Frege and Kellly, 2020_chapter 2
Frege and Kellly, 2020_chapter 2
Frege and Kellly, 2020_chapter 2
comparative employment
relations
Carola Frege and John Kelly
the field detaches analysis from broader social science traditions, trivialises its con-
ceptual apparatus and privileges pragmatism over theoretical imagination. If theor-
ies are used they are mainly mid-range, thus hypotheses-testing of psychological
(behaviourist) or economic theories.
10 Carola Frege and John Kelly
One promising development in rectifying these weaknesses can be seen in the
growth of comparative research in employment relations (CER) since the late 1980s,
marked by the first publication of leading comparative textbooks by Bamber and
Lansbury (1987) and Ferner and Hyman (1992, 1998; and see also Hyman and
Ferner 1994) as well as by more recent texts and handbooks e.g. Wilkinson et al.
(2014), Milner (2015) and Bamber et al. (2015). One of the potential benefits of
comparative research is that it can help to advance a more inter-disciplinary and the-
oretical understanding of employment relations and thus provide an important
opportunity to rectify the empiricist bias of past research. Yet, until now much of
the recent comparative research presented even less theoretical ambition and fre-
quently remained within empirical comparisons of national employment models.
In our understanding, CER is not just about a more international scope of
research on work and employment, or a particular scientific method (comparison),
but ideally should also be advancing specific paradigms and theories about the nature
and processes of employment relations systems. Cross-national comparative method-
ology is in many ways the fundamental laboratory for employment relations. With-
out the ability to compare across countries it is virtually impossible to understand
and explain the scientific importance of findings in one particular economy. More-
over, one of the core functions of comparative research is to link conceptually
micro- and macro-levels of analysis (for example, employees’ job happiness with col-
lective representation systems) and to compare across different national settings. In
other words, while most theoretical attempts in employment relations have essen-
tially focused at the micro level, for example attempting to understand the logic of
actors’ preferences and behaviour (e.g. managerial or union strategies), CER theory
should advance our understanding of how actors’ strategies are channelled through
national institutions but also actively shape institutions and regulations. As Crouch
(2005: 208) concludes, comparative research raises the awareness of academics that,
features of one’s native environment which one had thought to be distinctive and
had attributed to rather specific, local causes are in fact more general or in turn that
features of relationships between variables which one thought to be of universal
meaning are in fact locally embedded and not transferable to other countries.
Convergence theories
The first attempt to formulate an explicit theory of such a convergence is usually traced to
Kerr et al.’s seminal work Industrialism and Industrial Man (1960). Their main argument
was that the world’s employment regimes would experience a certain convergence to
greater uniformity. The central driving force was seen to be the homogenizing pressure of
new technologies, which was thought to be central to the logic of industrialism. Other
forces were the push of progress, education, equality and the ‘compulsion of comparisons’.
The underlying assumption was that structure follows functions. Thus, employment rela-
tions were thought to change in line with technological and developmental requirements.
Kerr further argued (e.g. 1983) that the emerging common model would match the
Anglo-American pattern of the time, which they called ‘pluralistic industrialism’. This
they defined as a system in which employers and unions developed increasingly effective
and non-conflictual bargaining relationships, making detailed state regulation unnecessary.
Hence in their view, ‘mature’ employment relations systems became detached from the
political process.
It is worth noting that Kerr et al. (1960) conceded that a range of different employ-
ment relations patterns within the rubric of ‘pluralistic industrialism’ could co-exist for
some time. They identified certain factors promoting continued diversity such as the
persistence of particular actor strategies, the imprint of national culture and existence
of distinctive industrial cultures. However, in the end the logic of industrialism would
override these diversities and produce a homogeneous set of labour market institutions
and regulations. Uniformity draws on technological imperatives and management’s
authority, divergence on individuality and workers’ rebellion (Kerr et al. 1960: 277).
This ‘convergence theory’ has been much debated ever since. Scholars have criti-
cized their work as excessively functionalist, technologically deterministic and
ethnocentric:
14 Carola Frege and John Kelly
It reflected the ethnocentrism pervasive in Anglo-American social science of the
(cold war) period in that the US was seen as the technological world leader and
therefore its institutions and practices were defined as ‘best practice’ for other
nations to emulate. Patterns in other countries were seen as derivative of, or devi-
ations from, the US model.
(Locke et al. 1995: xvi)
Moreover, as Traxler et al. (2001: 7) pointed out, their theory remains ultimately
based on the (neo-classical or neo-liberal) assumption that markets are superior, while
non-market institutions constitute performance-inhibiting rigidities. Consequently, the
theory concludes that the model best designed to succeed in the global economy is
the US model. However, empirical research from the 1970s onwards has challenged
this core assumption and suggests that rather than converging, ‘national patterns of
employment relations are increasingly diverging’ (Wailes et al. 2015: 12). In particular,
empirical studies revealed that technology cannot be seen as exogenous to economy
and society but instead is shaped by economic and societal forces (Sabel 1982). Fur-
thermore, the historical transformation of the American labour market in the 1980s
with the decline of collective bargaining rendered the Dunlop and Kerr approaches
less relevant. The preconditions for the consensual creation of bargaining rules were
vanishing. Finally, the frequently observed proactive role of management argued for
a stronger focus on the strategic choices of all actors as determinants of action rather
than on potentially exogenous factors, such as technology (Mueller-Jentsch 2004: 22).*
The focus on firms and market forces remained but was modified by an action the-
oretical extension of Dunlop’s systems approach. The influential textbook by Kochan
et al. (1986) developed a strategic choice theory, which argued that although markets
and institutional factors influence and shape actors’ behaviour, there remains a degree
of latitude within which the actors can make significant policy choices. Although all
employment actors are mentioned, their main focus remains almost exclusively on
management’s strategic choices and management–union relations. Thus, the relatively
autonomous strategic decisions of managers are seen as an intervening variable
between environmental conditions and company structures. Moreover, ‘the empirical
basis remains the USA, which continues to be characterized by state abstinence from
issues of employment relations, by the existence of company level unions, and the use
of human resource management, which prefers individual solutions to collective ones’
(Mueller-Jentsch 2004: 23). And so it comes as no surprise that strategic choice theory
has seldom been applied to the analysis of employment relations outside of the USA
or Britain (Mueller-Jentsch 2004).
More recently attempts have been made to upgrade the strategic choice
approach and to make it less functionalist. For example, Locke et al. (1995: xxvii)
compare the strategic choice and institutionalist approaches in order to ‘address
whether a focus on the competitive strategies of firms or one that emphasizes the
role of public policy and legal institutional arrangements (or some combination of
these two approaches) best explains recent shifts in employment relations’. Their
framework distinguishes between two core explanatory forces: ‘national, industry
and firm governance, institutions and structures’, and ‘firm strategies’ (competitive
strategies, technology/production, strategies). Their empirical answer is, however,
vague and ultimately points to a combination of both. Other studies have also pro-
moted a more nuanced argument that convergence might be taking place in two
Theoretical perspectives on CER 15
ways at the firm level due to increased international competition, thus narrowing
managerial strategic choices to a ‘high road’ or low road’ option. ‘High road’,
functionally flexible workplaces produce complex goods and services, mainly in
advanced economies, and are characterized by high pay and team-based work,
whereas ‘low road’, numerically flexible workplaces produce simple goods and ser-
vices, mainly in the developing countries, and are characterized by non-
unionization and Taylorist work practices’ (see Frenkel and Kuruvilla 2002: 388).
Globalization theories
In the meantime an increasing number of studies of globalization have come to the
fore, fostering a new discussion on a global market driven convergence of employ-
ment regimes towards the US model. This time the impact on employment relations
arises from major economic and financial characteristics of globalization, in particular:
Varieties of capitalism
The ‘Varieties of Capitalism’ literature (Hall and Soskice 2001; Amable 2003) con-
tinues the focus on the primacy of market forces. It identifies firms and financial mar-
kets as the core actors within capitalist economies, and suggests less prominent, less
strategic roles for both state and organized labour (Howell 2005: 27). It portrays
a firm-centred political economy where firms establish relationships with other actors
by strategic interaction (Hall and Soskice 2001: 6). At its core the theory combines
several theoretical approaches (game theory, transaction costs, institutionalism) with
a functionalist equilibrium model (Streeck 2009: 18). In particular, national models of
capitalism are characterized by distinctive institutional arrangements supporting specific
kinds of strategies on the part of firms in international markets (Thelen 2004: 2).
Institutions enter the analysis because they are seen as helping firms to solve several
coordination problems in five spheres: employment relations, vocational training and
education, corporate governance, interfirm relations, and the workforce. Different insti-
tutions deal with these different spheres but they are not isolated but interconnected and
produce ‘institutional complementarities’ where different institutions reinforce and
complement each other (Hall and Soskice 2001: 9). A core argument is that these insti-
tutional arrangements provide the foundation on which the competitive advantage of
firms and their national economies rest, so that employers as key actors, who have
organized their strategies around these institutions, will be reluctant to change them.
One implication of this argument is that institutions possess a significant degree of resili-
ence even in the face of strong market pressures and that the institutional changes that
do occur are likely to be incremental, revealing a strong degree of ‘path dependency’
(Kelly 2011: 64). These interlocking and mutually reinforcing institutions are thought
to co-vary systematically, yielding two major ideal-typical capitalist models – liberal
market economies (LME) and coordinated market economies (CME). Thus, both
models solve their coordination problems with a different set of institutions. In LMEs
firms tend to coordinate their activities via market relations and hierarchies and in
CMEs firms depend more on additional political and societal institutions.
Not surprisingly, the VoC theory has become the most popular vehicle for comparative
employment research in the last decade. According to Streeck (2009: 17), ‘VoC theory
must be applauded for its recognition of the importance of institutions, its emphasis on the
significance of national contexts even in times of globalization, and its rejection of a neo-
liberal convergence-on-best-practice model of political economies’. At the same time VoC
theory has been criticized on a number of grounds: for reducing the diversity of national
capitalist regimes to two types3; for ultimately rooting both models in efficiency-theoretical,
functionalist premises; for its underdeveloped account of change which may be linked to
the underlying idea that, conceptually, stability takes precedence over change (Streeck 2009:
18; Baccaro and Howell 2017; Heyes et al. 2012). Critics also argue that the theory falls
Theoretical perspectives on CER 17
short in explaining what brought these regimes into being in the first place, what holds
them together, and ‘how we should characterize the dynamics of change and weigh these
against the forces of institutional reproduction’ (Thelen 2004: 3).
Corporatism
A particular topic of interest for comparative political scientists has been the cap-
acity of the state to enable intermediary, private interest governance of employ-
ment relations, namely corporatist arrangements to regulate the potentially
conflictual employment relationship (Korpi 1978; Esping-Andersen 1985; Streeck
and Schmitter 1985). This approach analyzes the state ‘as a medium in institution-
building processes, particularly between parties with diverging interests, for their
capacities to build intermediating institutions (ones that bridge conflicting interests)
on their own are limited’ (Mueller-Jentsch 2004: 28). Corporatist arrangements
have been characterized by an all-encompassing scope of political governance and
a high degree of organizational centralization. Typical examples are the Scandi-
navian countries, as well as Austria, Switzerland and Germany. These corporatist
political economies have long been admired as models of economic efficiency and
social equality (Thelen 2004: 1). For example, Streeck and Schmitter (1985: 14)
examine the self-regulation of intermediary associations (besides family, commu-
nity, market or state actions) that shape and coordinate private interests in societies.
They argue that employment regulation in corporatist countries is governed by the
concerted coordination of the state and non-state (‘private’) institutions and inter-
est organizations (trade unions and employer associations), also called tripartism.
This coordination is embedded in an institutional system, often created and
changed with the aid of the state, without which the associative arrangement of
relevant interests would not work (Mueller-Jentsch 2004: 18). Necessary precondi-
tions for a functioning corporatist governance are ‘active economic policy-making
of the state, social democratic political parties that are part of the government and
that are supported by unions, and encompassing interest organizations that have
bargaining power and centralized representation structures’ (Mueller-Jentsch 2004:
18). Many authors have interpreted corporatism as a high point of workers’ power
in society (Esping-Andersen 1985; Rothstein 1987; Glyn 1991) and view large
20 Carola Frege and John Kelly
centralized political unions bargaining over national economic policy aspects as
revealing the ultimate strength of labour movements in democratic societies.
Moreover, a major underlying assumption is that non-market institutions in the
labour market (such as collective labour market regulations) are not necessarily per-
formance decreasing but on the contrary can enhance performance (Schmitter 1979).
Strong corporatist institutions (characterized by an all-encompassing scope of gov-
ernance and a high degree of internal centralization) can even outperform market-
based regimes (Traxler et al. 2001: 7). In fact, in the heyday of corporatist thinking
some scholars even predicted a universal trend toward ‘corporatist intermediation’
(Schmitter and Lehmbruch 1979; Lehmbruch and Schmitter 1982). Later on, from
the mid 1980s, corporatism fell into abeyance given the widespread decline of trade
union density and the decentralization of collective bargaining (e.g. Lash and Urry
1987). A major force behind these changes towards disorganizing corporatist
employment relations was, arguably, increasing international product market compe-
tition (Traxler et al. 2001: 9), as well as increasing strains on welfare states and pen-
sion systems. Liberal market economic models re-emerged onto the research agenda,
ironically supported by Hall and Soskice’s (2001: 30) prediction that LMEs will
adapt more easily to globalization, given ‘their preference for more flexible and
loose relations, both within and between firms’ (see also Baccaro and Howell 2017).
However, empirical studies have remained more ambiguous, revealing that the
increasing processes of disorganization and disintegration in national employment
regimes remain complex. Tendencies towards convergence on the LME model are
accompanied by increasing cross-national diversity (Hyman 1975; Ferner and
Hyman 1992; Crouch 1996; Visser 1996; Traxler et al. 2001) and corporatist
arrangements have been revived in many countries under the rubric of ‘social pacts’
(Avadgic et al. 2011; Hamann and Kelly 2011).
Conceptual framework
One of the major challenges for comparative empirical researchers is to specify the
conditions, under which certain sets of variables are more or less successful in
explaining attributes of work and employment and in particular how they can
account for change. Here we develop a broad conceptual framework, which focuses
on five core variables, based on Peters’ famous framework of comparative politics
22 Carola Frege and John Kelly
(2008): ‘actors’ interests’, ‘power resources’, ‘institutions’, ‘international environ-
ment’ and ‘ideas, ideologies and identities’.
(i) Employment actors should be defined broadly, integrating not only the three
traditional agents (employers, workers, state), but also non-traditional actors such
as worker centres (Fine 2006) or NGOs. As we have seen above, actors’ interests,
preferences and their subsequent strategic choices can be based on rational choice
explanations, as in basic neo-classical assumption that employers or employees are
utility maximizers, or, as the new institutional economists (Williamson 1985)
would argue, that they are minimizing their transaction costs (e.g. information
costs, negotiating and decision-making costs, controlling and monitoring costs).
However, as institutionalist theory in political science reminds us, reality is often
more complex. For example, employers are not necessarily only interested in short-
term profit maximizing but also in long-term sustainability. Moreover, in corporatist
countries employers and workers are given the right to participate in making eco-
nomic and employment policies, but in return have to be reliable partners, with
their membership abiding by agreements, avoiding for example wildcat strikes
(Peters 2008: 51). A good example is German-style works councils, which have, by
law, the dual task of representing workers interests and cooperating with manage-
ment. And governments as employment actors tend to pursue a complex mix of
complementary and sometimes conflicting goals and interests which can also change
over time. The state is also not autonomous in its decision-making but influenced by
various actors such as national constituencies, lobbyists and supranational bodies.
Recent network theorists have also propagated the importance of networked
groups, thus ‘surrounding almost all policy areas there is a constellation of actors and
groups (e.g. lobbyists) who seek to influence that policy, and who are increasingly
connected formally to one another and to the relevant policy-making institution’
(Peters 2008: 51). The examples modify the traditional, self-interested rational
choice assumption of employment actors, in favour of a mixture of individual and
collective preferences and actions.
(ii) A main emphasis of our textbook is a focus on the power resources of the employ-
ment actors, a topic that has been neglected or underestimated in traditional theoretical
approaches. In particular, the importance of power as an institution-building and insti-
tution-preserving force has usually been underplayed by most market-oriented
approaches. Yet, as outlined above, capitalist labour markets can be convincingly char-
acterized by ‘structural antagonism’ and power therefore plays an important role. We
strongly agree with Mueller-Jentsch (2004: 27) that ‘the building of employment insti-
tutions by two or more actors in conflictual interactions cannot be explained without
the notion of power and counterpower’. In employment relations actors’ power is
inevitably influenced by a variety of factors, in particular by market forces (the state of
the economy), by political forces (political parties and policies), but also by internal
organizational capacities of the actors (e.g. degree of centralization of unions or
employer associations), and by the changing nature of work and technology and
group relations at the production level. Power resources are therefore dynamic and in
constant flux.
(iii) Employment institutions are generally interpreted as norms and rules, which
enable markets to operate but can also constrain markets. Employment institutions are
usually taken to comprise labour laws, collective bargaining institutions, and arbitration
bodies, but can also include broader economic institutions such as free trade zones or
Theoretical perspectives on CER 23
trade agreements; and political institutions such as different forms of democracy (for
example direct or representative electoral systems) and their path dependencies, which
have an impact on employment regimes. Institutions do not rigidly determine individ-
ual actions but rather establish trajectories for possible actions. Those trajectories have
‘conditioning effects on the goals, strategies, and interest definitions of the actors as
well as on the power relations between them’ (Mueller-Jentsch 2004: 12). Thus,
actors are seen as being embedded in a rich institutional context consisting of social
ties, organizations, and disparities in social power (Western 1998: 224). Moreover, as
the historical-institutionalist theorists have rightly reminded us, institutions have an
inherent tendency to persist over long periods of time, even in the face of their poten-
tial dysfunctionality (Peters 2008: 49). The difficulty is therefore not so much to
explain institutional stability but institutional change.
(iv) The international environment is increasingly important in the understanding of
employment relations. Much recent work has focused on comparing national actors
and institutions in two or more employment regimes and this is very valuable
research. However, as our introductory chapter revealed, global financial and product
markets, patterns of labour migration, global politics and institutions (such as the EU,
World Bank and the IMF) increasingly shape national employment regimes. For
example, there is an increasing number of studies on the links between national labour
laws and regulations and supranational bodies such as the WTO (Hepple 2005).
It is an obvious point to make that individual countries function in a globalized
environment and cannot be understood as isolated systems. An excellent example is
the member states of the EU or Eurozone, which have to conform to precise eco-
nomic and political membership conditions and witness increasing homogenization
and convergence tendencies (sometimes reluctantly as with case of the UK).
A dramatic example is provided by the institutions of Greek employment relations,
which have been subject to scrutiny and intervention by the European Central
Bank, the European Commission and the IMF institutions. Or again, with regard to
the transformation of post-communist Central Eastern Europe, the EU as well as the
IMF and the World Bank had a significant impact on the development of their
employment relations. The World Bank has also played a major role in influencing
employment relations institutions in Asia and South America (Evans 1995).
(v) Finally, the concept of ideas, ideologies or identities (to use Hyman’s phrase 2001b)
refers to the historical path dependencies or inherited normative or ideational tradi-
tions as well as to new ideas that shape actors’ interests as well as institutions. The
concept broadly refers to the ‘economic culture’ of a country,4 thus to the prevalent
societal ideas on private property, ownership, employment at will, industrial democ-
racy, workers’ dignity, justice, privacy, trust or social capital. Dominant social actors
might have very different understandings of what defines social justice in the labour
market or what entails private property and ownership in a capitalist society across
countries and the struggle of different ideologies and discourses certainly shapes the
institutional architecture of employment regimes. Of course, concepts such as ideas or
economic cultures might not be as easily measured as institutional constraints since
they have a more subtle or indirect effect. One option is therefore to analyze actors’
legitimation for certain strategic choices (such as companies’ corporate social responsi-
bility claims) or the social and discursive (de)construction of political agendas in the
media or public arena (e.g. Schroeder’s Hartz reforms, Merkel’s policy on minimum
wages in Germany or Obama’s ‘American Job Act’).
24 Carola Frege and John Kelly
Last, but not least, every comparative analysis of employment relations needs
to be specific about its dependent variables, that is, which outcomes are to be
explained. Different theories tend to concentrate on different outcomes; part 2 of
our book will discuss the major challenges and outcomes of employment regula-
tion. Market driven theories are usually interested in performance indicators, for
example which employment regime yields the highest labour productivity, high-
est skills or highest employment rates. Political economic theories tend to include
the outcomes for society as a whole such as the quality of their welfare states,
strike levels, social unrest, the quality of their civil societies or the wellbeing of
individual workers (happiness) and their social and political engagement levels.
Relatedly, different national employment regimes might focus on different
employment outcomes.5 Moreover, not all five variables will prove equally
important in different country settings. It remains an empirical task to analyze
the importance each factor plays in a particular historical and national setting.
This will be illustrated in the country studies in Part 4.
Notes
1 For example, with regard to the increasing influence of economics in the field of labour law
see Schwab (1997).
2 In more detail: System theory (Dunlop), Marxist approaches (political economy, labour pro-
cess debate, regulation theory), institutionalism (historical institutionalism, neo-corporatism),
action theory (micro politics, labour politics, negotiation of order, strategic choice) and eco-
nomic approaches (rational choice, transaction costs).
3 Note, however, that Hall and Soskice acknowledged there might be a third type, the Mediterranean
economy, a theme developed in Hancké et al. (2007) through the concept of the ‘mixed market
economy’.
4 Note that legal scholars are discussing a similar concept, ‘legal cultures’, across countries
(Finkin 2004; Nelken 2004; Whitman 2004).
5 Interestingly, on the international policy level, the Stiglitz Commission on the Measurement
of Economic Performance and Social Progress, initiated by former French President Sarkozy
in 2008, was trying to combine both.
References
Adams, R. and Meltz, N. (eds) (1993) Industrial Relations Theory: Its Nature, Scope and Pedagogy,
Metuchen, Canada: Scarecrow Press.
Amable, B. (2003) The Diversity of Modern Capitalism, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Avdagic, S., Rhodes, M. and Visser, J. (eds) (2011) Social Pacts in Europe: Emergence, Evolution and
Institutionalization, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Baccaro, L. and Howell, C. (2017) Trajectories of Neoliberal Transformation: European Industrial Rela-
tions since the 1970s, New York: Cambridge University Press.
Bamber, G.J. and Lansbury, R.D. (eds) (1987) International and Comparative Industrial Relations,
London: Allen and Unwin.
Bamber, G.J., Lansbury, R.D., Wailes, N. and Wright, C.F. (eds) (2015) International and Com-
parative Employment Relations: National Regulation, Global Changes, 6th edn, London: Sage.
Burawoy, M. (1985) The Politics of Production: Factory Regimes Under Capitalism and Socialism,
London: Verso Books.
Burgess, K. (2004) Parties and Unions in the New Global Economy, Pittsburgh, PA: University of
Pittsburgh Press.
Theoretical perspectives on CER 25
Colling, T. and Terry, M. (2010) ‘Work, the employment relationship and the field of industrial
relations’, in T. Colling and M. Terry (eds) Industrial Relations: Theory and Practice, 3rd edn,
Oxford: Wiley, 3–26.
Crouch, C. (1993) Industrial Relations and European State Traditions, London: Clarendon Press.
Crouch, C. (1996) The Social Contract and the Problem of the Firm, Florence: European University
Institute.
Crouch, C. (2005) Capitalist Diversity and Change: Recombinant Governance and Institutional Entrepre-
neurs, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Dicken, P., Kelly, P.F., Olds, K. and Yeung, H. (2001) ‘Chains and networks, territories
and scales: towards a relational framework for analysing the global economy’, Global
Network, 1(2): 89–112.
Dunlop, J. (1958) Industrial Relations Systems, New York: Henry Holt.
Edwards, P.K. (1986) Conflict at Work, Oxford: Blackwell.
Elster, J. (1982) ‘Marxism, functionalism, and game theory’, Theory and Society, 11(4):
453–482.
Esping-Andersen, G. (1985) Politics against Markets: The Social-Democratic Road to Power, Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press.
Esping-Andersen, G., Friedland, R. and Wright, E.O. (1976) ‘Modes of class struggle and the
capitalist state’, Kapitalstate, 4–5: 184–220.
Estlund, C. (2010) Regoverning the Workplace: From Self-Regulation to Co-Regulation, New Haven,
CT: Yale University Press.
Evans, P. (1995) Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation, Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
Ferner, A. and Hyman, R. (eds) (1992) Industrial Relations in the New Europe: Changing Industrial
Relations in Europe. 2nd edn, 1998. Oxford: Blackwell.
Fine, J. (2006) Worker Centers: Organizing Communities at the Edge of the Dream, Ithaca, NY:
Cornell University Press.
Finkin, M. (2004) ‘Menschenbild: the conception of the employee as a person in Western law’,
Comparative Labor Law and Policy Journal, 23(2): 577–637.
Flanders, A. (1975) Management and Unions, 2nd edn, London: Faber and Faber.
Fox, A. (1974) Beyond Contract: Work, Power and Trust Relations, London: Faber and Faber.
Frege, C. (2007) Employment Research and State Traditions: A Comparative History of Britain,
Germany and the United States, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Frenkel, S. and Kuruvilla, S. (2002) ‘Logics of action, globalization and changing employment
relations in China, India, Malaysia, and the Philippines’, Industrial and Labor Relations
Review, 55(3): 387–412.
Gallie, D. (2007) ‘Production regimes and the quality of employment in Europe’, Annual Review
of Sociology, 33: 85–104.
Gereffi, G. (2005) ‘The global economy: organization, governance and development’, in N.J. Smelser
and R. Swedberg (eds) The Handbook of Economic Sociology, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press, 160–182.
Glyn, A. (1991) ‘Corporatism, patterns of employment and access to consumption’, in
J. Pekkarinen, M. Pohjola and B. Rowthorn (eds) Social Corporatism: A Superior Economic
System?, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 132–177.
Grossman, S.J. and Hart, O. (1986) ‘The costs and benefits of ownership: a theory of vertical and
lateral integration’, Journal of Political Economy, 94(4): 691–719.
Hall, P.A. and Soskice, D. (2001) ‘An introduction to varieties of capitalism’, in P.A. Hall and
D. Soskice (eds) Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage,
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1–68.
Hamann, K. and Kelly, J. (2011) Parties, Elections and Policy Reforms in Western Europe: Voting for
Social Pacts, Abingdon: Routledge.
26 Carola Frege and John Kelly
Hamann, K., Johnston, A. and Kelly, J. (2013) ‘Unions against governments: general strikes in
Western Europe 1980–2006’, Comparative Political Studies, 46(9): 1030–1057.
Hancké, B., Rhodes, M. and Thatcher, M. (eds) (2007) Beyond Varieties of Capitalism: Conflict,
Contradictions, and Complementarities in the European Economy, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hart, O. and Moore, J. (1990) ‘Property rights and the nature of the firm’, Journal of Political
Economy, 98(6): 1119–1158.
Hepple, B. (2005) Labour Laws and Global Trade, Oxford: Hart Publishing.
Herrigel, G. and Wittke, V. (2005) ‘Varieties of vertical disintegration: the global trend
toward heterogeneous supply relations and the reproduction of difference in US and
German manufacturing’, in G. Morgan, E. Moen and R. Whitley (eds) Changing Capital-
isms: Internationalisation, Institutional Change and Systems of Economic Organization, Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 312–351.
Heyes, J., Lewis, P. and Clark, I. (2012) ‘Varieties of capitalism, neoliberalism and the economic
crisis of 2008–?’, Industrial Relations Journal, 43(3): 222–241.
Hollingsworth, J.R. and Boyer, R. (1997) ‘Continuities and changes in social systems of produc-
tion: the cases of Japan, Germany and the United States’, in J.R. Hollingsworth and R. Boyer
(eds) Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions, Cambridge: Cambridge Univer-
sity Press, 265–310.
Hollingsworth, J.R., Schmitter, P. and Streeck, W. (1994) Governing Capitalist Economies, Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Howell, C. (2005) Trade Unions and the State: The Construction of Industrial Relations Institutions in
Britain, 1890–2000, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Hyman, R. (1975) Industrial Relations: A Marxist Introduction, London: Macmillan.
Hyman, R. (2001a) Theorising Industrial Relations: Anglo-American Individualism versus the European
Social Model, London: London School of Economics, Working Paper.
Hyman, R. (2001b) Understanding European Trade Unionism: Between Market, Class and Society,
London: Sage.
Hyman, R. (2004) ‘Is industrial relations theory always ethnocentric?’, in B. Kaufman (ed.) Theoret-
ical Perspectives on Work and the Employment Relationship, Madison, WI: Industrial Relations
Research Association, 265–292.
Hyman, R. and Ferner, A. (eds) (1994) New Frontiers in European Industrial Relations, Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Kelly, J. (1998) Rethinking Industrial Relations: Mobilization, Collectivism and Long Waves, London:
Routledge.
Kelly, J. (2010) Ethical Socialism and the Trade Unions: Allan Flanders and British Industrial Relations
Reform, Abingdon: Routledge.
Kelly, J. (2011) ‘The political economy of comparative employment relations’, in M. Barry and
A. Wilkinson (eds) Research Handbook of Comparative Employment Relations, Cheltenham:
Edward Elgar, 56–74.
Kerr, C. (1983) The Future of Industrial Societies: Convergence or Continuing Diversity?, Boston, MA:
Harvard University Press.
Kerr, C., Dunlop, J.T., Harbison, F.H. and Myers, C.A. (1960) Industrialism and Industrial Man,
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Kochan, T. (1998) ‘What is distinctive about industrial relations research?’, in K. Whitfield and
G. Strauss (eds) Researching the World of Work, Ithaca, NY: ILR Press, 31–50.
Kochan, T., Katz, H.C. and McKersie, R.B. (1986) The Transformation of American Industrial
Relations, New York: Basic Books.
Korpi, W. (1978) The Working Class in Welfare Capitalism: Work, Unions and Politics in Sweden,
London: Routledge.
Korpi, W. (2006) ‘Power resources and employer-centered approaches in explanations of welfare
states and varieties of capitalism: protagonists, consenters, and antagonists’, World Politics, 58(2):
167–206.
Theoretical perspectives on CER 27
Lane, C. and Probert, J. (2009) National Capitalisms, Global Production Networks, Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Lash, S. and Urry, J. (1987) The End of Organized Capitalism, London: Polity Press.
Lehmbruch, G. and Schmitter, P. (eds) (1982) Patterns of Corporatist Policymaking, Beverly Hills,
CA: Sage.
Lewin, D. and Feuille, P. (1983) ‘Behavioral research in industrial relations’, Industrial and Labor
Relations Review, 36(3): 341–360.
Locke, R., Kochan, T. and Piore, M. (1995) Employment Relations in a Changing World Economy,
Boston, MA: MIT Press.
Marks, G. (1989) Unions in Politics: Britain, Germany and the United States in the Nineteenth and
Early Twentieth Centuries, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Marsden, R. (1982) ‘Industrial relations: a critique of empiricism’, Sociology, 16(4): 232–250.
Marshall, G. (1998) ‘Labour relations’, in J. Scott and G. Marshall (eds) Oxford Dictionary of
Sociology, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 310–311.
Milner, S. (2015) Comparative Employment Relations: France, Germany and Britain, Basingstoke: Pal-
grave Macmillan.
Mitchell, D. (2001) ‘IR journal and conference literature from the 1960s to the 1990s: what can
HR learn from it? Where is it headed?’, Human Resource Management Review, 11(4): 375–393.
Mueller-Jentsch, W. (2004) ‘Theoretical approaches to industrial relations’, in B. Kaufman (ed.)
Theoretical Perspectives on Work and the Employment Relationship, Madison, WI: Industrial Rela-
tions Research Association, 1–40.
Nelken, D. (2004) ‘Using the concept of legal culture’, Australian Journal of Legal Philosophy,
29(1): 1–26.
Offe, C. and Wiesenthal, H. (1980) ‘Two logics of collective action: theoretical notes on social
class and organizational form’, Political Power and Social Theory, 1: 67–115.
Ost, D. (2005) Defeat of Solidarity: Anger and Politics in Post-Communist Europe, Ithaca, NY: Cornell
University Press.
Peters, B.G. (2008) ‘Approaches in comparative politics’, in D. Caramani (ed.) Comparative
Politics, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 44–62.
Piore, M. and Sabel, C. (1984) The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity, New York:
Basic Books.
Rothstein, B. (1987) ‘Corporatism and reformism: the social democratic institutionalization of
class conflict’, Acta Sociologica, 30(3–4): 295–311.
Sabel, C. (1982) Work and Politics, Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
Schmitter, P. (1979) ‘Interessenvermittlung und regierbarkeit’, in U. Von Alemann and R.G. Heinze
(eds) Verbände Und Staat, Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag, 92–114.
Schmitter, P. and Lehmbruch, G. (eds) (1979) Trends towards Corporatist Intermediation, Beverly
Hills, CA: Sage.
Schwab, S. (1997) ‘The law and economics approach to workplace regulation’, in B. Kaufman
(ed.) Government Regulation of the Employment Relationship, Madison, WI: Industrial Relations
Research Association, 91–123.
Sommer Harrits, G. (2006) The class thesis revisited: Social Dynamics and Welfare State Change,
Conference Paper, ESPAnet, University of Bremen.
Streeck, W. (2001) ‘Introduction: explorations into the origins of nonliberal capitalism in Ger-
many and Japan’, in W. Streeck and K. Yamamura (eds) The Origins of Nonliberal Capitalism:
Germany and Japan, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1–38.
Streeck, W. (2009) Re-Forming Capitalism: Institutional Change in the German Political Economy,
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Streeck, W. and Schmitter, P. (1985) ‘Community, market, state and associations? The prospect-
ive contribution of interest governance to social order’, in W. Streeck and P. Schmitter (eds)
Private Interest Government: Beyond Market and State, London: Sage, 1–29.
28 Carola Frege and John Kelly
Thelen, K. (2004) How Institutions Evolve: The Political Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain, the
United States and Japan, New York: Cambridge University Press.
Thelen, K. (2010) ‘Beyond comparative statics: historical institutional approaches to stability
and change in the political economy of labor’, in G. Morgan, J.L. Campbell, C. Crouch,
O.K. Pedersen and R. Whitley (eds) The Oxford Handbook of Comparative Institutional Ana-
lysis, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 41–62.
Thelen, K. and Streeck, W. (2005) Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change in Advanced Political
Economies, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Traxler, F., Blaschke, S. and Kittel, B. (2001) National Labour Relations in Internationalized Markets:
A Comparative Study of Institutions, Change, and Performance, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Visser, J. (1996) ‘Traditions and transitions in industrial relations: a European view’, in J. van
Ruysseveldt and J. Visser (eds) Industrial Relations in Europe: Traditions and Transitions, London:
Sage, 1–41.
Wailes, N., Wright, C.F., Bamber, G.J. and Lansbury, R.D. (2015) ‘Introduction: an internation-
ally comparative approach to employment relations’, in G.J. Bamber, R.D. Lansbury,
N. Wailes and C.F. Wright (eds) International and Comparative Employment Relations, London:
Sage, 1–19.
Western, B. (1998) ‘Institutions and the labor market’, in M. Brinton and V. Nee (eds) New
Institutionalism in Sociology, New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 224–244.
Whitman, J.Q. (2004) ‘The two western cultures of privacy: dignity versus liberty’, The Yale Law
Journal, 113: 1151–1221.
Wilkinson, A., Wood, G. and Deeg, R. (eds) (2014) The Oxford Handbook of Employment Rela-
tions, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Williamson, O. (1985) The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting,
New York: Free Press.