Academia.eduAcademia.edu

Sources of Agricultural Productivity Growth in Central Asia

2009, 2009 Annual Meeting, July 26-28, 2009, Milwaukee, Wisconsin

The paper examines agricultural production and productivity growth in two Central Asian countries-Tajikistan and Uzbekistan. Both countries are characterized by a significant shift of resources from the traditional Soviet model of collective agriculture to more marketcompliant individual and family farming. In both countries, the beginning of the policy-driven switch to family farming around 1997 coincided with the beginning of recovery in agriculture, namely resumption of agricultural growth after a phase of transition decline since 1991. In addition to growth in total agricultural production, we also observe significant increases in productivity of both land and labor since 1997. These observations suggest that productivity growth may be attributable to the changes in farming structure in Central Asia. To check this conjecture we assess the sources of growth by applying the standard Solow growth accounting methodology. Using time series of country statistics for farms of different organizational forms, we decompose the growth in output into growth in the resource base (extensive growth) and growth in productivity (intensive growth). Solow growth accounting clearly shows that, first, much of the growth at the country level is attributable to increases in productivity rather than increases in resources and, second, the increases in productivity in family farms (especially household plots) outstrip the increases in productivity in former collective and state farms. These findings confirm that the recovery of agricultural production in Central Asia has been driven largely by productivity increases, and it is the individual farms that are the main source of agricultural productivity increases.

FAO Regional Office for Europe and Central Asia Policy Studies on Rural Transition No. 2009-5 Sources of Agricultural Productivity Growth in Central Asia: The Case of Tajikistan and Uzbekistan Zvi Lerman and David Sedik September 2009 The Regional Office for Europe and Central Asia of the Food and Agriculture Organization distributes this policy study to disseminate findings of work in progress and to encourage the exchange of ideas within FAO and all others interested in development issues. This paper carries the name of the authors and should be used and cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations and conclusions are the authors’ own and should not be attributed to the Food and Agriculture Organization of the UN, its management, or any member countries. Zvi Lerman is Sir Henry d’Avigdor Goldsmid Professor of Agricultural Economics, The Hebrew University of Jerusalem, Israel David Sedik is the Senior Agricultural Policy Officer in the FAO Regional Office for Europe and Central Asia. Contents Introduction............................................................................................................................1 Agricultural development .......................................................................................................2 Changes in farm structure and land tenure since independence ...............................................2 Changing structure of agricultural production.........................................................................4 Recovery of agricultural production........................................................................................5 Productivity gains after 1997 ..................................................................................................6 Productivity as a source of production growth ........................................................................9 Conclusion ...........................................................................................................................10 References............................................................................................................................11 Policy Studies on Rural Transition .......................................................................................13 Sources of Agricultural Productivity Growth in Central Asia: The Case of Tajikistan and Uzbekistan Zvi Lerman and David J. Sedik The paper examines agricultural production and productivity growth in two Central Asian countries – Tajikistan and Uzbekistan. Both countries are characterized by a significant shift of resources from the traditional Soviet model of collective agriculture to more marketcompliant individual and family farming. In both countries, the beginning of the policy-driven switch to family farming around 1997 coincided with the beginning of recovery in agriculture, namely resumption of agricultural growth after a phase of transition decline since 1991. In addition to growth in total agricultural production, we also observe significant increases in productivity of both land and labor since 1997. These observations suggest that productivity growth may be attributable to the changes in farming structure in Central Asia. To check this conjecture we assess the sources of growth by applying the standard Solow growth accounting methodology. Using time series of country statistics for farms of different organizational forms, we decompose the growth in output into growth in the resource base (extensive growth) and growth in productivity (intensive growth). Solow growth accounting clearly shows that, first, much of the growth at the country level is attributable to increases in productivity rather than increases in resources and, second, the increases in productivity in family farms (especially household plots) outstrip the increases in productivity in former collective and state farms. These findings confirm that the recovery of agricultural production in Central Asia has been driven largely by productivity increases, and it is the individual farms that are the main source of agricultural productivity increases. Introduction One of the items on the agricultural reform agenda in former Soviet republics forming the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS) involves transformation from the traditional corporate farms to substantially smaller family or individual farms. This transformation is motivated by the theoretical incentive analysis of farms of different organizational forms in market economies, which suggests that family farms can be expected to achieve higher levels of productivity and efficiency than corporate farms (Allen and Lueck 2002). Tajikistan and Uzbekistan embarked on the process of land reform in 1991-1992, immediately after gaining independence. However, the first years were characterized by hesitant and indecisive progress, largely attributable to lack of experience with the huge task on hand. In Tajikistan in particular further difficulties were created by the civil war that raged in this country until 1997. After 1997-98, however, both countries began to implement resolutely a comprehensive program of land reform and farm restructuring that culminated in a massive shift of agricultural land and agricultural production to small individual and family farms. These achievements of land reform in Tajikistan and Uzbekistan are particularly remarkable because the two countries are generally regarded as slow reformers and are assigned low ranks for their reform performance by international organizations (Csaki and Kray 2005). 1 The ultimate goal of land reform in all transition countries is to increase the incomes and the standard of living of their large rural populations, which rely on agriculture for a substantial part of the family budget. Every CIS transition country attempts to achieve this goal by encouraging growth in the agricultural sector and, whenever possible, improving farm productivity. In this paper, we accordingly analyze agricultural growth and productivity improvements in two specific Central Asian countries. The analysis is based on official country statistics of Tajikistan and Uzbekistan, the sources for which are listed under References at the end. Agricultural development Agricultural development in Tajikistan and Uzbekistan, as represented by changes in Gross Agricultural Output (GAO), exhibits four distinct stages (Figure 1) – robust Soviet growth (up to 1980), stagnation during the Gorbachev period (1980-1990), transition decline (from 1991 to 1996-97), and finally recovery (since 1997-98). The transition decline that began in 1990-91 exhibited the classic features of decline observed in all post-Soviet countries: the disintegration of the traditional Soviet agricultural system, with its rigidly planned supplies of inputs to and purchases of outputs from collective and state farms at fixed prices, caused a dramatic fall in agricultural production after 1991. This fall in production was largely due to the fall in the use of purchased inputs, including feed, machinery, and fertilizers, and the shrinkage of the livestock herd as a production resource. 400 350 300 250 Taj Uzb 200 150 100 50 0 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Figure 1. Growth of agricultural production in Tajikistan and Uzbekistan, 1965-2007 (GAO in percent of 1965). The transition decline was much more pronounced in Tajikistan than in Uzbekistan. By 1997 agricultural production in Tajikistan had fallen to levels not seen since the early 1960s. The perception of the transition decline in the 1990s was undoubtedly all the more negative because it was preceded by decades of steady agricultural growth during the Soviet period, as the GAO index in both countries doubled between 1965 and 1988, despite the relative slowdown during Gorbachev’s rule in the 1980s. Changes in farm structure and land tenure since independence Soviet agriculture was characterized by co-existence of two farm structures: large collective and state farms (“farm enterprises” or “agricultural enterprises”), which represented the formal commercial farm sector, and very small subsistence-oriented household plots, which constituted the “private” sector all through the Soviet era. Land reform processes in all CIS countries substantially enlarged the household plots through land allocation programs and in 2 addition created a new private sector of so-called “peasant farms”, which by design were larger and more commercially oriented than the traditional household plots. The farm structure in almost all CIS countries today is characterized by the existence of three farm types that span the entire spectrum of sizes: large corporate farms (“enterprises”) that succeeded the former collective and state farms; mid-sized peasant farms; and small (albeit enlarged) household plots that survived the Soviet regime. Household plots and peasant farms are classified as individual or family farms. By contrast, the successors of agricultural enterprises are referred to as corporate farms.1 1200 '000 ha 1000 800 Households Peasant farms Enterprises 600 400 Figure 2. Use of arable land by farms of different organizational forms in Tajikistan, 1991-2007 (million hectares). 200 0 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 5 mln ha 4 3 Households Peasant farms Enterprises 2 Figure 3. Use of arable land by farms of different organizational forms in Uzbekistan, 1991-2006 (million hectares). 1 0 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 Up to 1990, Soviet agriculture in Tajikistan and Uzbekistan, as in all other former Soviet republics, was characterized by total dominance of large collective and state farms, which controlled over 90% of both agricultural and arable land in the pre-reform era. The dominance of large agricultural enterprises began to wane when serious land reform measures were launched in the second half of the 1990s (after 1997-98; the bottom layer in Figures 2, 3). The share of arable land in enterprises dropped steadily from the Soviet level of over 90% to around 20% in 2007. Much of this land shifted to new emergent farm structures – the socalled peasant farms, which now control 60% of arable land, more than double what remains 1 There is a potential for terminological confusion among individual farms. In Tajikistan, peasant farms are called “dekhkan farms” (“dekhkan” or “dehqan” is literally a peasant in Central Asian languages). In Uzbekistan, on the other hand, peasant farms are called “fermery” in Uzbek or “fermerskie khozyaistva” in Russian, while the term “dekhkan farms” today designates the small household plots cultivated by the rural population at large. Regardless of the specific name used, the two types of individual farms are subject to different laws in the two countries. 3 in corporate farms. The remaining 10%-20% of arable land is in household plots – the traditional private agriculture carried over from the Soviet era. Their share also increased markedly through allocation of additional land in the process of land reform (again at the expense of agricultural enterprises). The changes in land holdings are presented for selected years in Table 1. The share of the individual farming sector – both household plots and peasant farms – increased from about 3% to 30% in agricultural land since 1991. The share of individual farms – both household plots and peasant farms – in arable land rose from less than 10% to around 80%, but it is the newly created peasant farms that now control most of the arable land in Tajikistan and Uzbekistan. Pastures are still largely managed by agricultural enterprises, which is reflected in their higher share of agricultural land, especially in Uzbekistan (agricultural land includes pastures as well as arable land). Table 1. Structure of land use by farm type 1991-2007 Agricultural land Enterprises Peasant Household farms plots Tajikistan 1991 98 0 2 1995 98 0 2 2000 64 32 4 2007 30 64 6 Uzbekistan 1991 1995 2000 2006 98 97 94 68 0 1 4 29 2 2 2 3 Enterprises Arable land Peasant farms Household plots 95 93 63 19 0 1 29 62 5 6 8 19 92 88 72 25 0 3 18 65 8 9 10 11 Changing structure of agricultural production The differential changes in the distribution of land across farms of different organizational types have led to striking changes in the structure of agricultural production, especially after 1997-1998. The production in enterprises shrank dramatically from around 40% in 1997 to less than 10% in 2007. The production in household plots remained fairly stable at close to 60% of the total. The production in peasant farms took up the slack released by the shrinkage of enterprises, increasing from 3% in 1997 to about 30% in 2007. We clearly see from Figures 4, 5 that agricultural production has in fact shifted from enterprises to peasant farms since 1997: the decrease in production in agricultural enterprises (bottom dark gray layer) has been compensated by a corresponding increase in production in peasant farms (black layer above it), while the household plots (top light gray layer) have retained a dominant – and relatively constant – share throughout the entire period despite their small share in arable land.2 The observed shift in production from enterprises to peasant farms is consistent with the shifts in arable land in Figures 2, 3. 2 The changes in production structure by farm type in Figures 4, 5 reflect primarily crop production, as in livestock production, the household sector is a clear leader, with over 90% of the output over time. 4 100% 80% 60% Households Peasant farms Enterprises 40% Figure 4. Structure of agricultural production (GAO) by farm type in Tajikistan, 1997-2007 20% 0% 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 100% 80% 60% households peasant farms enterprises 40% 20% 0% Figure 5. Structure of agricultural production (GAO) by farm type in Uzbekistan, 1997-2007. 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Table 2. Structure of agricultural production by farm type 1997-2007 Tajikistan 1997 2002 2007 1997 Agricultural production Enterprises 46 38 14 36 Peasant farms 3 14 28 3 Household plots 51 48 58 61 Crop production Enterprises 52 35 14 63 Peasant farms 4 22 35 4 Household plots 44 43 50 33 Livestock production Enterprises 13 5 3 10 Peasant farms 0 1 3 1 Household plots 87 94 94 89 Uzbekistan 2002 2007 26 10 64 3 33 64 43 18 40 2 57 41 9 2 89 4 4 93 Recovery of agricultural production The transition decline changed to recovery around 1997, and both countries registered impressive growth in agricultural production, which rose between 1997 and 2007 by more than 90% for Tajikistan and nearly 70% for Uzbekistan (black curve in Figures 6, 7). This growth was driven entirely by the individual sector, i.e., household plots and peasant farms, as the corporate sector (agicultural enterprises) continued its general decline after 1997 (gray 5 curve in Figures 6, 7).3 The process of agricultural reform encouraging and emphasizing transition from the traditional large-scale enterprises to individual farms – both peasant farms and enlarged household plots – has produced remarkable results in terms of production growth in agriculture. This effect of agricultural growth spurred by individualization of agriculture is not unique to Tajikistan and Uzbekistan: it is observed also in other CIS countries that have encouraged transition to individual farming. 120 percent of 1991 (based on 2003 prices) 100 80 All farms Enterprises 60 Figure 6. Growth of agricultural production for all farms and agricultural enterprises in Tajikistan, 1991-2007 (GAO in percent of 1991, based on constant prices). 40 20 0 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 160 140 120 100 all farms enterprises 80 60 40 20 0 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Figure 7. Growth of agricultural production for all farms and agricultural enterprises in Uzbekistan, 1991-2006 (GAO in percent of 1991, based on constant prices). Productivity gains after 1997 Growth in agricultural output can originate from increases in the resources utilized (so-called extensive growth) or from increases in the efficiency with which resources are employed (intensive growth). For example, the value of crop production can increase as a result of increases in sown area, increases in the productivity with which farms utilize land, or a combination of these two factors. Likewise, growth in the value of livestock production can derive from increases in livestock inventories, increases in the productivity with which farms make use of livestock (e.g., milk yields achieved by dairy farmers), or a combination of the two. The rationale behind agrarian reform has always been the potential productivity gains due to the transfer of land and other assets from collective and state farms to individual farms. Therefore, an important indicator of the success of reforms is the presence or absence of productivity increases as a source of recovery. 3 Figures 6, 7 show the agricultural production curves for all farms and for agricultural enterprises only, as the curve for individual farms rises so steeply that it simply goes off the vertical scale. 6 Productivity can be calculated in physical units, as the number of kilograms produced per hectare (for crops) or per cow (for milk). More generally, agricultural productivity is calculated in aggregated value terms as partial productivity of land (aggregated value of agricultural output per hectare of agricultural land) and partial productivity of labor (aggregated value of agricultural output per agricultural worker, including self-employed peasants).4 Figures 8, 9 show the three curves that constitute the basis for value-based productivity calculations: agricultural production (gray curve), agricultural land in use (thin black curve), and agricultural labor (thick black curve). The curves span the period 1980-2007 and they are all normalized to index numbers with 1980=100, thus eliminating problems due to differences in units of measurement. 250 1980=100 200 150 GAO AgLand Labor 100 Figure 8. Basic data for productivity calculations: GAO, agricultural land, and agricultural labor for Tajikistan, 1980-2007 (index numbers in percent of 1980). 50 0 1980 200 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 1980=100 150 labor land GAO 100 50 0 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 Figure 9. Basic data for productivity calculations: GAO, agricultural land, and agricultural labor for Uzbekistan, 1980-2007 (index numbers in percent of 1980). In both Tajikistan and Uzbekistan, agricultural output (GAO) has increased dramatically since 1997, while agricultural land has remained generally constant (in Tajikistan) or even declined (in Uzbekistan). This essentially means that the partial productivity of land increased, almost doubling (in constant prices) between 1997 and 2007 in both countries (Figure 10). Agricultural labor, unlike agricultural land, showed steady increase in Tajikistan since 1980, but its increase lagged behind the growth in agricultural output after 1997 and as a result the productivity of agricultural labor also increased between 1997 and 2007, although more moderately than the productivity of land (Figure 10). In Uzbekistan, the steady increase of 4 More sophisticated measures rely on total factor productivity (TFP), which aggregates the partial measures into one index that allows for the entire basket of resources and inputs used in agriculture. TFP is technically difficult to calculate, however, as it requires estimation of the production function to obtain the weights for the aggregation of inputs. 7 agricultural labor during the Soviet period changed to moderate decline after 1990 (Figure 9), which combined with growth in agricultural production led to a robust increase in partial productivity of labor after 1997 (Figure 11). Agricultural reforms in Tajikistan and Uzbekistan are thus seen to have had a highly beneficial outcome, producing robust growth in both production and productivity. Another dimension that needs to be checked in future work is the impact of these processes on rural incomes and the wellbeing of the rural population. 700 somoni/ha somoni/worker 3500 600 3000 500 2500 400 2000 300 1500 200 1000 100 500 land labor Figure 10. Productivity of land and labor in Tajikistan, 1991-2007 (GAO per hectare of agricultural land and per agricultural worker, all farms, somoni per ha in constant 2003 prices). 0 0 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 300 1980=100 250 200 land labor 150 Figure 11. Productivity of land and labor in Uzbekistan, 1980-2006 (GAO per hectare of agricultural land and per agricultural worker, all farms, in percent of 1980). 100 50 0 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 The case for land reform and the potential yield improving effects can be seen in Figure 12 which shows (for Tajikistan) the huge differences in productivity of land between household plots on one side and enterprises and peasant farms on the other. Household plots – the undisputed individual farms in all CIS countries – consistently achieve much higher levels of land productivity: agricultural land in household plots is utilized 20 to 50 times more productively than in farms of other types. Further redistribution of land to household plots could substantially increase average productivity in agriculture, thus leading to a large increase in agricultural production. Figure 12 also illustrates that farms of all three types in Tajikistan achieved increases in land productivity since 1999. While growth in agricultural production was driven entirely by the individual sector (see Figure 6), the growth in land productivity appears to be driven by farms of all organizational forms. At the same time it is noteworthy that peasant farms in Tajikistan are not doing better than agricultural enterprises on average. This puzzling result may stem 8 from the fact that at least one-third of the peasant farms in Tajikistan are not really individual farms at all: they are collective dehkan farms (partnerships) created in the process of reorganization of traditional farm enterprises and their incentives are closer to those of corporate farms than individual farms. Many of these collective dehkan farms were only cosmetically reorganized and the management structures have remained unchanged (FAO 2004). Under these circumstances we should not be surprised that the productivity of peasant farms in Tajikistan, taken as a heterogeneous group, is not different from that of the farm enterprises they succeeded. Future analytical efforts should attempt to separate the performance of individual dehkan farms from collective dehkan farms in Tajikistan. 100000 somoni/ha (2003 prices) 10000 1000 Enterprises Peasant farms Households Figure 12. Productivity of land by farm type in Tajikistan, 1991-2007 (GAO per hectare of agricultural land, by type of farm, somoni per ha in constant 2003 prices, log scale). 100 10 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Productivity as a source of production growth To assess the sources of growth since 1997, we applied the standard Solow growth accounting methodology, which separates growth in output into two components: growth in the resource base (extensive) and growth in productivity (intensive). Tables 3, 4 show the change in the value of crop production (in constant prices) since 1997 and the corresponding change in the resource base (represented by the sown area). The growth in production not accounted for by the change in the resource component is by definition the contribution from increases in productivity. The decomposition in Table 3 shows that 55% of growth in crop production in Tajikistan is attributable to increases in land area, while the remaining 45% can be attributed to increases in productivity. The numbers for livestock production are essentially the same (57% due to change in herd size, 43% due to changes in productivity). For Uzbekistan as a whole, the increase in aggregate value of crop production was achieved in parallel with a decrease in sown area (Table 4). In other words, growth in agricultural output occurred despite a decrease in resources, and this may be interpreted as indicating that the entire change in output (100%) was attributable to productivity, with no contribution whatsoever from change in resources. There are large differences in the contribution of productivity growth by farm type and by country. Yet individual farms seem to be associated with larger productivity changes: household plots and peasant farms in Uzbekistan achieve implied productivity change of 1.61.7 (compared with 1.4 for enterprises), and in Tajikistan household plots – individual farms par excellence – achieve an implied productivity change of 2.1 (peasant farms in Tajikistan are a heterogeneous groups consisting of both individual and collective dehkan farms, which 9 may account for their lower productivity change component: see the previous discussion in connection with Figure 12). Table 3. Changes in output and resources in crop production for farms of different types in Tajikistan, 1997-2006 (2006/1997, times) Tajikistan Agricultural Peasant farms Household enterprises plots Aggregate value of crop production 2.0 0.6 17.2 2.3 Sown area 1.1 0.4 16.7 1.1 Implied productivity change 1.8 1.3 1.0 2.1 Contribution of change in resources 55 78 97 48 to change in production (%) Percent of aggregate crop production 100 14 36 50 in 2006 (%) Table 4. Changes in output and resources in crop production for farms of different types in Uzbekistan, 1997-2007 (2007/1997, times) Uzbekistan Agricultural Peasant farms Household enterprises plots Aggregate value of crop production 2.04 0.04 19.83 1.84 Sown area 0.86 0.03 11.45 1.17 Implied productivity change 2.4 1.4 1.7 1.6 Contribution of change in resources 0 70 58 64 to change in production (%) Percent of aggregate crop production 100 2 57 41 in 2006 (%) Tables 3, 4 confirm that the recovery of agricultural production in Tajikistan and Uzbekistan has been driven to a considerable by productivity increases (intensive growth), less by changes in resources (extensive growth). They also confirm that the majority of productivity change contributing to GAO growth has come from individual farms (household plots and peasant farms in Uzbekistan; household plots only in Tajikistan) rather than from corporate farm types. Conclusion The empirical results of this paper have important implications for the ongoing policy debate between the supporters of large corporate farms, who continue to advocate economies of scale, and the supporters of smaller family farms, who emphasize the advantages of individual incentives. This debate is not limited to Central Asia, and it is relevant also for the rest of the CIS. The results will hopefully inform this ongoing debate and incrementally add to the growing body of evidence that highlights the performance advantages of family farms in transition countries. The analysis in this paper is based on aggregate country statistics. Ongoing work not reported here utilizes cross-section data from several farm surveys conducted in Tajikistan and Uzbekistan by international organizations (Asian Development Bank, FAO, UNDP, USAID, World Bank) between 2003 and 2008. From these survey data we intend to calculate partial land and labor productivity, total factor productivity (based on both accounting data and the production function approach), and technical efficiency scores for farms of different organizational forms. We believe that these future results will demonstrate that, contrary to established convictions among decision makers in Central Asia and the rest of the 10 Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS), the large corporate farms (former collectives) are not more productive than the smaller family farms. Moreover, some subsectors of the individual farm sector (specifically, the small household plots) are resoundingly more productive than the large corporate farms. These anticipated findings for two Central Asian countries will reinforce recent results for Ukraine (Lerman et al. 2007), Moldova (Lerman and Sutton 2008), Russia (Lerman and Schreinemachers 2005), and the United States (Ahearn et al. 2002), which demonstrate that large (corporate) farms do not perform better than small (family) farms. References Ahearn, M., Yee, J., Huffman, W. (2002). “The effect of contracting and consolidation on farm productivity,” paper presented at the Economics of Contracting in Agriculture Workshop, Annapolis, MD (July). Allen, D.W. and Lueck, D. (2002). The Nature of the Farm: Contracts, Risk, and Organization in Agriculture, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press. Csaki, C. and Kray, H. (2005), The Agrarian Economies of Central-Eastern Europe and the CIS: An Update on Status and Progress in 2004, ECSSD Environmentally and Socially Sustainable Development Working Paper, No. 40, World Bank, Washington, DC (June). FAO (2004), Inception Mission Report OSRO/TAJ/402/CAN (June). Lerman, Z. and Schreinemachers, P. (2005). “Individual farming as a labor sink: Evidence from Poland and Russia,” Comparative Economic Studies, 47(4): 675-695 (December). Lerman, Z., Sedik, D., Pugachov, N., and Goncharuk, A. (2007), Rethinking Agricultural Reform in Ukraine, Studies on the Agricultural and Food Sector in Central and Eastern Europe, Vol. 38, IAMO, Halle, Germany. Lerman, Z. and Sutton, W. (2008), “Productivity and Efficiency of Small and Large Farms in Transition: Evidence from Moldova,” Post-Soviet Affairs, 24(2): 97-120. Official statistical publications: Tajikistan Agriculture in Tajikistan, statistical yearbook, Dushanbe, 2001, 2002, 2003, 2004, 2005, 2006, 2007, 2008. Tajikistan: 15 Years of Independence), statistical yearbook, Dushanbe, 2006. Statistical Yearbook of Tajikistan, Dushanbe, 2005, 2007. Tajikistan in Figures 2008), statistical digest, Dushanbe, 2008. The Economy of Tajik SSR, statistical yearbook, Dushanbe, 1981, 1984, 1985, 1988. Official statistical publications: Uzbekistan Statistical Yearbook of Uzbekistan 2004, Tashkent (2005), in Uzbek and Russian. Agriculture in Uzbekistan 2006, statistical yearbook, Tashkent (2007). Agriculture in Uzbekistan 2008, statistical yearbook, Tashkent (2007). Uzbekistan in Numbers 2008, statistical yearbook, Tashkent (2008). The Economy of Uzbek SSR, statistical yearbook, Tashkent, 1981, 1984, 1985, 1989. 11 12 FAO Regional Office for Europe and Central Asia Policy Studies on Rural Transition 2009-5 2009-4 2009-3 2009-2 2009-1 2008-2 2008-1 Sources of Agricultural Productivity Growth in Central Asia: The Case of Tajikistan and Uzbekistan. Zvi Lerman and David Sedik The Diversity of Effects of EU Membership on Agriculture in New Member States. Csaba Csaki and Attila Jambor Agricultural Recovery and Individual Land Tenure: Lessons from Central Asia. Zvi Lerman and David Sedik The Feed-Livestock Nexus in Tajikistan: Livestock Development Policy in Transition. David Sedik Agrarian Reform in Kyrgyzstan: Achievements and the Unfinished Agenda. Zvi Lerman and David Sedik Farm Debt in Transition: The Problem and Possible Solutions. Zvi Lerman The Economic Effects of Land Reform in Tajikistan. Zvi Lerman and David Sedik 13 Regional Office for Europe and Central Asia Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations 34 Benczur ut. 1068 Budapest, Hungary Telephone: +36 1 461 2000 Fax: +36 1 351 7029 http://www.fao.org/world/Regional/REU 14