necessary to support this fiduciary obligation.
Indeed, the obligation extends to anyone who receives
information knowing that they are receiving it in breach of a
duty of confidentiality imposed upon the person communicating
the information.34
If the duty attaches, the holder of the information may not use
it (for example, by trading in securities) or disclose it (for
example, to another person so that that person may trade)35
without the permission of the confider. Breach of the duty gives
rise to a liability to account for the profits made, potentially the
most useful civil sanction in the case of insider dealing on
securities markets. The confidant may have to pay damages to
the confider but it is far from clear that the confider actually
suffers any loss if the confidant uses the information for the
purposes of insider dealing and does not, in so doing,
communicate the information to other persons. However, the
cause of action again lies in the hands of the person to whom the
fiduciary obligation is owed (i.e. the confider), not in the hands
of the person with whom the confidant has dealt in the securities
transaction or other participants in the market at the time. This
might not matter if in fact the duty of confidence was routinely
used to deprive insiders of their profits,36 but, although much
inside information must also be received in confidence and
although the law in this area has achieved much greater
prominence in recent years than it had previously, there are no
reported cases of its use against insider dealers. This may be
because the difficulties of detection and proof, which abound in
this area, operate so as to deprive confiders of the incentive to
use their private law rights to secure the transfer of insider
dealing profits from the insiders to themselves.
Misrepresentation
30–10
When in 1989 the Government was considering its response to
the EU’s first Directive on insider dealing, it decided to continue
its policy of not providing civil sanctions under the insider
dealing legislation partly on the grounds that these worked
satisfactorily only in face-to-face transactions and that the
general law already provided remedies in that situation.37 Apart
from the insider’s liability to the company, discussed above, the
Government referred to liability for fraudulent
misrepresentation. Misrepresentation-based liability, however,
whether for fraudulent, negligent or innocent misrepresentation,
faces a formidable obstacle in relation to insider trading. This is
the need to demonstrate either that a false statement has been
made or that there was a duty to disclose the inside information
to the other party to the transaction. As to the former, the insider
can avoid liability by not making any statements to the other
party relating to the area of knowledge in which he holds the
inside information. Liability might arise if the other party to the
transaction has the good luck or the right instinct to extract a
false statement from the insider by probing questions, but
liability on this basis is unlikely to be widespread.
As to non-disclosure, the current legislation does not adopt the
technique contained in some earlier proposals for insider dealing
legislation: requiring insiders in face-to-face transactions to
disclose the information before dealing.38 Consequently, the
potential plaintiff has to fall back on the common law, which
imposes a duty of disclosure in only limited circumstances. The
most relevant situation would be where the insider was in a
fiduciary or other special relationship with the other party, but,
as we have seen above, even as between directors and
shareholders, the current law recognises such a relationship only
exceptionally, whilst many insiders and their counterparties are
simply not in the relationship of director and shareholder at all.39
There is also little evidence at present of a willingness on the
part of the courts to expand the categories of fiduciary or other
special relationships in this area40 or to bring securities contracts
within the category of contracts uberrimae fidei.
Prohibiting insider dealing
30–11
The above analysis leaves only the approach of prohibiting
dealing by those who actually possess inside information. This
can be said to constitute the core of the current law. However,
the prohibition can take two forms. The first involves the
criminalisation of insider dealing and certain associated acts.
The original criminal legislation was contained in Pt V of the
Companies Act 1980 and was later consolidated in the Company
Securities (Insider Dealing) Act 1985. As a result of the adoption
by the European Community of the Insider Dealing Directive in
1989,41 some amendment of the British law became necessary,
and the Department of Trade and Industry also took the
opportunity to simplify the 1985 Act in some respects. However,
Pt V of the Criminal Justice Act 1993, the current law, is still
recognisably in the mould established by the 1980 Act, though it
contains some interesting new features and has abandoned some
old obfuscations.42 Experience showed, however, that it was
difficult to secure convictions for this offence, partly because of
difficulties of detection but partly also because of the standards
of evidence and proof required in criminal trials. The legislature
responded in the market abuse provisions of the FSMA 2000,
which allow the FCA to impose administrative penalties upon
those who engage in this activity, which is defined so as to
include insider dealing. Thus, the second main form of the
prohibition on trading is the deployment of regulatory sanctions
against insider dealing, which is the area where EU law has been
most influential.
THE CRIMINAL JUSTICE ACT 1993 PART V
30–12
Section 52(1) of the 1993 Act defines the central offence which
it creates in the following terms: “An individual who has
information as an insider is guilty of insider dealing if, in the
circumstances mentioned in subs. (3), he deals in securities that
are price-affected securities in relation to the information”. This
definition, however, conceals as much as it reveals, for it is
much elaborated and qualified in the remaining sections of the
Part. It is proposed in the following sections to try to elucidate
the central elements of the offences created and of the defences
available.
Regulating markets
30–13
Pursuing the reference to s.52(3), contained in the above
definition, reveals at once that the Act does not aim to control all
dealings in shares where one of the parties has price-sensitive,
non-public information in his or her possession. On the contrary,
it is only when the dealing takes place “on a regulated market”
and in certain analogous situations does the Act bite. If, say, the
transaction occurs face-to-face between private persons, then the
situation is outside the control of this particular legislation. The
Act leaves regulated markets to be identified by statutory
instrument and that instrument includes any market established
under the rules of the London Stock Exchange (thus including
AIM).43
However, the legislation has always applied to certain “off-
market” deals and these are now defined as those where the
person dealing “relies on a professional intermediary or is
himself acting as a professional intermediary”.44 Section 59
makes it clear that the profession in question must be that of
acquiring or disposing of securities (for example, as a market
maker45) or acting as an intermediary between persons who wish
to deal (for example, as a broker46), and that a person does not
fall within the definition if the activities of this type are merely
incidental to some other activity or are merely occasional.
30–14
Despite this extension, which was in any event required by the
1989 Directive,47 the main thrust of the legislation is the
regulation of dealings on formalised markets, and the extension
was designed to prevent the evasion of such regulation, which
might occur if trading were driven off formalised markets into
less efficient, informal arrangements. The concentration of the
prohibition on formal markets also makes it much easier to
justify the restriction of the sanctions for breaches of the Act to
the criminal law. In addition to the other difficulties which
surround the creation of a coherent civil remedy in this area, the
fact that the trading has occurred on a public exchange means
that the identity of the counterparty to the transaction with the
insider is a matter of chance. In any liquid stock many thousands
of persons may be trading in the market at the same time as the
insider. To give a civil remedy to the person who happened to
end up with the insider’s shares and not to the others who dealt
in the market at the same time in the security in question would
be arbitrary, whilst to give a civil remedy to all relevant market
participants might well be oppressive of the insider.48 By
confining the sanction to the criminal law, Parliament avoided
the need to address these difficulties. Moreover, if the main
argument against insider trading is that it undermines public
confidence in the securities markets, the criminal law is capable
of expressing the community’s view of that public interest,
provided it can be effectively enforced.49
Finally, in this section on the definition of markets a few
words should be said about the international dimension of
insider dealing. It is now extremely easy, technically, for a
person in one country to deal in the shares of a company which
are listed or otherwise open to trading in another country; or for
a person to deal in shares of a company quoted on an exchange
in his or her own country via instructions placed with a foreign
intermediary. For the domestic legislator not to deal with this
situation runs the risk that the domestic legislation will be
circumvented wholesale. To apply the domestic sanctions
irrespective of the foreign element, on the other hand, is to run
the risk of creating criminal law with an unacceptable extra-
territorial reach. The latter risk is enlarged by the 1989
Directive’s requirement that the Member States must prohibit
insider dealing in transferable securities “admitted to a market of
a Member State”50 and not just those admitted to its own
markets. In line with this requirement, the 1994 Order extends
the application of the Act to securities which are officially listed
in or are admitted to dealing under the rules of any investment
exchange established within any of the states of the European
Economic Area.51
This clearly should not mean, however, that a French citizen
dealing on the basis of inside information on the Paris Bourse or
even on the Milan Exchange in the shares of a British company
(or a company of any other nationality) is guilty of an offence
under UK law. Consequently, s.62(1)52 of the Act lays down the
requirement of a territorial connection with the UK before a
criminal offence can be said to have been committed in the UK.
This requires the dealer or the professional intermediary to have
been within the UK at the time any act was done which forms
part of the offence or the dealing to have taken place on a
regulated market situated in the UK.53 Consequently, our French
citizen will commit a criminal offence in the UK only if the deal
is transacted on a regulated market located in the UK,54 unless
the trader or the professional intermediary through whom the
deal is transacted is in the UK at the time of the dealing.55 This
approach does not eliminate all potential of the insider dealing
legislation for extra-territorial effect, but it does limit it to
situations where there is some substantial connection between
the offence and the UK.
Regulating individuals
30–15
A striking feature of the 1993 Act is that it regulates insider
dealing only by individuals. The Act does not use the more usual
term “person” to express the scope of its prohibition, so that
bodies corporate are not liable to prosecution under the Act.
Corporate bodies were excluded, not because it was thought
undesirable to make them criminally liable but because of the
difficulties it was thought would be faced by investment banks
when one department of the bank had unpublished price-
sensitive information about the securities of a client company
and the dealing department had successfully been kept in
ignorance of that information by a “Chinese Wall”56 or
otherwise. If someone in the dealing department entered into a
trade, it was thought to be arguable that the bank as a single
corporate body would have committed an offence, had the Act
applied to corporate bodies, the act of one employee and the
knowledge of the other being attributed to the bank. However, it
should be noted that these arguments were not regarded as
decisive by those who drafted the various versions of the
administrative sanction regime. Their policy was to bring insider
dealing, even by corporate bodies, within the scope of the
regulatory prohibitions but then to deal expressly with the
problem of attributed knowledge.57
In any event, it should be noted that an individual can be
liable under the Act even if the dealing in question is done by a
company. Companies can act only through human agents, and,
as we shall see below,58 the Act’s prohibition on dealing extends
to procuring or encouraging dealing in securities. Thus, if the
individuals who move the company to deal do so on the basis of
unpublished price-sensitive information, they may well have
committed the criminal offence of procuring or encouraging the
company to deal, even if the company itself commits no offence
in dealing. These extensions embrace encouraging and procuring
“persons” to deal—though, of course, the encourager or procurer
must be an individual.
Inside information
30–16
The definition of inside information is a core feature of the Act
and has always been controversial. The general principle stated
in the preamble to the 1989 Directive was: investor confidence
in security markets depends inter alia on “the assurance afforded
to investors that they are placed on an equal footing and that they
will be protected against the improper use of inside
information”. However, it is much easier to state this general
principle than to cast it into precise legal restrictions. As we have
noted, placing investors “on an equal footing” cannot mean that
all those who deal on a market should have the same
information.59 The aim of the legislation is not to eliminate all
informational advantages, but to proscribe those advantages
whose use would be improper, often because their acquisition is
not the result of skill or effort but of the mere fact of holding a
particular position. This general issue will be seen to recur in
relation to all four of the limbs of the statutory definition of
“inside information”.
Section 56 defines inside information as information which:
(a) relates to particular securities or to a particular issuer of
securities and not to securities generally or to issues of
securities generally;
(b) is specific or precise;
(c) has not been made public;
(d) if it were made public would be likely to have a significant
effect on the price of any securities.
Particular securities or issuers
30–17
The first limb of the definition is the subject of a crucial
clarification in s.60(4) that information shall be treated as
relating to an issuer of securities “not only where it is about the
company but also where it may affect the company’s business
prospects”. This makes it clear that the definition of inside
information includes information coming from outside the
company, for example, that the Government intends to liberalise
the industry in which the company previously had a monopoly,
as well as information coming from within the company, for
example, that the company is about to declare a substantially
increased or decreased dividend or has won or lost a significant
contract. This casts the net very wide, but it is difficult to see
that any narrower formulation would have been appropriate.
Whatever the source of the information, it must relate to
particular securities or a particular issuer60 or particular issuers
of securities and not to securities or issuers generally. So
information relating to a particular company or sector of the
economy is covered, but not information which applies in an
undifferentiated way to the economy in general. This is not an
entirely easy distinction; nor is its policy rationale self-evident. It
would seem to mean that knowledge that the Government is,
unexpectedly, to increase or decrease interest rates would fall
within the definition in relation to bank shares (because interest
rates are central to the bank’s business of borrowing and lending
money) but not in relation to the shares in all companies (where
the implication of the rate rise is simply a less rapid future
growth of the economy).
Specific or precise
30–18
The second limb of the definition restricts the scope of inside
information further: the information must also be specific or
precise.61 The 1989 Directive required simply that the
information be “precise”,62 but this was thought by Parliament to
be possibly too restrictive, so the alternative of “specific” was
added. The example was given of knowledge that a takeover bid
was going to be made for a company, which would be specific
information, but might not be regarded as precise if there was no
knowledge of the price to be offered or the exact date on which
the announcement of the bid would be made.63 However, the
crucial effect of this restriction is that it apparently relieves
directors and senior managers of the company and analysts who
have made a special study of the company from falling foul of
the legislation simply because they have generalised
informational advantages over other investors. Having a better
sense of how well or badly the company is likely to respond to a
particular publicly known development does not amount to the
possession of precise or specific information.
Made public
30–19
The tension between the policy of encouraging communication
between companies and the investment community and of
stimulating analysts and other professionals to play an
appropriate role in that process, on the one hand, and that of
preventing selective disclosure of significant information to the
detriment of investors who are not close to the market, on the
other, is further revealed in s.58 of the Act, which deals with the
issue of when information can be said to have been “made
public”. The Government initially proposed to leave the problem
to be solved by the courts on a case-by-case basis, but came
under pressure in Parliament to deal with the issue expressly.
The pressure probably reflected the accurate perception that,
with the broadening of the definition of “insider”,64 more weight
would fall on the definition of “inside information” and
especially this limb of the definition. Section 58 is not, however,
a comprehensive attempt to deal with the issue. It stipulates four
situations where the information shall be regarded as having
been made public and five situations where the court may so
regard it; otherwise, the court is free to arrive at its own
judgment.65
The most helpful statement in s.58 from the point of view of
analysts is that “information is public if it is derived from
information which has been made public”.66 It is clear that this
provision was intended to protect analysts who derive insights
into a company’s prospects which are not shared by the market
generally (so that the analyst is able to out-guess competitors)
where those insights are derived from the intensive and
intelligent study of information which has been made public. An
analyst in this position can deal on the basis of the insights so
derived without first disclosing to the market the process of
reasoning which has led to the conclusions, even where the
disclosure of the reasoning would have a significant impact on
the price of the securities dealt in. This seems to be the case even
where the analyst intends to and does publish the
recommendations after the dealing, i.e. there is what is called
“front running” of the research.67
30–20
The utility of this subsection to the analyst and others is
enhanced by the other provisions of s.58(2). Section 58(2)(c)
comes close to providing an overarching test for whether
information is “made public” by stating that this is so if the
information “can readily be acquired” by those likely to deal in
the relevant securities. In other words, the public here is not the
public in general but the dealing public in relation to the
securities concerned (which is obviously sensible) and, more
controversially, the issue is not whether the information is
known to that public but whether it is readily available to them.
This is a more relaxed test than that applied under the previous
legislation, which required knowledge of the information on the
part of the public.68 The former test in effect required those close
to the market to wait until the information had been assimilated
by the investment community before trading. Now it appears that
trading is permitted as soon as the information can be readily
acquired by investors, even though it has not in fact been
acquired. In other words, a person who has advance knowledge
of the information can react as soon as it can be “readily
acquired” and reap a benefit in the period before the information
is in fact fully absorbed by the market. This consequence of
s.58(2)(c) is strengthened by the express provisions that
publication in accordance with the rules of a regulated market or
publication in records which by statute are available for public
inspection mean that the information has been made public.69
However, the extent of the move away from actual public
knowledge in the current legislation should not be exaggerated.
The test laid down in s.58(2)(c) is not that information is public
if it is available to the relevant segment of investors but whether
it “can readily be acquired” by them. That information could be
acquired by investors, if they took certain steps, is surely not
enough in every case to meet the test of ready availability. One
can foresee much dispute over what in addition is required to
make information readily available. Section 58(3) helps with this
issue to the extent of stating that certain features of the
information do not necessarily prevent it from being brought
within the category of information which “can be readily
acquired”. Thus, information is not to be excluded solely
because it is published outside the UK, is communicated only on
payment of a fee, can be acquired only by observation or the
exercise of diligence or expertise, or is communicated only to a
section of the public. However, in the context of particular cases,
information falling within these categories may be excluded
from the scope of “public information”, for instance because the
information is supplied for a (high) fee or is supplied to a very
restricted number of persons. To this extent, the legislation has
necessarily ended up adopting the Government’s initial
standpoint that much would have to depend upon case-by-case
evaluation by the courts in the context of particular prosecutions.
Impact on price
30–21
The final limb of the definition is the requirement that the
information should be likely to have “a significant effect” on the
price of the securities, if it were made public.70 The law has
chosen not to pursue those who will reap only trivial advantages
from trading on inside information. At first sight, the test would
seem to present the court (or jury) with an impossibly
hypothetical test to apply. In fact, in most cases, by the time any
prosecution is brought, the information in question will have
become public,71 and so the question will probably be answered
by looking at what impact the information did in fact have on the
market when it was published. However, it would seem
permissible for an insider to argue in an appropriate case that the
likely effect of the information being made public at the time of
the trading was not significant, even if its actual disclosure had a
bigger effect, because the surrounding circumstances had
changed in the meantime.
Insiders
30–22
We have already noted72 the important restriction in the
legislation that insiders must be individuals. Beyond that, it
might be thought that nothing more needs to be said other than
that an insider is a person in possession of inside information. In
other words, the definitional burden should fall on deciding what
is inside information and the definition of insider should follow
as a secondary consequence of this primary definition. The
Government’s consultative document on the proposed
legislation73 rejected this approach as likely to cause “damaging
uncertainty in the markets, as individuals attempted to identify
whether or not they were covered”. This is not convincing.
Either the definition of inside information is adequate or it ought
to be reformed. If it is adequate, so that it can be applied
effectively to those who are insiders under the Act, then it is not
clear why it cannot be applied to all individuals, whether they
meet the separate criteria for being insiders or not. If the
definition of inside information is not adequate, it is not proper
to apply it even to those who clearly are insiders under the
legislation and it should be changed. In fact, the proposal that
insiders should be defined as those in possession of inside
information would to some extent reduce uncertainty, because
the only question which would have to be asked is whether the
individual was in possession of inside information and the
additional question of whether the individual met the separate
criteria for being classed as an insider would be irrelevant.
However, the Government stuck to its guns whilst simplifying
the criteria which had been used in the earlier legislation and,
following the Directive, expanding the category of insiders quite
considerably.74 By virtue of s.57(2)(a) two categories of insider
are defined. The first are those who obtain inside information
“through being” a director, employee or shareholder of an issuer
of securities.75 Although it is not entirely clear, it seems that the
“through being” test is simply a “but for” test. If a junior
employee happens to see inside information in the non-public
part of the employer’s premises, he or she would be within the
category of insider, even if the duties of the employment do not
involve acquisition of that information. On the other hand,
coming across such information in a social context would not
make the junior employee an insider, even though the
information related to the worker’s employer. In other words,
there must be a causal link between the employment and the
acquisition of the information, but not in the sense that the
information must be acquired in the course of the employee’s
employment (though the latter remains a possible interpretation
of the subsection). It may be thought that shareholders, who
were excluded from the definition of insider in the previous
legislation, are unlikely to obtain access to inside information
“though being” shareholders, but this is in fact a likely situation
in relation to large institutional shareholders, which may, either
as a general practice or in specific circumstances, keep in close
touch with at least the largest companies in their portfolios.
The second category of insider identified by s.57(2)(a) is the
individual with inside information “through having access to the
information by virtue of his employment, office or profession”,
whether or not the employment, etc. relationship is with an
issuer. Thus, an insider in this second category maybe, or be
employed by, a professional adviser to the company76; an
investment analyst, who has no business link with an issuer; a
civil servant or an employee of a regulatory body; or a journalist
or other employee of a newspaper or printing company.77 Again,
the question arises about the exact meaning of the phrase “by
virtue of”: is it again a simple “but for” test or does it mean “in
the course of” (perhaps a slightly stronger suggestion in this
second situation)? Even if the latter interpretation is ultimately
adopted, this second category would be wide enough to embrace
partners and employees of an investment bank or solicitors’ firm
retained to advise an issuer on a particular matter, employees of
regulatory bodies who are concerned with the issuer’s affairs,
journalists researching an issuer for a story and even employees
of a printing firm involved in the production of documents for a
planned but unannounced takeover bid.78 If the broader “but for”
test is adopted, then employees of these organisations, not
employed on the tasks mentioned, but who serendipitously come
across the information in the workplace, would be covered too.79
Recipients from insiders
30–23
In practice, the need to define the exact scope of the second
category of insider is reduced by the third category, created by
s.57(2)(b). In the US persons in this third category are
distinguished from primary insiders by the use of the graphic
expression “tippee”,80 but the British legislation lumps them in
with primary insiders. This third category consists of those who
have inside information “the direct or indirect source of” which
is a person falling within either of the first two categories. Thus,
subject to the point about mens rea made in the next paragraph,
the employee of an investment bank who overhears a colleague
talking about a takeover bid on which the latter is engaged
would be in all probability an insider in the third category if he
or she does not fall within the second category. This example
also makes it clear that the more striking American terminology
might be somewhat misleading. It does not matter whether the
primary insider has consciously communicated the information
to the secondary insider (i.e. “tipped the latter off”). Provided the
latter has acquired the information from an inside source, even
indirectly, he or she will fall within the scope of the Act; indeed,
as in the example, the “tipper” may be entirely unaware that
inside information has been communicated to anyone else.81
Furthermore, a certain type of tipping will not in fact make the
tippee liable for dealing. If the insider within the first two
categories encourages another person to deal without
communicating to that other person any inside information, the
latter can deal without being exposed to liability under the Act—
though the tipper would be liable for encouraging the dealing.82
Mental element
30–24
Finally, the requirement of having information “as an insider” in
s.57 was used by the drafters to put a crucial limitation on the
scope of the offence created by the Act. This is the required
mental element, a not surprising precondition for criminal
liability, but nevertheless one which has made enforcement of
the legislation often difficult.83 The requirement in this regard is
a two-fold one: the accused must be proved to have known that
the information in question was inside information and that the
information came from “an inside source”, i.e. accused knew the
information was obtained in one of the three ways discussed
above. The requirement of knowledge is likely to be difficult to
meet, especially in the case of recipients of information from
insiders via a chain of communications. Proving that a “sub-
tippee” or even a “sub-sub-tippee” knew that the ultimate source
of the information was a primary insider could be fraught with
problems.
Prohibited acts
30–25
What is an individual with inside information and who is an
insider and meets the required mental element prohibited from
doing? There are four prohibitions and, before describing them,
it should be pointed out that it is not necessary that the accused
should be an insider at the time he or she does the prohibited act.
Once inside information has been acquired by an insider, the
prohibitions apply even though the accused resigns the
directorship or employment through which he obtained the
information.84 On the other hand, if by the time of the dealing the
information enters the public domain, the prohibitions of the Act
will cease to apply. It should also be noted that the prohibitions
apply not only to the company’s securities but also to futures
contracts85 and contracts for differences,86 where the reference
security is a security issued by the company.87
First, and most obviously, there must be no dealing in the
relevant securities.88 The relevant securities are those which are
“price-affected”, i.e. those upon the price of which the inside
information would be likely to have a significant effect, if made
public.89 Dealing is defined as acquiring or disposing of
securities.90 Thus, a person who refrains from dealing or cancels
a deal on the basis of inside information is not covered by the
legislation.91 In principle, it is difficult to defend this exclusion
since the loss of public confidence in the market will be as
strong as in a case of dealing, if news of the non-dealing
emerges. The exclusion was presumably a pragmatic decision
based on the severe evidential problems which would face the
prosecution in such a case. The dealing prohibition is broken
quite simply by dealing; the Act does not require the prosecution
to go further and prove that the dealing was motivated by the
inside information, though the accused may be able to put
forward the defence that he would have done what he did even if
he had not had the information.92 The Act covers dealing as an
agent (not only as a principal) even if the profit from the dealing
is thereby made by someone else, for one can never be sure that
the profit made by the third party will not filter back to the trader
in some form or other. And it covers agreeing to acquire or
dispose of securities as well as their actual acquisition or
disposal, and entering into or ending a contract which creates the
security93 as well as contracting to acquire or dispose of a pre-
existing security.
Secondly, the insider is prohibited from procuring, directly or
indirectly, the acquisition or disposal of securities by any other
person. Technically, this result is achieved by bringing procuring
within the definition of dealing.94 Procurement will have taken
place if the acquisition is done by the insider’s agent or nominee
or a person acting at his or her direction, but this does not
exhaust the range of situations in which procurement can be
found.95 Since the person procured to deal may well not be in
possession of any inside information and the procurer has not in
fact dealt, without this extension of the statutory meaning of
“dealing” there would be a gap in the law.
Thirdly, there is a prohibition on the individual encouraging
another person to deal in price-affected securities, knowing or
having reasonable cause to believe that dealing would take place
on a regulated market or through a professional intermediary.96
Again, it does not matter, for the purposes of the liability of the
person who does the encouraging, that the person encouraged
commits no offence, because, say, no inside information is
imparted by the accused. Indeed, it does not matter for these
purposes that no dealing at all in the end takes place, though the
accused must at least have reasonable cause to believe that it
would. The existence of this offence is likely to discourage over-
enthusiastic presentations by company representatives to
meetings of large shareholders or analysts.
Finally, the individual must not disclose the information
“otherwise than in the proper performance of the functions of his
employment, office or profession to another person”.97 Unlike in
the previous two cases, the communication of inside information
is a necessary ingredient of this offence, but no response on the
part of the person to whom the information is communicated
need occur nor be expected by the accused. However, in effect,
this element is built into the liability, for the accused has a
defence that “he did not at the time expect any person, because
of the disclosure, to deal in securities” on a regulated market or
through a professional intermediary.98 So, even if it occurs
outside the proper performance of duties, disclosure which is not
expected to lead to dealing will not result in liability, but the
burden of proving the absence of the expectation falls on the
accused. This prohibition helps to put the issuer in the position
of being the sole source of the disclosure of internally generated
inside information to the market.99
Defences
30–26
The Act provides a wide range of defences,100 which fall within
two broad categories. First, there are two general defences which
carry further the task of defining the mischief at which the Act is
aimed.101 Secondly, there are the special defences, set out mainly
but not entirely, in Sch.1 to the Act, which frankly accept that in
certain circumstances the policy of prohibiting insider trading
should be overborne by the values underlying the exempted
practices. These special defences, which were foreshadowed in
the recitals to the 1989 Directive, will be dealt with only briefly
here.102
General defences
30–27
The more important of the general defences is that the accused
“would have done what he did even if he had not had the
information”.103 This defence benefits liquidators, receivers,
trustees, trustees in bankruptcy and personal representatives who
may find themselves in the course of their offices advised to
trade when in fact themselves in possession of inside
information.104 Thus, a trustee, who is advised by an investment
adviser to deal for the trust in a security in relation to which the
trustee has inside information, will be able to do so, relying on
this defence. But the defence applies more generally than that
and would embrace, for example, an insider who dealt when he
did in order to meet a pressing financial need or legal obligation.
However, the accused will carry the burden of showing that his
or her decision to deal at that particular time in that particular
security was not influenced by the possibility of exploiting the
inside information which was held.
The other general defence is that the accused did not expect
the dealing to result in a profit attributable to the inside
information.105 Although the defence is general in the sense that
it is not confined to particular business or financial transactions,
the range of situations falling within it is probably quite narrow.
The Government’s attempts in the parliamentary debates to
produce examples of situations for which this defence was
needed and which were at all realistic were not entirely
convincing.106
Special defences
30–28
The Act provides six special defences, two in the body of the
Act and four in Sch.1. One of those provided in the body of the
Act appears to be a general defence and is to the effect that
dealing is not unlawful if the individual “believed on reasonable
grounds that the information had been disclosed widely enough
to ensure that none of those taking part in the dealing would be
prejudiced by not having the information”.107 In fact, however,
this defence is aimed particularly at underwriting
arrangements,108 where those involved in the underwriting may
trade amongst themselves on the basis of shared knowledge
about the underwriting proposal but that information is not
known to the market generally. The other defence provided in
the body of the Act109 concerns things done “on behalf of a
public sector body in pursuit of monetary policies or policies
with respect to exchange rates or the management of public debt
or foreign exchange reserves”. So reasons of state, relating to
financial policy, trump market integrity.110
The four special defences provided in the Schedule do not
extend to the disclosure of inside information. Where these
defences apply, those concerned may trade or encourage others
to do so but may not enlarge the pool of persons privy to the
inside information. In all four cases, what are judged to be
valuable market activities would be impossible without the
relaxation of the insider dealing prohibition. Thus, market
makers111 may often be in possession of inside information but
would not be able to discharge their undertaking to maintain a
continuous two-way market in particular securities if they were
always subject to the Act. So para.1 of Sch.1 exempts acts done
by a market maker in good faith in the course of the market-
making business. More controversially, para.5 does the same
thing in relation to price stabilisation of new issues.112
The final two special defences relate to trading whilst in
possession of “market information”, which is, in essence,
information about transactions in securities being contemplated
or no longer contemplated or having or not having taken place.
First, an individual may act in connection with the acquisition or
disposal of securities and with a view to facilitating their
acquisition or disposal where the information held is market
information arising directly out of the individual’s involvement
in the acquisition or disposal.113 An example is where the
employees of an investment bank advising a bidder on a
proposed takeover procure the acquisition of the target’s shares
on behalf of the bidder but before the bid is publicly announced,
in order to give the bidder a good platform from which to launch
the bid. This defence would not permit the employees to
purchase shares for their own account, because they would not
then be acting to facilitate the proposed transaction out of which
the inside information arose. Even so, permitting a bidder to act
in this way is somewhat controversial for those who procure the
purchase of the shares know that a bid at a price in excess of the
current market price is about to be launched and those who sell
out to the bidder just before the public announcement may feel
that they have been badly treated.114 Another situation covered
by the provision is that of a fund manager who decides to take a
large stake in a particular company. The manager can go into the
market on behalf of the funds under management and acquire the
stake at the best prices possible, without announcing in advance
the intention to build up a large stake, which would immediately
drive up the price of the chosen company’s shares.
Under the second and more general “market information”
defence the individual may act if “it was reasonable for an
individual in his position to have acted as he did” despite having
the market information.115 This is so broadly phrased that it
would seem wide enough to cover the situations discussed in the
previous paragraph. The more specific provisions were included
as well presumably in order to give comfort to those who would
otherwise have had to rely on the general reasonableness
provision and who might have wondered whether the courts
would interpret it in their favour.
CRIMINAL PROHIBITIONS ON MARKET MANIPULATION
30–29
The criminal prohibitions on market manipulation are now to be
found in Pt 7 of the Financial Services Act 2012. Section 89
creates an offence in relation to misleading statements made in
order to induce trading in securities. It can clearly be used to
catch egregious cases of market manipulation116 and has been
discussed in Ch.26.117 The second offence is more interesting
and was introduced by s.47(2) of the Financial Services Act
1986 (now repealed). As reformulated by s.90 of the 2012 Act,
this criminalises an act or course of conduct118 which creates a
false or misleading impression as to the market in or price or
value of any investment (as widely defined), if done for one or
other (or both) of two purposes. The first is where the defendant
intends by creating the impression to induce a person to acquire
or dispose of investments or to refrain from doing so or to
exercise or not to exercise rights attached to investments.119 It is
to be noted that the offence is complete whether or not the
accused knew that, or was reckless whether, the impression
created was misleading: all that has to be shown is that he acted
for the purpose of creating an impression which was in fact
misleading. However, a defence is provided where the accused
can show that he reasonably believed that the impression was not
misleading.120 In effect, negligence as to the misleading nature of
the impression is made a crime and the burden of disproving
negligence is placed upon the maker of the impression.
The second purpose does depend upon the creator of the
impression knowing that it is false or misleading or being
reckless as to whether this is the case. If the defendant intends
through the impression to make a gain for himself or another or
cause loss (or the risk of loss) to another, that person commits an
offence, as will also be the case where the defendant is aware
that these consequences are likely to result.121 Thus, if in the De
Berenger case,122 the fraudsters had acted somewhat more subtly
and refrained from openly stating that Napoleon had been killed
but had allowed that impression to arise (for example, through
their joyous behaviour as if by soldiers released from a
successful army), they would be caught by this version of the
second offence.
Some basic forms of manipulative behaviour are offences at
common law,123 but the statute extends and makes clearer the
reach of the criminal law in this area. This offence is rarely
prosecuted,124 but the following examples of contraventions can
be given. The promoters of a company fund the underwriters of a
share issue to buy shares in the market when dealings begin in
order to give the impression that there is a greater market interest
in the shares than is in fact the case125; or the directors of a
company, believing the market price of its shares not to reflect
the net tangible asset value of the company, persuade its brokers
to buy shares in the market at some four times the previous
market price, in order to move the market price closer to what
the directors believe to be the “true” value of the shares.126
REGULATORY CONTROL OF MARKET ABUSE
Background
30–30
So far, we have looked at the criminal prohibitions on insider
dealing and market manipulation. We now turn to the practically
more important form of control of market abuse, namely, that
administered by regulators, which do not require resort to the
criminal law and the criminal courts. In fact, with the enactment
of the FSMA 2000, the main thrust of the legal rules controlling
market abuse, in which term is to be included both insider
dealing and market manipulation, shifted from the criminal law
to administrative sanctions which have been placed in the hands
of the FCA. At this point, the main source of the rules was Pt
VIII of FSMA which was used later to transpose the first EU
Directive on market abuse,127 but in significant ways went
beyond that Directive. From the beginning the regulatory
sanctions were applied to companies as well as to individuals.
Moreover, they applied to all those whose actions had an effect
on the market, whether they were persons authorised to carry on
financial activities or not. They thus applied as much to
industrial companies and their directors, for example, as to
investment banks and their directors and employees. These
statements are true also of the MAR, now the central legal
instrument on administrative control.
Part of the reason for the emphasis on administrative penalties
from 2000 onwards was that successful deployment of the
criminal law on a wide scale against insider dealing and market
manipulation proved difficult. Only after the financial crisis of
2007/8 did the FSA/FCA put substantial resources into the
enforcement of the relevant criminal laws. Even so, between
2009 and mid-2015 there were only 27 successful prosecutions
for insider dealing (about four a year), of which 23 resulted in
custodial sentences (in no case for more than four years).128 The
move towards a regime based on administrative penalties was
driven by the desire to address two of the obstacles raised by the
criminal offences, namely the need to show intention, at least in
relation to insider dealing,129 and the high evidential
requirements of the criminal law. Even so, in the 12 years to
March 2015 the FSA/FCA issued only 85 “Final Notices” in
relation to market abuse, i.e. about seven a year.130
However, the proposals which were eventually embodied in
the FSMA 2000 proved highly controversial during the
parliamentary debates on the Bill, those opposing it claiming that
it would infringe rights conferred by art.6 of the European
Convention on Human Rights (right to a fair trial).131 The central
claim of the opponents was that the penalty regime proposed by
the Government, although clearly not part of the domestic
criminal law, would be classified as criminal by the European
Court of Human Rights, whose classification criteria are
independent of those used domestically. Without ever conceding
the correctness of this claim, the Government nevertheless did
make substantial amendments to its proposals in order to
promote the fairness of the new regime, the regime being subject
in any event to a general fairness test under the European
Convention, even if regarded as civil rather than criminal in
nature. These amendments involved in particular the elaboration
by the then FSA of a Code on Market Abuse in order to give
guidance on the scope of the prohibitions, and the creation of
rights of appeal to an independent tribunal (now the Upper
Tribunal) to be granted to persons penalised by the FCA.132
In the aftermath of the financial crisis, the debate turned on its
head. Now, it was argued that the market abuse provisions were
inadequate. This was an argument advanced at EU level as well
as at domestic level. It led to the replacement of the EU
Directive by a Regulation on market abuse (MAR). MAR both
expanded the scope of the substantive EU laws on market abuse,
but also removed the need for domestic transposition of those
laws, thus bringing about a major change in the structure of the
domestic law. In fact, with regard to the securities markets
aspects of market abuse, which are the focus of this chapter, the
structural changes were probably more important than the
substantive ones. In particular, MAR led to the removal of the
FCA’s power to make a Code in this area.133
Insider dealing
30–31
The definition of insider dealing in MAR is somewhat more
simply phrased than under the CJA.
“For the purposes of this Regulation, insider dealing arises where a person
possesses inside information and uses that information by acquiring or disposing of,
for its own account or for the account of a third party, directly or indirectly,
financial instruments to which that information relates.”134
30–46
Putting together the provisions of MAR and the technical
regulatory standards of the Commission developed under the
prior EU law, the main conditions to be met for the price
stabilisation safe harbour are likely to be, briefly, as follows:
(a) The stabilisation may be carried out only within a limited
period of time, for example, in the case of shares, within 30
calendar days of the date on which shares offered in an initial
offer commence trading.188
(b) The market must be informed before the shares are offered to
the public that stabilisation may be undertaken (but that there
is no guarantee that it will or that it will be at any particular
level) and of the period during which it may be undertaken
and who will be undertaking it.189 Stabilisation activity must
be reported to the FCA within seven working days of its
taking place, and within one week of the end of the
stabilisation period the market must be informed of what
stabilisation activity occurred, including the dates and
prices.190
(c) The price at which the stabilisation activity took place must
not be above the offer price.191
ENFORCEMENT AND SANCTIONS
30–47
Although the substantive rules on market abuse are set at EU
level, enforcement and sanctions are in the hands of national
competent authorities. However, this does not mean that MAR
ignores these topics. Rather, it proceeds by requiring Member
States to confer on their national authorities at least the
investigatory and sanctioning powers specified in Chs 4 and 5 of
MAR and by imposing obligations to cooperate on those
authorities. Although the range of powers and sanctions
contained in these chapters is wide, by and large they are not
new powers for the FCA. The current investigation and penalty
powers of the FCA in relation to market abuse are set out in Pts
VIII and XI of FSMA but will need some amendment to deal
with the provisions of MAR.
Investigation into market abuse
30–48
MAR requires competent authorities to have 13 powers so that
they may police and enforce the prohibition on market abuse
effectively.192 Among the more notable ones, are access to data
in any form, the right to summon persons and demand answers
to questions, to carry out on-site inspections (other than
residences), to enter premises and seize documents (subject to
judicial control if the Member State requires it), to require
recordings of telephone conversations and copies of emails from
financial institutions, to require traffic data from telecom
operators (if national law permits this) and, crossing the border
into remedies, to impose various interlocutory remedies and to
require the correction of misstatements to the market.
Information obtained must be subject to confidentiality
requirements and be governed by national data protection
laws.193
In order to maximise the chances of national regulators
learning of potential infringements of MAR, Member States are
required to ensure that “whistle-blowing” procedures exist, both
for the provision of information to the competent authority and
for the provision of information to the employer concerned,
where the employer is engaged in providing regulated financial
services.194 However, there is no obligation on the whistle-
blower to report first to the employer before approaching the
competent authority. In relation to reporting to the competent
authority the Commission Implementing Directive195 provides
that there should be a dedicated function within the authority to
receive the reports, that its operation should be explained on the
authority’s website and that, in all normal circumstances, the
identity of the reporting person should not be revealed and that
that person should be protected against discriminatory acts of the
employer, if the identity does become known. MAR permits the
provision of financial inducements to make reports, provided the
informer is not under an existing legal or contractual duty to
report and that the report leads to the imposition of a penalty or
sanction.196
30–49
Since market manipulation is often a cross-border activity, MAR
requires national competent authorities to cooperate both with
ESMA (mainly in the communication of information)197 and
with other national authorities and ESMA for the purposes of
investigation, supervision and enforcement.198 The latter form of
cooperation is likely to involve the provision of information but
may go much further. For example, cooperation requests from
other national competent authorities, which may be refused on
only limited grounds,199 may extend to initiating on-site
investigations in the country receiving the request.200
Investigation requests assume that the requesting state is itself
already knows or suspects some potential wrongdoing in its own
jurisdiction and is seeking to investigate it, but knowledge of
that wrongdoing might first emerge as a result of the activities of
a competent authority in another Member State. The Member
State with the knowledge must report the facts to the Member
State where the activities appear to be located and to ESMA and
both Member States are under an obligation to coordinate their
subsequent actions.201 What gives bite to these requirements is
the role afforded to ESMA where a Member State’s request for
information or assistance is rejected by another Member State’s
competent authority or not accepted within a reasonable time.
ESMA may either deal with the matter as an example of a
disagreement between national authorities, as discussed above,202
or, if it believes one of the competent authorities is acting in
breach of EU law, take action against it on that basis. In either
case ESMA may end up requiring the recalcitrant national
authority to take specific action or to refrain from action or, if
that fails, itself requiring market participants to take specific
action or to refrain from action.203
30–50
Since financial activity is often a global matter, cooperation
among EU regulators, although highly desirable, is unlikely to
be enough. MAR therefore envisages cooperation agreements
with the supervisory authorities of third countries. Reflecting
prior practice, but somewhat out of tune with MAR’s objectives,
the conclusion of such agreements is a matter for national
competent authorities. However, ESMA is inserted into the
process. It is “where possible” to facilitate and coordinate the
third-party agreements and is to draft regulatory technical
standards, to be adopted by the Commission, aimed at producing
a “template” for such agreements, which national competent
authorities are to use, again “where possible”.204
Under the pre-MAR rules the UK signed Memoranda of
Understanding relating to co-operation with regulators from
other leading countries in the financial services field, such as the
US, Japan, Hong Kong, Switzerland and Australia. These
international agreements and the pre-MAR EU obligations are
underpinned by s.169 of FSMA, which authorises or, in the case
of the EU obligation, requires the FCA to appoint investigators
at the behest of a non-British regulator to investigate “any
matter”. The FCA may permit a representative of the overseas
regulator to be present and ask questions, provided the
information obtained is subject to the same confidentiality
requirements in the hands of the overseas regulator as it would
be under the FSMA.205 Where assistance is not obligatory, the
overseas regulator may be required to contribute to the costs of
the investigation and the FCA considers, before granting the
request, whether similar assistance would be forthcoming from
the overseas regulator if it were requested by a British regulator,
whether the breach of the law to be investigated has no close
parallel in the UK, whether the matter is of importance to people
in the UK and whether the public interest requires that the
assistance be given.206 In the case of insider dealing, it seems
likely that these criteria could easily be satisfied, so that
assistance should normally be given, even where there is no EU
obligation to provide it, subject to the matter of cost. The Court
of Appeal has interpreted the section liberally, notably by not
requiring the FCA investigate the genuineness or validity of the
foreign regulator’s request and by permitting the investigators to
require the production of any documents which are relevant to
their investigation.207
Sanctions for market abuse
30–51
MAR requires a wide range of administrative sanctions to be
available for breach of the prohibitions on market abuse.208
These are expressly stated to be minimum requirements to which
Member States may add, both by making sanctions available
other than those listed in MAR and by making the listed
sanctions more powerful.209
In relation to companies and individuals other than investment
firms and their managers and employees, the sanctions required
to be made available are:
• injunctions requiring the conduct constituting the market
abuse to cease;
• disgorgement of profits made or losses avoided through the
market abuse “insofar as they can be determined”210;
• a maximum administrative penalty of ‘at least’ three times
the profit made or loss avoided under the previous item211;
• public warnings;
• financial penalties up to a maximum of €5,000,000 in the
case of individuals and €15,000,000 or 15 per cent of annual
turnover in the case of companies.212
In the case of investment firms and those employed within them
there are additional sanctions consisting of temporary or
permanent (i) withdrawal of the authorisation of the firm to carry
on financial business; and (ii) bans on the individual from
discharging managerial responsibilities within such a firm or
dealing on their own account.
These sanctions are already available in principle to the FCA.
Penalties
30–52
The penalty provisions were another of the human rights battle
grounds in the parliamentary debates preceding the passing of
FSMA 2000 and a number of restrictions on the FCA’s powers
are the result. First, although there is no statutory restriction on
the size of penalty the FCA may impose, the FCA is required to
produce a statement of policy on the factors which will
determine its approach to penalties.213 That policy now appears
in the Decision Procedure and Penalties Manual (“DEPP”)
which contains a list of the factors the FCA considers relevant to
the decisions whether to seek a financial penalty, whether to
substitute public censure for a monetary penalty and to
determining the level of penalty. The FCA’s views on the
appropriate level of penalties were significantly strengthened as
from March 2010, under the impact of the financial crisis.
Secondly, the FCA may not impose a penalty upon a person
without sending him first a “warning notice” stating the level of
penalty proposed or the terms of the proposed public
statement.214 Thirdly, if the FSA does impose a penalty or make
a public statement, it must issue the person concerned with a
decision notice to that effect,215 which triggers the person’s right
to appeal to the Upper Tribunal.216 That right must normally be
exercised within 28 days.217 The Tribunal, consisting of a legally
qualified chair and one or more experienced lay persons,
operates by way of a re-hearing of the case, and so can consider
evidence not brought before the FCA, whether it was available at
that time or not,218 and must arrive at its own determination of
the appropriate action to be taken in the case,219 which,
presumably, could be a tougher penalty than the one the FCA
had proposed. There is a legal assistance scheme in operation for
proceedings before the Tribunal, funded by the FCA, which
recoups the cost from a levy on authorised persons.220 Appeals
lie on a point of law from the Tribunal to the Court of Appeal or
Court of Session.221
Fourthly, a prohibition on the use of compelled testimony
applies not only to subsequent criminal charges but also to
proceedings for the imposition of a penalty, whether before the
FCA or the Tribunal.222
Injunctions
30–53
The FCA may apply to the court under s.381 for an injunction to
restrain future market abuse, whether such abuse has taken place
already or not, and the court may grant an injunction where there
is a “reasonable likelihood” that the abuse will occur or be
repeated.223 The court has two further and independent powers
under s.381. If, on the application of the Authority, the court is
satisfied that a person may be, or may have been, engaged in
market abuse, it may order a freeze on all or any of that person’s
assets. This helps to ensure that any later restitution order has
something to bite on. Secondly, if the court is satisfied that the
person is or has been engaged in market abuse, it may, on the
application of the Authority, order the person to take such steps
to remedy the situation as the court may direct. Finally, in an
injunction (or restitution) application the court may impose a
penalty of such amount as it considers appropriate.224
Sanctions for breach of the criminal law
30–54
The Criminal Justice Act 1993 places exclusive reliance upon
criminal sanctions for its enforcement. Section 63(2) states that
no contract shall be “void or unenforceable” by reason only of
an offence committed under the Act, a provision which was
redrafted in 1993, it would seem, in order to close the loophole,
as the Government saw it, identified in Chase Manhattan
Equities v Goodman.225 Although the Act does not deal expressly
with the question of whether a civil action for breach of statutory
duty could be built on its provisions, it seems unlikely that the
Act would be held to fall within either of the categories
identified for this purpose in the case law.226
The criminal sanctions imposed by the Act are, on summary
conviction, a fine not exceeding the statutory maximum and/or a
term of imprisonment not exceeding six months, and on
conviction on indictment an unlimited fine and/or imprisonment
for not more than seven years.227 The power of the judge on
conviction on indictment to impose an unlimited fine means that,
in theory at least, the court could ensure that the insider made no
profit out of the dealing.228 Prosecutions in England and Wales
may be brought only by or with the consent of the Secretary of
State or the Director of Public Prosecutions. In England and
Wales prosecutions may be brought by the FCA as well as by the
usual prosecution bodies, the Crown Prosecution Service, the
Serious Fraud Office and the relevant government department.229
Indeed, the FCA has the prime responsibility for bringing
criminal prosecutions for breach of the criminal laws in the area
of market abuse. As we have noted above, the number of
criminal prosecutions brought by the FCA is small, but
increasing.230
The FCA is also the lead prosecutor under Pt 7 of FSA 2012.
This section is less used than the CJA provisions, but will be
invoked in what the FCA regards as serious cases.231
Restitution orders and injunctions
30–55
On the application of the FCA or the Secretary of State, the court
may impose a restitution order or an injunction where a breach
has occurred or is threatened of Pt 7 of FSA 2012.232 In practice,
it is unlikely this adds anything significant to the court’s and
FCA’s powers to seek restitution or an injunction on grounds of
market abuse, since the criminal law is narrower than the civil
penalty regime.
Disqualification
30–56
In addition to the traditional criminal penalties which may be
visited upon those engaging in market abuse, the disqualification
sanction is available against them in some cases, the effect of
which is to disable the person disqualified from being involved
in the running of companies in the future.233 In R. v Goodman234
the Court of Appeal upheld the Crown Court’s decision to
disqualify, for a period of 10 years, a managing director
convicted of insider dealing. The Crown Court had invoked s.2
of the Company Directors Disqualification Act 1986 which
enables a court to disqualify a person who has been convicted of
an indictable offence in connection with the management of a
company. The Court of Appeal took a liberal view of what could
be said to be “in connection with the management of the
company”, so as to bring within the phrase the managing
director’s disposal of his shares in the company in advance of
publication of bad news about its prospects. It would seem, too,
that a disqualification order could be made on grounds of
unfitness under s.8 of the 1986 Act upon an application by the
Secretary of State in the public interest. In that case, conviction
by a court of an indictable offence would not be a pre-condition
to a disqualification order, but the court would have to be
satisfied that the person’s conduct in relation to the company
made him unfit to be concerned in the management of a
company and this section, unlike s.2, is capable of applying to
market abuse only by directors and shadow directors.
CONCLUSION
30–57
Regulation of market abuse has been an area of enormously
rapid growth in recent years, to which the adoption of MAR has
most recently added. Before 1980 insider dealing was tackled
mainly through statutory disclosure requirements, whilst broader
forms of market abuse received at best a shadowy control in the
common law of crimes. Today, both insider dealing in particular
and market abuse in general are the subject of detailed criminal
and regulatory rules. Why should this have happened? It may
well reflect a deterioration in standards of market conduct as a
result of powerful financial incentives to “do the business”.
Probably, it also an example of the growth of shareholder (or, in
this case, investor) power as financial markets have come to play
a more important role in national and international business.235 In
general, the regulation discussed in this chapter aims to protect
investors, individual and collective, against opportunistic
behaviour by corporate and market insiders and thus make
securities markets more attractive places in which to participate.
Of course, it is another question whether the law is as
effective in practice as it could be. Research published by the
FSA suggests there is still a high level of abnormal price
movements ahead of takeover announcements, though in recent
years there has been a decline in such movements ahead of
trading statements.236 Until recently, whilst the FCA’s budget
was not out of line with that of its US equivalent, the Securities
Exchange Commission, when adjusted for market capitalisation,
it seemed to devote a lower proportion of its budget to
enforcement and to impose lower penalties when it did take
action.237 The FCA has up-graded the resources it devotes to
enforcement and changed its view about the appropriate level of
penalties since the financial crisis, but the effects of this policy
re-orientation remain to be seen.
1
The Criminal Justice Act 1993 Pt V and the Market Abuse Regulation (Regulation
(EU) No.596/2014) (MAR) use the word “dealing”.
2 Clearly, the insider buys in the former case and sells in the latter.
3 R. v De Berenger (1814) 3 M. & S. 68. This was long before there was specific
legislation on market manipulation but the defendants were convicted of the common
law offence of fraud. The case was also an example of manipulation in the government
bond, rather than the corporate securities, market.
4 Of course, those who buy and sell before the truth emerges may suffer no loss but may
actually benefit from the manipulation, so the loss is normally suffered by those holding
the securities at the moment of truth.
5 The analysis might be different in face-to-face transactions but in fact the market abuse
rules apply only to securities which are publicly traded.
6 See para.26–5, above.
7 The loss is in fact crystallised only when the truth emerges. See fn.4.
8
So, the distinction between trading and non-disclosure may seem trivial. However,
without the disclosure rule, the insider could plausibly say that s/he could have complied
with the insider trading provisions by simply not dealing.
9
The very act of trading will reveal some information to the market about the analysts’
position.
10
See H. Schmidt, “Insider Dealing and Economic Theory” in K.J. Hopt and E.
Wymeersch (eds), European Insider Dealing (Butterworths, 1991).
11
For an example see R. v De Berenger (1814) 3 M. & S. 68. For the specific statutory
definition of market abuse in the current legislation, see para.30–29, below.
12
Above fn.1. MAR is in force, for the most part, as from July 2016, but at the time of
writing not all the Commission’s delegated legislation was in place.
13 The area of enforcement and sanctions is the most important one where Member State
transformation is required, because there the Regulation is formulated as a direction to
the Member States to introduce specified powers.
14 Directive 2014/57/EU. But the Government has committed itself to the principle that
the UK criminal sanctions should be at least as tough as those in the Directive. See
Treasury, Bank of England, FCA, Fair and Effective Markets Review: Final Report,
June 2015, 6.3.1.
15 See above, paras 26–9 et seq.
16
Report of the Company Law Committee, Cmnd. 6659 (1945), paras 86–87.
17
See above, paras 26–5 et seq.
18 See above, paras 26–14 et seq.
19Though note that for the prospective bidder itself to buy shares on the basis of its
knowledge that it is going to launch a bid is not regarded as insider trading (see below,
para.30–28), but it would be for a person in the know to do so for his or her own
account.
20 Which are, of course, no longer mandatory. See para.26–4.
21 Nor might the company or any other company in the group trade in its securities at a
time when the director was prohibited from trading, unless this was done in the ordinary
course of securities dealing or at the behest of a third party: LR 9.2.7.
22LR 9.2.8. The code itself was appended to Ch.9. On listing and premium listing see
para.25–6.
23
LR 9.2.8. On the meaning of those “discharging managerial responsibilities”, which
term includes both directors and senior executives, see para.26–11.
24 MAR art.19(11).
25 See para.26–11 for the meaning of these two terms.
26
MAR art.19(12)(13). Certain limited routine trading is permitted, for example, in
relation to employee share schemes. ESMA’s advice is that a narrow view be taken of
“exceptional circumstances”, embracing only situations which are “extremely urgent,
unforeseen and compelling and where their cause is external to the person discharging
managerial responsibilities who has no control over them” (ESMA, Final Report:
ESMA’s technical advice on possible delegated acts concerning the Market Abuse
Regulation, 2015, 5.4).
27
FCA, Policy proposals and Handbook changes related to the implementation of the
Market Abuse Regulation (2014/596/EU), November 2015, paras 4.130 et seq.
28
FCA, Policy proposals and Handbook changes related to the implementation of the
Market Abuse Regulation (2014/596/EU), November 2015, paras 4.130 et seq.
29
Of course, the insider trading prohibition itself will apply during the run-up to the
preliminary announcement, but that is hardly an adequate response if one thinks the
blanket ban on trading is a valuable technique during pre-result periods.
30
See paras 16–86 et seq., above.
31
The leading case is the decision of the New York Court of Appeals in Diamond v
Oreamuno (1969) 248 N.E. 2d 910. The precise situation has not yet arisen in an English
court.
32 For an early example of the directors constituting themselves agents in this way, see
Allen v Hyatt (1914) 30 T.L.R. 444 PC. Or the court may find a fiduciary relationship in
a small company even in the absence of agency: see para.16–6, above.
33 Percival v Wright [1902] 2 Ch. 421: see para.16–5, above.
34
For both these propositions see Schering Chemicals Ltd v Falkman Ltd [1982] Q.B. 1
CA.
35 And by virtue of the Schering Chemicals case (see previous note) the recipient of the
information (the “tippee”) would also be in breach of duty by using or disclosing the
information if aware that it had been communicated in breach of the duty of confidence
imposed on the tipper.
36That is, one might be more concerned with depriving the insiders of their profits than
with working out who precisely are the best persons to receive them.
37 DTI, The Law on Insider Dealing: A Consultative Document (1989), paras 2.11–2.12.
38 Companies Bill, Session 1978/79, H.C. Bill 2, cl.59. As we saw in Ch.26 those with
management responsibilities in companies traded on regulated markets are obliged to
disclose inside information, but this requirement is likely to pick up a few face-to-face
transactions.
39
For example, where the director is selling shares in the company to a person who is
not presently a shareholder or where the insider is not a corporate fiduciary at all.
40 See Chase Manhattan Equities v Goodman [1991] B.C.L.C. 897, where the judge
passed up the opportunity to use the FCA’s Model Code as the basis of an extended duty
of disclosure.
41 Directive 89/592/EEC [1989] O.J. L334/30. This Directive was replaced by Directive
2003/6/EC (the Market Abuse Directive) in 2003, but the Government took the view that
the criminal law provisions of domestic law did not require amendment as a result,
though the 2006 Directive had a substantial impact on the administrative sanction
regime. The 2006 Directive was repealed by MAR.
42
For an analysis of the changes see Davies, (1991) 11 O.J.L.S. 92.
43Insider Dealing (Securities and Regulated Markets) Order (SI 1994/187) art.10, as
amended. Confusingly, the term “regulated market” in the 1993 Act does not have the
meaning attached to the term in the EU instruments: see para.25–8. In particular, trading
on AIM does fall within the CJA (AIM being a market established under the rules of the
LSE), even though AIM is not a regulated market for EU law purposes but a multi-
lateral trading facility.
44
1993 Act s.52(3).
45
A firm which has undertaken to make a continuous two-way market in certain
securities, so that, in relation to those securities, it will always be possible to buy from or
sell to the market maker, though, of course, at a price established by the market maker.
46
Following the “Big Bang” on the Stock Exchange in 1986 it is no longer required that
market makers and brokers be entirely distinct functions, though equally it is not
required that brokers make a continuous two-way market in any particular securities.
Some broking firms act as market makers as well; others are only intermediaries.
47
1989 Directive art.2(3).
48
In some cases it might not even be possible to identify the counterparty.
49
See further below, para.30–30.
50 1989 Directive art.5.
51 Above fn.43, arts 4 and 9 and Schedule.
52
1993 Act s.62(2) provides that in the case of the offences of encouraging dealing or
disclosing inside information (see para.30–25, below) either the encourager or discloser
must be in the UK when he did the relevant act or the recipient of the encouragement or
information must be.
53
See above, para.30–10.
54If French law adopts the same territorial rules as the UK, the citizen would also
commit a criminal offence under French law if he gave the instructions to deal from
France. His liability in the UK would not depend, of course, upon the nationality of the
company in whose shares on a UK regulated market the trading occurred.
55 If the French citizen is in the UK at the relevant time, he will commit a criminal
offence in the UK even if the trading occurs on a regulated market outside the UK but
within the EEA. However, if the market is outside the EEA (say, New York or Tokyo)
and involves no professional intermediary who is within the UK it would seem that the
offence of dealing is not committed in the UK even if the instruction to deal is given by
a person in the UK. This is because the dealing will not have taken place on a regulated
market within s.52(3) and the 1994 Order and will not have involved a professional
intermediary who is within the scope of s.62. However, the offence of encouraging
dealing may have been committed, the encourager being in the UK even if the person
encouraged is not. See fn.52, above.
56
An arrangement designed to prevent information in one part of a firm from being
available to individuals working elsewhere in the firm.
57 See para.30–38, below.
58See below, para.30–25. Otherwise a person could avoid the prohibition on insider
dealing simply by setting up a company to do the trading.
59 Above, para.30–2.
60The Act uses the term “issuer” rather than “company” because the Act applies not
only to securities issued by companies but also to government securities or even, though
this is unlikely, securities issued by an individual: s.60(2).
61
1993 Act s.56(1)(b).
62 1989 Directive art.1.
63
HC Debs, Session 1992–93, Standing Committee B, col. 174 (10 June 1993). It seems
that, on this argument, precise information will always be specific.
64
See para.30–22, below.
65
In the permissive cases the situation is, presumably, that the facts described in the
subsections do not prevent the court from holding the information to have been made
public, but whether the court in a particular prosecution will so hold will depend on the
circumstances of the case as a whole.
66
1993 Act s.58(2)(d).
67 Query whether front-running a recommendation, not based upon any research but
where its publication will have an impact on the price of the securities because of the
reputation of the recommender, would be protected by s.58(2)(d). cf. US v Carpenter
(1986) 791 F. 2d 1024. The trader might have a defence under para.2(1) of Sch.1 to the
Act, but that would depend upon his having acted “reasonably”: see para.30–28, below.
Such conduct might in extreme cases even be a breach of Pt 7 of the FSA 2012. See
para.30–29, below.
68 Company Securities (Insider Dealing) Act 1985 s.10(b).
69
1993 Act s.58(2)(a) and (b) respectively. The former would cover publication on a
Regulatory News Service and the latter documents field at Companies House or the
Patents Registry.
70 1993 Act s.56(1)(d).
71
Insiders have little incentive to trade on the basis of inside information which will
never become public or will do so only far into the future.
72 See above, para.30–15.
73 DTI, The Law on Insider Dealing (1989), para.2.24.
74In particular, the requirement of “being connected with the company” was removed.
See the Company Securities (Insider Dealing) Act s.9.
75
The relationship does not have to exist with the issuer of the securities which are dealt
in. So a director of Company A who is privy to his or her company’s plans to launch a
bid for Company B is an insider in relation to the securities of Company B (as well as
those of A).
76
In the course of their professional duties such individuals may well obtain inside
information in relation to a company other than the instructing company. Thus,
employees of an investment bank preparing a takeover bid would become insiders in
relation to both the proposed bidder (i.e. the bank’s client) and in relation to the target
company.
77Of course, the journalist’s employer may be a listed company, in which case he would
seem to fall within the first category as well.
78
cf. US v Chiarella (1980) 445 U.S. 222.
79
An even more restrictive test would be in the course of an employment which is likely
to provide access to inside information. Such a test would exclude the famous, if
unlikely, example of the cleaner who finds inside information in a waste-paper basket.
However, there seems to be no warrant in the Act or the Directive for such a restrictive
test, which would come close to reinstating the clearly discarded test of s.9(b) of the
1985 Act.
80
The guru of securities regulation, Professor Louis Loss of Harvard Law School, first
used this expression and the Oxford English Dictionary has credited him with this fact.
81
Moreover, since it is enough that the individual in the third category “has” the
information from a source falling within the first or second categories, it does not matter
either whether the “tippee” has solicited the information. Inadvertent acquisition of
inside information is covered. This was a point of controversy under the previous
legislation until cleared up by the House of Lords, in favour of liability. See Attorney-
General’s Reference (No.1 of 1988) [1989] A.C. 971.
82 See para.30–25, below.
83
See para.30–30, below.
84
This is the significance of prohibiting acts by a person who has information “as an
insider”, which s.57 makes clear refers to the situation at the time of the acquisition of
the information, rather than the simpler formulation of prohibiting acts by an insider,
which might well refer to the accused’s status at the time of the prohibited acts.
85 A contract of the sale or purchase of securities at a future date.
86A contract not involving an agreement to transfer an interest in the underlying
securities but simply to pay the difference between the price of the securities on a
particular date and their price on a future date. For discussion of the problems which
CfDs have created in relation to disclosure obligations, see above at para.26–20 and at
para.28–45.
87
Certain types of security are omitted, perhaps most notably the purchase or sale of
units in unit trusts, though shares in companies which operate investment trusts are
within the scope of the Act. Presumably, the former were excluded on the pragmatic
grounds that it was unlikely that a person would have inside information which would
significantly affect the price of the units, which normally reflect widely diversified
underlying investments, though query whether this is always the case with more focused
unit trusts. See para.26–12. In any event, the Treasury has power to amend the list of
securities contained in Sch.2 (see s.54(2)).
88 1993 Act s.52(1).
89
See s.56(2) and para.30–21, above.
90 1993 Act s.55.
91 Ditto an individual who discovers good news and decides not to dispose of its shares.
92
See below, para.30–27.
93 As is the case with derivatives.
94 1993 Act s.55(1)(b).
95 1993 Act s.55(4) and (5).
96 1993 Act s.52(2)(a).
97
1993 Act s.52(2)(b).
98
1993 Act s.53(3)(a).
99
See paras 26–5 et seq.
100
We have already dealt, in the previous paragraph, with one of the defences relevant
to the disclosure offence.
101
Though s.53 makes it clear that the burden of proof falls on the accused, thus
obviating a possible ambiguity which was found by some in the previous legislation. See
R. v Cross [1991] B.C.L.C. 125.
102
Sch.1 may be amended by the Treasury by order (s.53(5)), presumably so that it may
be kept current with developments in financing techniques.
103
1993 Act s.53(1)(c) and (2)(c). This defence does not apply to the disclosure offence,
though it is an essential ingredient of that offence that the disclosure should not have
occurred in the proper performance of the accused’s functions.
104
Previously they were covered by more targeted provisions: 1985 Act ss.3(1)(b) and
7.
105 1993 Act s.53(1)(a). The same defence is provided, mutatis mutandis, in relation to
the other offences by s.53(2)(a) and (3)(b). Making a profit is defined so as to include
avoiding a loss: s.53(6). This is considerably narrower than the defence in the 1985 Act
s.3(1)(a), which applied when the individual traded “otherwise than with a view to the
making of a profit”.
106
HC Debs, Session 1992–93, Standing Committee B (10 June 1993). A suggestion
was where the insider sold at a price which took into account the impact the (bad)
information would have on the market when released.
107
1993 Act s.53(1)(b),(2)(b) provide a similar defence in relation to the encouraging
offence.
108 On underwriting, see para.25–12, above.
1091993 Act s.63, applying to all offences under the Act. Technically, s.63 does not
provide a defence but rather describes a situation where the Act “does not apply”.
110 As art.2(4) of the Directive permits.
111
See above, fn.45.
112 This is discussed further below at para.30–45.
113 See para.3.
114
Nevertheless, the Code on Takeovers and Mergers adopts the same approach as the
Act. See r.4.1. However the potential bidder would have to comply with the statutory
provisions on the disclosure of shareholdings. See paras 26–17 et seq.; and P. Davies,
“The Takeover Bidder Exemption and the Policy of Disclosure” in K.J. Hopt and E.
Wymeersch (eds), European Insider Dealing (London, 1991). Even so, the bid
facilitation argument ought not to be employed to justify the purchase of derivatives
where the aim of the purchase is simply to give the bidder a cash benefit rather than to
take a step towards the acquisition of voting control.
115 See para.2(1). Some guidance on what is reasonable is given in para.2(2).
116
As in R. v De Berenger (1814) 3 M. & S. 68.
117
See para.26–32, above.
118
2012 Act s.90(1). The act or course of conduct must occur in the UK or the
misleading impression must be created in the UK: s.90(10).
119
2012 Act s.90(2).
120
2012 Act s.90(9)(a).
121
2012 Act s.90(3)(4).
122
R. v De Berenger (1814) 3 M. & S. 68 (see para.30–1, above).
123
Scott v Brown Doering & Co [1892] 2 Q.B. 724.
124 Though there has been recent interest in relation to the manipulation of interest-rate
or foreign exchange benchmarks, topics outside the scope of this chapter.
125 As in Scott v Brown Doering & Co [1892] 2 Q.B. 724. There is a defence in s.90(9)
(b) for such behaviour carried out in accordance with the price stabilisation rules. See
para.30–45.
126
North v Marra Developments (1981) C.L.R. 42 HCA. Both this and the case
mentioned in the previous note were civil actions in which the criminal nature of the
activity was used to defeat a contractual claim on grounds of the illegality of the
contract.
127Directive 2003/6/EC on insider dealing and market manipulation (market abuse)
[2003] O.J. L96/16.
128
Treasury, Bank of England, FCE, above fn.14, Chart 11. In general those convicted
were not sophisticated criminals.
129 As we have seen, in relation to misleading impressions, mens rea is required only in
an attenuated form under what is now the Financial Services Act 2012.
130
Above, fn.128, p.85.
131
See Joint Committee on Financial Services and Markets, First Report, Draft
Financial Services and Markets Bill, Vol. I, Session 1998/99, HL 50-I/HC 328-I, pp.61–
67 and Annexes C and D; Second Report, HL 66/HC 465, pp.5–10 and Minutes of
Evidence, pp.1–27.
132
The Financial Services and Markets Tribunal, the predecessor to the Upper Tribunal,
tended to view the penalty proceedings as being criminal in nature for the purposes of
the Convention. However, the standard of proof required by the Convention is not
necessarily that of “beyond reasonable doubt”. The standard will depend, as is the case
with the civil burden in domestic law, on the seriousness of the allegation which has to
be proved. See Davidson & Tatham v FSA, FSM Case No. 31; Parker v FSA [2006]
UKFSM FSM037; Mohammed v FSA [2005] UKFSM FSM012.
133 FCA, above fn.27, para.3.15.
134
MAR art.8(1).
135 MAR art.7(1).
136 See above, para.30–24. However, knowledge or negligence might to relevant to the
size of the penalty imposed: art.31.
137
Case C-45/08 Spector Photo Group NV v CBFA [2010] 2 B.C.L.C. 200. Rebuttable
presumably involves showing that the insider would have traded whether he had the
inside information or not. A specific defence of this sort is provided in art.9(3)—trading
carried out under an obligation which had come into effect before the inside information
was acquired.
138
Above, para.30–22.
139
MAR art.8(2).
140
MAR art.8(3). MAR inelegantly talks about the third party ‘using’ the
recommendation or inducement.
141
MAR art.10(1). The CJEU has indicated that this exception is to be construed
narrowly: Case C-384/02 Criminal Proceedings against Grongaard [2005] E.C.R. I-
9939.
142MAR art.10(3). Unless the transmitter knows the information underlying the
recommendation or inducement, that person would not otherwise fall within the
prohibition because not in possession of inside information.
143 MAR art.7(4).
144
Case C-628/13 Lafonta v Autorité des marchés financiers [2015] Lloyd’s Rep FC
113. This was in fact a disclosure case, but its rationale seems equally applicable to
trading. The Upper Tribunal had taken a different view: Hannam v Financial Conduct
Authority [2014] UKUT 0233 (TCC).
145
In this respect it is important to note that the definition of insider trading quoted
above embraces “financial instruments” and not just the securities issued by the
company.
146
Above, para.30–18.
147 Above, para.26–6.
148 Case C-19/11 Geltl v Daimler AG, decision of 28 June 2012, also a disclosure case.
149 FSMA s.118(4).
150 FSMA s.118(9).
151 The FCA’s Code of Market Conduct gave the following example of RINGA: “An
employee of B Plc is aware of contractual negotiations between B Plc and a customer.
Transactions with that customer have generated over 10 per cent of B Plc’s turnover in
each of the last five financial years. The employee knows that the customer has
threatened to take its business elsewhere, and that the negotiations, while ongoing, are
not proceeding well. The employee, whilst being under no obligation to do so, sells his
shares in B Plc based on his assessment that it is reasonably likely that the customer will
take his business elsewhere”. Query whether this situation would fall within art.7(2) of
MAR (above).
152MAR art.8(5). “National law” is left to determine how these natural persons are
identified. In the UK the rules of agency and employment will presumably be used, in a
form of “reverse” vicarious liability.
153 MAR art.9(1).
154 See para.26–14.
155
MAR art.9(1)(2).
156
MAR art.9(5)(7).
157
ESMA, Final Report: Draft technical standards on the Market Abuse Regulation,
2015, §4 and Annex VIII; ESMA, Consultation Paper: Draft guidelines on the Market
Abuse Regulation, 2016.
158
MAR art.12(1)(a).
159 FSA 2012 s.90. Above, para.30–29.
160
MAR art.15.
161
MAR art.12(1)(b).
162
See FCA, Code of Market Conduct, 1.6.2.
163
FCA, Code of Market Conduct, 1.7.2.
164 MAR art.12(1)(c). See also art.12(2)(d) dealing with statements (not required to be
false or misleading) about a financial instrument where the maker of the statement
already has a position in the instrument but has not disclosed it.
165
Though the defences discussed below are still available.
166 The breadth of the prohibition was thought to put financial journalists at particular
risk and so art.21 provides that the liability of journalists is to be assessed on a basis
which takes into account the codes of conduct governing that profession, provided the
journalist derives no direct or indirect benefit from the dissemination of the information
and did not intend to mislead the market.
167
See Ch.26 at para.26–29, above.
168
See above, Ch.26 at para.26–31.
169 MAR art.2(1) applies the Regulation to MTFs as well as regulated markets and to
derivatives referencing securities so traded.
170 MAR art.12(2)(a).
171 MAR art.12(2)(b).
172
MAR art.12(2)(c). There is considerable debate about the extent to which high
frequency or algorithmic trading can or bring about such distortions.
173 MAR art.13.
174 MAR art13(2).
175
MAR art.13(2) and ESMA, above fn.157, §5 and Annex X.
176 MAR art.13(3).
177 MAR art.13(4).
178 MAR art.13(5).
179 MAR art.13(6). ESMA’s procedure for giving a binding decision is set out more
fully in art.19 of Regulation (EU) No.1095/2010, which establishes ESMA. ESMA’s
power to give binding decisions in inter-Member State disputes is not confined to this
instance, but it must be specifically provided for in the relevant EU instrument dealing
with the subject in question.
180
MAR art.5; ESMA, above fn.157, §3 and Annex 7.
181 FSA 2012 ss.89(3),90(9).
182
At paras 13–11 et seq.
183
See para.26–6.
184
See, for example, FSA, The Listing Rules, May 2000 edition, Ch.15.
185
See above, para.13–15.
186
See above, para.30–6.
187
FSA, The Price Stabilising Rules, CP 40, January 2000.
188Commission Regulation (EC) No.2273/2003 issued under the former Market Abuse
Directive art.8.
189
This matter is currently covered in the Commission Regulation (EC) No.809/2004,
Annex III para.6.5, implementing the Prospectus Directive.
190
Commission Regulation implementing the Market Abuse Directive art.9.
191
Commission Regulation implementing the Market Abuse Directive art.10.
192 MAR art.23(2).
193 MAR arts 27 and 28.
194 MAR art.32.
195
Commission Implementing Directive (EU) 2015/2392.
196
MAR art.32(4).
197 MAR art.24.
198 MAR art.25(1).
199 MAR art.25(2).
200MAR art.25(6). That request may be given effect to in a variety of ways, ranging
from the requested state carry it out itself to the requesting state doing so. ESMA may
coordinate the cross-border investigation if one of the participating states so requests.
201 MAR art.25(5).
202 See para.30–42, above.
203
MAR art.25(7) and arts 17 and 19 of Regulation (EU) No.1095/2010.
204 MAR art.26.
205 FSMA s.169(7) and (8).
206 FSMA s.169(4).
207R. (on the application of Amro International SA) v Financial Services Authority
[2010] 2 B.C.L.C. 40 CA.
208 MAR art.30. A Member State may choose not to have administrative sanctions in an
area where criminal sanctions are available, for example, in the UK under FSA 2012 Pt
7. The UK seems unlikely to take advantage of this provision since it traditionally has
made both types of sanction available to the FCA in the area of market abuse. On the
FCA’s policy about the choice between criminal and administrative sanctions, see FCA,
Enforcement Guide, paras 12.7–12.10.
209
MAR art.30(3).
210
On the potential difficulties with this remedy see para.26–28, above.
211
In other words Member States may set the maximum penalty at a higher level but not
at a lower level than three times the profit or loss. Although the actual penalty imposed
will often be below the maximum, the thought is that the higher the maximum, the
higher the range of penalties actually imposed.
212
See previous note.
213
FSMA ss.124 and 125.
214
FSMA s.126. Sections 392 and 393 extend the warning notice procedure to third
parties, but only if the third party is identified in the FCA’s decision notice: Watts v
Financial Services Authority [2005] UKFSM FSM022.
215
FSMA s.127. MAR art.34 requires decisions to impose sanctions normally to be
published.
216 FSMA s.126.
217
FSMA s.133(1).
218
FSMA s.133(4). Although the hearing function was transferred to the Upper Tribunal
in 2010, the statutory provisions in FSMA, as amended, governing the appeal hearing
continue to apply.
219
FSMA s.133(4). The action must be one the FCA could have taken: s.133A.
220
FSMA ss.134 and 135, even though in the case of market abuse appeals, the
appellant may not be an authorised person. The details of the assistance scheme are set
out in Financial Services and Markets Tribunal (Legal Assistance) Regulations 2001 (SI
2001/3632) and the Financial Services and Markets Tribunal (Legal Assistance—Costs)
Regulations 2001 (SI 2001/3633).
221
Now by virtue of the general provisions applying to appeals from the Upper
Tribunal.
222 FSMA s.174(2).
223 FSMA s.381(1).
224
FSMA s.129; FCA v Da Vinci Invest Ltd [2016] 1 B.C.L.C. 554, where Snowden J
examines fully the scope of this power.
225Chase Manhattan Equities v Goodman [1991] B.C.L.C. 897 at 930–935, where the
judge held that the previous legislative formulation did not prevent the court from
holding a contract unenforceable when it had been concluded in breach of the 1985
Act’s provisions.
226
See especially Lonrho Ltd v Shell Petroleum Co Ltd (No.2) [1982] A.C. 173 HL.
227 1993 Act s.61.
228
The Crown Court has power under the Criminal Justice Act 1988, as amended by the
Proceeds of Crime Act 1995, to make an order confiscating the proceeds of crime, which
could also be used to this end.
229
FSMA s.402(1)(a). This implies that some cases which might previously have been
dealt with through regulatory sanctions will now be subject to criminal prosecution, but
the courts have refused to treat this change of policy as a ground for special leniency
when sentencing offenders: R. v McQuoid [2010] 1 Cr. App. R. (S.) 43.
230
See para.30–30.
231
See para.26–32.
232
FSMA ss.382(9) and 380(6).
233
See Ch.10, above. These powers are in addition to the powers of (probably more
important) the FCA to disqualify persons from operating within the financial services
industry.
234
R. v Goodman [1993] 2 All E.R. 789 CA.
235 cf. the increased importance of shareholder interests in corporate governance, above,
Pt 3.
236
FSA, Updated Measurement of Market Cleanliness, Occasional Paper 25, March
2007.
237J. Coffee Jr, “Law and the Market: The Impact of Enforcement” (2007) 156
University of Pennsylvania L.R. 229.
PART 7
DEBT FINANCE
Introduction 31–1
Difference between debt (loans), equity (shares) and
hybrid instruments 31–2
Should a company use debt or equity in its
financing? 31–4
Different Structures in Debt Financing 31–5
Terminology 31–5
Defining a “debenture” 31–6
Small and large scale loans 31–8
Debts and “debt securities” 31–9
Single and Multiple Lenders 31–10
Single lenders 31–10
Syndicated loans 31–11
Debt securities: distinguishing “bonds” and “stocks” 31–12
Debt securities: trustees for the bondholders or
stockholders 31–14
Issue of Debt Securities 31–15
Private issues 31–15
Public issues of debt securities 31–17
Special rules: covered bonds 31–19
Transfer of Debts and Debt Securities 31–21
Transfer of simple debts 31–21
Transfer of debt securities 31–22
Protective Governance Regimes in Debts 31–24
General 31–24
Defining repayment terms 31–25
Protecting the debt holder against the borrower’s
possible default 31–26
Protecting multiple lenders from their lead
intermediary 31–28
Protecting multiple lenders from each other 31–30
Conclusion 31–32
INTRODUCTION
31–1
A company will inevitably finance itself not only through
issuing shares (of various classes) but also by taking loans or,
alternatively, by making use of credit. Given that around 77 per
cent of UK registered companies have an issued share capital of
£100 or less,1 the need for this sort of alternative funding is
clear.2 Of these options, taking loans, i.e. debt financing,
including its more sophisticated variants, is the main source of
non-equity finance for companies, and is the focus of this
chapter. Nevertheless, most companies (small and large) will
also make use of various forms of credit, including quite
sophisticated forms of asset-based financing.3
One basic divide in all debt financing is between simple debts
(not always so simple in their documentation, and including
large syndicated loans) and marketable “debt securities”4 (with
their obvious parallels with equity securities, i.e. shares).5 As
with shares, debt securities may be issued and traded privately or
on public markets, with the latter being more tightly regulated.
With the terminology, context is important: the terms “debt” and
“debt financing” can be used perfectly generally to embrace all
the options open to a company; only as the terms become more
specific, and “debt” and “debt securities” are contrasted, do they
reveal anything of the nature of the underlying debt instrument.
Some elements of debt financing turn out to be especially
important in the corporate context. We focus on these, especially
the regulated use of marketable corporate debt contracts (i.e.
debt securities), including the transfer of these interests; the
protective creditor-imposed governance constraints common in
all debt financing; and—at various points—the similarities and
differences between debt and equity financing. But some
introductory points are necessary before we can address that
detail. We start with the basic differences between debt and
equity, and the various structural choices in debt financing.
Difference between debt (loans), equity (shares) and
hybrid instruments
31–2
Often the expected sharp differences between debt and equity
are blurred or non-existent. Take the financing decision itself.
The choice is for the directors, and is subject to all their general
duties. At first blush the constraints on directors, and the controls
given to members, seem greater with share issues than with debt:
recall the decisions on “proper purposes” in share issues, and the
statutory rules on pre-emption rights.6 There are no direct
general law parallels when the decision concerns debt, but in
practice many lenders will impose even greater constraints in
their own loan agreements, insisting on contractual terms
prohibiting further corporate borrowing, or at least further
secured borrowing (i.e. negative pledge clauses), unless the
consent of the lender is first obtained.
The same blurring is true of the contrast between members
and creditors: in law a member of the company has rights in it,
while a creditor has rights against it. In reality, however, the
difference between the debt-holder and the share-holder may not
be anything like as clear-cut, for the debt instrument may give
the holder contractual rights akin to those of a shareholder, e.g.
to appoint a director; to receive a share of profits (whether or not
available for dividend)7; to repayment at a premium; to attend
and vote at general meetings.8 Covenants in the loan instrument
may also, as we shall see, give debt holders considerable
influence over the way in which the company is managed.9
Moreover, where the debt instrument is secured by a floating
charge on all the assets and undertaking of the company, the
holder will have a legal or equitable interest in the company’s
business, albeit of a different kind from that of its shareholders.
The line between the holder of a debt instrument and a share is
particularly narrow if the contrast is made with a preference
shareholder, who is a member of the company, but a member
whose share rights may limit the shareholder’s dividend to a
fixed percentage of the nominal value of the share and give that
shareholder no right to participate in surplus assets in a winding-
up, and perhaps only limited voting rights.10 The main difference
between the two in such a case may then be that the dividend on
a preference share is not payable unless profits are available for
distribution,11 whereas the debt holder’s interest entitlement is
not subject to this constraint; and that the debt holder will rank
before the preference holder in a winding-up. Thus, the legal
rules operate with a binary divide between debt and equity, but
the accounting rules and general practice leads to the creation of
securities whose classification in accordance with this divide is
problematic.
31–3
These difficulties of classification are magnified in relation to
securities which are “hybrid” in character, in that the terms of
the issue provide for conversion, whether from a preference
share convertible into debt, or a debt convertible into equity12 at
a later date and on fixed terms. A simple way of looking at such
securities is to say that they are simply one form until
conversion, at which point they become the other. However,
where the bond is required to be converted into equity at a
certain future date, for example, it may be possible to classify it
as equity in the company’s accounts from the beginning, whilst
nevertheless treating the interest payable on the debt before
conversion as deductible for tax purposes, so that the same
security is equity for one purpose and debt for another.13
Notably, these hybrid securities do not provide a mechanism
for avoiding the statutory rules regulating shares. They do not,
for example, provide a way around the prohibition on issuing
shares at a discount to their nominal value.14 And in takeover
situations, debts that are convertible to shares, or debts that have
voting rights, are treated as if they were shares for the purposes
of the squeeze-out and sell-out provisions in the Act.15
Should a company use debt or equity in its
financing?
31–4
How does a company decide what mix of debt and equity is
appropriate for its operations? Clearly its aim is to access the
necessary funds at the least cost to the company. The options
available will depend on the size of the company, the funding
purpose, and the riskiness of the endeavour.16 The choice can be
difficult, since the similarities between corporate debts and
shares are often strong, and can be made even stronger in
“hybrid” securities, as we have seen. With both debts and shares,
the investor has limited liability (limited to the sum invested by
way of loan or share price); with both, the rate of return likely to
be demanded is reduced if the security is highly liquid; and with
both, the desire for some form of governance control is present,
and increases with the risk of the investment. True, the return to
the debt-holder is a binding and quantified commitment made in
advance, and if not met according to its terms the company risks
insolvency.
Despite this, financial economists have suggested that the cost
of capital is unaffected by the debt to equity ratio: this is based
on the Modigliani-Miller propositions that no combination of
debt and equity is better than any other, and that a company’s
total market value is independent of its capital structure.17 This,
as with many economic theories, is based on an “ideal” market.
When real market frictions are included, it seems that companies
may add some debt without reducing the return to shareholders
because the interest payable on debt is tax deductible for the
company, whereas dividends payable to shareholders are not.
But there is a tipping point: too much debt raises the risk of
corporate default, and continuing default on debt obligations
will, in the end, lead to corporate insolvency, whereas for
shareholders it would simply lead to no payment of dividends.
As well as the negative financial pressures of the debt-equity
mix, there are however also advantageous pressures the mix puts
on directors in their management of the company: managers can
be over-inclined to prefer the interests of either themselves or
their shareholders, and debt provides a disciplining effect
because it requires directors to find the funds to make principal
and interest repayments.
DIFFERENT STRUCTURES IN DEBT FINANCING
Terminology
31–5
The literature on debt financing quickly makes it plain that a
wide variety of terms are used to describe different debt
financing arrangements, although none constitute terms of art.
Perhaps because the debt instrument is simply a creature of
contract, and the relationship between debt-holder and company
creates no particular conceptual puzzles—the relationship is
simply the contractual relationship of debtor and creditor,
coupled, if the debt is secured on some or all of the company’s
assets, with that of mortgagor and mortgagee or chargor and
chargee—different terms have come to be used in commercial
practice as a matter of fashion, and changing fashion at that.
Many of the terms now in popular current usage emerge in the
discussions which follow.
Defining a “debenture”
31–6
By contrast, instead of any of the modern terms in use in the
market, the rather old-fashioned term “debenture” is the only one
used in the Act. And even there it is not defined: s.738 merely
says that the term “includes debenture stock, bonds and any
other securities of a company,[18] whether or not constituting a
charge on the assets of the company”.19 This is helpful in
indicating that a debenture need not be secured on the
company’s assets, but not for much else; and indeed commercial
practice rather contradicts this, typically using the word
“debenture” to refer precisely to the proprietary security
agreement which secures the debt owed by the company to its
lender.20
This lack of clear definition is despite the fact that the Act
contains a (short) Pt 19, headed “Debentures”, as well as
frequent references throughout the Act to debentures and
debenture holders.21 The question this raises is whether the term
“debenture”, as defined in s.738, is wide enough to include all
debts (i.e. all loan agreements), or whether it is implicitly limited
to “issues” of debt which have parallels of some sort with issues
of shares, noting of course that the latter embraces private issues
as well as issues to the public.22 The answer matters because of
the particular statutory rules which then apply to “debentures”.
Outside the statutory context, the term is certainly wide
enough to include simple loans. In Fons HK (In Liquidation) v
Corporal Ltd, Pillar Securitisation Sàrl,23 the Court of Appeal
had to decide whether an unsecured debt was a debenture, thus
sweeping it into the assets subjected to a charge. The court
reviewed and accepted earlier authorities which had held that
simple loan agreements could be considered as debentures, and
then held that, in the absence of other contractual terms or
circumstances limiting the definition of debentures in the
contract before them, the term simply meant an
acknowledgement of debt recorded in a written document,
whether or not secured. In doing so, the court rejected the
approach of the lower court which had adopted a criterion of
business common sense in contractual interpretation, and had
held that, since an ordinary businessman would be surprised to
hear a simple loan agreement described as a debenture, the
contractual term did not cover unsecured debts.24
Although this case raised uncertainties in the market about
similar breadth being assumed in the statutory definition, that
seems misplaced. The case itself makes it clear that the
necessary interpretation of agreements (and, by analogy,
statutes) is contextual, and in the statutory context the term
“debenture” is most often used in contexts where the analogy is
with other issued securities.25
31–7
This is especially true of the statutory provisions requiring
registration of “an allotment of debentures” (s.741), the keeping
of a register of “debenture holders” (ss.743 et seq.), and the
prohibition on private companies offering “securities” to the
public, with “securities” meaning shares or debentures
(s.755(5)).26 These provisions are quite inapt for general
application to all loan contracts.
The issue is perhaps less clear in two further contexts, where
the statute overrides equity’s traditional rules. First, s.740
provides that contracts to take up and pay for debentures may be
specifically enforceable, thus overriding the normal contractual
rule that the lender is liable only in damages.27 The arguments
for enforcing subscriptions and underwriting obligations when
an “issue” of debt securities is made may be strong, but they do
not seem to apply to a single creditor who, in breach of contract,
fails to make an advance. Then, damages would seem a perfectly
adequate remedy. The issue does not seem to have troubled
modern courts,28 but giving s.740 a more limited remit could be
achieved either by defining “debentures” more narrowly,
especially since s.740 refers to a contract to “take up and pay
for” debentures (terminology which seems inapt for general loan
agreements); or by relying on the use of “may” in s.740, and
interpreting it as merely conferring a discretion on the court.
Secondly, s.739 specifically excludes irredeemable and long
term debentures from the protective equitable doctrine
prohibiting such “clogs on the equity”. This, too, seems more
appropriately applied to “issues” of debentures, but the statutory
predecessor to s.739 was applied very generally, in 1940, in
Knightsbridge Estates Ltd v Byrne.29 The House of Lords held
that an ordinary mortgage granted by a company was a
debenture,30 and so subject to the statutory provision disentitling
the mortgagor from insisting on its equitable right to make early
repayment. However, even a narrow application of the statutory
provision, holding it inapplicable in this context, might not have
prevented the same outcome on these facts: we might now
simply say that a mortgagor has no right to early repayment
unless the contract provides for it, and that a long but properly
agreed maturity term is not itself sufficient to attract equitable
relief.31
Despite these concerns, the absence of a precise statutory
definition of “debenture” has given rise to surprisingly few
problems, and to even fewer reported cases. In addition, modern
financial markets regulation is typically directed at the product
being issued rather than at the issuer or the investors, and it then
defines its focus more clearly than by use of the broad term
“debenture”. Nevertheless, in what follows we have tried to
avoid the use of the term “debenture” in favour of either more
specific descriptions of the contracts in issue or, by contrast,
when breadth is intended, the more generic term, “debt”.
Small and large scale loans
31–8
Small and medium size companies tend to rely on loans from
banks and, especially in very small companies, loans from
directors and shareholders.32 Salomon33 is an old and typical
illustration. Invariably the loan terms will be individually
negotiated to reflect the risk, and, as we shall see, can be quite
demanding in terms of the ongoing obligations imposed on the
borrower, the potential consequences of any “event of default”,
and the various forms of security (proprietary and personal)
required to support the company’s primary obligation to repay
the debt.
Large-scale debt financing for bigger companies is more
varied. It comes in two main forms: from banks (perhaps by way
of “indirect financing”, so called because the banks in turn need
to seek investment funds from third parties) and from the capital
markets (“direct financing”, because the relationship is directly
with the lender). Here, too, the terms of the debt security are
individually negotiated, even if against industry models.
Sizeable transactions may involve both types of debt. The initial
debt finance for a major acquisition may, for example, be
provided wholly by banks, often under a syndicated loan
agreement34 involving several banks and providing for a variety
of types of senior and junior (or “mezzanine”) debt, the terms
“senior” and “junior” referring to the order in which the debt
falls to be repaid (the ranking of their claims on the assets of the
debtor).35 The banks may, subsequently, offload that debt (in a
wide variety of ways) to third parties so as to realise the value of
the asset earlier than the debt’s maturity date (i.e. capitalise the
debt) or so as to shed some of the risk. On the company’s side,
sometimes this form of bank debt is too short-term and is
provided on such financially unattractive terms that the company
itself has a strong incentive to finance differently or to re-finance
the bank loan as soon as possible.
Debts and “debt securities”
31–9
So far the distinction has been between small and large-scale
loans, and single and multiple lenders. But lenders are likely to
be persuaded to accept a lower rate of return if their loans are
highly liquid. This is not to say that traditional loans cannot be
transferred, as we shall see, but there is no organised secondary
market for their transfer. Thus, as with shares, the company has
an incentive to arrange for its debts, as “debt securities”, to be
traded on a secondary public market, so enabling a lender to
liquidate its investment easily by selling it to a third party.36 It
follows that a company might make an offer of “debt securities”
(analogous in many ways to “equity securities”) on the public
(retail or wholesale) markets, much like a company might offer a
new issue of its equity securities (shares) so as to raise funds. It
might also make similar issues privately. As with shares, public
offers are strictly regulated; private offers less so. This is
considered below, along with the different and rather more
complicated structures used for different debt security issues,
although otherwise many of the applicable rules are those which
have already been dealt with in relation to shares.37
SINGLE AND MULTIPLE LENDERS
Single lenders
31–10
In the simplest of cases, the company borrows from a single
lender. The loan contract between the parties will define their
rights and obligations. As we will see later, their contract will
undoubtedly include covenants restricting the company’s power
to act completely autonomously,38 and may include terms
providing for the debt to be secured against the company’s
assets, or for “equity-like” features (such as voting rights for the
lender), or for conversion from debt to equity in defined
circumstances.
The company may repeat this borrowing process as it grows,
entering into sequential loans agreements with different lenders,
with the general law then governing any competition between
the lenders seeking to have their secured or unsecured loans
repaid. The general law outcome is often varied by agreement
between the lenders (a “subordination agreement”), although the
limitations inherent in these subordination agreements should be
noted: the borrower cannot agree with lenders that the general
insolvency law rules will not apply to the distribution of its own
assets, but that itself some other distribution will be effected; the
lenders, by contrast, can agree amongst themselves to share their
different insolvency entitlements in any way they wish. Thus a
lender who might otherwise have had priority may agree with
other lenders to be deferred; or a secured or unsecured lender
may agree to take nothing until other lenders have been paid in
full.39 It may be wondered why lenders would agree to this, but it
is relatively common for insiders (whether the company’s
directors or other members of the same corporate group) to agree
to be subordinated so as to enable the company to attract further
external financing, or at least to attract it on commercially
acceptable terms.
This all works well for smaller scale financing needs, but if
the company has more substantial needs, then it is likely to need
to access a number of different lenders simultaneously. This can
be achieved either by means of a syndicated loan or by the issue
of marketable debt securities. The underlying contracts for such
loans come in as many varieties as individual loans, with
covenants and security interests as agreed by contract, but each
must also of necessity be overlaid by some sort of organisational
structure which enables the different lenders to co-ordinate their
information and decision needs in relation to the borrower and,
importantly, to control hold-out or independent-mover problems
within the group. These problems are not unlike the various co-
ordination problems which exist between shareholders.40 As
well, it will be in the interests of the lenders themselves that their
chosen structure does not inhibit their rights to transfer their
interests, although only debt securities are deliberately designed
as marketable securities. We discuss these transfer and
governance features later, but first say a little more about the
structures themselves.41
Syndicated loans
31–11
Syndicated loans are typically embodied in a single contract,
signed by all parties, although usually put together by a lead
bank or underwriter of the loan, known as the “arranger”,
“agent”, or “lead lender”.42 This lender may put up a
proportionally bigger share of the loan, or perform duties like
dispersing cash flows amongst the other syndicate members, and
other administrative tasks. But the syndicated lenders are
explicitly not partners, and their interests are deliberately
several, not joint, although, as perhaps one mark of the joint
endeavour, their agreement is likely to provide for “no-action
clauses” and for pari passu recovery should the borrower
become insolvent,43 thus denying any one lender a first-mover
advantage if the debt looks risky.44 As with all agreements
involving multiple lenders, the lenders’ own internal governance
arrangements are often subject to decision by majority rule (as
with shareholders), and to various exclusions of liability by the
arranger: these are considered below.45
It can be seen even from this brief outline that syndicated
loans are essentially scaled up versions of single bank loans (or
loans from non-bank entities), and are likely to contain similar
sorts of detailed protective covenants, although with the
advantage that one lender is not required to carry the entire risk.
As with single bank loans, it is also generally true that these
transactions are not motivated by the lenders’ desire to acquire
marketable securities46; the lenders’ interests may be transferable
under general law provisions, and there is a good private market
in such interests, but these lenders are quite likely to remain
engaged in the deal for its full term.
Debt securities: distinguishing “bonds” and
“stocks”
31–12
By contrast, where marketability of the underlying debt is a
material consideration, the company usually attracts loans from
multiple lenders, again typically financial institutions and
specialist investors, by issuing either “bonds” (or “notes” or
“commercial paper”)47 or “loan stock” (often labelled “debenture
stock” if the loan is secured on a pool of assets, although neither
term is a term of art, and both are often used more broadly).48
Such issues are often tradeable on a public secondary market,49
although this is not essential.50 There was, historically, a
fundamental structural difference between bonds and stock,
although in modern practice both the structure and co-ordination
problems turn out to be rather similar.
Bonds (or notes) are, in theory, individual debt obligations
owed by the company to each of the bondholders, whether they
are registered holders or holders of bearer bonds,51 with the latter
being far more common. Historically, each individual lender
(bondholder) purchased a number of bonds from the company,
denominated in appropriate amounts, much as shareholders
purchase equity interests by buying different numbers of issued
shares. In the same way, too, each bondholder became the legal
owner of its own bonds.52 Co-ordination problems between the
bondholders were, and are still, typically resolved by appointing
an appropriately authorised agent, or, more commonly, a trustee
for the bondholders,53 and also requiring, in certain
circumstances, majority votes of the bondholders themselves.54
However, as with shares, bonds are now typically held via an
intermediary, whether or not they are traded on public markets.
So a “global note” is issued by the company to the intermediary
(representing the debt due from the company to the
intermediary), and the intermediary, as legal owner (of either a
registered or a bearer bond, again with the latter being more
common, except when intended for the US market) holds its
interest on trust for a number—often a large number—of
account holders.55 The intermediary can then perform a number
of important services for the account holders, including holding
any security for the bond, and, at least from a functional
perspective, the resulting organisational structure ends up being
similar to that operating with loan stock.56
Loan or debenture stock, by contrast, consists of a single debt
obligation issued by the company and typically held by a trustee
on behalf of the various stockholders.57 If the loan is secured, the
trustee will also hold the security on trust. The stockholders
therefore have only an equitable interest in the debt (secured or
not), held as tenants in common in proportion to the amount of
the debt they own (with no limit on how the fractions are
denominated, in contrast to bonds). Even as beneficiaries under
the trust, however, the stockholders are nevertheless entered on
the company’s register of debenture holders (in contrast to
equitable owners of shares, who are not recognised in the
company’s register of shareholders58). These debenture holders
receive a certificate (if the stock is certificated); if it is
dematerialised, a similar register is kept in the CREST system.59
It follows that, unlike the largely meaningless distinction
between “shares” and “stock”,60 the similar distinction between
“debentures” and “debenture stock” is far from meaningless and
debenture stock has considerable practical advantages. Thus, in
this structure, the stockholders have all the advantages of a
protective trustee structure, but with the (relatively few)
disadvantages of only having equitable interests in the
underlying asset.61
31–13
One clear difference between bonds (and notes) and stock is that
the former can be transferred only in complete units, whereas
stock is expressed in terms of an amount of money and may be
transferred in any fraction of that amount. This is an attribute of
the transferable interest being merely a fractional equitable
interest in a debt. Thus, if a public company wishes to raise £1
million, it could create £1 million of debenture stock, and then
issue it62 to subscribers in such amounts as each wants,63 giving
each a single certificate of an appropriate denomination,64 and
each subscriber can in turn sell and transfer any fraction of it. By
contrast, the company could issue a series of bonds, say £1, £10,
£100, or £1,000 bonds, each representing a separate debt
totalling in aggregate £1 million. This would result in an
enormous bundle of paper for the company to process and
subscribers to handle. And, if a subscriber for a single bond
wanted to sell half of it, that would not be possible at law, only
in equity.
Debt securities: trustees for the bondholders or
stockholders
31–14
As we have already noted, it is now almost invariable practice
for an issue of marketable loans to interpose a trustee, normally a
trust corporation,65 between the company and the bondholders or
stockholders. The loan contract is then between the company and
the trustee, and any security over the company’s assets can be
made out in favour of the trustees, who hold it on trust for the
benefit of the debt security holders. Such an arrangement has
many advantages.
First, it greatly simplifies the security arrangements.66 A legal
mortgage can be vested in the trustees, on trust for the debt
security holders, and the trustees retain custody of the title
deeds; a charge can be granted in favour of the trustees, and the
rights under the charge document exercised by the trustees for
the benefit of the debt security holders. This is difficult,
sometimes impossible, with multiple parties.
Secondly, the primary enforcement of the loan (and any
security) will be between the company and the trustees, being
the parties to the loan agreement.67 A practical side-effect of this
is to impose equality amongst the debt security holders, although
their own governance arrangements generally reinforce that.68
Finally, it will provide a single trustee corporation or a small
body of persons charged with the duty of monitoring the debt
security holders’ interests and of intervening if they are in
jeopardy. This is obviously far more satisfactory than leaving it
to a widely dispersed class of investors, each of whom may lack
the skill, interest and financial resources required to take action
alone.69 It will also be possible, by the trust deed, to impose on
the trustee company or its directors additional obligations,
regarding the submission of information and the like, which
might not otherwise be practicable.70 Similarly, the trustees can
be empowered to convene meetings of the holders in order to
acquaint them with the position and to obtain their instructions.
ISSUE OF DEBT SECURITIES
Private issues
31–15
The act of issuing debt securities (assuming no public offer) is
not much regulated by the Act. The one significant provision is
to the effect that a contract with a company to “take up and pay
for debentures” is specifically enforceable, as noted earlier.71
Otherwise, in the absence of a public offer, the Act is notable for
the absence of regulation of the issuing process, assuming
instead that debenture holders will themselves make appropriate
provision for their own protection.72
In addition, and unlike the rule applying to shares,73 there is
no rule in the Act, even for public companies, requiring the
authorisation of either the shareholders or the existing debt
security holders for a new issue of debt, although this matter
may well be one of the matters regulated in the trust deed of the
existing debt securities.74 In some ways this is surprising, since a
large increase in the company’s debt could have a significant
impact—positive or negative depending on whether the venture
in which the new funds are embarked is successful—on the
prospects of the shareholders and debt holders.75 Nor does the
Act create pre-emption rights76 on an issue of debt, probably
because the rights of the existing debt holders are not affected by
a new issue, although their value might be, since a company seen
to be overburdening itself with debt would cause the market
value of its existing debt instruments to fall. Again, however,
this matter can be dealt with in the trust deed governing the
existing debt.
Finally, since debt does not count as legal capital, the rules
relating to issue at a discount and to the quality of the
consideration received, which apply to shares,77 are not extended
to debt generally or debt securities in particular.78 For the same
reason, the distribution and capital maintenance rules79 do not
apply to loans, so that interest may (normally must) be paid on
loans even though no profits have been earned, and debts may be
freely repurchased by the company (subject to the loan terms
themselves), assuming in both cases it has the cash to do so. The
only specific statutory provision in this area in fact facilitates
repurchases of debt by providing that redeemed debt securities
may be reissued with their original priority, rather than
cancelled, unless the company’s articles contain provisions to
the contrary or the company in some other way resolved to
cancel them.80
31–16
Of course, the general duties of directors will still apply to their
decisions relating to the issue of debt securities, even, perhaps
especially, in the absence of specific statutory regulation in the
area.
Although all this is left unregulated, the Act does contain a
number of largely administrative provisions relating to the issue
of debt securities. Section 741 requires companies to register an
allotment of debentures with the Registrar of companies, as is
required for shares, so that the existence of the debentures is
public knowledge (unless the debentures are issued as bearer
debentures). A company is not obliged itself to keep a register of
debenture holders, but, if it does, it must locate it and make it
available for inspection by debenture holders and members of
the public in the same way as the register of shareholders.81 This
includes the power, applicable also to the share register, to apply
to the court for an order not to comply with the request for
inspection.82 Probably more important in practice is the
provision which entitles a debenture-holder to be provided at any
time (on payment of the appropriate fee) with a copy of the trust
deed on which the debentures are secured, if, as is normal, there
is such a trust.83 This provision is perhaps the functional
equivalent of the public availability of the articles in the case of
shareholders.
Finally, as we shall see in Ch.32, where debentures are
secured against the company’s assets, it is often necessary to
register those security instruments at Companies House, on pain
of invalidity against the liquidator on the company’s insolvency.
Public issues of debt securities
31–17
Matters change radically, however, if there is a public offer of
debt securities. In that case, much of the law discussed in Ch.25
will be applicable. As with shares, this is to ensure that those
buying debt securities on the primary or secondary markets have
the appropriate information necessary to assess the risks. One
difference, though, is that it might be thought that the risks are
inherently smaller with debt securities, since the holder of a debt
has the ultimate right to sue for the sum due under the debt, and
is also commonly protected by powerful contractual and perhaps
proprietary provisions to assist on that front, whereas the holder
of the share has a mere expectation of benefit and therefore
perhaps requires a wider range of information upon which assess
the relevant risks. This is perhaps the explanation for the
hierarchy of information requirements,84 which puts equity
securities ahead of debt securities issued to the retail market, and
then debt securities issued to the wholesale market,85 and leaves
the private syndicated loan market completely unregulated by
the Act.
The prohibition on private companies offering their shares to
the public extends to a public offer of any securities, including
debt securities.86 If public companies do offer their debt
securities to the public, the required disclosure varies depending
upon whether the offer is general, or is, on the other hand, either
explicitly directed only to sophisticated (“qualified”) investors or
is of such large denomination (i.e. at least €100,000) that it can
be assumed to be addressed only to such a sophisticated
(“wholesale”) market.87 And if the issued securities are then to
be traded on a secondary market, as would be typical for reasons
already discussed,88 the continuing disclosure rules again depend
upon the sophistication of the market participants, with securities
listed on the Professional Securities Market (“PSM”) attracting a
less onerous regime.89
It might be thought that if companies already have listed
shares, then they would automatically opt for the more onerous
regime, since it opens the debt issue to wider markets and the
companies are already subject to onerous disclosure regimes in
respect of their equity securities. However, the specific
disclosure required for a new issue is substantial, and debt
security issues are typically put together in quick order, so
companies will make use of whatever exemptions are possible,
while still ensuring they have access to the most fruitful
markets.90
31–18
All this may change quite substantially in the near future,
however, with the European Commission proposing to remove
these heavy-weight debt exemptions, in the interest of opening
up this exclusive market to smaller investors,91 and achieving
this by removing the incentive to create large-denomination debt
securities, and at the same time putting in place an appropriate
information regime for general investors.
Otherwise, many of the rules on public issues of shares also
apply equally to public issues of debt securities, and for similar
reasons. One notable difference however, is that there is no
limitation on the payment of underwriting commissions, and an
allotment may be made no matter how small a response there is
to the offer.92 This is no doubt because the rights of the
debenture-holder are comprehensively specified in the debt
contract, whereas with shares, the expected returns may depend
very materially on these two features.
Finally, note that an issue may begin as a private issue to an
underwriter or other financial institution, and those institutions
may then themselves provide the necessary disclosure to enable
the securities to be traded on either wholesale or retail markets.
Special rules: covered bonds
31–19
A further means of regulation is focused not broadly on all
public offers, but more narrowly on specifically defined types of
transactions. We see this in evidence in the regulatory regime
which has been put in place relating to financial collateral,93 and
to the credit derivatives market.94 Similarly, specific regulation
has been implemented related to covered bonds, in the form of
the Regulated Covered Bonds Regulations 2008.95 A “covered”
bond (sometimes called a “structured covered bond”) is a
particular form of bond which is payable by the issuer (typically
a bank or building society96), but is also backed by a specific
pool of high quality assets, in the UK held by a special purpose
vehicle (“SPV”), so that the assets are ring-fenced with the result
that, if the issuer becomes insolvent, the repayments on the bond
can continue to be made by recourse to the those assets, and in
priority to the issuer’s general creditors.
The regulations are designed to ensure that the asset pool is
high quality97; that its value is maintained throughout the life of
the bond at a high enough figure to ensure that the bond is 8 per
cent “over-collateralised”,98 thus guaranteeing sufficient
resources to cover realisation costs and bondholder repayment in
full; that there is regulated oversight of the collateral by the
issuer and the “Asset Pool Monitor” (analogous to an external
auditor)99; and that there is consistent and frequent reporting to
investors. These additional reporting and oversight requirements
aside, a covered bond differs from a normal securitisation
principally in that the issuer of a covered bond remains liable to
the bondholder, whereas a securitisation is typically non-
recourse; and the pool of assets associated with a covered bond
is regulated so that the issue is compulsorily “over-
collateralised”.
What has this structure achieved? From the company’s point
of view, it has turned (illiquid) mortgages into cash which it can
use to expand its business. And, conversely, from the investors’
point of view, they have made a loan to the company but of a
highly secure type. Provided the SPV has been set up in such a
way that the assets purchased by the SPV cannot be clawed back
by the issuer in the latter’s liquidation and provided the issuer is
obliged to maintain the quality and value of the mortgages held
by the SPV, the note-holders can remain unconcerned about such
an event because their security will remain intact. This is why
the bond is “covered”.100 Overall, the issuer is incurring debt
through the covered bond in order to further the business of itself
making secured loans to others, its business model turning on its
ability to borrow money through the bond at a lower rate of
interest than it itself charges when lending to others.
31–20
It will be apparent that the above structure can be created by
contract and so it may be wondered how the need for the
Regulations arises. Such bonds were not brought into existence
by the Regulations, though they are a relatively recent
development in the UK. In fact, the purpose of the Regulations is
to create a more ready market for covered bonds rather than to
bring them into existence. The market for them is restricted, in
the absence of the Regulations, by provisions in EU law and,
equally, EU law indicates the way forward to the expansion of
that market. In particular, the UCITS (undertakings for collective
investment in transferable securities) Directive 2009/65/EC (as
amended by Directive 2014/91/EU), which governs what are or
used to be referred to in the UK as unit and investment trusts,
contains the prudential rule that such a body may invest no more
than 5 per cent of its assets in the securities issued by the same
body.101 However, this limit may be raised to 25 per cent in the
case of bonds meeting certain quality standards, set out in the
Directive.102 A similar restriction on investment by insurance
companies and relaxation of that restriction in the case of
UCITS-compliant bonds are also to be found in EU law. Finally,
UCITS-compliant bonds are less heavily weighted in banks’ risk
profiles than non-compliant bonds.103
However, producing a UCITS-compliant covered bond
requires the use of legislation. Article 52(4) of the UCITS
Directive requires (a) that the issuer (which may only be a
“credit institution”, i.e. a bank or similar deposit-taking body) be
“subject by law to special public supervision designed to protect
bond-holders”—presumably additional to the supervision to
which it is already subject by virtue of being a bank—and (b)
that the law control the assets in which the proceeds of the bond
may be invested and ensure the priority of the investors’ claims
in the event of the insolvency of the issuer. It is perfectly lawful
to continue to issue covered bonds which do not comply with the
new regulations, but in this case they will not benefit from the
additional market possibilities, noted above. The Regulations
implement the above principles by creating registers of
“recognised” issuers and issues of covered bonds, access to
which is controlled by the Financial Conduct Authority.104 An
applicant must have its registered office in the UK and be a body
already authorised under the Financial Services and Markets Act
to carry on activities as a deposit-taker and the FCA must also be
satisfied that the applicant issuer and the owner of the asset pool
(i.e. the SPV), will comply with the requirements imposed on
them by the Regulations.105 To claim to issue recognised covered
bonds without issuer and issue being on the registers is a breach
of the Regulations and makes the issuer liable at a minimum to
monetary penalties imposed by the FCA.106
The proceeds of the issue may be used only to acquire
“eligible assets” which term goes beyond mortgages on
residential or commercial real property to include public sector
loans, loans to a registered social landlord which may be secured
on the income arising from letting of the properties as well as
loans secured on the properties themselves, and loans to project
companies under certain types of public-private partnerships.
The property must be situated in any EEA State or in one of a
limited number of other designated States.107 Those assets must
be transferred to an asset pool which must be capable throughout
the life of the bond of covering the bond-holders’ claims and the
costs of administering the pool.108 Priority is given to the claims
of bond-holders in insolvency of the owner.109
TRANSFER OF DEBTS AND DEBT SECURITIES
Transfer of simple debts
31–21
Although the rules on legal capital do not stand in the way of re-
purchase by a company of its debts, unlike its shares,110 it may
well be financially extremely inconvenient for the company to
do so (or indeed it may be prohibited by the lender111). However,
it is normally possible for the lender to find liquidity in other
ways. There may be a private market in the loans, and indeed
many banks lending to private equity funds aim to have only a
small, if any, proportion of the loans made on their books six
months after the transaction completes.112 These loans can be
transferred by outright sales, such as invoice discounting to a
financier (of distressed debt if the rating of the debt security is
poor), or by securitisation transactions (real or synthetic),113 or in
other ways.
The ability to transfer debt in this way helps persuade lenders
to agree to provide finance, but, on the other side, it may also
tempt lenders to worry less about the repayment risks, knowing
that they can shift those risks to third parties. The financial crisis
in 2008 presents clear evidence of this. Where debt securities are
traded on public markets, the compulsory disclosure rules are
designed to minimise those risks for secondary purchasers,
although their effectiveness in this regard might be questioned;
otherwise, as elsewhere, the rule is, “buyer beware”.
Transfer of debt securities
31–22
Turning from transfers of debt generally to transfers of debt
securities, these can be absolute (whether at law or in equity) or
by way of security interest (see Ch.32, below). We do not say a
great deal about the legal rules here,114 since the legislation
clearly assumes that debt securities will be transferred in much
the same way as shares, and so reference can simply be made to
the discussion in Ch.27. Hence, initial allotments and subsequent
transfers of registered debt securities must be registered (s.741,
as s.554 for shares; and s.771 for transfers of both), and the
register must be open for inspection with the right to obtain
copies of it (ss.743, 744); as with shares, the bond
documentation or certificates of debenture stock must be issued
by the company to the holder within two months, unless the
issue is to a clearing house or its nominee (ss.769, 776, 778,
although for debt securities there is no equivalent of s.768
providing for the certificate to be evidence of title); and, as with
shares, the transfer, unless by operation of law or by CREST,
must be in writing using an appropriate instrument of transfer
(s.770). Equally, the Uncertificated Securities Regulations 2001
(as amended) uses the word “securities”, and so permits the
transfer of title to debt securities held in uncertificated form.115
And in relation to these debt securities held in uncertificated
form, the Operator is now required to maintain in the UK a
register of the names and addresses of those holding debt
securities in this way, together with a statement of the size of the
individual holdings.116
Transferees could also be faced with problems, similar to
those in relation to shares, regarding equitable and legal
ownership of debt securities and the priority of competing
transferees. On general principles relating to assignments of
choses in action, a transfer of legal title to a debt security should
be an equitable assignment only, until it becomes a legal
assignment when the company receives notice of it. But, as with
shares, and given that registration is compulsory under the 2006
Act, it seems the legal title should pass from transferor to
transferee only at the later date of actual registration. But it is
now usually only the trustee for the debt security holders who
has legal title to the debt. The question is different, of course,
and can involve nice matters of law, where the transferor’s
interest is only ever equitable, as it invariably is with debenture
stock (notwithstanding that the holders must be registered) and
also with other intermediated securities, as is now common
practice with most marketable debt securities.117
Other differences flow from the fact that, whereas the rights of
shareholders depend mainly on the provision of the company’s
articles, which will have been drafted in the interests of the
company, those of debt holders depend upon the terms of a
contract between lender and borrower and its terms will have to
be acceptable to the lender as well as the borrower. Some debt
securities will, like shares, include non-assignability clauses, or
clauses restricting assignment subject to conditions.118 This
might seem an odd clause to include in a debt, but it will protect
the corporate debtor from losing potentially valuable post-
assignment rights of set-off against the creditor, or protect
against possible transfer of the debt to a third party who may not
be quite so generous in deciding when and how to enforce the
agreed debt covenants. The question then arises, precisely as
with shares, whether a purported assignment in breach of the
anti-assignment clause is effective to give the assignee any rights
at all. The answer, as with shares, depends upon the precise
terms of the clause, but the analysis can be difficult.119
31–23
With marketable debt securities, by contrast, there will be no
problems arising from restrictions on transferability or from a
company’s lien; debt securities will invariably provide that the
money expressed to be secured will be paid, and that the debt
securities are transferable, free from any equities or claims
between the company and the original or any intermediate
holder.120 It is possible that the terms of issue of the debt
securities will be inconsistent with their being held in
uncertificated form, in which case they will need to be altered if
the company wishes to make this form of holding debt securities
available.121 The Regulations do not provide a simple shortcut to
the necessary amendments, as they do in the case of shares, but
they do something to encourage trustees to agree to such
amendments without holding a meeting of the debt security
holders. A trustee for debt security holders is not to be
chargeable with breach of trust by reason only of his assenting to
changes in the trust deed necessary to enable the debt security
holders to hold the debt securities in uncertificated form or to
transfer them or exercise any rights attached to them
electronically.122
The great contrast, however, between debt and equity
securities is that debt securities secured by charges on the
company’s property throw up problems regarding the priority
between conflicting charges. These problems are dealt with in
the next chapter.
PROTECTIVE GOVERNANCE REGIMES IN DEBTS
General
31–24
The terms on which debt financing is agreed will depend upon
the risk-reward calculations between the lender and borrower.
Higher interest rates and greater restrictions on the debtor’s
autonomy, as well as proprietary security, are typical if the risk
is high. As well, where there are multiple lenders, the lending
parties need to put in place co-ordination rules. These aspects are
considered briefly; they are not peculiar to companies.
Defining repayment terms
31–25
A debt security issued by a company (or indeed any debt) is
primarily a matter of contract between lender and company. The
legislature does not specify one, or even a number, of forms that
the debt security must take, any more than it does with shares.
Nor, however, does it even provide any equivalent of the model
articles. It is thus difficult to describe a “typical” debt security.
However, the security will normally have, unlike a share, an
end-date, i.e. a point at which the amount still outstanding has to
be repaid (its “maturity date”)—though it is possible to make the
loan totally irredeemable (s.739). That maturity date can be set
as the parties wish, but may be quite long, for example, 40 years.
The instrument also typically requires the amount lent to be
repaid in regular instalments over the life of the loan (in which
case it is called “amortising” debt), although it is also possible
for the parties to provide that nothing needs to be repaid either
until maturity (which is unlikely in the case of long maturities,
unless the loan is backed by very high quality assets) or only
after a considerable period of time has passed (say, eight to ten
years), at which point the amount becomes repayable which
would have been paid over this period through a normal
amortisation arrangement. Such debt is sometimes called
“bullet” debt, perhaps because of its likely impact on the
borrower.123
The instrument will normally provide for the periodic
payment of a fixed rate of interest at fixed points in time, but
there is no reason why the interest rate so specified should not
vary (provided there is a clear mechanism for working out what
it is at any one time) nor, as we have seen, why interest should
not be “rolled up” and be payable at a later date (sometimes on
the maturity of the loan). In such a case the lender earns a return
by buying the security at a discount to its face (or nominal or
principal) value (i.e. the amount the company promises to repay)
and takes the return as a capital gain rather than income, but only
at maturity or, if the price of security in the market rises, upon
sale to a third party.
The lender may have the right to recall or the borrower to
repay the loan ahead of the repayment schedule,124 or they may
be specifically prohibited from so doing. Section 739 recognises
that the security may be made irredeemable by the borrower, or
redeemable only in certain circumstances, “any rule of equity to
the contrary notwithstanding”. This removes any doubt about the
validity of such a restriction.125
Protecting the debt holder against the borrower’s
possible default
31–26
None of the above clauses provide the lender with ongoing
reassurance that the borrower remains able to repay the debt.
Accordingly, it is common to insert a variety of covenants in the
loan documentation with this objective in mind. Through such
covenants, lenders become part of the corporate governance
structure of the company, and may have a far more significant
impact on management than the shareholders if the company is
near to breaching its loan covenants.
Of course, the extent to which lenders are able to insert such
covenants in their loans depends upon the level of competition in
the market for such loans. For a period in the early 2000s up
until the middle of 2007, competition among banks for the
opportunity to fund private equity buy-outs was so great that
“covenant-light” loans became common, i.e. bank loans with
little by way of restrictive covenants inserted. In more normal
circumstances, however, substantial loans are typically issued
subject to important constraints on management.126
The best protection is proprietary security. That is discussed in
the next chapter. If the lender does not have the bargaining
power to insist on security, or if the company has no further
assets over which security might be granted, then alternative
contractual protections become increasingly important. They are,
however, typically included even when security is taken.
31–27
Loan covenants typically require the borrowing company to
provide the lender with periodic accounting information, perhaps
including credit ratings, to conduct its operations so as to
maintain pre-determined financial ratios between assets and
liabilities, and to refrain from certain defined acts or activities, or
at least refrain from them without the prior consent of the lender.
The list of prohibitions typically includes disposing of
substantial assets, changing the primary business activities of the
company, taking on additional loans, granting further security,
distributing dividends above a nominated level of return, or
changing the management or ownership structure.127 The list of
possibilities does not end there, but their objective is clear. In
addition, the debenture may provide for the lender to be part of
the management of the company by giving it the right to appoint
a director.128
If any of these covenants is breached, the debenture usually
defines this as “an event of default” upon which the lender is
given various rights, usually including the right to accelerate
repayment, to take new security, to enforce existing security, to
impose repayment penalties (drafted, of course, to avoid
invalidity as a “penalty clause”129), and such like. From this list,
the lender can elect the most appropriate course of action. It is
not usual to make the consequences of default automatic, as
undoing their automatic effect can be very difficult if the breach
is, for example, merely technical and one which the lender is
inclined to ignore.
It might be asked what consequences would follow if the
company decided unilaterally to exercise its powers, either at
board level or in general meeting, to subvert these covenants—
for example by the general meeting dismissing the debenture
holder’s nominee director,130 or effecting other significant
changes to the articles. But this is hardly a live issue: the breach
would invariably constitute an event of default, normally
entitling the debenture-holder to require the debt to be repaid
immediately and, if it was secured by a charge on the company’s
property, to enforce the security. This is a far more effective
remedy—and disincentive—than a claim for damages for the
breach. Thus, while the value of the lender’s rights may depend
on the continued prosperity of the company, particularly if the
loan is unsecured, lenders (including debt security holders) are
not normally subject, as is a shareholder, to any serious
possibility that the agreed rights will be varied by the company
by corporate action without the lender’s consent.
Protecting multiple lenders from their lead
intermediary
31–28
With both syndicated loans and debt securities, there is a
“leader” in the collaboration between the multiple lenders, with
the leader typically being the person to whom the corporate
debtor is to make the necessary loan repayments, and who can
enforce the debt, or implement acceleration provisions, or agree
to modifications of the terms of the debenture. Thus, by contract,
the parties provide for collective enforcement of their debt.131
But when things go wrong and the debt is not repaid
according to its terms, or negotiations seem to go awry, these
leaders are especially likely to come in for criticism. Different
obligations are owed depending on the selected debt structure
and the terms of the contractual engagement, but a brief outline
gives the general features.
In syndicated loan agreements, the arranger, in putting the
deal together, will clearly owe a duty of care to the other
participants, although this duty can be expressly excluded in
large measure,132 especially in relation to misrepresentations as
to the features of the loan and the standing of the debtor.133
Whether, during the term of the loan, the arranger also owes the
other lenders general fiduciary duties seems unlikely, unless the
particular facts are such as to call into play such a relationship,134
but otherwise the general rules of contract and tort apply, with
no special statutory overlay.
31–29
By contrast, there is less flexibility with debt securities using
trustees as intermediaries,135 as is now the practice. The debt
security holders are dependent on the trustees for the proper
protection of their interests, and their remedies are primarily
against the trustees, rather than the company. This is made all
the more attractive since these trustees are likely to have deep
pockets, although note that in modern structures with account
holders and a string of sub-trusts, the beneficiary’s only claim is
against the immediate trustee—there is a “no look through” rule
preventing access to trustees higher up the chain. The trustees
are subject to all the general common law, equitable and
statutory duties imposed on trustees, and the extent to which
these can be relaxed by the trust deed is limited, not only by the
common law,136 but more importantly by what is now s.750,
which invalidates provisions in trust deeds (or elsewhere) which
purport to exempt a trustee from, or to indemnify him against,
“liability for breach of trust where he fails to show the degree of
care and diligence required of him as a trustee having regard to
the provisions of the trust deed conferring on him any powers,
authorities or discretions”.137 As a result, the powers and
obligations of trustees are likely to be set out fairly fully in the
trust deed, and to be supplemented, typically, by arrangements
for debt holder voting on difficult issues, so as to protect the
trustee against internal complaints and potential litigation
concerning the exercise of its powers.138
Even so, trustees can be excessively cautious in fulfilling their
obligations. In Concord Trust v Law Debenture Trust Corp
Plc,139 the House of Lords found that the debtor company had
“terrified the trustee” into declining to implement a valid
instruction given to it by the requisite majority of the
bondholders unless the trustee was given an indemnity by the
bondholders against what the court thought was a fanciful
liability to the company on the part of the trustee should the
trustee’s action of declaring a default and accelerating the bond
(i.e. requiring it to be repaid) turn out to be ill-founded.
Protecting multiple lenders from each other
31–30
As well as settling the boundaries for the relationship between
the multiple lenders and their leader, the lenders need some
protection from each other. Typical trust deeds therefore include
“no action” and “pari passu” provisions, expressly prohibiting
individual debt holders from seeking to enforce any rights
against the debtor company, or to recover any more individually
than would be recovered under collective action. In addition, in
syndicated loans, there can be complicated subordination
agreements between the different parties. All these, added to the
formal collective action structure, are designed to prevent any
one party gaining “first mover advantage”.140
But these days the more difficult governance issue concerns
the possible judicial review of voting at meetings of debt
security holders. There has to be a decision-making process, but
it must be such that it does not oppress minorities. The trust deed
typically provides for the security holders to give directions,
often by majority vote (perhaps a simple majority or some
special majority, in number or in value or both, depending on the
issue under review, or perhaps some other agreed regime that
seems, at the time of the agreement, to afford the participants the
necessary protection of their personal interests). This decision is
commonly required to be reached at a meeting of the security
holders, called in an agreed way, with specified notice, and
typically allowing representation by proxies. The parallels
between this contractually agreed regime for debt securities and
the combined statutory and contractual regime for equity
securities is obvious, and so too the legal issues in its
resolution.141
In these circumstances the debt holders do not have the
protection of the unfair prejudice provisions which apply only to
“members”.142 The issues are left to the common law. The first
requirement is that any decision must be fully informed. It is
usually left to the trustee to ensure that proposals are fully and
fairly explained in the circulars seeking the needed consents.143
Further, the courts have applied to decisions of a majority of the
debenture holders binding on the minority the same common law
doctrine applied to decisions by shareholders to alter the
articles,144 i.e. the decision must be made bona fide145 in the
interests of the debenture holders,146 and for the purposes for
which the power is granted.147 Taking each of these requirements
in turn (although in older cases they are often regarded as
comprehending a single test), the limits of the controls become
readily apparent. It is usually impossible to prove absence of
bona fides. Further, as we saw with shareholders, it is often
equally difficult to prove that a decision is not “in the interests of
the debenture holders”, especially if—as with shareholders—this
is taken to mean that the decision is one which the debenture
holders themselves subjectively view as in their interests, subject
only to a rationality test. Indeed, proof that a decision is not in
their interests is generally even more difficult than with
shareholders, since the voting requirement is often designed
precisely to resolve issues where the different debtholders’
interests may be in conflict. Faced with these facts, it is
necessarily the final strand in the test—the proper purposes
aspect—which is to the fore in determining whether the majority
decision should stand.
31–31
However, even a “proper purposes” test does not give the courts
much leverage to intervene, especially where the various
interests of the debenture holders are in conflict, and the vote is
designed (i.e. its purpose is) to resolve the outcome in favour of
one or other side, and there is nothing in the facts which suggests
more than a predictable difference of opinion.148
On the other hand, there are a small number of cases which
show that the rule has some teeth.149 Thus, in British America
Nickel Corp Ltd v O’Brien150 a decision of the majority of the
bondholders, modifying their rights, was invalidated on the
grounds that one of the bondholders, whose support was
necessary for the passing of the resolution, was to receive under
the scheme a block of ordinary shares, with that opportunity not
available to the other bond-holders.151 In the O’Brien case,
Viscount Haldane said that the power of alteration “must be
exercised for the purpose of benefiting the class as a whole”, and
the courts have often been quick to conclude that the purpose is
self-interest, not class interest, where there are particular and
exclusively personal benefits hanging on the voting outcome
(beyond those, of course, which are inherently and necessarily
delivered by the vote itself).
This same approach was adopted by Briggs J in Assénagon
Asset Management SA v Irish Bank Resolution Corp Ltd,152 with
more modern, and more explicit, reference to the equitable
requirement of proper purposes in the exercise of power, and the
need to ensure powers were not used to oppress minorities. This
case involved a more complicated inducement from the debtor
company to the debt holder to vote in a particular way,153
adopting an apparently common technique of requesting “exit
consents”, which offered the debt holder a lower denomination
bond in exchange for a commitment to vote in a way which
would, effectively, destroy or extinguish the existing bond. Of
course, the bondholders who did not accept this inducement
before the pre-meeting deadline (thinking it priced their bonds
too conservatively) ran the risk—the prisoner’s dilemma—of the
vote going against them, and being left with an old bond
rendered almost worthless. Gamesmanship was clearly an
essential part of the debtor company’s strategy,154 and its
effectiveness was ensured because the timing went against
effective co-ordination by the bondholders. But in legal terms,
the real question is what distinguishes Assénagon from
Azevedo.155 In both cases there was an inducement offered to all
bondholders, but accepted only by some; in both the vote
reduced the value of the old bonds. The legal difference cannot,
it seems, lie merely in the size of the inducement or the
magnitude of the devaluation. But quite where it lies is not clear.
These cases reinforce the conclusion that although this
protection is important to debt security holders, and although the
principles in play may be readily stated, they are anything but
easy to apply with confidence.
Where there is some doubt as to the legitimacy of a decision
taken in this way, the parties may feel more secure seeking the
sanction of the court via a scheme of arrangement if the
company is solvent,156 or a company voluntary arrangement if
the company is insolvent.157
CONCLUSION
31–32
From the above analysis it will be clear that the terms and
structure of debt which companies take on are left very much to
be bargained out between lenders and borrowers. Consequently,
most of the law in this area consists of the principles of the law
of contract and the law of property, with relatively little in the
way of special company law regulation, except where the
company wishes to issue its debt securities to the public, or
enable those securities to be traded on a secondary market
(where the rules are similar to those applying to equity
securities), or where the company agrees to give a charge over
its property to secure the loan, which is the topic for the
following chapter.
1
BIS/Companies House, Statistical Tables on Companies Registration Activities
2012/13, Table A6.
2
Apple is perhaps one of the few companies that may not need loans to fund its
operations (although it chose to do so to maximise returns); it can rely on operating
profits, especially as it has also had, until 2012, a policy of not paying dividends on
shares.
3
These forms of financing are not discussed here, but include, e.g. the familiar
mechanisms of hire-purchase, retention of title, conditional sales, sale and leaseback,
finance leases, supply-chain financing, debt/receivables factoring and “repos” (sale on
terms providing for repurchase). These are all well-covered in specialist texts such as L.
Gullifer and J. Payne, Corporate Finance Law: Principles and Policy, 2nd edn (Oxford:
Hart Publishing, 2015). With all of these, proper characterisation can be problematic,
raising the risk that the courts will instead characterise the arrangement as a charge,
which may be void for want of registration: see below, paras 32–24 et seq.
4 With these further subdivided into “bonds” and “stock”, although with the use of
global notes and intermediation, the modern differences between these have become
rather slender.
5 Or—looking at the transaction from the other end of the telescope—we might speak
not of debts and debt securities, but “loans” and “marketable loans”. The latter perhaps
gives a clearer sense of the similarities and distinctions in issue.
6 See paras 16–26 et seq. and 24–6 et seq. respectively.
7 Lemon v Austin Friars Investment Trust Ltd [1926] Ch. 1 (instrument not prevented
from being a debenture because interest payable only out of profit, which might or might
not be earned in any particular year).
8But the debt-holder’s vote should not be counted if the Act requires the resolution to be
passed by “members”.
9 See below, para.31–26.
10 On whether they should be treated as debt or equity, see W. Bratton and M. Wachter,
“A Theory of Preferred Stock” (2013) 161 University of Pennsylvania L.R. 1815. The
classification may be different for different purposes, e.g. accounting purposes, or tax
purposes.
11
See para.12–1. Whether the preference shareholder is entitled by contract to the
dividend, even if the company cannot lawfully pay it, is a separate question. And a
potentially important one, because non-payment of the contractually due dividend may
trigger voting rights for the preference shareholders or affect the amount due to the
preference shareholders when the company returns to profit or is wound up: Re Bradford
Investments Plc (No.1) [1991] B.C.L.C. 224.
12 An alternative to conversion is to issue debt securities with attached warrants which
give the lender the option to subscribe for shares. The debt is then not swapped—it
continues—but the lender has the added benefit of an equity interest in the company.
13 See generally P. Pope and A. Puxty, “What is Equity? New Financial Instruments in
the Interstices between Law, Accounting and Economics” (1991) 54 M.L.R. 889.
14
To issue at a discount debt instruments which can be immediately converted into
shares of the full par value would be a colourable device to evade the prohibition on
issuing shares at a discount (Moseley v Koffyfontein Mines [1904] 2 Ch. 108 CA) but
appears to be unobjectionable if the instrument is convertible only when the debentures
are due for repayment at par since the shares will then be paid up in cash “through the
release of a liability of the company for a liquidated sum”: s.583(3)(c). See also, above
at para.11–15 on debt/equity swaps.
15
See ss.989, 990 (but see ss.983(2)(b) and (3)(b) ignoring such debentures in
calculating the 90 per cent threshold for the exercise of the sell-out right).
16
See the summary in BIS, Financing a Private Sector Recovery (Cm 7923, July 2010),
Ch.3.
17
F. Modigliani and M.H. Miller, “The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the
Theory of Investment” (1958) 48 American Economic Review 433; and also see Miller,
“The Modigliani-Miller Propositions After Thirty Years” (1988) 2 Journal of Economic
Perspectives 99.
18
And, with unhelpful circularity, “securities” are then defined to “mean shares or
debentures” (s.755(5)).
19See below, para.31–13, for more detail on debenture stock and bonds, neither of
which are defined in the Act.
20See below, Ch.32. And unsecured loans are sometimes referred to as “loan stock”, in
contradistinction to “debenture stock”.
21The courts have not done much better: Levy v Abercorris Slate & Slab Co (1887) 37
Ch. 260 at 264; British India Steam Navigation Co v IRC (1881) 7 Q.B.D. 165 at 172;
Lemon v Austin Friars Trust [1926] Ch. 1 at 17 CA; Knightsbridge Estates Co v Byrne
[1940] A.C. 613 HL.
22
See above, Chs 24 and 25.
23Fons HK (In Liquidation) v Corporal Ltd, Pillar Securitisation Sàrl [2014] EWCA
Civ 304 CA.
24 Fons HF (In Liquidation) v Corporal Ltd [2013] EWHC 1801 (Ch).
25 See Tijo, (2014) 73 C.L.J. 503; Roberts, [2014] J.I.B.F.L. 431.
26 Where the difficult issue, if there is one, is usually whether there has been an offer to
the public, rather than whether what is offered falls within the exceptionally wide and
inclusive definition of a debenture.
27Thus overcoming the decision in South African Territories Ltd v Wallington [1898]
A.C. 309 HL.
28
Perhaps because the claim would in any event be regarded as one in debt, not
damages; or perhaps that damages, assessed in context, would in any event give the
company full recovery.
29
Knightsbridge Estates Ltd v Byrne [1940] A.C. 613 HL.
30 Whilst also accepting that the mortgage would not be a “debenture” for the purposes
of some of the other sections of the Act: Viscount Maugham at 624. Clearly such a
mortgage does not have to be registered in the company’s register of debenture holders
under s.743 in addition to registration of the mortgage under Pt 25.
31
See Hooper v Western Counties and South Wales Telephone Co Ltd (1892) 68 L.T.
78; Hyde Management Services (Pty) Ltd v FAI Insurances (1979–80) 144 C.L.R. 541
Aust HC. And in the Knightsbridge Estates case, Viscount Maugham suggested as
much, at least between competent and well-advised contracting parties: at 626.
32
Care must be taken with these transactions. Often, it is true; the insiders provide loans
on very favourable terms. But sometimes the terms are exploitative, and the risk is that
they may then be held to amount to an unlawful return of capital: Ridge Securities Ltd v
IRC [1964] 1 W.L.R. 479; Progress Property Co Ltd v Moore [2010] UKSC 55; [2011]
1 W.L.R. 1 SC.
33
Salomon v Salomon & Co Ltd [1897] A.C. 22 HL. See above, para.2–1.
34
With the various banks using either agency or trust structures to manage their
relationship with each other: see below, paras 31–10 et seq.
35 For a description of typical funding arrangements see FSA, Private Equity: a
discussion of risk and regulatory engagement, DP 06/6, November 2006, paras 3.52 et
seq.
36
So, as with shares, the Stock Exchange can provide a primary market for the issuance
of debt securities and a secondary market for trading in them.
37 See above, Chs 24 and 25 and below, paras 31–17 et seq.
38
See below, paras 31–24 et seq.
39
See below, para.32–12.
40 See above, Ch.19.
41See L. Gullifer and J. Payne, Corporate Finance Law: Principles and Policy, 2nd edn
(Oxford: Hart Publishing, 2015), Ch.8.
42
On the related duties, see below, para.31–28.
43Assuming there is no pragmatic reason for some alternative explicit subordination
agreement.
44See P. Rawlings, “The Management of Loan Syndicates and the Rights of Individual
Lenders” (2009) 24 J.I.B.L.R. 179.
45
See below, paras 31–28 and 31–30.
46 And thus typically are not rated by credit rating agencies.
47 The difference between the two used to be that bonds had longer maturities than notes
or commercial paper, although it was never clear precisely where the line was drawn.
Both terms are now used far more indiscriminately.
48
As already noted, the definition of “debenture” in s.738 includes both “bonds” and
“debenture stock”.
49
In the future, all traded securities will be obliged to be either dematerialised, or
immobilised and held through intermediaries, in order to improve the efficiency and
integrity of the market: Regulation (EU) No.909/2014, recital 11 and arts 3 and 79 (form
1 January 2023 for new issues after that date, and from 1 January 2025 for all
transferable securities).
50
Some would have the necessary characteristics, but nevertheless be traded “over the
counter” (“OTC”).
51
See above, Ch.24, for the equivalent terminology in relation to shares.
52
This was essential if the bond was a bearer bond, and thus intended to be a negotiable
instrument.
53
Although then there is the nice question of what, precisely, is the subject-matter of the
trust: see L. Gullifer and J. Payne, Corporate Finance Law: Principles and Policy, 2nd
edn (Oxford: Hart Publishing, 2015), pp.383–390.
54
See below, para.31–30.
55 For details of the transfer of intermediated securities, see Ch.27.
56
See below, para.31–14.
57Alternatively, the company can create loan stock by deed poll, i.e. by unilaterally
executing a deed which promises to pay those registered as stockholders, which is
enforceable by anyone who is a stockholder. This structure is less common, usually
confined to larger issues with few holders and no active market.
58 2006 Act s.126.
59
See above, para.27–12.
60
See above, para.23–11 where it is noted that conversion of shares into stock is no
longer permitted.
61 Made especially few because the competing interests are also typically equitable, e.g.
sale of stock by a stockholder is sale of an equitable interest, so does not raise the spectre
of competition with a bona fide purchaser for value. But also see Re Dunderland Iron
Ore Co [1909] 1 Ch. 446, 452, and noted below, fn.67.
62 Debenture stock can be created de novo; there is no need to create debentures and
then to convert them to debenture stock as there is in relation to shares and stock.
63
In practice there is likely to be a prescribed minimum amount which can be
subscribed for or transferred. If this minimum amount is equal to the nominal value of
any bonds which the company might otherwise issue, then, of course, this particular
advantage of debenture stock disappears.
64
A simple document of one sheet, similar to a share certificate, in contrast with a bond
which will, unless there is a trust deed (see below, and now almost invariably the case),
have to set out all the terms.
65
Formerly it was common for banks to undertake this work but they have tended to
fight shy of it since Re Dorman Long & Co [1934] Ch. 635 drew attention to the conflict
of interest and duty which might arise when the bank was both a creditor in its own right
and a trustee. Today, therefore, the duties are generally undertaken by other professional
trust corporations.
66 Such securities are, nevertheless, subject to all the rules considered in Ch.32. Note
that it is uncommon for major publicly traded companies today to give security over
their assets in public issues of debentures.
67 Re Uruguay Central and Hygueritas Railway Co of Monte Video (1879) 11 Ch. D.
372; Re Dunderland Iron Ore Co Ltd [1909] 1 Ch. 446. Theoretically, although there are
trustees, an individual security-holder could take steps to enforce the security (using the
Vandepitte procedure: Vandepitte v Preferred Accident Insurance Corp of New York
[1933] A.C. 70 PC), but trust deeds typically contain a “no action” clause. And, in other
respects, the security-holder will not be regarded as a creditor of the borrowing
company, so, for example, cannot petition for its winding up if there is default: Re
Dunderland Iron Ore Co [1909] 1 Ch. 446, 452.
68
See below, para.31–30.
69
Although the governance arrangements typically prohibit this in any event: see below,
para.31–30.
70
See the facts which gave rise to the litigation in New Zealand Guardian Trust Co Ltd
v Brooks [1995] 1 W.L.R. 96 PC.
71
2006 Act s.740. See above, para.31–7.
72 See below, paras 31–24 et seq.
73 See para.24–4.
74
See below, at para.31–26.
75
Even the “Class 1 transaction” rule of the Listing Rules, requiring shareholder
consent, does not apply to an issue of securities, unless the transaction involves the
acquisition or disposal of a fixed asset of the company or a subsidiary: LR 10.1.3.
76
On pre-emption rights for shareholders see para.24–6.
77 See Ch.11.
78 Re Anglo-Danubian Steam Navigation and Colliery Co (1875) L.R. 20 Eq. 339.
79
See Chs 12 and 13.
80
2006 Act s.752. On treasury shares, see para.13–24. Note also s.753 which is
designed to remove the technical difficulties revealed in Re Russian Petroleum Co
[1907] 2 Ch. 540 CA when a company secures its overdraft on current account by
depositing with the bank a debenture for a fixed amount.
812006 Act ss.743–748. Less detail is required in the register of debentures, if there is
one, than in the share register. On the share register, see para.24–21.
82 2006 Act s.745.
832006 Act s.749. Non-compliance is a criminal offence on the part of any officer of the
company in default.
84
See Commission Regulation (EC) No.809/2004 art.21(2).
85 Compare Commission Regulation (EC) No.809/2004 Annexes I, IV and V.
86 2006 Act s.755. See para.24–2.
87 See Prospectus Directive art.3(2)(d) (no prospectus on a public offer of heavy-weight
debt) and art.7(2)(b) (less detail in a prospectus if one is nevertheless needed on an
introduction to trading). FSMA 2000 ss.102B, 86(1), (1A), (1B).
88 Often bonds are traded over the counter (“OTC”), even though the bonds are listed.
Many institutional investors are not permitted to invest in unlisted securities, so listing
sometimes simply provides a necessary quality kitemark (as backed by the requirements
of the LSE for listing).
89
This is the exchange-regulated market, requiring only listing particulars (unless the
securities are initially offered to the public generally). The LSE’s regulated market for
debt securities is the Gilt-Edged and Fixed Interest Market (sometimes also referred to
as the Main Market, as is the analogous market for equity securities, although all debt
security listings are “Standard”, not “Premium”; for this market, a full Prospectus
Directive prospectus is required: see above, para.25–17).
90
This is unless the passporting of the prospectus to other EEA Member States is
important: see Prospectus Directive 2003/71/EC art.17 and above, para.25–44.
91
In November 2015, the European Commission proposed replacing the Prospectus
Directive (an odd Directive in any event) with a Prospectus Regulation as part of its
move to create a “capital markets union” within the EU: see above, para.25–10. The
proposal is to remove the heavy-weight debt exemptions in PD arts 3(2)(d) and 7(2)(b),
so that a prospectus is required for a public offer and more burdensome disclosure is
required for an introduction to trading.
92 i.e. for marketable loans, there is no equivalent of CA 2006 ss.552 and 578.
93
For an informative description, see L. Gullifer, “What Should We Do About Financial
Collateral?” (2012) C.L.P. 1.
94See S. Firth, Derivatives Law and Practice (London, Sweet & Maxwell, 2012); A.
Hudson, The Law on Financial Derivatives, 5th edn (London, Sweet & Maxwell, 2012).
95
SI 2008/346, as amended by SI 2008/1714, SI 2011/2859 and SI 2012/2977. Also see
Review of the UK’s Regulatory Framework for Covered Bonds—FSA and HM Treasury
Consultation Paper, April 2011 (Consultation Paper).
96
There are, in 2015, only 12 UK issuers registered to issue covered bonds.
97
Public sector or residential or commercial mortgages, with the register indicating the
class or the mixture, which cannot then be changed over the life of the bond. In order to
maintain investor confidence, securitisations do not constitute eligible collateral.
98
With the FCA having the right to impose over-collateralisation requirements on a
case-by-case basis.
99
2008 Regulations reg.17A.
100 The structure would be even simpler if the notes were issued by the SPV and the
investors’ money paid directly to it. However, investors may have good reasons for
preferring the loans to be made to the issuer, so that the investors have the benefit of
both the issuer’s promise to repay and the claim on the asset pool held by the SPV.
Where the note or bond is issued by the SPV itself, the arrangement is referred to as an
“asset-backed” or “mortgage-backed” security, but is non-recourse and does not count as
a covered bond. Equally, in the UK, if the issuer merely secures the bond against a ring-
fenced pool of its own assets, without transferring them to a SPV, the arrangement is
certainly a secured bond (assuming the security is properly registered), but it cannot be a
covered bond in the UK (although other European jurisdictions have more relaxed rules
in this regard, adopting what is called an “integrated model” covered bond), but the UK
rules are designed to be as protective as possible to attract the greatest number of market
participants.
101 Directive 2009/65/EC, as amended, art.52(1)(a).
102 2009 Directive art.52(4).
103 HM Treasury and FSA, Proposals for a UK Recognised Covered Bonds regulatory
framework, July 2007, para.1.7. The third advantage, as with the other two, accrues, of
course, to a bank which purchases the bonds, not to the issuer bank.
104
The Regulated Covered Bonds Regulations 2008/346 (as amended) Pts 2 and 3.
105
2008 Regulations reg.9. The owner is not an applicant for registration, though
various obligations are laid on it by the Regulations. The proposals (above, fn.103) did
not envisage a requirement for UK registration, but in this and in a number of other
respects, the “credit crunch” of 2007 caused the Regulations to be more tightly drawn.
106
The enforcement powers of the FCA are set out in Pt 7 of the Regulations and follow
those normally available to it. See para.25–41.
107
2008 Regulations reg.2. Partly, this definition is achieved by cross-reference to
art.129 Regulation (EU) 575/2013 (the requirements regulation), which determines
which assets may be used to collateralise a covered bond, if a bank investing in such
bonds is to benefit from a lower risk rating. However, a recognised covered bond is not
limited to such collateral, though an issuer which uses the wider type of collateral will
not be able to confer the benefit of the lower risk rating on banks which purchase the
bonds.
108
2008 Regulations reg.17(2), imposing the obligation on the issuer; reg.23(1)
imposing it on the owner of the asset pool.
109 2008 Regulations reg.27. The proposals (above, fn.103) envisaged an alternative
model (the “integrated” model) in which the assets remained with the issuer but were
ring-fenced. Insisting on a SPV made the priority issue somewhat simpler to deal with.
110See paras 13–2 et seq. The capital maintenance rules do not apply to debt because
debt is not legal capital: above, para.11–1.
111
Knightsbridge Estates Ltd v Byrne [1940] A.C. 613 HL.
112 FSA, above, fn.35, paras 3.67 et seq.
113 The detail is not examined in this book, but the basic structure is that the bank sells
the securities to a SPV, so that the bank obtains immediate cash (inevitably discounted)
in return for the debts which were due for repayment in the future, and the sale also
ensures that those debts are no longer on the bank’s balance sheet. The SPV then in turn
issues debt securities to third parties on the basis that their repayment is to come
exclusively from the original assets (the debts) now held by the SPV (with the securities
repayable on the basis of this non-recourse liability being, more positively, described as
“asset-backed securities” (“ABS”)). This basic structure has been developed in various
ways. One of these is “synthetic securitisation”, where the debts are not sold to the SPV,
but the SPV instead makes a loan to the bank, secured on the pool of debts, and then the
SPV, as before, issues securities to fund that loan. It is crucial to the success of this
synthetic structure that the SPV can easily enforce its security against the pooled assets,
and to that end the IA 1986 ss.72B–72D enables such floating charge security holders to
continue to be able to appoint an administrative receiver provided the debt is over £50
million, and despite the abolition of administrative receivers generally in the Enterprise
Act 2002 (see below, para.32–34). The credit rating of these bonds then depends upon
the quality of the secured assets, not the overall credit rating of the company.
114 Although there are some difficult conceptual problems, especially with transfer of
intermediated securities: see L. Gullifer and J. Payne, Corporate Finance Law:
Principles and Policy, 2nd edn (Oxford: Hart Publishing, 2015), Ch.9. As a result, the
trust deeds of debenture stock issues or the documentation associated with bond issues
typically provide explicitly that the holder takes free of all equities affecting the current
and previous holders (including the account holder for bond issues). The effectiveness of
these provisions is not guaranteed, and clear wording is essential: see Re Kaupthing
Singer and Friedlander Ltd; Newcastle Building Society v Mill [2009] EWHC 740 (Ch).
115
Reg.19 and the definition of “security” in reg.3(1). See generally Ch.27, above.
116
Uncertificated Securities Regulations 2001 reg.22(3). If the terms of issue of the
debentures require the company to maintain a register of holders in the UK, then this
rule still applies but the company’s register reflects that of the Operator: reg.22(1) and
(2).
117
The details are not discussed here, but the difficult issues of analysis are well
described in L. Gullifer and J. Payne, Corporate Finance Law: Principles and Policy,
2nd edn (Oxford: Hart Publishing, 2015), Ch.9.
118
In Barbados Trust Co Ltd v Bank of Zambia [2007] EWCA Civ 148, where consent
of the debtor was required, such consent not to be unreasonably withheld.
119See Barbados Trust Co Ltd v Bank of Zambia [2007] EWCA Civ 148; Linden
Gardens Trust Ltd v Lenesta Sludge Disposal Ltd [1994] 1 A.C. 85; Morris v Royal
Bank of Scotland Plc unreported 3 July 2015 No. HC-2014-001910 Norris J; R. Goode,
“Inalienable Rights?” (1979) 42 M.L.R. 553; M. Bridge, “The Nature of Assignment and
Non-Assignment Clauses” (2016) 132 L.Q.R. 47; L. Gullifer and J. Payne, Corporate
Finance Law: Principles and Policy, 2nd edn (Oxford: Hart Publishing, 2015), pp.434–
443.
120 Without this, debenture holders and their transferees would be in grave danger, for a
debenture, unless in bearer form and thus a negotiable instrument (Bechuanaland
Exploration Co v London Trading Bank Ltd [1898] 2 Q.B. 658), would, as a chose in
action, be transferable only subject to the state of the account between the company and
the transferor. As stressed in Ch.27, neither shares (unless in the form of share warrants
to bearer) nor debentures (unless bearer bonds) are negotiable instruments like bills of
exchange. Although CARD (above, para.25–15) requires listed shares and debt
securities to be “freely negotiable” (arts 46 and 60) this is interpreted as “freely
transferable” and not as prescribing that they must be “negotiable instruments” in full
sense.
121 See Ch.27, above.
122
2008 Regulations reg.40(2), provided notice is given to the holders at least 30 days
before the changes become effective.
123
Where such debt is part of a private equity transaction, it is a strong candidate for
early re-financing.
124 And, for example, bank overdrafts are typically repayable on demand and regardless
of breach (unless the facility agreement provides otherwise), with the bank not required
to refrain from making a demand simply because it will tip the company into insolvency:
Williams and Glyn’s Bank Ltd v Barnes [1981] Com. L.R. 205.
125 See above, para.31–7.
126 Bratton, “Bond Covenants and Creditor Protection” (2006) 7 E.B.O.R. 39.
127
However, since these are contractual restrictions, they will not bind third parties (in
whose favour, for example, assets have been pledged in breach of covenant), unless
equity will intervene (see above, para.16–134), or the ingredients of the tort of inducing
breach of contract have been established, notably knowledge on the part of the third
party of the contractual restrictions: Swiss Bank Corp v Lloyds Bank Ltd [1979] Ch. 548.
128
Of course, such nominee directors owe their duties to the company, not the nominee:
see the discussion above, para.16–63.
129
Lordsvale Finance Plc v Bank of Zambia [1996] Q.B. 752; although now see
Cavendish Square Holding BV v Talal El Makdessi; ParkingEye Ltd v Beavis [2015]
UKSC 67.
130
See above, para.19–25. It seems clear that an injunction could not be granted to
restrain the general meeting from removing a nominated director under s.168.
131
Elektrim SA v Vivendi Holdings 1 Corp [2008] EWCA Civ 1178.
132
IFE Fund SA v Goldman Sachs International [2007] EWCA Civ 811 at [28];
Raiffeisen Zentralbank Osterreich AG v Royal Bank of Scotland Plc [2010] EWHC 1392
at [65].
133 Peekay Intermark v ANZ Banking Group [2006] EWCA Civ 386.
134
Although see the dicta in UBAF Ltd v European American Banking Corp [1984]
Q.B. 713, 728.
135 It is possible, although now less common, for the company to issue bonds directly to
the bondholders, and for the bondholders then to appoint an agent to act as their point of
contact. Such an appointed agent will have whatever powers are expressly agreed by the
parties, and these may well be fewer than those typically enjoyed by a trustee for the
bondholders in a structure where the trustee holds the global note and any associated
security on trust for the bondholders. But such an agent is nevertheless subject to
common law and equitable duties, providing the bondholders with fairly extensive
protection.
136
Armitage v Nurse [1998] 1 Ch. 241. Although see the pro-trustee approach to
restrictive clauses in Citibank NA v MBIA Assurance SA [2006] EWHC 3215. Also see
M. Bryan, “Contractual Modification of the Duties of a Trustee” in S. Worthington,
(ed.), Commercial Law and Commercial Practice (Oxford, Hart Publishing, 2003),
p.513.
137 But note the exceptions and qualifications in subss.(2)–(4) permitting 75 per cent in
value of the debenture holders present and voting to give a release from liability to the
trustee in respect of prior specific acts or omissions of the trustee (or on the latter’s death
or ceasing to act). In addition, reg.40(2) of the Uncertificated Securities Regulations
2001 (above, Ch.27) exempts the trustees from liability simply for assenting to
amendments of the trust deed to enable title to debentures to be held and transferred
under the electronic system and for rights attached to debentures to be exercised in that
way.
138Especially if the trustee’s opinion differs: see Citibank NA v MBIA Assurance SA
[2006] EWHC 3215 (Ch); [2007] EWCA Civ 11 (see “Issue 2” in the Court of Appeal);
and Law Debenture Trust Corp Plc v Concord Trust [2007] EWHC 1380.
139Concord Trust v Law Debenture Trust Corp Plc [2006] 1 B.C.L.C. 616 HL. The
event of default was a failure to maintain on the board of the borrowing company a
nominee of the lenders, who had been placed there to protect the bond-holders’ interests.
Having accelerated the bond, as a consequence of the HL judgment, and secured
substantial payments from the company, the trustee then took an overly cautious line
about how much of the monies recovered it could distribute to the bond-holders: Law
Debenture Trust Corp Plc v Concord Trust [2007] EWHC 1380 (Ch).
140
The aim is to achieve, by contract between the multiple lenders alone, at least the
level of protection that the IA 1986 attempts to deliver between all unsecured creditors,
despite the fact that they are often strangers to each other. See below, Ch.33. See above,
paras 31–24 et seq.
141
See above, paras 19–4 et seq.
142
See para.20–1. Nor, of course, will the class rights provisions afford protection as
they too apply only to members. See para.19–13.
143
The Listing Rules require that any circular must include an explanation of the effect
of proposed amendments: LR 17.3.10.
144
See the detailed discussion at paras 19–4 et seq., much of which is equally relevant
here.
145 Goodfellow v Nelson Line (Liverpool) Ltd [1912] 2 Ch. 324, 333.
146 British America Nickel Corp Ltd v MJ O’Brien [1927] A.C. 369, 371; Redwood
Master Fund Ltd v TD Bank Europe Ltd [2002] EWHC 2703; [2006] 1 B.C.L.C. 149 at
[84], a case concerning syndicated lenders, relying on the shareholder case of
Greenhalgh v Ardene Cinemas Ltd [1951] Ch. 286, 291; and Law Debenture Trust Corp
Plc v Concord Trust [2007] EWHC 1380 at [123]; Assénagon Asset Management SA v
Irish Bank Resolution Corp Ltd [2012] EWHC 2090 (Ch).
147Redwood Master Fund Ltd v TD Bank Europe Ltd [2002] EWHC 2703; [2006] 1
B.C.L.C. 149 at [101]–[105]; Assénagon Asset Management SA v Irish Bank Resolution
Corp Ltd [2012] EWHC 2090 (Ch) at [85]–[86].
148
See the detailed analysis in Redwood Master Fund Ltd v TD Bank Europe Ltd [2002]
EWHC 2703; [2006] 1 B.C.L.C. 149.
149
R. Peel, “Assessing the Legality of Coercive Restructuring Tactics in UK Exchange
Offers” (2015) 4 UCL Journal of Law and Jurisprudence 162.
150 British America Nickel Corp Ltd v O’Brien [1927] A.C. 369 PC.
151
There appears to be no problem if the opportunity to benefit by voting in a particular
way is fully disclosed and available to all members of the class: Azevedo v IMCOPA —
Importacao, Exportaacao e Industria de Oleos Ltda [2013] EWCA Civ 364.
152
Assénagon Asset Management SA v Irish Bank Resolution Corp Ltd [2012] EWHC
2090 (Ch). Briggs J also held, as an alternative, that the vote belonged beneficially to,
and was exercised by, the debtor company, in contravention of the trust deed, so the
decision of the majority could not stand because the majority had no power to exercise,
i.e. on these facts, the same result could be delivered by an analysis based on absence of
power, or, alternatively (as discussed here), on abuse of power.
153As in Azevedo v IMCOPA – Importacao, Exportaacao e Industria de Oleos Ltda
[2013] EWCA Civ 364.
154Otherwise the same outcome might have been achieved by a straightforward vote to
devalue the old bond to the value of the offered inducement.
155
See above, fnn.146 and 151.
156 2006 Act s.895; see above, paras 29–1 et seq. But note Re Lehman Brothers
International (Europe) (In Administration) [2009] EWCA Civ 1161, indicating that
beneficial owners (as opposed to creditors, even those with security) cannot avail
themselves of these provisions.
157
2006 Act s.899; see below, para.29–24.
CHAPTER 32
COMPANY CHARGES
Introduction 32–1
Security Interests 32–2
The legal nature of security interests 32–2
The benefits of taking security 32–4
The Floating Charge 32–5
The practical differences between fixed and floating
charges 32–5
Crystallisation 32–8
Priority accorded to floating charges 32–10
Statutory limitations on the floating charge 32–13
Distinguishing between fixed and floating charges 32–21
Registration of Charges 32–24
The purpose of a registration system 32–24
The reformed registration system 32–26
Reform proposals and registration systems
elsewhere 32–33
Enforcement of Floating Charges 32–34
Receivers and administrators 32–34
Receivership 32–37
Administration 32–43
Conclusion 32–51
INTRODUCTION
32–1
Borrowers are often obliged to provide security for the
repayment of their debts. In this respect a company is no
different from any other borrower. However, there are
sufficiently unique features associated with the granting of
security by a company to justify it being treated here as a
separate topic. In particular, one type of security (the floating
charge) is practicable only if created by a body corporate,1 there
is a separate system for the registration of company charges,2
there are distinct statutory procedures for the enforcement of the
floating charge,3 and certain provisions of the Insolvency Act
1986 affecting company charges apply on corporate insolvency.
Coupled with these, the granting of security by a company is
subject to the law relating to corporate capacity and directors’
duties,4 although compliance in that regard is assumed in what
follows.
SECURITY INTERESTS
The legal nature of security interests
32–2
Some knowledge of this general topic is essential in order to
understand the particular nature of the rights conferred on a
secured charge holder, the priorities of charges, and the system
for the registration of company charges.5 Some understanding is
also needed of nomenclature. Various forms of security are
possible, as described below, but the most common form granted
by a company is a charge. “Charge” has a restricted technical
meaning in equity, although this technical distinction is not
always maintained in the literature or in the Act,6 and, unless the
context indicates otherwise, the terms “charge”, “security” or
“security interest” are often used interchangeably.
Browne-Wilkinson VC, without claiming that it was
comprehensive, accepted the following as a description of a
security interest7:
“Security is created where a person (‘the creditor’) to whom an obligation is owed
by another (‘the debtor’) by statute or contract, in addition to the personal promise
of the debtor to discharge the obligation, obtains rights exercisable against some
property in which the debtor has an interest in order to enforce the discharge of the
debtor’s obligation to the creditor.”
Introduction 33–1
Types of Winding Up 33–2
Winding up by the court 33–3
Voluntary winding up—general 33–9
Members’ voluntary winding up 33–11
Creditors’ voluntary winding up 33–13
Powers and Duties of the Liquidator 33–16
Collection, Realisation and Distribution of the Company’s
Assets 33–17
Maximising the assets available for distribution 33–17
Proof of debts and mandatory insolvency set off 33–22
Distribution of the company’s assets 33–24
Dissolution 33–27
After winding up 33–27
Striking off of defunct companies 33–29
Voluntary striking off 33–30
Resurrection of Dissolved Companies 33–31
Administrative restoration 33–32
Restoration by the court 33–33
Conclusion 33–34
INTRODUCTION
33–1
Where a company no longer has the funds to function, or its
members no longer wish it to function, then there needs to be a
process for bringing the existence of the legal entity to an end.
This is achieved by winding up, or liquidation (the two terms can
be used interchangeably).1 The process of winding up, or
liquidation, is designed to ensure that, before the company
ceases to exist, all its outstanding obligations are met (so far as
they can be) and any surplus assets (if there are any) are
distributed to the members according to their agreed
entitlement.2 For reasons which might be obvious, especially
given the competing interests which may need to be balanced,
this process is not undertaken by the company’s own directors,
but by independent appointees who are qualified insolvency
practitioners and who act professionally as company liquidators
(alternatively, in some circumstances, the process is carried out
by the Official Receiver). When this process is completed, the
company is removed from the register: it is “dissolved”. Clearly
this is a dramatic step, and, as we have seen already, there are
less terminal alternatives which may provide avenues for the
successful rescue of failing companies: recall the use of
administration, administrative receivership and company
voluntary arrangements and reconstructions, often also making
use of professional outsiders.3
The provisions relating to winding up and dissolution are now
to be found almost exclusively4 in the Insolvency Act 1986 and
Pt IV of the Insolvency Rules,5 and not in the Companies Act:
and rightly so where the company is insolvent. But, although
insolvency is the most common reason for winding up, it is far
from being the only one and, when the company is fully solvent,
it seems, on the face of it, somewhat illogical to treat the process
as part of insolvency law rather than company law. The reason
why the legislation relating to liquidation of solvent companies
is in the Insolvency Act is probably to avoid duplicating those
many provisions that apply whether or not the company is
insolvent—to repeat them in the Companies Act would have
added substantially to the length of the combined legislation. But
it can also be justified as realistic. Once a company goes into
liquidation, the distinction between shareholders and creditors
becomes more than usually difficult to draw: the members’
interests will, in effect, have become purely financial interests
deferred to those of the creditors.
TYPES OF WINDING UP
33–2
The basic distinction is between voluntary winding up and
compulsory winding up by the court.6 But voluntary winding up
is subdivided into two types—members’ voluntary winding up
and creditors’ voluntary winding up. In relation to companies
registered under the Companies Acts which are dealt with in Pt
IV of the Insolvency Act, Chs I and VII–X of that Part relate to
all three types, except where it is otherwise stated; Chs II and V
relate to both types of voluntary winding up; Ch.III relates only
to members’ voluntary winding up; Ch.IV only to creditors’
voluntary winding up; and Ch.VI only to winding up by the
court. This arrangement of the sections is not exactly “user
friendly” for it means that, to grasp which sections apply to the
type of winding up with which one is concerned, it is necessary
to refer to various chapters of Pt IV. Nor is life made easier
because other Parts of the Act may also be relevant: for example
Pt VI on “miscellaneous provisions” and Pt VII on
“interpretation for first group of Parts”.
As their names imply, an essential difference between
compulsory winding up by the court and voluntary winding up is
that the former does not necessarily involve action taken by any
organ of the company itself, whereas voluntary winding up does.
The essential difference between members’ and creditors’
winding up is that the former is possible only if the company is
solvent, in which event the company’s members appoint the
liquidator, whereas, if it is not, its creditors have the whip hand
in deciding who the liquidator shall be. In all three cases, the
winding up process is not exclusively directed towards realising
the assets and distributing the net proceeds to the creditors and,
if anything is left, to the members, according to their respective
priorities; it also enables an examination of the conduct of the
company’s management to be undertaken. This may result in
civil and criminal proceedings being taken against those who
have engaged in any malpractices thus revealed7 and in the
adjustment or avoidance of various transactions.8
Winding up by the court
Grounds for winding up
33–3
Under s.122 of the Insolvency Act, a company may be wound up
by the court9 on one or more of eight specified grounds. Of these
grounds, by far the most important is ground (f), that the
company is unable to pay its debts, and the next most important
is ground (g), that the court is of the opinion that it is just and
equitable that the company should be wound up. The latter has
been dealt with in Ch.20 (where we saw that it may be used as a
remedy in cases where members are being unfairly prejudiced or
there is a deadlocked management) and in Ch.18 (where we saw
that it may be invoked by the Secretary of State following the
exercise of his or her investigatory powers). The presence of a
minority protection remedy in the Insolvency Act is, in fact,
something of an anomaly.
Who may petition for a court ordered winding up?
33–4
It should be noted that the company itself can opt for winding up
by the court, since ground (a) is that the company has by special
resolution resolved that the company be so wound up. But
normally that is the last thing that those controlling the company
will want: winding up by the court is the most expensive type of
winding up and the one in which their conduct is likely to be
investigated most thoroughly.10 Alternatively, s.124 makes it
clear that a wide range of people may, in different and
sometimes specifically limited circumstances, petition for the
winding up of a company by the court; the list includes the
company’s directors, its members,11 its creditors (including
prospective and contingent creditors), and various parties with
official public status.12
Proof that a company is unable to pay its debts
33–5
Creditors are among those who may petition for a winding up13
and this they are likely to do once it becomes widely known that
the company is in financial difficulties14; like a petition for the
bankruptcy of an individual, a petition for winding up is the
creditors’ ultimate remedy. Indeed, about 95 per cent of petitions
for court ordered winding ups are by creditors. And although the
company itself or its directors15 or members16 may petition, the
court will be reluctant to grant it on ground (f) if it is opposed by
a majority of the creditors.
The Insolvency Act s.123 affords creditors owed more than
£750 a simple means of establishing ground (f), that the
company is unable to pay its debts, by serving a “statutory
demand”.17 Because of the presumption of insolvency inherent in
this, the courts are astute to prevent creditors relying on the sub-
section if the debt itself is disputed,18 or if the sum is disputed so
that £750 may not be owed,19 or if the statutory demand has not
been properly put together or properly served.20 Otherwise, it is
usually necessary for the creditor to prove “to the satisfaction of
the court that the company is unable to pay its debts as they fall
due”.21
The court’s discretion
33–6
The court has a statutory discretion to refuse to order a winding
up on a contributor’s petition if some other remedy is available
and it seems that the petitioners are acting unreasonably in
seeking this rather drastic option.22 In addition, the court has an
inherent jurisdiction to refuse to make the order if it considers
the petition to have been brought for improper or extraneous
purposes,23 and may simply strike out as an abuse of process any
petition which is bound to fail.24
Liquidators, provisional liquidators and official
receivers
33–7
If a winding up order is made, the first step needing to be taken
will be to appoint a liquidator to whom, as in all types of
winding up, the administration of the company’s affairs and
property will pass. In contrast with an individual’s trustee in
bankruptcy, the company’s property does not vest in the
liquidator25; but the control and management of it and of the
company’s affairs do, and the board of directors, in effect,
becomes functus officio.26 A liquidator may, indeed, be
appointed before a final order for winding up is made, for at any
time after the presentation of a winding up petition the court may
appoint a provisional liquidator, normally the official receiver
attached to the court.27
The important role played by official receivers in compulsory
liquidations in England and Wales28 is perhaps the major
difference between compulsory and voluntary liquidations.29
Official receivers are officers of the Insolvency Service, an
Executive Agency of BIS, attached to courts having bankruptcy
jurisdiction.30 Not only will an OR normally be the provisional
liquidator (if one is appointed) but he or she will generally be the
initial liquidator and often will remain the liquidator throughout
in a court ordered winding up. On the making of a winding up
order31 the OR automatically becomes liquidator by virtue of his
or her office and will remain so unless and until another
liquidator is appointed.32 The OR may succeed in getting rid of
the office by summoning separate meetings of the creditors and
of the members for the purpose of appointing another
liquidator.33 And if that does not succeed,34 the OR may decide
to refer the need to appoint another liquidator to the Secretary of
State who may appoint.35 But, whenever any vacancy occurs, the
OR again becomes the liquidator until another is appointed.36
The liquidator, provisional liquidator and official receiver are
all officers of the court, required to behave as such, if they have
been appointed by the court to execute a court ordered
compulsory liquidation.
Whether or not the official receiver becomes the liquidator,
the OR has important investigatory powers and duties. When the
court has made a winding up order, the OR may require officers,
employees and those who have taken part in the formation of the
company to submit a statement as to the affairs of the company
verified by affidavit.37 It is the duty of the OR to investigate the
causes of the failure, and to make such report, if any, to the court
as he or she thinks fit.38 The OR may apply to the court for the
public examination of anyone who is or has been an officer,
liquidator, administrator, receiver or manager of the company, or
anyone else who has taken part in its promotion, formation or
management, and must do so, unless the court otherwise orders,
if requested by one-half in value of the creditors or three-
quarters in value of the members.39 And if the OR is not the
liquidator, the person who is must give the OR all the
information and assistance reasonably required for the exercise
of these functions.40
Once a liquidator is appointed, the process of the winding up
proceeds very much as it would in the case of a voluntary
liquidation since the objective is identical and the liquidator’s
functions are the same as those in voluntary windings up,
namely “to secure that the assets of the company are got in,
realised, and distributed to the company’s creditors41 and, if
there is a surplus, to the persons entitled to it”.42 The main
difference is that, in a winding up by the court, the liquidator in
the exercise of powers given under Sch.4 to the Insolvency Act
will more often be required to obtain the sanction of the court
before entering into transactions, and that throughout the
liquidation process the liquidator will be subject to the
surveillance of the OR, acting, in effect, as an officer of the
court.
In a court-ordered winding up where the liquidator is not the
OR, the creditors may appoint a “liquidation committee”, so that
they have some formal voice in the liquidation proceedings.43
Timing of commencement of winding up
33–8
On the making of a winding up order the winding up is deemed
to have commenced as from the date of the presentation of the
petition (or, indeed, if the order is made in respect of a company
already in voluntary winding up, as from the date of the
resolution to wind up voluntarily).44 This dating back is
important since it can have the effect of invalidating property
dispositions45 and executions of judgments46 lawfully undertaken
during the period between the presentation of the petition and the
order,47 and of affecting the duration of the periods prior to “the
onset of insolvency” in which, if certain transactions are
undertaken, they are liable to adjustment or avoidance in the
event of winding up or administration.48
Voluntary winding up—general
Instigation of winding up
33–9
In contrast with winding up by the court, voluntary winding up
always starts with a resolution of the company. In the unlikely
event of the articles fixing a period for the duration of the
company49 or specifying an event on the occurrence of which it
is to be dissolved,50 all that is required is an ordinary resolution
in general meeting.51 Otherwise, what is required is a special
resolution that the company be wound up voluntarily.52 In either
case the resolution is subject to the requirement that a copy of it
has to be sent to the Registrar within 15 days53 and the company
must give notice of the resolution by advertisement in the
Gazette within 14 days of its passing.54
Timing of commencement of winding up
33–10
A voluntary winding up is deemed to commence on the passing
of the resolution55; there is no “relating back” as there is in the
case of winding up by the court. As from the commencement of
the winding up, the company must cease to carry on its business,
except so far as may be required for its beneficial winding up,56
and any transfer of shares, unless made with the sanction of the
liquidator, is void, as is any alteration in the status of the
members.57
Members’ voluntary winding up
Declaration of solvency
33–11
The most important question which the directors of the company
will have had to consider prior to the passing of the resolution is
whether they can, in good conscience and without dire
consequences to themselves, allow the voluntary winding up to
proceed as a members’, as opposed to a creditors’, winding up.
In order for that to occur they, or if there are more than two of
them, the majority of them, must, in accordance with IA 1986
s.89, make at a directors’ meeting58 a statutory declaration (the
“declaration of solvency”) to the effect that they have made a
full inquiry into the company’s affairs and that, having done so,
they have formed the opinion that the company will be able to
pay its debts in full, together with interest at the “official rate”,59
within such period, not exceeding 12 months from the
commencement of the winding up, as may be specified in the
declaration.60 This was the origin of the declaration of solvency
now used in the out-of-court procedure for a reduction of
capital61 and in respect of an acquisition of shares out of
capital.62
The declaration is ineffective unless:
(a) it is made within five weeks preceding the date of the passing
of the resolution; and
(b) it embodies a statement of the company’s assets and
liabilities as at the latest practicable date before the making of
the declaration.63
If a director makes the declaration without having reasonable
grounds for believing that the company will be able to pay its
debts with interest within the period specified in the declaration,
he or she is liable to a fine and imprisonment,64 and if the debts
are not so paid it is presumed, unless the contrary is shown, that
the director did not have reasonable grounds for that opinion.65 It
therefore behoves the directors to take the utmost care and to
seek professional advice before they make the declaration.
Especially is this so because, even if the winding up is a
members’ one, a licensed insolvency practitioner will have to be
appointed as liquidator and the liquidator is likely to detect
whether the declaration was over-optimistic long before the
expiration of the 12 months. Formerly, small private companies
could, and often did, appoint as liquidator one of the directors
and, in effect, continued to proceed much as they would have
when a partnership was being dissolved. This is no longer
possible66: despite the efforts begun by the 1989 Act to reduce
the burdens on private companies, the Insolvency Act has
increased their burdens as regards winding up even if they are
quasi-partnerships.
If the professional liquidator, appointed as described below,
forms the opinion that the company will not be able to pay its
debts within the stated period, he or she must summon a meeting
of the creditors and supply them with full information in
accordance with IA 1986 s.95 and, as from the date when the
meeting is held, the winding up is converted under s.96 from a
(solvent) members’ to a (insolvent) creditors’ voluntary winding
up.67 So long, however, as the liquidator shares the view of the
directors (and if they are wise they will have consulted him, as
their proposed nominee, before they made the declaration) all
should proceed smoothly as a members’ winding up.
Appointment and obligations of liquidator
33–12
The company in general meeting will appoint one or more
liquidators for the purpose of winding up the company’s affairs
and distributing its assets68 whereupon “all the powers of the
directors cease except so far as a general meeting or the
liquidator sanctions their continuance”.69 If a vacancy in the
office of liquidator “occurs by death, resignation or otherwise”
the company in general meeting may fill the vacancy,70 subject
to any arrangement with the creditors.71 If the winding up
continues for more than a year,72 the liquidator must summon a
general meeting at the end of the first and any subsequent year,
or at the first convenient date within three months from the end
of the year or such longer period as the Secretary of State may
allow.73 The liquidator must lay before the meeting an account of
his or her acts and dealings, and of the conduct of the winding up
during the year.74
When the company’s affairs are fully wound up the liquidator
must draw up an account of the winding up, showing how it has
been conducted and the company’s property disposed of, and
must call a final meeting of the company for the purpose of
laying before it the account and giving an explanation of it.75 The
fact that this meeting is being called is something which is of
wider interest than to members alone for, as we shall see,76 it will
lead to the final dissolution of the company. The Insolvency Act
provides that it shall be called by advertisement in the Gazette,
specifying its time, place and object and published at least one
month before the meeting.77 Within one week after the meeting
the liquidator must also send the Registrar a copy of the account
and make a return of the holding of the meeting.78
Creditors’ voluntary winding up
Instigation of winding up
33–13
Here, in contrast with members’ winding up, the company is
assumed to be insolvent and it is the creditors in whose interests
the winding up is undertaken and they who have the whip hand.
If no declaration of solvency has been made, the company must
cause a meeting of its creditors to be summoned for a day not
later than the 14th day after the resolution for voluntary winding
up is to be proposed. It must cause notices to be sent by post to
the creditors not less than seven days before the date of the
meeting and must advertise it once in the Gazette and once at
least in two newspapers circulating in the locality in which the
company’s principal place of business in Great Britain was
situated during the previous six months.79 This must state either
(a) the name of a qualified insolvency practitioner80 who, before
the meeting, will furnish creditors with such information as they
may reasonably require; or (b) a place where, on the two
business days before the meeting, a list of the company’s
creditors will be available for inspection free of charge.81
Further, the directors must prepare a statement of the company’s
affairs verified by affidavit and cause it to be laid before the
creditors’ meeting. The directors must also nominate one of their
number to preside at the creditors’ meeting—an unenviable task
which it is the nominee’s duty to perform.82
Appointment of liquidator
33–14
At their respective meetings, the creditors and the members may
nominate a liquidator, and if the creditors do so their nominee
becomes the liquidator, unless, on application to the court by a
director, creditor or member, the court directs that the
company’s nominee shall be liquidator instead of, or jointly
with, the creditors’ nominee, or it appoints some other person
instead of the creditors’ nominee.83 Provisions, similar in effect,
apply when a members’ winding up is converted to a creditors’
winding up because the liquidator concludes that the company’s
debts will not be paid in full within the 12 months, except that
the obligations of the directors have to be undertaken by the
incumbent liquidator.84
“Liquidation committee”
33–15
In a creditors’ voluntary winding up,85 or in a winding up by the
court,86 the creditors may decide at their initial or a subsequent
meeting to establish what used to be called a “committee of
inspection” but which the Insolvency Act now calls a
“liquidation committee”, and, in the case of a creditors’ winding
up, may appoint not more than five members of it.87 If they do
so, the company in general meeting may also appoint members
not exceeding five in number.88 However, if the creditors resolve
that all or any of those appointed by the general meeting ought
not to be members of the committee, the persons concerned will
not be qualified to act unless the court otherwise directs.89
The functions of a liquidation committee are to be found in
the Insolvency Rules rather than the Insolvency Act, and for
present purposes can be summarised by saying that they give the
liquidator the opportunity of consulting the creditors and the
members without having to convene formal creditors’ and
company meetings, and indeed the committee has substantial
powers to agree to matters on behalf of the creditors or the
company.90 They also provide additional means whereby the
creditors and members can keep an eye on the liquidator. In the
latter respect, liquidation committees are, perhaps, likely to be
more valuable in creditors’ voluntary windings-up (rather than in
windings-up by the court) owing to the lesser role played by
official receivers.
It may be thought somewhat anomalous that, when the
company is insolvent, the members should have equal (or any)
representation on the liquidation committee. But the Cork
Committee rejected the argument that they should not, because
“it is rarely possible to assess the interest of shareholders at the
outset of proceedings”.91 This is certainly true. What at the
commencement of the winding up would seem to be a clear case
of the company’s liabilities greatly exceeding its assets (so that
the shareholders have no prospective stake in the outcome of the
winding up) may turn out otherwise if the winding up is
prolonged.92
In other respects a creditors’ winding up proceeds up to and
including the final meeting in much the same way as in a
members’ winding up, although notably SBEEA 2015 and the
proposed new Insolvency Rules 2016 now much reduce the
requirements for, and formalities of, any creditors’ meeting,
including the largely pointless final meeting.93
If the required procedures are not followed, the court can give
directions under IA 1986 s.166. This was done in Re
WeSellCNC.Com Ltd,94 where it was discovered by the
appointed liquidator that no declaration of solvency had been
made; this was therefore necessarily a “creditors’ voluntary
winding up” pursuant to IA 1986 s.89, but no creditors’ meeting
had been summoned (and no statement of affairs prepared).
Accepting that the company was in fact well and truly solvent
with a considerable surplus, and with all creditors having been
paid and distributions made to shareholders, the judge declared
that the liquidation was a creditors’ voluntary winding up, but
dispensed with the requirement of a creditors’ meeting (and the
laying before it of a statement of affairs).
POWERS AND DUTIES OF THE LIQUIDATOR
33–16
In order to make possible the orderly winding up the company,
the Insolvency Act confers a wide range of powers on the
liquidator (ss.165 et seq.), and Sch.4 sets out an extensive list of
specific powers, including the power to carry on the company’s
business, to borrow and grant security over the company’s
property, and to bring and defend proceedings. Importantly,
ss.178 et seq. empowers the liquidator to “disclaim any onerous
property”, meaning that the liquidator can terminate the
company’s obligations under any unprofitable contracts, and the
contracting counterparty is then left to claim damages as a
creditor in the company’s insolvency. This power is typically
used to terminate the company’s leases of premises and other
property, on the basis that otherwise the company’s available
assets would be disproportionately appropriated to the creditor
holding the onerous right.95
In exercising these powers, the liquidator typically acts in the
company’s name96 (the company retains its separate legal
personality until the winding up is completed and the company is
dissolved).97
The liquidator’s duties are owed to the company,98 not to
individual creditors or members, and the liquidator may
therefore be sued in misfeasance proceedings under IA 1986
s.212 and held personally liable for misapplication of the
company’s assets,99 negligence100 or breach of fiduciary duties
(conflicts and profits rules) owed to the company.
COLLECTION, REALISATION AND DISTRIBUTION OF THE
COMPANY’S ASSETS
Maximising the assets available for distribution
33–17
The task of the liquidator in winding up the company is to
finalise the company’s affairs, and to get in the company’s assets
so as to maximise the return to those entitled to the assets on a
winding up.101 In getting in the assets, the liquidator will take
control of all the assets owned beneficially102 by the company
and, crucially, will seek to “claw back” assets which the
company should not have disposed of (or should not have
disposed of on the terms actually agreed) and will also pursue
claims against any officers or third parties who may be liable to
the company for breach of their duties or for other wrongs.103 In
this way, the asset pool available for distribution will be
maximised, to the benefit of those entitled to share in it.
In all of this, a word ought to be said about the position of
secured creditors in order to draw attention to the difference
between their position and that of general creditors on a winding
up, and also the different between their position on a winding up
compared with that during an administration. As we saw, so far
as the latter is concerned, unless the secured creditors have taken
steps to enforce their security prior to the administration, they
may be in difficulties in doing so while it lasts.104 In contrast, on
a winding up, a secured creditor is in the enviable position of
having the choice of realising its security and, if this does not
raise sufficient to pay what is due in full, to prove for the
balance, or to surrender its security for the benefit of the general
body of creditors and prove for the whole debt.105 Normally, of
course, the former option will be adopted.106
Statutory “claw back” and avoidance provisions
33–18
From the date of commencement of the winding up,107 transfers
of shares are avoided,108 and, for compulsory liquidations,
dispositions of the property by the company (unless the court
otherwise orders)109 and attachments, distress and execution
which have not been completed110 are void. This can prove
awkward, unless the court is minded to approve what has
happened. For example, in Re Gray’s Inn Construction Co
Ltd,111 the company continued to trade unprofitably after the date
the winding up petition had been presented; counsel conceded
that both sums credited and debited to the company’s bank
account were “dispositions” which, in the exercise of its
discretion, the court mostly declined to validate in the interests
of preserving rateable distributions to all creditors rather than
enabling some to be paid in full. The banking community has,
however, since been reassured that its potential exposure to
restitutionary liability of this sort is rather less, with the
important Court of Appeal decision in Hollicourt (Contracts) Ltd
v Bank of Ireland,112 to the effect that where a bank meets a
cheque drawn by the company as its customer (whether the
account is in credit or overdrawn), it does so merely as the
company’s agent; as a result, while there is clearly a disposition
in favour of the payee, there is no disposition to the bank itself.
Where, on the other hand, the company merely pays sums into
its bank account, if the account is overdrawn, then the payment
is a disposition to the bank,113 whereas if the account is in credit
then it has been held that the payment is not a disposition,114
which is perhaps a pragmatic conclusion since the transaction
simply converts the company’s cash receipts into an equivalent
claim against the bank.
Far more significantly, however, the liquidator is also given
the right to look backwards, and unwind transactions entered
into within prescribed periods before the commencement of an
insolvent winding up. We have seen this already in relation to
avoiding floating charges created within 12 months (or, in the
case of connected persons, two years) of that date.115 Similar
rules enable the liquidator to unwind transactions entered into at
an undervalue (s.238) within two years of the onset of
insolvency, at a time where the company was already
insolvent116 or became so as a result of the transaction.117 The
court has wide powers in framing its orders to effect restitution
of the company’s estate.118 Another provision with the same
timing restrictions avoids transactions motivated by the desire to
prefer one creditor over other (s.239).
A leading case on both these provisions remains Re MC
Bacon,119 the first decided case on s.239. The company, a bacon
importer and wholesaler, went into liquidation some time after
losing its principal customer. The liquidator challenged a
debenture granted to the company’s bank during the period
where the company was attempting to stay afloat, and when it
was probably insolvent or almost so, and could not have
continued without the support of its bank. Millett J declined to
strike down the debenture, holding that it was not a voidable
preference, since the company had not been motivated by a
desire to prefer the bank but merely by a desire to avoid their
overdraft being recalled; and it was not a transaction at an
undervalue,120 since the granting of security had neither depleted
the company’s assets nor diminished their value (although the
unsecured creditors may well have taken a rather different view
of this).
This outcome, although clearly defended in the judgment,
raises starkly the substantial practical shortcomings of these claw
back provisions. The fact that a preference is only voidable if
motivated by the insolvent debtor’s desire to prefer creates the
rather odd result that if the creditor aggressively demands early
repayment under threat of refusing further supplies or services,
the payment is unlikely to be caught, to the distinct advantage of
the creditor who has now been paid in full and the corresponding
disadvantage of the remaining unsecured creditors. By contrast,
in both the US and Australia, a disposition is voidable if it has
the effect of preferring one creditor, whatever the debtor’s
motivation. And the practical consequences for unsecured
creditors where valid late security is granted (presumably
security not otherwise caught by the floating charge provisions
in s.245) is obvious on the face of it. Interestingly, this odd
outcome has been the subject of some attention, obiter only, with
Arden LJ suggesting that the grant of a legal mortgage could in
the right circumstances be classified a transaction at an
undervalue121; this then raises the nice question of whether the
property disposition required to effect a legal mortgage merits a
different treatment from the granting of a security interest by
way of charge.
Whatever their shortcomings, however, these claw-back
provisions can provide vital additional reserves for creditors, and
occasionally for members, but, in conclusion, it might also be
noted that their backdated effect sits uneasily with the aims of
the protective notice rules which require notice of the winding
up to be published in the Gazette.122
Statutory provisions requiring wrongdoers to make
contributions
33–19
We have in earlier chapters already considered the provisions in
the Insolvency Act which enable the liquidator to pursue the
directors, and sometimes others, making them liable to account
or pay compensation or contribute to the assets of the company
by way of remedy for their breach of duty (s.212, a purely
procedural provision, but one which does give the court a
discretion to require compensation to be paid in full or in part
“as the court thinks just”, although the wrong being pursued is
necessarily a general law wrong, either statutory or common
law), fraudulent trading (s.213), or wrongful trading (s.214, also
allowing the court a discretion to order “such contribution (if
any) as the court thinks proper”).123
The common law “anti-deprivation principle”
33–20
When a company is insolvent, the widely accepted objective of
regulated insolvency distribution, and the clear goal of the
statutory rules just considered, is to ensure that the company’s
assets are preserved for distribution, and that the distribution,
when effected, is for the collective benefit of the company’s
creditors. Put another way, although it is accepted that some
businesses will inevitably fail, even when run without fault,124
and that innocent parties will then have to bear the resulting
losses, the general consensus is that the losses should then be
borne rateably.125
This then raises the question of whether there is common law
support for this endeavour, or whether the task falls entirely to
statute. A number of old cases and one House of Lords authority
suggest the common law has a role. In British Eagle
International Airlines Ltd v Cie Nationale Air France,126 the
House of Lords, by a 3:2 majority, overruled both the Court of
Appeal and the trial judge to hold that a contractual netting-out
agreement between international airline companies could not
operate on Air France’s insolvency so as to prevent Air France
from collecting in full the sums owed to it by certain airlines,
even though sums which it owed to different airlines would
obviously not be met in full.127
Perhaps predictably, the 2008 financial crisis generated
litigation which tested the breadth of this common law
restriction. The difficult case of Belmont Park Investments Pty
Ltd v BNY Corporate Trustee Services Ltd and Lehman Brothers
Special Financing Inc128 is the only case to reach the Supreme
Court to date. The clause under review was not a British Eagle
“contracting out” provision (operating against the pari passu
rule),129 but a clause which effected an insolvency-triggered
deprivation to the pool of assets available for distribution (as
outlawed in Ex p. Mackay130).131 The Supreme Court did not
follow the analysis in Mackay, but gave powerful backing to
freedom of contract, and unanimously upheld these “flawed
asset” depletion provisions, denying that they offended the
common law anti-deprivation principle. The derivatives markets,
and perhaps financial markets more generally, applauded the
outcome and the freedom it provides to parties to organise their
affairs at will, although the result stands in stark contrast to the
strict approach still favoured in British Eagle type arrangements,
and also to the broader approach to protecting creditors against
flawed asset provisions that is favoured in US bankruptcy
legislation.
Benefit of the statutory claw backs and wrongdoer
contributions
33–21
Money that is ordered to be paid under most of the sections just
discussed (ss.238, 239, 213 and 214, but not s.212) typically
goes into the general assets of the company in the hands of the
liquidator, not to individual victims of the wrongs, and not,
importantly, into the clutches of floating charge holders. This is
because the right to sue belongs exclusively to the liquidator, not
the company. Receipts from s.212 actions, by contrast, are
regarded as the products of a chose in action which belonged to
the company before liquidation, and so will be caught by an
appropriately worded floating charge.132
Proof of debts and mandatory insolvency set off
33–22
The liquidator will only pay those debts which are provable in
the insolvency, and proved. The rules specifying which debts
these are and how they are proved are contained in the
Insolvency Rules 1986.133 All claims by creditors are provable,
whether the debts are present or future, certain or contingent,
ascertained or sounding only in damages,134 provided the
company was, on that basis, subject to the claim at the time the
winding up commenced.135 The liquidator has the power to
estimate the value of contingent or uncertain debts,136 and may if
necessary apply to the court for assistance.137
In a compulsory winding up, the creditors must submit written
“proof” or their debts, and in a voluntary winding up the
liquidator usually elects to impose the same requirement. The
liquidator then examines the proofs and decides whether to
admit all or part of the debt or reject it; aggrieved creditors may
apply to the court for review.138 This all sounds eminently simple
and sensible, and generally it is, although more complicated
facts can throw up conceptually difficult problems. One rule
which helps solve some of these problems is the “rule against
double proof”, which prevents more than one creditor suing the
insolvent company for the same debt. This is not as unlikely as it
might at first seem. For example, consider the situation where A
guarantees a debt which B owes to C. Although this looks like a
problem where there are two debtors, not two creditors, looked
at the other way it is also true that the primary creditor (C) has a
right to sue B on the debt, and the guarantor (A) has a contingent
right to sue B to enforce its indemnity rights under the guarantee.
If B is insolvent, can A and C both prove in the insolvency? The
answer is no, and the rule against double proof prevents this,
denying creditors whose rights relate to the same underlying
debt the possibility to prove together. Were it otherwise, it would
follow that if a debt were guaranteed by several parties, they
could all prove in the liquidation; this makes it clear that the
logic delivering this conclusion is flawed. So held the Supreme
Court in Kaupthing Singer & Friedlander Ltd (In
Administration); sub nom Mills v HSBC Trustee (CI) Ltd.139
As already noted, secured creditors often elect to stand outside
this process.140
33–23
A further limitation on the amount for which creditors may
prove is imposed by the mandatory insolvency set off rules,141
which require the sums due from the creditor to be set off against
the sums due from the company where those sums arise from
mutual credits, mutual debts or other mutual dealings between
the company and the creditor proving in the liquidation. In
practice, this arrangement invariably benefits the creditor,
because at least some part of the debt due to the creditor from
the company is effectively paid off in full by virtue of the set off,
and the creditor only has to prove for the remaining balance
(which balance will constitute a claim against the insolvency
pool, with the inevitable risk of being paid very little, as we shall
see).
It is quite hard to find a compelling justification for this rather
generous exception to the strict pari passu rule of insolvency
distribution, which generally insists that losses are shared
rateably, and that all unsecured creditors are only paid pro rata.
True, the rule is longstanding,142 and perhaps it simplifies the
work required to be done by the liquidator in accepting proof of
debts,143 and perhaps it reduces exposure and therefore total risk
in the financial markets,144 but it is quite hard to find reasons of
fairness145 which explain why creditors with mutual dealings
with the insolvency debtor should effectively be preferred in the
sharing of losses by all the debtor’s unsecured creditors.146
Whatever the justifications for the rule, because it is so
advantageous to creditors, they will be keen to classify their
dealings as mutual. Often this can be relatively easy to prove.
The 1990s litigation surrounding the collapse of the Bank of
Credit and Commerce International147 illustrated that customers
who both saved with and borrowed from the bank came within
the rules, and so were protected from having to repay their loans
in full while only recovering a fraction of their savings as
unsecured creditors in the insolvency. The same was true of
companies who had borrowed on the security of their own
deposits with the Bank. But where these types of corporate loans
were secured not on the borrowing company’s own Bank
deposits, but on deposits belonging to third parties, typically
those of the borrowing company’s director, the outcome was
different. The directors, so it was held, had not undertaken any
personal liability to the Bank; they had merely allowed their
assets to be used as security; there was therefore no debt owed
by the director to the Bank which could be set off against the
debt owed by the Bank to the director in relation to the director’s
deposit.148 The net result was that the borrowing companies
would have to repay their loans in full (the Bank could not be
forced to rely on the director’s secured guarantee), and the
directors by contrast would recover only minimal sums in the
Bank’s insolvency. The seeming injustice of the outcome did not
escape Lord Hoffmann.
And of course, no set off is possible if the creditor’s claims
against the company arose after the commencement of winding
up,149 or if the creditor’s obligations to the company arose by
way of liability for misfeasance (that not being a mutual
“dealing” with the company).150
Distribution of the company’s assets
33–24
Once the liquidator has gathered in the company’s assets, they
must be distributed in an orderly fashion to those entitled to
them. The basic rules are clear. The funds are devoted first, to
paying the expenses of liquidation; then to the preferred
creditors; then the general unsecured creditors; then the deferred
creditors; then, if there is anything left, the members, according
to the entitlements associated with their class rights. If the funds
are not sufficient to pay all of a particular class in this hierarchy
in full, then they share pro rata. It then follows, necessarily, that
the classes below that class will receive nothing. It is common
knowledge that the unsecured creditors often secure almost
nothing in an insolvent liquidation; the banks take the lion’s
share, as secured creditors, and the preferential creditors take
most of the little that remains.
In examining in more detail the order of distribution of the
company’s assets, recall, first, that the pool of assets includes
only assets owned beneficially by the company.151 Moreover, the
claims of secured creditors to the assets specifically secured rank
ahead of any claim in the winding up to those secured assets,
including even the costs of liquidation,152 but with the significant
exception noted in Ch.32 in relation to floating charge holders,
who must cede priority to quite an astonishing number of
preferred claims.153
The first call for payment from the company’s assets are the
proper expenses of liquidation, as defined authoritatively by the
classes of debts set out in the IR 1986 r.4.218, which also
defines the priorities as between these classes of expenses.154
There is no additional implicit requirement that to be classed as
an expense, the expenditure must also have been, or have been
intended to be, for the benefit of the company.155 These
liquidation expenses include the liquidator’s remuneration
(without which guarantee no liquidator would be persuaded to
act), post-liquidation debts and certain pre-liquidation debts.156
The total size of these claims can be enormous, but perhaps the
greatest recent surprise was delivered by Re Nortel GmbH and
Lehman Bros International (Europe) Ltd,157 which held that a
Financial Support Direction (an order to pay) issued by the
Pensions Regulator to a holding company after the
commencement of that company’s liquidation, was a liquidation
expense, and therefore, with the other liquidation expenses, had
to be paid in priority to all the company’s other unsecured
claims. This would clearly have had a dramatic impact on the
likely payout to claimants further down the chain, and so it came
as some relief when the Supreme Court overturned this decision,
in Bloom v Pensions Regulator,158 to hold that the debt was
simply one of the company’s general unsecured debts, provable
and payable in the ordinary course.
33–25
Costs of litigation can also be recovered as an expense. After
several contrary judicial determinations, the statutory rules have
now been changed to make it clear that a liquidator who is
sanctioned to bring proceedings directed at clawing back assets
or pursuing wrongdoers to compel them to make contributions to
the company’s assets will be able to recover the costs of such
litigation as a proper expense of the liquidation.159
Finally, in the context of expenses, the 1986 Insolvency Act
introduced protective provisions to prevent public utilities from
putting pressure on liquidators to pay their outstanding pre-
commencement debts as a condition of further supply,160 which
effectively enabled such companies to extract preferential
repayment of their pre-winding up debts. Any supply which
comes after the commencement of winding up will normally
rank as a liquidation expense, and so is likely to be paid in full,
but suppliers are nevertheless permitted to require the liquidator
personally to guarantee payment.161
The second call on the pool is to pay the preferential creditors,
as defined in IA 1986 s.386 and Sch.6.162
33–26
The third call on the funds is to pay the general unsecured
creditors, unless their debts are deferred, as described next
below. Recall that the unsecured creditors may also receive a
boost to the pool dedicated to them as a result of compulsory
contributions of a “prescribed part” from floating charge
realisations.163
The fourth call on the funds is to pay deferred debts to
creditors. There are three classes of such deferred debts. First,
interest on all debts payable in the winding up, calculated from
the date of commencement of the winding up until the date of
payment of the interest, with all relevant debts treated as ranking
equally for this purpose.164 Secondly, money due to a member on
a contract to redeem or repurchase shares which was not
completed before the winding up.165 And, thirdly, debts due to
members in their character as members, whether by way of
dividends, profits or otherwise.166 The House of Lords had cause
to consider the scope of this last category in Soden v British and
Commonwealth Holdings Plc,167 and held that it embraced only
claims by members based on the statutory contract between the
company and its members, and that debts due to members in
other capacities, such as lenders to or trade creditors of the
company, are not deferred in the same way, but are typically
general unsecured debts. In the case in question, the member was
claiming damages for misrepresentations which allegedly
induced the member to acquire shares in the company. The
House of Lords held this was a claim arising outside the context
of what is now the Companies Act 2006 s.33 contract, so would
not be a deferred debt.
And, finally, whatever remains then goes to the members.
Typically the class rights as between shareholders will ensure
that the preferential shareholders get preferential rights to the
return of their capital, then capital is returned to the ordinary
shareholders, and then any surplus after that is usually only for
the ordinary members (the preferential shareholders often not
being entitled to share in any surplus on a winding up).
It is tolerably clear that the objective behind these distribution
rules, so far as they apply on insolvency, is for the company’s
creditors and members to share the inevitable losses roughly
according to pari passu rules, whilst marginally adjusting those
rules to specially favour those who have contractually pre-agreed
security rights168 or who are non-adjusting creditors with little
wherewithal to negotiate for their own priority (e.g. employees),
and, by contrast, to disfavour those with debts that are truly of
second order importance (e.g. interest only on all provable debts)
or with debts that reflect the claims of members to the
company’s capital (at least as the position appears on
insolvency), which claims should, in the natural order of things,
be deferred to the claims of the company’s creditors.
DISSOLUTION
After winding up
The normal process
33–27
In contrast with the formalities attendant on the birth of a
company,169 its death takes place with a singular absence of
ceremony. In the case of voluntary liquidations, once the
liquidator has sent to the Registrar the liquidator’s final account
and return,170 and on the expiration of three months from their
registration, the company is deemed to be dissolved,171 unless the
court, on the application of the liquidator or any other person
who appears to the court to be interested, makes an order
deferring the date of dissolution.172
Normally, the position is much the same where the winding
up is by the court. Once it appears that the winding up is for all
practical purposes complete, the liquidator must currently
summon a final meeting of creditors173 (although this is expected
to be abolished in late 2016174) which receives the liquidator’s
report on the winding up and determines whether the liquidator
shall be released.175 The liquidator then gives notice to the court
and to the Registrar that the meeting has been held and of the
decisions (if any) of the meeting. When the Registrar receives
the notice, it is registered and, unless the Secretary of State, on
the application of the official receiver or anyone else who
appears to be interested, directs a deferment,176 the company is
dissolved at the end of three months from that registration.177
If the official receiver is the liquidator, the procedure is the
same except that registration is of a notice from the official
receiver that the winding up is complete.178
Early dissolution
33–28
However, there is a sensible procedure whereby the OR may
bring about an early dissolution if it appears that the realisable
assets are insufficient to cover the costs of the winding up179 and
that the affairs of the company do not require any further
investigation.180 Before doing so, the OR must give at least 28
days’ notice of the proposal to the company’s creditors and
members and to an administrative receiver if there is one,181 and,
with the giving of that notice, the OR ceases to be required to
undertake any duties other than to apply to the Registrar for the
early dissolution of the company.182 On the registration of that
application, the company becomes dissolved at the end of three
months183 unless the Secretary of State, on the application of the
official receiver or any creditor, member or administrative
receiver,184 gives directions to the contrary before the end of that
period.
The grounds upon which the application to the Secretary of
State may be made are (a) that the realisable assets are in fact
sufficient to cover the expenses of the winding up; or (b) that the
affairs of the company do require further investigation185; or (c)
that for any other reason the early dissolution of the company is
inappropriate.186 And the directions that may be given may make
provision for enabling the winding up to proceed as if the
official receiver had not invoked the procedure or may include a
deferment of the date of dissolution.187
There are no similar provisions for early dissolution on a
voluntary winding up; once the company has resolved on
voluntary winding up it is expected to go through with it. But if
there is a vacancy in the liquidatorship and no one can be found
who is willing to accept the office because there is clearly not
enough left to pay the expenses of continuing it (no insolvency
practitioner will accept office in such circumstances unless
someone is prepared to pay the costs), it is difficult to see how
the Registrar could do other than to strike the company off the
register as a defunct company (see below)—as, indeed, that
section specifically recognises.
Striking off of defunct companies
33–29
The striking off of defunct companies affords a method whereby
a small company can, in practice, often be inexpensively
dissolved without the expense of any formal winding up.
Although the rules are contained in Pt 31 of the Companies Act,
rather than in the Insolvency Act, they are an integral part of the
machinery by which companies cease to exist.
Under s.1000 of the Companies Act 2006, if the Registrar has
reasonable cause to believe that a company is not carrying on
business or is not in operation, the Registrar may send to the
company a letter inquiring whether that is so. If within a month
of sending the letter a reply is not received, the Registrar shall,
within 14 days thereafter, send a registered letter referring to the
first letter and stating that no answer to it has been received and
that, if an answer to the second letter is not received within one
month from its date, a notice will be published in the Gazette
with a view to striking the company’s name off the register.188 If
the Registrar receives a reply to the effect that the company is
not carrying on business or is not in operation, or if, within one
month of sending the second letter, no reply is received, the
Registrar may publish in the Gazette and send to the company by
post a notice that at the expiration of three months from the date
of the notice the name of the company will, unless cause to the
contrary is shown, be struck off the register and the company
will be dissolved.189 At the expiration of the time mentioned in
the notice, the Registrar may, unless cause to the contrary is
shown, strike the company off the register and publish notice of
this in the Gazette, whereupon the company is dissolved.190
This section is most commonly used when what has afforded
the Registrar reasonable cause to believe that the company is not
carrying on business or in operation is the fact that it is in arrears
with the lodging of its annual returns and accounts.191 When so
used by the Registrar, it is both a method of inducing those
companies that are operating in breach of their filing obligations
to mend their ways, as well as a method of clearing the register
of companies which are indeed defunct.
A problem discovered by the CLR arises out of the fact that
the section requires the Registrar to communicate with the
company at its registered address192 which, for a variety of good
and not-so-good reasons, might be an ineffective form of
communication. The CLR encouraged the Registrar to
experiment with writing also to the directors of the company at
their last known residential address, where correspondence to the
company’s address was returned, before striking the company
off, and it appears that this measure has had some success and is
now part of the Registrar’s administrative practice.193 The
advantage is that it may avoid striking off companies which are
in fact still operational, and thus avoid the expense of seeking to
restore them to the register when they discover they have been
struck off (see below). From 11 July 2014 onwards, the Registrar
may now send communications electronically, as opposed to
communicating via letters by post.194
However, the above procedure can also be used to deal with
the situation referred to above when winding up proceedings
have been started but insufficient resources are available to
complete them.195 If the Registrar has reasonable cause to
believe either that no liquidator is acting or that the affairs of the
company are fully wound up and, in either case, that the returns
required to be made by the liquidator have not been made for a
period of six consecutive months, the Registrar shall publish in
the Gazette and send to the company or the liquidator (if any) a
like notice which causes the company to be dissolved.196
Voluntary striking off
33–30
Further, the predecessor to the above sections used to provide
companies with a method of dissolving without the expense of a
formal winding up and especially without the appointment of an
insolvency practitioner to oversee the process: the directors of a
company which had ceased trading would simply write to the
Registrar inviting the Registrar to exercise the statutory power to
strike it off. Under the Deregulation and Contracting Out Act
1994,197 perhaps somewhat ironically, this practice was
formalised in the statute and it is understood that the Registrar
discontinued the old practice and will now only entertain formal
applications for striking off under the new procedure. The new
sections in large part replicated the old practice, so the change
helped to make this course of action more transparent.
The statutory procedure enables a company,198 which has not
traded or carried on business199 during the previous three
months, to apply by its directors (or a majority of them)200 to the
Registrar for the company to be struck off. The directors must
ensure that notice of the application is given to a list of persons,
who include, notably, its creditors (contingent and prospective
creditors being embraced within the term),201 its employees, the
managers and trustees of any pension fund and its members.202
On receipt of the application the Registrar publishes a notice in
the Gazette stating that the company may be struck off and
inviting any person to show cause why it should not be.203 Not
less than three months later the Registrar may strike the
company off and, on publication of a notice to this effect in the
Gazette, the company is dissolved.204
The purpose of requiring notice to be given by the directors is
obviously to see if the people most likely to object to the
striking-off in fact oppose this course of action, but the
legislation lays down no particular procedure which the
Registrar must follow in dealing with objections. The fact that
the company has creditors clearly does not debar it from using
this procedure (otherwise the Act would not require notice to be
given to creditors) but it is not intended to be used in place of
liquidation where the company has substantial assets or
liabilities outstanding at the time of application.205 Nor may an
application be made for striking off where the company is
currently the subject of an application to the court for consent to
a compromise or arrangement under the Companies Act206 or
other procedures for handling insolvent companies contained in
the Insolvency Act 1986.207
The range of matters which the Registrar must keep in mind
upon an application under s.1003 is much reduced by the
provision that dissolution under the procedure does not inhibit
the enforcement of any liability of the erstwhile company’s
directors, managing officers or members, so that these people
cannot escape their common law or statutory duties by causing
their company to be dissolved.208 Moreover, a company
dissolved under the new procedure, like companies dissolved in
other ways, may be restored to the register in certain
circumstances, a topic to which we now turn.
RESURRECTION OF DISSOLVED COMPANIES
33–31
A contrast between the death of an individual and that of a
company is that, without divine intervention, a dissolved
company can be resurrected. Following the CLR,209 the Act
made two innovations in this area. First, it introduced a limited
form of administrative restoration to the register, a result which
had previously required a court order. Secondly, a single method
of court restoration replaced the formerly existing two methods,
which the courts had found some difficulty in making sense of
and which overlapped to a considerable extent.
Administrative restoration
33–32
The new form of administrative restoration applies only where
the company was dissolved by the Registrar under the provisions
relating to defunct companies.210 Thus, it does not apply to either
dissolution after winding up or to voluntary striking off. The
conditions for administrative restoration to the register confine it
to situations where the company was carrying on business or in
operation at the time it was struck off.211 Thus, the main purpose
of administrative restoration is to deal more cheaply with
reversing a striking off which, ideally, should not have occurred
in the first place. For probably the same reason, the application
for restoration may be made only by a former director or former
member of the company,212 but no application for restoration
may be made more than six years after its dissolution.213 If any
of the company’s property is vested in the Crown as bona
vacantia,214 the Crown’s representative must consent and the
applicant must offer to pay any costs of the Crown in relation to
the application and, more importantly, dealing with the property
during the period of dissolution.215 Finally, the applicant must
deliver to the Registrar such documents as are necessary to bring
the company’s public records up-to-date and to pay any penalties
outstanding at the time the company was dissolved.216
If these conditions are met, the Registrar is under a duty to
restore the company to the register.217 Notice of the decision
must be given to the applicant and the restoration takes effect
when that notice is sent.218 Public notice must be given of the
restoration.219 The effect of restoration is that the company is
deemed to have continued in existence as if it had not been
struck off.220 However, any consequential directions, if
necessary, for placing the company and all other persons in the
position (as nearly as possible) as they would have been in, had
the company not been struck off, are to be given, not by the
Registrar, but by a court, to which application may be made
within three years of the restoration.221
Restoration by the court
33–33
The two court-based restoration methods previously provided
were contained in ss.651 and 653 of the 1985 Act. The current
provisions are based on those of s.653, the somewhat simpler
procedure. The court-based procedure applies to all forms of
dissolution222 and a much wider range of persons may apply for
restoration. These include not just former directors or members,
but any creditor of the company at the time of its dissolution,
anyone who but for the dissolution would have been in a
contractual relationship with it, any person with a potential legal
claim against the company, any manager or trustee of an
employee pension fund, any person interested in land in which
the company had an interest, and the Secretary of State.223 This
caters for a much wider range of reasons for wanting to have the
company restored to the register, a common one being in order
to sue or assert a right against it. Normally, such persons must
act within six years of the date of dissolution,224 but a claim for
restoration in order to bring a claim for damages for personal
injury against the company may be made at any time.225
The court has power to order restoration if (a) in the case of
striking off of a defunct company, it was carrying on business or
in operation at the time; (b) in the case of voluntary striking off,
the conditions for such a striking off were not complied with;
and (c) in any other case the court thinks it just to do so.226
Restoration, if ordered, takes effect from the time the court’s
order is delivered to the Registrar and the Registrar must give
publicity to the order in the usual way.227 The effect of
restoration by the court is the same as with administrative
restoration,228 and the court may give the necessary directions to
effect the principle that the company should be treated as if
never dissolved.229
CONCLUSION
33–34
This final chapter has considered the means by which the lives
of companies are deliberately brought to an end, against their
natural characteristic of perpetual succession. The overview has
been brief, especially given the great complexities and doctrinal
and policy difficulties in the current structure. The source of
those difficulties is, at root, the result of a simple problem:
mostly when companies are wound up, they are insolvent; their
liabilities exceed their assets. In such circumstances, innocent
parties will inevitably face losses, whatever efforts are made to
protect them (and we have seen the lengths to which the winding
up regime goes in that regard). Perhaps then the best the law can
do is try to minimise obvious unfairness and ensure the rules,
even if not perfect, are at least certain. Given the entrepreneurial
imagination of commercial parties and our flexible and
sophisticated mix of statute, contract and property law rules, this
is a challenge, but one against which the current winding up
regime might be judged to be doing tolerably well.
1
And, more rarely, simply by striking the company off the register: see below, paras
33–29 and 33–30 et seq.
2
See Ch.23, above.
3 See above, Chs 29, 32.
4
But see Pt 31 of CA 2006, noted below, paras 33–29 and 33–30.
5
Insolvency Rules 1986 (SI 1986/1925), amended on numerous occasions, and with the
Insolvency Service planning a revised and consolidated version for 2016, to take effect
from 1 October 2016. The details of these new Rules can be found at
https://www.gov.uk/government/news/draft-insolvencyrules-sent-to-the-insolvency-rules-
committee-for-statutory-consultation [Accessed 27 February 2016]. The Explanatory
Notes indicate that the new Rules (i) consolidate existing rules; (ii) modernise and
simplify the language; and (iii) incorporate various changes in the law intended to
reduce the burden of red tape (especially in relation to creditors’ meetings, which will
become the exception, rather than the default rule). To the extent that the rules are
consolidated and recast, this is not intended to change the law. Both IA 1986 and the
Rules eschew the use of the word “members” and substitute “contributories”, thus
perhaps giving the misleading impression that it means only members who are called
upon to contribute because their shares are partly paid (or in the case of guarantee
companies because of the minimal amounts that they have agreed to contribute on a
winding up). To avoid this impression, here “members” has been substituted; but this too
is not wholly accurate, for “contributories” also includes past members unless they
ceased to be members more than 12 months before the commencement of the winding
up: see IA 1986 ss.74 and 76; and Re Anglesea Collieries (1866) L.R. 1 Ch. 555 CA;
and Re Consolidated Goldfields of New Zealand [1953] Ch. 689. On the other hand, the
benefits of participating as a contributory are denied to those whose obligation to
contribute arises from a misfeasance to the company: see IA 1986 s.79(2) in respect of
liability under IA 1986 ss.213, 214 (fraudulent and wrongful trading respectively); and
Re AMF International Ltd [1996] 1 W.L.R. 77 in respect of liability under IA 1986
s.212.
6
In relation to the winding up of “unregistered companies” (on which see paras 1–31 et
seq., above) winding up by the court is the only method allowed: see IA 1986 Pt V. A
company incorporated outside Great Britain which has been carrying on business in
Britain may be wound up as an unregistered company notwithstanding that it has ceased
to exist under the law of the country of incorporation: IA 1986 s.225.
7 See IA 1986 Pt IV Ch.X.
8
See IA 1986 Pt VI ss.238–246.
9 Normally the High Court, but the county court of the district in which the company has
its registered office has concurrent jurisdiction if the company’s paid-up capital is small
and if that county court has jurisdiction in relation to bankruptcy of individuals: IA 1986
s.117.
10
But it might be used if the court is already involved because the liquidation of the
company is part of a scheme requiring its sanction in accordance with the provisions
discussed in Ch.29, above.
11
Notwithstanding anything to the contrary in the articles: Re Pervil Gold Mines Ltd
[1898] 1 Ch. 122 CA.
12
And, as we have noted earlier, the Secretary of State (also see ss.124A, 124B), the
FCA (also see s.124C), the Regulator of Community Interest Companies, the Official
Receiver of the court, and designated officers of the magistrates court, each in specified
circumstances.
13
IA 1986 s.124.
14
Until then each may try to obtain judgment and levy execution thus getting ahead of
the pack.
15 Prior to the 1985/86 statutory reforms, it was held, somewhat surprisingly, that
directors could not apply: Re Emmerdart Ltd [1979] Ch. 540. Now they can. For the
interpretation of “the directors” see Re Equiticorp International Plc [1989] 1 W.L.R.
1010.
16 But unless the membership has been reduced below two, a member cannot apply
unless his (or her) shares were originally allotted to him or have been held and registered
in his name for at least 6 months during the 18 months prior to the commencement of the
winding up (on which see below) or have devolved on him through the death of a former
holder: IA 1986 s.124(2). This is designed to prevent a disgruntled person (e.g. an ex-
employee) from buying a share and then bringing a winding up petition (or threatening
to do so).
17 In accordance with IA 1986 s.123(1)(a).
18
Indeed, a creditor whose debt is bona fide disputed cannot petition at all: Stonegate
Securities Ltd v Gregory [1980] Ch. 576 CA; Re Selectmove Ltd [1995] 1 W.L.R. 474.
19 Re A company (No.003729 of 1982) [1984] 1 W.L.R. 1090.
20Re A company (No.008790 of 1990) [1991] B.C.L.C. 561; Stylo Shoes Ltd v Prices
Tailors Ltd [1960] Ch. 396.
21
IA 1986 s.123(1)(e). See BNY Corporate Trustee Services Ltd v Eurosail-UK 2007-
3BL Plc [2013] UKSC 28; [2013] 1 W.L.R. 1408 SC. While discrediting the “point of
no return” test, the Supreme Court affirmed the decision of the Court of Appeal that the
ability of a company to meet its liabilities, both prospective and contingent, was to be
determined on the balance of probabilities with the burden of proof on the party
asserting “balance-sheet insolvency”.
22IA 1986 s.125(2). This is typically relied on to resist orders made on the “just and
equitable” ground, where the unfair prejudice alternative may seem preferable.
23
Re Surrey Garden Village Trust Ltd [1995] 1 W.L.R. 974 Ch; Re JE Cade & Sons Ltd
[1992] B.C.L.C. 213. On the other hand, if the purpose of the petition is legitimate, it
does not matter if the petitioner’s motive is malicious: Bryanston Finance Ltd v De Vries
(No.2) [1976] Ch. 63 CA.
24 Charles Forte Investments Ltd v Amanda [1964] Ch. 240 CA.
25
Unless the court so orders, as it may: IA 1986 s.145(1).
26
By common law, even though not made explicit in the IA 1986 for compulsory
winding ups: Re Farrow’s Bank Ltd [1921] 2 Ch. 164 CA (contrast the statutory
provision in voluntary winding up (s.90(2)).
27
IA 1986 s.135.
28
Scotland manages without them but when the Government, in a desire to reduce civil
service manpower and public expenditure, proposed to remove their role in individual
bankruptcy there was bitter opposition (not least from the Cork Committee: see Cmnd.
8558, Ch.14) and the proposal was dropped.
29
In the latter, their role is principally in relation to disqualification of directors under
the Directors Disqualification Act (on which see Ch.10, above).
30Official receivers have the unique distinction of being entitled to act as liquidators
notwithstanding that they are not licensed insolvency practitioners under Pt XIII of the
IA 1986: ss.388(5) and 389(2).
31 Except when it is made immediately upon the discharge of an administration order or
when there is a supervisor of a voluntary arrangement under Pt I of the Act, when the
former administrator or the supervisor of the arrangement may be appointed by the court
as liquidator: IA 1986 s.140.
32 IA s.136(1) and (2).
33
See IA 1986 s.136(4) and (5). The nominee of the creditors prevails unless, on
application to the court, it otherwise orders (s.139) which it is unlikely to do if the
company is insolvent.
34
Which it may not since both creditors and members may be happy to leave the
liquidation to the official receiver since that may prove less expensive.
35
IA 1986 s.137.
36 IA 1986 s.136(3).
37IA 1986 s.131. See also ss.235 and 236. See Re Chesterfield United Inc [2012]
EWHC 244 (Ch); [2013] 1 B.C.L.C. 709; Re Comet Group Ltd [2014] EWHC 3477
(Ch); Re Corporate Jet Realisations Ltd [2015] EWHC 221 (Ch).
38 IA 1986 s.132.
39IA 1986 ss.133 and 134. It is this public examination that is the most dreaded ordeal,
particularly if the company is sufficiently well known to attract the attention of the
general public and the Press.
40 IA 1986 s.143.
41 Giving priority, of course, to preferred creditors as set out in Sch.6 to IA 1986.
42IA 1986 s.143(1). Normally the members (except in the case of non-profit-making or
charitable companies) in accordance with their class rights on a winding up.
43
See below, para.33–15.
44 IA 1986 s.129.
45 IA 1986 s.127.
46
IA 1986 s.128.
47
Which may be considerable if hearings are adjourned, as is not infrequent.
48
See IA 1986 ss.238–245.
49
This is rare but charters of incorporation of limited duration are not uncommon.
50
It is possible to conceive of circumstances in which this might be done: e.g. when a
partnership converts to an incorporated company because its solicitors and accountants
advise that this would be advantageous tax-wise, the partners might wish to ensure that it
could be dissolved by a simple majority if they were later advised that it would be better
to revert to a partnership.
51 IA 1986 s.84(1)(a).
52
IA 1986 s.84(1)(b).
53 IA 1986 s.84(3).
54 IA 1986 s.85(1).
55
IA 1986 s.86. And CA 2006 s.332, which provides that a resolution passed at an
adjourned meeting is treated as passed on the day it was in fact passed, prevents
companies backdating the commencement of winding up.
56 IA 1986 s.87(1).
57
IA 1986 s.88. Contrast the wording of the comparable IA 1986 s.127, above, in
relation to winding up by the court: that avoids also any disposition of the company’s
property (unless the court otherwise orders) which IA 1986 s.88 does not.
58
This, on the face of it rather curious, use of a board meeting as a venue for the making
of statutory declarations ensures that all the directors know what is going on.
59i.e. whichever is the greater of the interest payable on judgment debts or that
applicable to the particular debt apart from the winding up: IA 1986 ss.189(4) and 251.
60
IA 1986 s.89(1). In practice the declaration will play safe and not specify a shorter
period than 12 months even if the directors expect that it will be shorter.
61
See above, para.13–39 et seq.
62 See above, para.13–4.
63IA 1986 s.89(2). The declaration must be delivered to the Registrar within 15 days
immediately following the passing of the resolution: IA 1986 s.89(3) and (4).
64
IA 1986 s.89(4).
65 IA 1986 s.89(5).
66But see below at paras 33–30 et seq. for the possible resort to s.1003 of the
Companies Act.
67
Indeed, it may become a winding up by the court, for a winding up order may be
made notwithstanding that the company is already in voluntary winding up and an
official receiver, as well as the other persons entitled under IA 1986 s.124, may present a
petition: IA 1986 s.124(5). But unless the court, on proof of fraud or mistake, directs
otherwise, all proceedings already taken in the voluntary winding up are deemed to have
been validly taken: IA 1986 s.129(1).
68
IA 1986 s.91(1).
69
IA 1986 s.91(2).
70
IA 1986 s.92(1). The meeting to do so may be convened by any continuing liquidators
if there was more than one or by a member: IA 1986 s.92(2).
71
This reference to “creditors” is presumably to cover the case where the members’
voluntary winding up forms part of a reorganisation of one of the types dealt with in
Ch.29, above, in which creditors are involved.
72
Which it may, because although the creditors should be paid within 12 months the
subsequent distribution of the remaining assets or their proceeds does not have to be
completed within any prescribed time.
73
IA 1986 s.93(1).
74 IA 1986 s.93(2).
75
IA 1986 s.94(1).
76
See below, paras 33–27 et seq.
77 What is surprising is that neither the IA 1986 nor the Insolvency Rules seem to
require the liquidator to give written notice to the members. If this is not done, it is not
surprising that the final meeting is frequently inquorate.
78
IA 1986 s.94(3) and (4). If a quorum is not present the liquidator must send instead a
return that the meeting was duly summoned and that no quorum was present.
79 IA 1986 s.98(1).
80
In practice he or she will probably be the person that the directors intend to propose to
the company meeting for appointment as liquidator.
81 IA 1986 s.98(2).
82 IA 1986 s.99.
83 IA 1986 s.100.
84 IA 1986 ss.95 and 96.
85
IA 1986 s.101, and, when a members’ is converted to a creditors’ winding up, IA
1986 s.102.
86 IA 1986 s.141.
87 IA 1986 s.101(1). In the case of windings-up by the court the position under IA 1986
s.141 and Ch.12 of Pt IV of the Rules is somewhat different and is designed to ensure
that, when the official receiver is the liquidator, the committee’s functions are performed
instead by the Insolvency Service and that, if the liquidator is some other person, it is left
to that person to decide whether to convene a meeting of creditors to establish a
liquidation committee (unless one-tenth in value of the creditors require him to do so).
88 IA 1986 s.101(2).
89 IA 1986 s.101(3).
90
See, e.g. IA 1986 ss.103, 110, 165(2)(b) and (6), and the Insolvency Regulations 1986
(SI 1986/1994), reg.27(2), and Insolvency Rules 1986 (as amended), r.4.151ff.
91
Cmnd. 8558, para.939.
92
But, unless it is, the reverse is at present likely to be the case, resulting in members’
windings-up having to be converted into creditors’ (or to winding up by the court).
93
See IA 1986 ss.246ZE and 246ZF, and Insolvency Rules 2016 Explanatory Notes
(https://www.gov.uk/government/news/draft-insolvency-rules-sent-to-the-insolvency-
rules-committee-for-statutory-consultation [Accessed 27 February 2016]).
94
Re WeSellCNC.Com Ltd [2013] EWHC 4577 (Ch).
95
Re Celtic Extraction Ltd [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 555 at 568 CA.
96
With the exception of the exercise of certain statutory powers given specifically to the
liquidator: e.g. IA 1986 ss.212, 213 and 214.
97
But the liquidator may nevertheless sometimes incur personal liability if costs exceed
the company’s assets: Re Wilson Lovatt & Sons Ltd [1977] 1 All E.R. 274.
98
Knowles v Scott [1891] 1 Ch. 717.
99
Re Home and Colonial Insurance Co Ltd [1930] 1 Ch. 12; Pulsford v Devenish [1903]
2 Ch. 625.
100 Re Windsor Steam Coal Co (1901) Ltd [1928] Ch. 609.
101 This will be the creditors only, and perhaps not even all of them, if the company is
insolvent; and both creditors and members if the company is solvent. Special rules
govern the order of distribution, as described below.
102 Thus excluding assets in the company’s possession but, e.g. held on hire purchase, or
subject to retention of title agreements; or assets which the company does own, but
which are held on trust for the benefit of third parties or are subject to valid security
interests in favour of third party creditors.
103 This latter option for enhancing the asset pool has largely been examined already in
earlier chapters: see Ch.9 on fraudulent and wrongful trading.
104
See paras 32–44 et seq., above.
105Insolvency Rules 1986 (as amended) r.4.88. If the winding up follows an
administration in which the administrator has exercised his or her powers under Sch.B1,
paras 70 and 71 (para.32–45, above) it would seem that the effect of paras 70(2) and
71(3) will be to preserve the security holder’s rights by treating the sums mentioned in
those subsections as the security in the winding up.
106Unless the secured creditor is unusually altruistic or wants to maximise his or her
votes at a creditors’ meeting.
107 i.e. presentation of the petition (compulsory winding up, s.129) or passing of the
resolution (voluntary winding up, s.86).
108 IA 1986 ss.88, 127.
109
IA 1986 s.127.
110 IA 1986 s.128, and see ss.183–184 for all winding ups.
111 Re Gray’s Inn Construction Co Ltd [1980] 1 W.L.R. 711 CA.
112 Hollicourt (Contracts) Ltd v Bank of Ireland [2001] Ch. 555 CA.
113
On this point it seems Re Gray’s Inn Construction Co Ltd [1980] 1 W.L.R. 711 CA,
is still good authority.
114
Re Barn Crown Ltd [1995] 1 W.L.R. 147.
115
IA 1986 s.245, and see above, para.32–14.
116
On the s.123 test.
117
IA 1986 s.240(2). There is a rebuttable presumption that this is the case if the
transaction is with a connected person.
118
IA 1986 s.241.
119
Re MC Bacon [1990] B.C.L.C. 324 Ch.
120
Also see Phillips v Brewin Dolphin Bell Lawrie Ltd [2001] 1 W.L.R. 143 HL.
121
Hill v Spread Trustee Co Ltd [2006] EWCA Civ 542 (a case on IA 1986 s.423).
122 Companies Act 2006 s.1079.
123 See above, Ch.9.
124
But where there is fault, the defaulters should contribute to the insolvent company’s
assets, as we have already seen.
125
With some minor exceptions for identified vulnerable creditors (see below, at
para.33–24), and of course the major exception accorded to secured creditors who often
escape the burden of shared loses entirely, and in doing so disproportionately reduce the
assets available for those who are unsecured (see above, Ch.32).
126British Eagle International Airlines Ltd v Cie Nationale Air France [1975] 1 W.L.R.
758 HL.
127
By contrast, had the issue been mutual debits and credits been between Air France
and a single third party airline, insolvency set off would have allowed offsetting.
128Belmont Park Investments Pty Ltd v BNY Corporate Trustee Services Ltd and
Lehman Brothers Special Financing Inc [2011] UKSC 38. Commented on in
Worthington, “Good faith, flawed assets and the emasculation of the UK anti-
deprivation rule” (2012) 75 M.L.R. 112.
129 The existing approach to which the Supreme Court supported.
130 Ex p. Mackay (1873) L.R. 8 Ch. App. 643.
131It achieved this by clauses which altered net liability and flipped non-recourse
security arrangements so that third parties were preferred, not the insolvent company
(and therefore its general creditors).
132Re Anglo-Austrian Printing & Publishing Union [1895] 2 Ch. 891. Also see Re
Oasis Merchandising Services Ltd [1998] Ch. 170.
133 Insolvency Rules 1986 rr.4.73–4.94.
134 Insolvency Rules 1986 r.12.3(1).
135 Insolvency Rules 1986 r.13.12(1).
136 Insolvency Rules 1986 r.4.86.
137
IA 1986 s.168(3),(5).
138
Insolvency Rules 1986 rr.4.73, 4.82, 4.83.
139
Kaupthing Singer & Friedlander Ltd (In Administration); sub nom Mills v HSBC
Trustee (CI) Ltd [2011] UKSC 48; [2011] 3 W.L.R. 939 SC.
140
See above, fn.125.
141
Insolvency Rules 1986 r.4.90.
142
Stein v Blake [1996] 1 A.C. 243 at 251 (Lord Hoffmann).
143
National Westminster Bank Ltd v Halesowen Presswork and Assemblies Ltd [1972]
A.C. 785 at 809 (Lord Scarman), although the extent is surely not great.
144
P. Wood, Set-off and Netting, Derivatives and Clearing Systems, (London: Sweet &
Maxwell, 2007), para.1–012.
145 Although, to the contrary, see the claims for fairness in National Westminster Bank
Ltd v Halesowen Presswork and Assemblies Ltd [1972] A.C. 785 at 813 (Lord Cross);
Stein v Blake [1996] 1 A.C. 243 at 251 (Lord Hoffmann); Forster v Wilson (1843) 12 M.
& W. 191 at 204 (Parke B).
146 Contrast this outcome with that where the debts are not mutual, as in British Eagle:
see above, para.33–20.
147
Re Bank of Credit and Commerce International SA (No.8) [1998] A.C. 214 HL.
148 Contrast the outcome in MS Fashions Ltd v BCCI SA (No.2) [1993] Ch. 425, where
the guaranteeing director had expressly agreed to accept liability as principal debtor for
the borrowing company’s loan.
149
Insolvency Rules 1986 r.4.90(3).
150 Manson v Smith [1997] 2 B.C.L.C. 161 CA.
151 See above, para.33–17.
152But if the security is more than adequate to enable full repayment of the outstanding
secured debt, then the extra is added to the insolvency pool to be distributed in the same
way as the rest.
153 See above, paras 32–15 et seq.
154 Re Toshuku Finance UK Plc, Kahn v IRC [2002] UKHL 6 (on the relevant
corporations tax being such an expense). Also see IA 1986 s.156 and IR 1986 r.4.220(1)
which gives the court a discretion in a compulsory winding up to change this order of
priority between expenses. But once something is determined to be a liquidation
expense, the court has no discretion to deny it priority over other creditors’ claims which
are not liquidation expenses.
155 Re Toshuku Finance UK Plc, Kahn v IRC [2002] UKHL 6.
156 IA 1986 s.156 (compulsory liquidation) and s.115 (voluntary liquidation).
157Re Nortel GmbH and Lehman Bros International (Europe) Ltd [2011] EWCA Civ
1124 CA.
158 Bloom v Pensions Regulator [2013] UKSC 52; [2014] A.C. 209.
159
IA 1986 1986 Sch.4 and IR 1986 r.4.218(a) as amended, effectively reversing the
outcome in Re MC Bacon Ltd (No.2) [1990] B.C.L.C. 607 (Millett J); Re RS&M
Engineering Ltd, Mond v Studdards [1999] 2 B.C.L.C. 485 CA; and Re Floor Fourteen
Ltd, Lewis v IRC [2001] 2 B.C.L.C. 392 CA.
160
IA 1986 s.233(2)(b).
161
IA 1986 s.233(2)(a).
162
See the earlier discussion in relation to floating charges, above, para.32–15.
163
See above, para.32–17.
164
IA 1986 s.189.
165
Companies Act 2006 s.735.
166
IA 1986 s.74(2)(f).
167 Soden v British and Commonwealth Holdings Plc [1997] 2 B.C.L.C. 501 HL.
168 The justifications for this are various, not all equally compelling, but the gist is that
assets that are owned and worked produce more wealth, which is good for all, and the
availability of credit provides liquidity, enabling capital to be used profitably.
169 See Ch.4.
170In accordance with IA 1986 s.94 (members’ voluntary) or IA 1986 s.106 (creditors’
voluntary).
171
IA 1986 s.201(1) and (2).
172 IA 1986 s.201(3). It is then the duty of the applicant to deliver a copy of the order to
the Registrar for registration: IA 1986 s.201(4).
173
The relevant statutory provisions appear to apply to windings-up by the court on any
ground and whether or not the company is insolvent and not to require any final meeting
of the company (as in a voluntary liquidation). If this is correct, it is very curious. In a
winding up on the petition of a member on the ground that it is just and equitable, if the
company’s creditors have been fully paid it is only the members who will have any
interest in the result of the winding up.
174 See the draft Insolvency Regulations 2016:
https://www.gov.uk/government/news/draftinsolvency-rules-sent-to-the-insolvency-rules-
committee-for-statutory-consultation [Accessed 27 February 2016].
175
IA 1986 ss.146 and 172(8).
176 IA 1986 s.205(3). An appeal to the court lies from any such decision of the Secretary
of State: IA 1986 s.205(4).
177 IA 1986 s.205(1) and (2).
178 IA 1986 s.205(1)(b).
179 In Scotland (lacking official receivers) there is a procedure for early dissolution on
this ground alone but it involves an application to the court: IA 1986 s.204.
180 IA 1986 s.202(1) and (2).
181
IA 1986 s.202(3).
182
IA 1986 s.202(4).
183
IA 1986 s.202(5).
184
There is an apparent inconsistency between IA 1986 s.202(5) which says that the
application can be made by the official receiver “or any other person who appears to the
Secretary of State to be interested” and IA 1986 s.203(1) which says that it must be by
one of the persons mentioned in the text above. Presumably the Secretary of State will
not regard any other person as “interested”.
185
Neither of which is likely to be accepted by the Secretary of State if the official
receiver has concluded the contrary.
186
IA 1986 s.203(2).
187
IA 1986 s.203(3). There can be an appeal to the court against the Secretary of State’s
decision: IA 1986 s.203(4).
188CA 2006 s.1000(2). From hereon references to “the Act” are to the Companies Act
2006 unless the context otherwise requires.
189 CA 2006 s.1000(3).
190 CA 2006 s.1000(4)–(6).
191
See para.21–34.
192
See CA 2006 s.1002 for the methods of communication with the company.
193 Final Report I, para.11.20.
194Companies (Striking Off) (Electronic Communications) Order 2014; ss.1000 and
1002 as amended.
195
CA 2006 s.1001.
196 CA 2006 s.1001(1)–(4).
197 CA 2006 s.13 and Sch.5.
198 Under s.652A of the 1985 Act the provision applied only to private companies, but
s.1003 of the 2006 Act applies to public companies as well.
199
What this involves (or rather does not involve) is set out in some detail in s.1004. A
change of name during the period will bar an application even if there has been no
trading: s.1004(1)(a).
200 CA 2006 s.1003(2).
201 CA 2006 s.1011.
202
CA 2006 s.1006(1).
203 CA 2006 s.1003(3).
204 CA 2006 s.1003(4),(5).
205
If the company has assets and the application is successful, these will become bona
vacantia upon the dissolution of the company and so pass to the Crown or one of its
emanations: s.1012. Chapter 2 of Pt 31 contains provisions dealing with the methods and
consequences of disclaimer by the Crown of bona vacantia, which are not dealt with
here.
206
See Ch.29, above.
207 CA 2006 s.1005—or the Insolvency (Northern Ireland) Order 1989. If an application
for striking off has been made and any of these events occurs or the company does any
of the acts mentioned in s.1004 (see fn.199, above), the then directors of the company
are under a duty to withdraw the application: s.1009.
208
CA 2006 s.1003(6)(a). The same provision applies to a striking off under the
Registrar’s own motion: s.1000(7)(a).
209
Final Report I, paras 11.17–11.19.
210
CA 2006 s.1024(1).
211
CA 2006 s.1025(2). See Re Priceland Ltd [1997] 1 B.C.L.C. 467.
212 CA 2006 s.1024(3)—who must provide a certificate that he or she has the necessary
standing: s.1026.
213
CA 2006 s.1024(4). By that time, it may be thought, those involved with running the
former company will have accepted its striking off.
214 See fn.205, above.
215 CA 2006 s.1025(3),(4).
216
CA 2006 s.1025(5).
217
CA 2006 s.1025(1). There is no formal right of appeal if the Registrar refuses to
restore, but (a) presumably judicial review is available; and (b) the disappointed
applicant could re-apply under the court-based procedure (see below) and is given 28
days to do so, even if the six-year time limit for that procedure has expired: s.1030(5).
218 CA 2006 s.1027(2).
219 CA 2006 s.1027(3),(4).
220 CA 2006 s.1028(1)—but not so as to make the company liable for failing to file
reports and accounts during the period of dissolution (s.1028(2))! Section 1033 deals
with the situation where the company cannot be restored under its former name without
a breach of s.66 because another company now has that name. See Ch.4.
221 CA 2006 s.1028(3), (4). The statute appears not to undermine the distinction drawn
by the courts between dissolution after winding up and administrative striking off (of
either type) in terms of the impact of restoration on action purportedly taken by the
company in litigation during the period of dissolution. In the latter case subsequent
restoration automatically validates action during the period of dissolution: Top Creative
Ltd v St Albans DC [2000] 2 B.C.L.C. 379 CA.
222 CA 2006 s.1029(1).
223 CA 2006 s.1029(2).
224
CA 2006 s.1030(4). Under the 1985 Act the limitation period for s.651 claims was
two years and for s.653 claims 20 years. Six years is the period in England and Wales
after which many claims against the company will be time-barred.
225 CA 2006 s.1030(1)—though if the claim against the company appears to the court to
be time-barred, it may not order the restoration of the company: s.1030(2), (3). However,
the court may order under s.1032(3) that the period of dissolution should not count for
limitation purposes in respect of the personal injury claim. See Smith v White Knight
Laundry Ltd [2002] 1 W.L.R. 616 CA.
226
CA 2006 s.1031(1). The wording of the section suggests that the third ground applies
as well to a defunct company and voluntary striking off where the particular ground set
out in (a) or (b) is not available. On the exercise of the court’s discretion see Re
Priceland Ltd [1997] 1 B.C.L.C. 467; Re Blenheim Leisure (Restaurants) Ltd (No.2)
[2000] B.C.C. 821; Re Blue Note Enterprises Ltd [2001] 2 B.C.L.C. 427.
227
CA 2006 s.1031(2),(3).
228
CA 2006 s.1032(1),(2).
229
CA 2006 s.1032(3). See Joddrell v Peaktone Ltd [2012] EWCA Civ 1035; [2013] 1
W.L.R. 784 CA at [40]–[49] (Munby LJ) for a description of the retrospective effect of
s.1032. Note, too, County Leasing Asset Management Ltd v Hawkes [2015] EWCA Civ
1251, where a limitation direction preventing time running granted in favour of a
restored company.
INDEX
This index has been prepared using Sweet and Maxwell’s Legal Taxonomy. Main index entries
conform to keywords provided by the Legal Taxonomy except where references to specific
documents or non-standard terms (denoted by quotation marks) have been included. These
keywords provide a means of identifying similar concepts in other Sweet and Maxwell publications
and online services to which keywords from the Legal Taxonomy have been applied. Readers may
find some minor differences between terms used in the text and those which appear in the index.
Suggestions to sweetandmaxwell.taxonomy@thomson.com.
All references are to paragraph number
Acceptance of benefits from third parties see Directors’ powers and duties
Accessories
criminal liability, 7–36
Account of profits
breach of directors’ duties
generally, 16–114—16–115
introduction, 16–106
substantial property transactions, 16–76
breach of promoter’s duties, 5–18—5–19
Accounting records see Financial records
Accounting standards
annual accounts
Companies Act accounts, 21–16
conclusion, 21–43
form and content, 21–13—21–21
generally, 21–17
going concern, 21–15
IAS accounts, 21–18—21–19
introduction, 21–7
small companies, 21–20
annual reporting requirement, 21–1
auditors
claims by audit client, 22–36—22–37
independence and competence, 22–11
regulation, 22–28
generally, 21–17
introduction, 3–9
self-dealing, 16–54
Accounts
Accounting Principles and Rules, 21–16
accounting records, 21–7
accounting standards, 21–17
annual accounts
accounting records, 21–7
accounting standards, 21–17
balance sheet, 21–16
financial year, 21–8
form and content, 21–13—21–21
going concern, 21–15
group accounts, 21–9—21–12
IAS requirements, 21–18—21–19
individual accounts, 21–9—21–12
notes, 21–21
profit and loss account, 21–16
small companies, 21–20
true and fair view, 21–14
approval, 21–29
balance sheet, 21–16
circulation to members
generally, 21–40
Strategic Report only, of, 22–41
classification of companies
introduction, 21–2
large companies, 21–6
medium-sized companies, 21–5
micro companies, 21–3
public interest entities, 21–6
rationale, 21–1
scope, 21–1
small companies, 21–4
Companies Act requirements, 21–16
filing
introduction, 21–33
modifications of requirements, 21–35—21–36
speed, 21–34
financial records, 21–7
foreign companies, 6–6
going concern, 21–15
group accounts
companies excluded from consolidation, 21–12
introduction, 21–9
parent and subsidiary undertakings, 21–10
parent companies which are part of larger group, 21–11
IAS requirements, 21–18—21–19
individual accounts
companies excluded from consolidation, 21–12
introduction, 21–9
parent companies, 21–10
parent companies which are part of larger group, 21–11
laying before members, 21–42
notes, 21–21
profit and loss account, 21–16
publicity, 21–39
records, 21–7
revision, 21–31—21–32
shareholder meetings, 15–43
small companies, 21–20
standards, 21–17
‘statutory accounts’, 21–39
true and fair view, 21–14
Acquisition of own shares
company may not be member of its holding company, 13–4
court orders, 13–5
exceptions to general rule
effect, 13–6
generally, 13–5
forfeiture, 13–5
general prohibition, 13–2—13–6
gifts, 13–5
nominee, through, 13–3
purchase of own shares
background, 13–8
conclusion, 13–29
creditor protection, 13–11—13–12
failure by company to perform, 13–28
general restrictions, 13–9—13–10
introduction, 13–7—13–10
private companies, 13–13—13–18
shareholder protection, 13–19—13–23
Treasury shares, 13–24—13–27
redemption
background, 13–8
conclusion, 13–29
creditor protection, 13–11—13–12
failure by company to perform, 13–28
general restrictions, 13–9—13–10
introduction, 13–7—13–10
private companies, 13–13—13–18
shareholder protection, 13–19—13–23
reduction of capital, 13–5
repurchase
background, 13–8
conclusion, 13–29
creditor protection, 13–11—13–12
failure by company to perform, 13–28
general restrictions, 13–9—13–10
introduction, 13–7—13–10
private companies, 13–13—13–18
shareholder protection, 13–19—13–23
Treasury shares, 13–24—13–27
share premium account, 13–1
unfair prejudice, 13–5
Act within scope of powers conferred see Directors’ powers and duties
Acting in concert see Takeovers
Acts of Parliament
unregistered companies, 1–31
Adjournments
shareholder meetings, 15–83
Adjudicators
company names, 4–27—4–29
Administrators
appointment, 32–44
duties, 32–45—32–46
end of appointment, 32–50
expenses, 32–49
function, 32–43
introduction, 32–34—32–36
powers, 32–45—32–46
protection for creditors and members, 32–47
publicity for appointment, 32–48
Admission to listing see Public offers
Agency
administrators, 32–47
attribution rules, 7–18
conclusion, 7–48
contracting through agents, 7–16
contractual liability of agents
agency principles, 7–18—7–19
attribution, 7–18
authority of corporate agents, 7–20—7–23
generally, 7–16—7–17
knowledge, 7–24—7–26
ostensible authority, 7–20—7–23
overall, 7–28
overview, 7–4
ratification, 7–27
directors’ duties
individual shareholders, 16–5—16–6
senior managers, 16–11
general principles, 7–18—7–19
limited liability
generally, 8–13
introduction, 2–11
ostensible authority, 7–20—7–23
overseas companies, 6–2
partnership law, 1–2
proxies, 15–71
receivers, 32–38
vicarious liability, 7–31
Agendas
shareholder meetings
circulation of members’ statements, 15–59
information concerning, 15–60
introduction, 15–56
placing item on the agenda, 15–57—15–58
Agents
see also Agency
contractual liability
agency principles, 7–18—7–19
attribution, 7–18
authority of corporate agents, 7–20—7–23
generally, 7–16—7–17
knowledge, 7–24—7–26
ostensible authority, 7–20—7–23
overall, 7–28
overview, 7–4
ratification, 7–27
Alternative Investment Market
exchange admission standards, 25–16
promoters, 5–5
public offers, 25–5
publicly traded companies, 1–25
purchase of own shares, 13–19
redeemable shares, 13–19
Annual accounts
Accounting Principles and Rules, 21–16
accounting records, 21–7
accounting standards, 21–17
approval, 21–29
auditors’ role, 22–1
balance sheet, 21–16
circulation to members
generally, 21–40
Strategic Report only, of, 22–41
classification of companies
introduction, 21–2
large companies, 21–6
medium-sized companies, 21–5
micro companies, 21–3
public interest entities, 21–6
rationale, 21–1
scope, 21–1
small companies, 21–4
Companies Act requirements, 21–16
filing
introduction, 21–33
modifications of requirements, 21–35—21–36
speed, 21–34
financial records, 21–7
foreign companies, 6–6
form and content
accounting standards, 21–17
balance sheet, 21–16
going concern, 21–15
IAS requirements, 21–18—21–19
introduction, 21–13
notes, 21–21
profit and loss account, 21–16
small companies, 21–20
true and fair view, 21–14
going concern, 21–15
group accounts
companies excluded from consolidation, 21–12
introduction, 21–9
parent and subsidiary undertakings, 21–10
parent companies which are part of larger group, 21–11
IAS requirements, 21–18—21–19
individual accounts
companies excluded from consolidation, 21–12
introduction, 21–9
parent companies, 21–10
parent companies which are part of larger group, 21–11
large companies, 21–6
laying before members, 21–42
medium-sized companies, 21–5
micro companies, 21–3
notes, 21–21
profit and loss account, 21–16
public interest entities, 21–6
publicity, 21–39
records, 21–7
revision, 21–31—21–32
shareholder meetings, 15–43
small companies
generally, 21–4
parent companies, 21–20
standards, 21–17
true and fair view, 21–14
Annual general meetings
see also General meetings
agenda items, 15–56—15–62
annual reporting requirement, 21–1
audit committees, 22–25
conclusion, 15–87
generally, 15–49—15–50
introduction, 15–48
pre-emption rights, 24–14
private companies, 15–8—15–9
verifying votes, 15–76
voluntary arrangements, 15–36
Annual reports
approval, 21–29
business review
introduction, 21–24
verification, 21–26
classification of companies, 21–2
directors’ reports
approval, 21–29
introduction, 21–23
liability for misstatements, 21–27—21–28
foreign companies, 6–6
narrative reporting
approval, 21–29
background, 21–22
directors’ remuneration reports, 21–22
directors’ reports, 21–23
generally, 21–22
liability for misstatements, 21–27—21–28
strategic reports, 21–24—21–25
verification, 21–26—21–27
Annual returns
disclosure of major shareholding, 26–14
generally, 21–38
Anti-deprivation principle
collection realisation and distribution of company’s assets, 33–20
“Appraisal rights”
mergers, 29–1
minority shareholders, 19–3
reorganisations, 29–25
Articles of association
alterations, 3–31—3–32
board of directors
default provision, 14–3—14–4
legal effect, 14–5—14–10
distributions and dividends, 12–1
enforcement
individual rights, 3–27—3–30
rights ‘as a member’, 3–23—3–26
filing, 21–37
formation of companies
choice, 4–32—4–33
generally, 4–5
generally, 3–14—3–15
individual rights to correct irregularities, 3–27—3–30
legal status
alterations, 3–31—3–32
articles of association, 3–14—3–15
individual rights to correct irregularities, 3–27—3–30
introduction, 3–18
limits to enforcement, 3–23—3–30
nature, 3–16—3–17
parties to the contract, 3–19
public document, 3–20—3–22
rights ‘as a member’, 3–23—3–26
nature, 3–16—3–17
parties to the contract, 3–19
public document, 3–20—3–22
rights ‘as a member’, 3–23—3–26
self-help, 19–23—19–24
shareholder agreements, 3–33—3–35
significance, 3–13
written resolutions, 15–14
Assumption of responsibility
tortious liability, 7–32
Attendance
shareholder meetings
company representatives, 15–72
proxies, 15–67—15–71
Audit committees
auditor independence and competence, 22–10
composition, 22–24
directors’ duties of skill care and diligence, 16–19
functions, 22–25
introduction, 22–23
Auditors
see also Audits
annual accounts, 22–1
appointment, 22–17
competence
auditing standards, 22–28
generally, 22–26
introduction, 22–10
investigations, 22–29
qualifications, 22–27
quality assurance, 22–29
regulatory structure, 22–11
criminal liability, 22–43
directors’ remuneration reports, 22–1
directors’ reports, 22–1
discipline, 22–29
disqualified persons
auditors becoming non-independent, 22–14
auditors becoming prospectively non-independent, 22–15
non-audit remuneration, 22–13
non-independent persons, 22–12
duties, 22z-3
ethical standards, 22–13
failure to re-appoint, 22–20
independence
auditors becoming non-independent, 22–14
auditors becoming prospectively non-independent, 22–15
direct regulation, 22–12—22–
introduction, 22–10
non-audit remuneration, 22–13
non-independent persons, 22–12
regulatory structure, 22–11
investigations, 22–29
liability
criminal liability, 22–43
negligence, 22–31—22–52
negligence
assumption of responsibility, 22–47—22–51
client claims, 22–36—22–43
contractual limitation, 22–42
defences, 22–39—22–41
establishing liability, 22–36—22–37
introduction, 22–31—22–33
limits of liability, 22–38—22–42
nature of the issue, 22–31—22–33
provision of audit services, 22–34—22–35
third party claims, 22–44—22–52
non-audit remuneration, 22–13
non-independent persons
becoming non-independent, 22–14
becoming prospectively non-independent, 22–15
generally, 22–12
overarching issues, 22–4
powers, 22–30
qualifications, 22–27
qualified reports, 22–1
quality assurance, 22–29
removal
failure to re-appoint, 22–20
notifications, 22–19
shareholder resolution, 22–18
remuneration, 22–17
reports, 22–22
requests for information, 22–30
resignation
non-independent persons, and, 22–12
notifications, 22–19
prospectively non-independent persons, and, 22–15
shareholder resolution, 22–18
role, 22–1—22–2
shareholders’ role
appointment of auditors, 22–17
audit reports, 22–22
introduction, 22–16
removal of auditors, 22–18—22–19
remuneration of auditors, 22–17
whistleblowing, 22–21
third party claims
assumption of responsibility, 22–47—22–51
duty of care, 22–44—22–46
other issues, 22–52
unqualified reports, 22–1
volunteered information, 22–32
whistleblowing, 22–21
Auditors’ reports
generally, 21–30
revision, 21–31—21–32
Audits
see also Auditors
audit committees
composition, 22–24
functions, 22–25
introduction, 22–23
auditing standards, 22–28
auditors
appointment, 22–17
competence, 22–26—22–30
disqualified persons, 22–12—22–15
failure to re-appoint, 22–20
independence, 22–10—22–15
liability for negligence, 22–31—22–52
non-audit remuneration, 22–13
powers, 22–30
qualifications, 22–27
removal, 22–18—22–19
remuneration, 22–17
role, 22–1—22–2
whistleblowing, 22–21
charitable companies, 22–5
conclusion, 22–53
dormant companies, 22–8
exemption
charitable companies, 22–5
dormant companies, 22–8
non-profit public sector companies, 22–9
small companies, 22–5—22–6
subsidiary companies, 22–7
introduction, 22–1
non-profit public sector companies, 22–9
overarching issues, 22–4
purpose, 22–1
reports, 22–22
shareholders’ role
appointment of auditors, 22–17
audit reports, 22–22
introduction, 22–16
removal of auditors, 22–18—22–19
remuneration of auditors, 22–17
whistleblowing, 22–21
small charitable companies, 22–5
small companies, 22–5—22–6
sources of law, 22–2
subsidiary companies, 22–7
Authority
board of directors
confirmation powers of general meeting, 14–11—14–14
default provision, 14–3—14–4
involvement of shareholders, 14–18—14–20
legal effect, 14–5—14–10
unanimous consent of shareholders, 14–15—14–17
Balance sheet
accounting records, 21–7
annual accounts, 21–16
capital
capitalisation issues, 11–20
meaning, 11–1
capital maintenance
acquisition of own shares, 13–6
introduction, 13–1
reduction of capital, 13–30
dividends and distributions, 12–2—12–4
filing, 21–35—21–36
generally, 21–16
medium-sized companies, 21–5
micro companies, 21–3
parent companies, 21–10
public interest entities, 21–2
publicity, 21–39
small companies
audit exemption, 22–6
generally, 21–4
subsidiary companies, 21–10
takeovers, 28–21
Bankruptcy
borrowing, 2–31
derivative claims, 17–12
directors disqualification, 10–16
share transfers, 27–21
wrongful trading, 9–8
Bearer bonds
debentures, 31–12
Beneficial ownership
takeovers, 28–50—28–52
Board of directors
appointment of directors, 14–23—14–29
articles of association
default provision, 14–3—14–4
legal effect, 14–5—14–10
authority
confirmation powers of general meeting, 14–11—14–14
default provision, 14–3—14–4
involvement of shareholders, 14–18—14–20
legal effect, 14–5—14–10
unanimous consent of shareholders, 14–15—14–17
company incorporation, 2–27—2–30
composition
employee representatives, 14–67
gender diversity, 14–68
introduction, 14–63
legal rule, 14–67—14–74
UK Corporate Governance Code, 14–69—14–80
conclusion, 14–81
confirmation powers of general meeting
generally, 14–11—14–14
unanimous consent of shareholders, 14–15—14–17
contractual liability
constructive notice, 7–6—7–8
introduction, 7–5
overview, 7–4
protection for third parties dealing with the board, 7–9—7–15
rule in Turquand’s case, 7–6—7–8
Corporate Governance Code
enforcement, 14–77—14–80
generally, 14–69—14–74
requirements, 14–75—14–76
derivative claims, 17–2
directors’ remuneration report, 14–44—14–47
distributions and dividends, 12–1
employee representatives, 14–67
functions, 14–21—14–22
gender diversity, 14–68
involvement of shareholders in decisions, 14–18—14–20
long-term incentive pay schemes, 14–35—14–37
management, 14–9—14–10
powers, 14–5—14–17
removal of directors
directors’ contractual rights, 14–53—14–55
directors’ procedural rights, 14–52
introduction, 14–48
shareholders’ statutory rights, 14–49—14–55
termination payments, 14–56—14–62
weighted voting rights, 14–51
remuneration of directors
composition of remuneration committee, 14–33
disclosure, 14–44—14–47
generally, 14–30—14–32
long-term incentive pay schemes, 14–35—14–37
remuneration report, 14–44—14–47
shareholder advisory vote, 14–38—14–43
shareholder approval of aspects, 14–34—14–37
requirements of UK Code, 14–75—14–80
role
default provision, 14–3—14–4
generally, 14–1—14–2
involvement of shareholders, 14–18—14–20
legal effect, 14–5—14–10
senior management, 14–9—14–10
shareholders
confirmation powers, 14–15—14–17
general role, 14–5—14–8
removal of directors, 14–49—14–55
remuneration of directors, 14–34—14–43
termination payments for directors, 14–59—14–62
structure
introduction, 14–63
legal rule, 14–64—14–66
termination payments for directors
disclosure, 14–57—14–58
general controls, 14–56
shareholder approval, 14–62
terms governing duration of directors’ contracts, 14–60—14–61
Bonds
debentures, 31–12—31–13
Bonus issues
capital, 11–20
financial assistance, 13–50
variation of class rights, 19–16—19–17
Borrowing powers
company incorporation, 2–31—2–33
Branches
foreign companies, 6–4
Breach of duty of care
directors’ duties
remedies, 16–109—16–116
shareholder approval, 16–117—16–124
remedies
accounting for profits, 16–114—16–115
act within scope of powers conferred, 16–30—16–32
avoidance of contracts, 16–113
benefits from third parties, 16–108
compensation, 16–111
competing directorships, 16–106
damages, 16–111
declarations, 16–110
diligence, 16–20
disclosure of interest in existing transactions, 16–66
disclosure of interest in proposed transactions, 16–62
disgorgement of disloyal gains, 16–114—16–115
generally, 16–109
injunctions, 16–110
multiple directorships, 16–106
restoration of property, 16–112
shareholder approval, 16–117—16–132
skill and care, 16–20
substantial property transactions, 16–73—16–76
summary dismissal, 16–116
types, 16–109
use of corporate opportunities, 16–106
shareholder approval
decisions being made, 16–118
disenfranchising voters, 16–121—16–122
introduction, 16–117
not-ratifiable breaches, 16–124
person taking the decision, 16–119—16–120
voting majorities, 16–123
“Break-through rule”
takeovers, 28–22—28–24
Building societies
generally, 1–34—1–35
Business commencement
formation of companies, 4–38
Business names
formation of companies, 4–20—4–21
Business reviews
introduction, 21–24
verification, 21–26
Capital
authorised capital, 11–12
board of directors, 12–1
bonus issues, 11–20
conclusion, 11–21
consideration received upon issue
all companies, 11–14
introduction, 11–13
non-cash consideration, 11–16—11–17
public companies, 11–15
sanctions, 11–18
currency, 11–19
disclosure and verification
abolition of authorised capital, 11–12
consideration received upon issue, 11–13—11–18
currency, 11–19
introduction, 11–10
return of allotments, 11–11
statements of capital, 11–11
distributions and dividends, 12–1
meaning, 11–1—11–2
minimum capital
general requirement, 11–8
introduction, 11–2
objections to requirement, 11–9
no issue of shares at a discount, 11–4—11–5
nominal value, 11–3
non-cash consideration, 11–16—11–17
public companies, 11–15
return of allotments, 11–11
share premium, 11–6—11–7
statements of capital, 11–11
Capital maintenance
acquisition of own shares
company may not be member of its holding company, 13–4
court orders, 13–5
exceptions to general rule, 13–5—13–6
forfeiture, 13–5
general prohibition, 13–2—13–6
gifts, 13–5
nominee, through, 13–3
redemption, 13–7—13–29
reduction of capital, 13–5
re-purchase, 13–7—13–29
unfair prejudice, 13–5
conclusion, 13–59
financial assistance
background, 13–44—13–46
exceptions, 13–50—13–54
general prohibition, 13–47—13–49
introduction, 13–44
private company exemption, 13–55
rationale of rule, 13–44
remedies for breach of prohibition, 13–56—13–58
introduction, 13–1
overview, 11–2
purchase of own shares
background, 13–8
conclusion, 13–29
creditor protection, 13–11—13–12
failure by company to perform, 13–28
general restrictions, 13–9—13–10
introduction, 13–7—13–10
private companies, 13–13—13–18
shareholder protection, 13–19—13–23
Treasury shares, 13–24—13–27
redeemable shares
background, 13–8
conclusion, 13–29
creditor protection, 13–11—13–12
failure by company to perform, 13–28
general restrictions, 13–9—13–10
introduction, 13–7—13–10
private companies, 13–13—13–18
shareholder protection, 13–19—13–23
reduction of share capital
all companies, 13–34—13–38
confirmation by court, 13–36—13–38
creditor objection, 13–35
generally, 13–30—13–32
private companies, 13–39—13–43
purpose, 13–31
statutory procedures, 13–33—13–43
“Capital redemption reserve”
distributions and dividends, 12–2
purchase of own shares, 13–11—13–12
redeemable shares, 13–11—13–12
Care and skill see Directors’ powers and duties
“Certificated shares”
company lien, 27–11
estoppel, 27–6
generally, 27–5—27–11
legal ownership, 27–5
meaning, 27–3—27–4
positions of transferor and transferee, 27–8
priorities between competing transferees, 27–10
restrictions, 27–7
Certificates of incorporation
challenges to, 4–34—4–37
charter companies, 4–3
choice of type of company, 4–10—4–12
generally, 4–7—4–8
Chairman
shareholder meetings, 15–82
Charges
administrators
appointment, 32–44
duties, 32–45—32–46
end of appointment, 32–50
expenses, 32–49
function, 32–43
introduction, 32–34—32–36
powers, 32–45—32–46
protection for creditors and members, 32–47
publicity for appointment, 32–48
benefits of security, 32–4
conclusion, 32–51
enforcement
administration, 32–43—32–50
introduction, 32–34—32–36
receivership, 32–37—32–42
floating charges
administrators’ powers, 32–20
automatic crystallisation, 32–9
costs of liquidation, 32–18—32–19
crystallisation, 32–8—32–9
defective charges, 32–25—32–14
distinction from fixed charges, 32–21—32–23
enforcement, 32–34—32–50
negative pledge clauses, 32–11
practical differences from fixed charges, 32–5—32–7
preferential creditors, 32–15—32–16
prescribed part, 32–17
priority, 32–10—32–12
registration, 32–24—32–33
sharing with unsecured creditors, 32–17
statutory limitations, 32–13—32–20
subordination agreements, 32–12
introduction, 32–1
legal nature, 32–2—32–3
receivers
appointment, 32–37
function, 32–38—32–39
introduction, 32–34—32–36
liability with respect to contracts, 32–40—32–41
publicity for appointment and reports, 32–42
status, 32–38—32–39
registration
current system, 32–26
defective, 32–31
effect, 32–32
failure to register, 32–29
geographical reach, 32–28
late, 32–30
mechanics, 32–27
purpose, 32–24—32–25
reform proposals, 32–33
registrable charges, 32–26
security interests, 32–2—32–4
Charitable companies
audits, 22–5
conflicts of interest, 16–86
contractual liability, 7–29
incorporation, 1–30
name, 4–15
not-for-profit organisations, 1–7
self-dealing, 16–86
Charitable incorporated organisations
classification of companies, 1–30
formation, 4–1
Charter companies
formation, 4–3
generally, 1–31—1–33
Circulars
shareholder meetings, 15–65
City Code on Takeovers and Mergers
see also Takeovers
companies covered
generally, 28–15
jurisdiction, 28–15—28–17
divided jurisdiction, 28–16—28–17
General Principles, 28–18
generally, 28–13
introduction, 28–3
jurisdiction
divided, 28–16—28–17
full, 28–15
scope
companies, 28–15—28–17
introduction, 28–13
transactions, 28–14
structure, 28–18
transactions covered, 28–14
Civil proceedings
company incorporation, 2–18
Class meetings
see also General meetings
generally, 15–84
Class rights
company constitution, 3–16
definition, 19–18—19–20
disclosure of shareholdings, 26–17
distribution of company’s assets on winding-up, 33–24—33–26
introduction, 19–13
other cases, 19–21
procedure for variation, 19–14—19–15
reduction of capital, 13–34
self-help, 19–22
share classes, 23–6
shareholders’ role in management, 14–18
‘variation’, 19–16—19–17
Clawback
collection realisation and distribution of company’s assets
anti-deprivation principle, 33–20
avoidance provisions, 33–18
benefit, 33–21
clawback, 33–18
distribution of company’s assets, 33–24—33–26
generally, 33–18
maximising assets available for distribution, 33–17—33–21
proof of debts, 33–22
set off, 33–23
wrongdoer contributions, 33–19
Common law
sources of law, 3–10
Community interest companies
charitable companies, 1–7
classification of companies, 1–29
formation of companies, 4–6
generally, 1–12
re-registration, 4–46
Companies
advantages, 1–13—1–16
business vehicles, 1–2—1–5
classification
activity, 1–29—1–30
limited, 1–27
officially listed, 1–22—1–26
public and private, 1–18—1–21
publicly traded, 1–22—1–26
size, 1–28
unlimited, 1–27
conclusion, 1–47
European Community forms, 1–37—1–46
incorporation, 2–1—2–48
legislative background, 1–2—1–5
meaning, 1–1
not-for-profit organisations, 1–6—1–7
types, 1–17—1–36
uses, 1–1—1–16
Companies limited by guarantee
not-for-profit organisations, 1–8—1–10
Company constitutions
see also Articles of association
alterations, 3–31—3–32
articles of association, 3–14—3–15
filing, 21–37
individual rights to correct irregularities, 3–27—3–30
legal status
alterations, 3–31—3–32
articles of association, 3–14—3–15
individual rights to correct irregularities, 3–27—3–30
introduction, 3–18
limits to enforcement, 3–23—3–30
nature, 3–16—3–17
parties to the contract, 3–19
public document, 3–20—3–22
rights ‘as a member’, 3–23—3–26
limits to enforcement, 3–23—3–30
nature, 3–16—3–17
parties to the contract, 3–19
public document, 3–20—3–22
rights ‘as a member’, 3–23—3–26
shareholder agreements, 3–33—3–35
significance, 3–13
Company formation see Company
incorporation
Company incorporation
advantages and disadvantages, 2–1—2–48
application, 4–5
articles of association
choice, 4–32—4–33
generally, 4–5
borrowing, 2–31—2–33
business names, 4–20—4–21
certificate of incorporation
challenges to, 4–34—4–37
generally, 4–7—4–8
charter companies, 4–3
choice of type of company, 4–10—4–12
commencement of business, 4–38
community interest companies, 4–6
company names
adjudicators, 4–27—4–29
changes to, 4–22—4–31
choice, 4–13—4–21
defunct company’s name, 4–19
effect of change, 4–31
election to change, 4–30
illegal names, 4–16
index, 4–18
limited suffix, 4–14—4–15
mandatory changes, 4–23—4–24
name already allocated, 4–18
offensive names, 4–16
passing off actions, 4–25—4–26
phoenix companies, 4–19
special approval requirement, 4–17
conclusion, 4–47
documentation, 4–5—4–6
expense, 2–35—2–38
formalities, 2–35—2–38
introduction, 4–1
legal entity distinct from members, 2–1—2–8
limited liability, 2–9—2–15
management under Board structure, 2–27—2–30
memorandum of association, 4–5
property, 2–16—2–17
public companies, 4–4
publicity
company’s affairs, 2–39
directors, 2–40
members of company, 2–41
‘people with significant control’, 2–42—2–47
registered companies, 4–4
registration
articles of association, 4–32—4–33
certificate of incorporation, 4–7—4–8
challenges, 4–34—4–37
choice of type, 4–10—4–12
company names, 4–13—4–31
documentation, 4–5—4–6
shelf companies, 4–9
shelf companies, 4–9
statement of compliance, 4–5
statutory undertakings, 4–2
succession, 2–19—2–23
suing and being sued, 2–18
taxation, 2–34
transferable shares, 2–24—2–26
Company investigations
appointment of inspectors, 18–5—18–6
company ownership, 18–11
conclusion, 18–15
disclosure of documents and information, 18–2—18–4
follow-ups, 18–13—18–14
formal investigations
appointment of inspectors, 18–5—18–6
conduct, 18–7—18–9
powers of inspectors, 18–7—18–9
reports, 18–10
informal investigations, 18–2—18–4
inspectors
appointment, 18–5—18–6
powers, 18–7—18–9
reports, 18–10
introduction, 18–1
liability for costs, 18–12
powers of inspectors, 18–7—18–9
reports, 18–10
Company law
constitution
alterations, 3–31—3–32
articles of association, 3–14—3–15
individual rights to correct irregularities, 3–27—3–30
legal status, 3–18—3–32
limits to enforcement, 3–23—3–30
nature, 3–16—3–17
parties to the contract, 3–19
public document, 3–20—3–22
rights ‘as a member’, 3–23—3–26
shareholder agreements, 3–33—3–35
significance, 3–13
EU law
corporate governance, 6–15
harmonisation, 6–9—6–11
reform of directives, 6–16
single financial market, 6–14
subsidiarity, 6–12—6–13
sources of law
common law, 3–10
delegated rule-making, 3–7—3–9
European companies, 3–36
FRC, 3–9
FSA rules, 3–7—3–8
introduction, 3–1—3–2
primary legislation, 3–3—3–4
reform, 3–11—3–12
secondary legislation, 3–5—3–6
Company management
company incorporation, 2–27—2–30
Company names
adjudicators, 4–27—4–29
changes to
adjudicators, 4–27—4–29
effect of change, 4–31
election by company, 4–30
introduction, 4–22
passing off actions, 4–25—4–26
Secretary of State, 4–23—4–24
choice, 4–13—4–21
defunct company’s name, 4–19
effect of change, 4–31
election to change, 4–30
foreign companies, 6–7
illegal names, 4–16
index, 4–18
liability for abuses
exceptions, 9–19
generally, 9–16
prohibition, 9–17—9–18
limited suffix, 4–14—4–15
mandatory and elective changes
adjudicators, 4–27—4–29
effect of change, 4–31
election by company, 4–30
introduction, 4–22
passing off actions, 4–25—4–26
Secretary of State, 4–23—4–24
name already allocated, 4–18
offensive names, 4–16
passing off actions, 4–25—4–26
phoenix companies, 4–19
prohibitions
illegal names, 4–16
name already allocated, 4–18
offensive names, 4–16
special approval requirement, 4–17
use of name already allocated, 4–18
Company registration
application, 4–5
articles of association
choice, 4–32—4–33
generally, 4–5
business names, 4–20—4–21
certificate of incorporation
challenges to, 4–34—4–37
generally, 4–7—4–8
charter companies, 4–3
choice of type of company, 4–10—4–12
commencement of business, 4–38
community interest companies, 4–6
company names
adjudicators, 4–27—4–29
changes to, 4–22—4–31
choice, 4–13—4–21
defunct company’s name, 4–19
effect of change, 4–31
election to change, 4–30
illegal names, 4–16
index, 4–18
limited suffix, 4–14—4–15
mandatory changes, 4–23—4–24
name already allocated, 4–18
offensive names, 4–16
passing off actions, 4–25—4–26
phoenix companies, 4–19
special approval requirement, 4–17
conclusion, 4–47
documentation, 4–5—4–6
introduction, 4–1
memorandum of association, 4–5
public companies, 4–4
registered companies, 4–4
re-registration
community interest companies, 4–46
company becoming unlimited, 4–43—4–44
introduction, 4–39
private company becoming public, 4–40
public company becoming private, 4–41—4–42
unlimited company becoming private, 4–45
shelf companies, 4–9
statement of compliance, 4–5
statutory undertakings, 4–2
Compensation
breach of directors’ duties, 16–111
disqualification of directors, 10–4
takeovers, 28–10
Competing directorships see Directors’ powers
and duties
Compulsory winding-up
discretion of court, 33–6
grounds, 33–3
inability to pay debts, 33–5
liquidators, 33–7
official receivers, 33–7
petitioners, 33–4
proof of inability to pay debts, 33–5
provisional liquidators, 33–7
timing of commencement, 33–8
Confirmation statements
generally, 21–38
Conflicts of interest
acceptance of benefits from third parties
generally, 16–107
remedies for breach, 16–108
credit transactions
arrangements covered, 16–78—16–80
disclosures, 16–81
exceptions, 16–82
method of approval, 16–81
remedies for breach, 16–83
directors’ powers and duties
benefits from third parties, 16–107—16–108
exemptions from liability, and, 16–126—16–127
generally, 16–52—16–53
self-dealing, 16–54—16–66
transactions with the company, 16–54—16–85
use of corporate property etc, 16–106
directors’ remuneration, 16–84
directors’ service contracts, 16–84
disclosure of interest in existing transactions
generally, 16–64
introduction, 16–54
methods, 16–65
remedies for breach, 16–66
disclosure of interest in proposed transactions
generally, 16–57
interests to be disclosed, 16–60
introduction, 16–54
methods of disclosure, 16–61
persons subject to duty, 16–59
purpose of requirement, 16–58
remedies for breach, 16–62
role of articles of association, 16–63
generally, 16–52—16–53
loans
arrangements covered, 16–78—16–80
disclosures, 16–81
exceptions, 16–82
method of approval, 16–81
remedies for breach, 16–83
payments for loss of office, 16–84
political donations and expenditure, 16–85
self-dealing
approval mechanisms, 16–55—16–56
interest in existing transactions, 16–64—16–66
interest in proposed transactions, 16–57—16–63
introduction, 16–54
substantial property transactions
listed companies, 16–77
remedies for breach, 16–73—16–76
requirement for approval, 16–70—16–71
transactions requiring special approval of members
directors’ remuneration, 16–84
directors’ service contracts, 16–84
introduction, 16–67
loans and credit, 16–78—16–83
payments for loss of office, 16–84
political donations and expenditure, 16–85
relationship with general duties, 16–68—16–69
substantial property transactions, 16–70—16–77
transactions with the company
requiring special approval, 16–67—16–85
self-dealing, 16–54—16–66
use of corporate information, 16–86
use of corporate opportunities
authorisation by the board, 16–103—16–104
conceptual issue, 16–105
generally, 16–87—16–88
identification, 16–89—16–98
introduction, 16–86
remedies for breach, 16–106
use of corporate property, 16–86
Consent
shareholder decision-making, 15–15—15–21
Consideration
capital
all companies, 11–14
introduction, 11–13
non-cash consideration, 11–16—11–17
public companies, 11–15
sanctions, 11–18
Consolidated Admissions Requirements
Directive (2001/34/EC)
admission to listing, 25–15
introduction, 25–5
types of listing, 25–6
Constructive notice
contracting through the board or shareholders collectively, 7–6—7–8
Contractual liability
charitable companies, 7–29
contracting through agents
agency principles, 7–18—7–19
attribution, 7–18
authority of corporate agents, 7–20—7–23
generally, 7–16—7–17
knowledge, 7–24—7–26
ostensible authority, 7–20—7–23
overall, 7–28
overview, 7–4
ratification, 7–27
contracting through the board or shareholders collectively
constructive notice, 7–6—7–8
introduction, 7–5
overview, 7–4
protection for third parties dealing with the board, 7–9—7–15
rule in Turquand’s case, 7–6—7–8
employees, 7–31
introduction, 7–4
objects clause, 7–29
ostensible authority, 7–20—7–23
protection for third parties dealing with the board
‘dealing with a company’, 7–11
directors, 7–13
effects of lack of authority, 7–15
‘in favour of a person dealing with a company in good faith’, 7–10
introduction, 7–9
lack of authority, 7–15
limitations under constitution, 7–14
‘persons’, 7–12
special cases, 7–29—7–31
ultra vires, 7–29
Co-operative societies
generally, 1–34—1–35
Corporate governance
board of directors
appointment of directors, 14–23—14–29
composition, 14–67—14–74
conclusion, 14–81
functions, 14–21—14–22
powers, 14–5—14–17
removal of directors, 14–48—14–62
remuneration of directors, 14–30—14–47
requirements of UK Code, 14–75—14–80
role, 14–1—14–21
structure, 14–63—14–66
controlling members’ voting
class rights, 19–13—19–21
conclusion, 19–29
introduction, 19–1—19–3
review of shareholders’ decisions, 19–4—19–12
self-help, 19–22—19–28
derivative claims
board of directors, 17–2
conclusion, 17–39
conduct, 17–25—17–28
generally, 17–4—17–6
introduction, 17–1
other solutions, 17–7—17–10
permission, 17–17—17–21
political expenditure, and, 17–29—17–31
purpose, 17–1
scope, 17–11—17–16
shareholders, 17–3
shareholders against directors, by, 17–32—17–38
types, 17–22
directors’ duties
act within powers, 16–23—16–32
approval of breach of duty, 16–117—16–124
benefits from third parties, 16–107—16–108
care and skill, 16–15—16–20
conclusion, 16–140—16–141
diligence, 16–15—16–20
exemptions from liability, 16–125—16–132
exercise independent judgment, 16–33—16–36
introduction, 16–1—16–3
liability of third parties, 16–134—16–137
limitation of actions, 16–138—16–139
loyalty, 16–21—16–22
no-conflict rules, 16–52—16–53
persons by whom duties owed, 6–13—6–26
persons to whom owed, 16–4—16–7
promote success of company, 16–37—16–51
relief from, 16–133
remedies for breach, 16–109—16–116
self-dealing, 16–54—16–66
skill and care, 16–15—16–20
transactions with the company, 16–54—16–85
use of corporate property etc, 16–106
EU law, 6–15
investigations
company ownership, 18–11
conclusion, 18–15
follow-ups, 18–13—18–14
formal investigations, 18–5—18–9
informal investigations, 18–2—18–4
introduction, 18–1
liability for costs, 18–12
reports, 18–10
minority shareholders
class rights, 19–13—19–21
conclusion, 19–29
introduction, 19–1—19–3
review of shareholders’ decisions, 19–4—19–12
self-help, 19–22—19–28
shareholders
conclusion, 15–87
decision-making without meetings, 15–6—15–21
meetings, 15–42—15–86
participation, 15–22—15–41
role, 15–1—15–5
unfair prejudice
conclusion, 20–23
derivative claims, 20–14—20–17
equitable considerations, 20–6—20–13
independent illegality, 20–6
introduction, 20–1—20–3
legitimate expectations, 20–6—20–13
litigation costs, 20–18
remedies, 20–19—20–20
scope of provisions, 20–4—20–5
winding up on just and equitable ground, 20–21—20–22
Corporate liability
accessory liability, 7–36
conclusion, 7–48
contracting through agents
agency principles, 7–18—7–19
attribution, 7–18
authority of corporate agents, 7–20—7–23
generally, 7–16—7–17
knowledge, 7–24—7–26
ostensible authority, 7–20—7–23
overall, 7–28
overview, 7–4
ratification, 7–27
contracting through the board or shareholders collectively
constructive notice, 7–6—7–8
introduction, 7–5
overview, 7–4
protection for third parties dealing with the board, 7–9—7–15
rule in Turquand’s case, 7–6—7–8
contractual rights and liabilities
charitable companies, 7–29
contracting through agents, 7–16—7–29
contracting through the board or shareholders collectively, 7–5—7–15
employees, 7–31
introduction, 7–4
special cases, 7–29—7–31
criminal liability
corporate manslaughter, 7–43
‘directing mind and will’, 7–41
directors, of, 7–42
failure to prevent criminal acts, 7–46
generally, 7–38
identification, 7–40
introduction, 7–30
personal liability, 7–45
regulatory offences, 7–39
sanctions, 7–44
introduction, 7–1—7–3
litigation by the company, 7–47
objects clause, 7–29
protection for third parties dealing with the board
‘dealing with a company’, 7–11
directors, 7–13
effects of lack of authority, 7–15
‘in favour of a person dealing with a company in good faith’, 7–10
introduction, 7–9
lack of authority, 7–15
limitations under constitution, 7–14
‘persons’, 7–12
tortious liability
accessory liability, 7–36
assumption of responsibility, 7–32
direct liability, 7–37
fraud, 7–33
introduction, 7–30
non-involved directors, 7–35
recovery by company from the agent, 7–34
ultra vires, 7–29
vicarious liability, 7–31
Corporate manslaughter
generally, 7–43
“Corporate mobility”
conclusion, 6–28—6–29
domestic rules, 6–18—6–19
EU law
alternative transfer mechanisms, 6–27
initial incorporation, 6–20—6–23
subsequent re-incorporation, 6–24—6–26
generally, 6–17
Corporate opportunities see Directors’ powers
and duties
Corporate property see Directors’ powers and
duties
Corporate representatives
shareholder meetings, 15–72
Costs
unfair prejudice, 20–18
Covered bonds
debentures, 31–19—31–20
Credit
directors’ duties
arrangements covered, 16–78—16–80
disclosures, 16–81
exceptions, 16–82
method of approval, 16–81
remedies for breach, 16–83
Creditors’ voluntary winding-up
appointment of liquidators, 33–14
instigation, 33–13
liquidation committees, 33–15
timing of commencement, 33–10
CREST
share transfers, 27–3—27–4
Criminal liability
auditors, 22–43
corporate manslaughter, 7–43
‘directing mind and will’, 7–41
directors, of, 7–42
failure to prevent criminal acts, 7–46
generally, 7–38
identification, 7–40
introduction, 7–30
personal liability, 7–45
regulatory offences, 7–39
sanctions, 7–44
takeovers, 28–12
Cross-border mergers
schemes of arrangement
employee participation, 29–20—29–21
further uses, 29–22—29–23
introduction, 29–16—29–19
Crystallisation
floating charges, 32–8—32–9
Currencies
capital, 11–19
Damages
breach of directors’ duties, 16–111
breach of promoter’s duties, 5–16, 5–19
De facto directors
see also Directors’ powers and duties
generally, 16–8—16–10
Debentures
bearer bonds, 31–12
bonds, 31–12—31–13
conclusion, 31–32
covered bonds, 31–19—31–20
debenture stock, 31–12
debenture-holders
protection of rights, 31–24—31–31
trustees, 31–14
debt and equity
choice by companies, 31–4
differences between, 31–2—31–3
default by borrowers, 31–26—31–27
definition, 31–6—31–7
direct financing, 31–8
indirect financing, 31–8
introduction, 31–1—31–4
issue
covered bonds, 31–19—31–20
private issues, 31–15—31–16
public issues, 31–17—31–18
junior debt, 31–8
large scale loans, 31–8
loan stock, 31–12
mezzanine finance, 31–8
multiple lenders
generally, 31–10—31–14
protection from each other, 31–30—31–31
protection from their lead intermediary, 31–28—31–29
notes, 31–12—31–13
private issues, 31–15—31–16
protection of debenture-holders’ rights
borrower’s possible default, 31–26—31–27
introduction, 31–24
multiple lenders, 31–28—31–31
repayment terms, 31–25
public issues, 31–17—31–18
repayment terms, 31–25
senior debt, 31–8
single lenders, 31–10—31–14
small scale loans, 31–8
stock, 31–12
structures, 31–5—31–9
subordination agreement, 31–10
syndicated loans, 31–11
terminology, 31–5
trading, 31–9
transfer
debt securities, 31–22—31–23
simple debts, 31–21
trustees for debenture-holders, 31–14
use by companies, 31–4
Debt securities
charges conclusion, 32–51
enforcement, 32–34—32–50
floating charges, 32–5—32–23
introduction, 32–1
registration, 32–24—32–33
security interests, 32–2—32–4
debentures conclusion, 31–32
introduction, 31–1—31–4
issue, 31–15—31–20
protection of holders’ rights, 31–24—31–31
single and multiple lenders, 31–10—31–14
structures, 31–5—31–9
terminology, 31–5
transfer, 31–21—31–23
use by companies, 31–4
Decision-making
shareholder participation
nature of problem, 15–6—15–7
unanimous consent, 15–15—15–21
written resolutions, 15–8—15–14
Declarations of interest
approval mechanisms, 16–55—16–56
breach of directors’ duties, 16–110
existing transactions
generally, 16–64
introduction, 16–54
methods, 16–65
remedies for breach, 16–66
proposed transactions
generally, 16–57
interests to be disclosed, 16–60
introduction, 16–54
methods of disclosure, 16–61
persons subject to duty, 16–59
purpose of requirement, 16–58
remedies for breach, 16–62
role of articles of association, 16–63
Delegated powers
sources of law
FRC, 3–9
FSA, 3–7—3–8
Delisting
public offers, 25–45
Derivative claims
board of directors, 17–2
conclusion, 17–39
costs, 17–27
existing claims, 17–22—17–23
generally, 17–4—17–6
individual shareholders
generally, 17–32—17–33
introduction, 17–4—17–6
reflective loss, 17–34—17–38
information rights, 17–26
introduction, 17–1
judicial management of proceedings, 17–18
minority shareholders, 19–2
multiple claims, 17–24
permission
discretionary grant, 17–20—17–21
introduction, 17–17
judicial management of proceedings, 17–18
mandatory refusal, 17–19
prima facie case, 17–18
political donations, 17–29—17–31
purpose, 17–1
reflective loss, 17–34—17–38
rule in Foss v Harbottle, 17–4—17–6
scope, 17–11—17–12
settlement, 17–28
Diligence
directors’ duties
historical development, 16–15
remedies for breach, 16–20
statutory standard, 16–16—16–19
Directors
appointment, 14–23—14–29
criminal liability, 7–42
disclosure of shareholdings
disclosable information, 26–12
generally, 26–9—26–10
‘person discharging managerial responsibilities’, 26–11
recipients, 26–13
timing, 26–12
disqualification
bankruptcy, 10–16
conclusion, 10–18
foreign companies, 10–17
grounds of unfitness, 10–5—10–11
introduction, 10–1
non-mandatory, 10–12—10–15
orders and undertakings, 10–2—10–3
duties
act within powers, 16–23—16–32
approval of breach of duty, 16–117—16–124
benefits from third parties, 16–107—16–108
care and skill, 16–15—16–20
conclusion, 16–140—16–141
diligence, 16–15—16–20
exemptions from liability, 16–125—16–132
exercise independent judgment, 16–33—16–36
introduction, 16–1—16–3
liability of third parties, 16–134—16–137
limitation of actions, 16–138—16–139
loyalty, 16–21—16–22
no-conflict rules, 16–52—16–53
persons by whom duties owed, 6–13—6–26
persons to whom owed, 16–4—16–7
promote success of company, 16–37—16–51
relief from, 16–133
remedies for breach, 16–109—16–116
self-dealing, 16–54—16–66
skill and care, 16–15—16–20
transactions with the company, 16–54—16–85
use of corporate property etc, 16–106
fraudulent trading
declaration, 9–8
generally, 9–4—9–5
liability for abuse of limited liability
conclusion, 9–25
duties as to creditors, 9–11—9–15
fraudulent trading, 9–4—9–5
introduction, 9–1—9–2
misdescription of the company, 9–20
phoenix companies, 9–16—9–19
premature trading, 9–3
wrongful trading, 9–6—9–10
list, 21–37
misdescription of the company, 9–20
premature trading, 9–3
removal
directors’ contractual rights, 14–53—14–55
directors’ procedural rights, 14–52
introduction, 14–48
shareholders’ statutory rights, 14–49—14–55
termination payments, 14–56—14–62
weighted voting rights, 14–51
remuneration
composition of remuneration committee, 14–33
disclosure, 14–44—14–47
generally, 14–30—14–32
incentive pay schemes, 14–35—14–37
remuneration report, 14–44—14–47
shareholder advisory vote, 14–38—14–43
shareholder approval of aspects, 14–34—14–37
termination payments
disclosure, 14–57—14–58
general controls, 14–56
shareholder approval, 14–62
terms governing duration of directors’ contracts, 14–60—14–61
wrongful trading
declaration, 9–8
generally, 9–6
impact, 9–9—9–10
shadow directors, 9–7
Directors disqualification
bankruptcy, 10–16
breach of commercial morality, 10–9
compensation, 10–4
conclusion, 10–18
court’s role, 10–8
disqualification orders
generally, 10–2
register, 10–15
scope, 10–3
disqualification undertakings
generally, 10–2
register, 10–15
scope, 10–3
failure to comply with reporting requirement, 10–14
foreign companies, 10–17
fraudulent trading, 10–13
incompetence, 10–10—10–11
Insolvency Service’s role, 10–7
introduction, 10–1
market abuse, 30–56
non-mandatory
failure to comply with reporting requirement, 10–14
fraudulent trading, 10–13
serious offences, 10–12
wrongful trading, 10–13
orders and undertakings
generally, 10–2
register, 10–15
scope, 10–3
recklessness, 10–10—10–11
serious offences, 10–12
unfitness
breach of commercial morality, 10–9
generally, 10–5—10–6
incompetence, 10–10—10–11
introduction, 10–1
recklessness, 10–10—10–11
role of Insolvency Service, 10–7
role of the court, 10–8
wrongful trading, 10–13
Directors’ powers and duties
acceptance of benefits from third parties
generally, 16–107
remedies for breach, 16–108
accounting for profits, 16–114—16–115
act in accordance with the constitution, 16–24—16–25
act within scope of powers conferred
improper purposes, 16–26—16–29
in accordance with the constitution, 16–24—16–25
introduction, 16–23
remedies for breach, 16–30—16–32
approval of breach of duty
decisions being made, 16–118
disenfranchising voters, 16–121—16–122
introduction, 16–117
not-ratifiable breaches, 16–124
person taking the decision, 16–119—16–120
voting majorities, 16–123
avoidance of contracts, 16–113
background, 16–1—16–3
benefits from third parties
generally, 16–107
remedies for breach, 16–108
breach of duty
remedies, 16–109—16–116
shareholder approval, 16–117—16–124
care and skill
historical development, 16–15
remedies for breach, 16–20
statutory standard, 16–16—16–19
common law principles, 16–1—16–3
compensation, 16–111
competing directorships
generally, 16–100—16–101
introduction, 16–99
remedies for breach, 16–106
conclusion, 16–140—16–141
conflicts of interest
benefits from third parties, 16–107—16–108
exemptions from liability, and, 16–126—16–127
generally, 16–52—16–53
self-dealing, 16–54—16–66
transactions with the company, 16–54—16–85
use of corporate property etc, 16–106
constitutional limitations, 16–24
corporate information, 16–86
corporate opportunities
authorisation by the board, 16–103—16–104
conceptual issue, 16–105
generally, 16–87—16–88
identification, 16–89—16–98
introduction, 16–86
remedies for breach, 16–106
corporate property, 16–86
credit transactions
arrangements covered, 16–78—16–80
disclosures, 16–81
exceptions, 16–82
method of approval, 16–81
remedies for breach, 16–83
damages, 16–111
declarations, 16–110
diligence
historical development, 16–15
remedies for breach, 16–20
statutory standard, 16–16—16–19
directors’ remuneration, 16–84
directors’ service contracts, 16–84
disclosure of interest in existing transactions
generally, 16–64
introduction, 16–54
methods, 16–65
remedies for breach, 16–66
disclosure of interest in proposed transactions
generally, 16–57
interests to be disclosed, 16–60
introduction, 16–54
methods of disclosure, 16–61
persons subject to duty, 16–59
purpose of requirement, 16–58
remedies for breach, 16–62
role of articles of association, 16–63
disclosure of wrongdoing, 16–45
disgorgement of disloyal gains, 16–114—16–115
exemptions from liability
conflicts of interest, 16–126—16–127
insurance, 16–129
introduction, 16–125
pension scheme indemnity, 16–132
provisions providing director with indemnity, 16–128—16–132
third party indemnities, 16–130—16–131
exercise of future discretion, 16–35
exercise of independent judgment
delegation of authority, 16–34
future discretion, 16–35
introduction, 16–33
nominee directors, 16–36
taking advice, 16–34
improper purposes
general rule, 16–26
meaning, 16–27—16–28
when is power exercised, 16–29
indemnities
insurance, 16–129
pension scheme, 16–132
provisions providing director, 16–128—16–132
third party, 16–130—16–131
injunctions, 16–110
insurance, 16–129
introduction, 16–1—16–3
liability of third parties, 16–134—16–137
limitation of actions, 16–138—16–139
loans
arrangements covered, 16–78—16–80
disclosures, 16–81
exceptions, 16–82
method of approval, 16–81
remedies for breach, 16–83
loyalty
act within powers conferred, 16–23—16–32
background, 16–21
benefits from third parties, 16–107—16–108
categories of duties, 16–22
exercise independent judgment, 16–33—16–36
generally, 16–21—16–22
no-conflict rules, 16–52—16–53
promote success of company, 16–37—16–51
self-dealing, 16–54—16–66
transactions with the company, 16–54—16–85
use of corporate property etc, 16–106
multiple directorships
generally, 16–102
introduction, 16–99
remedies for breach, 16–106
no-conflict rules
benefits from third parties, 16–107—16–108
generally, 16–52—16–53
self-dealing, 16–54—16–66
transactions with the company, 16–54—16–85
use of corporate property etc, 16–106
not to accept benefits from third parties
generally, 16–107
remedies for breach, 16–108
payments for loss of office, 16–84
pension scheme indemnity, 16–132
persons by whom duties owed
de facto directors, 16–8—16–10
directors of insolvent companies, 16–14
former directors, 16–13
senior managers, 16–11—16–12
shadow directors, 16–8—16–10
persons to whom owed
company, 16–4
individual shareholders, 16–5—16–6
other stakeholders, 16–7
political donations and expenditure, 16–85
promote success of company
common law, 16–37—16–39
corporate groups, 16–47
creditors, 16–49
defining company’s success, 16–40
disclosure of wrongdoing, 16–45
donations, 16–50—16–51
employees, 16–48
failure to have regard to relevant matters, 16–41—16–44
groups of companies, 16–47
interpreting the statutory formula, 16–40—16–51
introduction, 16–37—16–39
‘short-termism’, 16–46
quasi-loans
arrangements covered, 16–78—16–80
disclosures, 16–81
exceptions, 16–82
method of approval, 16–81
remedies for breach, 16–83
reasonable skill and care
historical development, 16–15
remedies for breach, 16–20
statutory standard, 16–16—16–19
relief from, 16–133
remedies for breach
accounting for profits, 16–114—16–115
act within scope of powers conferred, 16–30—16–32
avoidance of contracts, 16–113
benefits from third parties, 16–108
compensation, 16–111
competing directorships, 16–106
damages, 16–111
declarations, 16–110
diligence, 16–20
disclosure of interest in existing transactions, 16–66
disclosure of interest in proposed transactions, 16–62
disgorgement of disloyal gains, 16–114—16–115
generally, 16–109
injunctions, 16–110
multiple directorships, 16–106
restoration of property, 16–112
shareholder approval, 16–117—16–132
skill and care, 16–20
substantial property transactions, 16–73—16–76
summary dismissal, 16–116
types, 16–109
use of corporate opportunities, 16–106
remuneration, 16–84
restoration of property, 16–112
self-dealing
approval mechanisms, 16–55—16–56
interest in existing transactions, 16–64—16–66
interest in proposed transactions, 16–57—16–63
introduction, 16–54
service contracts, 16–84
shareholder approval of breaches of duty
decisions being made, 16–118
disenfranchising voters, 16–121—16–122
introduction, 16–117
not-ratifiable breaches, 16–124
person taking the decision, 16–119—16–120
voting majorities, 16–123
skill and care
historical development, 16–15
remedies for breach, 16–20
statutory standard, 16–16—16–19
substantial property transactions
exceptions, 16–72
listed companies, 16–77
remedies for breach, 16–73—16–76
requirement for approval, 16–70—16–71
summary dismissal, 16–116
third party indemnities, 16–130—16–131
transactions requiring special approval of members
directors’ remuneration, 16–84
directors’ service contracts, 16–84
introduction, 16–67
loans and credit, 16–78—16–83
payments for loss of office, 16–84
political donations and expenditure, 16–85
relationship with general duties, 16–68—16–69
substantial property transactions, 16–70—16–77
transactions with the company
requiring special approval, 16–67—16–85
self-dealing, 16–54—16–66
use of corporate information, 16–86
use of corporate opportunities
authorisation by the board, 16–103—16–104
conceptual issue, 16–105
generally, 16–87—16–88
identification, 16–89—16–98
introduction, 16–86
remedies for breach, 16–106
use of corporate property, 16–86
‘whitewash’ of breaches of duty
decisions being made, 16–118
disenfranchising voters, 16–121—16–122
introduction, 16–117
not-ratifiable breaches, 16–124
person taking the decision, 16–119—16–120
voting majorities, 16–123
Directors’ remuneration
composition of remuneration committee, 14–33
disclosure, 14–44—14–47
generally, 14–30—14–32
incentive pay schemes, 14–35—14–37
remuneration report, 14–44—14–47
shareholder advisory vote, 14–38—14–43
shareholder approval of aspects, 14–34—14–37
transactions requiring special approval of members, 16–84
unfair prejudice, 20–10—20–11
Directors’ remuneration reports
auditors’ role, 22–1
generally, 14–44—14–47
introduction, 21–22
revision, 21–31—21–32
Directors’ reports
approval, 21–29
auditors’ role, 22–1
introduction, 21–23
liability for misstatements, 21–27—21–28
revision, 21–31—21–32
Directors’ service contracts
transactions requiring special approval of members, 16–84
Disclosure
acquisition of shares prior to takeover bid
acting in concert, 28–54
beneficial holdings, 28–50—28–52
company-triggered disclosures, 28–51—28–52
generally, 28–50
interests in shares, 28–54
major shareholdings, 26–14—26–32
s 793 notice, 28–51—28–53
capital
abolition of authorised capital, 11–12
consideration received upon issue, 11–13—11–18
currency, 11–19
introduction, 11–10
return of allotments, 11–11
statements of capital, 11–11
control structures, 28–25
directors’ shareholdings
disclosable information, 26–12
generally, 26–9—26–10
‘person discharging managerial responsibilities’, 26–11
recipients, 26–13
timing, 26–12
foreign companies
annual reporting, 6–6
background, 6–3
generally, 6–5—6–6
trading disclosure, 6–6
interests in existing transactions
generally, 16–64
introduction, 16–54
methods, 16–65
remedies for breach, 16–66
interests in proposed transactions
generally, 16–57
interests to be disclosed, 16–60
introduction, 16–54
methods of disclosure, 16–61
persons subject to duty, 16–59
purpose of requirement, 16–58
remedies for breach, 16–62
role of articles of association, 16–63
liability for abuse of limited liability, 9–20
major shareholdings
background, 26–15
companies affected, 26–16
exemptions, 26–22
financial instruments, 26–20—26–21
generally, 26–14—26–15
indirect holdings of voting rights, 26–19
procedure, 26–23
rationale, 26–14
sanctions for non-disclosure, 26–31
scope of obligation, 26–16—26–23
timing, 26–17—26–18
takeovers
acquisition of shares prior to bid, 28–50—28–54
control structures, 28–25
wrongdoing, 16–45
Disguised distributions see Distributions
Disqualification of directors see Directors
disqualification
Disqualification orders
generally, 10–2
register, 10–15
scope, 10–3
Disqualification undertakings
generally, 10–2
register, 10–15
scope, 10–3
Dissolution
early dissolution, 33–28
normal process, 33–27
resurrection of dissolved companies
administrative restoration, 33–32
court restoration, 33–33
generally, 33–31
striking off of defunct companies, 33–29
voluntary striking off, 33–30
Distributions
adverse developments subsequent to accounts, 12–8
articles of association, 12–1
balance sheet test, 12–2
basic rules
generally, 12–1
private companies, 12–3—12–4
public companies, 12–2—12–4
board of directors, 12–1
capital, 12–1
capital redemption reserve, 12–2
definition, 12–9
disguised distributions
generally, 12–9—12–10
intra-group transfers, 12–11
distributable amount
adverse developments, 12–8
generally, 12–5
initial accounts, 12–6
interim accounts, 12–6
interim dividends, 12–7
relevant accounts, 12–5
financial assistance, 13–50
initial accounts, 12–6
interim accounts, 12–6
intra-group transfers, 12–11
private companies, 12–3—12–4
public companies, 12–2—12–4
recovery of
directors, from, 12–13—12–14
reform of rules, 12–15—12–16
unfair prejudice, 20–10—20–11
unlawful distributions
recovery from directors, 12–13—12–14
recovery from members, 12–12
‘unrealised profits’, 12–3
Diversity
board of directors, 14–68
Dividends
see also Distributions
interim amounts, 12–7
introduction, 12–1
unfair prejudice, 20–10—20–11
Doing business etc without a trading certificate
see Limited liability
Dormant companies
audits, 22–8
Employee representatives
board of directors, 14–67
Employees
contractual liability, 7–31
“Empty voting”
shareholder meetings, 15–81
Equity finance
ad hoc reporting, 26–5—26–8
allotment of shares
directors’ authority, 24–4—24–5
failure of offer, 24–20
generally, 24–18
pre-emption rights, 24–6—24–16
renounceable allotments, 24–19
terms, 24–17
classes of shares
conversion of shares into stock, 23–11
introduction, 23–6
ordinary shares, 23–9
preference shares, 23–7—23–8
special classes, 23–10
continuing obligations of publicly traded companies
ad hoc reporting, 26–5—26–8
compensation for misleading statements to the market, 26–25—26–27
compensation through FCA action, 26–28
conclusion, 26–33
criminal sanctions, 26–32
disclosure of directors’ interests, 26–9—26–13
disclosure of major shareholdings, 26–14—26–23
episodic reporting, 26–5—26–8
introduction, 26–1—26–2
penalties for breaches of rules, 26–29—26–31
periodic reporting, 26–3—26–4
reporting requirements, 26–3—26–8
sanctions, 26–24—26–32
de-listing of shares, 25–45
disclosure of directors’ shareholdings
disclosable information, 26–12
generally, 26–9—26–10
‘person discharging managerial responsibilities’, 26–11
recipients, 26–13
timing, 26–12
disclosure of major shareholdings background, 26–15
companies affected, 26–16
exemptions, 26–22
financial instruments, 26–20—26–21
generally, 26–14—26–15
indirect holdings of voting rights, 26–19
procedure, 26–23
rationale, 26–14
sanctions for non-disclosure, 26–31
scope of obligation, 26–16—26–23
timing, 26–17—26–18
episodic reporting, 26–5—26–8
insider dealing (criminal prohibition)
breach of confidence, 30–9
conclusion, 30–57
defences, 30–26—30–28
directors’ fiduciary duties, 30–8
disclosure, 30–5
general law, 30–7—30–10
impact on price, 30–21
inside information, 30–16—30–21
insiders, 30–22—30–23
introduction, 30–1—30–4
made public, 30–19—30–20
meaning, 30–1
mental element, 30–24
misrepresentation, 30–10
particular securities or issuers, 30–17
precise information, 30–18
price impact, 30–21
prohibited acts, 30–25
prohibited dealing, 30–11
prohibited trading, 30–6
public information, 30–19—30–20
recipients from insiders, 30–23
regulated individuals, 30–15—30–14
regulated markets, 30–13—30–14
regulatory approaches, 30–5—30–11
specific information, 30–18
statutory basis, 30–12
insider dealing (regulatory control)
dealing, 30–32—30–36
exemptions, 30–38
generally, 30–31
inside information, 30–37
overview, 30–30
persons covered, 30–38
market abuse
background, 30–4
conclusion, 30–57
criminal prohibitions, 30–5—30–29
enforcement, 30–47—30–56
injunctions, 30–53
insider dealing, 30–5—30–28, 30–31—30–38
introduction, 30–1—30–4
investigations, 30–48—30–50
market distortion, 30–41
market manipulation, 30–29, 30–39—30–42
meaning, 30–1
penalties, 30–52
regulatory control, 30–30—30–46
restitution, 30–53
safe harbours, 30–43—30–46
sanctions, 30–51—30–56
types, 30–1
market manipulation (criminal prohibition)
generally, 30–29
introduction, 30–1
meaning, 30–1
market manipulation (regulatory control)
accepted market practices, 30–42
dissemination of information, 30–40
market distortion, 30–41
misleading behaviour, 30–41
orders to trade, 30–39
overview, 30–30
transactions, 30–39
mergers
conclusion, 29–26
generally, 29–2
introduction, 29–1
reorganisations, 29–24—29–25
schemes of arrangement, 29–2—29–23
takeovers, 29–3
nature of shares, 23–1—23–3
periodic reporting, 26–3—26–4
pre-emption rights
criticisms, 24–15—24–16
guidelines, 24–14
listed companies, 24–13
policy issues, 24–6
sanctions, 24–12
scope of right, 24–7—24–9
waiver, 24–10—24–11
presumption of equality between shareholders, 23–4—23–5
public offers
admission to listing, 25–15—25–16
cross-border listings, 25–44
de-listing, 25–45
introduction, 25–1—25–2
listing, 25–5—25–6
prospectus, 25–17—25–30
public markets, 25–7—25–9
regulatory goals, 25–3
regulatory structure, 25–10
sanctions, 25–31—25–43
trading on public markets, 25–15—25–16
types, 25–11—25–14
reorganisations
conclusion, 29–26
generally, 29–24—29–25
introduction, 29–1
reporting requirements
ad hoc reporting, 26–5—26–8
compensation for misleading statements to the market, 26–25—26–27
compensation through FCA action, 26–28
conclusion, 26–33
criminal sanctions, 26–32
episodic reporting, 26–5—26–8
introduction, 26–1—26–2
penalties for breaches of rules, 26–29—26–31
periodic reporting, 26–3—26–4
sanctions, 26–24—26–32
schemes of arrangement
conclusion, 29–26
creditors’ schemes, 29–5
cross-border mergers, 29–16—29–23
function, 29–1
generally, 29–2—29–3
introduction, 29–1
meetings, 29–8—29–10
other cases, 29–4
procedure, 29–6—29–11
proposal, 29–6
public companies, 29–12—29–15
sanction of the court, 29–11
uses, 29–2
share issues
allotment of shares, 24–18—24–20
conclusion, 24–23
directors’ authority to allot, 24–4—24–5
introduction, 24–1
non-public offers, 24–2—24–3
pre-emption rights, 24–6—24–16
public offers, 25–1—25–45
registration, 24–21—24–22
terms, 24–17
shares
classes, 23–6—23–11
definition, 23–2
equality, 23–4—23–5
generally, 23–1—23–3
issue, 24–1—24–23
nature, 23–1—23–3
public offers, 25–1—25–45
transfers, 27–1—27–21
takeovers
allocation of acceptance decision, 28–19—28–25
City Code on Takeovers and Mergers, 28–13—28–18
conclusion, 28–77
equality of treatment of target shareholders, 28–37—28–48
introduction, 28–1—28–2
Panel on Takeovers and Mergers, 28–4—28–12
procedure, 28–49—28–76
promotion of a bid, 28–26—28–36
transfer of shares
certificated shares, 27–5—27–11
introduction, 27–1—27–2
operation of law, 27–21
register, 27–16—27–20
types of shares, 27–3—27–4
uncertificated shares, 27–12—27–15
EU law
company law
corporate governance, 6–15
harmonisation, 6–9—6–11
reform of directives, 6–16
single financial market, 6–14
subsidiarity, 6–12—6–13
foreign companies, 6–2
European companies
background, 6–13
board structure, 14–66
generally, 1–40—1–46
sources of law, 3–36
European economic interest groupings
generally, 1–37—1–39
Execution
documents
foreign companies, 6–7
Exercise of independent judgment see Directors’ powers and duties
“Exit rights”
minority shareholders, 19–3
Fidelity
see also Directors’ powers and duties
acceptance of benefits from third parties
generally, 16–107
remedies for breach, 16–108
act within powers conferred
improper purposes, 16–26—16–29
in accordance with the constitution, 16–24—16–25
introduction, 16–23
remedies for breach, 16–30—16–32
credit transactions
arrangements covered, 16–78—16–80
disclosures, 16–81
exceptions, 16–82
method of approval, 16–81
remedies for breach, 16–83
directors’ powers and duties
act within powers conferred, 16–23—16–32
background, 16–21
benefits from third parties, 16–107—16–108
categories of duties, 16–22
exercise independent judgment, 16–33—16–36
generally, 16–21—16–22
no-conflict rules, 16–52—16–53
promote success of company, 16–37—16–51
self-dealing, 16–54—16–66
transactions with the company, 16–54—16–85
use of corporate property etc, 16–106
directors’ remuneration, 16–84
directors’ service contracts, 16–84
disclosure of interest in existing transactions
generally, 16–64
introduction, 16–54
methods, 16–65
remedies for breach, 16–66
disclosure of interest in proposed transactions
generally, 16–57
interests to be disclosed, 16–60
introduction, 16–54
methods of disclosure, 16–61
persons subject to duty, 16–59
purpose of requirement, 16–58
remedies for breach, 16–62
role of articles of association, 16–63
generally, 16–52—16–53
loans
arrangements covered, 16–78—16–80
disclosures, 16–81
exceptions, 16–82
method of approval, 16–81
remedies for breach, 16–83
no-conflict rules
benefits from third parties, 16–107—16–108
generally, 16–52—16–53
self-dealing, 16–54—16–66
transactions with the company, 16–54—16–85
use of corporate property etc, 16–106
payments for loss of office, 16–84
political donations and expenditure, 16–85
promote success of company
common law, 16–37—16–39
corporate groups, 16–47
creditors, 16–49
defining company’s success, 16–40
disclosure of wrongdoing, 16–45
donations, 16–50—16–51
employees, 16–48
failure to have regard to relevant matters, 16–41—16–44
groups of companies, 16–47
interpreting the statutory formula, 16–40—16–51
introduction, 16–37—16–39
‘short-termism’, 16–46
self-dealing
approval mechanisms, 16–55—16–56
interest in existing transactions, 16–64—16–66
interest in proposed transactions, 16–57—16–63
introduction, 16–54
substantial property transactions
listed companies, 16–77
remedies for breach, 16–73—16–76
requirement for approval, 16–70—16–71
transactions requiring special approval of members
directors’ remuneration, 16–84
directors’ service contracts, 16–84
introduction, 16–67
loans and credit, 16–78—16–83
payments for loss of office, 16–84
political donations and expenditure, 16–85
relationship with general duties, 16–68—16–69
substantial property transactions, 16–70—16–77
transactions with the company
requiring special approval, 16–67—16–85
self-dealing, 16–54—16–66
use of corporate information, 16–86
use of corporate opportunities
authorisation by the board, 16–103—16–104
conceptual issue, 16–105
generally, 16–87—16–88
identification, 16–89—16–98
introduction, 16–86
remedies for breach, 16–106
use of corporate property, 16–86
Financial assistance
background, 13–44—13–46
exceptions
general, 13–52—13–54
specific, 13–50—13–51
general prohibition, 13–47—13–49
introduction, 13–44
private company exemption, 13–55
rationale of rule, 13–44
remedies for breach of prohibition, 13–56—13–58
Financial Conduct Authority
public offers, 25–5
Financial records
annual accounts, 21–7
Financial Reporting Council
audit committees, 22–25
auditing standards, 22–28
contractual limitations, 22–42
ethical standards, 22–13
independence of auditors, 22–12
introduction, 22–11
qualifications of auditors, 22–27
quality assurance, 22–29
sources of law, 3–9
Financial Services Action Plan
EU law, 6–14
public offers, 25–10
Financial Services Authority
sources of law, 3–7—3–8
“Financial year”
annual accounts, 21–8
Firm intention to bid see Takeovers
Floating charges
administrators
appointment, 32–44
duties, 32–45—32–46
end of appointment, 32–50
expenses, 32–49
function, 32–43
introduction, 32–34—32–36
powers, 32–45—32–46
protection for creditors and members, 32–47
publicity for appointment, 32–48
administrators’ powers, 32–20
automatic crystallisation, 32–9
benefits, 32–4
conclusion, 32–51
costs of liquidation, 32–18—32–19
crystallisation
automatic crystallisation, 32–9
introduction, 32–8
defective charges, 32–25—32–14
distinction from fixed charges, 32–21—32–23
enforcement
administration, 32–43—32–50
introduction, 32–34—32–36
receivership, 32–37—32–42
introduction, 32–1
legal nature, 32–2—32–3
negative pledge clauses, 32–11
practical differences from fixed charges, 32–5—32–7
preferential creditors, 32–15—32–16
prescribed part, 32–17
priority, 32–10—32–12
receivers
appointment, 32–37
function, 32–38—32–39
introduction, 32–34—32–36
liability with respect to contracts, 32–40—32–41
publicity for appointment and reports, 32–42
status, 32–38—32–39
registration
current system, 32–26
defective, 32–31
effect, 32–32
failure to register, 32–29
geographical reach, 32–28
late, 32–30
mechanics, 32–27
purpose, 32–24—32–25
reform proposals, 32–33
registrable charges, 32–26
security interests, 32–2—32–4
sharing with unsecured creditors, 32–17
statutory limitations, 32–13—32–20
subordination agreements, 32–12
Foreign companies
annual reporting, 6–6
‘branch’, 6–4
company names, 6–7
directors disqualification, 10–17
disclosure obligations
annual reporting, 6–6
background, 6–3
generally, 6–5—6–6
trading disclosure, 6–6
establishment, 6–4
EU law, 6–2
execution of documents, 6–7
generally, 6–2—6–3
other mandatory provisions, 6–8
overview, 6–1
‘place of business’, 6–4
Forfeiture
acquisition of own shares, 13–5
Formalities
company incorporation, 2–35—2–38
Formation of companies see Company
formation
Fraud
tortious liability, 7–33
Fraudulent trading
declaration, 9–8
generally, 9–4—9–5
Freedom of establishment
corporate mobility
alternative transfer mechanisms, 6–27
conclusion, 6–28—6–29
domestic rules, 6–18—6–19
EU law, 6–20—6–27
generally, 6–17
initial incorporation, 6–20—6–23
subsequent re-incorporation, 6–24—6–26
Friendly societies
generally, 1–34—1–35
Gender diversity see Diversity
General meetings
accounts, 15–43
adjournments, 15–83
agenda items
circulation of members’ statements, 15–59
information concerning, 15–60
introduction, 15–56
placing item on the agenda, 15–57—15–58
annual general meetings, 15–49—15–50
annual reports, 15–43
attendance
company representatives, 15–72
proxies, 15–67—15–71
chairman, 15–82
circulars, 15–65
circulation of members’ statements, 15–59
class meetings, 15–84
communication of notice, 15–66
company representatives, 15–72
conduct, 15–43—15–47
contents of notice, 15–65
convening
annual general meetings, 15–49—15–50
court-ordered meetings, 15–53—15–54
general meetings, 15–51—15–52
introduction, 15–48
court-ordered meetings, 15–53—15–54
‘empty’ voting, 15–81
forms of communication
by the company, 15–85
to the company, 15–86
generally, 15–51—15–52
introduction, 15–42
length of notice, 15–61—15–62
minutes, 15–80
miscellaneous matters, 15–82—15–86
nature, 15–55
notices
communication to members, 15–66
contents, 15–65
generally, 15–60—15–66
length, 15–61—15–62
resolutions, 15–47
special notice, 15–63—15–64
ordinary resolutions, 15–44
placing item on the agenda, 15–57—15–58
polls
generally, 15–75
introduction, 15–45
proxies, 15–67—15–71
publicity for votes and resolutions, 15–78—15–80
record dates, 15–77
resolutions
contents, 15–47
introduction, 15–43
notices, 15–47
ordinary resolutions, 15–44
publicity, 15–78—15–80
special resolutions, 15–44
types, 15–44—15–46
voting requirements, 15–45—15–46
wording, 15–47
show of hands
generally, 15–75
introduction, 15–45
special notice, 15–63—15–64
special resolutions, 15–44
verifying votes, 15–76
voting
‘empty’ voting, 15–81
generally, 15–73—15–74
polls, 15–75
publicity, 15–78—15–80
record dates, 15–77
resolutions, 15–45—15–46
show of hands, 15–75
verification, 15–76
Gifts
acquisition of own shares, 13–5
Going concern
annual accounts, 21–15
Group accounts
companies excluded from consolidation, 21–12
introduction, 21–9
parent and subsidiary undertakings, 21–10
parent companies which are part of larger group, 21–11
Groups of companies
accounts
companies excluded from consolidation, 21–12
introduction, 21–9
parent and subsidiary undertakings, 21–10
parent companies which are part of larger group, 21–11
limited liability
generally, 9–21—9–23
‘lifting the veil’, 9–24
Guarantee companies see Companies limited by
guarantee
Harmonisation
EU law, 6–9—6–11
Incorporation of companies see Company
incorporation
Independence
auditors
direct regulation, 22–12—22–
introduction, 22–10
regulatory structure, 22–11
Indirect investors
generally, 15–31—15–33
governance rights, 15–34—15–39
information rights, 15–40—15–41
mandatory transfer options in traded companies, 15–40—15–41
role, 15–31—15–41
voluntary arrangements, 15–34—15–39
Individual accounts
companies excluded from consolidation, 21–12
introduction, 21–9
parent and subsidiary undertakings, 21–10
parent companies which are part of larger group, 21–11
Industrial and provident societies
generally, 1–35
Injunctions
breach of directors’ duties, 16–110
market abuse
administrative provisions, 30–53
criminal prohibition, 30–55
Insider dealing
background, 30–4
breach of confidence, 30–9
conclusion, 30–57
criminal prohibition
breach of confidence, 30–9
conclusion, 30–57
defences, 30–26—30–28
directors’ fiduciary duties, 30–8
disclosure, 30–5
general law, 30–7—30–10
impact on price, 30–21
inside information, 30–16—30–21
insiders, 30–22—30–23
introduction, 30–1—30–4
made public, 30–19—30–20
meaning, 30–1
mental element, 30–24
misrepresentation, 30–10
particular securities or issuers, 30–17
precise information, 30–18
price impact, 30–21
prohibited acts, 30–25
prohibited dealig, 30–11
prohibited trading, 30–6
public information, 30–19—30–20
recipients from insiders, 30–23
regulated individuals, 30–15—30–14
regulated markets, 30–13—30–14
regulatory approaches, 30–5—30–11
sanctions, 30–54—30–56
specific information, 30–18
statutory basis, 30–12
dealing, 30–32—30–36
defences
general, 30–27
introduction, 30–26
special, 30–28
development of the law, 30–4
directors’ disqualification, 30–56
directors’ fiduciary duties, 30–8
disclosure, 30–5
enforcement
introduction, 30–47
investigations, 30–48—30–50
sanctions, 30–51—30–56
impact on price, 30–21
injunctions, 30–53
inside information
generally, 30–16
impact on price, 30–21
made public, 30–19—30–20
particular securities or issuers, 30–17
precise information, 30–18
regulatory control, and, 30–37
specific information, 30–18
insiders
generally, 30–22
recipients from, 30–23
introduction, 30–1—30–4
investigations, 30–48—30–50
made public, 30–19—30–20
meaning, 30–1
misrepresentation, 30–10
particular securities or issuers, 30–17
precise information, 30–18
price impact, 30–21
price stabilisation, 30–45
prohibited acts, 30–25
prohibited dealing, 30–11
prohibited trading, 30–6
public information, 30–19—30–20
recipients from insiders, 30–23
regulated individuals, 30–15—30–14
regulated markets, 30–13—30–14
regulatory approaches
breach of confidence, 30–9
directors’ fiduciary duties, 30–8
disclosure, 30–5
misrepresentation, 30–10
reliance on general law, 30–7—30–10
trading prohibition, 30–6
regulatory control
dealing, 30–32—30–36
exemptions, 30–38
generally, 30–31
inside information, 30–37
overview, 30–30
persons covered, 30–38
sanctions, 30–51—30–53
reliance on general law, 30–7—30–10
restitution, 30–55
safe harbours
generally, 30–43
price stabilisation, 30–45
share buy-backs, 30–44
sanctions for breach of administrative provisions
injunctions, 30–53
introduction, 30–51
penalties, 30–52
restitution, 30–53
sanctions for breach of criminal law
directors’ disqualification, 30–56
injunctions, 30–55
introduction, 30–54
restitution, 30–55
share buy-backs, 30–44
specific information, 30–18
statutory basis, 30–4
takeovers, and, 28–57
trading prohibition, 30–6
types, 30–1
Institutional investors
conflicts of interest, 15–27—15–28
fiduciary investors, 15–29
generally, 15–25—15–26
inactivity, 15–27—15–28
Myners Report, 15–25—15–29
role, 15–25—15–30
Statement of Investment Principles, 15–28
UK Stewardship Code, 15–30
Walker Report, 15–25
Intentions as to future business see Takeovers
“Interests of justice”
limited liability, 8–14
Interim dividends see Distributions
Internal market
EU law, 6–14
International co-operation
market abuse, 30–50
Investigations
company investigations
company ownership, 18–11
conclusion, 18–15
disclosure of documents and information, 18–2—18–4
follow-ups, 18–13—18–14
formal investigations, 18–5—18–9
informal investigations, 18–2—18–4
introduction, 18–1
liability for costs, 18–12
reports, 18–10
market abuse
generally, 30–48—30–49
international co-operation, 30–50
Judgments and orders
acquisition of own shares, 13–5
financial assistance, 13–50
shareholder meetings, 15–53—15–54
Judicial review
takeovers, 28–6
Junior debt see Debentures
Just and equitable see Winding-up
Large companies
annual reporting, 21–6
generally, 1–28
Legal personality
common law
agency argument, 8–13
façade or sham, 8–12
impropriety, 8–15—8–16
interests of justice, 8–14
introduction, 8–10
‘single economic unit’, 8–11
contract, 8–8—8–9
groups of companies, 9–24
introduction, 8–7
statute, 8–8—8–9
Legislation
sources of law
primary, 3–3—3–4
reform, 3–11—3–12
secondary, 3–5—3–6
Legitimate expectation
unfair prejudice
balance between dividends and directors’ remuneration, 20–10—20–11
informal arrangements among members, 20–7—20–9
introduction, 20–6
other categories, 20–12
prejudice, 20–13
Letters patent
unregistered companies, 1–31
“Lifting the veil”
see also Limited liability
common law, 8–10—8–16
contract, 8–8—8–9
groups of companies, 9–24
statute, 8–8—8–9
Limitation periods
breach of directors’ duties, 16–138—16–139
Limited companies see Companies
Limited liability
agency argument, 8–13
‘asset partitioning’ rationale, 8–2
company incorporation, 2–9—2–15
company names
exceptions, 9–19
generally, 9–16
prohibition, 9–17—9–18
conclusion, 8–17
disclosure of information, 8–6
doing business etc without a trading certificate, 9–3
façade or sham, 8–12
fraudulent trading
declaration, 9–8
generally, 9–4—9–5
groups of companies
generally, 9–21—9–23
‘lifting the veil’, 9–24
impropriety, 8–15—8–16
interests of justice, 8–14
legal personality
common law, 8–10—8–16
contract, 8–8—8–9
groups of companies, 9–24
introduction, 8–7
statute, 8–8—8–9
legal responses
disclosure of information, 8–6
generally, 8–5
‘lifting the veil’
common law, 8–10—8–16
contract, 8–8—8–9
groups of companies, 9–24
introduction, 8–7
statute, 8–8—8–9
misdescription of the company, 9–20
personal liability for abuses
conclusion, 9–25
duties as to creditors, 9–11—9–15
fraudulent trading, 9–4—9–5
introduction, 9–1—9–2
misdescription of the company, 9–20
phoenix companies, 9–16—9–19
premature trading, 9–3
wrongful trading, 9–6—9–10
phoenix companies
exceptions, 9–19
generally, 9–16
prohibition, 9–17—9–18
premature trading, 9–3
rationale, 8–1—8–4
separate legal personality
common law, 8–10—8–16
contract, 8–8—8–9
groups of companies, 9–24
introduction, 8–7
statute, 8–8—8–9
‘single economic unit’, 8–11
trading disclosures, 9–20
wrongful trading
declaration, 9–8
generally, 9–6
impact, 9–9—9–10
shadow directors, 9–7
Limited liability partnerships
business vehicles, 1–4—1–5
Liquidation
anti-deprivation principle, 33–20
avoidance provisions, 33–18
clawback
benefit, 33–21
generally, 33–18
collection realisation and distribution of company’s assets
anti-deprivation principle, 33–20
avoidance provisions, 33–18
clawback, 33–18
distribution of company’s assets, 33–24—33–26
maximising assets available for distribution, 33–17—33–21
proof of debts, 33–22
set off, 33–23
wrongdoer contributions, 33–19
compulsory winding-up
discretion of court, 33–6
grounds, 33–3
inability to pay debts, 33–5
liquidators, 33–7
official receivers, 33–7
petitioners, 33–4
proof of inability to pay debts, 33–5
provisional liquidators, 33–7
timing of commencement, 33–8
conclusion, 33–34
creditors’ voluntary winding-up
appointment of liquidators, 33–14
instigation, 33–13
liquidation committees, 33–15
timing of commencement, 33–10
dissolution
early dissolution, 33–28
normal process, 33–27
striking off of defunct companies, 33–29
voluntary striking off, 33–30
distribution of company’s assets, 33–24—33–26
early dissolution, 33–28
introduction, 33–1
just and equitable ground, 20–21—20–22
liquidators’ powers and duties, 33–16
maximising assets available for distribution
anti-deprivation principle, 33–20
avoidance provisions, 33–18
clawback, 33–18
generally, 33–17—33–21
wrongdoer contributions, 33–19
members’ voluntary winding-up
appointment of liquidators, 33–12
declaration of solvency, 33–11
instigation, 33–9
timing of commencement, 33–10
proof of debts, 33–22
resurrection of dissolved companies
administrative restoration, 33–32
court restoration, 33–33
generally, 33–31
set off, 33–23
striking off of defunct companies
generally, 33–29
voluntary, 33–30
types
compulsory winding-up, 33–3—33–8
creditors’ voluntary winding-up, 33–13—33–15
generally, 33–2
members’ voluntary winding-up, 33–11—33–12
voluntary winding-up
creditors, 33–27—33–32
general, 33–9—33–10
instigation, 33–9
members, 33–19—33–26
timing of commencement, 33–10
wrongdoer contributions
benefit, 33–21
generally, 33–19
Liquidators’ powers and duties
generally, 33–16
Listed companies
generally, 1–22—1–26
Listing
see also Public offers
admission, 25–15—25–16
cross-border, 25–44
generally, 25–5
regulated markets, 25–9
types, 25–6
Listing Rules
publicly traded companies, 1–23—1–25
Litigation
companies, and, 7–47
Loans
company incorporation, 2–31—2–33
directors’ duties
arrangements covered, 16–78—16–80
disclosures, 16–81
exceptions, 16–82
method of approval, 16–81
remedies for breach, 16–83
London Stock Exchange
generally, 25–7
introduction, 25–2
Loss of office
transactions requiring special approval of members, 16–84
Loyalty see Directors’ powers and duties
Major shareholders
disclosure
background, 26–15
companies affected, 26–16
exemptions, 26–22
financial instruments, 26–20—26–21
generally, 26–14—26–15
indirect holdings of voting rights, 26–19
procedure, 26–23
rationale, 26–14
sanctions for non-disclosure, 26–31
scope of obligation, 26–16—26–23
timing, 26–17—26–18
Management see Company management
Market abuse
background, 30–4
conclusion, 30–57
criminal prohibitions
insider dealing, 30–5—30–28
introduction, 30–1—30–4
market manipulation, 30–29
sanctions, 30–54—30–56
development of the law, 30–4
enforcement
introduction, 30–47
investigations, 30–48—30–50
sanctions for breach of administrative provisions, 30–51—30–53
sanctions for breach of criminal law, 30–54—30–56
injunctions, 30–53
insider dealing (criminal prohibition)
breach of confidence, 30–9
conclusion, 30–57
defences, 30–26—30–28
directors’ fiduciary duties, 30–8
disclosure, 30–5
general law, 30–7—30–10
impact on price, 30–21
inside information, 30–16—30–21
insiders, 30–22—30–23
introduction, 30–1—30–4
made public, 30–19—30–20
meaning, 30–1
mental element, 30–24
misrepresentation, 30–10
particular securities or issuers, 30–17
precise information, 30–18
price impact, 30–21
prohibited acts, 30–25
prohibited dealing, 30–11
prohibited trading, 30–6
public information, 30–19—30–20
recipients from insiders, 30–23
regulated individuals, 30–15—30–14
regulated markets, 30–13—30–14
regulatory approaches, 30–5—30–11
sanctions, 30–54—30–56
specific information, 30–18
statutory basis, 30–12
insider dealing (regulatory control)
dealing, 30–32—30–36
exemptions, 30–38
generally, 30–31
inside information, 30–37
overview, 30–30
persons covered, 30–38
sanctions, 30–51—30–53
introduction, 30–1—30–4
investigations, 30–48—30–50
market distortion, 30–41
market manipulation (criminal prohibition)
generally, 30–29
introduction, 30–1
meaning, 30–1
sanctions, 30–54—30–56
market manipulation (regulatory control)
accepted market practices, 30–42
dissemination of information, 30–40
market distortion, 30–41
misleading behaviour, 30–41
orders to trade, 30–39
overview, 30–30
sanctions, 30–51—30–53
transactions, 30–39
meaning, 30–1
penalties, 30–52
price stabilisation, 30–45
regulatory control
background, 30–30
insider dealing, 30–31—30–38
market manipulation, 30–39—30–42
safe harbours, 30–43—30–45
sanctions, 30–51—30–53
restitution, 30–53
safe harbours
generally, 30–43
price stabilisation, 30–45
share buy-backs, 30–44
sanctions for breach of administrative provisions
injunctions, 30–53
introduction, 30–51
penalties, 30–52
restitution, 30–53
sanctions for breach of criminal law
directors’ disqualification, 30–56
injunctions, 30–55
introduction, 30–54
restitution, 30–55
share buy-backs, 30–44
statutory basis, 30–4
types, 30–1
Market manipulation
accepted market practices, 30–42
background, 30–4
conclusion, 30–57
criminal prohibition
generally, 30–29
introduction, 30–1
meaning, 30–1
sanctions, 30–54—30–56
development of the law, 30–4
directors’ disqualification, 30–56
dissemination of information, 30–40
enforcement
introduction, 30–47
investigations, 30–48—30–50
sanctions for breach of administrative provisions, 30–51—30–53
sanctions for breach of criminal law, 30–54—30–56
injunctions, 30–55
introduction, 30–1—30–4
investigations, 30–48—30–50
market distortion, 30–41
meaning, 30–1
misleading behaviour, 30–41
orders to trade, 30–39
price stabilisation, 30–45
regulatory control
accepted market practices, 30–42
dissemination of information, 30–40
market distortion, 30–41
misleading behaviour, 30–41
orders to trade, 30–39
overview, 30–30
sanctions, 30–51—30–53
transactions, 30–39
restitution, 30–53
safe harbours
generally, 30–43
price stabilisation, 30–45
share buy-backs, 30–44
sanctions for breach of administrative provisions
injunctions, 30–53
introduction, 30–51
penalties, 30–52
restitution, 30–53
sanctions for breach of criminal law
directors’ disqualification, 30–56
injunctions, 30–55
introduction, 30–54
restitution, 30–55
share buy-backs, 30–44
statutory basis, 30–4
transactions, 30–39
Markets in Financial Instruments Directive
(2004/39/EC)
public offers, 25–8
Medium-sized companies
annual reporting, 21–5
Members’ voluntary winding-up
appointment of liquidators, 33–12
declaration of solvency, 33–11
instigation, 33–9
timing of commencement, 33–10
Memorandum of association
formation of companies, 4–5
Mergers
conclusion, 29–26
cross-border mergers
employee participation, 29–20—29–21
further uses, 29–22—29–23
introduction, 29–16—29–19
introduction, 29–1
rationale, 29–1
reorganisations
conclusion, 29–26
generally, 29–24—29–25
introduction, 29–1
schemes of arrangement
conclusion, 29–26
creditors’ schemes, 29–5
cross-border mergers, 29–16—29–23
function, 29–1
generally, 29–2—29–3
introduction, 29–1
meetings, 29–8—29–10
other cases, 29–4
procedure, 29–6—29–11
proposal, 29–6
public companies, 29–12—29–15
sanction of the court, 29–11
uses, 29–2
Mezzanine finance
debentures, 31–8
Microenterprises
annual reporting, 21–3
generally, 1–28
Minimum share capital
general requirement, 11–8
introduction, 11–2
objections to requirement, 11–9
Minority shareholders
appraisal rights, 19–3
class rights
definition, 19–18—19–20
introduction, 19–13
other cases, 19–21
procedure for variation, 19–14—19–15
‘variation’, 19–16—19–17
conclusion, 19–29
derivative claims, 19–2
exit rights, 19–3
introduction, 19–1—19–3
ratification of wrongdoing, 19–4
related party transactions, 19–2
review of shareholders’ decisions
introduction, 19–4—19–5
other resolutions, 19–10—19–11
resolutions generally, 19–7
resolutions to expropriate members’ shares, 19–8—19–9
resolutions where company’s interests are centre stage, 19–6
voting at class meetings, 19–12
self-help
articles of association, 19–23—19–24
binding only the shareholders, 19–28
introduction, 19–22
prior contracts, 19–26—19–27
shareholder agreements, 19–25—19–28
shareholder agreements
binding only the shareholders, 19–28
introduction, 19–25
prior contracts, 19–26—19–27
Minutes
shareholder meetings, 15–80
Misleading statements
market manipulation, 30–29
Misstatements
takeovers, 28–64
Multilateral trading facilities
public offers, 25–8
Myners Report (2001)
institutional investors, 15–25—15–29
Narrative reporting
approval, 21–29
background, 21–22
directors’ remuneration reports, 21–22
directors’ reports, 21–23
generally, 21–22
liability for misstatements, 21–27—21–28
revision, 21–31—21–32
strategic reports, 21–24—21–25
verification, 21–26—21–27
Negative pledges
floating charges, 32–11
Negligence
auditors
assumption of responsibility, 22–47—22–51
client claims, 22–36—22–43
contractual limitation, 22–42
defences, 22–39—22–41
establishing liability, 22–36—22–37
introduction, 22–31—22–33
limits of liability, 22–38—22–42
nature of the issue, 22–31—22–33
provision of audit services, 22–34—22–35
third party claims, 22–44—22–52
No-conflict rules see Conflicts of interest
Nominal value
capital, 11–3
Nominees
acquisition of own shares, 13–3
“Non-audit remuneration”
generally, 22–13
Not-for-profit organisations
audits, 22–9
classification of companies, 1–29—1–30
generally, 1–6—1–7
Notices
shareholder meetings
communication to members, 15–66
contents, 15–65
generally, 15–60—15–66
length, 15–61—15–62
resolutions, 15–47
special notice, 15–63—15–64
Objects clauses
ultra vires, and, 7–29
Offers for sale
public offers, 25–12
“Offers for subscription”
public offers, 25–12
Open-ended investment companies
generally, 1–36
Operating and financial review
generally, 21–24
Ordinary resolutions
shareholder meetings, 15–44
Ordinary shares
generally, 23–9
Overseas companies see Foreign companies
Panel on Takeovers and Mergers
see also Takeovers
‘cold-shoulder’, 28–11
compensation powers, 28–10
composition, 28–4
criminal sanctions, 28–12
disciplinary powers, 28–10
establishment, 28–3
generally, 28–3
internal appeals, 28–5
judicial review, 28–6
powers, 28–7—28–10
production of documents or information, 28–8
rule-making, 28–7
rulings on rules, 28–7
sanctions, 28–9—28–12
status, 28–4
Partnerships
business vehicles, 1–2—1–5
Passing off
company names, 4–25—4–26
Penalties
market abuse, 30–52
People with significant control
generally, 2–42—2–47
“Phoenix companies”
abuse of company names
exceptions, 9–19
generally, 9–16
prohibition, 9–17—9–18
company names, 4–19
Place of business
foreign companies, 6–4
Placings
public offers, 25–13
PLUS Market
public offers, 25–7
Political donations
derivative claims, 17–29—17–31
transactions requiring special approval of members, 16–85
“Poll”
generally, 15–75
introduction, 15–45
Preference shares
canons of construction, 23–8
generally, 23–7
Preferential creditors
floating charges, 32–15—32–16
Pre-incorporation contracts
promoters, 5–24—5–28
“Premature trading”
liability for abuse of limited liability, 9–3
Premium listing
generally, 25–6
Price stabilisation
market abuse, 30–45—30–46
Primary legislation
sources of law, 3–3—3–4
Private companies
generally, 1–18—1–21
Profit and loss account
generally, 21–16
Profit forecasts
takeovers, 28–63
Promote success of company see Directors’
powers and duties
Promoters
conclusion, 5–29
duties
common law rules, 5–10
consent, 5–11—5–14
disclosure, 5–11—5–14
equitable rules, 5–10
introduction, 5–6
remedies for breach, 5–15—5–20
statutory rules, 5–7—5–8
introduction, 5–1
meaning, 5–2—5–5
pre-incorporation contracts, 5–24—5–28
preliminary contracts, 5–23
remuneration, 5–21—5–22
Property
company incorporation, 2–16—2–17
Prospectuses
admission to trading trigger, 25–20—25–21
authorisation to omit material, 25–29
contents
generally, 25–22—25–23
registration statement, 25–25
securities note, 25–25
supplementary prospectus, 25–24
exemptions from requirement, 25–19
FCA vetting, 25–28
form, 25–22—25–25
introduction, 25–17
public offer trigger, 25–18
publication, 25–30
registration statement, 25–25
reputational intermediaries, 25–27
securities note, 25–25
supplementary prospectus, 25–24
verification authorisation to omit material, 25–29
FCA vetting, 25–28
generally, 25–26
reputational intermediaries, 25–27
vetting, 25–28
Proxies
shareholder meetings, 15–67—15–71
Public companies
formation of companies, 4–4
generally, 1–18—1–21
officially listed companies, 1–22—1–26
publicly traded companies, 1–22—1–26
“Public interest entities”
annual reporting, 21–6
audits, 22–2
Public markets see Securities markets
Public offers
admission to listing cross-border, 25–44
eligibility criteria, 25–15
exchange admission standards, 25–16
Alternative Investment Market, 25–5
Consolidated Admissions Requirements Directive
admission to listing, 25–15
introduction, 25–5
types of listing, 25–6
cross-border offers, 25–44
de-listing, 25–45
Financial Conduct Authority, 25–5
Financial Services Action Plan, 25–10
introduction, 25–1—25–2
listing
admission, 25–15—25–16
cross-border, 25–44
generally, 25–5
regulated markets, 25–9
types, 25–6
London Stock Exchange
generally, 25–7
introduction, 25–2
Markets in Financial Instruments Directive, 25–8
multilateral trading facility, 25–8
offers for sale, 25–12
offers for subscription, 25–12
placings, 25–13
PLUS Markets, 25–7
premium listing, 25–6
prospectuses
admission to trading trigger, 25–20—25–21
authorisation to omit material, 25–29
contents, 25–22—25–25
exemptions from requirement, 25–19
FCA vetting, 25–28
form, 25–22—25–25
introduction, 25–17
public offer trigger, 25–18
publication, 25–30
registration statement, 25–25
reputational intermediaries, 25–27
securities note, 25–25
supplementary prospectus, 25–24
verification, 25–26—25–29
vetting, 25–28
public markets
exchange-regulated markets, 25–8
generally, 25–7
introduction, 25–2
listing, 25–9
regulated markets, 25–8
types, 25–7—25–9
regulatory goals, 25–3
regulatory structure, 25–10
rights issues, 25–14
sanctions
breach of contract, 25–40
civil remedies, 25–36—25–40
compensation under the Act, 25–32—25–35
criminal proceedings, 25–41—25–43
damages, 25–37—25–38
ex ante controls, 25–42
ex post sanctions, 25–43
generally, 25–31
regulatory proceedings, 25–41—25–43
rescission, 25–39
securities markets
generally, 25–7—25–9
introduction, 25–2
standard listing, 25–6
supplementary prospectus, 25–24
trading on public markets, 25–15—25–16
types
introduction, 25–11
offers for sale, 25–12
offers for subscription, 25–12
placings, 25–13
rights issues, 25–14
UK Listing Authority, 25–5
Publicity
company incorporation
company’s affairs, 2–39
directors, 2–40
members of company, 2–41
‘people with significant control’, 2–42—2–47
votes and resolutions, 15–78—15–80
Publicly controlled companies
ad hoc reporting, 26–5—26–8
continuing obligations
ad hoc reporting, 26–5—26–8
compensation for misleading statements to the market, 26–25—26–27
compensation through FCA action, 26–28
conclusion, 26–33
criminal sanctions, 26–32
disclosure of directors’ interests, 26–9—26–13
disclosure of major shareholdings, 26–14—26–23
episodic reporting, 26–5—26–8
introduction, 26–1—26–2
penalties for breaches of rules, 26–29—26–31
periodic reporting, 26–3—26–4
reporting requirements, 26–3—26–8
sanctions, 26–24—26–32
disclosure of directors’ shareholdings
disclosable information, 26–12
generally, 26–9—26–10
‘person discharging managerial responsibilities’, 26–11
recipients, 26–13
timing, 26–12
disclosure of major shareholdings
background, 26–15
companies affected, 26–16
exemptions, 26–22
financial instruments, 26–20—26–21
generally, 26–14—26–15
indirect holdings of voting rights, 26–19
procedure, 26–23
rationale, 26–14
sanctions for non-disclosure, 26–31
scope of obligation, 26–16—26–23
timing, 26–17—26–18
episodic reporting, 26–5—26–8
formation of companies, 4–4
generally, 1–18—1–21
officially listed companies, 1–22—1–26
periodic reporting, 26–3—26–4
public offers
admission to listing, 25–15—25–16
cross-border listings, 25–44
de-listing, 25–45
introduction, 25–1—25–2
listing, 25–5—25–6
prospectus, 25–17—25–30
public markets, 25–7—25–9
regulatory goals, 25–3
regulatory structure, 25–10
sanctions, 25–31—25–43
trading on public markets, 25–15—25–16
types, 25–11—25–14
publicly traded companies, 1–22—1–26
related party transactions, 26–1
reporting requirements
ad hoc reporting, 26–5—26–8
compensation for misleading statements to the market, 26–25—26–27
compensation through FCA action, 26–28
conclusion, 26–33
criminal sanctions, 26–32
episodic reporting, 26–5—26–8
introduction, 26–1—26–2
penalties for breaches of rules, 26–29—26–31
periodic reporting, 26–3—26–4
sanctions, 26–24—26–32
substantial property transactions, 26–1
Purchase of own shares
background, 13–8
capital redemption reserve, 13–11—13–12
conclusion, 13–29
creditor protection, 13–11—13–12
failure by company to perform, 13–28
financial assistance, 13–50
general restrictions, 13–9—13–10
‘greenmail’, 13–7
introduction, 13–7—13–10
private companies
appeals to court, 13–16
capital consequences, 13–17—13–18
creditor protection, 13–11—13–12
directors’ statement, 13–14
generally, 13–13—13–18
restrictions, 13–9
shareholder protection, 13–19—13–23
shareholder resolution, 13–15
public companies
creditor protection, 13–11—13–12
restrictions, 13–9
shareholder protection, 13–19—13–23
purpose, 13–7
shareholder protection
generally, 13–19
market purchases, 13–21—13–22
off-market purchases, 13–20
payments otherwise than by way of price, 13–23
Treasury shares
exercise of rights, 13–27
generally, 13–24—13–25
sale, 13–26
“Put up or shut up”
takeovers, 28–56
Quasi-loans
directors’ duties
arrangements covered, 16–78—16–80
disclosures, 16–81
exceptions, 16–82
method of approval, 16–81
remedies for breach, 16–83
Reasonable skill and care
directors’ duties
historical development, 16–15
remedies for breach, 16–20
statutory standard, 16–16—16–19
Receivers
appointment, 32–37
function, 32–38—32–39
introduction, 32–34—32–36
liability with respect to contracts, 32–40—32–41
publicity for appointment and reports, 32–42
status, 32–38—32–39
Recklessness
directors disqualification, 10–10—10–11
shareholder meetings, 15–77
Redeemable shares
background, 13–8
capital redemption reserve, 13–11—13–12
conclusion, 13–29
creditor protection, 13–11—13–12
failure by company to perform, 13–28
financial assistance, 13–50
general restrictions, 13–9—13–10
introduction, 13–7—13–10
private companies
creditor protection, 13–11—13–12
generally, 13–13—13–18
restrictions, 13–9
shareholder protection, 13–19
public companies creditor protection, 13–11—13–12
restrictions, 13–9
shareholder protection, 13–19
purpose, 13–7
shareholder protection, 13–19
Redemption
acquisition of own shares
background, 13–8
conclusion, 13–29
creditor protection, 13–11—13–12
failure by company to perform, 13–28
general restrictions, 13–9—13–10
introduction, 13–7—13–10
private companies, 13–13—13–18
shareholder protection, 13–19
Reduction of share capital
acquisition of own shares, 13–5
all companies procedure
confirmation by court, 13–36—13–38
creditor objection, 13–35
generally, 13–34
confirmation by court, 13–36—13–38
creditor objection, 13–35
financial assistance, 13–50
generally, 13–30—13–32
private companies procedure
effect, 13–43
generally, 13–39
solvency statement, 13–40—13–42
purpose, 13–31
statutory procedures
all companies, 13–34—13–38
generally, 13–33
private companies, 13–39—13–43
Registered companies see Companies
Registered offices
corporate mobility
alternative transfer mechanisms, 6–27
conclusion, 6–28—6–29
domestic rules, 6–18—6–19
EC law, 6–20—6–27
generally, 6–17
initial incorporation, 6–20—6–23
subsequent re-incorporation, 6–24—6–26
filing details, 21–37
Registers of interests in shares
generally, 27–16—27–18
rectification, 27–19—27–20
Registration
charges
current system, 32–26
defective, 32–31
effect, 32–32
failure to register, 32–29
geographical reach, 32–28
late, 32–30
mechanics, 32–27
purpose, 32–24—32–25
reform proposals, 32–33
registrable charges, 32–26
Regulatory offences
criminal liability, 7–39
Related party transactions
minority shareholders, 19–2
Relief
breach of directors’ duties, 16–133
Remedies
breach of directors’ duties
accounting for profits, 16–114—16–115
act within scope of powers conferred, 16–30—16–32
avoidance of contracts, 16–113
benefits from third parties, 16–108
compensation, 16–111
competing directorships, 16–106
damages, 16–111
declarations, 16–110
diligence, 16–20
disclosure of interest in existing transactions, 16–66
disclosure of interest in proposed transactions, 16–62
disgorgement of disloyal gains, 16–114—16–115
generally, 16–109
injunctions, 16–110
multiple directorships, 16–106
restoration of property, 16–112
shareholder approval, 16–117—16–132
skill and care, 16–20
substantial property transactions, 16–73—16–76
summary dismissal, 16–116
types, 16–109
use of corporate opportunities, 16–106
breach of promoter’s duties, 5–15—5–20
public offers
breach of contract, 25–40
civil remedies, 25–36—25–40
compensation under the Act, 25–32—25–35
criminal proceedings, 25–41—25–43
damages, 25–37—25–38
ex ante controls, 25–42
ex post sanctions, 25–43
generally, 25–31
regulatory proceedings, 25–41—25–43
rescission, 25–39
unfair prejudice, 20–19—20–20
Removal
auditors
failure to re-appoint, 22–20
notifications, 22–19
shareholder resolution, 22–18
Remuneration
auditors, 22–17
directors
composition of remuneration committee, 14–33
disclosure, 14–44—14–47
generally, 14–30—14–32
incentive pay schemes, 14–35—14–37
remuneration report, 14–44—14–47
shareholder advisory vote, 14–38—14–43
shareholder approval of aspects, 14–34—14–37
promoters, 5–21—5–22
Remuneration committee
composition, 14–33
Reorganisations
conclusion, 29–26
generally, 29–24—29–25
introduction, 29–1
reporting requirement
classification of companies, 21–2
introduction, 21–1
large companies, 21–6
medium-sized companies, 21–5
micro companies, 21–3
public interest entities, 21–6
rationale, 21–1
revision, 21–31—21–32
scope, 21–1
shareholder meetings, 15–43
small companies, 21–4
strategic reports
approval, 21–29
background, 21–24
contents, 21–25
rationale, 21–24
Reports
ad hoc reporting, 26–5—26–8
directors’ shareholdings
disclosable information, 26–12
generally, 26–9—26–10
‘person discharging managerial responsibilities’, 26–11
recipients, 26–13
timing, 26–12
episodic reporting, 26–5—26–8
major shareholdings
background, 26–15
companies affected, 26–16
exemptions, 26–22
financial instruments, 26–20—26–21
generally, 26–14—26–15
indirect holdings of voting rights, 26–19
procedure, 26–23
rationale, 26–14
sanctions for non-disclosure, 26–31
scope of obligation, 26–16—26–23
timing, 26–17—26–18
periodic reporting, 26–5—26–8
publicly traded companies
ad hoc reporting, 26–5—26–8
compensation for misleading statements to the market, 26–25—26–27
compensation through FCA action, 26–28
conclusion, 26–33
criminal sanctions, 26–32
episodic reporting, 26–5—26–8
introduction, 26–1—26–2
penalties for breaches of rules, 26–29—26–31
periodic reporting, 26–3—26–4
sanctions, 26–24—26–32
sanctions
administrative penalties for breaches, 26–29—26–31
compensation for misleading statements to the market, 26–25—26–27
compensation through FCA action, 26–28
criminal, 26–32
introduction, 26–24
Re-registration
community interest companies, 4–46
company becoming unlimited, 4–43—4–44
introduction, 4–39
private company becoming public, 4–40
public company becoming private, 4–41—4–42
unlimited company becoming private, 4–45
Rescission
breach of promoter’s duties, 5–15—5–19
Resignation
auditors non-independent persons, and, 22–12
notifications, 22–19
prospectively non-independent persons, and, 22–15
shareholder resolution, 22–18
Resolutions
ordinary resolutions, 15–44
shareholder meetings contents, 15–47
introduction, 15–43
notices, 15–47
ordinary resolutions, 15–44
publicity, 15–78—15–80
special resolutions, 15–44
types, 15–44—15–46
voting requirements, 15–45—15–46
wording, 15–47
special resolutions, 15–44
written resolutions
articles of association, 15–14
generally, 15–8—15–9
members’ proposal, 15–13
procedure, 15–11—15–12
when not available, 15–10
Restitution
market abuse
administrative provisions, 30–53
criminal prohibition, 30–55
Restoration of goods
breach of directors’ duties, 16–112
Return of allotments see Capital
Rights issues
public offers, 25–14
Royal British Bank v Turquand (1856)
contracting through the board or shareholders collectively, 7–6—7–8
Royal prerogative
unregistered companies, 1–31
Safe harbour
market abuse introduction, 30–43
price stabilisation, 30–45—30–46
share buy-backs, 30–44
Schemes of arrangement
conclusion, 29–26
creditors’ schemes, 29–5
cross-border mergers
employee participation, 29–20—29–21
further uses, 29–22—29–23
introduction, 29–16—29–19
function, 29–1
generally, 29–2
introduction, 29–1
meetings, 29–8—29–10
mergers, 29–2
other cases, 29–4
procedure
introduction, 29–6
meetings, 29–8—29–10
proposal, 29–7
sanction of the court, 29–11
proposal, 29–7
public companies, 29–12—29–15
sanction of the court, 29–11
takeovers, 29–3
uses, 29–2
Secondary legislation
sources of law, 3–5—3–6
Secret profits
breach of promoter’s duties, 5–15—5–16
Securities markets
exchange-regulated markets, 25–8
generally, 25–7
introduction, 25–2
listing, 25–9
regulated markets, 25–8
types, 25–7—25–9
Security
charges
conclusion, 32–51
enforcement, 32–34—32–50
floating charges, 32–5—32–23
introduction, 32–1
registration, 32–24—32–33
security interests, 32–2—32–4
debentures
conclusion, 31–32
introduction, 31–1—31–4
issue, 31–15—31–20
protection of holders’ rights, 31–24—31–31
single and multiple lenders, 31–10—31–14
structures, 31–5—31–9
terminology, 31–5
transfer, 31–21—31–23
use by companies, 31–4
Security interests see Charges
Self-dealing
approval mechanisms, 16–55—16–56
disclosure of interest in existing transactions
generally, 16–64
introduction, 16–54
methods, 16–65
remedies for breach, 16–66
disclosure of interest in proposed transactions
generally, 16–57
interests to be disclosed, 16–60
introduction, 16–54
methods of disclosure, 16–61
persons subject to duty, 16–59
purpose of requirement, 16–58
remedies for breach, 16–62
role of articles of association, 16–63
introduction, 16–54
Self-help
articles of association, 19–23—19–24
binding only the shareholders, 19–28
introduction, 19–22
prior contracts, 19–26—19–27
shareholder agreements
binding only the shareholders, 19–28
introduction, 19–25
prior contracts, 19–26—19–27
“Sell-out rights”
takeovers, 28–75—28–76
Senior debt see Debentures
Senior managers
see also Directors’ powers and duties
directors’ duties, 16–11—16–12
Service contracts
transactions requiring special approval of members, 16–84
Set off
winding-up, 33–23
Shadow directors
see also Directors’ powers and duties
directors’ duties, 16–8—16–10
wrongful trading, 9–7
“Share buy-backs”
disclosure of major shareholdings, 26–18
market abuse, 30–44
Share certificates
company lien, 27–11
CREST, 27–3—27–4
estoppel, 27–6
generally, 27–5—27–11
legal ownership, 27–5
meaning, 27–3—27–4
positions of transferor and transferee, 27–8
priorities between competing transferees, 27–10
registers of interests in shares
generally, 27–16—27–18
rectification, 27–19—27–20
restrictions on transferability, 27–7
Share issues
allotment of shares
directors’ authority, 24–4—24–5
failure of offer, 24–20
generally, 24–18
pre-emption rights, 24–6—24–16
renounceable allotments, 24–19
terms, 24–17
bearer shares, 24–22
conclusion, 24–23
directors’ authority to allot, 24–4—24–5
introduction, 24–1
non-public offers, 24–2—24–3
pre-emption rights
criticisms, 24–15—24–16
guidelines, 24–14
listed companies, 24–13
policy issues, 24–6
sanctions, 24–12
scope of right, 24–7—24–9
waiver, 24–10—24–11
public offers
admission to listing, 25–15—25–16
cross-border listings, 25–44
de-listing, 25–45
introduction, 25–1—25–2
listing, 25–5—25–6
prospectus, 25–17—25–30
public markets, 25–7—25–9
regulatory goals, 25–3
regulatory structure, 25–10
sanctions, 25–31—25–43
trading on public markets, 25–15—25–16
types, 25–11—25–14
registration
bearer shares, 24–22
generally, 24–21
terms, 24–17
Share premium account
acquisition of own shares, 13–1
capital, 11–6—11–7
Share transfers
certificated shares
company lien, 27–11
estoppel, 27–6
generally, 27–5—27–11
legal ownership, 27–5
meaning, 27–3—27–4
positions of transferor and transferee, 27–8
priorities between competing transferees, 27–10
restrictions, 27–7
CREST, 27–3—27–4
introduction, 27–1—27–2
operation of law, 27–21
registers of interests in shares
generally, 27–16—27–18
rectification, 27–19—27–20
TALISMAN, 27–3
types of shares, 27–3—27–4
uncertificated shares
generally, 27–12—27–13
meaning, 27–3—27–4
protection of transferees, 27–14—27–15
Shareholder agreement see Shareholders’ agreements
“Shareholder democracy”
decision-making, 15–4
Shareholder meetings see General meetings
Shareholder resolutions
company’s interests are centre stage, where, 19–
expropriate members’ shares, to, 19–8—19–9
generally, 19–7
introduction, 19–4—19–5
other, 19–10—19–11
voting at class meetings, 19–12
Shareholders
approval of breaches of directors’ duties
decisions being made, 16–118
disenfranchising voters, 16–121—16–122
introduction, 16–117
not-ratifiable breaches, 16–124
person taking the decision, 16–119—16–120
voting majorities, 16–123
audits
appointment of auditors, 22–17
introduction, 22–16
removal of auditors, 22–18—22–19
remuneration of auditors, 22–17
small charitable companies, 22–5
board of directors
confirmation powers, 14–15—14–17
general role, 14–5—14–8
removal of directors, 14–49—14–55
remuneration of directors, 14–34—14–43
termination payments for directors, 14–59—14–62
conflicts of interest, 15–27—15–28
contractual liability
constructive notice, 7–6—7–8
introduction, 7–5
overview, 7–4
protection for third parties dealing with the board, 7–9—7–15
rule in Turquand’s case, 7–6—7–8
corporate governance conclusion, 15–87
decision-making without meetings, 15–6—15–21
meetings, 15–42—15–86
participation, 15–22—15–41
role, 15–1—15–5
decision-making without meetings nature of problem, 15–6—15–7
unanimous consent, 15–15—15–21
written resolutions, 15–8—15–14
derivative claims
approach to litigation, 17–3
claimants, 17–16
entitlement to vote, 15–4—15–5
indirect investors generally, 15–31—15–33
governance rights, 15–34—15–39
information rights, 15–40—15–41
mandatory transfer options in traded companies, 15–40—15–41
role, 15–31—15–41
voluntary arrangements, 15–34—15–39
institutional investors
conflicts of interest, 15–27—15–28
fiduciary investors, 15–29
generally, 15–25—15–26
inactivity, 15–27—15–28
Myners Report, 15–25—15–29
role, 15–25—15–30
Statement of Investment Principles, 15–28
UK Stewardship Code, 15–30
Walker Report, 15–25
liability for abuse of limited liability, 9–1—9–2
meetings
adjournments, 15–83
agenda items, 15–56—15–59
annual general meetings, 15–49—15–50
attendance, 15–67—15–72
chairman, 15–82
circulars, 15–65
circulation of members’ statements, 15–59
class meetings, 15–84
communication of notice, 15–66
company representatives, 15–72
conduct, 15–43—15–47
contents of notice, 15–65
convening, 15–48—15–54
court-ordered meetings, 15–53—15–54
‘empty’ voting, 15–81
forms of communication by and to the company, 15–85—15–86
general meetings, 15–51—15–52
introduction, 15–42
length of notice, 15–61—15–62
minutes, 15–80
miscellaneous matters, 15–82—15–86
nature, 15–55
notice, 15–60—15–66
placing item on the agenda, 15–57
polls, 15–75
proxies, 15–67—15–71
publicity for votes and resolutions, 15–78—15–80
record dates, 15–77
resolutions, 15–44—15–47
show of hands, 15–75
special notice, 15–63—15–64
verifying votes, 15–76
voting, 15–73—15–81
minority shareholders
appraisal rights, 19–3
class rights, 19–13—19–21
conclusion, 19–29
derivative claims, 19–2
exit rights, 19–3
introduction, 19–1—19–3
ratification of wrongdoing, 19–4
related party transactions, 19–2
review of shareholders’ decisions, 19–4—19–12
self-help, 19–22—19–28
Myners Report, 15–25—15–29
participation
analyses, 15–22—15–24
indirect investors, 15–31—15–41
institutional investors, 15–25—15–30
purchase of own shares
generally, 13–19
market purchases, 13–21—13–22
off-market purchases, 13–20
payments otherwise than by way of price, 13–23
redeemable shares, 13–19
removal of directors, 14–49—14–55
remuneration of directors, 14–34—14–43
review of decisions
introduction, 19–4—19–5
other resolutions, 19–10—19–11
resolutions generally, 19–7
resolutions to expropriate members’ shares, 19–8—19–9
resolutions where company’s interests are centre stage, 19–6
voting at class meetings, 19–12
role, 15–1—15–5
‘shareholder democracy’, 15–4
Statement of Investment Principles, 15–28
termination payments for directors, 14–59—14–62
UK Stewardship Code, 15–30
unanimous consent, 15–15—15–21
voting entitlement, 15–4—15–5
Walker Report, 15–25
written resolutions
articles of association, 15–14
generally, 15–8—15–9
members’ proposal, 15–13
procedure, 15–11—15–12
when not available, 15–10
Shareholders’ agreements
binding only the shareholders, 19–28
company constitution, and, 3–33—3–35
introduction, 19–25
prior contracts, 19–26—19–27
shareholders, by
approach to litigation, 17–3
claimants, 17–16
subsequent conduct
costs, 17–27
generally, 17–25
information rights, 17–26
settlement, 17–28
taking over existing claims, 17–22—17–23
types
existing claims, 17–22—17–23
generally, 17–13—17–15
multiple claims, 17–24
shareholder claimants, 17–16
unauthorised political expenditure, 17–29—17–31
unfair prejudice, 20–14—20–17
Shares
allotment of shares
directors’ authority, 24–4—24–5
failure of offer, 24–20
generally, 24–18
pre-emption rights, 24–6—24–16
renounceable allotments, 24–19
terms, 24–17
bearer shares, 24–22
certificated shares
company lien, 27–11
estoppel, 27–6
generally, 27–5—27–11
legal ownership, 27–5
meaning, 27–3—27–4
positions of transferor and transferee, 27–8
priorities between competing transferees, 27–10
restrictions, 27–7
classes of shares
conversion of shares into stock, 23–11
introduction, 23–6
ordinary shares, 23–9
preference shares, 23–7—23–8
special classes, 23–10
conversion into stock, 23–11
definition, 23–2
directors’ authority to allot, 24–4—24–5
disclosure of directors’ holdings
disclosable information, 26–12
generally, 26–9—26–10
‘person discharging managerial responsibilities’, 26–11
recipients, 26–13
timing, 26–12
disclosure of major holdings
background, 26–15
companies affected, 26–16
exemptions, 26–22
financial instruments, 26–20—26–21
generally, 26–14—26–15
indirect holdings of voting rights, 26–19
procedure, 26–23
rationale, 26–14
sanctions for non-disclosure, 26–31
scope of obligation, 26–16—26–23
timing, 26–17—26–18
generally, 23–1—23–3
issue
allotment of shares, 24–18—24–20
conclusion, 24–23
directors’ authority to allot, 24–4—24–5
introduction, 24–1
non-public offers, 24–2—24–3
pre-emption rights, 24–6—24–16
public offers, 25–1—25–45
registration, 24–21—24–22
terms, 24–17
nature, 23–1—23–3
non-public offers
allotment of shares, 24–18—24–20
conclusion, 24–23
directors’ authority to allot, 24–4—24–5
generally, 24–2—24–3
introduction, 24–1
pre-emption rights, 24–6—24–16
registration, 24–21—24–22
terms, 24–17
ordinary shares, 23–9
pre-emption rights
criticisms, 24–15—24–16
guidelines, 24–14
listed companies, 24–13
policy issues, 24–6
sanctions, 24–12
scope of right, 24–7—24–9
waiver, 24–10—24–11
preference shares
canons of construction, 23–8
generally, 23–7
presumption of equality, 23–4—23–5
public offers admission to listing, 25–15—25–16
cross-border listings, 25–44
de-listing, 25–45
introduction, 25–1—25–2
listing, 25–5—25–6
prospectus, 25–17—25–30
public markets, 25–7—25–9
regulatory goals, 25–3
regulatory structure, 25–10
sanctions, 25–31—25–43
trading on public markets, 25–15—25–16
types, 25–11—25–14
registers of interests in shares
generally, 27–16—27–18
rectification, 27–19—27–20
registration
bearer shares, 24–22
generally, 24–21
special classes, 23–10
terms of issue, 24–17
transfers certificated shares, 27–5—27–11
introduction, 27–1—27–2
operation of law, 27–21
register, 27–16—27–20
types of shares, 27–3—27–4
uncertificated shares, 27–12—27–15
uncertificated shares generally, 27–12—27–13
meaning, 27–3—27–4
protection of transferees, 27–14—27–15
Shelf companies
formation of companies, 4–9
“Show of hands”
generally, 15–75
introduction, 15–45
“Single economic unit”
limited liability, 8–11
Single financial market see Internal market
Skill and care see Reasonable skill and care
Small companies
annual reporting
generally, 21–4
parent companies, 21–20
audits, 22–5—22–6
Societas Europaea see European companies
Solvency statements
reduction of share capital, 13–40—13–42
Sources of law
common law, 3–10
delegated rule-making, 3–7—3–9
European companies, 3–36
FRC, 3–9
FSA rules, 3–7—3–8
introduction, 3–1—3–2
primary legislation, 3–3—3–4
reform, 3–11—3–12
secondary legislation, 3–5—3–6
Special resolutions
shareholder meetings, 15–44
Squeeze outs
challenging, 28–73—28–74
generally, 28–69—28–72
Standard listing
generally, 25–6
Statement of Investment Principles
shareholder participation, 15–28
Statements of capital
capital, 11–11
Statements of compliance
formation of companies, 4–5
Statutory undertakings
formation of companies, 4–2
generally, 1–31—1–33
Strategic reports
approval, 21–29
background, 21–24
contents, 21–25
rationale, 21–24
revision, 21–31—21–32
Striking off
defunct companies
generally, 33–29
voluntary, 33–30
Subordination agreements
debentures, 31–10
floating charges, 32–12
Subsidiarity
EU law, 6–12—6–13
Subsidiary companies
audits, 22–7
Substantial property transactions
listed companies, 16–77
remedies for breach, 16–73—16–76
requirement for approval, 16–70—16–71
Succession
company incorporation, 2–19—2–23
Summary dismissal
breaches of directors’ duties, 16–116
Summary financial statements
generally, 21–41
Syndicated loans
debentures, 31–11
Takeover Panel
see also Takeovers
‘cold-shoulder’, 28–11
compensation powers, 28–10
composition, 28–4
criminal sanctions, 28–12
disciplinary powers, 28–10
establishment, 28–3
generally, 28–3
internal appeals, 28–5
judicial review, 28–6
powers
generally, 28–7—28–8
sanctions, 28–9—28–12
production of documents or information, 28–8
rule-making, 28–7
rulings on rules, 28–7
sanctions
‘cold-shoulder’, 28–11
criminal sanctions, 28–12
generally, 28–9—28–10
status, 28–4
Takeovers
acquisition of shares, 28–50
acting in concert, 28–54
allocation of acceptance decision
break-through rule, 28–22—28–24
disclosure of control structures, 28–25
generally, 28–19
post-bid defensive measures, 28–20
pre-bid defensive measures, 28–21—28–25
auctions, 28–34—28–35
basic tenets, 28–2
before approach to target board, 28–50—28–54
before formal offer made to target shareholders
generally, 28–55
initial announcements, 28–57
put up or shut up, 28–56
beneficial holdings, 28–50—28–52
bid documentation, 28–61
binding target board by contract, 28–36
break-through rule, 28–22—28–24
City Code on Takeovers and Mergers
companies covered, 28–15
divided jurisdiction, 28–16—28–17
General Principles, 28–18
generally, 28–13
introduction, 28–3
jurisdiction, 28–15—28–17
scope, 28–13—28–18
structure, 28–18
transactions covered, 28–14
compensation, 28–10
compensation for loss of office, 28–28—28–32
competing bids
auctions, 28–34—28–35
binding target board by contract, 28–36
introduction, 28–33
conclusion, 28–77
conditions, 28–58
consideration, 28–39—28–40
contractual compensation, 28–32
criminal sanctions, 28–12
dealings in shares, 28–65
defensive measures
post-bid, 28–20
pre-bid, 28–21—28–25
disciplinary powers, 28–10
disclosure of acquisition of shares
acting in concert, 28–54
beneficial holdings, 28–50—28–52
company-triggered disclosures, 28–51—28–52
generally, 28–50
interests in shares, 28–54
major shareholdings, 26–14—26–32
s 793 notice, 28–51—28–53
disclosure of conflicts, 28–27
disclosure of control structures, 28–25
disclosure of major shareholdings
background, 26–15
companies affected, 26–16
exemptions, 26–22
financial instruments, 26–20—26–21
generally, 26–14—26–15
indirect holdings of voting rights, 26–19
procedure, 26–23
rationale, 26–14
sanctions for non-disclosure, 26–31
scope of obligation, 26–16—26–23
timing, 26–17—26–18
employees’ interests, 28–62
equality of treatment of target shareholders
consideration, 28–39—28–40
introduction, 28–37
mandatory offers, 28–41—28–46
partial bids, 28–38
recipients of offer, 28–47
wait and see, 28–48
firm intention to bid notice, 28–55
formal offer
bid documentation, 28–61
conditions, 28–58
dealings in shares, 28–65
employees’ interests, 28–62
intentions as to future business, 28–62
liability for misstatements, 28–64
pre-vetting of advertisements, 28–66—28–67
profit forecasts, 28–63
solicitation, 28–66—28–67
telephone campaign rules, 28–66—28–67
timetable, 28–59—28–60
valuations, 28–63
General Principles, 28–18
gratuitous payments, 28–29—28–31
independent advice, 28–27
initial announcements, 28–57
insider dealing, 28–57
intentions as to future business, 28–62
internal appeals, 28–5
introduction, 28–1—28–2
judicial review, 28–6
liability for misstatements, 28–64
mandatory offers acting in concert, 28–44
conclusion, 28–46
exemptions, 28–43
generally, 28–41—28–42
interests in shares, 28–45
relaxations, 28–43
market abuse, 28–57
meaning, 28–1
misstatements, 28–64
no frustration rule
allocation of acceptance decision, 28–19
divided jurisdiction, 28–17
introduction, 28–1
post-bid defensive measures, 28–20
notification of firm intention to bid, 28–55
Panel on Takeovers and Mergers
‘cold-shoulder’, 28–11
compensation powers, 28–10
composition, 28–4
criminal sanctions, 28–12
disciplinary powers, 28–10
establishment, 28–3
generally, 28–3
internal appeals, 28–5
judicial review, 28–6
powers, 28–7—28–10
production of documents or information, 28–8
rule-making, 28–7
rulings on rules, 28–7
sanctions, 28–9—28–12
status, 28–4
partial bids, 28–38
post-bid defensive measures, 28–20
post-offer period
bidding again, 28–68
sell-out rights, 28–75—28–76
squeeze-out rights, 28–69—28–74
pre-bid defensive measures
break-through rule, 28–22—28–24
disclosure of control structures, 28–25
generally, 28–21
pre-vetting of advertisements, 28–66—28–67
procedure
before approach to target board, 28–50—28–54
before formal offer made to target shareholders, 28–55—28–57
formal offer, 28–58—28–67
introduction, 28–49
post-offer period, 28–68—28–76
production of documents or information, 28–8
profit forecasts, 28–63
promotion of offer by target management
compensation for loss of office, 28–28—28–32
competing bids, 28–33—28–36
contractual compensation, 28–32
disclosure of conflicts, 28–27
gratuitous payments, 28–29—28–31
independent advice, 28–27
introduction, 28–26
put up or shut up, 28–56
recipients of offer, 28–47
rulings on interpretation application or effect of rules, 28–7
s 793 notices
generally, 28–51—28–52
sanctions, 28–53
sell-out rights, 28–75—28–76
shareholder protection, 28–1
solicitation, 28–66—28–67
squeeze-out rights
challenging, 28–73—28–74
generally, 28–69—28–72
Takeover Panel
‘cold-shoulder’, 28–11
compensation powers, 28–10
composition, 28–4
criminal sanctions, 28–12
disciplinary powers, 28–10
establishment, 28–3
generally, 28–3
internal appeals, 28–5
judicial review, 28–6
powers, 28–7—28–10
production of documents or information, 28–8
rule-making, 28–7
rulings on rules, 28–7
sanctions, 28–9—28–12
status, 28–4
telephone campaign rules, 28–66—28–67
timetable, 28–59—28–60
valuations, 28–63
wait and see, 28–48
Tax
company incorporation, 2–34
Termination payments
directors
disclosure, 14–57—14–58
general controls, 14–56
shareholder approval, 14–62
terms governing duration of directors’ contracts, 14–60—14–61
Tortious liability
accessory liability, 7–36
assumption of responsibility, 7–32
direct liability, 7–37
fraud, 7–33
introduction, 7–30
non-involved directors, 7–35
recovery by company from the agent, 7–34
vicarious liability, 7–31
Transfer of shares see Share transfers
Treasury shares
purchase of own shares
exercise of rights, 13–27
generally, 13–24—13–25
sale, 13–26
True and fair view
annual accounts, 21–14
UK Corporate Governance Code
audit committees
composition, 22–24
functions, 22–25
introduction, 22–23
board of directors
enforcement, 14–77—14–80
generally, 14–69—14–74
introduction, 14–1
requirements, 14–75—14–76
UK Listing Authority
public offers, 25–5
UK Stewardship Code
institutional investors, 15–30
Ultra vires
objects clauses, and, 7–29
Unfair prejudice
acquisition of own shares, 13–5
conclusion, 20–23
controlling shareholders, 20–2
derivative claims, 20–14—20–17
directors’ remuneration, 20–10—20–11
dividends, 20–10—20–11
equitable considerations, 20–6—20–13
independent illegality, 20–6
informal arrangements among members, 20–7—20–9
introduction, 20–1—20–3
legitimate expectations
balance between dividends and directors’ remuneration, 20–10—20–11
informal arrangements among members, 20–7—20–9
introduction, 20–6
other categories, 20–12
prejudice, 20–13
limitations, 20–7—20–8
litigation costs, 20–18
other categories, 20–12
prejudice, 20–13
remedies, 20–19—20–20
restrictions, 20–7—20–8
right to relief, 20–4
scope of provisions, 20–4—20–5
winding up on just and equitable ground, 20–21—20–22
Unlimited companies
generally, 1–27
Unregistered companies
generally, 1–31—1–33
Utilities
unregistered companies, 1–31
Vicarious liability
generally, 7–31
Voluntary winding-up
creditors’ voluntary winding-up
appointment of liquidators, 33–14
instigation, 33–13
liquidation committees, 33–15
timing of commencement, 33–10
general, 33–9—33–10
instigation, 33–9
members’ voluntary winding-up
appointment of liquidators, 33–12
declaration of solvency, 33–11
instigation, 33–9
timing of commencement, 33–10
timing of commencement, 33–10
Voting
shareholder meetings
‘empty’ voting, 15–81
generally, 15–73—15–74
polls, 15–75
publicity, 15–78—15–80
record dates, 15–77
resolutions, 15–45—15–46
show of hands, 15–75
verification, 15–76
shareholders’ role, 15–4—15–5
Walker Report (2009)
institutional investors, 15–25
Whistleblowers
auditors, 22–21
Winding-up
anti-deprivation principle, 33–20
avoidance provisions, 33–18
clawback
benefit, 33–21
generally, 33–18
collection realisation and distribution of company’s assets
anti-deprivation principle, 33–20
avoidance provisions, 33–18
clawback, 33–18
distribution of company’s assets, 33–24—33–26
maximising assets available for distribution, 33–17—33–21
proof of debts, 33–22
set off, 33–23
wrongdoer contributions, 33–19
compulsory winding-up
discretion of court, 33–6
grounds, 33–3
inability to pay debts, 33–5
liquidators, 33–7
official receivers, 33–7
petitioners, 33–4
proof of inability to pay debts, 33–5
provisional liquidators, 33–7
timing of commencement, 33–8
conclusion, 33–34
creditors’ voluntary winding-up
appointment of liquidators, 33–14
instigation, 33–13
liquidation committees, 33–15
timing of commencement, 33–10
dissolution
early dissolution, 33–28
normal process, 33–27
striking off of defunct companies, 33–29
voluntary striking off, 33–30
distribution of company’s assets, 33–24—33–26
early dissolution, 33–28
introduction, 33–1
just and equitable ground, 20–21—20–22
liquidators’ powers and duties, 33–16
maximising assets available for distribution
anti-deprivation principle, 33–20
avoidance provisions, 33–18
clawback, 33–18
generally, 33–17—33–21
wrongdoer contributions, 33–19
members’ voluntary winding-up
appointment of liquidators, 33–12
declaration of solvency, 33–11
instigation, 33–9
timing of commencement, 33–10
proof of debts, 33–22
resurrection of dissolved companies
administrative restoration, 33–32
court restoration, 33–33
generally, 33–31
set off, 33–23
striking off of defunct companies
generally, 33–29
voluntary, 33–30
types
compulsory winding-up, 33–3—33–8
creditors’ voluntary winding-up, 33–13—33–15
generally, 33–2
members’ voluntary winding-up, 33–11—33–12
voluntary winding-up
creditors, 33–27—33–32
general, 33–9—33–10
instigation, 33–9
members, 33–19—33–26
timing of commencement, 33–10
wrongdoer contributions
benefit, 33–21
generally, 33–19
Written resolutions
articles of association, 15–14
generally, 15–8—15–9
members’ proposal, 15–13
procedure, 15–11—15–12
when not available, 15–10
“Wrongdoer contributions”
benefit, 33–21
generally, 33–19
Wrongful trading
declaration, 9–8
generally, 9–6
impact, 9–9—9–10
shadow directors, 9–7
SWEET & MAXWELL TEXTBOOKS
NOW AVAILABLE ON
ProViewTM
A FREE, PROFESSIONAL-GRADE
PLATFORM
THAT ALLOWS YOU TO INTERACT WITH YOUR
eBOOKS IN ENTIRELY NEW WAYS.
ProView enables you to bookmark pages and highlight passages, as
well as create notes, search across your library and more.
Available on iPad, Android tablets or computers, ProView enables you
to access your Thomson Reuters eBooks online and offline, wherever
you are.
FOR MORE INFORMATION
VISIT thomsonreuters.com/site/proview