Chapter 4
Chapter 4
Chapter 4
Quantitative development planning
techniques
• The Harrod-Domar and the two-gap models are aggregate where as the input-
output model, the social-accounting-matrix-based and linear
programming models are disaggregated models.
Aggregate consistency models
• The well-known aggregate consistency models are the Harrod-Domar (H-D)
model and the two-gap model.
The Harrod-Domar growth model
In drawing up a development plan, the usual first step is to assess the
aggregate rate of growth of the economy that can be attained within the
prevailing socio economic conditions.
The possible overall rate of growth can most easily be determined by
analysing the past and present relationships between such aggregate variables
as gross domestic product (GDP), consumption, savings, investment and the
rate of population growth.
• The basic H-D model can be summarized as follows. We make the following
assumptions.
Harrod-Domar Model
Harrod- Domar states that the rise in GDP from period t to period t+1 is determined by the net
amount of new capital formation in period t and its productivity measured by the inverse
capital output ratio.
Net investment (In) is assumed to be limited by the level of saving (S), which in turn is
functionally related to the level of income (Y) through a propensity to save (s).
The model also assumes a stable capital output ratio. The basic model can be summarized as
follows.
1) S= sY = the saving function
Where S = level of saving
s = average
propensity to save Y = Income
2) K = kY = Capital stock income relationship
Where K = Total capital formation (Stock)
k = incremented capital output
𝑠 = 𝑠𝑌 = 𝑘Δ𝑌 = Δ𝐾
Substituting 1 and 2a in 3 we get
5. 𝛻𝑌𝑌 = 𝐾
𝑆
or 𝑔𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑡ℎ = 𝑌
𝛻𝑌
So 𝐾𝑔 = s=saving ratio
Where
𝑆
The Foreign Exchange Gap: Where earnings of foreign exchange fall short of
the amounts needed to purchase the necessary foreign materials,
components, etc.
• In order to derive the two gap we start with the basic macroeconomic identity where aggregate output
=
𝑌 = 𝐶 + 𝐼 + (𝑋 − 𝑀 )
aggregate expenditure. Thus, assuming that there is no government sector
assuming no government role
Where Y= GNP; C= Consumption; I= Investment (or Domestic Capital
formation) X = Exports; M = Imports
Now,
𝑌+
Sources of resources used in 𝑀 = = Uses𝐶of+resources
the economy 𝐼 in the economy:
expenditure C from both sides we get: + 𝑋
𝑌−𝐶 𝐼
Subtracting
𝑆+𝑀 𝐼+𝑋
(domestic) Then,
(Injections)
= investment can be financed by domestic saving as well as through inflows of
This implies that domestic
𝑆−𝐼 𝑋−𝑀……………….…………………………
capital. But these two constitute two separate constraints. Eliminating one does not get rid of the other.
(Withdrawals)
=
(2)
𝐼−𝑆=𝑀−𝑋……………………………………………………………………
(Saving gap) (Foreign exchange gap)
… … … . (3)
• Note: The analysis rests on the premise that domestic investment can be
financed by domestic saving as well as through inflows of capital.
• If we let (M – X) = F, then we can represent the above as follows
• F = I – S or as in the text I = F + S
• Possible Scenarios
• Using the relationship posited above, the following scenarios may arise:
• S may be too small to permit the amount of I that the country would otherwise
have the capability to undertake. Therefore, a savings gap would exist.
• X may be too small to permit the M required to make full use of the resources
of the economy. Therefore a foreign exchange (or trade) gap would exist.
• While the two gaps are distinct and separate ones, international transfers can, in
fact, be used to fill both.
• For example, a machine given to a country represents both an import for which
no resources need to be exported (thus alleviating the foreign exchange gap)
and an investment good which does not have to be offset by domestic
saving (thus alleviating the savings gap).
• Assessment of the Two Gaps
• Even though, according to the national accounts identity, the ex post investment-
savings gap must be equal to the ex post import-export gap, there is no
reason for these two gaps to be equal ex ante (in a planned sense).
Therefore, the investment-savings and import-export gaps (ex ante) can be
written as
In some of the work done on the two-gap model, it is suggested not only that
they exist but that, most often; the trade gap exceeds the savings gap. This
suggests that the trade gap is more powerful - i.e. is the binding constraint.
• Thus, it is intuitively clear that if the target growth is to be achieved, foreign
capital inflow must fill the larger of the two gaps so that the bottleneck can
be avoided.
• Developing countries are often found to suffer from the ‘foreign exchange
constraint’ (i.e. the import-export gap is larger than the investment-savings
gap).
• In this situation, the willingness to save is frustrated by the inability to acquire
imports which are required to produce investment goods. That is, a portion
of the maximum potential domestic savings remains unutilized in the
presence of a constraint imposed by the availability of foreign exchange.
• This conclusion, however, crucially depends on the assumption of no
substitution between foreign and domestic resources; in other words, if
foreign exchange is scarce it is impossible to use domestic resources
to earn more foreign exchange.
Critics
• Critics of the two-gap model have argued that developing countries should be
able to transform surplus domestic resources into export production.
• But, as Thirlwall (1983:295) has put it: ‘If it were that easy, the question might
well be posed, why do most developing countries suffer from chronic
balance of payments deficits over long periods despite vast reserves of
unemployed resources?’
• Critics have also pointed out that, instead of supplementing domestic savings,
foreign aid/exchange may substitute for it, if foreign aid relaxes the
domestic savings effort.
• It is also argued that foreign aid has allowed governments to delay making
difficult decisions regarding domestic resource mobilization.
Disaggregated Consistency Models
• The planning exercise does not stop at the most aggregate level with the setting
of a GNP growth target and the calculation of required investment, savings
and foreign capital inflows.
• As mentioned earlier, the whole process proceeds in stages, and the second
stage of the planning exercise usually involves a further breakdown of
the plan to cover a number of strategic sectors of the economy.
• The economy is the sum of the individual sectors, so the target growth of GNP
will imply specific rates of growth for the component sectors.
• The second stage therefore involves the translation of the overall growth
target and investment requirements into sectoral growth targets and
investment requirements.
• This is the concern of disaggregated consistency models. In this chapter we
consider models such as the multi-sector model.
Multi-sector models: Input-output analysis
• At the core of a multi-sector planning model is the input-output analysis. The
essence of the input-output analysis is that it captures the interrelationships
of the production structure arising through the flow of intermediate
goods.
• There are numerous uses of the input-output technique and it is the most widely
used planning tool.
• The most common uses of it for planning purposes can be summarized as
follows.
1) Being a consistency model, the input-output technique can be used for
projecting and forecasting sectoral production or supply requirements to
meet the sectoral demands implied by alternative targets for GDP.
2) Once the sectoral supply is projected, the analysis can be extended to forecast
the requirements for (a) primary factors, e.g. skilled labour, (b) sectoral
capacity expansion and investment and (c) non-competitive imports.
Multi-sector models: Input-output analysis
3)Since the input-output table contains information on intermediate
transactions between the producing sectors, it can be used to identify the ‘key’
sectors with maximum interdependence.
4)The input-output table can also be used to forecast the impact of supply
shocks and cost inflation.
• Thus most of the models in economics are constructed taking the basic
assumption ceteris paribus and other assumptions.
• Taking this fact, therefore, before we are going to deal with the details of the
input- output analysis, it is important to note the basic assumptions.
The assumptions of input-output Analysis
• The assumptions that the I-O analysis includes are the following:
• An economy is decomposed in to n sector (industries) and each of these produces only
one kind of product i.e. no two products are produced jointly.
• The total output of any industry is capable of being used as inputs by other inter- industry
sectors, by itself and by final demand sector.
• There are constant returns to scale. This is the crucial assumption of input- output analysis
i.e. the one that makes the system operationally effective. This assumption implies that
in any productive process all inputs are used in fixed proportions and increase in inputs
is in proportion with the level of output.
• Prices, consumer demands and factor supplies are given
• There are no external economics and diseconomies of production.
• All transactions may be considered in terms of money value since money is a
suitable common unit for aggregating inputs and out puts of industries.
The Structural Nature of an Input-Output System
• As it indicated above input- output analysis emphasized general equilibrium
phenomena and it is based on the belief that an economy consists of
different sectors, which are interdependent to each other.
• So that each industry employs the output of other industries as its raw
material. Its output
in turn is used by other industries as a productive sector. In other
words it implies there is transaction between industries.
• Thus the input output model can be portrayed by table (more formally, a
matrix) that shows how the output of each sector is distributed in the form of
intermediate products, for itself and for other sectors and as final product to
households, government and export.
• Each sector is indicated in the table both as purchaser and supplier of a
product.
• The input output table is therefore important in the analysis by providing a
convenient framework for measuring and tracing these interindustry flows
of current inputs and outputs among the various sectors of the economy.
• A table summarizing the origin of all the various inputs and the distribution
of all the various outputs of all industries in an economy is therefore
known as input output table.
• The framework of the input output table is generally represented as follows and
is indicated in the table that follows.
• Most of the important information contained in the table is located with in
four main quadrants (Blocks):
I. Block I (Inter industry Transactions block)
II. Block II (Value added quadrant)
III. Block III (Final use block)
IV. Block IV (Direct factor purchase quadrant) - This quadrant is not as
important for planning purposes as the other three although it is necessary
for accounting purposes specially for measuring gross domestic product.
• Block I shows the supply of output from one sector to another for use in the
production process of each sector.
• The producing sectors of the economy are listed as rows 1, 2, - - -, n in this
quadrant while these same industries is also listed by column as using sectors.
• Thus the inter industry transaction quadrant is a " square matrix " with the
same number of rows as columns, one for each sector of the economy.
• Each row shows the distribution of outputs of a sector to other sectors and each
column shows the receipt of an industry as an input from other sectors and
itself.
• In short rows indicate outputs, columns represent inputs and each sector is
• Block III shows the final demand use of the sectoral output, products,
which are consumed for their own sake and not for use in further
production.
• They may be purchased as consumption goods by individual consumers or
by the central government or they may be sold to foreign demanders in the
form of exports.
• The horizontal summation of the outputs of the sector sold as intermediate
goods to the other sectors plus the output sold to private, public and
foreign final demanders yields the total output of the given sector.
• Block II shows the primary input (land, labour, capitals) required by each sector in the
production of its output.
• The sum of value of these primary inputs used in the whole economy yields the total value
added by the sectors.
• For any particular sector the elements in each column of this block when added to the
elements in the corresponding columns of the transactions block yield a value for total
inputs purchased or used up by this industry during the accounting period i.e. the total
cost of operation.
• Block IV- shows those primary inputs, which are employed by final users.
• The main component of this quadrant would be the purchase of labour services the
central government, households for their own consumption.
If the final demand is added to this intermediate we obtain the new gross
output of each sector.
For instance for agriculture sector the total intermediate use is 69.39+188.865
while final demand is given as 150. Thus the total output is 408.15.
Use of Input-Output Analysis in Planning
• As you see in the previous discussion the input output analysis tells us about
the inter relationships between various sectors and the structural relations
with in each factor.
• The basic concept of input output analysis has been adopted by many countries,
which have undertaken programmes of economic development.
• The most important questions that may be raised in planning a given
economy includes, what level of total output, what will be the level of
employment and what will be the balance payment position of the country
by the coming plan periods etc.
• Considering this and other questions and the basic concept of the input
output analysis discussed what importance would the model has. Would
you explain the roles of the model?
• The input output analysis can help planners:
1) To for cast the sectoral output needed to sustain a given desired level of final
demand.
2) To forecast the primary factor or resource required to produce the given
level of sectoral output.
3) Forecast capacity expansion (investment requirements) consistent with a
given growth target if information is available on incremental capital
output ratios sector by sector.
4) To for cast import requirements and the balance of payments effects of given
changes in final demand.
Limitation of Input Output Analysis
• Despite its obvious advantages, the input output analysis cannot be wholly
accepted for purposes of planning. The assumptions set out for the discussion
of I-O analysis help us to understand the major limitations of the model.
1. The input output technique is based on the assumption of constant returns
to scale and constant technique of production in technology. However, these
coefficients may not remain constant when growth is taking place. In the long
run the validity of the assumption of a constant coefficient becomes invalid
as technical progress gains momentum, substitution possibilities arise and
returns to scale might be rising instead of being constant. Thus marginal input
coefficients might no longer be equal to the average.
2. The I-o analysis assumes that each industry has only one way of producing a
given product. But there could be more than one process or activity to
produce a commodity.
Assignment
1. A simple economy has three sectors Agriculture, industry & service. Suppose
that the final demand for agriculture, industry & service sector are birr 30,birr
250 and 120 worth of the three sectors respectively. It is given that a birr worth
of agriculture requires 10 cents, 50 cents and 15 cents worth of agriculture,
industry & service sector respectively as input; a birr worth of industry
requires 25 cents, 5 cents& 10 cents worth of agriculture, industry & service
sector products respectively as input; and that of a birr worth of service sector
requires 5 cents from it self and 25 cents & 15 cents worth of goods from
agriculture and industry respectively as inputs. Given the above information
and assuming the economy is in equilibrium answer the following questions.
Assignment
A. Determine the technical coefficient or technology matrix of the economy.
B. Determine the gross output of each sector for the given final demand.
C. Calculate the balance of payment of this economy assuming that from the
given final demand of each sector 30% is used for export purpose and from the
total primary input requirement of each sector 25% is imported from foreign
countries.
D. Determine the total output of each sector if the final demand changes to 60 for
agriculture, 300 for industry and 200 for service
E. Determine the value addition associated with the new equilibrium output
level of each sector and the new balance of payment taking the assumptions
in C
What is a SAM?
• A SAM is also a representation of the economy. More specifically, it is an
accounting framework that assigns numbers to the incomes and expenditures
in the circular flow diagram.
• A SAM is laid out as a square matrix in which each row and column is called
an “account.” Table 1 shows the SAM that corresponds to the circular flow
diagram in Figure 1. Each of the boxes in the diagram is an account in the
SAM. Each cell in the matrix represents, by convention, a flow of funds from a
column account to a row account.
• For example, the circular flow diagram shows private consumption spending as
a flow of funds from households to commodity markets. In the SAM, it is
entered in the household column and commodity row. The underlying principle
of double-entry accounting requires that, for each account in the SAM, total
revenue equals total expenditure. This means that an account’s row and
column totals must be equal.
Activities and commodities
• The SAM distinguishes between “activities” and ”commodities.”
• Activities are the entities that produce goods and services, and commodities are
those goods and services produced by activities.
• They are separated because sometimes an activity produces more than one kind
of commodity (by-products).
• Similarly, commodities can be produced by more than one kind of activity: for
example, maize can be produced by small or large-scale farmers. The values
in the activity accounts are usually measured in producer prices (that is,
farm or factory gate prices).
• Activities produce goods and services by combining the factors of production
with intermediate inputs. This is shown in the activity column of the
SAM, where activities pay factors the wages, rents, and profits they
generate during the production process (that is, value-added).
Activities and commodities
• This is a payment from activities to factors, and so the value-added entry in the
SAM appears in the activity column and the factor row [R3-C1].
• Similarly, intermediate demand is a payment from activities to commodities
[R2-C1].
• Adding together value-added and intermediate demand gives gross output.
• The information on production technologies contained in the activity column is
the input part of a typical “input–output table,” or factor and intermediate
inputs per unit of output.
• Commodities are either supplied domestically [R1-C2] or imported [R7-C2].
Indirect sales taxes and import tariffs are paid on these commodities [R5-
C2].
• This means that the values in the commodity accounts are measured at market
prices. A number of economic entities purchase commodities.
• As discussed, activities buy commodities to be used as intermediate inputs
for production [R2-C1].
• Final demand for commodities consists of household consumption spending
[R2-C4], government consumption, or recurrent expenditure [R2-C5],
gross capital formation or investment [R2-C6], and export demand [R2-C7].
• All of these sources of demand make up the commodity row (payments by
different entities for commodities).
• On their own, the commodity row and column accounts are sometimes referred
to as a “Supply–Use Table,” or the total supply of commodities and their
different kinds of uses or demands.
….
• The SAM in Table 1 shows only single activity and commodity rows and
columns. However, a SAM generally contains a number of different activities
and commodities.
• For example, activities may be divided into agriculture, industry, and
services.
• The information needed to construct these detailed activity and commodity
accounts is usually found in a country’s national accounts, input–output
table and/or supply–use table.
• All of these data are usually published by a country’s statistical bureau.
Domestic institutions
• A SAM is different from an input–output matrix because it not only traces
the income and expenditure flows of activities and commodities, but it
also contains complete information on different institutional accounts, such
as households and the government.
• Households are usually the ultimate owners of the factors of production, and so
they receive the incomes earned by factors during the production process
[R4- C3].
• They also receive transfer payments from the government [R4-C5] (for
example, social security and pensions) and from the rest of the world [R4-C7]
(such as remittances received from family members working abroad).
• Households then pay taxes directly to the government [R5-C4] and purchase
commodities [R2-C4]. The remaining income is then saved (or dis-saved
if expenditures exceed incomes) [R6-C4].
• Information in household accounts is usually drawn from national accounts and
household surveys from the country’s statistics bureau.
….
• The government receives transfer payments from the rest of the world [R5-C7]
(such as foreign grants and development assistance).
• This is added to all of the different tax incomes to determine total government
revenues.
• The government uses these revenues to pay for recurrent consumption
spending [R2-C5] and transfers to households [R4-C5].
• The difference between total revenues and expenditures is the fiscal surplus (or
deficit, if expenditures exceed revenues) [R6-C5]. Information on the
government accounts is normally drawn from public-sector budgets published
by a country’s ministry of finance.
Savings, investment, and the foreign account
• According to the ex post accounting identity, investment or gross capital
formation, which includes changes in stocks or inventories, must equal
total savings. So far we have accounted for private savings [R6-C4] and
public savings [R6-C5].
• The difference between total domestic savings and total investment demand is
total capital inflows from abroad, or what is called the current account
balance [R6-C7].
• This is also equal to the difference between foreign exchange receipts (exports
and foreign transfers received) and expenditures (imports and government
transfers to foreigners). Information on the current account (or rest of world) is
drawn from the balance of payments, which is usually published by a
country’s central bank.
Balancing a SAM
• The information needed to build a SAM comes from a variety of sources, such
as national accounts, household surveys, government budgets, and the
balance of payments.
• Placing these data within the SAM framework almost always reveals
inconsistencies between the incomes and expenditures of each account.
• For example, government spending in national accounts may not be the same
as what is reported in the government budget.
• A number of statistical estimation techniques exist to balance SAM accounts
or reconcile incomes and expenditures.
• Cross entropy estimation is generally the preferred method. More information
on this approach can be found in various IFPRI discussion papers.
Linear programming and development
•planning
The main task of development planning is to ensure that resources will be used
to meet the goals of a development programme, and that the resources are
allocated efficiently subject to certain constraints.
• Programming is a mathematical tool, which is now being increasingly used, in
economic analysis. Its use in the field of development planning is of much
interest chiefly because it helps the planners to allocate resources optimally
among alternative uses with in the specific constraints.
• At the micro level the technique could be used to find out optimal and efficient
(least cost) methods of production.
• Most of the time it deals a whole complex of ingenerated projects rather than
with a marginal project, and is concerned with much wider considerations
than marginal analysis.
….
• It provides a simultaneous solution to the three basic purposes of development
planning, which are:
• (i) The optimum allocations of resources
• (ii) efficiency in the use of resources; and
• (iii) the balance between different branches of the national economy.
• One particular programming technique which can assist in providing a
simultaneous solution to these basic questions is the technique of linear
programming. Thus here in this section we will deal with such
technique.
Linear programming
• Linear programming is a mathematical technique for the analysis of optimum
decisions, subject to certain constraints in the form of linear inequities.
• It applies to those problems, which require the solution of maximization, or
minimization problems subject to a system of linear inequalities stated in
terms of certain variables.
• The problems of maximization and minimization are also called optimization
problems. It is a method used to decide the optimum combination output to
be produced by a given plant and equipment.
• It is also used to decide between the varieties of techniques to produce a
commodity.
• The technique involved in linear programming is similar to the technique
used in input output analysis, However, LP is more realistic than the input
output approach.
• The input output analysis a single method of production to a given commodity.
• It does not take in to account the constraints, which a development project has to
face. But in an LP problem all the possible processes or techniques are taken
in to account for achieving the desired objective.
• This might necessitate the substitution of one factor by another so the LP, as a
tool of development planning is superior to the input output technique.
• And it is considered as a powerful and complementary tool, which can be used
to analyse the I-O tables in order to solve the problems of choice of
techniques on the supply side as well as the problem of choice of final
demand.
• Most linear programming techniques have been found to be extremely useful
for sectoral planning, in respect to selecting the optimum alternative
technology and location.
• For example, the techniques have been frequently used in farm management for
determining the optimum combination of different crops and live stock.
• Similarly, transport, purchasing, assembling, production and marketing
problems are being solved through LP technique in order to minimize costs
and maximize profits.
General Formulation of LP Problems
And Assumptions
• Four important uses (generalizations) that LP can be put in any
countries concerned with allocation efficiency are:
1. It can be used for choosing between techniques for making the same
commodity.
2. It can be used for deciding the best combination of outputs with
given techniques and factor endowments.
3. It can be used for deciding whether it is more efficient to produce
commodities at home or buy them from abroad.
4. It can be used to determine the most efficient spatial location of
activities.
All these issues are optimizing decisions of one form or another and can be
incorporated in to the standard form of a programming problem which consists
I. The objective function- it may be maximization of profits or national income
or employment or the minimization of costs.
II. The constraints- They may be limitations of resources such as land, labour, or
capital.
III. The non-negativity conditions e.g. that outputs or exports should not be
negative
Mathematically
Max or minimize Z= C1X1C2X2+---+CnXn
Subject to a12 X 2 a1n X n b1
a11 X 1
a 22 X 2 a 2 n Xn b2
⁝ a 21 X 1 ⁝ ⁝
a n1 X 1 an 2 X 2 a n n Xn bn
and Xi 0
• Let us assume that a country produces two products: agricultural and manufactured.
Each unit of agricultural product sells at birr 1 and the manufactured product at birr 4.
It takes two workers and 4 units of capital to produce one unit of agricultural products
and 10 workers and 5 units of capital to produce one unit of manufactured product.
The total number of workers and amount of capital available are 1000 and 600
respectively.
• Given this information a planner can structure a linear program to allocate the
country’s resources (labour and capital) so as to maximize the total value of
output or GDP.
• The first step is to define the decision variables and the parameters.
• The decisions are the amounts of products (level of agricultural and
manufactured output) that the country should produce. Let X1 is the level of
agricultural output that should be produced and X2 is the level of manufactured
product. The parameters of the problem are:
• The number of workers required par unit of agricultural and manufactured
products.
• Units of capital required per unit of agricultural and manufactured
products.
• Total available amount of resources (labour and capital)
• Price per unit of agricultural and manufactured products.
The next step is to state the objective function and constraints. The
objective is to maximize the value of total output (or GDP). Therefore
the objective function is.
Maximize Y = 1X2 + 4X2
Were Y = Total value of output (total
income) 1X1 = Value of
agricultural output 4X2 = Value of
manufacture output
• Assignment!!
Thank
You