Eco Analysis of Water Resources
Eco Analysis of Water Resources
Eco Analysis of Water Resources
Lecture Notes CE 385D: Water Resources Planning and Management Daene C. McKinney Department of Civil Engineering The University of Texas at Austin
Contents
Section Page 1. Engineering Economics ........................................................................................................... 1 1.1 Choosing Among Feasible Alternatives .............................................................................. 1 1.2 Cost-effectiveness analysis .................................................................................................. 2 1.3 Benefit-cost analysis ............................................................................................................ 2 1.3.1 Interest Rate Calculations ............................................................................................. 3 1.4 Financial Analysis................................................................................................................ 4 1.5 Discount Rate....................................................................................................................... 5 2. Demand ................................................................................................................................... 11 2.1 Introduction........................................................................................................................ 11 2.2 Consumers Problem.......................................................................................................... 12 2.3 Demand .............................................................................................................................. 15 2.4 Willingness-to-pay............................................................................................................. 15 2.5 Elasticity (of demand)........................................................................................................ 18 2.6 Water Values in the US...................................................................................................... 20 3. Supply...................................................................................................................................... 21 3.1 Introduction........................................................................................................................ 21 3.2 The Firms Problem ........................................................................................................... 24 3.3 Crop Production Functions with Water ............................................................................. 29 3.3.1 Introduction................................................................................................................. 29 3.3.2 Types of Production Function Models........................................................................ 30 3.3.3 Example: Production of wheat in the Maipo basin, Chile ......................................... 32 3.4 Opportunity Cost................................................................................................................ 40 3.5 Average Cost Pricing ......................................................................................................... 40 3.6 Criteria for Decision Making............................................................................................. 41 3.7 Externalities ....................................................................................................................... 45 3.8 Production of Multiple Outputs ......................................................................................... 46 4. Water Rights and Markets.................................................................................................... 51 4.1 Introduction........................................................................................................................ 51 4.2 Water Rights ...................................................................................................................... 52 4.2.1 Riparian water rights systems ..................................................................................... 54 4.2.2 Appropriative water rights systems ............................................................................ 54 4.3. Water Markets.................................................................................................................... 56 4.3.1 Right to divert or consume.......................................................................................... 56
1/10/2003
4.3.2 Tradable water rights markets..................................................................................... 58 4.3.3 Modeling tradable water rights markets ..................................................................... 61 Exercises ...................................................................................................................................... 63 References.................................................................................................................................... 73
ii
1/10/2003
1. Engineering Economics
1.1 Choosing Among Feasible Alternatives
Economic analysis, or the understanding and prediction of decision making under conditions of resource scarcity, plays a major role in the planning, design and management of sustainable water resource systems. Allocation of water among competing uses to obtain an optimum value in terms of market or welfare measures is one of the main problems of water resources planners. Price theory is very relevant where markets are operating efficiently, whereas welfare economics seeks to maximize human welfare in situations where desirable social gains and undesirable social costs are not fully accounted for in a profit maximizing, market economy (North, 1985). Price theory and welfare economics tend to focus on static analyses of projects, whereas, financial analysis considers the time value of investments and decisions. In this section, we will consider some aspects of financial analysis. Choice is governed by economic and financial feasibility and acceptability with respect to social and environmental impacts. Here we want to consider investment analysis which serves as a guide for allocating resources between present and future consumption. The process consists of: Identifying alternatives to be considered; Predicting the consequences resulting from these alternatives; Converting the consequences into some commensurable units (e.g., $s); and Choosing among the alternatives One project may produce one type of output, while another project produces another kind of output. In order to compare the projects and make investment decisions, common units must be used to express the outputs of each alternative before any comparison can be made. Monetary units are the most commonly used units. Some projects will provide outputs in the near future and other projects may delay outputs for an appreciable time or distribute them uniformly over the project lifetime. Outputs today do not have the same value as outputs tomorrow and the following observations are appropriate: Investors often prefer early return on investments since it provides them with more flexibility in making future investment decisions; Benefits and costs at different times should not be directly compared or combined, since they are not in common units; Future benefits and costs must be multiplied by a factor that becomes progressively smaller for times further into the future. This multiplicative factor is called the discount rate and it has a great impact on the alternative selected; Future benefits and costs are given more weight with lower discount rates and less weight with higher discount rates; and
1/10/2003
Committing resources to one project may deny the possibility of investing in some other project. This brings up the question of opportunity costs, or what must be foregone in order to undertake some alternative.
One should always keep in mind that different points of view may be adopted in analyzing alternatives, e.g., project sponsors; people in a specific area or region; and an entire nation. Each point of view may value benefits and costs differently and even define items differently (i.e., one persons cost may be another persons benefit.).
In benefit cost analyses, any costs and benefits that are unaffected by which alternative is selected should be neglected. That is, the differences between alternatives need only be considered. Estimates of benefits and costs are typically uncertain because of imprecision in both underlying data and modeling assumptions. Because such uncertainty is basic to many analyses, its effects should be analyzed and reported (OMB, 1992). Uncertainty may exist in: objectives, constraints, public response, technological change, or extreme events and recurrence.
1/10/2003
1.3.1 Interest Rate Calculations Consider investing $100 at a rate of 5%. At the end of one year the value of the investment would be:
F1 = $100(1+ 0.05) = $105
Similarly, at the end of 2 years, the value would be F2 = $105(1+ 0.05) = $100(1+ 0.05) 2 = $110.25 or, generalizing this, we have at the end of t years that an initial investment of $P would be worth
Ft = P(1+ i )t Put another way, a single payment of Ft available t years in the future is worth
P = Ft (1+ i )t
and a series of (not necessarily equal) payments Ft available t years in the future is worth
P =
(1+i)
t =1
Ft
Example. Assume that an initial investment of $50 disbursement at t=0 is required and that this will result in $200 receipt at t= 1 year and $150 receipt at t = 2 years with an interest rate of 7% annually (see figure).
$200
$150
$50
What is the Present Value, P, of the given cash flow? P = C + Ft (1 + i ) t = C + F1 (1 + i ) 1 + F2 (1 + i ) 2
t
1/10/2003
P=( P=(
)+( )$
)+(
What is the Future Value of the given cash flow? F = C (1 + i ) 2 + F1 (1 + i ) +1 + F2 F=( F=( )+( )$ )+( )
1/10/2003
where NBt = Net benefits at time t Bt benefits at that time C t costs at that time The Present Value of net benefits is
P =
T
NBt
t
t =1 (1+i )
Often it is convenient to convert a present value to an equivalent annual value. For this we can use the Capital Recovery Factor (CRF)
CRFT = Then
A = P CRFT
i (1 + i )T (i + 1)T 1
1/10/2003
US federal practice (Senate Doc. 97, 1962) Average rate of interest payable by the US Treasury on interest-bearing marketable securities outstanding at the end of the fiscal year preceding computation which had terms to maturity of 15 years or more See http://waterhome.tamu.edu/NRCSdata/PriceIndexes/Rates.htm for current and historic rates.
Two alternative plans are considered for a section of an aqueduct. Plan A uses a tunnel, and Plan B uses a lined canal and steel flume. Both plans yield the same revenues over the life of the project.
Plan A Tunnel Plan B Canal lining 20 yr $50,000 $10,500
Canal
Flume 50 yr $90,000
Life First cost Annual cost Interest rate = 6 % per year Study period = 100 years
Compare the equivalent annual costs of the two plans CRF = where i = 0.06 and N = 20, 50, and 100 years i (1 + i ) N (i + 1) N 1
Plan A
Capital recovery cost for the tunnel Annual maintenance cost Total annual cost $450,000 x 0.060177 = $27,080 $4,000 $31,080
Plan B
Capital recovery cost for canal $120,000 x 0.060177 = $7,221 Capital recovery cost for canal $50,000 x 0.087184 = $4,359 lining Capital recovery cost for flume $90,000 x 0.063444 = $5,710 Annual maintenance cost $10,500 Total annual cost $27,790
1/10/2003
Total investment is $450,000 and $260,000, respectively, for the two projects. Even though the annual O&M costs are lower for Plan A, the annual cost comparison tells us that the extra investment is not justified. Thus Plan B should be selected. Where the capacity of the project is to be determined, we simply determine the project with the maximum net benefits (difference of benefits over costs). That is:
Max NB ( x) = B( x) C ( x)
where x is the capacity of the project. Thus
dB( x) dC ( x) = dx dx or dB ( x) =1 dC ( x) That is, we increase the capacity up to the point where the marginal (incremental) benefits just exceed the marginal (incremental) costs and then stop.
Example. (after North, 1985, Ex. 5-1):
A flood control district can construct several alternative control works to alleviate flooding. These alternatives include the construction of dam A, dam B, and a system of levees C. Each of these works can be built to function alone or together with any other or all other projects. Thus we have a possibility of the following combinations: ABC, A, B, C, AB, AC, and BC. The life of each dam is 80 years and the life of the levee system is 60 years. The cost of capital is 4% . Information on total investment, operation and maintainence costs, and average annual flood damages is given in the table. Which flood control undertaking is the most economical? Project A B C AB AC BC ABC Do nothing
Table. Flood Control Project data Total Investment Annual Operation (million $) and Maintainence (thous. $) 6 90 5 80 6 100 11 170 10 190 9 180 15 270 0 0
Average Annual Flood Damages (million $) 1.10 1.30 0.70 0.90 0.40 0.50 0.25 2.00
1/10/2003
The annual investment costs can be computed for each alternative by multiplying the investiment cost by the appropriate capital recovery factor: CRFT = i (1 + i )T (i + 1)T 1
where T = 80 years for dams and 60 for levees, respectively. Project Total Investment ($ mln) 6 5 6 11 10 9 15 CRF Annual Investment Costs ($ mln) 0.251 0.209 0.265 0.460 0.516 0.474 0.725 Annual Operation and Maintainence ($ mln) 0.090 0.080 0.100 0.170 0.190 0.180 0.270 Total Annual Cost ($ mln) 0.341 0.289 0.365 0.630 0.706 0.654 0.995
A B C AB AC BC ABC
The Incremental Benefit Cost Ratio Method compares the additional benefit to the cost of any alternative compared to other alternatives to find the solution. The procedure is: 1. Discard any alternative with B/C < 1 2. Rank order the alternatives from lowest to highest cost 3. Compute the incremental benefit - cost ratio for the contender versus current best alternative. If that ratio is greater than 1, contender becomes current best. 4. Repeat until all alternatives have been tested. Final current best is preferred alternative.
Comparison BA CA AB C BC C AC C ABC C Project B A C AB BC AC ABC Benefits ($ mln) 0.7 0.9 1.3 1.1 1.5 1.6 1.75 Cost ($ mln) 0.289 0.341 0.365 0.63 0.654 0.706 0.995 B/C Ratio 2.42 2.64 3.56 1.75 2.29 2.27 1.76 B ($ mln) 0.7 0.2 0.4 -0.2 0.2 0.3 0.45 C ($ mln) 0.289 0.052 0.024 0.265 0.289 0.341 0.63 B/C 2.4 3.8 17 -0.75 0.69 0.88 0.71 Conclusion < A>B C>A C > AB C > BC C > AC C > ABC
Determine the optimal scale of development of a hydroelectric project using benefit cost analysis. Various alternative size projects and corresponding benefits are shown in the table below.
Notes on Economics McKinney
1/10/2003
Scale (MW)
Benefits
B
Costs
C
($ mln) 50 60 75 90 100 125 150 200 18.0 21.0 26.7 29.8 32.7 38.5 42.5 50.0
Net Benefits B-C ($ mln) 3.0 3.6 5.7 6.4 6.7 6.0 5.0 0.0
The following figures show plots of the (1) project benefits and costs versus capacity, and (2) project benefits versus costs. Using a marginal analysis we find that the optimal capacity is 100 MW.
50 Benefits 45 40 Benefits or Costs ($ mln) 35 30 25 20 15 10 40 60 80 100 120 Capacity (MW) 140 160 180 200 Benefits
Costs
Costs
Max ( B - C )
1/10/2003
60
50
40 Benefits ($ mln)
B = C line
30
Max NB
20
10
0 0 10 20 30 Costs ($ mln) 40 50 60
The incremental benefit cost ratio method to find the same solution as before. Incremental
Comparison Scale (MW) B C B C B/C Conclusion ($ mln) ($ mln) ($ mln) ($ mln)
<I II > I III > II IV > III V > IV VI <V VII < V VIII < V
10
1/10/2003
2. Demand
2.1 Introduction
Consumers purchase goods produced by firms. They have preferences for some goods over others and they choose purchases from a set of feasible options. A utility function u(x) is a numerical representation of consumer preferences. If one bundle of goods is preferred to another bundle, then it must have a higher utility. Indifference curves are the level sets of some utility function (see Figure 2.1.1). Consider the case when there are 2 goods to choose from, x1 and x2. If the consumer changes consumption by a small amount (dx1, dx2 ) but keeps utility constant, say at level uo, then
du ( x) = u u dx1 + dx2 = 0 x1 x2 (2.1.1)
x2 u(x1,x2)
where MU i =
u xi
i = 1,2
(2.1.2)
11
1/10/2003
is the marginal utility or the change in utility due to a small change in xi. Then using Eq. 2.1.2 in Eq. 2.1.1, we can write
dx 2 MU1 = = MRS12 dx1 MU 2
(2.1.3)
where MRS12 is the marginal rate of substitution, that is, the rate at which a consumer can substitute good 1 for good 2.
(2.2.1)
(2.2.2)
separates the space into two regions: (1) a region containing those combinations of goods whose purchase would exceed the budget; and (2) a region where those combinations that would not exceed the budget (See Figure 2.2.1). The slope of the budget line ( p1 / p2 ) is the rate at which the market will substitute good 1 for good 2.
12
1/10/2003
Affordable bundles
m/p1 x1
Now, in the general case of K goods, the consumer is faced with the problem
r maximize u( x ) subject to r r p x m r x0
(2.2.3) (2.2.4)
That is, the consumer tries for maximize utility while satisfying the budget constraint. Now, assume that the budget constraint (Eq. 2.2.4) holds as an equality (all funds are expended or one of the goods is actually a savings account) and that the levels of consumption are all positive. Then we have the classical programming problem with a Lagrangian function
K L ( x, ) = u ( x ) + m p k x k k =1
(2.2.5)
k = 1,..., K
(2.2.6)
(2.2.7)
13
1/10/2003
The first condition (Eq. 2.2.6) says that the ratio of the marginal utility to price is constant for all inputs
MU k = pk u x k = pk
k = 1,..., K
(2.2.8)
or
MU1 MU 2 MU K = = ... = = p1 p2 pK
(2.2.9)
That is, a consumer chooses purchases such that the ratio of marginal benefit (marginal utility) to marginal cost (price) is equal among all purchases. This ratio, with units of $/unit of commodity or (shadow) price, is the value of the Lagrange multiplier () which is also the ratio of the change in total utility for a change in income, or
u m
(2.2.10)
(2.2.11)
which says that the slope of the budget line will equal the slope of the indifference curve. or the ratio of the marginal utilities of any two goods equals the ratio of their prices (See Figure 2.2.2).
x2
x1*
x1
14
1/10/2003
2.3 Demand
The optimal solution to the consumers problem depends on income and prices so solving the r r r problem (Eq. 2.2.3 and 2.2.4) results in an optimal level of consumption x * = x * ( p, m ) which is a function of the prices and the available income. This is the demand function. A typical r r r demand function is shown in Figure 2.3.1. Often the inverse demand function ( p = p( x*, m ) ) is needed in analyses, this is simply the inverse of the demand function or price as a function of quantity and income. Market demand is the aggregation of all of the individual consumers demands. Market demand depends on prices and the distribution of income in the economy.
Price, p
Quantity, x
2.4 Willingness-to-pay
The value of a good to a person is what that person is willing and able to sacrifice for it (willingness to pay). How do we measure what a person is willing to pay for a good? Assume that a farmer has no irrigation water for production of a particular crop, but desires to purchase some water. If one unit of water became available, how much would the farmer be willing to pay to obtain that unit of water, rather than have no water at all? Suppose the farmer is willing to pay $38 for this first unit (see Figure 2.4.1) even though (s)he would prefer to pay less. Now, suppose that the farmer is willing to pay $26 for a second unit of water. Further, suppose that the farmer is willing to pay $17 for a third unit. According to the figure, at p* = $10 per unit, the 15
1/10/2003
farmer would purchase 4 units of water for a total cost of $40, but (s)he would have been willing to pay $93 for that water. Thus, the farmer receives a surplus of $53 (consumer surplus) when purchasing the 4 units of water.
Price, p 40 38 WTP = 93 30 26
20 CS = 53 17 12 p*=10 Cost = 40
Quantity, x
If we assume that fractional amounts of a unit of a good can be purchased, then we obtain a continuous graph, as in Figure 2.4.2. Marginal willingness-to-pay is the height of the curve. Total willingness-to-pay is the sum of the heights of the rectangles between the origin and the particular consumption level of interest. In the case of the continuous curve, willingness-to-pay is the area under the curve from the origin and the particular consumption level of interest and this represents the gross benefit of purchasing this amount of the good. The net-benefit from this purchase is the willingness-to-pay minus the cost or
NB = p ( , m)d p * x *
0 x*
(2.4.1)
16
1/10/2003
p*
Cost = p*x*
x*
Quantity, x
Measuring benefit of water use in this manner requires that we can derive the demand curve for the water used for a particular purpose. For marketed commodities with available information on prices and quantities we can: (1) derive a demand curve, (2) quantify willingness-to-pay, and (3) use WTP to represent benefits. However, in many cases market prices may not exist, demands may not be revealed, and the change in benefits over time may be extremely uncertain. Examples include (1) the benefits of preserving space for recreation, and (2) the benefits derived from damages prevented due to pollution controls. If the physical damages of pollution can be identified and estimated, then a monetary value may be placed on them (for an example of applying this to the Aral Sea basin, see Anderson, 1997). Sometimes it is possible to survey people to determine their willingness-to-pay for different environmental assets such as environmental preservation, damage reductions, and lower risks. From these survey results we may be able to infer the valuation of the assets. Indeed, we may also be able to infer these values from related markets where values are observable. The value of municipal water at its source is net of the water utility costs and is represented by the consumers' surplus. The area under the demand curve for an increment from x1 to x2 is (Gibbons, 1986)
Area =
px2 x2 x 1 1 x x 1 2
(2.4.2)
17
1/10/2003
(2.5.1)
This quantity depends on the units used to describe the inputs and price. If we normalize this function, we obtain the price elasticity of demand elasticity = = dx dp x p (2.5.2)
Consider the following example adapted from Merrett (1997). Table 2.5.1 shows the quantity of water demanded for different prices along with the price elasticity of water at various increments. Figure 2.5.1 plots the demand function for water and illustrates the ranges of elastic and inelastic behavior. Merrett (1997) proposes a cubic form for the demand function
p = ax 3 + bx 2 + cx + d
(2.5.3)
where a < 0, b > 0, c < 0, and d > 0. He points out, at low quantities, higher prices for water have little effect due to the intense need for the water. Similarly, at low quantities, higher prices for water have little effect due to the abundance of water. In the middle quantities, changes in price produce significant changes in the quantity of water demanded.
18
1/10/2003
Table 2.5.1. Price Elasticity of Water (adapted from Merrett, 1997) Quantity Price Q P 3 3 (m /month) (per m ) 700 6 300 -1 1.8 1000 5 500 -1 1.67 1500 4 500 -1 1 2000 3 500 -1 0.6 2500 2 300 -1 0.21 2800 1
6 >1, elastic P, Q, TR 5
2 <1, inelastic P, Q, TR 1
19
1/10/2003
Price elasticity of municipal water demand was estimated (Gibbons, 1986) and in-house water use was found to be price-inelastic (= -0.23), while sprinkling use was found to be more elastic and differ between the Eastern US (= -1.6) and the Western US ( = -0.7).
Table 2.6.2 shows data on the value of water for recreations and fish & wildlife uses within the United States and Table 2.6.3 shows the value of water use in irrigated agriculture.
Table 2.6.2. Water Values for Recreation/F&W Habitat ($/af) [Frederrick et al. (1996)] Average Median Min Max Fishing 34 5 0 158 Wildlife Refuge 24 6 1 44 Fishing & Whitewater 1042 1505 6 3 Whitewater 9 9 5 4 Shoreline Recreation 19 19 17 2
20
1/10/2003
Table 2.6.3. Water Values by Crop ($/af) [Frederrick et al. (1996)] Average Median Alfalfa 51 44 Apples 151 151 Barley 33 39 Beans 58 58 Carrots 550 550 Corn 91 98 Cotton 114 103 Grain Sorgham 57 44 Hay 36 36 Hops 18 18 Lettuce 208 208 Melons 54 54 Onions 40 40 Pears 137 137 Potatoes 710 784 Rice 86 86 Safflower 53 58 Soybeans 121 127 Sugar Beets 121 119 Tomatoes 686 686 Vegetables 206 206 Wheat 51 47
3. Supply
3.1 Introduction
Firms produce outputs from various combinations of inputs. The objective of a firm is to maximize profit subject to constraints imposed by technological capabilities. As long as inputs are costly, we can limit our consideration to those combinations of inputs that will produce the maximum output for a given level of inputs. This represents the boundary of the so-called production possibilities set and it is called the production function (see Figure 3.1.1)
r y = f ( x)
(3.1.1)
r Level curves of the production function are called isoquants where f ( x ) = y 0 . For a firm producing a single output (y) from two inputs (x1 and x2), the isoquants may look like those in Figure 3.1.2.
21
1/10/2003
df dx
Input, x1
Suppose that the firm wants to increase the amount of one input and decrease the amount of the r other while maintaining a constant level of output f ( x ) = y 0 . So if production is to remain constant, we can write dy = f f dx1 + dx2 = 0 x1 x 2 (3.1.2)
22
1/10/2003
is the marginal product or the additional output available from using an additional unit of input xi in the production process. Now, from Equations 3.1.1 and 3.1.2, we have dx2 MP = 1 = TRS12 dx1 MP2 (3.1.3)
where TRS12 is the technical rate of substitution. That is, the rate at which x1 can replace x2 (see Figure 3.1.3). TRS12 is the slope of the isoquant f ( x1 , x2 ) = y0 .
x2
Revenue R is the amount of money that a firm receives for selling an amount y of a product for a particular price p:
R = py
(3.1.4)
Marginal revenue is the change in revenue for a change in the output or the quantity sold dR R R dp dp = + = p+ y dy y p dy dy (3.1.5)
23
1/10/2003
p( y ) = a by
Then, revenue is given by the quadratic function R = py = ay by 2 and marginal revenue is dR = a 2by dy
(3.1.6)
(3.1.7)
(3.1.8)
Thus, the slope of the marginal revenue curve is twice as steep as that of the demand curve (see Figure 3.1.4).
p a Demand function p = a - by Revenue py = ay by2 a Marginal Revenue = a 2by
2b
a/b
y*
a/2b
Figure 3.1.4. Marginal revenue and demand curves for a linear demand function.
Profit is the difference between the revenue a firm receives and the cost that it incurs
( p, w) = py wn x n = pf ( x1 ,..., x n ) wn x n
n =1 n =1
(3.1.9)
24
1/10/2003
maximize ( p, w) = pf ( x1 ,..., x n ) wn x n
n =1
(3.2.1)
w f f = wn , or = n p x n x n
n = 1,..., N
(3.2.2)
This condition says that the value of the marginal product (price times marginal product p f xn ) for input n must equal the price of that input (wn). This tangency condition is illustrated in Figure 3.2.1.
y Isoprofit line = py wx slope = w/p
df = w/p dx
y*
/w
We can define a variant of the firms problem, where a firm strives to minimize its costs while producing a specified level of output (y0) minimize wn x n
n =1 N
(3.2.3)
(3.2.4)
25
1/10/2003
L f = wn =0 xn xn L = f y0 = 0
n = 1,..., N
(3.2.5)
(3.2.6)
wi MPi = = TRS ij w j MP j
(3.2.7)
That is, the technical rate of substitution equals the price ratio. The tangency condition for optimality in this case is illustrated in Figure 3.2.2.
x2
Isoquant y0 = f(x1,x2)
x2*
x1*
Figure 3.2.2. Cost minimization.
x1
(3.2.8)
The firms total cost is comprised of fixed (FC) and variable (VC) costs
TC ( y ) = FC + VC ( y )
(3.2.9)
26
1/10/2003
The firms average cost is the cost per unit to produce y units of output, or
AC =
TC ( y ) y
(3.2.10)
The firm's marginal cost is the cost of producing an additional unit of output
MC =
dTC dVC = dy dy
(3.2.11)
Example: How much water should a water industry firm sell (produce) and at what price? The firms problem can be defined as
maximize py TC ( y )
The first-order optimality conditions are
(3.2.12)
MR( y ) =
dp y + p = MC ( y ) dy
(3.2.13)
p = MC
as illustrated in Figure 3.2.3.
(3.2.14)
27
1/10/2003
Demand
MC
p = MC p*
AC
y*
Figure 3.2.3. Average cost (AC), and Marginal cost (MC) curves. The optimal level of production occurs where the demand intersects the MC curve.
However, if the firm is monopolistic, it is unlikely to take the output price as given, since the monopolistic firm recognizes its influence over market price. The firm is free to choose the price and level of output so as to maximize its profit. Since for a monopoly the price is not constant, but is a function of output, we have
MR =
dp y+p = MC dy
(3.2.15)
If the monopolistic firm chooses to maximize profit, then its chosen price and level of output will be pM and yM in order to set MR = MC. However, the firm knows that consumers are willing to pay a price p>MC (see Figure3.2.4). Since the MR curve lies below the demand curve, the monopolistic firm will produce (yM) which is less than the amount (yC) which a competitive firm would produce. That is, the price will be higher and the output lower for the monopolistic firm. Government regulatory commissions often have substantial power over the prices charged by public utilities. Without regulation, the firm will charge the price pM and produce yM. By setting a maximum price of pC, the commission can make the monopolist increase output, thus making price and output correspond more closely to what they would be if the industry were organized competitively. Commissions often set prices at the level at which it equals average cost.
28
1/10/2003
Demand MR
MC
AC pm p* p = MC
MR = MC
ym
y*
Figure 3.2.4. Optimal production level and price for a competitive firm and a monopolistic firm producing a good with a linear demand curve p(q) = a - bq.
29
1/10/2003
the following, the advantages and disadvantages of alternative production functions are summarized.
The following overview on production functions related to water use draws heavily on Dinar and Letey (1996), chapters 2 and 3, for the first three types of models.
Evapotranspiration and Transpiration Models
Evapotranspiration models are physical models that predict crop yield under varying conditions of salinity levels, soil moisture conditions, and irrigation strategies. They assume a linear yieldevapotranspiration relationship and are usually site-specific and very data intensive (see also Hanks and Hill 1980). A basic yield-seasonal evapotranspiration relationship is represented by:
Y / Ymax = 1 kc * (1 E / E max )
where
(3.3.2.1)
Y Ymax kc E Emax
= = = = =
actual yield (ton/ha) maximum dry matter yield (ton/ha) crop coefficient actual evapotranspiration (mm) maximum evapotranspiration (mm)
E = w + r + q o d
where
(3.3.2.2)
w r q o d
= = = = =
applied water (mm) rainfall (mm) change in soil water storage (mm) runoff drainage
30
1/10/2003
Transpiration models use a similar approach but measurement of transpiration is more difficult because it is difficult to separate it from evaporation. Although evapotranspiration and transpiration models capture important aspects of crop-water relationships, they have limited ability to capture the impacts of non-water inputs, and are of limited use for policy analysis.
Simulation Models
Within the category of simulation models, Dinar and Letey (1996) distinguish between holistic simulation models, that simulate in detail the production process of one crop and specific models, that focus on one production input or the subsystems associated with a particular production input. Detailed, data-intensive holistic models have been developed for most of the basic crops and a series of other agricultural production features (e.g., peanuts potatoes, maize, soybeans, and spring wheat). See also the CAMASE register, which currently includes more than 200 agroecosystem models or similar registers (CAMASE 1997). COTMOD, a model for cotton, for example, can be used to simulate the effects of various irrigation schedules, fertilizer application rates, and other management practices on cotton yield (Marani 1988). The relatively complicated data generation through field experiments and calibration procedures prevents the easy transferability of this model. Dinar and Letey (1996) specify a model, in which annual applied water, irrigation water salinity, published coefficients relating crop sensitivity to salinity, the relationship between yield and evapotranspiration, and the maximum evapotranspiration for the area are the input parameters. Outputs include crop yield, amount of drainage water, and salinity of the drainage water. It is assumed that all nonwater-related inputs are applied at the optimum level. Water is the only limiting factor in the production process.
Estimated Production Function Models
Estimated production functions are more flexible than other model types. However, specification and estimation procedures must comply with plant-water relationships: (1) plant yield increases as water quantity increases beyond some minimum value; (2) yield possibly decreases in a zone of excessive water applications; (3) yields decrease as the initial level of soil salinity in the root zone or the salt concentration in the applied irrigation water increase beyond some minimum value; and (4) the final level of root zone soil salinity decreases with increasing irrigation quantities (except for possible increases, where relatively insufficient water quantities have been applied) (Dinar and Letey 1996). In order to meet these requirements, polynomial functions have been applied in many production functions. Dinar and Letey (1996) present the following quadratic polynomial form in the case of three production inputs:
Y / Ymax = a0 + a1 w + a 2 s + a3u + a 4 w s + a5 w u + a6 s u + a7 w 2 + a8 s 2 + a9 u 2
(3.3.2.3) where
31
1/10/2003
Y Ymax w s u ai
= yield = maximum potential yield = water application to potential evapotranspiration, = salinity of the irrigation water, = irrigation uniformity, = estimated coefficients (i=1,..9)
The quadratic form implies that an increase in the level of one of the decision variables results in a constant change in the level of the dependent variable up to a point. Any further increase results in an opposite response (positive-diminishing marginal-productivity zone on the production surface), followed by a zone of negative marginal productivity.
Hybrid Production Function Models
Hybrid models, which draw on the strengths of each production function approach, may offer considerable advantages to the three types of approaches taken individually. As noted above, each of the three basic methodologies for production functions have some weaknesses. Particularly limiting may be the data requirements for any given approach. It is likely that, for some relationships embodied in the model, available experimental and non-experimental data, especially on the interrelationships of water use, resource degradation, and production, may be inadequate. Several reasons can account for this. Non-experimental data (cross-section and time series data) collected by government agencies or targeted surveys rarely can adequately measure or control for water and important environmental variables (like water table depth and soil and water quality). Generation of this type of data can also be difficult, expensive, and often impractical, if not impossible, to achieve. In many instances, however, data are not entirely absent. If data are relatively sparse, the available observations may not be adequate for statistical analysis but can be useful in calibrating generalized versions of simulation models. When important bio-physical and environmental variables in the study are inadequate or unavailable, simulation models can be used to generate pseudo-data. Pseudo-data are not true historical data, but rather are derived from process models replicating the real-world processes in computer experiments. Observations are generated by repeatedly solving the model for different initial values, and by parametrically varying input or output quantities and values. Simulation models are practical substitutes for complex biophysical experiments (or even non-experimental data), where it is often difficult to isolate the impacts of important policy, management, or environmental variables on output variables. In simulation models, the analyst can control institutional, technological and environmental factors, which is not possible with real-world experiments.
32
1/10/2003
water provides values of crop yield under various water application, irrigation technology, and irrigation water salinity. The production function can be used directly used in an optimization model to calculate crop yields with varying water application, salt concentration, and irrigation technology. The crop yield (production) function is specified as follows:
y= y max[a0 + a1 ( x / Emax )+ a2 ln(x / Emax )]
(3.3.3.1)
where
a0 = b0 + b1u + b2 c
a1 = b3 + b4 u + b5 c a2 = b6 + b7 u + b8 c
and
(3.3.3.2)
crop yield (metric tons [mt]/ha), maximum attainable yield (mt/ha) coefficients, coefficients, infiltrated water (mm) maximum evapotranspiration (mm) salt concentration in water application (dS/m). Use the factor 1.14 to convert dS/m to g/L, and Christiensen Uniformity Coefficient (CUC).
Uniformity (CUC) is used as a surrogate for both irrigation technology and irrigation management activities. The CUC value varies from approximately 50 for flood irrigation, to 70 for furrow irrigation, 80 for sprinklers, and 90 for drip irrigation, and also varies with management activities. By including explicit representation of technology, the choice of water application technology can be determined endogenously. The coefficients for the function in Eq. 3.3.3.1 as estimated by Rosegrant et al. (2000) are shown in Table 3.3.3.1. Using these coefficients in Table 3.3.3.2.
Table 3.3.3.1. Coefficients for the Production Function.
B5 B6 B7 B8 B9
33
1/10/2003
Coefficient Wheat a0 1.037233 a1 -0.35431 a2 0.937176 For the wheat produced in the Maipo basin in Chile, we have
x = x * E max *10,000m 2 / ha
8.00
(3.3.3.3)
I
Output, y (ton/ha)
6.00
II
III
4.00
2.00
0.00 0 5,000
Input, x (m3/ha)
10,000
15,000
20,000
Figure 3.3.3.1. Production function for wheat as a function of applied water (CUC=0.7, salinity = 0.7).
In Fig. 3.3.3.1, it is evident that a certain amount of water must be applied to the crop before any production can result. Output increases at an increasing rate as the first few units of input are added; it continues to increase at a decreasing rate at higher input levels (Law of Diminishing Returns). Average product is obtained by dividing the output by the input
34
1/10/2003
AP =
y x
(3.3.3.4)
and it measures the efficiency of the input used in the production. Marginal product is the change in the output resulting from a unit increment in input, that is
MP = a a dy = Ymax ( 1 + 2 ) dx E max x
(3.3.3.5)
I
0.002 0.002 0.001 0.001 0.000 0 5,000
II
III
AP, MP
AP MP
10,000
15,000
20,000
Input, x (m3/ha)
The production function can be broken into three regions, depending on the efficiency of resource use:
Region I
If the product has value, input use should be increased until Region II is reached, since the physical efficiency of the input increases throughout Region I. It is not reasonable to cease using the input while efficiency is increasing.
Region II
Region II defines the area of economic relevance and optimal input use must be in this range. The exact level of production and resource use depend on the input and output prices.
Region III
35
1/10/2003
Even if the input is free, it will not be used in this stage, since maximum output occurs at the boundary of Region II and further inputs simply decrease output. Table 3.3.3.3 includes the costs of production for this example. Fixed costs, FC, are $100/ha and include ground preparation and other costs. Variable cost, VC, is computed by multiplying the input, x, by the unit price of the input, w ($0.05/m3 in this example)
VC = wx
(3.3.3.6)
The shape of the VC curve depends on the shape of the production function (see Fig. 3.3.3.3). Total cost, TC, is simply the sum of FC and VC. Average costs (AC) follow in the same way that average production does, they are the costs divided by the amount of the output AC = VC wx = y y (3.3.3.7)
Average variable cost (AC) is inversely related to the average product, attaining a minimum when AP is at a maximum. When AC is decreasing, the efficiency of the input is increasing and efficiency is maximum when AC is minimum. Marginal cost (MC) is the change in the cost per unit of input (see Fig. 3.3.3.4)
MC = dVC w = dy dy dx
(3.3.3.8)
This is the slope of the cost curve cost and its value is the cost of producing an additional unit of output.
36
1/10/2003
1,000 FC 800
Cost ($/ha)
VC TC
II
III
1000 800
Cost/Output
I
AC MC
II
III
Output, y (ton/ha)
Figure 3.3.3.4. Average and marginal costs and the point where p = MC.
To determine the most profitable level of input, or the most profitable level of output, profit
= py wx
(3.3.3.9)
is maximized, where w is the price of the produced good (wheat in this example and p = $230/mt). The problem is to find the level of x which maximizes this function. The derivative with respect to input must be set equal to zero
37
1/10/2003
d dy = p w=0 dx dx
We can rearrange this expression to yield
(3.3.3.10)
dy w = dx p
or
p= w dy dx
(3.3.3.11)
(3.3.3.12)
resulting in
p = MC
This condition is shown in Fig. 3.3.3.4.
800 600
Profit ($)
(3.3.3.13)
38
1/10/2003
40
1/10/2003
D W MC
S U Price T V R
AC
Quantity
Figure 3.5.1. Average cost (AC), and Marginal cost (MC) curves. The optimal level of production occurs where the demand intersects the MC curve.
41
1/10/2003
This section is largely adapted from Hutchens and Mann1. Figures 3.6.1 3.6.4 illustrate the roles of demand and supply functions, in the theoretical derivation of consumers' and producers' surpluses, and show the proportioning of each as a result of market interaction. Figure 3.6.1 presents a demand curve and the total utility derived by consumers in the consumption of quantity x0. The negative slope of the demand curve is derived from the definition of demand, which states that for any commodity that can be purchased in a market, the quantity demanded in a given period of time varies inversely with the price, other things equal. The demand curve consists of the locus of points of marginal utility associated with each incremental unit of a commodity consumed. Consequently, total utility is the integral represented by the area under the demand curve. The area under the demand curve within the points O, p1, A, and x0 represents the maximum amount consumers would be willing to pay for the consumption of x0 units of the commodity rather than go without it. This maximum willingness to pay reflects the total utility or benefit to the consumer. However, resources were expended to produce that output and the value of those expended resources must be deducted from the total benefit to determine the net benefit. Figure 22 illustrates the cost of resources (factors of production) required to produce x0. The supply curve represents the locus of marginal cost associated with producing each increment of commodity x. The integral of that function, represented by the area under the supply curve delineated by points O, p2, A, and x0, is the total value of the resources required to produce x0. This cost represents the minimum amount that the producer will accept for x0 units and, therefore, the minimum amount that the consumer must pay.
Price, p p1
A Total Utility
Demand
x0
Output, y
Figure 3.6.1. Net-benefits for a linear demand function and constant marginal costs.
1
Hutchens, A.O., and P.C. Mann , Review of Water Pricing Policies, Institutions and Practices in Central Asia, Environmental Policy and Technology Project, US Agency for International Development, Almaty, Kazakhstan, 1998.
42
1/10/2003
Price, p
Supply A
p2
Figure 3.6.2. Marginal Opportunity Cost Curve for a constant marginal costs.
Figure 3.6.3 presents the results of superimposing Figure 3.6.2 onto Figure 3.6.1. The total utility or benefit illustrated in Figure 3.6.1 minus the total factor cost in Figure 3.6.2 yields the total surplus net of resource costs delineated by p2, p2, A. This, then, represents the difference between the maximum the consumer would be willing to pay rather than go without and the minimum he must pay in order to cover costs of production. It can also be viewed as the total net benefit to society. The crucial issue of how this surplus or net benefit is shared or proportioned between producers and consumers is determined by the interaction of supply and demand in the market to determine the market price, which is illustrated in Figure 3.6.4. The area O, p0, A, x0, represents the amount that the consumer actually pays and, also, the amount that the producer actually receives. Therefore, the price line p0, A, divides the total surplus into the amount the consumer would have been willing to pay, but did not have to, (consumers' surplus) and the amount in excess of what the producer would have been willing to accept, but was able to realize more (producers' surplus). Total costs shared in proportion to producers' and consumers' surpluses will be shared in proportion to benefits received, which satisfies the economic equity criterion. For most commodities, this would be automatically taken care of if there were an open competitive market; however, water and the necessary infrastructure to control it tend to exhibit some common property inflexibility and irreversibility characteristics that hinder a purely competitive market reallocation of water. Output from the Egyptian Agricultural Sector Model (EASM) was used to derive estimates of consumers' and producers' surpluses under both financial and economic (free market) prices (Huchens and Mann, 1998). A run of EASM89 model derived the following estimates of producers' and consumers' surpluses:
43
1/10/2003
Base Case (1986) Consumers' surplus Producers' surplus Total surplus 10067 8236 18303 55 45 100%
This shows that under 1986 financial price conditions, i.e., actual price controls and subsidies, consumers realized 55% and producers 45% of the "surplus value" in the agricultural sector. Under free market conditions, i.e., elimination of price, area and procurement controls, consumption subsidies, input subsidies and trade barriers, the proportions were estimated to be 32% consumers' surplus and 68% producers' surplus. The point to be realized from this is that, under free market conditions where farmers are not restricted by production quotas and administratively set prices, they will realize financial benefits that will enable him to pay for water services. Price, p p1
p2
Figure 3.6.3. Maximum net-benefits for linear demand and constant marginal costs.
44
1/10/2003
p2
Output, y
Figure 3.6.4. Maximum net-benefits for linear demand and constant marginal costs.
3.7 Externalities
The exclusivity of property rights is often violated, e.g., when a decision maker does not bear all of the consequences of a decision. Consider an example where a factory is producing a product and discharging waste to a nearby river. A hotel downstream of the factory uses the river for recreation. If there are different owners for the factory and the hotel, then an efficient use of the water in the river is not likely to occur. That is, the factory owner may not bear the cost of reducing business at the hotel as a result of the production decisions and resulting effluent discharge. The factory is likely to discharge too much effluent for a socially optimal solution. An externality exists whenever the welfare of some agent (firm or consumer) depends on its own activities and the activities of some other (external) agent as well. In the above example, the additional cost to the hotel as a result of the factory discharge is an externality.
45
1/10/2003
p, price
p social p privat e
y social y priv at e Socially opt imal product ion level, Maximum net -benef it s
46
1/10/2003
12 10
Output, y (mt/ha)
Y1 (wheat) Y2 (corn)
Figure 3.8.1. Production functions for wheat and corn. Table 3.8.1. Production Functions for Wheat and Corn. Production functions for wheat and corn Wheat Water x y1 (m3/ha) (mt/ha)
0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.22 2.08 3.27 4.10 4.70 5.14 5.46 5.70 5.87 5.98 6.04 6.07 6.06 6.02 5.96 5.88 5.77 0 883 1765 2648 3530 5295 7060 8825 10590 12355 14120 15885 17650 19415 21180 22945 24710 26475 28240 30005 31770
Water x (m3/ha)
0 536 1071 1607 2142 3213 4284 5355 6426 7497 8568 9639 10710 11781 12852 13923 14994 16065 17136 18207 19278
Corn y2 (mt/ha)
0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.21 3.87 5.60 6.83 7.74 8.43 8.96 9.37 9.68 9.91 10.08 10.19 10.26 10.28 10.27 10.23 10.17
47
1/10/2003
10 9 Corn (mt/ha) 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 0 1
Production possibilities curve for x - 10,000: slope = -dy 2/dy 1 Isorevenue line: slope = -p 1/p 2= -160/230
3 Wheat (mt/ha)
Figure 3.8.2. Production possibilities curve for wheat and corn with input of 10,000 m3/ha of water. Now, lets consider the problem of the farmer in this case. The decision to be made is how to r allocate the scarce resources, x = ( x1 ,..., x J ) , to the production of various combinations of r outputs, y = ( y1 ,..., y I ) . The objective is to maximize the farm income while satisfying the constraints of the production function. In general, we can write this problem as (Willis and Finney, 2000)
(3.8.1)
(3.8.2)
48
1/10/2003
U L f = = 0, x j x j x j U L f = = 0, yi yi yi r r L = f ( y, x ) = 0
j = 1,..., J i = 1,..., I
(3.8.3)
Now, if the second of these equations is written for two products i and k, we have U f =0 yi yi U f =0 y k y k or
(3.8.4)
U U
yi y k
f = f
yi y k
(3.8.5)
f f dyi + dy k = 0 yi y k
or
f f yi y k = dy k dyi
(3.8.6)
(3.8.7)
so
U U
yi y k
dy k = MRS i, k dyi
(3.8.8)
where MRSi,k is the marginal rate of substitution of product i for product k which is the slope of the production possibilities curve, and U is the marginal benefit from producing an yi additional unit of product i, that it, its price pi. Total revenue is the value of the output produced:
TR = p1 y1 + p 2 y 2
(3.8.9)
For various given values of total revenue (TR) this relationship is a straight line (isorevenue line). The distance of the isorevenue line from the origin is determined by the value of TR. As
Notes on Economics McKinney
49
1/10/2003
TR increases the line moves away from the origin. The slop of the isorevenue line is determined by the prices of the outputs.
Total costs are constant for all combinations of outputs on the production possibility curve. Profits will be maximized if the output combinations with the maximum TR is selected. This will be achieved at the point where the slope of the isorevenue line and the production possibility curve coincide. Consider the case where maximize p1 y1 + p 2 y 2 + FC subject to f ( x, y1 , y 2 ) = 0 The optimality conditions are
y y L f = p1 1 + p 2 2 =0 x x x x L f = p1 =0 y1 y1 L f = p2 =0 y 2 y 2 L = f ( x, y1 , y 2 ) = 0
(3.8.10)
(3.8.11)
(3.8.12)
(3.8.13)
or
f f
y1 y 2
dy 2 dy1
(3.8.14)
so
50
1/10/2003
p1 dy = 2 = MRS1,2 p2 dy1
(3.8.15)
Thus, we see from these results that the point of optimal production is where a line with slope equal to the ratio of the prices of the outputs is equal to the slope of the production possibilities curve. This is illustrated in Figure 3.8.2 for our example of wheat and corn production. The prices are p1 = $230/mt (wheat) and p2 = $160/mt (corn). The resulting outputs are 3.3 mt of wheat (which uses 4284 m3/ha of water) and 4.2 mt/ha of corn (which uses 5606 m3/ha of water). The resulting total revenue is $1450/ha.
51
1/10/2003
2. Reform of public management of water resource systems: (a) modification of water distribution methods, (b) implementation of water pricing policies, and (c) reform of water management bureaucracies. 3. Communal water resource system management which involve water users more directly in both the process of system management and improvement. 4. Establishment of tradable property rights in water and development of markets in these rights. Market allocation of resources may be efficient given well-defined and nonattenuated (completely specified, exclusive, transferable, and enforceable) initial property rights allocation and low transaction costs. Options 1 - 3 have been widely used by international lending institutions and national governments. Option 4 is somewhat new and is explored below.
52
1/10/2003
4. quality of the delivered water; 5. place of diversion; and 6. place of application. Changes in any of these characteristics will likely affect other water users in the basin or system. An efficient water rights structure should include:
Universality: specified.
Exclusivity: Benefits and costs accrued as a result of owning and using the rights accrue to the owner (and only the owner). This property of water rights is often violated, e.g., when a user does not bear all of the costs of a water allocation, creating an externality that is not paid for by the user. An externality may exist whenever the welfare of some user depends on its own activities and the activities of some other user(s) as well. Transferability: The transfer of rights from one user to another must be entirely voluntary. The inability to transfer the rights would prevent the owner of the right from recognizing the true opportunity cost of the water, i.e., the value that another person may place on it. Enforceability: Right owners must be secure from involuntary seizure of their rights or encroachment on their rights.
Usually, systems for water rights (implicit or explicit) fall into one of several categories (Howe, 1996):
Non-tradable permits for water from undeveloped (natural) supplies Non-tradable permits or rights are typically specified by laws or regulations, they are for specific or defined periods and they are not tradable. Problems associated with this type of arrangement include the fact that this method of water allocation does not consider the economic efficiency or equity of the use, and allocations may be inflexible and unresponsive to changes in social values. Contracts for water from developed supplies Developed supplies usually provide storage and distribution facilities and water is allocated to customers by contracts (as opposed to non-tradable permits where water is distributed by water right). Contracted water supply is usually for a specific use. Problems associated with this type of arrangement include the fact that the economic efficiency or equity of the water use is not considered.
In many cases, water demand is estimated from the projected requirement or need for water, that is, the farmer's ability to put water to use (Gardner, 1983). This method of demand estimation results in a maximization of physical yield rather than profit or social benefits. This can lead to the development of new water supplies rather than using economic incentives and market mechanisms to allocate water to its best uses. Systems of this type are common in the states of California (Gardner, 1983) and Texas (TWDB, 1997).
Notes on Economics McKinney
53
1/10/2003
In other cases, a fixed cost per hectare of crop is charged for water. This violates economic principles since the price is not related to the quantity of water applied or used, and there is little incentive to conserve water. This type of system is often justified by the difficulty and expense of determining how much water is delivered to a farm. 4.2.1 Riparian water rights systems Under riparian water rights systems, the owner of land bordering a stream or lake has the right to take water for use on the land. The right to use the water exists solely because of the relation of the land to the water and resides in the ownership of the land. The first riparian user acquires no priority over those who may use the stream at a later date; the rights of upstream and downstream users are viewed as being coequal (Hirshleifer et al., 1960). Under riparian systems, the owners of lands bordering water bodies may have "reasonable use" of the waters, provided that the water is returned undiminished in quality or quantity (Howe et al., 1986). That is, the withdrawal must be reasonable with respect to the requirements of the other riparians. The determination of what constitutes reasonable use is left to the courts. A riparian right subject to the reasonable use doctrine has no guaranty to a definite quantity of water. Under the riparian system, the transfer of water rights between competing uses by a market system is severely hampered (Hirshleifer et al., 1960). Riparian rights are most appropriate for humid regions. Where water is truly scarce and/or where water quality problems are important, the riparian doctrine simply doesn't work (Howe, 1996). 4.2.2 Appropriative water rights systems The doctrine of appropriation gives no preference to the use of water by riparian landowners. Appropriative (or prior) systems tend to exist in areas of water scarcity where users are located away from water bodies. Scarcity means that each succeeding appropriation results in fewer or less valuable resources available for other users. Scarce resources come to be appropriated in their natural state according to the principles of priority of right and beneficial use (Cuzan, 1983). The earliest water right on a given watercourse has preference over later users, "first in time means first in right." Once the appropriation is granted, it becomes senior to subsequent appropriations. In times of shortage senior or older rights have precedence over junior or newer rights. That is, senior rights have first call on available water. Appropriative rights are a right to use, not a right to own, and the beneficial use of the water is required. Beneficial use has been described as use of water in a useful industry or to supply a well-recognized want (Tregarthen, 1983). In many cases, the owner of an appropriation may lose the right as a result of failure to put it to beneficial use.
54
1/10/2003
The two rules of appropriative water rights, priority and beneficial use, result in the separation of rights to water from the rights to land. Persons can mobilize capital to build water supply works and transport water to wherever it is most productively used (Cuzan, 1983). Appropriative rights may be a system in which rights are clearly defined and transferable subject to the stipulation of "no injury" (Tregarthen, 1983). It is the severability of appropriative rights that causes them to be transferable. Often under appropriative rights systems water is owned by the public and appropriators are granted the right to use the water but ownership of the resource remains with the state (Cuzan, 1983). Often this state expropriation of water rights leads to a system of controls which makes it difficult for water to be transferred privately through sales. These systems can generate pressure for monumental water schemes by governmental agencies which subsidize low-value water uses. Economic efficiency requires that the marginal value of water used be equal in each use, net of transport costs, and assuming that marginal values include both private and social benefits and costs (Gardner, 1983; Howe et al., 1986). Assuming that water is homogeneous, i.e., no quality variations, water prices should vary among users only by the cost of moving it from one user to another (Hirshleifer, et al., 1960). Two main types appropriative rights systems are common: priority rights and proportional rights systems
Priority rights
Priority rights operate on the doctrine of "first in time, first in right." If the flow in a river is sufficient to provide only x% of the water appropriated, then a call for water from the senior water rights holders can shut off diversions to the lowest (100 - x)% priority rights holders. Senior water rights holders have less risk than junior rights holders, but senior rights holders may place a lower value on the last unit of water than junior rights holders. In this case, a trade should occur, the senior rights holder selling water rights to junior rights holders, thus reducing the risk to the junior appropriators (Tregarthen, 1983). Priority rights allow different degrees of water supply reliability to be purchased, but the heterogeneous nature of the rights makes it difficult to organize markets.
Proportional rights
A proportional rights system shares available water among users according to a set of percentages determined by the number of rights owned, e.g., if a user owns 10 rights out of 100, then the owner is entitled to 10% of available water. Proportional rights systems require the purchase of more shares to reach any given level of assurance of water supply. The homogeneity of proportional rights makes it much easier to create markets than under the priority system.
55
1/10/2003
S = 1000
S1=1000 R1*S1 =500 S2=500 R2*S2=250 S3=250 R3*S3=125
User 1
User 2
User 3
C3=(1-R3)*S3=125 B3(S3)=$250
Now consider that User 1 decides to sell his/her entire diverted amount to another user outside the basin for $1.1 per unit. The net result is that User 1 is no better off than before, but Users 2 and 3 have been left without any water to divert and there is an overall net loss for the basin of $650
56
1/10/2003
S = 1000
S1=1000 R1*S1 =0 S2=0 R2*S2=0 S3=0 R3*S3=0
User 1
User 2
User 3
C1=(1-R1)*S1=1000 B1(S1)=$1100
C2=(1-R2)*S2=0 B2(S2)=$0
C3=(1-R3)*S3=0 B3(S3)=$0
An appropriator (user) may own a right to divert a given quantity of water but the user can only transfer this right according to the amount of water consumed. Determining the consumptive use of water and the amount of water that returns to the river or canal can be difficult and costly. Consider again the above example, but now User 1 decides to only sell the amount of his/her previous consumptive use (500 units) for a price of $1.1 per unit. In this case the downstream users continue to receive their water and may divert as before.
S
R1*S1 =0 S2=500 R2*S2=250 S3=250 R3*S3=125
S = 1000
S1=500
User 1
User 2
User 3
C3=(1-R3)*S3=125 B3(S3)=$250
Several authors have suggested that it is better to define water rights according to the consumptive use system rather than the diversion rights system. Using the consumptive rights system the ownership of the right is clear, transfers do not require litigation, the incentive to
57
1/10/2003
conserve water exists, and this conservation leads to water that can be sold to downstream users (Tregarthen, 1983). However, others have suggested that the diversionary rights system is preferable (Rosegrant et al. 1995). The definition of the tradable portion of a water right depends on the method of handling return flows. In California, the tradable portion is limited to consumptive use (consumptive right) with protection of third-party rights to return flows. This method increases transaction costs because of the difficulty in measuring consumptive use and return flows. Consumptive use is defined to be the actual evapotranspiration of crops plus any water lost to deep percolation. Thus, the water available to trade includes water that would have been consumptively used and water that would be irretrievably lost to beneficial use. In Chile and Mexico, rights are proportional to streamflow (diversionary right) and rights to return flow are retained by the water authority. Return flows are made available to users at no charge, but no rights are assigned to these flows. Changes in return flows due to water rights trades are not actionable. This method has been demonstrated to reduce transaction costs. So the tradable water is the full diversion right which is proportional to stream flow. What is the most appropriate method in developing countries? The transaction costs of enforcing consumptive rights increase but they protect third-parties against adverse impacts from water trades. If the lost benefits from not trading exceed the costs of adverse impact from lost return flows, then diversionary rights system is preferred. In general, the diversionary rights system will be preferred in developing countries so as to prevent high transaction costs, thus preventing the development of markets. 4.3.2 Tradable water rights markets Tradable water rights are rights to use water that can be transferred all or in part, separately from the transfer of land (Rosegrant et al., 1996). Tradable water rights may be permanent, long-term, or even short-term. Tradable water rights markets may be capable of allocating water more effectively than other more restrictive and centrally controlled systems. Markets can operate most efficiently when the commodity being allocated is homogeneous (Howe et al., 1986). Heterogeneity of uses leads to difficulty in organizing a market, transmitting information to users, and matching sellers and buyers. Rights to water resources already exist in most countries (a) by custom, or (b) by law and regulation. Establishing tradable rights is a matter of reforming existing systems.
Characteristics of markets
Several desirable characteristics for water allocation mechanisms (regional, river basin or irrigation district level) have been described by Howe (Howe et al., 1986; Howe, 1996):
Water can be shifted from use to use and place to place as climate, demographics, and economic conditions change over time. Short-term (responding to climatic factors) and longNotes on Economics McKinney
58
1/10/2003
term (responding to demographic and economic factors) flexibility is necessary. It is important to note that not all water must be subject to reallocation, only a tradable margin must exist within each water-using area that is subject to low cost reallocation and this volume can be a relatively small part of the regional supply (Howe et al., 1986). Flexibility allows equating the marginal values in the water's various uses (Howe et al., 1986; Gisser and Johnson, 1983).
Water users must be assured of continued use or they will not invest in and maintain the water resource system. This encourages long-term investments that generate positive net benefits. In a market system, no one can be forced to sell.
Valuation of water at its opportunity cost, the maximum value of outputs that could have been produced had inputs not been used to produce the item in question (Field, 1994), provides incentives for users to shift from inefficient water uses and methods to more highly valued, less water-intensive uses and methods. Opportunity cost pricing can be implemented through the establishment of tradable water rights and development of markets in these rights (Rosegrant et al., 1996). Water is often a scarce input to production and it is frequently priced well below its value in use (Gardner, 1983). Historically, the price of water, at most, has reflected the costs of its capture and distribution. The control of low priced water can provide access to enormous profits in many cases. A perpetual contract for the supply of water at a fixed price may fail to reflect changing opportunity costs involved in continued use. Water is one input to agricultural production, other inputs include land, capital, energy, chemicals, and labor. If production is to be profitable, all inputs used must be valued at least at their opportunity costs. A price for water established in a market and the ability to sell water (transfer or trade water rights) recognizes the real opportunity costs of the water in the use being considered. This prevents the acceptance of water uses that are less valuable than alternative uses. It is desirable to maximize the scope of a water rights market so that transactions take place over as wide a geographical area and among as wide a variety of users as possible, subject to transaction cost limitations.
Differentiated risk-bearing
While old methods are familiar even if they are outmoded, new methods may increase uncertainty, even while they promise advantages. Predictability of the outcome of the transfer process is necessary to ensure that long-term investments that generate positive net benefits are encouraged.
59
1/10/2003
Fairness to participants
Water users should not impose uncompensated costs (externalities) on other parties. Externalities occur whenever withdrawal, consumption, or quality changes by one user affect other water users. Parties giving up water should be compensated and those injured by changes in allocations should be compensated. Market transactions should guarantee fairness since no person will sell if they will not be made better off.
Some values may be of little concern to individual water users and they may not be adequately reflected in the market exchange and these must be protected by social oversight, e.g., water quality and instream flows (Howe, 1996). Protection of public values will ensure that allocations will achieve the highest aggregate benefit level.
Benefits of tradable water rights markets
The benefits from establishing tradable water rights markets include (Rosegrant and Binswanger, 1994; Rosegrant et al., 1996):
Empowerment of water users by requiring their consent to any reallocation of water and compensation for any water transferred; Security of tenure of water rights to the water users, which encourages investment in system efficiency improvements;
Induces users to consider the full opportunity cost of water, including its value in alternative uses, providing incentives to efficiently use water and gain additional income through the sale of saved water; Provide incentives for users to take account of external costs imposed by their water use, reducing resource and environmental degradation;
Formalizes existing rights to water; and Provides maximum flexibility in responding to changes in crop prices and water values. Constraints of tradable water rights markets
Constraints to establishing tradable water rights markets leading to high transaction costs include (Rosegrant and Binswanger, 1994; Rosegrant et al., 1996):
The unique physical, technological and economic characteristics of water resources systems pose problems;
60
1/10/2003
The variable nature of water flow makes achieving necessary certainty; and
Return flows from water use can generate environmental degradation. Multiple reuse of water creates the likelihood of significant externalities imposed on third parties. Policy considerations of tradable water rights markets
Policy considerations in developing tradable water rights markets include (Rosegrant et al., 1996):
Definition of a method of initial allocation of water rights. This can be based on, among other things, historic water use (Chile and Mexico), fully appropriated existing rights (California); Type of rights, prior or proportional appropriative rights: Prior rights (California), Proportional (Chile and Mexico); Consumptive use or diversionary treatment of return flows; Indirect economic effects; Environmental protection; Water user associations; Infrastructure; Public and private institutions; and Regulations: Excessive regulation leads to high transaction costs, inadequate regulation leads to third-party costs or environmental degradation
4.3.3 Modeling tradable water rights markets There are two fundamental strategies for dealing with water scarcity in river basins, supply management and demand management; the former involves activities to locate, develop, and exploit new sources of water, and the latter addresses the incentives and mechanisms that promote water conservation and efficient use of water (Rosegrant et al., 2000). Markets in tradable water rights can reduce information costs; increase farmer acceptance and participation; empower water users; and provide security and incentives for investments and for internalizing the external costs of water uses. Market allocation can provide flexibility in response to water demands, permitting the selling and purchasing of water across sectors, across districts, and across time by opening opportunities for exchange where they are needed. The outcomes of the exchange process reflect the water scarcity condition in the area with water flowing to the uses where its marginal value is highest (Rosegrant and Binswanger 1994; Rosegrant 1997). Markets also provide the foundation for water leasing and option contracts, which can quickly mitigate acute, short-term urban water shortages while maintaining the agricultural production base (Michelsen and Young 1993). Water trading in a basin is constrained by the hydrologic balance in the river basin network; water may be traded taking account of physical and technical constraints of the various users, reflecting their relative profitability in trading prices; water trades reflect water scarcity in
61
1/10/2003
the basin that is influenced by both basin inflows and the water use plans of the users (Rosegrant et al., 2000). The price that a water user would be willing to pay to acquire additional water must be determined for each user. This can be achieved by determining a shadow price water withdrawal relationship can determined for each user. For this, a model must be run with varying water rights for each user as inputs and shadow prices or marginal values as output derived from the water balance equations (each user has a water balance equation in the model). If necessary, these shadow prices can be averaged over all uses for each user to obtain one shadow price for each water supply level for user. The Figure below shows the result of this for the problem of Exercise 1 below.
160 Shadow Price ($/unit) 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 Water Right (unit)
2 = -10.3S2 + 150.88
User2 User3
3 = -1.310S3 + 18.276
In the model of water trading, the objective is to maximize the combined benefits of all the users
Maximize B = Bi = ( ai Si bi Si2 + xi , j wtp j x j ,i wtpi )
i i j j
(4.3.3.1)
where
B Bi Si wtpi xi,j
Total benefit to all water users; Benefit to User i, a quadratic benefit function is assumed here with coefficients ai and bi; Water withdrawal by user i; Water trading price for user i; Water sold by user i to user j;
62
1/10/2003
Si wrighti xi , j + x j ,i
j j
(4.3.3.2)
where wright is water allocated to a user under prescribed water rights. Each user has shadow price for water which is a linear function of the amount of water demanded
wtpi = ami + bmi Si
(4.3.3.3)
(4.3.3.4)
Trades are unidirectional, that is, if a user buys water from another user, then they can not sell water to the same user
xi , j * x j , i = 0
(4.3.3.5)
Exercises
1. You are working with the manager of an irrigation facility who is interested in installing a more efficient pumping system. The proposed system costs $15,000 and you project that it will reduce the annual utility costs by $2,000. After five years, you expect to upgrade the system for $4,000. This upgrade is expected to further reduce utility costs by $1,000 annually. The annual effective interest rate is 7% and the life of the system, after upgrade is 50 years. What is the Present Value of the investment in the system? 2. You have a small excavation firm and wish to purchase a small backhoe. Based on your research, you need to have $54,000 to purchase one used. If your cost of capital is 0.50%/month and you want to recover your capital (on a Present Worth basis) in 20 months, how much profit must this backhoe generate each month. 3. (after North, 1985, Exercise 5.8) A flood control district can construct a number of alternative control works to alleviate the flood pattern in that area. These alternatives include dam A, dam B, and a levee system C. The levee system can be built alone or in combination with dam A or B. Both dams can not be built together but either one can function alone. The lofe of each dam is 80 years and the life of the levee system is 60 years. The cost of capital is 6 percent. Information on total investment, operation and maintenance costs, and average annual flood damage is given below. What form of flood control would be the most economical?
63
1/10/2003
Table. Flood Control Project data Total Investment Annual Operation (million $) and Maintainence (thous. $) 6.2 93 5.3 89 6.7 110 0 0
4. (after Mays & Chung, 1992, Exercise 2.2.2) Four alternative projects can be used for developing a water supply for a community for the next 40 years. Use the incremental benefitcost method to compare and select an alternative. Use a 6% interest rate. Years 0 10 20 30 0-10 10-20 20-30 30-40 Project A Project B Project C Construction cost ($) 40,000,000 30,000,000 20,000,000 Project D
10,000,000
20,000,000
Operation and Maintenance Cost ($) 100,000 110,000 120,000 120,000 110,000 130,000 140,000 120,000 140,000 160,000 140,000 150,000
5. (after James and Lee, 1971, Problem 2.6) The three alternatives described below are available for supplying a community water supply for the next 50 years when all economic lives as well as the period of analysis terminates.
Construction cost Year 0 Year 20 Year 35 O&M cost Year 1-20 Year 21-35 Year 36-50
Using $2,500,000 in benefits each year for each project, and a 4.5% discount rate where applicable, compare the projects using:
64
1/10/2003
a. The present-worth method The present-worth method selects the project with the largest present worth of the discounted sum of benefits minus the costs over its life
Pw = Bt Ct t t =1 (1+i )
T
where Ct is the cost and Bt is the benefit in year t, T is the period of analysis, and i is the discount rate. b. The rate-of-return method The rate-of-return is the discount rate at which the present worth as defined above equals zero as found by trial and error. c. The benefit-cost ratio method The benefit-cost ratio PWb/PWc is the present worth of the benefits PWb divided by the present worth of the costs PWc. Annual values can be used with out altering the ratio.
PWb =
T
Bt
t
t =1 (1+i )
and
PWc =
Ct
t =1(1+i )
d. The annual-cost method The annual-cost method converts all benefits and costs into equivalent uniform annual figures.
6. (after Thuesen et al., 1977, Problem 10.20) The federal government is planning a hydroelectric project for a river basin. In additionto the production of electric power, this project will provide flood control, irrigation, and recreation benefits. The estimated benefits and costs that are expected to be derived from the three alternatives under consideration are listed below:
Construction cost Project A Project B Project C Initial cost $25,000,000 $35,000,000 $50,000,000 Annual benefits and costs Power sales $1,000,000 $1,200,000 $1,800,000 Flood control savings 250,000 350,000 500,000 Irrigation benefits 350,000 450,000 600,000 Recreation benefits 100,000 200,000 350,000 O&M costs 200,000 250,000 350,000
65
1/10/2003
The interest rate is 5% and the life of each of the projects is estimated to be 50 years. a. Using the incremental benefit-cost method, determine which project should be selected. b. Calculate the benefit cost ratio for each alternative. Is the best alternative selected if the alternative with the maximum benefit cost ratio is chosen? c. If the interest rate is 8%, what alternative would be chosen?
7. (After D. P. Loucks, Course Notes, Engineering Economics, Cornell University.) Three mutually exclusive water resources projects, A, B, and C, are under consideration. Each project has a fixed initial cost (FCA, FCB, and FCC). Their (unequal) useful lives are LA, LB, and LC, and during each year y of those lives they generate annual benefits of BAy, BBy, and BCy, and costs of CAy, CBy, and CCy. Assume that an appropriate interest rate, r, has already been determined for this analysis. Show how you would calculate each projects equivalent end-ofyear annual benefits and costs, and based on these, their benefit-cost ratios. 8. Find the optimal levels of two goods purchased by a consumer with a utility function
u ( x1 , x 2 ) = x11.5 x 2
where qi is the yield in hectares of crop i, ai, bi, and ci are parameters of the production functionfor crop i, and xi is the amount of water (m3) applied to crop i. The unit cost of water is w; the unit market price of each crop is pi. Develop a model, based on the theory of the firm, to determine the optimal water allocation to each crop. What is the demand function for water assuming the production function is a concave function of xi (i.e., ci < 0).
10. (After Mays and Tung, 1992, Problem 2.4.1; 2.4.4; 2.4.5)
(1) For the production process in the following Table, determine and plot the total, average, and marginal product curves for nitrogen fertilizer given that water is fixed at x1 = 7 inches/acre. (2) Determine and plot the cost curves for the production process. Assume that water is fixed at 7 inches per acre. Use input prices of $2.50 per pound of nitrogen fertilizer and $10 per acre-
66
1/10/2003
inch of water. Plot average fixed cost (AFC), average variable cost (AVC), average total cost (ATC), and marginal cost (MC) on one plot. (3) Determine the profit for various levels of output for the production process. Assume that corn sells for $1.49 per bushel, and input prices are the same as in Part (2) and that irrigation water is fixed at 7 inches per acre. How much corn should be produced? How much nitrogen fertilizer is used in this production. What it the value of total product that maximizes profit?.
Table. Production Schedule of the Relationship Between Irrigation Water, Fertilizer & Yield (bushels per acre) of corn.
x1* x2**
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 120 130
0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
1 0.0 1.8 5.0 9.0 13.2 17.0 19.8 21.0 20.0 16.2 9.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
2 0.0 5.0 12.8 22.2 32.0 41.0 48.0 51.8 51.2 45.0 32.0 11.0 0.0 0.0
3 0.0 9.0 22.2 37.8 54.0 69.0 81.0 88.2 88.0 81.0 63.0 33.0 0.0 0.0
4 0.0 13.2 32.0 54.0 76.8 98.0 115.2 126.0 128.0 118.8 96.0 57.2 0.0 0.0
5 0.0 17.0 41.0 69.0 98.0 125.0 147.0 161.0 164.0 153.0 125.0 77.0 6.0 0.0
6 0.0 19.8 48.0 81.0 115.2 147.0 172.8 189.0 192.0 178.2 144.0 85.8 0.0 0.0
7 0.0 21.0 51.8 88.2 126.0 161.0 189.0 205.8 207.2 189.0 147.0 77.0 0.0 0.0
8 0.0 20.0 51.2 88.0 128.0 164.0 192.0 207.2 204.8 180.0 128.0 44.0 0.0 0.0
9 0.0 16.2 45.0 81.0 118.8 153.0 178.2 189.0 180.0 145.8 81.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
10 0.0 9.0 32.0 63.0 96.0 125.0 144.0 147.0 128.0 81.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
11 0.0 0.0 11.0 33.0 57.2 77.0 85.8 77.0 44.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
12 13 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 6.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
(1) Calculate the farmers willingness-to-pay for a quantity of water q. (2) If the cost of delivering a quantity of water q is C(q) = cq, c > 0, how much water should a public agency supply to maximize willingness-to-pay minus cost? (3) If the local water district is owned and operated by a private firm whose objective is to maximize profit, how much water would they supply and how much would they earn? (4) The farmers consumer surplus is their willingness-to-pay minus what they must pay for the resource. Compare the farmers consumer surplus in the two cases. (5) Does the farmer lose more than the private firm gains by moving from the social optimum to the point that maximizes the firms profit?
67
1/10/2003
(6) Illustrate these relationships with a graph showing the demand curve and the unit cost c of water. Label the firms profits and the farmers consumer surplus?
12. Given the production functions for wheat and corn in the Maipo basin of Chile shown in the following Table, determine a Production Possibility curve if x = 15,000 m3/ha of water is available. If the prices are p1 = $230/mt (wheat) and p2 = $160/mt (corn), find the point of optimal production. What are the resulting outputs and amounts of water used for wheat and corn. What is the resulting total revenue? Table. Production functions for wheat and corn.
Water x (m3/ha) 0 536 1071 1607 2142 3213 4284 5355 6426 7497 8568 9639 10710 11781 12852 13923 14994 16065 17136 18207 19278
Production functions for wheat and corn Wheat Water y1 (mt/ha) x (m3/ha) 0.00 0 0.00 883 0.00 1765 0.00 2648 0.22 3530 2.08 5295 3.27 7060 4.10 8825 4.70 10590 5.14 12355 5.46 14120 5.70 15885 5.87 17650 5.98 19415 6.04 21180 6.07 22945 6.06 24710 6.02 26475 5.96 28240 5.88 30005 5.77 31770
Corn y2 (mt/ha) 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.21 3.87 5.60 6.83 7.74 8.43 8.96 9.37 9.68 9.91 10.08 10.19 10.26 10.28 10.27 10.23 10.17
13. (After Willis and Finney, 2000, Example Problem 4-8) Water quality pollution is an example of an externality, i.e., a harmful effect on one or more individuals that emenates from the action of a different person or firm (Samuelson, 1973). Downstream water users, for example, will have to treat water prior to use because of upstream firms dont consider the externalities in their decision making process.
A regional water management authority proposes to reduce point source wastewater discharges by imposing an effluent tax on each unit of waste discharged. These effluent charges are a method of internalizing the externalities created by the discharges. Investigate how the effluent charge affects the optimum production levels for a firm discharging waste. Assume: 1. the tax, , is expressed in $ per unit of output of the firm, q, and
Notes on Economics McKinney
68
1/10/2003
2. the pollution generated by the firm, P, is a linear function of the production level, P=q. a. Find the first order optimality conditions for the firm production. b. What is the effect of the tax on marginal revenue and marginal cost? b.1 Plot a diagram of Price versus Quantity showing marginal revenue with and without the tax (make whatever assumptions you need to to develop the graph). b.2 What is the difference between the point of intersection of the marginal cost curve and the marginal revenue curve with and without the tax? b.3 What is the difference in the production level with and without the tax? c. What is the effect on the level of pollution produced with and without the tax?
14. A regional water management authority must pay an effluent tax on waste discharged. Consider
q p( q) = q
C ( q) = q 2 D( q) = + q t = pc
= firms output (units) = price of the firms output ($/unit) = firms cost function ($) = firms pollution level (kg) = pollution tax ($/kg of waste produced)
, , , pc , , and are just constants, but you and I do not know their values.
Part A: Suppose the firm is maximizing profits and price is given as p = constant (that is, p( q) = = p, and = 0 ).
(1) If the tax is zero (t = 0), what level of output (q) will the firm select? (2) If the tax is not zero ( t = pc ), what level of output (q) will the firm select?
PART B: Suppose that the firm is socially conscious and wishes to maximize the benefits of the consumers and the inverse demand function (marginal willingness-to-pay) for its product is given by p( q) = q . Be sure to continue considering the cost function in your model.
(1) If the tax is zero (t=0), what level of output (q) will the firm select? (2) If the tax is not zero ( t = pc ), what level of output (q) will the firm select?
69
1/10/2003
15. The inverse demand curve for a depletable, nonrecyclable resource in year t is
where qt is the amount of resource demanded in year t, pt is the price of the resource in year t, and a,b > 0 are constants. The marginal cost of extracting a unit of resource in any year is a constant ( = c ). The total amount of resource available ( = Q ) is less than the amount needed to satisfy demand over a T year planning horizon. (a) Determine the first order optimality conditions for resource extraction if the objective of the extraction is to balance the current and future uses of the resource by maximizing the present value of net benefits derived from the use of the resource over the T years. Assume that the discount rate is i. (b) Calculate numerical values for the optimal extraction rates ( = qt, t = 1,2, ..., T) if T = 2, a = 8, b = 0.4, c = 2, Q = 20, i = 0.10.
16. Part A. Assume that stream flow ( S ) is 26 million m3 per unit of time and there is an interstate agreement ( S ) calling for 14.5 million m3 Also, initially there are two users on the river diverting S2 and S3 million m3. The benefits to each user are:
2 2 User 2: B2 ( S 2 ) = a 2 S 2 + b2 S 2 = 150S 2 5S 2 2 2 User 3: B3 ( S 3 ) = a3 S 3 + b3 S 3 = 18S 3 0.6S 3
In addition, both users have the same return flow coefficient, R2 = R3 = 0.5 . Write an optimization model to determine an efficient allocation that results in maximizing the value of water use in the basin and respects the interstate compact. What are the water allocations and the benefits to each user?
Part B. Now, assume that an additional user wants to divert S1 million m3 of water from the river. User 1s benefit function is identical to User 2s benefit, i.e.,
2 2 User 1: B1 ( S1 ) = a1S1 + b1S1 = 150 S1 5S1
User 1 also has a return coefficient of R1 = 0.5. Modify your optimization model to determine a new efficient allocation that results in maximizing the value of water use for all three users in the basin and respects the interstate compact. What are the water allocations and the benefits to each user?
Part C. Assume that the solution to Part A represents the initial water rights of Users 2 and 3, using the results obtained in Part B, what is the minimum payment that User 1 should pay to
70
1/10/2003
Users 2 and 3 in order to divert water from the river? What are the resulting net benefits to each of the three users?
Part D. Assume that the system described in Part B is modeled as a water market where users 1, 2, and 3 have water right allocations, 0.0, 4.0, and 7.5, respectively. Develop a model which will determine the optimal use of water by each user, assuming that the users are free to trade their water rights according to the model structure described in the text above. 17. Lewis and Clark Lake is a large reservoir in South Dakota created on the Missouri River by the Gavins Point Dam. It is located in an area where there are few natural bodies of water, and it has become very popular as a recreational area. Suppose that 10,000 families are potential users of the lake for recreational purposes and that each familys demand curve for recreational trips to the lake is as follows:
(1) If an ordinance were passed which limited each family to no more than 5 trips per year to the lake, what is the loss (in money terms) to each family? (2) If an ordinance were passed which allowed a family to use the lake for recreational purposes only if it purchased a permit for $75 a year, would it be worthwhile for each family to buy a permit, if it could not use the lake without the permit (and it could use the lake as much as it liked with one)? (3) How much is the consumers surplus from each familys utilization of the lake if there is a charge of $8 for each trip to the lake?
Notes on Economics McKinney
71
1/10/2003
18. (after North, 1985) Part A. Consider the following set of data regarding the production of lettuce
Production of lettuce 186 698 1185 1648 2085 2496 2883 3245 3582 3895 4184 4442 4679 4891
Price of lettuce/head 50 25 20 18 17 16 15 14 13 12 10 8 6 4
(1) Physical production (total, average, and marginal) (2) Cost functions (total, average, and marginal for both input and output) (3) Revenue functions (total, average, and marginal for both a competitive market price of 15 cents per head of lettuce and for the industry demand schedule given in column 3 below)
Part B. What are the firm equilibrium positions for both the competitive and monopolistic price structures, demonstrating total revenues, total costs, and net revenues. Part C. What are the optimum levels of production and resource use under both pricing structures when water costs $40/acre-inch and fixed costs are $160. 19. (After Linsley et al., 1079) The average annual damage from floods in a river basin is estimated to be $400,000. Estimates have been made for several alternate proposals for flood mitigation works: channel improvements (25 yr life), two mutually exclusive dams (A and B, 100 yr lives), and various combinations of these. The table below shows the first cost, estimated annual damages, and the annual OM&R disbursements for each alternative, and the sum of the annual damages and annual costs.
72
1/10/2003
Project Do nothing I. Channel Improvement II. Dam A III. Dam B IV. Dam A with Channel Improvements V. Dam B with Channel Improvements
1. Compare the projects using an interest rate of 6 percent. 2. Compare the conclusions of the economic analysis with the interest rate of 3 percent used in Sec. 13-9 of Linsley and Franzini, Water Resources Engineering, with the 6 percent rates used in your solution to Part (1). What generalizations can you make regarding the influence of the interest rate on such studies? 3. Comment on the statement, I would select the plan with the highest benefit cost ratio of all the plans. 4. Comment on the statement, I would select the plan with the highest possible benefits for which benefits are greater than costs.
References
Anderson, R. C., Environmental Damage Assessment of the Aral Sea Disaster, Issue Paper No. 1, USAID Environmental Policy and Technology Project, Almaty Kazakhstan, 1997. CAMASE, Register of Agro-ecosystem models, 1997. < http:/ / camase/ aboutreg.html>. Cuzan, A.G., Appropriators Versus Expropriators: The Political Economy of Water in the West, in Water Rights: Scarce Resource Allocation, Bureaucracy, and the Environment, T.L. Anderson (ed.), Pacific Institute for Public Policy Research, San Francisco, pp. 13-43, 1983. Dinar, A., and J. Letey, Modeling Economic Management and Policy Issues of Water in Irrigated Agriculture, Praeger, Westport, 1996. Dorfman, in Maas, A. et al., Design of Water Resource Systems, Harvard, Cambridge, 1962 Field B.C., Environmental Economics: An Introduction, McGraw Hill Publishers, New York, 1994 Frederick, K.D., T. Vandenberg, and J. Hanson, Economic Values of Freshwater in the United States, Discussion Paper 97-03, Resources for the Future, Washington D.C., 1996.
73
1/10/2003
Gardner, B.D., Water Pricing and Rent Seeking in California Agriculture, in Water Rights: Scarce Resource Allocation, Bureaucracy, and the Environment, T.L. Anderson (ed.), Pacific Institute for Public Policy Research, San Francisco, pp. 83-116, 1983. Gibbons, D. C., The Economic Value of Water, Resources for the Future, Washington D.C., 1986. Gisser, M., and R.N. Johnson, Institutional Restrictions on the Transfer of Water Rights and the Survival of an Agency, in Water Rights: Scarce Resource Allocation, Bureaucracy, and the Environment, T.L. Anderson (ed.), Pacific Institute for Public Policy Research, San Francisco, pp. 137-165, 1983. Hanks, R.J. 1983. Yield and water use relationships: An overview. In Limitations to efficient water use in crop production, eds. H.M. Taylor, W.R. Jordan and T.R. Sinclair. Madison, Wisc.: American Society of Agronomy. Hanks, R.J. and R.W. Hill. 1980. Modeling crop response to irrigation in relation to soils, climate and salinity. Oxford: Pergamon. Hirshleifer, J., J. C. De Haven, and J. W. Milliman, Water Supply: Economics, Technology, and Policy, Univ of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1960. Howe, C.W., Protecting Public Values under Tradable Water Permit Systems: Efficiency and Equity Considerations, Environment and Behavior Program, Institute of Behavioral Science, University of Colorado, Boulder, Dec. 1996. Howe, C.W., D.R. Schurmeier, and W.D. Shaw, Jr. Innovative Approaches to Water Allocation: The Potential for Water Markets, Water Resources Research, 22(4): 439-445, 1986. Huchens, A.O., and P.C. Mann, Review of Water Pricing Policies, Institutions and Practices in Central Asia, Environmental Policy and Technology Project, USAID, Almaty, Kazakhstan, 1998. James, L.D., and R.R. Lee, Economics of Water Resources, McGraw-Hill Book Co., New York, 1971 Linsley, R.K., and J.B. Franzini, Water Resources Engineering, McGraw-Hill, Inc., New York, 1979 Loucks, D. P. J. R. Stedinger, and D. A. Haith, Water Resource Systems Planning and Analysis, Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, 1981 Marani, A. 1988. COTMOD A model to optimize cotton response to irrigation and nitrogen. In Optimal yield management, ed. D. Rymon. Brookfield: Avebury. Mays, L.W., and Y-K, Tung, Hydrosystems Engineering and Management, McGraw Hill, 1992
74
1/10/2003
Merrett, S., Introduction to the Economics of Water Resources, UCL Press Limited, London, 1997. Michelsen, A.M. and R.A. Young, Optioning agricultural water rights for urban water supplies during drought, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 75(11): 1010-1020, 1993. North, R. M. Economics and Financing, Chapter 5 in Viessman, W. Jr. and C. Welty, Water Management: Technology and Institutions, Harper & Row, Publishers, New York 1985. Office of Management and Budget (OMB), Guidelines and Discount Rates for Benefit-Cost Analysis of Federal Programs Circular No. A-94 (Revised; Transmittal Memo No. 64), October 29, 1992 (http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/circulars/a094/a094.html) Pearce, D. W., and R. K. Turner, Economics of natural Resources and the Environment, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, 1990. Rosegrant, M.W., Water resources in the twenty-first century: Challenges and implications for action, Food, Agriculture, and the Environment Discussion Paper No. 20, Washington, D.C., IFPRI, 1997. Rosegrant, M.W., and H.P. Binswanger, Markets in Tradable Water Rights: Potential for Efficiency Gains in Developing Country Water Resource Allocation, World Development, 22(11):1613-1625, 1994. Rosegrant, M.W., R. Gazmuri Schleyer, and S.N. Yadav, Water Policy for Efficient Agricultural Diversification: Market Based Approaches, Food Policy, 20(3):203-223, 1995. Rosegrant, M.W., C. Ringler, D.C. McKinney, X. Cai, A. Keller, and G. Donoso, Integrated economic-hydrologic water modeling at the basin scale: the Maipo river basin. Agricultural Economics, Vol.24, No.1, pp.33-46, 2000. Senate Document 97 of the Eighty-seventh Congress on May 29, 1962, as amended by the Federal Register December 24, 1968 (33 F.R. 19170; 18 C.F.R. 704.39). Thuesen, H.G., W.J. Fabrycky, and G.J. Thuesen, Engineering Economy, Prentice Hall Publishers, Englewood Cliffs, 1977. Texas Water Development Board (TWDB), Water for Texas: Today and Tomorrow, Austin, Texas, 1997. Tregarthen, T.D., Water in Colorado: Fear and Loathing in the Marketplace, in Water Rights: Scarce Resource Allocation, Bureaucracy, and the Environment, T.L. Anderson (ed.), Pacific Institute for Public Policy Research, San Francisco, pp. 119-136, 1983. Vaux, H.J. and W.O. Pruitt. 1983. Crop-water production functions. In Advances in irrigation, ed. D. Hillel. New York: Academic Press.
Notes on Economics McKinney
75
1/10/2003
Willis, R. L. and B. A. Finney, Environmental Systems Engineering and Economics, Environmental Resources Engineering, Humboldt State Univ., Arcata, 2000
76
1/10/2003