Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect
Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect
Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect
EQUILIBRIUM OUTPUT
AND THE MULTIPLIER EFFECT
Equilibrium Output
Equilibrium output happens
when aggregate expenditures
equal aggregate income.
Aggregate expenditures may
also be labeled as aggregate
demand., while aggregate
income may also be labeled as
aggregate supply. Hence,
equilibrium output may be
identified as the point where
Sa (aggregate supply)
intersects (aggregate demand)
in the expenditure and income
graph.
Table 4.1
Income, Consumption and Savings
Y
160
320
-160
200
350
-150
400
500
-100
800
800
1200
1100
100
1600
1400
200
2000
1700
300
Table 4.1 shows that negative savings may happen because even at zero income
need to spend, e.g., food and minimal clothing in order o keep themselves alive.
Where do they get the money? Maybe from borrowing, spot from relatives,
subsidies from government welfare agencies.
Since Y = C + S, C / Y + S + Y
= 1, hence, APC + APS = 1
also, because income can
only be either spent or
saved. So adding two more
columns to Table 4.2 for
APC and APS, the result can
be seen as follows.
Table 4.2
Income, Consumption, Savings, Average Propensity to
Consume and Average Propensity to Save
Y
160
200
400
800
1200
1600
2000
C
320
350
500
800
1100
1400
1700
S
-160
-150
-100
0
100
200
300
APC
2
1.75
1.25
1
0.92
0.86
0.85
APS
-1
-0.75
-0.25
0
0.08
0.14
0.15
Adding each row in the APC and APS columns gives us a uniform sum of 1. Also
in table 4.2, we can see that APC and APS move in opposite directions, that is,
as APC decreases, APS increases. Conversely, as APC rises, APS moves down.
The APC and APS are useful tools in planning as they may be used by
planner (economists) to determine the spending and saving patterns of various
regions and localities of a country, which could guide decision makers in their
policy-making activities.
Table 4.3
Relationship of Income, Consumption, Savings,
APC , APS, MPC and MPS
Y
160
200
400
800
1200
1600
2000
C
320
350
500
800
1100
1400
1700
S
-160
-150
-100
0
100
200
300
APC
2
1.75
1.25
1
0.92
0.86
0.85
APS
-1
-0.75
-0.25
0
0.08
0.14
0.15
MPC
0.75
0.75
0.75
0.75
0.75
0.75
MPS
0.25
0.25
0.25
0.25
0.25
0.25
We can see that the first two row in the <PC and MPC are unfilled, because there are no
previous data on Y and C columns prior to Y = 160 and C = 320 date. Hence, MPC and
MPS cannot be calculated in this instance. We can also notice, that really, if we add the
two columns for each row, MPC + MPS = 1. Finally, we also see that the ratios of MPC
and MPS in relation to income and steady throughout. This kind of pattern has had
empirical validations in the several studies made in this direction in the past.
The MPC and MPS are very useful tools in economic planning as they give planners
and decision makers inputs that are necessary in formulating and implementing policies
related to wages and investment.
Consumption Function
At equilibrium, income (Y) is equal to expenditure (C + I),
and between C and I, C always comprises the larger share
of Y. This logical flow is an extension of Keynes observation
that saving is just a residual fund after an individual or
household had already satisfied his consumption needs,
and that investment (Y) is merely a portion of (S), and at
equilibrium S = I.
Consumption Function
From this graph, we can see
the value of C at any point
along the C curve is C = a + bY.
So that we can forecast the
consumption behavior if we
are able to establish the ratio
of C and Y (change in C for
every change in Y). In this
assumed linear relationship
between C and Y, a = origin or
starting value of C and b =
slope of the curve or C line.
Consumption Function
Revisiting the date we generated
in Table 4.1, we will validate the
linear relationship of C and Y by
calculating its slopes are every
paired rows:
1. At Y = 160 and C = 320
Y = 200 and C = 350
Solve for B.
DC
b=
DY
350 - 320
b=
200 -160
30
b=
40
b = 0.75
Consumption Function
3. At Y = 400 and C = 500
Y = 800 and C = 800
Solve for B.
DC
DY
300
b=
400
b=0.75
b=
5. At Y = 1200 and C
=1100
Y = 1600 and C = 1400
DC
DY
300
b=
400
b=0.75
b=
6. At Y = 1600 and C
=1400
Y = 2000 and C = 1200
DC
DY
300
b=
400
b=0.75
b=
Consumption Function
Since the slope of s straight
line is the same at any paired
points along the line, we are
able to prove the linear
relationship between Y and C
in our sample date. With this
linearity, we can forecast the
value of C at any level of Y.
Example:
Y = 900
a = 200
Solve for C. C = ?
Solution:
C = a + bY
C = 200 + 0.75 (900)
C = 100 + 675
C = 875
Planned Investments
And Its Multiplier Effect
Planned Investments
And Its Multiplier Effect
With this clarification, henceforth, we will
consider planned investments as investment
Investment may be defined as that part of
savings used to create future value, e.g.,
sewing machine to create clothes I the future,
beer mixing machines to crease future beers,
buildings to create more space foe
warehousing, etc.
Planned Investments
And Its Multiplier Effect
Planned investment is normally not
dependent on income. Firms do not normally
alter its investments expenditures as planned
for a given year. Why? Because a capital
expenditure plans which was made in prior
years is very costly for the firm to change in
terms of additional man-hour cost, which will
rework the plan, and for cost opportunities in
doing other things rather than reworking plan
Planned Investments
And Its Multiplier Effect
Figure 4.3 shows a perfectly
elastic I curve showing that
the level of investment by
firms is not dependent on the
level of income (Y).
Planned Investments
And Its Multiplier Effect
Planned Investments
And Its Multiplier Effect
After deducting the reduction in income brought about by
the damaged facilities, will a 100 million increase in
investment in Meralco to repair the facilities bring an
additional income of 100 million in the economy? Since Y
= C + I, hence an increase by 100 million of I will result in
100 million of I will result in Y also increase by 100
million.
Planned Investments
And Its Multiplier Effect
Let us explain this phenomenon. Initially, income will increase by
the same amount as the increase in I. But the money from the
investment will be paid o additional workers who will work to repair
the damaged facilities and/or to those existing employees who will
render overtime; some will be paid to suppliers of equipment,
wires, transformer, bus-station spare parts, etc.
Planned Investments
And Its Multiplier Effect
The graph in Figure 4.4
shows the effect of I to
Y. By ocular inspection,
we can easily see that the
distance from Y0 to Y1 is
longer than the distance
from I0 to I1. Hence, Y >
I because of the
multiplier effect of I in
the economys income.
Hence, Y = C + I at equilibrium
Therefore, Y = a + bY + I
Y - by = a + I, and
Y (1 - b) = a + I, and
1
a+I
Y=
or Y= a + I
1 - b
1- b
Hence, if I is increased
by I,
1
DY=DI
b
and because b=MPC
1
DY=DI
1-MPC
Hence, the value of the multiplier is
1
1-MPC
Using the computed MPC of 0.75 in Figure 4.4, estimate the effect on
income at equilibrium of the change in planned investment using the
following data:
Given:
I0 = 850
I1 = 900
a = 350
b = 0.75
Calculate:
I change in investment= ?
Y change in income= ?
Y (resulting income)= ?
Y0income before I appears= ?
1-MPC
1
= 50
0.25
= 200
3. Y = C + I + DI
= a + bY + I +D I
=350 + 0.75Y + 50
Y - 0.75Y = 350 + 50
0.25Y = 400
400
0.25
Y=1,600
Y=
4. Y0 = Y - DY
= 1600 - 200
= 1400