World Applied Sciences Journal 22 (9): 1367-1372, 2013
ISSN 1818-4952
© IDOSI Publications, 2013
DOI: 10.5829/idosi.wasj.2013.22.09.492
Who Do We Trust for Antitrust? Deconstructing Structural IO
Anand N. Asthana
Centrum Católica Graduate Business School, Pontificia Universidad Católica Del Perú
Abstract: The annual volume of corporate mergers and acquisitions in the world exceeds two trillion dollars.
The high level of merger and acquisition activity over the past quarter of a century has revitalised the field of
Industrial Organisation (IO). For policy formulation, the antitrust authorities are increasingly relying on research
in this field to understand the determinants of firm and market organisation and behaviour. Yet there has been
little evaluation of whether or not the mergers that have been permitted are anti-competitive. The use of ever
more complex models has made IO a high-tech highbrow area of research, but the theoretical adequacy,
empirical validity and policy effectiveness are yet to be established. This paper looks at the research models
and methodologies used in contemporary IO research and concludes that to lend credibility to IO studies a
more robust analytical framework is needed. Further, focusing on the elegance of the solution is leading
researchers towards less-important questions; while there is an unfulfilled need to look at areas which are
probably more relevant from the point of view of likelihood of collusive behaviour.
Key words: Antitrust
mergers
Acquisitions
Industrial organisation
INTRODUCTION
What is the raison d'être of a firm and what
determines its scope? These remain some of the central
questions for business scholars, executives and corporate
strategists. The annual worldwide volume of corporate
mergers and acquisitions exceeds two trillion dollars.
Undoubtedly, some of it was on account of hubris
displayed by the ‘leaders’ of business. Asymmetric
managerial incentives motivate some mergers that
ultimately diminish shareholder value [1]. There is also
evidence that many CEO’s pursue acquisitions to
enhance their prestige and status [2]. But it is unlikely that
so much time, effort and investment bankers’ fees would
be spent on adjusting firm boundaries unless there was
some underlying economic gain. These gains could be in
terms of operational and managerial efficiency which in
turn may increase consumer surplus. However, analysis
of many high-profile mergers like the acquisition of Time
Warner by America Online during the merger wave of late
1990’s reveals the role of ‘spin’ and the stories about
merger synergies turned out to be fiction made up by
the business leaders and spin doctors to provide rationale
for mergers that were actually driven by market
overvaluations [3]. Some mergers are aimed at increasing
Corresponding Author:
market power which could result in monopoly or
oligopoly. In most countries mergers are allowed to
proceed only with the permission of an antitrust authority
which is expected to allow mergers that do not result in
creation of excessive market power.
High level of merger and acquisition activity over the
past quarter of century has revitalised the field of
Industrial Organisation (IO) which is concerned with
determinants of firm and market organisation and
behaviour. In the seventies, this field was preoccupied
with analysis across industries. Lack of new theoretical
insights and inability to find data to solve pressing
problems of the day hampered its progress and it was
becoming apparent that the field was losing its way
[4: xv]. Pre-1980 IO literature is read these days mainly as
a historical curiosity. This literature had been “so
nontheoretical, or even antitheoretical, that few economic
theorists were attracted to it.” [5: 1]. In the eighties its
research agenda moved toward analysing individual
industries and boundaries of the firm. “Market structure”
became an unfashionable term in IO and the general
Structure-Conduct-Performance (SCP) paradigm that made
links between structure and performance was buried.
Questions about the overall organisation of production in
the economy were ceded to other fields of economics like
Anand N. Asthana, Centrum Católica Graduate Business School,
Pontificia Universidad Católica Del Perú.
1367
World Appl. Sci. J., 22 (9): 1367-1372, 2013
trade and macroeconomics. Application of game theory
and better availability and use of data gave respectability
to IO. Oliver Williamson proclaimed IO as “the queen of
microeconomics” and insisted, “Antitrust enforcement
has been and will continue to be its main beneficiary.”
[6: 306].
MATERIALS AND METHODS
By and large, the law makers and antitrust authorities
across the world seem to be satisfied by the work they are
doing. For instance, the latest report of the US Antitrust
Modernization Commission while recommending more
retrospective analysis of government merger enforcement,
judges the state of the U.S. antitrust laws as ‘sound’ and
opines that U.S. antitrust enforcement has achieved an
appropriate focus on (1) fostering innovation; (2)
promoting competition and consumer welfare; and (3)
aggressively punishing criminal cartel activity [7: 4].
The economists are less sanguine. Significant public and
private resources are devoted to the review of the
potential anticompetitive effects of mergers before they
are approved. Yet there has been little evaluation of
whether or not the mergers that have been permitted are
anticompetitive. Without this information analysis of
government policies is hardly possible [8]. Crandall and
Winston [9], for example, argue that antitrust policy has
not been favourable to the consumers, while in the same
issue of Journal of Economic Perspectives Baker [10]
argues to the contrary. If IO is to inform antitrust policy
and practice, it should have its main focus on the effect of
past corporate mergers on prices. This does not seem to
be the case. While in the field of labour economics, one
can find hundreds of empirical studies on how wages are
affected by unionisation, minimum wage laws etc., there
are only a few dozen empirical studies in IO with direct
evaluation of the price effects of consummated mergers.
Research on the aggregate effects of merger policy is
even more limited [11].
The basic approach of the econometric industry
studies has been christened as ‘new empirical industrial
organisation’ (NEIO). The methodology of initial studies
under this approach lacked sophistication. Behavioural
interpretations were assigned to ‘conjectural variations’
which in turn was used as a measure of market power [13].
To avoid estimation of numerous cross-elasticities in
these studies, strong restrictions on demand function
were imposed. Endogeneity of prices and quantities and
other identification problems were not taken care of.
During the late 1990’s better techniques have developed
under the brand of ‘structural IO’ [14; 15]. Demand system
is usually estimated using discreet choice models of
product differentiation [16]. Nested demand structures
that impose restrictions on substitution effects between
brands in different segments have been developed and
demand modelling has centred on the trade-off between
allowing flexible substitution patterns and the lack of
variation in typical data that allows such substitution
patterns to be flexibly identified. Demand elasticities are
identified using instrumental variables like prices in
other markets. Next, a model of market conduct is
formulated using the substitution matrix. This enables
simulation of industry behaviour with and without merger.
These methods have finally removed low-brow low-tech
stigma from IO but their credibility is still to be
demonstrated.
Mergers in the ready-to-eat-cereal industry is a case
in point as it could affect the price of a product consumed
by millions of households as a breakfast item for the
last hundred years. Cereal is one of the most
recession-resistant meals because it is fairly cheap and
easy to prepare. The cereal industry has been one of the
most prodigious in new brand introduction. The products
are differentiated or closely related but not identical [17].
Moreover there is differing amounts of similarity across
cereal brands. For example, Cheerios is closer to some
brands of multigrain oats than to, say, brands corn flakes.
One strategy is to divide products into segments and
estimate a model that restricts substitution patterns
across segments but allows flexibility within segments.
As per new methodologies developed under NEIO and
structural IO [18, 19], ‘front-end’ estimation of the
structural parameters calculates demand functions and
supply relations and these estimates are used to simulate
post-merger equilibrium in the ‘back-end’ analysis. Aviv
Nevo has tried to measure market power and implications
of mergers in ready-to-eat cereal industry in his Ph.D.
dissertation [20] and publications in esteemed journals
including Rand Journal of Economics [21] and
Econometrica [22] which show a deep knowledge of the
industry and painstaking empirical work. Assumptions
made are of some concern. The demand system
formulated imposes restrictions on substitution patterns
which are unconvincing. Instrumental variables are almost
always difficult to find and in this case, prices in other
markets used as instrumental variables could be arbitrary
as it is based on independence assumption across
markets. It has been assumed that the mergers affect
prices through a single channel, i.e., the reduction in the
number of competitors. This is difficult to believe because
1368
World Appl. Sci. J., 22 (9): 1367-1372, 2013
other factors like cost reductions can also affect prices.
Similar problems beset structural models of mergers in
airline industry. Supply-side effects, such as changes in
marginal costs or deviations from the assumed model of
firm conduct are difficult to incorporate in the model
designed to measure the effect of the change in
ownership on unilateral pricing incentives. Craig Peters
looks at the airline industry consolidation of the 1980s
[23]. He finds that structural analyses of these mergers
yield poor predictions of the post-merger ticket prices and
concludes that future research should aim at
incorporating more flexible models of firm conduct into the
methodology.
An alternative could be use of difference-indifference (DD) approach by considering the
counterfactual, i.e., a situation if merger had not occurred.
This approach is being increasingly used in the
economics profession where researchers attempt to find
a naturally occurring comparison group that can mimic the
properties of a control group in a physical experiment.
Obviously, the assignment between the treatment group
and the comparison group cannot be randomised; but it
can be assumed to be ‘as if random’ [24]. Using this
approach Ashenfelter and Hosken analyse merger in
cereal industry and state: “It is unclear why Nevo's
predictions are so different from our estimates” [8, 450].
This approach has been applied by Hastings on a
panel of station specific prices to examine the price effects
of acquisition of a gasoline retailer, Thrifty by ARCO
(Atlantic Richfield Company) [25]. The research design
includes station-level fixed effects as well as city-time
effects. Whereas Nevo’s framework is a complex set of
equations wherein it is difficult to see what is driving the
result, DD results come from a straightforward equation
revealing the average change caused by the treatment.
Hasting’s equation (slightly simplified) to determine the
variable of interest price p at station i at time t is:
pit = µ +
i
+
t + zit +
it
(1)
where µ is constant and i is time-invariant stationspecific deviation from it.
is city dummy. zit is an
indicator of competition with independent station. It could
either be a dummy variable indicating whether or not the
station competes with independent stations or it could be
an integer indicating the number of independent station
with whom the station i competes. it is the error term.
The coefficient of interest is which will indicate whether
presence or absence of an independent competitor has a
significant effect on the local retail price.
One weakness of this analysis is that it captures the
effects of a merger on Thrifty’s competitors, but not on
the former Thrifty stations. Even so the randomistas
(a growing tribe among econometricians) like Angrist and
Pischke have showered praise on this type of analysis as
a fruitful change in direction [11]. However, such
endorsement could be premature. The size of the
estimated effect was five cents per gallon which means
that retail margins went up by as much as 50 percent.
This would be an eye-opener for antitrust authorities.
However, six years after the publication of Hasting’s
paper in the American Economic Review, came another
paper in the same journal wherein the authors revisited
Hasting’s analysis. The authors Taylor, Kreisle and
Zimmerman [26] used almost the same dataset (of higher
frequency and for a longer time) and present their results
Table 2 presents the result of estimating the following
regression:
pit = µ +
i
+
Conversionit +
j
k
jk
i t
+
it
(2)
where pi,t, µ, i and it have the same meanings as in
equation (1). The dummy variable Conversionit takes a
value of one if station i is located within a mile of a Thrifty
station during period t (i.e., “competed” with an
independent Thrifty outlet prior to its conversion).
Thus, a negative estimate of the coefficient implies that
the transaction (the loss of an independent competitor) is
correlated with an increase in the average price at these
competing stations. The city-time fixed effects are
captured by the interaction of city dummies, i and time
dummies t.
Equation (2) may appear to be outwardly different,
but is virtually identical to equation (1). The coefficient
estimates of control variables (e.g., city-time interactions)
are quite similar to those obtained by Hastings. But the
coefficient estimates of the variable of main interest, i.e.,
Conversion are vastly different. In summary, the price
increase was found to be of little economic
significance - one fiftieth of that found by Hastings.
This finding is robust to using various sub-samples and
the authors doubt whether ARCO’s acquisition Thrifty
led to higher prices. Moreover, while Hastings finds
support for the underlying model of consumer
preference - differentiated products with consumer brand
loyalty – Taylor et al. doubt whether this model depicts
consumer behaviour dispute the underlying model of
consumer preferences. With time DD methodology is
becoming more and more sophisticated; but is unable to
shrug the criticism that it is atheoretical and highly
sensitive to assumptions.
1369
World Appl. Sci. J., 22 (9): 1367-1372, 2013
Question of Trust: If we can trust neither the structurally
derived estimates nor direct DD estimates, where do we
go from here? Structural models are likely to become more
sophisticated with time. Whether they will be able to rest
on fewer and plausible assumptions remains an open
question. Randomistas believe that a few structural
models should be tried out and whichever fits the direct
estimates better should be declared the winner. In this
vein Hausman and Leonard [27] use three structural
models in their study relating to new brands of toilet
paper and find that the Nash-Bertrand model which is
frequently employed in studies of the competitive effects
of mergers yield indirect estimates reasonably similar
to the direct estimates and superior to the indirect
estimates produced by the two alternative models they
tried. This begs the question: are the direct estimates the
gold standard? As seen in the case study of acquisition
of Thrifty gas stations by ARCO, DD estimates cannot be
relied upon. On theoretical grounds many eminent
scholars have decried emphasis on experimental or
quasi-experimental results. For example Nobel Laureate
James Heckman points out that the retreat to statistics
has abandoned economic choice theory. Important
distinctions about ex ante and ex post outcomes and
subjective and objective evaluations that are central to
structural econometrics are forgotten [28]. Finally, even if
we are able to draw some plausible conclusions from past
mergers, how relevant are these estimates to future
mergers? Liran Einav and Jonathan Levin ask whether the
votaries of direct measurement seriously think that while
reviewing a merger of Microsoft and Yahoo! the
Department of Justice should rely on the price effect of
past airline or office supply company mergers or the
subsets obtained from chance meetings of CEO’s or from
lunar eclipses [29: 159].
Merger analysis presents peculiar problems in case of
multinationals. While it is not difficult to take stock prices
and balance sheets into account, the cultural context is
difficult to grasp. For example, there are significant
differences between human resource management
practices of western multinationals
and
Asian
multinationals operating outside the countries of their
national origin [30]. As far as between-industry
differences are concerned, the
US
Antitrust
Modernization Commission reported in 2007 that it does
not believe that new or different rules are needed to
address so-called “new economy” and insisted that
the
antitrust
laws
remain relevant in today’s
environment and tomorrow’s as well [7: 4].. Further the
Commission submitted that differential treatment to
different industries. In the current state of IO research
there is insufficient emphasis on applied work on
measurement based data that that continues by framing
the empirical exercise in terms of a coherent economic
model.
CONCLUSION
Economic theory has not had much to say about
exactly how organisation should matter. On the other
hand, non-economists in business schools generally think
that organization matters and that firms are not, regardless
of what economic theory may suppose, undifferentiated
profit maximizing agencies which react to given market
situations in ways which are independent of their
organisation. The most important area of public action
related to market structure that IO economists have
sought to inform has been the merger policy. U.S. policy
toward horizontal mergers is enormously more
sophisticated now than it was when the first Guidelines
were issued in 1968 [31]. This is a result of the influence
of IO scholars as compared to that of lawyers and jurists
[32]. Market shares are no longer the main structural
indicator considered. Unilateral effects, the performance
impacts of changing structure assuming no change in the
nature or intensity of competition, are considered more
important. The Guidelines issued in 2010 outline a much
more complex analytical framework based on advances in
theory and enforcement experience but not on empirical
findings. For reasons not made clear, coordinated
effects - adverse changes in (expected) market
performance that occur because changes in market
structure make collusive behaviour more likely – have
taken a back seat. According to Richard Schmalensee it
could be so because the tools available to analyse
unilateral effects have become much more powerful [33].
Merger simulation models formulated by Budzinski and
Ruhmer [34] can be employed to integrate information
from a variety of sources and the newly introduced
Upward Pricing Pressure (UPP) test is an improvement
over the traditional market definition approach in case of
differentiated products. But these new tools shed no light
whatever on coordinated effects. Merger simulation
models usually assume single-period Bertrand
competition and the UPP test assumes that the demand
curves facing the merging firms do not change as a
consequence of their merger or their post-merger price
changes [35]. Antitrust policy is incorporating the areas
where heavy artillery of econometrics has cleared the way.
The areas which are probably more relevant from the point
of view of likelihood of collusive behaviour as revealed
through coordinated effects lie largely unexplored.
1370
World Appl. Sci. J., 22 (9): 1367-1372, 2013
REFERENCES
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
Morck, R., A. Shleifer and R.W. Vishny, 1990. Do
Managerial Objectives Drive Bad Acquisitions? The
Journal of Finance, 45(1): 31-48.
Avery, C., J.A. Chevalier and S. Schaefer, 1988. Why
Do Managers Undertake Acquisitions? An Analysis
of Internal and External Rewards for Acquisitiveness.
Journal of Law, Economics and Organization,
14(1): 24-43.
Shleifer, A. and R.W. Vishny, 2003. Stock market
driven acquisitions. Journal of Financial Economics,
70: 295-311.
Fuchs, V.R., 1972. Policy Issues and Research
Opportunities in Industrial Organization. NBER
Stigler, G.J., 1968. The Organization of Industry.
Irwin.
Williamson, O.E., 1996. The Mechanisms of
Governance. Oxford University Press.
Antitrust Modernization Commission, 2007. Report
and Recommendations. AMC.
Ashenfelter, O. and D. Hosken, 2010. The Effect of
Mergers on Consumer Prices: Evidence from Five
Mergers on the Enforcement Margin. Journal of Law
and Economics, pp: 417-466.
Crandall, R.W. and C. Winston, 2003. Does Antitrust
Policy Improve Consumer Welfare? Assessing the
Evidence. The Journal of Economics Perspectives,
17(4): 3-26.
Baker, J.B., 2003. The Case for Antitrust Enforcement.
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(4): 27-50.
Angrist, J.D. and J.S. Pischke, 2010. The Credibility
Revolution in Empirical Economics: How Better
Research Design Is Taking the Con Out of
Econometrics. Journal of Economic Perspectives,
24(2): 3-30.
Bresahan, T.F., 1989. Empirical Studies of Industries
with Market Power. In Schmalensee, R. & R. D. Willig
(Eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volume
2 (pp: 1011-1057). North-Holland.
Corts, K.S., 1999. Conduct Parameters and the
Measurements of Market Power. Journal of
Econometrics, 88(2): 227-250.
Ackerberg, D., L. Benkard, S. Berry and A. Pakes,
2007. Econometric Tools for Analyzing Market
Outcomes. In Heckman, J.J. and E.E. Leamer
(Eds.), Handbook of Econometrics, Volume 6, Part A
(pp: 4171-4276). Elsevier.
15. Reiss, P.C. and F.A. Wolak, 2007. Structural
Econometric Modeling: Rationales and Examples
from Industrial Organization. In Heckman, J.J. and
E.E. Leamer (Eds.), Handbook of Econometrics,
Volume 6, Part A (pp: 4227-4415). Elsevier.
16. Berry, S.T., 1994. Estimating Discrete Choice Models
of Product Differentiation. Rand Journal of
Economics, 25(2): 242-262.
17. Hausman, J.A., 1997. Valuation of New Goods under
Perfect and Imperfect Competition. In Bresnahan, T.F.
and R.J. Gordon, (Eds.), The Economics of New
Goods: 209-237. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
18. Baker, J. and T.F. Bresnahan, 1985. The Gains from
Merger or Collusion in Product Differentiated
Industries. Journal
of Industrial Economics,
33(4): 427-444.
19. Berry, S.T. and A. Pakes, 1993. Some Applications
and Limitations of recent advances in Empirical
Industrial Organization: Merger Analysis. American
Economic Review, 83: 247-252.
20. Nevo, A., 1997. Demand for Ready-to-Eat Cereal and
its Implications for Price Competition, Merger
Analysis and Valuation of New Brands. Ph.D.
Dissertation. Harvard University
21. Nevo, A., 2000. Mergers with Differentiated Products:
The Case of the Ready-to-Eat Cereal. Rand Journal of
Economics, 31(3): 395-421.
22. Nevo, A., 2001. Mergers with Differentiated Products:
The Case of the Ready-to-Eat Cereal. Econometrica,
69(2): 307-342.
23. Peters, C., 2010. Evaluating the performance of
Merger Simulation: Evidence from the US
Airline Industry. Journal of Law and Economics,
49(2): 627-49.
24. Asthana, A.N., S. Mohan and S. Khorana, 2012.
Physics envy and natural experiments in business
and economics. World Applied Sciences Journal,
20(3): 464-469.
25. Hastings Justine, S., 2004. Vertical Relationships and
Competition in Retail Gasoline Markets: Empirical
Evidence from Contract Changes in Southern
California. American Economic Review, 94(1): 317-28.
26. Taylor, C., N. Kreisle and P. Zimmerman, 2010.
Vertical Relationships and Competition in Retail
Gasoline Markets: Empirical Evidence from Contract
Changes in Southern California: Comment. American
Economic Review, 100(3): 1269-1276.
1371
World Appl. Sci. J., 22 (9): 1367-1372, 2013
27. Hausman, J.A. and G.K. Leonard, 2002. The
Competitive Effects of a New Product Introduction:
A Case Study. Journal of Industrial Economics,
50(3): 237-63.
28. Heckman, J.J., 2010. Building Bridges between
Structural and Program Evaluation Approaches to
Evaluating Policy. Journal of Economic Literature,
48(2): 356-398.
29. Einav, L. and J. Levin, 2010. The Credibility
Revolution in Empirical Economics: Empirical
Industrial Organisation: A Progress Report. Journal
of Economic Perspectives, 24(2): 145-162.
30. Nigam, R. and S. Zhan, 2011. Management in
Emerging versus Developed Countries: A
Comparative Study from an Indian Perspective.
Journal of Centrum Cathedra, 4(1): 121-133.
31. Shapiro, C., 2010. The 2010 Horizontal Merger
Guidelines: From Hedgehog to Fox in Forty Years.
Antitrust Law Journal, 77(1): 701-759.
32. White, L.J., 2010. The Growing Influence of
Economics and Economists on Antitrust: An
Extended Discussion. Economics, Management and
Financial Markets, 5(1): 26-63.
33. Schmalensee, R., 2012. On a Level with Dentists?
Reflections on the Evolution of Industrial
Organization. Review of Industrial Organizations,
41(3): 157-179.
34. Budzinski, O. and J. Ruhmer, 2010. Merger Simulation
in Competition Policy: A Survey. Journal of
Competition Law and Economics, 6(2): 277-319.
35. Jaffe, S. and E.G. Weyl, 2013 The First-Order
Approach to Merger Analysis. American Economic
Journal: Microeconomics, (forthcoming).
1372