Lecture 6-Resisting Temptation
Lecture 6-Resisting Temptation
Lecture 6-Resisting Temptation
he is in a hot state. When Sally is thinking abstractly on Tuesday about the right number of
cashews he should consume before dinner on Saturday, he is in a cold state. We will call
something “tempting” if we consume more of it when hot than when cold. None of this means
that decisions made in a cold state are always better.
Behavioral economist George Loewenstein (1996) calls the “hot-cold empathy
gap.”
When in a cold state, we do not appreciate how much our desires and our
As a result, our behavior reflects a certain naïveté about the effects that context
Similar problems affect those who have problems with smoking, alcohol, a failure
Mindless Choosing
The cashew problem is not only one of temptation. It also involves the type of
mindless behavior.
‘Automatic pilot’ in which they are not actively paying attention to the task at hand.
Eating turns out to be one of the most mindless activities we do. Many of us simply
When self-control problems and mindless choosing are combined, the result is a
Smokers temptation bias. Similarly obese people’s problems, fail to join retirement
Self Control Strategies
People are at least partly aware of their weaknesses, they take steps to engage
outside help.
In these cases, our Planners are taking steps to control the actions of our Doers.
recalcitrant Doers, but they can sometimes use some help from outsiders.
We will be exploring how private and public institutions can provide that help. In
Story of a Ph.D
In some situations, people may even want the government To Help Them Deal
With their self-control problems. In extreme cases, governments might ban some
items like drugs, drunken driving.
Such bans can be seen as pure rather than libertarian paternalism, Though third-
In other cases, individuals may prefer a less intrusive role for the government such
as Cigarette taxes.
Since no one is required to sign up, and since a refusal to do so is close to costless,
saving time.
In many cases, markets provide self-control services, and government is not needed at
all. Companies can make a lot of money by strengthening Planners in their battle with
Doers, often doing well by doing good.
known as The Christmas savings club from where Dhanteras schemes drew the idea.
Even when we’re on our way to making good choices, competitive markets find ways to
get us to overcome our last shred of resistance to bad ones→ KFC at the airport.
Mental Accounting
Alarm clocks and Christmas Clubs are external devices to solve self-control
problems.
Mental accounting is the system (most of the time implicit) that households use
Money is ‘fungible’ i.e. it does not come with labels but households and
Experimental evidence reveals that people are more willing to gamble with money
People take more chances with their ‘winnings’ when investments pay-off.
many people took on more and more risk with the justification that they were
playing only with their gains from the past few years.
People spent or ‘splurge’ on luxury items more with an unexpected windfall than
Mental accounting matters because these accounts are treated as non-fungible.
‘Arbitrage opportunity’ buying low and selling high, paying off credit card bills
Scenario 1:
Upon entering one of the sales person greets you at the door and hands you a scratch
You decide to amuse yourself and your company and bring out a penny and scratch the
card.
The Utility theory of money
In utility theory, the utility of a gain is assessed by comparing the utilities of two
states of wealth.
There is no way to represent the ‘disutility’ of losing $500 could be greater than
Researchers have always focused on the issue of ‘winning’ but it is the issue of
If you choose the option 1 instead of option 2, which 90% of the population do,
rather than another situation with a more predictable payoff but possibly
For example, a risk-averse investor might choose to put their money into
a bank account with a low but guaranteed interest rate, rather than into
a stock that may have high expected returns, but also involves a chance of losing
value.
Problem 2: You receive $50 with 100% chance or you get $100 with head in a coin
If you calculate the expected pay-off then in both of these scanarios expected
risk averse (or risk avoiding) - if they would accept a certain payment (certainty
equivalent) of less than $50 (for example, $40), rather than taking the gamble and
possibly receiving nothing.
risk neutral – if they are indifferent between the bet and a certain $50 payment.
risk loving (or risk seeking) – if they would accept the bet even when the
The explanation for this risk-seeking choice is the mirror image of the explanation
of risk aversion.
Sure loss is very aversive which induces people to accept the risky choice.
People become risk seeking when all of their options are ‘bad’.
different attitudes to risk for gains and losses, the fact that the attitudes differed
had to be ignored.
Problem 4: In addition to whatever you own, you have been given $1,000.
Problem 5: In addition to whatever you own, you have been given $2,000.
In the first choice, a large majority of respondents preferred the sure thing.
If the utility of wealth is all that matters, then transparently equivalent statements
The comparison of the problems highlights the all-important role of the ‘reference
point’ from which the options are evaluated. Reference points are generally
ignored.
The reason we all like the idea of gaining $100 and dislike the idea of losing $100
is not that these amounts change your wealth. You just like winning and dislike
losing —and you almost certainly dislike losing more than you like winning.
Prospect theory includes this ‘reference point’ which traditional expected utility
theory did not consider. Prospect theory is therefore more complex than utility
theory.
There are three cognitive features at the heart of prospect theory. They play an
essential role in the evaluation of financial outcomes and are common to many
automatic processes of perception, judgment, and emotion.
Perceived Value: Anchoring
The previous pricing policy of markdowns had one other distinct advantage over the
“fair and square” policy – anchoring. An anchor is a cognitive bias that can dramatically
impact our estimation of things. For example, what if I asked you “What is the
population of Venezuela?” versus asking “Is the population of Venezuela greater or
fewer than 65 Million?” With the first question, you will have to make a random guess –
say 10 Million. In the other question, you now have a starting point to work from and
will adjust your answer based on that starting point. You might think 65 Million sounds
like a lot for the small South American country but it must not be too far off, so you
guess something around 40 Million.