Academia.eduAcademia.edu

Connections Among Farsighted Agents

2011, Journal of Public Economic Theory

We study the stability of social and economic networks when players are farsighted. In particular, we examine whether the networks formed by farsighted players are different from those formed by myopic players. We adopt Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch's (Games and Economic Behavior, forthcoming) notion of pairwise farsightedly stable set. We first investigate in some classical models of social and economic networks whether the pairwise farsightedly stable sets of networks coincide with the set of pairwise (myopically) stable networks and the set of strongly efficient networks. We then provide some primitive conditions on value functions and allocation rules so that the set of strongly efficient networks is the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set. Under the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule, the set of strongly efficient networks and the set of pairwise (myopically) stable networks that are immune to coalitional deviations are the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set if and only if the value function is top convex.

NOTA DI LAVORO 30.2009 Connections Among Farsighted Agents By Gilles Grandjean, CORE, Université catholique de Louvain Ana Mauleon, FNRS and CEREC, Facultés universitaires Saint-Louis and FNRS and CORE, Université catholique de Louvain Vincent Vannetelbosch, FNRS and CORE, Université catholique de Louvain SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT Series Editor: Carlo Carraro Connections Among Farsighted Agents By Gilles Grandjean, CORE, Université catholique de Louvain Ana Mauleon, FNRS and CEREC, Facultés universitaires Saint-Louis and FNRS and CORE, Université catholique de Louvain Vincent Vannetelbosch, FNRS and CORE, Université catholique de Louvain Summary We study the stability of social and economic networks when players are farsighted. In particular, we examine whether the networks formed by farsighted players are different from those formed by myopic players. We adopt Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch’s (Games and Economic Behavior, forthcoming) notion of pairwise farsightedly stable set. We first investigate in some classical models of social and economic networks whether the pairwise farsightedly stable sets of networks coincide with the set of pairwise (myopically) stable networks and the set of strongly efficient networks. We then provide some primitive conditions on value functions and allocation rules so that the set of strongly efficient networks is the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set. Under the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule, the set of strongly efficient networks and the set of pairwise (myopically) stable networks that are immune to coalitional deviations are the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set if and only if the value function is top convex. Keywords: Farsighted Players, Stability, Efficiency, Connections Model, Buyerseller Networks JEL Classification: A14, C70, D20 Vincent Vannetelbosch and AnaMauleon are Research Associates of the National Fund for Scienti.c Research (FNRS). Vincent Vannetelbosch is Associate Fellow of CEREC, Facultés Universitaires Saint-Louis. Financial support from Spanish Min- isterio de Educacion y Ciencia under the project SEJ 2006-06309/ECON, support from the Belgian French Community.s program Action de Recherches Concertée 03/08-302 and 05/10-331 (UCL) and support of a SSTC grant from the Belgian Federal government under the IAP contract P6/09 are gratefully acknowledged. This paper has been presented at the 14th Coalition Theory Network Workshop held in Maastricht, The Netherlands, on 23-24 January 2009 and organised by the Maastricht University CTN group (Department of Economics, http://www.feem-web.it/ctn/12d_maa.php). Address for correspondence: Vincent Vannetelbosch Université catholique de Louvain 34 voie du Roman Pays B-1348 Louvain-la-Neuve Belgium E-mail: vincent.vannetelbosch@uclouvain.be The opinions expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect the position of Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Corso Magenta, 63, 20123 Milano (I), web site: www.feem.it, e-mail: working.papers@feem.it Connections among farsighted agents y Gilles Grandjeana, Ana Mauleonb;c, Vincent Vannetelboschc a CORE, Université catholique de Louvain, 34 voie du Roman Pays, B-1348 Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium. b FNRS and CEREC, Facultés universitaires Saint-Louis, Boulevard du Jardin Botanique 43, B-1000 Brussels, Belgium. c FNRS and CORE, Université catholique de Louvain, 34 voie du Roman Pays, B-1348 Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium. April 27, 2009 Abstract We study the stability of social and economic networks when players are farsighted. In particular, we examine whether the networks formed by farsighted players are di¤erent from those formed by myopic players. We adopt Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch’s (Games and Economic Behavior, forthcoming) notion of pairwise farsightedly stable set. We …rst investigate in some classical models of social and economic networks whether the pairwise farsightedly stable sets of networks coincide with the set of pairwise (myopically) stable networks and the set of strongly e¢cient networks. We then provide some primitive conditions on value functions and allocation rules so that the set of strongly e¢cient networks is the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set. Under the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule, the set of strongly e¢cient networks and the set of pairwise (myopically) stable networks that are immune to coalitional deviations are the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set if and only if the value function is top convex. JEL classi…cation: A14, C70, D20 Keywords: Farsighted players, Stability, E¢ciency, Connections model, Buyerseller networks. y Corresponding author: Prof. Vincent Vannetelbosch. E-mail addresses: gilles.grandjean@uclouvain.be (Gilles Grandjean), mauleon@fusl.ac.be (Ana Mauleon), vincent.vannetelbosch@uclouvain.be (Vincent Vannetelbosch). 1 Introduction The organization of individual agents into networks and groups or coalitions plays an important role in the determination of the outcome of many social and economic interactions. For instance, networks of personal contacts are important in obtaining information on goods and services, like product information or information about job opportunities. Many commodities are traded through networks of buyers and sellers. A simple way to analyze the networks that one might expect to emerge in the long run is to examine the requirement that individuals do not bene…t from altering the structure of the network. An example of such a condition is the pairwise stability notion de…ned by Jackson and Wolinsky (1996). A network is pairwise stable if no individual bene…ts from severing one of her links and no two individuals bene…t from adding a link between them, with one bene…ting strictly and the other at least weakly. Pairwise stability is a myopic de…nition. Individuals are not forward-looking in the sense that they do not forecast how others might react to their actions. For instance, the adding or severing of one link might lead to subsequent addition or severing of another link. If individuals have very good information about how others might react to changes in the network, then these are things one wants to allow for in the de…nition of the stability concept. For instance, a network could be stable because individuals might not add a link that appears valuable to them given the current network, as that might in turn lead to the formation of other links and ultimately lower the payo¤s of the original individuals. Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch (2009) have proposed the notion of pairwise farsightedly stable sets of networks that predicts which networks one might expect to emerge in the long run when players are farsighted.1 A set of networks G is pairwise farsightedly stable (i) if all possible pairwise deviations from any network g 2 G to a network outside G are deterred by the threat of ending worse o¤ or equally well o¤, (ii) if there exists a farsighted improving path from any network outside the set leading to some network in the set,2 and (iii) if there is no proper subset 1 Jackson (2003, 2005) provides surveys of models of network formation. Other approaches to farsightedness in network formation are suggested by the work of Chwe (1994), Xue (1998), Herings, Mauleon, and Vannetelbosch (2004), Mauleon and Vannetelbosch (2004), Page, Wooders and Kamat (2005), Dutta, Ghosal, and Ray (2005), and Page and Wooders (2009). 2 A farsighted improving path is a sequence of networks that can emerge when players form or sever links based on the improvement the end network o¤ers relative to the current network. Each 1 of G satisfying Conditions (i) and (ii). A non-empty pairwise farsightedly stable set always exists. Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch (2009) have provided a full characterization of unique pairwise farsightedly stable sets of networks. Contrary to other pairwise concepts, pairwise farsighted stability yields a Pareto dominant network, if it exists, as the unique outcome. They have also studied the relationship between pairwise farsighted stability and other concepts such as the largest pairwise consistent set and the von Neumann-Morgenstern pairwise farsightedly stable set.3 The objective of this paper is twofold. First, we investigate in some classical models of social and economic networks whether the pairwise farsightedly stable sets of networks coincide with the set of pairwise (myopically) stable networks and the set of strongly e¢cient networks. We reconsider three classical models of network formation: Jackson and Wolinsky’s (1996) symmetric connections model; Corominas-Bosch’s (2004) model of trading networks with bilateral bargaining; and Kranton and Minehart’s (2001) model of buyer-seller networks. We have chosen to analyze those models because they have di¤erent features. The symmetric connections model is a situation where homogeneous individuals obtain payo¤s not only from direct but also from indirect connections (where links represent social relationships between individuals such as friendships), while the models of buyer-seller networks are situations where heterogeneous individuals (sellers and buyers) bargain over prices for trade (where direct links are necessary for a transaction to occur). We …nd that, in the symmetric connections model, myopic or farsighted notions of stability do not diverge in terms of predictions. Therefore, farsightedness does not eliminate the con‡ict between stability and strong e¢ciency that may occur when costs are intermediate. In the bargaining model of Corominas-Bosch (2004), myopic or farsighted notions of stability sustain the set of strongly e¢cient networks when the costs of maintaining links are not too large. In the Kranton and Minehart (2001) model, pairwise farsighted stability may sustain the strongly e¢cient network while network in the sequence di¤ers by one link from the previous one. If a link is added, then the two players involved must both prefer the end network to the current network, with at least one of the two strictly preferring the end network. If a link is deleted, then it must be that at least one of the two players involved in the link strictly prefers the end network. 3 Notice that any von Neumann-Morgenstern pairwise farsightedly stable set is a pairwise farsightedly stable set. But, von Neumann-Morgenstern pairwise farsightedly stable set may fail to exist. Pairwise farsightedly stable sets have no relationship to either largest pairwise consistent sets or sets of pairwise stable networks. 2 pairwise (myopic) stability only sustains networks that are strongly ine¢cient or even Pareto dominated. Second, we provide some primitive conditions on value functions and allocation rules so that the set of strongly e¢cient networks is the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set. We …nd that, under the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule, the set of strongly e¢cient networks and the set of pairwise (myopically) stable networks that are immune to coalitional deviations are the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set if and only if the value function is top convex. A value function is top convex if some strongly e¢cient network also maximizes the per capita value among individuals. The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we introduce some notations and basic properties and de…nitions for networks. In Section 3 we de…ne the notion of pairwise farsightedly stable set of networks. In Section 4 we reconsider Jackson and Wolinsky (1996) symmetric connections model. In Section 5 we reconsider the bargaining model of Corominas-Bosch (2004) and the Kranton and Minehart (2001) model of buyer-seller networks. In Section 6 we look at the relationship between farsighted stability and e¢ciency of networks. In Section 7 we conclude. 2 Networks Let N = f1; : : : ; ng be the …nite set of players who are connected in some network relationship. The network relationships are reciprocal and the network is thus modeled as a non-directed graph. Individuals are the nodes in the graph and links indicate bilateral relationships between individuals. Thus, a network g is simply a list of which pairs of individuals are linked to each other. We write ij 2 g to indicate that i and j are linked under the network g. Let g N be the collection of all subsets of N with cardinality 2, so g N is the complete network. The set of all possible networks or graphs on N is denoted by G and consists of all subsets of g N : The network obtained by adding link ij to an existing network g is denoted g + ij and the network that results from deleting link ij from an existing network g is denoted g ij. For any network g, let N (g) = fi j 9 j such that ij 2 gg be the set of players who have at least one link in the network g. A path in a network g 2 G between i and j is a sequence of players i1 ; : : : ; iK such that ik ik+1 2 g for each k 2 f1; : : : ; K 1g with i1 = i and iK = j. A non-empty network h 3 g is a component of g, if for all i 2 N (h) and j 2 N (h) n fig; there exists a path in h connecting i and j, and for any i 2 N (h) and j 2 N (g), ij 2 g implies ij 2 h. The set of components of g is denoted by C(g). Knowing the components of a network, we can partition the players into groups within which players are connected. Let (g) denote the partition of N induced by the network g.4 A value function is a function v : G ! R that keeps track of how the total societal value varies across di¤erent networks. The set of all possible value functions is denoted by V. An allocation rule is a function Y : G V ! RN that keeps track of how the value is allocated among the players forming a network. It satis…es P i2N Yi (g; v) = v(g) for all v and g. Jackson and Wolinsky (1996) have proposed a number of basic properties of value functions and allocation rules. A value function is component additive if v(g) = P h2C(g) v(h) for all g 2 G. Component additive value functions are the ones for which the value of a network is the sum of the value of its components. An allocation rule Y is component balanced if for any component additive v 2 V, g 2 G, and P h 2 C(g), we have i2N (h) Yi (h; v) = v(h). Component balancedness only puts conditions on Y for v’s that are component additive, so Y can be arbitrary otherwise. Given a permutation of players and any g 2 G, let g = f (i) (j) j ij 2 gg. Thus, g is a network that is identical to g up to a permutation of the players. A value function is anonymous if for any permutation and any g 2 G, v(g ) = v(g). Given a permutation , let v be de…ned by v (g) = v(g 1 ) for each g 2 G. An allocation rule Y is anonymous if for any v 2 V, g 2 G, and permutation , we have Y (i) (g ; v ) = Yi (g; v). An allocation rule that is component balanced and anonymous is the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule. For a component additive v and network g, the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule Y ce is such that for any h 2 C(g) and each i 2 N (h), Yice (g; v) = v(h)=#N (h). For a v that is not component additive, Y ce (g; v) = v(g)=n for all g; thus, Y ce splits the value v(g) equally among all players if v is not component additive. In evaluating societal welfare, we may take various perspectives. A network g is Pareto e¢cient relative to v and Y if there does not exist any g 0 2 G such that Yi (g 0 ; v) 4 Yi (g; v) for all i with at least one strict inequality. A network g 2 G is Throughout the paper we use the notation for weak inclusion and Finally, # will refer to the notion of cardinality. 4 for strict inclusion. strongly e¢cient relative to v if v(g) v(g 0 ) for all g 0 2 G. This is a strong notion of e¢ciency as it takes the perspective that value is fully transferable. A simple way to analyze the networks that one might expect to emerge in the long run is to examine the requirement that agents do not bene…t from altering the structure of the network. A weak version of such a condition is the pairwise stability notion de…ned by Jackson and Wolinsky (1996). A network is pairwise stable if no player bene…ts from severing one of her links and no two players bene…t from adding a link between them, with one bene…ting strictly and the other at least weakly. Formally, a network g is pairwise stable with respect to value function v and allocation rule Y if (i) for all ij 2 g, Yi (g; v) Yi (g ij; v) and Yj (g; v) Yj (g ij; v), and (ii) for all ij 2 = g, if Yi (g; v) < Yi (g + ij; v) then Yj (g; v) > Yj (g + ij; v). 3 Pairwise farsightedly stable sets of networks A farsighted improving path is a sequence of networks that can emerge when players form or sever links based on the improvement the end network o¤ers relative to the current network. Each network in the sequence di¤ers by one link from the previous one. If a link is added, then the two players involved must both prefer the end network to the current network, with at least one of the two strictly preferring the end network. If a link is deleted, then it must be that at least one of the two players involved in the link strictly prefers the end network. We now introduce the formal de…nition of a farsighted improving path. De…nition 1. A farsighted improving path from a network g to a network g 0 6= g is a …nite sequence of graphs g1 ; : : : ; gK with g1 = g and gK = g 0 such that for any k 2 f1; : : : ; K (i) gk+1 = gk 1g either: ij for some ij such that Yi (gK ; v) > Yi (gk ; v) or Yj (gK ; v) > Yj (gk ; v), or (ii) gk+1 = gk + ij for some ij such that Yi (gK ; v) > Yi (gk ; v) and Yj (gK ; v) Yj (gk ; v). 5 If there exists a farsighted improving path from g to g 0 , then we write g ! g 0 . For a given network g, let F (g) = fg 0 2 G j g ! g 0 g. This is the set of networks that can be reached by a farsighted improving path from g. Thus, g ! g 0 means that g 0 is the endpoint of at least one farsighted improving path from g: Notice that F (g) may contain many networks and that a network g 0 2 F (g) might be the endpoint of several farsighted improving paths starting in g. We now introduce a solution concept due to Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch (2009), the pairwise farsightedly stable set. De…nition 2. A set of networks G G is pairwise farsightedly stable with respect v and Y if (i) 8 g 2 G, (ia) 8 ij 2 = g such that g+ij 2 = G, 9 g 0 2 F (g+ij)\G such that (Yi (g 0 ; v); Yj (g 0 , v)) = (Yi (g; v); Yj (g; v)) or Yi (g 0 ; v) < Yi (g; v) or Yj (g 0 ; v) < Yj (g; v), (ib) 8 ij 2 g such that g Yi (g 0 ; v) ij 2 = G, 9 g 0 ; g 00 2 F (g Yi (g; v) and Yj (g 00 ; v) ij) \ G such that Yj (g; v), (ii) 8g 0 2 G n G; F (g 0 ) \ G 6= ;: (iii) @ G0 G such that G0 satis…es Conditions (ia), (ib), and (ii). Condition (i) in De…nition 2 requires the deterrence of external deviations. Condition (ia) captures that adding a link ij to a network g 2 G that leads to a network outside of G; is deterred by the threat of ending in g 0 : Here g 0 is such that there is a farsighted improving path from g + ij to g 0 : Moreover, g 0 belongs to G; which makes g 0 a credible threat. Condition (ib) is a similar requirement, but then for the case where a link is severed. Condition (ii) in De…nition 2 requires external stability and implies that the networks within the set are robust to perturbations. From any network outside of G there is a farsighted improving path leading to some network in G. Condition (ii) implies that if a set of networks is pairwise farsightedly stable, it is non-empty. Notice that the set G (trivially) satis…es Conditions (ia), (ib), and (ii) in De…nition 2. This motivates the requirement of a minimality condition, namely Condition (iii). Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch (2009) have shown that a pairwise farsightedly stable set of networks always exists. 6 A network g strictly Pareto dominates all other networks if g is such that for all g 2 G n fgg it holds that, for all i, Yi (g; v) > Yi (g 0 ; v). Although the network that 0 strictly Pareto dominates all others is pairwise stable, there might be many more pairwise stable networks. Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch (2009) have shown that, if there is a network g that strictly Pareto dominates all other networks, then fgg is the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set. Thus, pairwise farsighted stability singles out the Pareto dominating network as the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set. 4 The symmetric connections model In Jackson and Wolinsky (1996) symmetric connections model, players form links with each other in order to exchange information. If player i is connected to player j by a path of t links, then player i receives a payo¤ of with player j. It is assumed that 0 < t from her indirect connection < 1, and so the payo¤ t decreases as the path connecting players i and j increases; thus information that travels a long distance becomes diluted and is less valuable than information obtained from a closer neighbor. Each direct link ij results in a cost c to both i and j. This cost can be interpreted as the time a player must spend with another player in order to maintain a direct link. Player i’s payo¤ from a network g is given by Yi (g) = X t(ij) j6=i X c, j:ij2g where t(ij) is the number of links in the shortest path between i and j (setting t(ij) = 1 if there is no path between i and j). Let g denote a star network encompassing everyone and g ? be the empty network (no links). Proposition 1 (Jackson and Wolinsky, 1996). Take the symmetric connections model. The unique strongly e¢cient network is (i) the complete network g N if c < (1 ), (ii) a star encompassing everyone if (1 (iii) the empty network if + ((n 2)=2) 2 ) < c < + ((n 2)=2) 2 , and < c. Proposition 2 (Jackson and Wolinsky, 1996). Take the symmetric connections model. For c < (1 g N . For (1 ), the unique pairwise stable network is the complete network ) < c < , a star encompassing all players is pairwise stable, but not necessarily the unique pairwise stable network. For 7 < c, any pairwise stable network which is non-empty is such that each player has at least two links and thus is ine¢cient. These two results show that there is a con‡ict between e¢ciency and pairwise stability for a large range of the parameters. Indeed, only for c < (1 ), there is no con‡ict between the e¢cient and the pairwise stable networks. When (1 )< c < , the e¢cient network is pairwise stable, but there are other pairwise stable networks that are not e¢cient. For < c < + ((n is never pairwise stable. And, …nally, for + ((n 2)=2) 2 , the e¢cient network 2)=2) 2 < c, the e¢cient network is pairwise stable, but there could be other pairwise stable networks that are not e¢cient. Proposition 3. Take the symmetric connections model. ), a set consisting of the complete network, fg N g, is the unique (i) For c < (1 pairwise farsightedly stable set. (ii) For (1 ) < c < , every set consisting of a star network encompassing all players, fg g, is a pairwise farsightedly stable set of networks, but they are not necessarily the unique pairwise farsightedly stable sets. (iii) For c > , a set consisting of the empty network, fg ? g, is the unique pairwise 2)=2) 2 . Otherwise, if farsightedly stable set if c > + ((n < c < + ((n 2)=2) 2 , fg ? g is not necessarily the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set. Proof. (i) Assume c < (1 ). Since < 1, we have that ( c) > 2 > 3 > ::: > n 1 . Thus, any two players who are not directly connected bene…t from forming a link. In this case, the complete network g N strictly Pareto dominates all other networks. That is, for every g 2 G n g N we have that, for all i, Yi (g N ) > Yi (g). Theorem 7 in Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch (2009) states that if there is a network g that strictly Pareto dominates all other networks, then fgg is the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set. Hence, we have that fg N g is the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set. (ii) Assume (1 ) < c < . Since 2 >( c), and 2 > 3 > ::: > n 1 , each player prefers an indirect link at a distance of two to any direct link and to any 8 indirect link at a distance greater than two. In a star network encompassing all players g there is n 1 links connecting one given player i to any other player j 2 N , j 6= i. Denote i(g ) the hub player at the star g . The payo¤ of the hub player i(g ) is Yi (g ) = (n player j, j 6= i(g ), is Yj (g ) = ( 1)( c) + (n c) and the payo¤ of any spoke 2 2) . Notice that the payo¤ of the spoke players is the maximum payo¤ a player can get in any network g 2 G. Using Theorem 4 in Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch (2009) which says that the set fgg is a pairwise farsightedly stable set if and only if for every g 0 2 G n fgg we have g 2 F (g 0 ), we will prove that every set consisting of a star network encompassing all players fg g is a pairwise farsightedly stable set since g 2 F (g) for any g 6= g . (ii.a) Consider …rst any network g containing at most n 1 links. Starting from the ? empty network g , it is straightforward to construct a farsightedly improving path leading to g so that g 2 F (g ? ). Take the hub player i and any other player and form the link between them. Then, add successively the links between the hub player and any other player until g is formed. Starting from any other network g with k n 1 links, if g is another star (g 6= g ) encom- passing all players, let the hub player at g, i(g), delete a link. Otherwise, if g is not a star encompassing all players, let any linked player j 6= i(g ) delete one link. In the next steps, any linked player di¤erent than i(g ) cuts one link until the empty network g ? is reached. From g ? , add successively the links between player i(g ) and the rest of the players until g is formed. Obviously, g 2 F (g) because every deviating player prefers g to the network they were facing before deviating in order to end up at g . (ii.b) Consider next any network g containing more than n 1 links. In such network g, there is always at least a player j 6= i(g ) with more than one direct link and that would like to move to g . From g, let one of such players delete one of her links. If the resulting network has still more than n 1 links, choose again a player l 6= i(g ) with more than one direct link and let her delete one link. The process continue until we reach at some point a network g 0 with n 0 0 1 links. If 0 g = g , we stop here. If g is another star (g 6= g ) encompassing all players, let the hub player at g 0 , i(g 0 ), delete a link. If g 0 is not a star encompassing all players, let any linked player j 6= i(g ) delete one link. In the next steps, any 9 linked player di¤erent than i(g ) cuts one link until the empty network g ? is reached. From g ? , add successively the links between player i(g ) and the rest of the players until g is formed. Thus, g 2 F (g) and Theorem 4 in Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch (2009) applies. (ii.c) It is straightforward to verify that, for n = 4, sets consisting of a star network encompassing all players are not the unique pairwise farsightedly stable sets. For instance, if (1 2 ) < c < , a set consisting of all lines where players get identical payo¤s is a pairwise farsightedly stable set. If (1 (1 2 ) < c < ), a set consisting of all circles is a pairwise farsightedly stable set. (iii.a) Assume …rst that c > + ((n 2)=2) 2 . In order to show that a set consisting of the empty network (with a payo¤ of 0 for all players) is the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set of networks, we need to show that Corollary 1 in Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch (2009) applies. That is, we need to show that g ? 2 F (g) for all g 6= g ? and that F (g ? ) = ?. Since c > + ((n 2)=2) 2 , the empty network g ? is the unique strongly e¢cient network. This implies that in any other network g, there is some player with a negative payo¤ that prefers the empty network and hence, we have that g 2 = F (g ? ). Now, from g, let one of the players with a negative payo¤ delete one of her links. Since in any resulting network g 0 there is some player preferring the empty network, by letting one of such players deleting one of her links at each step, we …nally end up at the empty network g ? , and g ? 2 F (g). Thus, g ? 2 F (g) for all g 6= g ? and Corollary 1 in Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch (2009) applies. (iii.b) Assume now that < c < + ((n 2)=2) 2 . In this case, the empty network is no more the strongly e¢cient network (a star encompassing everyone is the strongly e¢cient network). However, there are still some parameter values for which a set consisting of the empty network, fg ? g, is a pairwise farsightedly stable set. Indeed, the necessary and su¢cient condition in order to have that g ? 2 F (g) for all g 6= g ? is that mini Yi (g) < 0 for all g 6= g ? . That is, in every g 6= g ? , there should be a player with a negative payo¤ that would like to move to g ? (and then notice that every g 6= g ? is such that g 2 = F (g ? )). From any g 6= g ? , let at each step one of the players obtaining a negative payo¤ delete one of her links until g ? is reached. Thus, Corollary 1 in Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch (2009) applies, and fg ? g is the unique pairwise 10 farsightedly stable set. Notice that the above condition holds for values of c< + ((n 2)=2) 2 . On the contrary, if mini Yi (g) 0 for all i for some g 6= g ? , we have that g ? 2 = F (g) and then fg ? g is not a pairwise farsightedly stable set. However, it may happen that a set of networks containing among others the empty network is a pairwise farsightedly stable set of networks.5 Proposition 3 shows that replacing myopic by farsighted players in the symmetric connections model does not eliminate the con‡ict between strong e¢ciency and stability but, sometimes, it may help to reduce it. For instance, when +((n 2)=2) 2 < c, a set consisting of the unique strongly e¢cient network is the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set while other networks may be pairwise stable. Regarding the relationship between pairwise stability and pairwise farsighted stability, we observe that the concept of pairwise stability is quite robust to the introduction of farsighted players because, for a large range of parameters, we have that pairwise stable networks belong to pairwise farsightedly stable sets. Watts (2001) has analyzed the process of network formation in a dynamic framework where pairs of myopic players meet and decide whether or not to form or sever links with each other based on the improvement the resulting network o¤ers relative to the current network. If the bene…t from maintaining an indirect link is greater than the net bene…t from maintaining a direct link (case (ii) of Proposition 3), then it is di¢cult for the strongly e¢cient network (which is the star network) to form. In fact, starting at the empty network, the strongly e¢cient network only forms if the order in which the players meet takes a particular pattern. Moreover, as the number of players increases it becomes less likely that the strongly e¢cient network forms. These results contrast with ours, for such parameter values, since every set consisting of a star network is a pairwise farsightedly stable set whatever the number of farsighted players. Thus, it is not unlikely that forward looking players will increase the chances of the star forming. 5 Buyer-seller networks Corominas-Bosch (2004) has developed a simple model of trading networks with bilateral bargaining. The market consists of s sellers 1; 2; :::; s and b buyers s + 1; s + 5 For instance, in case of four players the set consisting of g ? , f12; 13; 34g and f14; 13; 32g is a pairwise farsightedly stable set. 11 2; :::; s + b. We denote the set of buyers as B and the set of sellers as S. Each seller owns a single object to sell that has no value to the seller. Buyers have a valuation of 1 for an object and do not care from whom they purchase the good. If a seller and a buyer trade at price p, the seller receives a payo¤ of p and the buyer a payo¤ of 1 p. Agents are embedded in a network that links sellers and buyers, and trade is only possible among linked agents. That is, a link in the network represents the opportunity for a buyer and a seller to bargain and potentially exchange an object.6 Let G(S; B) = fg 2 G j ij 2 g , i 2 S and j 2 Bg be the set of feasible buyer-seller networks. Agents incur a cost of maintaining each link equal to cs for sellers and to cb for buyers. So the payo¤ to an agent is her payo¤ from any trade on the network, less the cost of maintaining any links that she is involved with. In the …rst period sellers simultaneously call out prices. A buyer can only select from the prices that she has heard called out by the sellers to whom she is linked. Buyers simultaneously respond by either choosing to accept a single price o¤er received or rejecting all price o¤ers received.7 At the end of the period, trades are made and buyers and sellers who have traded are cleared from the market. In the next period the situation reverses and buyers call out prices. These are then either accepted or rejected by the sellers connected to them. Each period the role of proposer and responder alternates and this process repeats itself until all remaining buyers and sellers are not linked to each other. Buyers and sellers are impatient so that a transaction at price p in period t is worth buyer with 0 < t p to a seller and t (1 p) to a < 1 being the common discount factor. In a subgame perfect equi- librium with very patient agents ( close to 1), there are e¤ectively three possible outcomes for any given agent (ignoring the costs of maintaining links): either she gets all the available gains from trade (1), or half of the gains from trade (1=2), or none of the available gains from trade (0). Corominas-Bosch (2004) has provided an algorithm that subdivides any network into three types of subnetworks: those in which a set of sellers are collectively linked to a larger set of buyers (sellers obtain 1 6 A link is necessary between a buyer and a seller for a transaction to occur, but if an agent has several links, then there are several possible trading patterns. The network structure essentially determines the bargaining power of buyers and sellers. 7 If there are several sellers who have called out the same price and/or several buyers who have accepted the same price, and there is any discretion under the given network connections as to which trades should occur, then there is a careful protocol for determining which trades occur. The protocol is essentially designed to maximize the number of transactions. 12 as payo¤s, and buyers receive 0); those in which the collective set of sellers is linked to the same-sized collective set of buyers (each receives 1=2); and those in which sellers outnumber buyers (sellers receive 0, and buyers get 1).8 cs 1=2 Sellers u Buyers u 1=2 0 1 u cb 0 cs 0 2cs 0 cs u u u @ @ @ @ @ @ @ @ @u @u 1 2cs u A A A 2cb 1 2cb 1 u 0 cb 0 cb 1=2 AAu 0 cb 3cs 1=2 cs u u @ @ @ @ @u u cb 1=2 2cb 1=2 0 2cs 1=2 cs u u @ @ @ @ u @u cb 1=2 2cb cs 0 cs 1=2 2cs 1=2 2cs u u u u @ @ @ @ @u u u 1 3cb 1=2 2cb 1=2 cb Figure 2 : Limit payo¤s in the Corominas-Bosch (2004) model for some networks. Let G2 be the set of all buyer-seller networks consisting of pairs and so that the maximum number of potential pairs must form. That is, G2 = fg 2 G(S; B) j l(g) = minf#S; #Bg and li (g) 1 8i 2 S [ Bg where l(g) is the number of links in g and li (g) is the number of links player i has in g. Proposition 4 (Jackson, 2003). In the Corominas-Bosch model with 1=2 > cs > 0 and 1=2 > cb > 0, the set of pairwise stable networks is G2 which is exactly the set of strongly e¢cient networks. The intuition for this result is straightforward. An agent having a payo¤ of 0 cannot have any links since by deleting a link she could save the link cost and not lose any bene…t. So, all agents who have links must obtain payo¤s of 1=2 (ignoring 8 The algorithm works as follows. Step 1a: Identify groups of two or more sellers who are all linked only to the same buyer. Regardless of that buyer’s other connections, eliminate that set of sellers and buyer (with the buyer obtaining 1 and the sellers receiving 0). Step 1b: On the remaining network, repeat step 1a but with the role of buyers and sellers reversed. Step k: Proceed inductively in k, each time identifying subsets of at least k sellers who are collectively linked to some set of fewer-than-k buyers, or some collection of at least k buyers who are collectively linked to some set of fewer-than-k sellers. End: When all such subgraphs are removed, the buyers and sellers in the remaining network are such that every subset of sellers is linked to at least as many buyers and vice versa, and the buyers and sellers in that subnetwork get 1=2. 13 the costs of maintaining links). Then, we can show that if there are extra links in such a network relative to the strongly e¢cient network which consists of a maximal number of disjoint linked pairs, some links could be deleted without changing the payo¤s from trade but saving link costs. Thus, a pairwise stable network must consist of linked pairs, and the maximum number of potential pairs must form. Notice that if 1=2 < cs and/or 1=2 < cb then the empty network is the unique pairwise stable network. The empty network is strongly e¢cient only if cs + cb 1. e e = minf#S; #Bgg and S = fSe B j #B S j #Se = Let B = fB e S) e = fg 2 G(S; B) j l(g) = e 2 B and Se 2 S, let G2 (B; minf#S; #Bgg. Given B e and li (g) = 0 8i 2 e minf#S; #Bg, li (g) = 1 8i 2 Se [ B, = Se [ Bg. Of course, e S) e G2 (B; G2 . Proposition 5. In the Corominas-Bosch model with 1=2 > cs > 0 and 1=2 > cb > 0, e S) e is a pairwise farsightedly stable set of e 2 B and Se 2 S, the set G2 (B; for all B networks. e 2 B and Se 2 S. First, we show that for every g 0 2 e S) e Proof. Take any B = G2 (B; e S) e such that g 2 F (g 0 ). Notice that, for every g 2 G2 (B; e S), e there is g 2 G2 (B; each agent receives either Yi (g) = 1=2 ci > 0 if agent i is linked to another agent e S), e or Yi (g) = 0 if agent i has no link, and Yi (g1 ) = Yi (g2 ) for all g1 ; g2 2 G2 (B; for all i 2 N . Start with g 0 and build a sequence of networks where at each step some agent (who is looking forward to g) deletes a link until we reach a network g 00 consisting only of linked pairs of agents and/or agents having no links. Then, agents successively add the links that belong to g but do not belong to g 00 . Finally, at each following step some agent who has two links at the current network, one link with her partner in g and one link with another partner, deletes the latter link until we reach the network g. Step 1a: Agents who receive a payo¤ strictly less than 0 successively delete a link. Each agent is willing to delete a link looking forward to g since Yi (g) 0 for all i 2 S [ B. Step 1b: On the remaining network, delete a link from an agent who receives a payo¤ of 1=2 li ci with li > 1 and who obtains a payo¤ of 1=2 ci at the endpoint g. Step k: Proceed inductively in k, agents who receive a payo¤ strictly less than 0 successively delete a link; then, on the remaining network, delete a link from an agent who receives a payo¤ of 1=2 li ci with li > 1 and who obtains a payo¤ of 1=2 ci at the endpoint g. Step K: When all such links are removed, we end up 14 at a network g 00 2 fg 2 G(S; B) j l(g) minf#S; #Bg and li (g) 1 8i 2 S [ Bg 00 where all the buyers and sellers in g that do have a link get a payo¤ of 1=2 ci while e S) e we stop here. Otherwise, select g 2 G2 (B; e S) e the others get 0. If g 00 2 G2 (B; e S). e Step K + 1: Agents successively add such that g \ g 00 ge \ g 00 for all ge 2 G2 (B; the links that belong to g but do not belong to g 00 . That is, a pair of agents i and j will add the link ij so that ij 2 g and ij 2 = g 00 . Since at least one of the agent has no link at g 00 , say agent i (li (g 00 ) = 0), then Yi (g 00 ) = 0 < Yi (g) = 1=2 ci , and so agent i is willing to add the link. The other agent (agent j) has either no link (which gives her a payo¤ of 0) or has one link (which gives her a payo¤ of 1=2 and so she agrees to add the link with agent i since Yj (g 00 ) cj ) Yj (g). When all such links are added, we end up at a network g 000 . Step K + 2: Agents that have a link in g 00 but do not have a link in g are linked in g 000 to some agent who has two links in g 000 and so obtain a payo¤ of 0 ci . Those agents successively delete their links looking forward to g. When all such links are removed, we end up at the network g. e S) e we have that F (g) \ G2 (B; e S) e = ?. Second, we show that for every g 2 G2 (B; e S) e and for all i 2 S [ B, it follows that Since Yi (g1 ) = Yi (g2 ) for all g1 ; g2 2 G2 (B; g1 2 = F (g2 ). Theorem 3 in Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch (2009) states that if for every g 0 2 G n G we have F (g 0 ) \ G 6= ; and for every g 2 G; F (g) \ G = ;, then e S) e is a pairwise G is a pairwise farsightedly stable set. Hence, we have that G2 (B; farsightedly stable set. Proposition 6. In the Corominas-Bosch model with 1=2 > cs > 0 and 1=2 > cb > 0, there does not exist a pairwise farsightedly stable set G such that G \ G2 = ?. Proof. We will show that for all g 0 2 = G2 and for all g 2 G2 we have that g 0 2 = F (g) which guarantees that there does not exist a pairwise farsightedly stable set G such that G \ G2 = ?. The only networks g 0 2 = G2 that some forward looking agents may prefer to g 2 G2 are such that the agents deviating from g obtain a payo¤ of 1 in g 0 (ignoring the costs of maintaining links). To obtain 1 the deviating agents will have to form links along the sequence with agents that will obtain 0 in g 0 (ignoring the costs of maintaining links). But, before forming these additional links with the original deviating agents, these agents have a payo¤ of either 1=2 or 0 (ignoring the costs of maintaining links), and thus, they have incentives to block the formation of any additional costly link. In the bargaining model of Corominas-Bosch (2004) myopic or farsighted notions 15 of stability sustain the set of strongly e¢cient networks when the costs of maintaining links are not too large. Notice that if 1=2 < cs and/or 1=2 < cb then a set consisting of the empty network is obviously the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set. In that case, on at least one side of the market (buyers or sellers) agents who have some link in any network receive a payo¤ strictly less than 0 and thus are willing to delete their links looking forward to the empty network. It also implies that there are no farsighted improving path emanating from the empty network. The Kranton and Minehart (2001) model of buyer-seller networks is similar to the Corominas-Bosch model except that the valuations of the buyers for an object are random and the determination of prices is made through an auction rather than alternating-o¤er bargaining. Consider a version of the model with one seller (#S = 1) and some potential buyers (#B 1). So, there is one seller who has an indivisible object for sale and b potential buyers who have utilities for the object, denoted ui , which are uniformly and independently distributed on [0; 1]. The object to sell has no value to the seller. Each buyer knows her own valuation, but only the distribution over the buyers’ valuations. The seller also knows only the distribution of buyers’ valuations. The object is sold by means of a standard second-price auction. Only the buyers who are linked to the seller participate to the auction. The number of buyers linked to the seller is given by l(g). For a cost per link of cs to the seller and cb to the buyer, the allocation rule for any network g with l(g) 1 links between the buyers and the seller is 8 1 > > < l(g)(l(g)+1) cb if i is a linked buyer l(g) 1 , Yi (g) = l(g)cs if i is the seller l(g)+1 > > : 0 if i is a buyer without any links. The value function is v(g) = l(g) l(g)+1 l(g)(cs + cb ), which is simply the expected value of the object to the highest valued buyer less the cost of links. Let ls be the number of links l such that 2 l (l + 1) cs and 2 < cs , (l + 1) (l + 2) which is the optimal number of links for the seller. Let lb be the number of links l such that 1 l(l + 1) cb and 1 < cb , (l + 1) (l + 2) 16 which is the maximal number of links up to which buyers make positive payo¤s. A network g such that l(g) = minfls ; lb g is pairwise stable. Notice that if 1 lb (lb +1) = cb and ls = lb then g 2 ls (ls +1) = cs , ij such that l(g) = minfls ; lb g is pairwise stable too. Strongly e¢cient networks are not necessarily pairwise stable.9 If cs = 0 then the pairwise stable networks are exactly the e¢cient ones. Proposition 7. In the Kranton and Minehart model with one seller, (i) If 2 ls (ls +1) > cs and/or 1 lb (lb +1) > cb and/or ls 6= lb then fgg with g 2 G1 = fg 2 G(f1g; B) j l(g) = minfls ; lb gg are the unique pairwise farsightedly stable sets. (ii) If 2 ls (ls +1) 1 lb (lb +1) = cs , G(f1g; B) j l(g) = ls Proof. (i) Suppose 2 ls (ls +1) = cb and ls = lb then G1 [ fgg with g 2 G 1 = fg 2 1g are the unique pairwise farsightedly stable sets. 1 lb (lb +1) > cs and/or > cb and/or ls 6= lb ; and let G1 = fg 2 G(f1g; B) j l(g) = minfls ; lb gg. It is quite straightforward that (a) g 0 2 = F (g) for all g 0 2 = G1 and g 2 G1 ; (b) g 0 2 F (g) for all g; g 0 2 G1 ; (c) g 2 F (g 0 ) for all g 2 G1 , g 0 2 = G1 . Then, it follows that fgg with g 2 G1 are the unique pairwise farsightedly stable sets. (ii) Suppose l(g) = ls 2 ls (ls +1) = cs , 1 lb (lb +1) = cb and ls = lb . Let G 0 1 = fg 2 G(f1g; B) j 0 1g. We have Ys (g) = Ys (g ) for all g; g 2 G1 [ G 1 ; Yi (g) = 0 for all g 2 G1 , i 2 B; Yi (g) = 0 for all g 2 G 1 , i 2 B with li (g) = 0. It follows that (a) g0 2 = F (g) for all g; g 0 2 G1 [ fg 00 g with g 00 2 G 1 ; (b) for all g 0 2 = G1 [ fg 00 g with g 00 2 G 1 there is g 2 F (g 0 ) such that g 2 G1 [ fg 00 g with g 00 2 G 1 ; (c) g 0 2 = F (g) for all g 0 2 = G1 [ G 1 and g 2 G1 [ G 1 . (a) and (b) imply that G1 [ fg 00 g with g 00 2 G 1 is a pairwise farsightedly stable set while (c) implies that G1 [ fg 00 g with g 00 2 G 1 are the unique pairwise farsightedly stable sets. While the pairwise (myopically or farsightedly) stable networks may not be strongly e¢cient, they are Pareto e¢cient. However, when there are more sellers it is possible for non-trivial pairwise (myopically) stable networks to be Pareto ine¢cient. Consider a population with two sellers and four buyers. Let agents 1 and 2 be the sellers and 3, 4, 5 and 6 be the buyers. Some straightforward but tedious calculations lead to the payo¤s which are given in Figure 3 and Figure 4 for selected networks. 9 For instance, if cs = cb = 1=100 then the pairwise stable networks have 10 links, while networks with only 6 links are the strongly e¢cient ones. 17 24 60 Sellers t Buyers 9 60 cb 9 60 24 60 Sellers t Buyers 9 60 9 2cb 60 26 60 Sellers t Buyers 7 60 cb 7 60 20 60 Sellers t Buyers 5 60 cb 5 60 24 3cs 60 3cs t t @ @ @ @ @ @ @t @t t 2cb 9 60 2cb 9 60 24 60 t 9 60 cb 24 4cs 60 4cs tH t @HH @ @ H @ @ HH@ HH @t @t t 9 2cb 60 9 2cb 60 12 60 2cb 12 60 t 15 60 2cb cb 30 cb 60 2cb t 15 60 2cb cb 15 60 30 60 t 5 60 2cb cb 2cb 5 60 9 60 2cb 9 60 2cb 15 3cs 60 3cs tH t @HH @ @ H @ @ HH@ H@ @t Ht t 15 60 0 15 60 4cs 0 cs tH t @HH @ @ H @ @ HH@ H@ @t Ht t 15 60 9 60 15 60 18 4cs 60 2cs tH t @H @ @HHH@ H@ @ HH @t @t t cb cb 24 4cs 60 3cs tH t @H @ @HHH@ H@ @ HH @t @t t 2cb 15 60 3cs 15 2cs 60 t t @ @ @ @t t 2cb 15 60 2cb t 2cb 0 3cs 0 cs t t @ @ @ @ @ @ @t @t t cb 5 60 cb 30 60 cb Figure 3 : Payo¤s in the Kranton and Minehart (2001) model for selected networks. For instance, when cs = 5=60 and cb = 1=60, there are three types of pairwise stable networks: the empty network, networks that look like f13; 14; 15; 16g, and networks that look like f13; 14; 15; 24; 25; 26g. Both the empty network and f13; 14; 15; 24; 25; 26g are not Pareto e¢cient, while f13; 14; 15; 16g is. The empty network and the network f13; 14; 15; 24; 25; 26g are Pareto dominated by the network f13; 14; 25; 26g. In addition, the network f13; 14; 15; 16g is not strongly e¢cient. The network f13; 14; 25; 26g is strongly e¢cient but is not pairwise stable since agents 1 and 5 have incentives to add a link. However, the network f13; 14; 25; 26g is pairwise farsightedly stable. Indeed, we have that G0 = fg j d1 (g) = d2 (g) = 2 and d3 (g) = d4 (g) = d5 (g) = d6 (g) = 1g is a pairwise farsightedly stable set since for every g 0 2 = G0 we have F (g 0 ) \ G0 6= ? and for every g 2 G0 , F (g) \ G0 = ?. Thus, contrary to pairwise stability, pairwise farsighted stability may sustain strongly ef18 …cient networks when there are more than one seller. One open question is whether Pareto ine¢cient networks could belong to some pairwise farsightedly stable set with many sellers and buyers. 36 60 Sellers t Buyers 3 60 cb 3 60 20 60 Sellers t Buyers 10 60 cb Sellers t Buyers 10 60 cb t cb 2cs t 30 60 2cb 20 60 2cs t @ @ t cb 10 60 2cs t 0 t cb 30 60 cb 3 60 3cs 0 cs t t @ @ @ @t t 10 60 0 30 60 3 60 t Sellers Buyers cb 10 60 20 60 28 60 4cs 0 tH t @H H @ HH HH @ Ht @t t cb cb t 7 60 cb cb 7 60 0 t t 0 0 @ @t 10 60 cb cb 2cb 2cs 0 2cs t t @ @ @ @t t 2cb 30 60 2cb 15 60 2cs t 15 60 2cs t t 15 cb 60 cs t 12 60 30 60 t 15 60 18 3cs 60 2cs t t @ @ @ @ @ @ @t @t t t 15 2cb 60 0 t cb t 0 t cb 0 t 12 60 0 t t t t t t 0 0 0 0 0 0 Figure 4 : Payo¤s in the Kranton and Minehart (2001) model for selected networks (continued). 6 6.1 Farsighted stability and e¢ciency Primitive conditions on value functions Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch (2009) have shown that the set of pairwise farsightedly stable networks and the set of strongly e¢cient networks, those which are socially optimal, may be disjoint for all allocation rules that are component balanced and anonymous. However, as already mentioned, if there is a network g 19 that strictly Pareto dominates all other networks, then fgg is the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set. Suppose that Y is the egalitarian allocation rule and E(v) is the set of strongly e¢cient networks. Then, E(v) is the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set. We now provide some alternative primitive conditions on value functions and allocation rules so that the set of strongly e¢cient networks is the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set. It will turn out that under the conditions we will impose the notion of pairwise farsighted stability re…nes the notion of pairwise stability by eliminating the ine¢cient pairwise stable networks. A value function v is top convex if some strongly e¢cient network also maximizes the per capita value among players. Let g S be the collection of all subsets of S with cardinality 2. Let (v; S) = maxg convex if (v; N ) (v; S) for all S gS N v(g)=#S. The value function v is top N. Proposition 8. Consider any anonymous and component additive value function v. The set of strongly e¢cient networks E(v) is the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set under the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule Y ce if and only if v is top convex. Proof. Consider any anonymous and component additive value function v. (() Top convexity implies that all components of a strongly e¢cient network must lead to the same per-capita value (if some component led to a lower per capita value than the average, then another component would have to lead to a higher per capita value than the average which would contradict top convexity). It follows that under the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule any g 2 E(v) Pareto dominates all g 0 2 = E(v). Then, it is immediate that g 2 F (g 0 ) for all g 0 2 G n E(v) and that F (g) = ?. Using Theorem 5 in Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch (2009) which says that G is the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set if and only if G = fg 2 G j F (g) = ?g and for every g 0 2 G n G, F (g 0 ) \ G 6= ?, we have that E(v) is the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set. ()) Since E(v) is the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set, we have F (g) = ? for all g 2 E(v). It follows that under the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule (i) Yice (g; v) = Yjce (g; v) = Yice (g 0 ; v) = Yjce (g 0 ; v) for all i; j 2 N and for all g; g 0 2 E(v); (ii) Yice (g; v) Yice (g 0 ; v) for all i 2 N , for all g 2 E(v), for all g0 2 = E(v). Thus, v is top convex. 20 Jackson and van den Nouweland (2005) have shown that the set of strongly e¢cient networks coincides with the set of strongly stable networks under the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule if and only if v is top convex.10 Hence, the set of strongly stable networks is the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set under the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule if and only if the value function is top convex. So, pairwise farsighted stability selects under Y ce the pairwise stable networks that are immune to coalitional deviations if and only if v is top convex. Note that top convexity is a condition that is satis…ed in some natural situations. For instance, the value function of the symmetric connections model is top convex for all values of 2 [0; 1) and c 0, so that all strongly e¢cient networks with respect to v form the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set with respect to Y ce and v.11 6.2 Strict or weak deviations It is customary to require that a pair of players will deviate only if one player is made better o¤ and the other one at least equal o¤ at the end network. In many situations it should not be too di¢cult for the player who is better at the end network to convince the indi¤erent player to join her to move towards this end network. For instance, when small transfers between the deviating pair are allowed. The notion of farsighted improving path given in De…nition 1 captures this idea. But sometimes a pair of players will deviate only if both are made better o¤ at the end network, since changing the status-quo is costly, and players have to be compensated for doing so. The notion of strict farsighted improving path captures this idea. Let us introduce now a notion of pairwise farsighted stability that only accounts for deviations that make all players strictly better o¤. 10 Jackson and van den Nouweland (2005) have proposed a re…nement of pairwise stability where coalitionwise deviations are allowed: the strongly stable networks. A strongly stable network is a network which is stable against changes in links by any coalition of individuals. Strongly stable networks are Pareto e¢cient and maximize the overall value of the network if the value of each component of a network is allocated equally among the members of that component. 11 Provided that n is even, the value function of Jackson and Wolinsky’s (1996) co-author model is top convex as the strongly e¢cient network always involves pairs of players who are linked to each other. The value function of Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch’s (2009) criminal networks model is top convex too. Finally, the value function of Bramoullé and Kranton’s (2007) risk sharing networks model is top convex when the utility function is quadratic. 21 De…nition 3. A strict farsighted improving path from a network g to a network g 0 6= g is a …nite sequence of networks g1 ; : : : ; gK with g1 = g and gK = g 0 such that for any k 2 f1; : : : ; K (i) gk+1 = gk 1g either: ij for some ij such that Yi (gK ; v) > Yi (gk ; v) or Yj (gK ; v) > Yj (gk ; v), or (ii) gk+1 = gk + ij for some ij such that Yi (gK ; v) > Yi (gk ; v) and Yj (gK ; v) > Yj (gk ; v). For a given network g, let F s (g) be the set of networks that can be reached by a strict farsighted improving path from g. We have that F s (g) F (g). We now introduce the concept of strict pairwise farsightedly stable set based on the notion of strict improving path. De…nition 4. A set of networks G G is a strict pairwise farsightedly stable set with respect v and Y if (i) 8 g 2 G, (ia) 8 ij 2 = g such that g + ij 2 = G, 9 g 0 2 F s (g + ij) \ G such that Yi (g 0 ; v) Yi (g; v) or Yj (g 0 ; v) Yj (g; v), (ib) 8 ij 2 g such that g Yi (g 0 ; v) ij 2 = G, 9 g 0 ; g 00 2 F s (g Yi (g; v) and Yj (g 00 ; v) ij) \ G such that Yj (g; v), (ii) 8g 0 2 G n G; F s (g 0 ) \ G 6= ;: (iii) @ G0 G such that G0 satis…es Conditions (ia), (ib), and (ii). It is straightforward that if fgg is a strict pairwise farsightedly stable set then fgg is a pairwise farsightedly stable set. The reverse is not true. However, if G is a pairwise farsightedly stable set then (i) @ G0 farsightedly stable set, (ii) @ G0 G such that G0 is a strict pairwise G such that G0 is a strict pairwise farsightedly stable set as the following example shows. Consider a situation with three players where the payo¤s are given in Figure 5. It can be veri…ed that F (g0 ) = fg1 ; g3 ; g7 g, F (g1 ) = fg0 g, F (g2 ) = fg0 ; g1 ; g7 g, F (g3 ) = fg1 ; g6 ; g7 g, F (g4 ) = fg0 ; g1 ; g7 g, F (g5 ) = fg1 ; g3 ; g6 ; g7 g, F (g6 ) = fg1 ; g7 g, and F (g7 ) = fg6 g. Hence, the pairwise farsightedly stable sets are fg0 ; g7 g, fg0 ; g3 ; g6 g, 22 fg1 ; g6 g, fg1 ; g7 g. It can also be veri…ed that F s (g0 ) = ?, F s (g1 ) = fg0 g, F s (g2 ) = fg0 ; g1 g, F s (g3 ) = ?, F s (g4 ) = fg0 ; g1 g, F s (g5 ) = fg1 ; g3 g, F s (g6 ) = ?, and F s (g7 ) = fg6 g. Hence, the unique strict pairwise farsightedly stable sets is fg0 ; g3 ; g6 g, and strict pairwise farsighted stability re…nes (weak) pairwise farsighted stability. 2 P l:1 s 0 s P l:3 P l:2 s g0 1 s 1 s s g1 0 0 0 s 0 s s g2 0 s 1 s s g3 0 0 0 s 0 s 0 s 0 s 2 s 0 s 1 s 1 s s g4 s g5 s g6 s g7 0 0 0 0 Figure 5 : Strict versus weak pairwise farsighted stability: an example. 2 P l:1 s 0 s P l:3 P l:2 s g0 1 s 1 s s g1 0 0 0 s 0 s s g2 0 0 s 1 s s g3 0 0 s 0 s 0 s 0 s 0 s 0 s 1 s 1 s s g4 s g5 s g6 s g7 2 0 0 0 Figure 6 : Strict versus weak pairwise farsighted stability: another example. Consider another situation with three players where the payo¤s are given in Figure 6. It can be veri…ed that F (g0 ) = fg1 ; g3 ; g7 g, F (g1 ) = fg0 g, F (g2 ) = fg0 ; g1 ; g7 g, F (g3 ) = fg1 ; g7 g, F (g4 ) = fg0 ; g1 ; g7 g, F (g5 ) = fg1 ; g3 ; g4 ; g7 g, F (g6 ) = fg1 ; g7 g, and F (g7 ) = fg4 g. The pairwise farsightedly stable sets are fg0 ; g7 g, fg0 ; g3 ; g4 ; g6 g, 23 fg1 ; g4 g, fg1 ; g7 g. It can also be veri…ed that F s (g0 ) = ?, F s (g1 ) = fg0 g, F s (g2 ) = fg0 ; g1 g, F s (g3 ) = ?, F s (g4 ) = fg0 ; g1 g, F s (g5 ) = fg1 ; g3 g, F s (g6 ) = fg1 ; g7 g, and F s (g7 ) = fg4 g. Hence, the strict pairwise farsightedly stable sets are fg0 ; g3 ; g7 g, fg0 ; g3 ; g4 ; g6 g, fg0 ; g1 ; g3 ; g4 g. Thus, in general, there are no relationships between strict pairwise farsighted stability and (weak) pairwise farsighted stability. Let g(v; S) = argmax g gS v(g) #N (g) be the network with the highest per capita value out of those that can be formed by players in S N . Given a component additive value function v, …nd a network g v through the following algorithm. Pick some h1 2 g(v; N ). Next, pick some h2 2 g(v; N n N (h1 )). At stage k pick some hk 2 g(v; N n [i k 1 N (hi )). Since N is …nite this process stops after a …nite number K of stages. The union of the components picked in this way de…nes a network g v . We denote by Gv the set of all networks that can be found through this algorithm.12 More than one network may be picked up through this algorithm since players may be permuted or even be indi¤erent between components of di¤erent sizes. Proposition 9. Consider any anonymous and component additive value function v. The set Gv is the unique strict pairwise farsightedly stable set under the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule Y ce . Proof. Consider any anonymous and component additive value function v. First we show that F s (g) = ? for all g 2 Gv under the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule Y ce . Take any g 2 Gv . Players belonging to N (h1 ) in g who are looking forward will never engage in a move since they can never be strictly better o¤ than in g given the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule Y ce . Players belonging to N (h2 ) in g who are forward looking will never engage in a move since the only possibility to obtain a strictly higher payo¤ is to end up in h1 (if h1 gives a strictly higher payo¤ than h2 ) but players belonging to N (h1 ) will never engage a move. So, players belonging to N (h2 ) can never end up strictly better o¤ than in g given the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule Y ce . Players belonging to N (hk ) in g who are forward looking will never engage in a move since the only possibility to obtain 12 This algorithm was …rst introduced by Banerjee (1999) who works with a notion of strong stability but one that only accounts for deviations that make all players strictly better o¤. 24 a strictly higher payo¤ is to end up in h1 or h2 ... or hk [i k 1 N (hi ) 1 but players belonging to will never engage a move. So, players belonging N (hk ) can never end up strictly better o¤ than in g given the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule Y ce ; and so on. Thus, F s (g) = ?. Second, we show in a constructive way that for all g 0 2 = Gv there exists g 2 Gv such that g 2 F s (g 0 ) under the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule Y ce . Take any g 0 2 = Gv and g 2 Gv . In g 0 all players are strictly worse o¤ than the players belonging to N (h1 ) in g under the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule Y ce . From g 0 , let the players who belong to N (h1 ) in g and are looking forward to g …rst deleting successively all their links and then building successively the links in h1 (leading to g 00 = g 0 fij j i 2 N (h1 )g + h1 ). Along the sequence from g 0 to g 00 all players who are moving always strictly prefer the end network g to the current network. Once g 00 (and h1 ) is formed, all the remaining players who are belonging to N n N (h1 ) in g 00 are strictly worse o¤ than the players belonging to N (h2 ) in g. From g 00 , let the players who belong to N (h2 ) in g and who are looking forward to g …rst deleting successively all their links and then building successively the links in h2 (leading to g 000 = g 0 fij j i 2 N (h1 ) [ N (h2 )g + h1 + h2 ); and so on until we reach the network g. Thus, we have build a strict farsighted improving path from g 0 to g; g 2 F s (g 0 ). Using Theorem 5 in Herings, Mauleon and Vannetelbosch (2009) which says that G is the unique (strict) pairwise farsightedly stable set if and only if G = fg 2 G j F s (g) = ?g and for every g 0 2 G n G, F s (g 0 ) \ G 6= ?, we have that Gv is the unique strict pairwise farsightedly stable set. A network g is a strict pairwise stable network with respect to value function v and allocation rule Y if (i) for all ij 2 g, Yi (g; v) Yj (g Yi (g ij; v) and Yj (g; v) ij; v), and (ii) for all ij 2 = g, if Yi (g; v) < Yi (g + ij; v) then Yj (g; v) Yj (g + ij; v). We have that all networks belonging to Gv are strict pairwise stable networks. So, strict pairwise farsighted stability re…nes the notion of strict pairwise stability under Y ce . However, this proposition does not hold under the notion of (weak) pairwise farsighted stability. Consider a situation with …ve players where the payo¤s to players in networks of the types g c = f12; 23; 45g and g d = f12; 45g are, respectively, Y1 (g c ) = Y2 (g c ) = Y3 (g c ) = Y4 (g c ) = Y5 (g c ) = 10 and Y1 (g d ) = Y2 (g d ) = Y4 (g d ) = Y5 (g d ) = 10; Y3 (g d ) = 0 (see right part of Figure 7), while in all other networks payo¤s are equal to zero. Under the above algorithm, Gv consists 25 of all networks of the types g c and g d , but there is a (weak) farsighted improving path from g d to g c . Using Jackson’s algorithm would not help in recovering the proposition.13 For instance, consider a situation with six players where the payo¤s to players in networks of the types g a = f12; 23; 45; 56g and g b = f12; 34; 56g are equal to 10 (see left part of Figure 7), while in all other networks payo¤s are equal to zero. Jackson’s algorithm would only select the networks of the type g a while there are no farsighted improving path from g b to g a and vice-versa. Six players 10 u A A ga A 10 u A A A gc u AAu u AAu u 10 10 10 10 10 10 u A A 10 u gb Five players 10 10 u u A A A AAu u 10 10 u 10 u A 10 gd u u u AAu u u u 10 10 10 10 10 0 10 Figure 7 : Strict versus weak pairwise farsighted stability. Finally, consider a situation with …ve players where the payo¤s to players in networks of the type g e = f12; 23; 45g are Y1 (g e ) = Y2 (g e ) = Y3 (g e ) = 10, Y4 (g e ) = Y5 (g e ) = 5 while in all other networks payo¤s are equal to zero. The set of strongly e¢cient networks consists of networks of the type g e and is the unique strict pairwise farsightedly stable set. However, v does not satisfy top convexity. Thus, under the notion of strict pairwise farsighted stability, top convexity is not necessary to sustain the set of strongly e¢cient networks as the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set. 13 Jackson (2005) has proposed an alternative algorithm which is a bit di¤erent since it requires to pick the maximal number of links in the de…nition of each hk . Under a component additive v, a network de…ned by Jackson’s algorithm is pairwise stable and Pareto e¢cient under the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule Y ce . 26 7 Conclusion We have studied the stability of social and economic networks when players are farsighted. In particular, we have …rst examined whether the networks formed by farsighted players are di¤erent from those formed by myopic players in Jackson and Wolinsky’s (1996) symmetric connections model, in Corominas-Bosch’s (2004) model of trading networks with bilateral bargaining, and in Kranton and Minehart’s (2001) model of buyer-seller networks. We have then provided some primitive conditions on value functions and allocation rules so that the set of strongly e¢cient networks is the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set. Under the componentwise egalitarian allocation rule, the set of strongly e¢cient networks and the set of pairwise (myopically) stable networks that are immune to coalitional deviations are the unique pairwise farsightedly stable set if and only if the value function is top convex. Acknowledgments Vincent Vannetelbosch and Ana Mauleon are Research Associates of the National Fund for Scienti…c Research (FNRS). Vincent Vannetelbosch is Associate Fellow of CEREC, Facultés Universitaires Saint-Louis. Financial support from Spanish Ministerio de Educacion y Ciencia under the project SEJ 2006-06309/ECON, support from the Belgian French Community’s program Action de Recherches Concertée 03/08-302 and 05/10-331 (UCL) and support of a SSTC grant from the Belgian Federal government under the IAP contract P6/09 are gratefully acknowledged. References Banerjee, S., 1999. E¢ciency and stability in economic networks. Mimeo. Boston University. Bramoullé, Y., Kranton, R., 2007. Risk-sharing networks. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 64, 275-294. Chwe, M.S., 1994. Farsighted coalitional stability. Journal of Economic Theory 63, 299-325. Corominas-Bosch, M., 2004. Bargaining in a network of buyers and sellers. Journal of Economic Theory 115, 35-77. 27 Dutta, B., Ghosal, S., Ray, D., 2005. Farsighted network formation. Journal of Economic Theory 122, 143-164. Herings, P.J.J., Mauleon, A., Vannetelbosch, V., 2004. Rationalizability for social environments. Games and Economic Behavior 49, 135-156. Herings, P.J.J., Mauleon, A., Vannetelbosch, V., 2009. Farsightedly stable networks. Forthcoming Games and Economic Behavior. Jackson, M.O., 2003. The stability and e¢ciency of economic and social networks. In: Dutta, B., Jackson, M.O. (Eds.), Networks and Groups: Models of Strategic Formation. Springer-Verlag, Heidelberg, pp. 99-140. Jackson, M.O., 2005. A survey of models of network formation: stability and e¢ciency. In: Demange, G., Wooders, M. (Eds.), Group Formation in Economics: Networks, Clubs and Coalitions. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 11-57. Jackson, M.O., van den Nouweland, A., 2005. Strongly stable networks. Games and Economic Behavior 51, 420-444. Jackson, M.O., Wolinsky, A., 1996. A strategic model of social and economic networks. Journal of Economic Theory 71, 44-74. Kranton, R., Minehart, D., 2001. A theory of buyer-seller networks. American Economic Review 91, 485-508. Mauleon, A., Vannetelbosch, V., 2004. Farsightedness and cautiousness in coalition formation games with positive spillovers. Theory and Decision 56, 291-324. Page, F.H., Jr., Wooders, M., Kamat, S., 2005. Networks and farsighted stability. Journal of Economic Theory 120, 257-269. Page, F.H., Jr., Wooders, M., 2009. Strategic basins of attraction, the path dominance core, and network formation games. Forthcoming Games and Economic Behavior. Watts, A., 2001. A dynamic model of network formation. Games and Economic Behavior 34, 331-341. 28 Xue, L., 1998. Coalitional stability under perfect foresight. Economic Theory 11, 603-627. 29 NOTE DI LAVORO DELLA FONDAZIONE ENI ENRICO MATTEI Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Working Paper Series Our Note di Lavoro are available on the Internet at the following addresses: http://www.feem.it/Feem/Pub/Publications/WPapers/default.htm http://www.ssrn.com/link/feem.html http://www.repec.org http://agecon.lib.umn.edu http://www.bepress.com/feem/ SD 1.2009 SD SD 2.2009 3.2009 SD 4.2009 SD IM IM SD 5.2009 6.2009 7.2009 8.2009 SD SD SD 9.2009 10.2009 11.2009 SD 12.2009 SD 13.2009 SD 14.2009 IM 15.2009 GC SD 16.2009 17.2009 SD SD SD 18.2009 19.2009 20.2009 SD 21.2009 IM 22.2009 IM 23.2009 SD 24.2009 IM SD 25.2009 26.2009 IM SD SD 27.2009 28.2009 29.2009 SD 30.2009 NOTE DI LAVORO PUBLISHED IN 2009 Michael Hoel: Bush Meets Hotelling: Effects of Improved Renewable Energy Technology on Greenhouse Gas Emissions Abay Mulatu, Reyer Gerlagh, Dan Rigby and Ada Wossink: Environmental Regulation and Industry Location Anna Alberini, Stefania Tonin and Margherita Turvani: Rates of Time Preferences for Saving Lives in the Hazardous Waste Site Context Elena Ojea, Paulo A.L.D. Nunes and Maria Loureiro: Mapping of Forest Biodiversity Values: A Plural Perspective Xavier Pautrel : Macroeconomic Implications of Demography for the Environment: A Life-Cycle Perspective Andrew Ellul, Marco Pagano and Fausto Panunzi: Inheritance Law and Investment in Family Firms Luigi Zingales: The Future of Securities Regulation Carlo Carraro, Emanuele Massetti and Lea Nicita: How Does Climate Policy Affect Technical Change? An Analysis of the Direction and Pace of Technical Progress in a Climate-Economy Model William K. Jaeger: The Welfare Effects of Environmental Taxation Aude Pommeret and Fabien Prieur: Double Irreversibility and Environmental Policy Design Massimiliano Mazzanti and Anna Montini: Regional and Sector Environmental Efficiency Empirical Evidence from Structural Shift-share Analysis of NAMEA data A. Chiabai, C. M. Travisi, H. Ding, A. Markandya and P.A.L.D Nunes: Economic Valuation of Forest Ecosystem Services: Methodology and Monetary Estimates Andrea Bigano, Mariaester Cassinelli, Fabio Sferra, Lisa Guarrera, Sohbet Karbuz, Manfred Hafner, Anil Markandya and Ståle Navrud: The External Cost of European Crude Oil Imports Valentina Bosetti, Carlo Carraro, Romain Duval, Alessandra Sgobbi and Massimo Tavoni: The Role of R&D and Technology Diffusion in Climate Change Mitigation: New Perspectives Using the Witch Model Andrea Beltratti, Marianna Caccavaio and Bernardo Bortolotti: Stock Prices in a Speculative Market: The Chinese Split-Share Reform Angelo Antoci, Fabio Sabatini and Mauro Sodini: The Fragility of Social Capital Alexander Golub, Sabine Fuss, Jana Szolgayova and Michael Obersteiner: Effects of Low-cost Offsets on Energy Investment – New Perspectives on REDD – Enrica De Cian: Factor-Augmenting Technical Change: An Empirical Assessment Irene Valsecchi: Non-Uniqueness of Equilibria in One-Shot Games of Strategic Communication Dimitra Vouvaki and Anastasios Xeapapadeas: Total Factor Productivity Growth when Factors of Production Generate Environmental Externalities Giulia Macagno, Maria Loureiro, Paulo A.L.D. Nunes and Richard Tol: Assessing the Impact of Biodiversity on Tourism Flows: A model for Tourist Behaviour and its Policy Implications Bernardo Bortolotti, Veljko Fotak, William Megginson and William Miracky: Sovereign Wealth Fund Investment Patterns and Performance Cesare Dosi and Michele Moretto: Auctioning Monopoly Franchises: Award Criteria and Service Launch Requirements Andrea Bastianin: Modelling Asymmetric Dependence Using Copula Functions: An application to Value-atRisk in the Energy Sector Shai Bernstein, Josh Lerner and Antoinette Schoar: The Investment Strategies of Sovereign Wealth Funds Marc Germain, Henry Tulkens and Alphonse Magnus: Dynamic Core-Theoretic Cooperation in a TwoDimensional International Environmental Model Frank Partnoy: Overdependence on Credit Ratings Was a Primary Cause of the Crisis Frank H. Page Jr and Myrna H. Wooders (lxxxv): Endogenous Network Dynamics Caterina Calsamiglia, Guillaume Haeringer and Flip Klijnb (lxxxv): Constrained School Choice: An Experimental Study Gilles Grandjean, Ana Mauleon and Vincent Vannetelbosch (lxxxv): Connections Among Farsighted Agents (lxxxv) This paper has been presented at the 14th Coalition Theory Network Workshop held in Maastricht, The Netherlands, on 23-24 January 2009 and organised by the Maastricht University CTN group (Department of Economics, http://www.feem-web.it/ctn/12d_maa.php).