La bora t oire
de Re c he rc he
e n Ge st ion
& Ec onom ie
LARGE
LARGE
Papier
Papier
n° 2008-06
Is Corruption an Efficient Grease ?
Pierre-Guillaume Méon , Laurent Weill
Février 2008
Fa c ult é de s
sc ie nc e s é c onom ique s
e t de ge st ion
PEGE
61, avenue de la Forêt Noire
67085 STRASBOURG Cedex
Tél. : (33) 03 90 24 21 52
Fax : (33) 03 90 24 20 64
www-ulp.u-strasbg.fr/large
Institut d’Etudes Politiques
47, avenue de la Forêt Noire
67082 STRASBOURG Cedex
Is corruption an efficient grease?
Pierre-Guillaume Méon1* , Laurent Weill2
1
Université Libre de Bruxelles (ULB), DULBEA, CP-140, avenue F.D. Roosevelt 50, 1050 Bruxelles, Belgium.
(phone: +32 2 650 66 48, fax: +32 2 650 38 25, e-mail: pgmeon@ulb.ac.be)
2
Université Robert Schuman, Institut d’Etudes Politiques, 47 avenue de la Forêt Noire, 67082 Strasbourg
Cedex, France. (phone: +33 3 88 41 77 21, fax: +33 3 88 41 77 78, e-mail: laurent.weill@iep.ustrasbg.fr)
Abstract: This paper tests whether corruption can be viewed as an efficient grease in the wheels of an otherwise
deficient institutional framework. It does so by analyzing the interaction between aggregate efficiency,
corruption, and other dimensions of governance for a panel of 54 countries both developed and developing.
Using three measures of corruption and five measures of other aspects of governance, we repeatedly observe that
corruption is always detrimental in countries where institutions are effective, but that it may be positively
associated with efficiency in countries where institutions are ineffective. We thus find evidence of the grease the
wheels hypothesis.
Keywords: governance, corruption, income, aggregate productivity, efficiency.
JEL Classification: C33, K4, O43, O47.
*
Corresponding author.
Is corruption an efficient grease?
Abstract: This paper tests whether corruption can be viewed as an efficient grease in the wheels of an otherwise
deficient institutional framework. It does so by analyzing the interaction between aggregate efficiency,
corruption, and other dimensions of governance for a panel of 54 countries both developed and developing.
Using three measures of corruption and five measures of other aspects of governance, we repeatedly observe that
corruption is always detrimental in countries where institutions are effective, but that it may be positively
associated with efficiency in countries where institutions are ineffective. We thus find evidence of the grease the
wheels hypothesis.
Keywords: governance, corruption, income, aggregate productivity, efficiency.
JEL Classification: C33, K4, O43, O47.
1. Introduction
Very few people would dare say that corruption is efficient. 1 Nevertheless some
scholars, many of whom are economists, may. Leys (1965) even went so far as to wonder
what “the problem about corruption” was. This provocative claim is backed by various
theoretical justifications, as Aidt (2003)’s survey shows, but the most common argument in
favor of the beneficial effects of corruption rests on what is commonly referred to as the
“grease the wheels” hypothesis. According to that hypothesis, put forward by Leff (1964),
Leys (1965), or Huntington (1968), corruption may be beneficial in a second best world by
alleviating the distortions caused by ill-functioning institutions. The grease the wheels
argument postulates that an inefficient bureaucracy constitutes a major impediment to
economic activity that some “speed” or “grease” money may help circumvent. Lui (1985)
offers a formal illustration of this argument and showed that corruption may be an efficient
way of reducing the time cost of queues. In a nutshell, the grease the wheels hypothesis states
that, in a second best world, graft may act as a trouble-saving device, thereby raising
efficiency.
1
Corruption is understood here as the misuse of public office for private benefit, as is now common in the
literature.
1
Policy circles however do not share the idea that corruption may sometimes be
efficient. On the contrary, international organizations like the IMF or the OECD, view
corruption as a major hindrance to economic development. As a result, the fight against
corruption has raised considerable attention. This has resulted in international initiatives such
as the UN Convention against Corruption, adopted in 2003, or the OECD’s “Convention on
combating bribery of foreign public officials in international business transactions”, which
came into force in April 1999.
This point of view was recently backed by a strand of empirical literature aimed at
quantifying the consequences of corruption. This literature was pioneered by Mauro (1995),
who observed a significant negative relationship between corruption and investment that
extended to growth. Mauro (1995)’s results were later confirmed by Mo (2001) for example,
and extended to other macroeconomic variables like foreign direct investment by Wei (2000),
or productivity by Lambsdorff (2003).
Strictly speaking though, this evidence does not allow to reject the grease the wheels
hypothesis but may in fact be consistent with it. Indeed, the hypothesis simply implies that
corruption is beneficial in countries where other aspects of governance are defective, but
remains detrimental elsewhere. Therefore, the mere observation that corruption is on average
associated with more disappointing economic outcomes does not prevent the correlation from
being positive in those countries where governance is mediocre. The average result may thus
be driven by the negative correlation between corruption and economic performance in the
subset of countries whose institutional framework is effective, whereas the correlation may
indeed be positive elsewhere.
To our knowledge, attempts to specifically test the grease the wheels hypothesis
remain scarce. Mauro (1995) rejected it on the grounds that he could observe no significant
difference in the relationship between corruption and the investment ratio between high redtape and low red-tape countries. Ades and di Tella (1997) also rejected the hypothesis.
Kaufmann and Wei (1999) tackled the issue from a different angle by using firm-level data.
They observed that multinationals that pay more bribes also tend to spend more time
negotiating with foreign countries’ officials, which is hard to reconcile with the grease the
wheels hypothesis. Méon and Sekkat (2005) studied the hypothesis from a macroeconomic
perspective. They observed that corruption was detrimental to investment and growth
everywhere, and especially so in countries with an otherwise defective institutional
framework. This goes against what the grease the wheels hypothesis predicts but may reveal a
“sand the wheels” effect of corruption.
2
However, those contributions do not study the main determinant of cross-country
differences in economic performance, i.e. productivity, choosing to focus instead on factor
accumulation and endowments. Yet, evidence that cross-country differences in economic
performance are the result of differences in productivity is overwhelming, as Caselli (2005)’s
recent survey points out. Consequently, in order to test the economic significance of
corruption and of the grease the wheels hypothesis, one must focus on productivity. In other
words, one must wonder whether corruption helps countries with faulty institutions to take a
better advantage of their factor endowments. This is precisely the aim of the present paper.
To do so, this study applies efficiency frontiers to aggregate production functions,
following Moroney and Lovell (1997). That method provides a synthetic measure of the gap
between countries’ observed and optimal productions. The interrelationship between
corruption, efficiency, and the quality of the institutional framework can then be investigated
to test the grease the wheels hypothesis. This is done by assessing the interaction between
corruption and a wide range of indicators of the quality of governance, for a panel of
countries. The results appear to be inconsistent with the sand the wheels hypothesis. Instead,
they hint at the reverse hypothesis, the grease the wheels hypothesis, which posits that
corruption is even more harmful to efficiency when governance is poor.
To reach these conclusions, the remainder of this paper is organized as follows. The
next section briefly describes the grease the wheels and the sand the wheels hypotheses.
Section 3 outlines our method. Our data set is presented in section 4. We present our
empirical results in section 5. Concluding comments may be found in section 6.
2. Two testable hypotheses
The grease the wheels hypothesis finds its roots in a literature aimed at qualifying the
conclusions of what was dubbed the “moralistic view” of corruption. 2 Some scholars have
stressed that corruption may have its own merits in fostering development, and should
therefore not be judged solely on moral grounds. Their line of reasoning has often rested on a
few similar considerations emphasizing the accommodative properties of graft in the presence
of other imperfections in the rest of the political system. However one may also think of
2
The expression “moralistic approach” can for instance be found in Leys (1965) or Nye (1967). Those who
opposed that view were later deemed “functionalists” or “revisionists” by their own adversaries. On a general
plane, they seemed to be motivated by a concern that the moral implications of corruption may bias the
understanding of its economic consequences and by some concern that the western definition of graft may make
it ill-adapted to the context of developing countries.
3
mechanisms that may make corruption even more costly when institutions are deficient.
These mechanisms are at the core of the sand the wheels hypothesis.
The basis of both hypotheses lies in the distinction between corruption and other
institutional deficiencies. Leff (1964) for instance made a distinction between corruption as
such and the inefficiency of bureaucracy, namely its incapacity to attain goals it is given. A
survey of the two hypotheses is provided by Méon and Sekkat (2005). To save on space, the
present section only draws on that survey to describe how the impact of corruption on
efficiency may depend on the quality of the rest of the institutional framework. Our aim is to
identify a strategy to test the grease the wheels and the sand the wheels hypotheses against
each other.
2.1. The grease the wheels hypothesis
Unsurprisingly, the inefficiency of bureaucracy has often been considered the most
prominent inefficiency that corruption can grease. 3 The first bureaucratic inefficiency that can
be compensated by corruption is slowness. Leys (1965) therefore stressed that bribes could
give bureaucrats an incentive to speed up the establishment of new firms, in an otherwise
sluggish administration. The same argument was later adopted by Lui (1985) who showed in
a formal model that corruption could efficiently reduce the time spent in queues. It can also be
argued that corruption can amend a bureaucracy by improving the quality of its civil servants.
As Leys (1965) or Bailey (1966) claim, when government service wages are low, the
possibility of perks may attract able civil servants who would otherwise have opted for
another line of business.
Some, such as Leff (1964) or Bailey (1966), also argue that graft may simply be a
hedge against bad public policies. In these authors’ view, this is particularly true if the
bureaucrat is biased against entrepreneurship, for ideological reasons or due to a prejudice
against certain minority groups. 4 By simply impeding inefficient regulations, corruption may
then limit their adverse effects. The causality may in fact be subtler. Ehrlich and Lui (1999)
thus argue that autocratic regimes, which are able to steer the administration in a centralized
way, implement policies that are closer, if not equivalent, to first best policies. The reason is
that they wish to maximize their rents but internalize the deadweight loss associated with
3
As Huntington (1968, p.386) put it: “In terms of economic growth, the only thing worse than a society with a
rigid, overcentralized, dishonest bureaucracy is one with a rigid, overcentralized, honest bureaucracy”.
4
Nye (1967) by example reports that corruption was instrumental in making central planning more effective in
the Soviet Union. He also argues that it helped increase the influence of Asian minority entrepreneurs in East
Africa beyond what political conditions would have allowed.
4
corruption. These regimes have therefore incentives to avoid impairing the productivity of the
private sector. This incentive does not exist in more decentralized regimes where no
bureaucrat perceives the detrimental effect of bribes on productivity. We may conclude that
corruption provides an incentive to implement better policies in autocratic regimes but not in
democratic regimes. All things being equal, it is therefore beneficial in countries that are less
democratic.
Moreover, it has also been argued that graft may in some circumstances improve the
quality of investments. This is in particular the case, as Leff (1964) stresses, when
government spending is inefficient. If corruption is a means of tax evasion, it can reduce the
revenue of public taxes and, provided bribers have efficient investment opportunities,
improve the overall efficiency of investment. More generally, one may contend that
corruption is an efficient way of selecting investment projects, when such investments depend
on gaining a license. Bailey (1966) for instance claims that this may be true if the ability to
offer a bribe is correlated with talent. More specifically, one may argue that awarding a
license through corrupt methods is very similar to a competitive auction. This intuition was
offered by Leff (1964) who argues that favors tend to be allocated to the more generous
bribers, who can only be the most efficient. Beck and Maher (1986) and Lien (1986)
subsequently showed formally that corruption replicates the outcome of a competitive auction
aimed at attributing a government procurement contract, because the ranking of bribes
replicates the ranking of firms by efficiency.
All the above-mentioned arguments share the presumption that corruption may
positively contribute to the productivity of the factors of production with which a country is
endowed, because it compensates for the consequences of a defective institutional framework,
resulting in an inefficient administration, a low rule of law, or political violence. One may
nevertheless remark that graft also has its drawbacks. Indeed, although bribery may have its
benefits, it may also impose additional costs in a weak institutional environment. The
existence of such costs provides a rationale for the sand the wheels hypothesis.
2.2. The sand the wheels hypothesis
The specificity of the sand the wheels hypothesis is that it emphasizes that some of the
costs of corruption may precisely appear or be magnified in a weak institutional context.
For instance, the claim that corruption may speed up an otherwise sluggish
bureaucracy can be overturned. Myrdal (1968) argues that corrupt civil servants may cause
5
delays that would otherwise not appear, just to get the opportunity to extract a bribe.
Kurer (1993) argues along similar lines that corrupt officials have an incentive to create other
distortions in the economy to preserve their illegal source of income. These arguments are
perfectly compatible with the experience of individual bribers who can indeed improve their
own situation thanks to a perk. They stress however that nothing may be gained from
corruption at the aggregate level.5
Moreover, there are reasons to believe that corruption may not be the best way to
award a license to the most efficient producer. Thus, even if the analogy between corruption
and a competitive auction holds true, the winner is not necessarily the most efficient. In
auctions where the profitability of a license is uncertain, the winner may simply be the more
optimistic, according to the “winner’s curse”. Secondly, as Rose-Ackerman (1997) argues, the
highest briber may simply be the one most willing to compromise on the quality of the goods
he will produce if he gets a license. Under those circumstances, corruption will simply reduce
rather than improve efficiency.
The argument that states that corruption may raise the quality of investment is also
questionable. There is evidence that this may not be true for public investment. Thus,
Mauro (1998) observes that corruption results in a diversion of public spending towards less
efficient allocations. Overall, corruption therefore results in a greater amount of public
investments in unproductive sectors, which is unlikely to improve efficiency and result in
faster growth.
One can also doubt that corruption may serve as a hedge against risk in a politically
uncertain environment. This can only be true if corruption does not imply additional risktaking. However, corruption is not a simple transaction. As it is illegal, the commitment to
comply with the terms of the agreement may indeed be very weak, which may lead to
opportunism, especially on the bribee’s part. Furthermore, increased uncertainty due to
corruption may go beyond corrupt deals themselves. Thus, larger corruption was found to be
associated with a larger shadow economy, for instance by Dreher and Schneider (2006a, b).
Since transactions in the shadow economy are by definition unregulated they are therefore
subject to greater uncertainty than official transactions.
Consequently, as Bardhan (1997) points out, the inherent uncertainty of corrupt
agreements may simply make the efficiency-enhancing mechanisms described in the previous
5
Those effects can be exacerbated when the administration is made of a succession of decision centers or civil
servants. Shleifer and Vishny (1993) thus build a formal model where the cost of corruption is greater when the
administration is made of many independent agencies than when it is centrally managed.
6
section ineffective. This may provide an incentive to invest in general, as opposed to specific,
capital, which can easily be reallocated but is also less productive, as Henisz (2000) argues.
As a result, corruption may worsen the impact of political violence or a weak rule of law on
the quality of investment instead of reducing it.
To conclude, both the grease the wheels and the sand the wheels hypotheses may seem
reasonable on an abstract plane. However, they both remain very theoretical. Even so, they
both produce testable hypotheses that are summarized in table 1 below:
Table 1
Impact of corruption on efficiency
Grease the wheels
Sand the wheels
detrimental
detrimental
positive
detrimental
Effective institutions
Ineffective institutions
According to table 1, both hypotheses predict that an increase in corruption will
reduce efficiency in an otherwise efficient institutional context. They differ however in the
expected impact of corruption in a deficient institutional context. Namely, the grease the
wheels hypothesis predicts that corruption may help raise efficiency. By contrast, the sand the
wheels hypothesis predicts that an increase in corruption will reduce efficiency, even in a
deficient institutional context. In the next section, we describe how we put these two
competing hypotheses to an empirical trial.
3. Methodology
In this section, we explain how we measure aggregate efficiency, and then present its
determinants that are taken into account.
3.1. Measuring efficiency
Our aim is to measure aggregate efficiency in order to assess its link with corruption.
With this end in mind, we apply frontier efficiency techniques. Namely, we assess technical
efficiency, which measures how close a country’s production is to what a country’s optimal
production would be for using the same bundle of inputs. To measure efficiency, we use the
7
stochastic frontier approach, a method developed by Aigner, Lovell and Schmidt (1977) and
applied at the aggregate level notably by Adkins et al. (2002).
There are several reasons why macroeconomic productivity is better measured using
this approach rather than more common measures of productivity. First, it provides a
synthetic measure of productivity. Indeed, unlike basic productivity measures (e.g. per capita
income), the efficiency scores computed with the stochastic frontier approach allow us to
include several input dimensions in evaluating performances. As a result, output is not only
compared to the labor stock, but also to both the physical and human capital stocks.
Second, it provides relative measures of productivity. Namely, a common production
frontier is estimated, which allows the comparison of each country to the best-practice
countries. As a result, the efficiency score assesses how close a country’s actual production is
to what its optimal production would be for using the same bundle of inputs. This then gives
us a relative measure of productivity.
Third, whereas total factor productivity measures assess performance by the whole
residual from the production frontier for each country, the stochastic frontier approach allows
us to separate the distance to the production frontier into an inefficiency term and a random
error, taking into account exogenous events.
After having assessed each country’s level of efficiency, we may determine the
interrelationship between corruption, governance and efficiency in order to test the grease the
wheels versus the sand the wheels hypothesis. A natural way of estimating this relationship
would be to resort to a two-stage approach. This approach would consist of first estimating
efficiency scores, and then regressing them on the relevant set of explanatory variables.
Although widely used in microeconomic studies, this approach is inconsistent, as it assumes
in the first stage that inefficiencies are independently distributed, while the second-stage
regression does not respect the independence assumption.
Consequently, we resort to the one-stage approach developed by Battese and
Coelli (1995), whereby the stochastic frontier model includes a production frontier as well as
an equation in which inefficiencies are specified as a function of explanatory variables. This
approach is more consistent than the two-stage approach, which explains its application in
studies of the determinants of technical efficiency at the aggregate level, such as Adkins et
al. (2002).
Our stochastic frontier model thus includes two equations. The first one is the
specification of the production frontier. We assume a constant returns-to-scale Cobb-Douglas
8
production technology 6 , which we write as:
ln (Y/L)it = α0 + α1 ln (K/L)it + α2 ln (H/L)it + vit − uit
(1)
where i indexes countries and t the year of observation. (Y/L), (K/L), (H/L) are output
per worker, capital per worker, and human capital per worker respectively. vit is a random
disturbance, which reflects luck or measurement errors. It is assumed to have a normal
distribution with zero mean and variance σv². uit is an inefficiency term, capturing technical
inefficiencies. It is a one-sided component with variance σu². As is common in the literature,
we assume a half-normal distribution for the inefficiency term.
The second equation is the specification of inefficiencies as:
uit =δ zit + Wit
(2)
where uit is country i’s inefficiency, zit is a p×1 vector of p explanatory variables, δ is a
1×p vector of parameters to be estimated, Wit the random variable defined by the truncation of
the normal distribution with mean zero and variance σ ² = σu² + σv².
Finally, we use the Frontier software version 4.1 developed by Coelli (1996) to perform
the maximum likelihood estimation of the stochastic frontier model.
3.2. Testing the two competing hypotheses
The test of the grease the wheels and the sand the wheels hypotheses that we use
consists in assessing how a modification of the quality of the institutional framework affects
the impact of corruption on efficiency. More precisely, the relationship between the
coefficient of corruption in expression 2 and the quality of governance must be assessed.
Following Méon and Sekkat (2005), we do so by including an interaction term between a
corruption index and a governance index in expression (2), in addition to usual explanatory
variables. The estimated relationship therefore reads:
uit = δ0 + δ1 corrupi + δ2 corrupi × govi + δ3 govi + δc controlit + Wit
6
(3a)
When Hall and Jones (1999) estimate aggregate productivity in a related cross-country study, they find that
results obtained with a Cobb-Douglas production function are very similar to the results obtained when the
production function is not restricted to that specification. Kneller and Stevens (2003) reached similar conclusions
when estimating aggregate efficiency frontiers.
We also adopt constant returns-to-scale because, as Moroney and Lovell (1997, p.1086) put it, “at the economywide level, constant returns-to-scale is virtually compelling”.
9
where uit is country i’s inefficiency, corrupi a measure of corruption, govi a measure of the
quality of its institutional framework, and controlit a vector of control variables. δ0, δ1, δ2,
and δ3 are scalars, whereas δc is a vector of coefficients.
A reformulation of expression (3) shows more clearly how it can be used to test the
grease the wheels and the sand the wheels hypotheses:
uit = δ0 + (δ1 + δ2 × govi) corrupi + δ3 govi + δc controlit + Wit
(3b)
In order to answer the question we address, the key parameters are δ1 and δ2 . To
understand why, let us first assume that the sand the wheels hypothesis holds. In this case,
corruption always has a negative impact on efficiency, but that impact worsens when the
institutional framework deteriorates. The coefficient of corruption must therefore always be
positive but less so when the institutional framework is efficient. Accordingly, δ1 must be
positive but δ2 negative. Thereby the positive impact of corruption on inefficiency is a
decreasing function of the quality of the other dimensions of governance.
Let us now assume instead that the grease the wheels hypothesis holds. In this case,
corruption has a positive effect on efficiency when the quality of governance is very low, but
an effect that becomes negative when the quality of governance is high. Thus, it has a
negative impact on inefficiency if the index of governance is close to zero. For the coefficient
of corruption to be negative when govi is very small, coefficient δ1 must be negative.
However, the “grease the wheels hypothesis” implies that inefficiency is positively correlated
with corruption when governance is satisfactory, namely when govi is large. δ2 must therefore
be positive. Moreover, for the grease the wheels hypothesis to be verified, the value must be
such that the overall coefficient of the corruption index (δ1 + δ2 × govi) may be negative for
low values of the governance parameter. That is, corruption must be negatively associated
with inefficiency for at least the worst governed country.
That δ1 and δ2 bear the necessary signs does not ensure however that the grease the
wheels hypothesis, as defined in the previous section, strictly holds. Instead, the value of the
coefficients and the range of the relevant governance index can be such that no country in our
sample will present a negative overall coefficient of corruption. In this case, the observed
coefficients simply mean that corruption is detrimental everywhere but less so in countries
where governance is poor.
10
One may therefore observe two forms of the grease the wheels hypothesis, depending
on the value of the coefficients and the range of the relevant governance index. Namely, if the
relevant governance index can reach such a low level that the overall coefficient of corruption
may be negative, then greater corruption can indeed reduce aggregate inefficiency in some
countries. This situation will henceforth be referred to as the “strong” grease the wheels
hypothesis. If, instead, no country in the sample exhibits a low enough institutional quality for
the overall coefficient of corruption to become positive, then the estimated coefficients only
imply that corruption is less detrimental in countries plagued by a deficient institutional
framework than in other countries. Corruption however remains positively correlated with
inefficiency in all countries. From now on, this result will be referred to as the “weak” grease
the wheels hypothesis. In any case, one must keep in mind that even the strong form of the
grease the wheels hypothesis never implies that corruption improves efficiency in all
countries. In contrast, it only does in those where governance is defective enough.
4. Data
We use three sets of data: measures of corruption, measures of the quality of
governance, and macroeconomic data. These must be described in turn.
4.1. Corruption data
Whereas corruption is easily defined as “the use of public office for private gains” (see
e.g. Bardhan, 1997), its proper measurement is less consensual. Basically, available measures
of corruption that allow cross-country comparisons fall into three broad categories. The first
set of indicators uses pools of experts to assess the level of corruption that prevails in a
country. More often than not, these ratings come from private risk-rating agencies, such as
Business International Corporation, whose index was used by Mauro (1995) for instance. The
second type of index is based on the results of surveys conducted on residents that are usually
carried out by international or non-governmental organizations. The index provided by the
World Economic Forum’s Global Competitiveness Report, used by Wei (2000), falls into this
category.
The third category consists of composite indices that aggregate those of the previous
two categories. This kind of index has two main advantages. First, composite indices allow
the biases of specific indices to cancel each other out, therefore determining an average
opinion of corruption. This advantage is sizeable, as basic indicators may be plagued by
11
important biases since they are subjective by construction. Secondly, composite indices can
provide data for wider samples of countries because they aggregate several other indices
thereby allowing one index to fill the gaps of another.
In this study, we use two composite indices and one survey index to assess the
consequences of corruption. Each index is used in turn, both as a robustness check and to
allow comparison with previous studies. Namely, we focus on the corruption index provided
by the World Bank (henceforth WB), and complement our results with those obtained with
the Corruption Perception Index (hereafter CPI) published by Transparency International, and
the corruption index used by Wei (2000) (from now on Wei).
The CPI index is available directly from the Transparency International website. This
index is simply an average of other indices. It ranges from zero, the most corrupt situation, to
ten, the least so. For the sake of clarity, we used the opposite of this index in our
computations so that an increase in the index can be directly interpreted as an increase in the
level of corruption.
The World Bank’s corruption indicator is also a composite index. However it is
estimated by an unobserved component model instead of being a simple average of existing
indices. 7 The CPI and the WB indices also differ in the sets of basic indicators of corruption
that they aggregate. 8 Therefore the two indices are complement each other, since they
aggregate two different sets of indicators using two different methods. 9
The WB indicator can be found in the Governance database posted on the World
Bank’s website. It ranges from −2.5 to +2.5. Like the CPI index, it is built so that an increase
of the index reflects a better control of corruption. To transform it from an indicator of probity
to an indicator of corruption, it was rescaled so as to increase with the level of corruption.
Wei (2000)’s index is an extension of the corruption index published in the World
Economic Forum’s Global Competitiveness Report 1997. To increase the coverage of his
dataset, Wei (2000) filled the gaps left by that first index with the information provided by the
World Bank’s World Development Report 1997.
Finally, in order to properly compare their estimates, all three indices were rescaled so
as to range from 0 to 10.
7
The construction of the World Bank’s index is described in Kaufmann et al. (1999a).
The interested reader may find an exhaustive description of the composition of each indicator in
Lambsdorff (1999) and Kaufmann et al. (1999b).
9
Dreher et al. (2007) moreover found that the CPI was strongly correlated with estimates of the extent of
corruption based on a structural model.
8
12
4.2. Governance data
Like corruption, other facets of governance do not lend themselves easily to an
objective evaluation. Quantitative indicators of governance therefore rest on subjective
evaluations. To date, the largest and most comprehensive set of data assessing institutional
quality is the data set from which our second corruption measure was extracted. Kaufmann et
al. (1999a, b) classify available indicators of governance into six clusters and aggregated them
into as many composite indices. 10 Each composite indicator represents a different dimension
of governance and ranges from –2.5 to +2.5, higher values being associated with better
governance. They were however all rescaled so as to range from 0 to 10, where 10
corresponds to the best possible governance. Having already explained the World Bank’s
corruption index in the previous section, we will now simply give the definitions of the other
five indicators as reported in Kaufmann et al. (1999b).
Table 2
Summary statistics on corruption and other governance variables
Variable
Mean
Minimum
Maximum
4.16
Standard
Deviation
2.06
Corruption WB
0.74
7.20
Corruption CPI
3.91
2.62
0.06
7.95
Corruption WEI
4.01
2.32
0.50
7.50
Voice
6.04
1.72
2.66
8.38
Lackviol
5.58
1.74
2.42
8.38
Goveff
5.88
1.86
2.74
9.16
Reg
6.10
0.89
4.32
7.48
Rulelaw
5.90
1.97
2.56
9.00
Higher values of corruption indices indicate a greater prevalence of corruption, while other indices
increase with the governance quality. Those statistics are computed for the sample of 54 countries.
The first pair of indicators measures aspects of governance that have been the focus of
a literature devoted to assessing the impact of democracy and political stability. More
precisely, Kaufmann et al. (1999a, b) “voice and accountability” indicator (Voice) measures
“the extent to which citizens of a country are able to participate in the selection of
governments”. It accordingly assesses the openness of the political system. The “lack of
10
For an example of utilization of those indices, one may either refer to Kaufmann et al. (1999b)’s original paper
or Easterly and Levine (2003).
13
political violence” indicator (Lackviol) provides an assessment of the political risk associated
to a country. It “measures perceptions of the likelihood that the government in power will be
destabilized or overthrown by possibly unconstitutional and/or violent means”.
The second pair of indicators assesses the soundness of a country’s policies and the
quality of the administration that is in charge of implementing them. Accordingly, the
indicator called “government effectiveness” (Goveff), concerns the “perceptions of the quality
of public service provision, the quality of the bureaucracy, the competence of the civil
servants, the independence of the civil service from political pressures, and the credibility of
the government’s commitment to policies”. The “regulatory burden” indicator (Reg) captures
“the incidence of market unfriendly policies such as price controls or inadequate bank
supervision, as well as perceptions of the burden imposed by excessive regulation”.
The final indicator provided by Kaufmann et al. (1999a, b) assesses the level of
respect of citizens have for their country’s legal framework. This “rule of law” indicator refers
to “the extent to which agents have confidence in and abide by the rules of society”
(Rulelaw). A chief component of this cluster is the enforceability of contracts.
4.3. Macroeconomic data and control variables
Real output per worker and labor force data are taken from the World Bank Indicators
database. Real capital per worker data are provided by Nehru and Dhareshwar (1994). They
were complemented after 1990 by applying the perpetual inventory method on real
investment figures from the World Bank. Because they are measured in local currency at
1987 prices, and because our computations require comparisons of output and input levels, we
convert them in US dollars, using the annual average exchange rate provided by the Macro
time series database of the World Bank. To smooth the impact of extreme exchange rate
fluctuations, we use an average of the exchange rate computed over the period 1985-1989.
Human capital is proxied by the total number of years of schooling of the working-age
population over 15 years old. That dataset is taken from the Barro-Lee (2000) education
dataset, and can be downloaded from the Economic Growth Resources website.
Due to the limited size of our sample, the number of control variables must remain
small. We restricted ourselves accordingly to three control variables that are commonly used
in the literature. The first one is openness to trade. It is proxied by Sachs and Warner (1995)’s
index (Openness). Although the debate on the impact of trade on growth is at least as old as
economics itself, recent evidence from Edwards (1998) among others suggests that openness
may be positively linked to productivity.
14
The second control variable is the index of ethno-linguistic fractionalization (Ethno.
Frac.). This index measures the probability that two individuals drawn at random from the
population of a country do not speak the same language. Mauro (1995) or Hall and
Jones (1999) for instance use this index. This variable is usually interpreted as proxying a
country’s sources of long-term political unrest.
As a third control variable, we consider latitude (Latitude). A negative correlation
between distance from the equator and economic performance has repeatedly been reported,
for instance in Sachs (2001), although no consensual explanation to this finding exists. 11
We focus on the years 1994 to 1997 because 1997 is the latest for which the capital per
worker ratio is available. Using the contemporaneous vintages of corruption and governance
indices, we could gather a data set for a sample of up to 54 countries whose descriptive
statistics are displayed in table 3. That sample features both developed and developing
countries, as the range of output per worker points out.
Table 3
Summary statistics on economic and control variables
Variable
Mean
Y/L
13,856.84
Standard
Deviation
14,844.14
Minimum
Maximum
317.99
43,917.22
K/L
44,392.18
50,528.82
819.42
168,891.01
H/L
10.91
4.56
2.94
Latitude
27.82
17.76
0.23
18.37
Openness
87.96
30.62
0.00
1.00
Ethno. Frac.
37.96
30.16
0.00
90.00
60.21
Y/L, K/L, H/L, are respectively output per worker, capital per worker, and human capital per worker.
Those statistics are computed for the sample of 54 countries.
5. Results
This section presents the main results of our estimations, and provides an assessment
of their significance, followed by robustness checks.
11
Hall and Jones (1999) however suggest that the history of former colonies may be linked to their location.
However, tropical diseases and disasters may also be responsible for that relationship.
15
5.1. Findings
Tables 4a to 4e display our first set of results. In each table, we study the interaction
between corruption and a different dimension of governance. For each of the three corruption
indices the relationship is estimated twice, first without interaction between corruption and
governance, then incorporating an interaction term. The first five lines exhibit the coefficients
of the estimated production frontier, whereas the lower part of the table is devoted to the
coefficients of the equation in which inefficiency is explained. 12 Three year-dummies for
1994, 1995, and 1996 (respectively Year94, Year95, and Year96) were introduced to the
specification of the production function to control for possible year-specific fluctuations of
the frontier.
Table 4a: estimation with voice and accountability as the governance variable
Intercept
Log (K/L)
Log (H/L)
Year94
Year95
Year96
Intercept
Corruption
WB
Without
With
interaction interaction
4a.1
4a.2
CPI
Without
With
interaction interaction
4a.3
4a.4
WEI
Without
With
interaction interaction
4a.5
4a.6
0.3448
(0.99)
0.8311***
(33.52)
0.1646***
(2.89)
-0.0065
(-0.20)
-0.0025
(-0.08)
0.0012
(0.04)
-3.2099
(-1.30)
0.4025
(1.57)
1.0800***
(3.07)
0.8134***
(48.92)
0.3302***
(4.79)
-0.0084
(-0.28)
-0.0015
(-0.05)
0.6971E-3
(0.02)
-0.9301***
(-2.69)
0.0659***
(4.24)
-0.4353
(-1.24)
0.8889***
(39.70)
0.0395
(0.63)
-0.0017
(-0.05)
0.0030
(0.09)
0.0051
(0.14)
1.3793*
(1.74)
-0.1208
(-1.17)
Corruption×Voice
Voice
Openness
Latitude
Ethno. Fraction.
Sigma
0.3067
(1.29)
-0.6209
(-1.27)
-0.0177
(-1.13)
-0.0014
(-0.44)
0.1274*
0.8604***
(2.63)
0.7858***
(35.98)
0.2386***
(4.21)
-0.0146
(-0.44)
-0.0059
(-0.18)
-0.0013
(-0.04)
2.1358**
(2.04)
-0.4517**
(-2.11)
0.1220***
(2.73)
-0.5344**
(-2.38)
-0.1929**
(-2.12)
-0.7100E-4
(-0.02)
0.0010
(0.81)
0.0764***
0.0783*
(1.87)
0.1630**
(2.43)
-0.0048*
(-1.84)
0.0026***
(2.91)
0.0148***
12
1.1873***
(3.70)
0.8015***
(42.99)
0.3425***
(5.62)
-0.0115
(-0.40)
-0.0011
(-0.04)
0.0016
(0.05)
-0.0096
(-0.02)
-0.0504
(-0.64)
0.0199
(1.42)
-0.0942
(-1.04)
0.2058***
(2.76)
0.0011
(0.52)
0.0021***
(3.08)
0.0165***
0.2203
(1.53)
-2.0841*
(-1.67)
-0.0767*
(-1.67)
-0.0133
(-1.33)
0.2790**
-0.2137
(-0.53)
0.8729***
(30.14)
0.0754
(1.13)
-0.0028
(-0.08)
0.0020
(0.06)
0.0036
(0.10)
3.1050*
(1.82)
-0.6471
(-1.49)
0.1056*
(1.82)
-0.2748***
(-2.61)
-1.6042
(-0.96)
-0.0551
(-1.01)
-0.0051
(-0.48)
0.2622
A minus sign indicates that an increase in the explanatory variable leads to less inefficiency, that is a rise in
efficiency.
16
Log−likelihood
LRT
N
(1.90)
65.432
216
(4.43)
71.547
12.23
***
216
(3.47)
104.047
(7.01)
104.520
0.946
(1.98)
50.967
(1.33)
51.398
0.862
144
144
204
204
t-statistics are displayed in parentheses under the coefficient estimates. *, **, *** denote an estimate
significantly different from zero at the 10%, 5% or 1% level.
17
Table 4b: estimation with lack of political violence as the governance variable
WB
Intercept
Log (K/L)
Log (H/L)
Year94
Year95
Year96
Intercept
Corruption
Openness
Latitude
Ethno. Fraction.
Sigma
Log−likelihood
LRT
N
WEI
Without
With
interaction interaction
4b.1
4b.2
Without
interaction
4b.3
With
interaction
4b.4
Without
interaction
4b.5
With
interaction
4b.6
0.4514
(1.23)
0.8156***
(30.35)
0.1659***
(2.85)
-0.0121
(-0.38)
-0.0052
(-0.17)
-0.4051E-3
(-0.01)
-1.1353
(-1.34)
0.2208**
(2.15)
0.8233**
(2.38)
0.8169***
(47.35)
0.2745***
(4.22)
-0.0085
(-0.28)
-0.7048E-3
(-0.02)
0.5146E-3
(0.02)
-0.6110***
(-3.20)
0.0601***
(3.92)
1.2109***
(3.67)
0.7857***
(44.07)
0.3342***
(5.25)
-0.0044
(-0.15)
0.3824E-4
(0.13E-2)
0.0076
(0.26)
0.2931
(0.72)
-0.0542
(-0.93)
0.0209*
(1.87)
-0.1241*
(-1.75)
0.1471**
(2.35)
-0.9156E-3
(-0.51)
0.0018**
(2.29)
0.0172***
(7.69)
104.858
4.94
**
144
-0.5863*
(-1.90)
0.8947***
(45.31)
0.0114
(0.21)
0.0010
(0.03)
0.0022
(0.07)
0.0031
(0.09)
4.6206**
(2.24)
-0.3515*
(-1.86)
0.5091
(1.36)
0.8081***
(31.39)
0.1802***
(2.91)
-0.0115
(-0.34)
-0.0064
(-0.19)
0.0015
(0.05)
3.8438***
(3.56)
-0.5839***
(-2.86)
0.1127***
(2.86)
-0.6313***
(-3.02)
-0.2922***
(-2.71)
-0.0104**
(-2.46)
-0.1589E-3
(-0.12)
0.0742***
(6.07)
63.869
23.55
***
204
Corruption×Lackviol
Lackviol
CPI
0.1008
(1.52)
-0.3384*
(-1.80)
-0.0091
(-1.34)
-0.9100E-3
(-0.49)
0.0991**
(2.28)
61.720
216
0.9096***
(2.82)
0.7674***
(38.43)
0.2314***
(4.06)
-0.0146
(-0.45)
-0.0065
(-0.20)
-0.0016
(-0.05)
2.0539**
(2.28)
-0.3446**
(-2.23)
0.1002***
(3.24)
-0.4692***
(-2.73)
-0.1703*
(-1.87)
-0.0052
(-1.58)
0.0007
(0.49)
0.0647***
(5.35)
69.292
15.14
***
216
0.0091
(0.54)
0.2091***
(4.22)
0.6081E-3
(0.36)
0.0024***
(3.66)
0.0147***
(5.09)
102.387
144
-0.3496**
(-2.19)
-1.4482**
(-2.25)
-0.0577**
(-2.19)
-0.0113*
(-1.86)
0.2465***
(3.02)
52.093
204
t-statistics are displayed in parentheses under the coefficient estimates. *, **, *** denote an estimate
significantly different from zero at the 10%, 5% or 1% level.
18
Table 4c: estimation with government efficiency as the governance variable
WB
CPI
Without
With
Without
interaction interaction interaction
4c.1
4c.2
4c.3
0.1719
0.4516
(0.50)
(1.30)
0.8283*** 0.7951***
Log (K/L)
(34.70)
(34.96)
0.1162**
0.1526**
Log (H/L)
(2.02)
(2.55)
-0.0128
-0.0155
Year94
(-0.40)
(-0.46)
-0.0048
-0.0050
Year95
(-0.15)
(-0.15)
-0.7773E-3 0.2914E-3
Year96
(-0.02)
(0.01)
2.0598***
3.9650***
Intercept
(2.86)
(4.71)
-0.0946
-0.4692***
Corruption
(-1.35)
(-3.43)
0.0765***
Corruption×Goveff
(3.00)
-0.2755***
-0.6426***
Goveff
(-2.70)
(-4.35)
-0.0991
-0.0614
Openness
(-0.99)
(-0.52)
-0.0056
-0.0025
Latitude
(-1.27)
(-0.67)
E
E
0.5410
-3
0.7762
-3
Ethno. Fraction.
(0.35)
(0.51)
0.0768*** 0.0632***
Sigma
(3.05)
(5.57)
69.453
75.544
Log−likelihood
12.18
LRT
***
216
216
N
Intercept
0.6992**
(2.06)
0.8199***
(46.05)
0.2487***
(3.90)
-0.0085
(-0.28)
-0.0017
(-0.05)
-0.2176E-3
(-0.01)
-0.1276
(-0.50)
0.0291
(1.45)
-0.0565**
(-2.02)
0.2473***
(4.68)
0.0014
(1.01)
0.0023***
(3.23)
0.0138***
(5.24)
105.264
144
WEI
With
Without
With
interaction interaction interaction
4c.4
4c.5
4c.6
0.9436***
(2.90)
0.8000***
(47.22)
0.2874***
(4.65)
-0.0124
(-0.42)
-0.0021
(-0.07)
0.9863E-3
(0.03)
0.4688
(1.14)
-0.0430
(-0.78)
0.0090
(1.10)
-0.1132**
(-2.09)
0.1711***
(3.00)
0.6880E-4
(0.05)
0.0021***
(3.39)
0.0136***
(5.52)
105.175
-0.178
144
-0.3056
0.6036*
(-0.80)
(1.67)
0.8573*** 0.7864***
(29.20)
(31.08)
0.0408
0.1797***
(0.68)
(2.88)
-0.0061
-0.0136
(-0.19)
(-0.37)
E
0.4378 -3
-0.0134
(0.01)
(-0.37)
0.0018
0.0039
(0.05)
(0.11)
2.1086*** 3.3328***
(2.67)
(9.66)
-0.1103 -0.4425***
(-1.36)
(-5.38)
0.0821***
(4.44)
-0.3078** -0.5848***
(-2.55)
(-7.20)
-0.0935
-0.0622
(-0.92)
(-0.61)
-0.0061
0.2159E-3
(-0.83)
(0.06)
0.0017
0.0010E-2
(0.97)
(0.79)
0.0685*** 0.0589***
(3.14)
(4.37)
71.803
80.853
18.09
***
204
204
t-statistics are displayed in parentheses under the coefficient estimates. *, **, *** denote an estimate
significantly different from zero at the 10%, 5% or 1% level.
19
Table 4d: estimation with quality of the regulatory framework as the governance variable
Intercept
Log (K/L)
Log (H/L)
Year94
Year95
Year96
Intercept
Corruption
WB
CPI
Without
With
Without
With
interaction interaction interaction interaction
4d.1
4d.2
4d.3
4d.4
Without
interaction
4d.5
With
interaction
4d.6
0.4084
(1.08)
0.8201***
(29.67)
0.1633***
(2.72)
-0.0087
(-0.27)
-0.0036
(-0.11)
0.6311E-3
(0.02)
-1.6603
(-1.27)
0.2306*
(1.77)
-0.4409
(-1.48)
0.8877***
(48.96)
0.0364
(0.68)
-0.0021
(-0.06)
0.0015
(0.04)
0.0022
(0.07)
3.4951*
(1.83)
-0.1783
(-1.56)
0.4863
(1.02)
0.8155***
(22.84)
0.1720**
(2.31)
-0.0132
(-0.38)
-0.0047
(-0.14)
0.2607E-4
(0.78E-3)
3.8040**
(2.14)
-0.6534*
(-1.83)
0.1138*
(1.91)
-0.5582*
(-1.85)
-0.4147**
(-2.26)
-0.0110
(-1.63)
0.4229E-3
(0.25)
0.1074**
(2.45)
53.257
6.06
**
204
Corruption×Reg
Reg
Openness
Latitude
Ethno. Fraction.
Sigma
Log−likelihood
LRT
N
0.1654
(1.39)
-0.5027
(-1.51)
-0.0086
(-1.07)
-0.7423E-3
(-0.31)
0.1139*
(1.83)
61.681
216
0.6082*
(1.91)
0.8027***
(34.74)
0.1945***
(3.66)
-0.0108
(0.34)
-0.0048
(-0.15)
-0.1495E-3
(-0.48E-2)
4.6520*
(1.65)
-0.8768
(1.62)
0.1781*
(1.79)
-0.8530*
(-1.66)
-0.4194**
(2.13)
-0.0056
(1.35)
0.5867E-4
(0.04)
0.1008***
(2.57)
66.156
8.95
***
216
0.8264**
(2.31)
0.8158***
(43.52)
0.2718***
(4.10)
-0.0113
(-0.39)
-0.0038
(-0.13)
-0.0031
(-0.11)
-0.4493*
(-1.69)
0.0568***
(3.69)
-0.0274
(-0.71)
0.2587***
(3.53)
0.0012
(0.80)
0.0026***
(3.46)
0.0152***
(3.97)
101.876
144
0.9124***
(2.87)
0.8192***
(42.95)
0.2962***
(4.94)
-0.0107
(-0.37)
-0.0016
(-0.05)
0.5759E-3
(0.02)
1.5749
(1.57)
-0.2711*
(-1.72)
0.0496**
(2.05)
-0.2991**
(-2.03)
0.1242
(1.33)
-0.6184E-5
(-0.41E-2)
0.0017***
(2.74)
0.0150***
(5.99)
104.831
5.91
**
144
WEI
-0.1548*
(-1.80)
-1.8285
(-1.49)
-0.0735*
(-1.66)
-0.0157
(-1.10)
0.3078**
(2.09)
50.226
204
t-statistics are displayed in parentheses under the coefficient estimates. *, **, *** denote an estimate
significantly different from zero at the 10%, 5% or 1% level.
20
Table 4e: estimation with the rule of law as the governance variable
WB
Intercept
Log (K/L)
Log (H/L)
Year94
Year95
Year96
Intercept
Corruption
Without
With
Without
With
interaction interaction interaction interaction
4e.1
4e.2
4e.3
4e.4
WEI
Without
With
interaction interaction
4e.5
4e.6
-0.1522
(-0.47)
0.8586***
(41.35)
0.0768
(1.36)
-0.0037
(-0.11)
-0.1141E-4
(-0.36E-3)
0.2292E-2
(0.07)
3.5793
(1.46)
-0.1834
(-0.86)
-0.6727**
(-2.43)
0.8849***
(54.16)
-0.0075
(-0.15)
0.0034
(0.11)
0.0058
(0.19)
0.0062
(0.20)
3.2598***
(8.18)
-0.2117***
(-5.68)
Corruption×Rulelaw
Rulelaw
Openness
Latitude
Ethno. Fraction.
Sigma
Log−likelihood
LRT
N
-0.4717
(-1.63)
-0.7549*
(-1.70)
-0.0136
(-1.24)
-0.0028
(-0.69)
0.1622*
(1.90)
63.627
216
CPI
0.5541*
(1.66)
0.7917***
(38.92)
0.1743***
(2.96)
-0.0136
(-0.43)
-0.0062
(-0.20)
-0.0012
(-0.04)
3.9667***
(4.85)
-0.5261***
(-3.83)
0.0961***
(3.68)
-0.6599***
(-4.54)
-0.1813*
(-1.76)
-0.0019
(-0.51)
0.2441E-3
(0.17)
0.0683***
(6.02)
74.518
21,78
***
216
0.8085**
(2.26)
0.8163***
(40.06)
0.2701***
(4.09)
-0.0094
(-0.31)
-0.0014
(-0.05)
0.6370E-3
(0.02)
-0.3101
(-1.27)
0.0385**
(2.01)
-0.0278
(-1.23)
0.2148***
(3.82)
0.0010
(0.77)
0.0025***
(3.37)
0.0146***
(4.62)
102.536
144
1.1026***
(3.31)
0.7849***
(40.84)
0.3056***
(4.70)
-0.0157
(-0.52)
-0.0038
(-0.13)
0.0017
(0.06)
1.0963*
(1.94)
-0.1390*
(-1.84)
0.0283**
(2.37)
-0.1985**
(-2.44)
0.0721
(1.39)
-0.0015
(-0.97)
0.0013*
(1.75)
0.0157***
(5.70)
105.398
5,72
**
144
-0.4664***
(-5.77)
-0.4396***
(-3.72)
0.0054
(0.94)
0.7511E-4
(0.05)
0.0568***
(6.52)
76.729
204
0.2191
(0.64)
0.8064***
(35.22)
0.1146**
(1.96)
-0.4305E-3
(-0.01)
0.0059
(0.18)
0.0170
(0.54)
3.8128***
(10.40)
-0.5197***
(-7.61)
0.0951***
(6.57)
-0.6396***
(-8.02)
-0.1255
(-1.52)
-0.0014
(-0.37)
0.3705E-3
(0.30)
0.0562***
(4.48)
90.275
27,09
***
204
t-statistics are displayed in parentheses under the coefficient estimates. *, **, *** denote an estimate
significantly different from zero at the 10%, 5% or 1% level.
At first glance, the estimated production frontiers are stable across estimations.
Moreover, estimated coefficients are similar to those reported in the literature, as for instance
in Kneller and Stevens (2003). Year-dummies never exhibit a significant coefficient, which
suggests that no major shift of the frontier was observed for the years featured in our study.
21
In addition, all control variables are either intuitively signed or insignificant. Thus the
openness index is usually correctly signed and often significant. The only exception appears
with the CPI, where openness can bear a positive and significant sign, although not in all
regressions, and in particular not in those that feature the interaction term between the CPI
and governance. The relationship between inefficiency and latitude is less surprising. As
expected, the sign of its coefficient is either insignificant or negative, implying that
inefficiency ceteris paribus tends to decrease as one moves away from the equator. Finally,
ethnic fractionalization is more robust than latitude, as it is positively and significantly
associated with inefficiency in eleven estimations. Accordingly, more ethnic homogeneity
appears to be positively correlated with aggregate efficiency.
With regards to the institutional and corruption variables, the general picture that
emerges from tables 4a to 4e is strikingly consistent across specifications, and regardless of
the governance variable taken into account. Thus, in benchmark estimations, that is oddnumbered ones, the relevant governance indicator is always negatively signed or insignificant,
the only exception being voice and accountability in the estimation that also features the CPI
among regressors. Accordingly, aggregate efficiency unsurprisingly rises with the quality of
governance as measured by the World Bank indicators.
In the same benchmark estimations, corruption indices lead to the same qualitative
results. Namely, the coefficient that affects corruption is positive in six estimations out of
fifteen, insignificant in seven estimations, and negative in only two estimations. If anything,
this finding means that greater corruption is on average associated with greater inefficiency in
the sample of our study. Again these results are in line with previous results on the impact of
corruption on growth, like Mauro (1995), or productivity growth, like Olson et al. (2000).
However, the most striking result, which is central to the question that is raised in the
present paper, materializes in even-numbered estimations, i.e. when the interaction term
between corruption and other facets of governance is added to the set of explanatory
variables. The coefficients that were significant in odd-numbered estimations remain
significant after including the interaction term. The only exception is the voice and
accountability index in estimation 4a.4, whose sign already appeared odd in 4a.3. In some of
our estimations, coefficients that were not significant become significant. This is particularly
the case of governance indices that are almost always significantly negative in these
estimations, while they were often insignificant in previous estimations. Moreover, loglikelihood most of the time substantially increases with the inclusion of the interaction term,
and even-numbered estimations pass the log-likelihood ratio test against odd-numbered ones.
22
The last two findings are arguments against the pooling of countries regardless of the quality
of their institutional framework.
But the truly remarkable feature of even-numbered estimations appears when one
looks at the coefficients of corruption and of the interaction term. We observe that in these
estimations corruption exhibits either a negative or insignificant coefficient. In addition, the
interaction term is also either positive or insignificant. In terms of our specification, these
results mean that in general δ1 is negative while δ2 is positive. In other words, we find
evidence of the grease the wheels hypothesis.
Finding that δ1 is negative and δ2 positive may be consistent with both the strong and
the weak form of the grease the wheels hypothesis. As indicated by expression (3b)
discriminating between the two versions of the grease the wheels hypothesis requires to
determine whether parameters δ1 and δ2 are such that the overall impact of corruption on
inefficiency may be negative for some low values of the relevant governance index. In order
to determine whether the displayed estimations are consistent with the strong version of the
grease the wheels hypothesis, one must study each estimation in turn and examine jointly the
estimated δ1 and δ2, and the range of the relevant governance index in the sample.
With these remarks in mind, one may classify our featured estimations in three
categories. The first category consists of the estimations that show no sign of any relationship
between corruption and efficiency. These are the estimations where neither δ1 nor δ2 is
significant. Estimations 4a.4. and 4c.4 come into this category.
The other two categories are those consistent with either form of the grease the wheels
hypothesis. 13 These require closer scrutiny. The weak form of the hypothesis appears in
estimations 4a.6, 4b.4, and 4d.2, where δ2 is significantly positive but δ1 is not significantly
different from zero. As governance indices are always positive, these estimations imply that
corruption is positively associated with inefficiency in all countries, but more so in countries
where governance is satisfactory. This is precisely what the weak form of the grease the
wheels hypothesis predicts.
The last category comprises all the estimations that show evidence of the strong form
of the grease the wheels hypothesis. The δ1 and δ2 coefficients of those estimations are such
that the overall coefficient of corruption can be negative, at least for the country that exhibits
the lowest value of the governance index. To illustrate this phenomenon, let us for instance
13
There is no estimation where corruption remains positively and significantly correlated with inefficiency after
the introduction of the interaction term. In other words, we find no instance of the sand the wheels hypothesis.
23
focus on estimation 4c.2, which estimates the interaction between corruption, as measured by
the World Bank index, and government effectiveness. According to this estimation,
δ1 ≅ −0.4692 and δ2 ≅ 0.0765. In addition, the country that fares worst in terms of government
effectiveness (i.e. Zimbabwe) scores 2.74 on the government effectiveness index.
Consequently, the total coefficient of corruption for this country is equal to
(−0.4692 + 0.0765 × 2.74) ≅ −0.2596. According to estimation 4c.2, this country may
improve its efficiency by allowing corruption to rise. Moreover, all countries whose
government effectiveness index is lower than −δ1 / δ2 ≅ 0.4692/0.0765 ≅ 6.13 may face the
same possibility. This means that 29 countries in the sample may be in a position to benefit
from a rise in corruption. Similar findings are obtained in estimations 4a.2, 4b.2, 4b.6, 4c.2,
4c.6, 4d.4, 4d.6, 4e.2, 4e.4, and 4e.6.
Table 5: summary of estimations
WB
Voice
Lackviol
Goveff
Reg
Rulelaw
CPI
Strong GWH
Threshold ≅ 3.70
6 countries
Strong GWH
Threshold ≅ 3.44
6 countries
Strong GWH
Threshold ≅ 6.13
29 countries
WEI
Weak GWH
Weak GWH
Strong GWH
Threshold ≅ 5.47
6 countries
Strong GWH
Threshold ≅ 4.91
1 country
Weak GWH
Strong GWH
Threshold ≅ 5.48
25 countries
Strong GWH
Threshold ≅ 5.18
25 countries
Strong GWH
Threshold ≅ 5.39
26 countries
Strong GWH
Threshold ≅ 5.74
28 countries
Strong GWH
Threshold ≅ 5.47
26 countries
In a nutshell, out of the fifteen estimations that include an interaction term, ten show
evidence of the strong form of the grease the wheels hypothesis, three are consistent with the
weak form of the grease the wheels hypothesis, and two show no sign of a relationship
between corruption and efficiency. None of them suggests a systematic detrimental effect of
corruption on aggregate efficiency. Furthermore, it must be pointed out that at least one
estimation consistent with the strong form of the grease the wheels hypothesis can be found
for each dimension of governance. All in all, one can conclude that there is clear evidence of
some form of grease the wheels hypothesis.
24
An interesting by-product of our estimations is that they allow us to gauge the relative
importance of the interrelationship between corruption and each of the five dimensions of
governance being analyzed. 14 It appears then that government efficiency is clearly the most
robust governance index in our sample. It is thus significantly associated with inefficiency in
all three baseline estimations and all three estimations that include an interaction with
corruption. This is reassuring insofar as this is the aspect of governance that corruption is
theoretically meant to grease. On the other hand, voice and accountability performs worst of
the various dimensions of governance. Namely, it only appears significantly in one baseline
estimation and two that include an interaction term. This finding is by and large consistent
with the literature, where the correlation between democracy and economic outcomes usually
appears fragile.
Finally, all other indices only appear significant in one baseline estimation out of
three, as well as in all estimations including an interaction term.
Our findings therefore contrast with previous empirical results that have in general
supported a clear negative impact of corruption on economic performance, such as
Mauro (1995), or Mo (2001). Most often they have not taken into account the non-linearity of
the estimated relationship. Thus it must be emphasized again that we could achieve more
usual results in our benchmark estimations where the interaction of corruption with other
dimensions of governance was not controlled for. The fact that our results are clearly at odds
with those of Méon and Sekkat (2005), where those interactions were specifically taken into
account may seem somewhat more puzzling. It must however be said that our estimations
cannot be directly compared with those of the above-mentioned authors. Méon and
Sekkat (2005) focused on the impact of corruption on growth and investment, while in this
paper we analyze aggregate efficiency. Also, their period of study is 1970-1998, whereas we
have focused on the years 1994-1997.
5.2. A quantitative assessment
To get a feel of the quantitative significance of our results, let us focus on three
countries from our sample whose government efficiency indicators differ, say the Philippines,
Tunisia, and Chile, and see what a reduction of corruption would imply for them. Our first
14
The results also underline differences between corruption indices. The results obtained with the World Bank’s
index and Wei’s index look very similar, while the CPI index stands out as slightly less robustly associated with
efficiency than the other two. Although we have no ready explanation for these differences, the size of the
sample may well play a sizeable role here.
25
country is plagued by a deficient government. The government efficiency index of our second
country is close to the threshold estimated in table 5. And finally, our third country boasts a
government efficiency index well above the estimated threshold. To save on space, we focus
on government efficiency, as it is the most relevant dimension of governance for the grease
the wheels hypothesis. A similar exercise could be done with other indices. Let us now
assume that these countries succeed in bringing down corruption by one standard deviation of
the World Bank’s corruption index, i.e. two points. Such a reduction would approximately
bring down the level of corruption to that of Italy for the Philippines, to that of Chile for
Tunisia, and to that of the Netherlands for Chile. 15
The coefficients estimated in estimation 4c.2 allow us to evaluate the impact of such a
reduction of corruption on the aggregate efficiency of these three countries under study. 16 To
do so, the first step is to compute the overall coefficient of corruption for each country. With
δ1 ≅ −0.4692 and δ2 ≅ 0.075, the overall coefficient of corruption reaches –0.0668 in the
Philippines, −0.0097 in Tunisia, and +0.092 in Chile, given their governance indices. 17 The
same reduction in the World Bank corruption index would therefore result in a different
impact on efficiency, and hence income. Thus, given each country’s initial efficiency score
and the quality of its government efficiency, the Philippines would witness a drop of 49.3
percentage points of its efficiency score, while Chile would see its efficiency score rise by
50.69 percentage points. The reduction of corruption will be accompanied by a small 5.76
percentage points reduction of Tunisia’s efficiency score.
Moreover, these variations in efficiency are synonymous to variations in output per
worker since they reflect each country’s distance to the common production frontier. 18 Thus,
the Philippines’ output per worker would fall from 1567 to 795 dollars per year, which is
similar to that of Kenya. On the other hand, Chile’s output per worker would rise from 7029
to 10590 dollars per year, which would bring it close to Portugal. Finally, Tunisia’s output per
worker would only rise marginally, from 4081 to 4316 dollars per year. This is not surprising,
15
The rescaled value of the World Bank corruption index is equal to 5.46 for the Philippines, 4.96 for Tunisia,
and 2.94 for Chile. Following a two points reduction in their indices, those countries would respectively end up
near Italy, whose index is 3.4, Chile, whose index is 2.94, and the Netherlands, whose index is equal to 0.94.
16
In fact, the estimated coefficients do not directly measure the first derivative of efficiency with respect to
corruption. Instead, they measure the derivative of ui, defined as ui = −log(efficiency). The variation of efficiency
can therefore be estimated as Δefficiency = (∂efficiency ∂ui ) ⋅ Δui .
17
Recall that the coefficient of corruption in a country is a function of that country’s government efficiency. The
government efficiency index of the three countries under study is respectively equal to 5.26 for the Philippines,
6.26 for Tunisia, and 7.34 for Chile.
18
The simulated value of output can easily be simply computed as y = efficiency i 0 y .
i0
i1
efficiency i 1
26
since government effectiveness in Tunisia is very close to the threshold value. The coefficient
of corruption in that country is therefore very close to zero. At any rate, the main message of
these simulations is that the impact of a reduction of corruption on output may be dramatic in
countries where the governance index takes on extreme values. 19 However, that impact varies
wildly with the quality of the rest of the institutional framework, and can be either positive or
negative.
5.3. Robustness checks
Although our results are obtained while controlling for several country-specific traits,
one may wonder whether they are not subject to a multi-colinearity problem. Namely, one
may for instance expect a positive correlation between corruption and other governance
indicators on the one hand, and the three control variables on the other hand. It can thus be
argued that greater openness to trade may reduce corruption or improve the institutional
framework, as it encourages ideas to circulate and subjects domestic practices to foreign
scrutiny. One may also suspect ethnic fractionalization to affect both institutions and
economic performance, through its impact on trust and social cohesion. Finally, geography
and latitude may also affect both economic performance, as suggested by Sachs (2001), and
income, because, historically, it determined the strategy of colonizers, as Acemoglu et
al. (2001) argue.
To check the robustness of our results to the choice of control variables, we therefore
ran our estimations again, dropping one control variable at a time then dropping all of them. 20
As table A1 in the appendix shows, our results were only slightly affected, either qualitatively
or quantitatively.
Another source of skepticism was that our estimations did not discriminate between
developed and developing countries. Pooling countries regardless of their level of
development may nevertheless neglect the fact that they may be operating along different
production frontiers. In addition, the determinants of efficiency may differ across developed
19
Those orders of magnitude may even seem huge. One should recall that cross-country output level differences
pertain to the long term, as Hall and Jones (1999) remark. The present orders of magnitude are moreover in line
with those reported in the literature. For instance, Mauro (1995) finds that a one standard deviation reduction in
corruption can raise an economy’s growth rate by 0.8 points. After a couple of decades, this would result in a
difference in its level of GDP comparable to the one that we describe here. Along similar lines, Hall and
Jones (1999) observe that differences in institutional quality can account for a 25.2 to 38.4-fold difference in
output per worker across countries.
20
To save on space, we restrict ourselves to one index of corruption, the World Bank index, and to one index of
institutional quality, namely government effectiveness, which is the most relevant to test the grease the wheels
hypothesis.
27
and developing countries. To address this issue, we split our sample into two equivalent
subsets according to per capita income, and created a dummy variable equal to one for every
observation whose per capita income is greater than the median, and zero elsewhere. We then
used this dummy variable in two ways. First, we interacted it with production factors’ stocks,
and included the resulting interaction terms as well as the dummy variable itself into the
expression of the production frontier. This is equivalent to estimating a distinct production
frontier for each sub-sample. The results displayed in table A2 of the appendix show that the
coefficients of the corruption and governance indices were only slightly affected. Second, we
added the dummy variable to the set of explanatory variables. The result of this estimation,
also reported in table A2, also exhibits little influence on governance indicators. Our findings
are therefore robust to distinguishing developed and developing countries.
We were also concerned that our results may be contingent on the period of study. We
accordingly estimated the production frontier with data pertaining to the 1988-1990 period.
That earlier period of time allowed for an additional robustness check, which consisted in
using a different dataset on output and capital per worker, namely Easterly and
Levine (2001)’s dataset. Table A2 reports the results of these estimations. Once again, the
coefficients of the governance and corruption indices remained significant, and exhibited
signs consistent with the grease the wheels hypothesis.
Our final concern was that the results might be driven by the Cobb-Douglas
specification of the production frontier with constant returns to scale. We therefore tested two
alternative specifications. The first one is a translog production function, which is specified as
follows:
ln (Y/L)it = α0 + α1 ln (K/L)it + α2 ln (H/L)it + α3 [ln (K/L)it]2 + α4 [ln (H/L)it]2
+ α5 ln (K/L)it ln (H/L)it + vit − uit
(4)
The second one is a production frontier with variable returns to scale. Namely, the
production frontier is similar to the one presented in equation (1) if we except that production,
physical capital and human capital are not normalized by labor, and that labor is added as a
term in the frontier. The results of these estimations are displayed in table A3. In both
estimations, the coefficients of the corruption and governance indices remained similar to
previous ones, both qualitatively and quantitatively. Our results are therefore robust to various
specifications of the production frontier.
Our findings have thus survived several robustness checks, leading to coefficients of
the corruption and governance indices that are consistent with the grease the wheels
28
hypothesis. More to the point, it must be stressed that their magnitude was systematically
consistent with the strong form of the grease the wheels hypothesis, implying that corruption
may lead to greater efficiency in some countries of the sample.
6. Concluding remarks
The present paper specifically tests the grease the wheels hypothesis and the sand the
wheels hypothesis of corruption by focusing on aggregate efficiency. Unlike most previous
studies, the results provide no evidence of the sand the wheels hypothesis but substantial
evidence of the grease the wheels hypothesis. Both the weak and the strong forms of the
grease the wheels hypothesis are observed. Namely, although it is repeatedly found that
corruption is less detrimental in countries where the rest of the institutional framework is
weaker, our estimations do not always imply that an increase in corruption may be beneficial
in at least one country in the sample. However, for each of the five dimensions of governance
taken into account, we find evidence of the strong grease the wheels hypothesis in at least one
estimation.
A possible policy implication of these results might be that countries plagued with a
very inefficient institutional framework may benefit from letting corruption grow. This
interpretation is however extreme and risky. A country that would let corruption frolic may
find itself stuck later on with an even worse global institutional framework, and thus end up in
a bad governance/low efficiency trap.
Encouraging countries to fight corruption while also striving to improve other aspects
of governance, mainly government efficiency, constitutes perhaps a safer advice. Indeed,
successful policy package should be multifaceted, while narrower reform programs may
instead prove counter productive. Which of these two sets of advice to follow depends
however on the dynamics of the interrelationship between corruption, governance, and
economic performance, which is not fully understood yet. Understanding these dynamics
should therefore feature highly on the political economy research agenda.
29
Appendix
A1: Countries in the sample
Australia, Austria, Belgium, Bolivia, Cameroon, Canada, Chile, Colombia; Costa Rica,
Denmark, Ecuador, Egypt, El Salvador, Finland, France, Ghana, Guatemala, Honduras,
India, Indonesia, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Jamaica, Japan, Jordan, Kenya, Korea (Republic),
Malawi, Malaysia, Mauritius, Mexico, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Pakistan,
Paraguay, Philippines, Portugal, Senegal, Singapore, South Africa, Sweden, Switzerland,
Thailand, Tunisia, Turkey, Uganda, United Kingdom, USA, Uruguay, Venezuela, Zambia,
Zimbabwe.
All countries are part of the sample for the World Bank measure of corruption.
Countries in italics are not part of the sample for the CPI measure of corruption. Countries in
bold are not part of the sample for the WEI measure of corruption.
30
A2: Robustness checks
Table A1: sensitivity to changes in the set of control variables
Without
Latitude
Without
Ethnic
Without
Openness
Without
control
variables
A1.2
A1.3
A1.4
A1.1
0.4782
Intercept
(1.44)
0.7979***
Log (K/L)
(37.17)
0.1614***
Log (H/L)
(2.82)
-0.0151
Year94
(-0.44)
-0.0062
Year95
(-0.18)
-0.0023
Year96
(-0.07)
3.9209***
Intercept
(4.56)
-0.4750***
Corruption
(-3.43)
Corruption×Goveff 0.0786***
(3.21)
-0.6596***
Goveff
(-4.63)
-0.0370
Openness
(-0.33)
Latitude
Ethno. Frac.
Sigma
Loglikelihood
N
0.0010
(0.67)
0.0647***
(5.89)
75.184
216
0.4270
0.4435
0.4395
(1.12)
(1.28)
(1.38)
0.7957*** 0.7978*** 0.8068***
(28.24)
(36.58)
(39.91)
0.1472**
0.1527**
0.1604***
(2.35)
(2.51)
(2.88)
-0.0141
-0.0181
-0.0174
(-0.42)
(-0.55)
(-0.53)
-0.0065
-0.0093
-0.0072
(-0.20)
(-0.28)
(-0.21)
-0.3445E-3
-0.0025
-0.0028
(-0.01)
(-0.08)
(-0.08)
3.9542*** 4.0157*** 4.2644***
(4.16)
(5.43)
(5.37)
-0.4579*** -0.4757*** -0.5085***
(-2.95)
(-3.94)
(-3.80)
0.0757**
0.0752*** 0.0808***
(2.50)
(3.29)
(2.99)
-0.6341*** -0.6596*** -0.7125***
(-3.27)
(-5.47)
(-5.08)
-0.0805
(-1.01)
-0.0032
-0.0019
(-1.08)
(-0.55)
0.0012
(1.02)
0.0632*** 0.0646*** 0.0725***
(5.07)
(5.06)
(5.78)
75.245
75.245
74.217
216
216
216
t-statistics are displayed in parentheses under the coefficient estimates. *, **, *** denote an
estimate significantly different from zero at the 10%, 5% or 1% level.
31
Table A2: specificity of developing countries and sensitivity to the estimation period
Development Development
dummy in the dummy in the 1988-1990
frontier
inefficiency
equation
Intercept
Log (K/L)
Log (H/L)
D
D*Log (K/L)
D*Log (H/L)
Year94
Year95
Year96
A2.1
A2.2
A2.3
0.6695
(1.23)
0.6106***
(10.26)
0.1359
(1.45)
0.2417
(0.36)
0.1998***
(3.05)
0.1471
(1.20)
-0.0083
(-0.27)
-0.0047
(-0.16)
0.0031
(0.10)
0.4504
(1.28)
0.7952***
(34.61)
0.1518**
(2.49)
4.7368***
(26.75)
0.4813***
(20.12)
0.0610
(1.12)
Year88
Year89
3.5340***
(4.68)
-0.3601***
Corruption
(-3.08)
Corruption×Goveff 0.0452**
(2.16)
-0.5077***
Goveff
(-4.19)
-0.1963*
Openness
(-1.89)
-0.0073*
Latitude
(-1.77)
0.0040**
Ethno. Frac.
(2.20)
Intercept
D
Sigma
Loglikelihood
N
0.0486***
(5.42)
90.255
216
-0.0175
(-0.52)
-0.0073
(-0.22)
-0.0020
(-0.06)
–0.0193
(–0.62)
–0.0058
(–0.19)
3.9709*** 2.8147***
(4.90)
(3.61)
-0.4715*** 0.2641**
(-3.45)
(–2.29)
0.0768*** 0.0523***
(2.98)
(2.82)
-0.6413*** 0.5299***
(-4.45)
(–4.37)
-0.0618
0.0013*
(-0.50)
(1.90)
-0.0025
0.0017
(-0.68)
(–1.13)
0.7493E-3 0.0036***
(0.44)
(3.19)
-0.0074
(-0.06)
0.0623*** 0.0553***
(5.18)
(6.32)
75.538
66.922
216
186
t-statistics are displayed in parentheses under the coefficient estimates. *,
**, *** denote an estimate significantly different from zero at the 10%,
5% or 1% level.
32
Table A3: sensitivity to the specification of the production function
Intercept
Log (K/L)
Log (H/L)
[Log (K/L)]²
[Log (H/L)]²
Log (K/L)×Log (H/L)
Translog
form
Variable returns to
scale
A3.1
A3.2
-5.4090***
(-3.03)
2.0178***
(7.53)
-1.6115**
(-2.43)
-0.1228**
(-1.96)
-0.0299**
(-2.28)
0.2268***
(4.84)
1.0194
(1.25)
Log (L)
Log (K)
Log (H)
Year94
Year95
Year96
Intercept
Corruption
Corruption×Goveff
Goveff
Openness
Latitude
Ethno. Frac.
Sigma
Loglikelihood
N
-0.0143
(-0.42)
-0.0069
(-0.20)
-0.0036
(-0.11)
3.6693***
(4.31)
-0.3873***
(-3.00)
0.0493**
(2.17)
-0.5302***
(-3.75)
-0.0933
(-0.95)
-0.0062*
(-1.75)
0.0020
(1.37)
0.0478***
(5.11)
88.693
216
0.0915*
(1.91)
0.7829***
(37.55)
0.1473**
(2.45)
-0.0209
(-0.62)
-0.0125
(-0.38)
-0.0059
(-0.18)
3.7293***
(5.44)
-0.4417***
(-4.05)
0.0747***
(3.68)
-0.6049***
(-5.11)
-0.0701
(-0.68)
-0.0017
(-0.52)
0.0013
(0.90)
0.0546***
(4.99)
78.304
216
t-statistics are displayed in parentheses under the coefficient estimates. *, **, *** denote an
estimate significantly different from zero at the 10%, 5% or 1% level.
33
References
Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J.A. Robinson (2001) “The Colonial Origins of Comparative
Development: An Empirical Investigation”, American Economic Review, vol. 91 n°5,
p.1369-1401.
Ades A. and R. Di Tella (1997) “The New Economics of Corruption: A Survey and Some
Results”, Political Studies, vol. 45 (special issue), p.496-515.
Adkins, C., Moomaw, R. and A. Savvides (2002) “Institutions, Freedom, and Technical
Efficiency”, Southern Economic Journal, vol. 69 n°1, p.92-108.
Aidt T.S. (2003) “Economic Analysis of Corruption: A Survey”, Economic Journal, vol. 113
n°491, p.632-652.
Aigner D., C.A.K. Lovell and P. Schmidt (1977) “Formulation and Estimation of Stochastic
Frontier Production Models”, Journal of Econometrics, vol. 6 n°1, p.21-37.
Bailey D.H. (1966) “The Effects of Corruption in a Developing Nation”, Western Political
Quarterly, vol. 19 n°4, p.719-732. Reprint in Political Corruption: A Handbook, A.J.
Heidenheimer, M. Johnston and V.T. LeVine (eds.), Oxford, Transaction Books,
p.934-952, 1989.
Bardhan P. (1997) “Corruption and Development: A Review of Issues”, Journal of Economic
Literature, vol. 35 n°3, p.1320-1346.
Barro R.J. and J.W. Lee (2000) “International Data on Educational Attainment Updates and
Implications”, NBER Working Papers: 7911.
Battese G.E. and T.J. Coelli (1995) “A Model for Technical Inefficiency Effects in a
Stochastic Production Frontier for Panel Data”, Empirical Economics, vol. 20 n°2,
p.325-332.
Beck P.J. and M.W. Maher (1986) “A Comparison of Bribery and Bidding in Thin Markets”,
Economics Letters, vol. 20, p.1-5.
Caselli F. (2005), “Accounting for Cross-country Income Differences”, in P. Aghion and S.
Durlauf (eds.) Handbook of Economic Growth, Elsevier, p.679-742.
Coelli T.J. (1996) “A Guide to Frontier 4.1: A Computer Program for Stochastic Production
and Cost Function Estimation”, Centre for Efficiency and Productivity Analysis,
University of New England, Working Paper 96/07.
Dreher A. and F. Schneider (2006a) “Corruption and the shadow economy - substitutes or
complements?”, in: M. Kreutner (ed.), The Corruption Monster - Ethik, Politik und
Korruption, Czernin Verlag, p. 363-370.
34
Dreher A. and F. Schneider (2006b) “Corruption and the Shadow Economy: An Empirical
Analysis”, KOF Working Paper 123, ETH Zurich.
Dreher A., C. Kotsogiannis, and S. McCorriston (2007) “Corruption Around the World:
Evidence from a Structural Model”, Journal of Comparative Economics, vol. 35 n°3,
p. 443-466.
Easterly W. and R. Levine (2001) “It’s Not Factor Accumulation: Stylized Facts and Growth
Models”, World Bank Economic Review, vol. 15 n°2, p.177-219.
Easterly W. and R. Levine (2003) “Tropics, Germs, and Crops: How Endowments Influence
Economic Development”, Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 50 n°1, p.3-39.
Edwards S. (1998) “Openness, Productivity and Growth: What Do We Really Know?”
Economic Journal, vol. 108, p.383-398.
Ehrlich I. and F. Lui (1999) “Bureaucratic Corruption and Endogenous Economic Growth”,
Journal of Political Economy, vol. 107 n°6, p.S270-S293.
Friedman E., S. Johnson, D. Kaufmann, and P. Zoido-Lobaton (2000) “Dodging the Grabbing
Hand: The Determinants of Unofficial Activity in 69 Countries”, Journal of Public
Economics, vol. 76 n°3, p. 459-493.
Hall R. and C.I. Jones (1999) “Why Do Some Countries produce So Much More Output Per
Worker Than Others?”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 114 n°1, p.83-116.
Henisz W.J. (2000) “The Institutional Environment for Economic Growth”, Economics and
Politics, vol. 12 n°1, p.1-31.
Huntington S.P. (1968) Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven, Yale University
Press.
Kaufmann D. and S.-J. Wei (1999) “Does ‘Grease Money’ Speed up the Wheels of
Commerce?”, NBER Working Paper, n°7093.
Kaufmann D., Kraay, A. and P. Zoido-Lobaton (1999a) “Aggregating Governance
Indicators”, World Bank, Working Paper n°2195.
Kaufmann D., Kraay, A. and P. Zoido-Lobaton (1999b) “Governance Matters”, World Bank,
Working Paper n°2196.
Kneller R. and P.A. Stevens (2003) “The specification of the aggregate production function in
the presence of inefficiency”, Economics Letters, vol. 81 n°2, p.223-226.
Kurer O. (1993) “Clientelism, Corruption and the Allocation of Resources”, Public Choice,
vol. 77 n°2, p.259-273.
Lambsdorff J.G. (2003) “How Corruption Affects Productivity”, Kyklos, vol. 56, n°4, p.457474.
35
Leff N.H. (1964) “Economic Development through Bureaucratic Corruption”, American
Behavioral Scientist, vol. 8, n°3, p.8-14. Reprint in Political corruption: A handbook,
A.J. Heidenheimer, M. Johnston and V.T. LeVine (eds.), Oxford, Transaction Books,
p.389-403, 1989.
Leys C. (1965) “What Is the Problem about Corruption?”, Journal of Modern African Studies,
vol. 3, n°2, p.215-230. Reprint in Political corruption: A handbook, A.J.
Heidenheimer, M. Johnston and V.T. LeVine (eds.), Oxford, Transaction Books, p.5166, 1989.
Lien D.H.D. (1986) “A Note on Competitive Bribery Games”, Economics Letters, vol. 22,
p.337-341.
Lui F.T. (1985) “An Equilibrium Queuing Model of Bribery”, Journal of Political Economy,
vol. 93, n°4, p.760-781.
Mauro P. (1995) “Corruption and Growth”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 110 n°3,
p.681-712.
Mauro P. (1998) “Corruption and the Composition of Government Expenditure”, Journal of
Public Economics, vol. 69 n°2, p.263-279.
Méon P.-G. and K. Sekkat (2005) “Does Corruption Grease or Sand the Wheels of Growth?”,
Public Choice, vol. 122 n°1-2, p.69-97.
Mo P.H. (2001) “Corruption and Economic Growth”, Journal of Comparative Economics,
vol. 29 n°1, p.66-79.
Moroney J. and C.A.K. Lovell (1997) “The Relative Efficiencies of Market and Planned
Economies”, Southern Economic Journal vol. 63 n°4, p.1084-1093.
Myrdal G. (1968) Asian Drama: An Enquiry into the Poverty of Nations, vol. 2, New York,
the Twentieth Century Fund. Reprint in Political Corruption: A Handbook, A.J.
Heidenheimer, M. Johnston and V.T. LeVine (eds.), Oxford, Transaction Books,
p.953-961, 1989.
Nehru V. and Dhareshwar A., “New Estimates of Total Factor Productivity Growth for
Developing and Industrial Countries”, Policy Research Working Paper n°1313, World
Bank, 1994.
Nye J.S. (1967) “Corruption and political development: a cost-benefit analysis”, American
Political Science Review, vol. 50, n°2, p.417-427. Reprint in Political corruption: A
handbook, A.J. Heidenheimer, M. Johnston and V.T. LeVine (eds.), Oxford,
Transaction Books, p.51-66, 1989.
36
Olson M., Sarna, N., and A.V. Svamy (2000) “Governance and Growth: A Simple Hypothesis
Explaining Cross-Country Differences in Productivity Growth”. Public Choice vol.
102 n°3-4, p.341-364.
Rock M.T., and H. Bonnett (2004) “The comparative politics of corruption: accounting for
the East Asian paradox in empirical studies of corruption, growth and investment”,
World Development, vol. 32 n°6, p.999-1017.
Rose-Ackerman R. (1997) “The Political Economy of Corruption”, in Corruption and the
global economy, K.A. Elliott (ed.), Washington DC, Institute for International
Economics, p.31-60.
Sachs J. (2001) “Tropical Underdevelopment”. NBER Working paper n°8119.
Sachs J. and Warner A. (1995) “Economic reform and the process of global integration”
Brookings Papers of Economic Activity, n°1, p.1-18.
Shleifer A. and R.W. Vishny (1993) “Corruption”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 108
n°3, p.599-617.
Wei S.-J. (2000) “Local Corruption and Global Capital Flows”, Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, vol. 2, p.303-346.
37
PAPIERS
Laboratoire de Recherche en Gestion & Economie
(LARGE)
______
D.R. n° 1
"Bertrand Oligopoly with decreasing returns to scale",
J. Thépot, décembre 1993
D.R. n° 2
"Sur quelques méthodes d'estimation directe de la structure par terme
des taux d'intérêt", P. Roger - N. Rossiensky, janvier 1994
D.R. n° 3
"Towards a Monopoly Theory in a Managerial Perspective",
J. Thépot, mai 1993
D.R. n° 4
"Bounded Rationality in Microeconomics", J. Thépot, mai 1993
D.R. n° 5
"Apprentissage Théorique et Expérience Professionnelle",
J. Thépot, décembre 1993
D.R. n° 6
"Stratégic Consumers in a Duable-Goods Monopoly",
J. Thépot, avril 1994
D.R. n° 7
"Vendre ou louer ; un apport de la théorie des jeux", J. Thépot, avril 1994
D.R. n° 8
"Default Risk Insurance and Incomplete Markets",
Ph. Artzner - FF. Delbaen, juin 1994
D.R. n° 9
"Les actions à réinvestissement optionnel du dividende",
C. Marie-Jeanne - P. Roger, janvier 1995
D.R. n° 10
"Forme optimale des contrats d'assurance en présence de coûts
administratifs pour l'assureur", S. Spaeter, février 1995
D.R. n° 11
"Une procédure de codage numérique des articles",
J. Jeunet, février 1995
D.R. n° 12
Stabilité d'un diagnostic concurrentiel fondé sur une approche
markovienne du comportement de rachat du consommateur",
N. Schall, octobre 1995
D.R. n° 13
"A direct proof of the coase conjecture", J. Thépot, octobre 1995
D.R. n° 14
"Invitation à la stratégie", J. Thépot, décembre 1995
D.R. n° 15
"Charity and economic efficiency", J. Thépot, mai 1996
D.R. n° 16
"Princing anomalies in financial markets and non linear pricing rules",
P. Roger, mars 1996
D.R. n° 17
"Non linéarité des coûts de l'assureur, comportement de prudence de
l'assuré et contrats optimaux", S. Spaeter, avril 1996
D.R. n° 18
"La valeur ajoutée d'un partage de risque et l'optimum de Pareto : une
note", L. Eeckhoudt - P. Roger, juin 1996
D.R. n° 19
"Evaluation of Lot-Sizing Techniques : A robustess and Cost Effectiveness
Analysis", J. Jeunet, mars 1996
D.R. n° 20
"Entry accommodation with idle capacity", J. Thépot, septembre 1996
D.R. n° 21
"Différences culturelles et satisfaction des vendeurs : Une comparaison
internationale", E. Vauquois-Mathevet - J.Cl. Usunier, novembre 1996
D.R. n° 22
"Evaluation des obligations convertibles et options d'échange",
A. Schmitt - F. Home, décembre 1996
D.R n° 23
"Réduction d'un programme d'optimisation globale des coûts et
diminution du temps de calcul, J. Jeunet, décembre 1996
D.R. n° 24
"Incertitude, vérifiabilité et observabilité : Une relecture de la
théorie de l'agence", J. Thépot, janvier 1997
D.R. n° 25
"Financement par augmentation de capital avec asymétrie d'information :
l'apport du paiement du dividende en actions",
C. Marie-Jeanne, février 1997
D.R. n° 26
"Paiement du dividende en actions et théorie du signal",
C. Marie-Jeanne, février 1997
D.R. n° 27
"Risk aversion and the bid-ask spread", L. Eeckhoudt - P. Roger, avril 1997
D.R. n° 28
"De l'utilité de la contrainte d'assurance dans les modèles à un risque et à
deux risques", S. Spaeter, septembre 1997
D.R. n° 29
"Robustness and cost-effectiveness of lot-sizing techniques under revised
demand forecasts", J. Jeunet, juillet 1997
D.R. n° 30
"Efficience du marché et comparaison de produits à l'aide des méthodes
d'enveloppe (Data envelopment analysis)", S. Chabi, septembre 1997
D.R. n° 31
"Qualités de la main-d'œuvre et subventions à l'emploi : Approche
microéconomique", J. Calaza - P. Roger, février 1998
D.R n° 32
"Probabilité de défaut et spread de taux : Etude empirique du marché français",
M. Merli - P. Roger, février 1998
D.R. n° 33
"Confiance et Performance : La thèse de Fukuyama",
J.Cl. Usunier - P. Roger, avril 1998
D.R. n° 34
"Measuring the performance of lot-sizing techniques in uncertain
environments", J. Jeunet - N. Jonard, janvier 1998
D.R. n° 35
"Mobilité et décison de consommation : premiers résultas dans un cadre
monopolistique", Ph. Lapp, octobre 1998
D.R. n° 36
"Impact du paiement du dividende en actions sur le transfert de richesse et la
dilution du bénéfice par action", C. Marie-Jeanne, octobre 1998
D.R. n° 37
"Maximum resale-price-maintenance as Nash condition", J. Thépot,
novembre 1998
D.R. n° 38
"Properties of bid and ask prices in the rank dependent expected utility model",
P. Roger, décembre 1998
D.R. n° 39
"Sur la structure par termes des spreads de défaut des obligations »,
Maxime Merli / Patrick Roger, septembre 1998
D.R. n° 40
"Le risque de défaut des obligations : un modèle de défaut temporaire de l’émetteur",
Maxime Merli, octobre 1998
D.R. n° 41
"The Economics of Doping in Sports", Nicolas Eber / Jacques Thépot,
février 1999
D.R. n° 42
"Solving large unconstrained multilevel lot-sizing problems using a hybrid genetic
algorithm", Jully Jeunet, mars 1999
D.R n° 43
"Niveau général des taux et spreads de rendement", Maxime Merli, mars 1999
D.R. n° 44
"Doping in Sport and Competition Design", Nicolas Eber / Jacques Thépot,
septembre 1999
D.R. n° 45
"Interactions dans les canaux de distribution", Jacques Thépot, novembre 1999
D.R. n° 46
"What sort of balanced scorecard for hospital", Thierry Nobre, novembre 1999
D.R. n° 47
"Le contrôle de gestion dans les PME", Thierry Nobre, mars 2000
D.R. n° 48
″Stock timing using genetic algorithms", Jerzy Korczak – Patrick Roger,
avril 2000
D.R. n° 49
"On the long run risk in stocks : A west-side story", Patrick Roger, mai 2000
D.R. n° 50
"Estimation des coûts de transaction sur un marché gouverné par les ordres : Le cas des
composantes du CAC40", Laurent Deville, avril 2001
D.R. n° 51
"Sur une mesure d’efficience relative dans la théorie du portefeuille de Markowitz",
Patrick Roger / Maxime Merli, septembre 2001
D.R. n° 52
"Impact de l’introduction du tracker Master Share CAC 40 sur la relation de parité callput", Laurent Deville, mars 2002
D.R. n° 53
"Market-making, inventories and martingale pricing", Patrick Roger / Christian At /
Laurent Flochel, mai 2002
D.R. n° 54
"Tarification au coût complet en concurrence imparfaite", Jean-Luc Netzer / Jacques
Thépot, juillet 2002
D.R. n° 55
"Is time-diversification efficient for a loss averse investor ?", Patrick Roger,
janvier 2003
D.R. n° 56
“Dégradations de notations du leader et effets de contagion”, Maxime Merli / Alain
Schatt, avril 2003
D.R. n° 57
“Subjective evaluation, ambiguity and relational contracts”, Brigitte Godbillon,
juillet 2003
D.R. n° 58
“A View of the European Union as an Evolving Country Portfolio”,
Pierre-Guillaume Méon / Laurent Weill, juillet 2003
D.R. n° 59
“Can Mergers in Europe Help Banks Hedge Against Macroeconomic Risk ?”,
Pierre-Guillaume Méon / Laurent Weill, septembre 2003
D.R. n° 60
“Monetary policy in the presence of asymmetric wage indexation”, Giuseppe Diana /
Pierre-Guillaume Méon, juillet 2003
D.R. n° 61
“Concurrence bancaire et taille des conventions de services”, Corentine Le Roy,
novembre 2003
D.R. n° 62
“Le petit monde du CAC 40”, Sylvie Chabi / Jérôme Maati
D.R. n° 63
“Are Athletes Different ? An Experimental Study Based on the Ultimatum Game”,
Nicolas Eber / Marc Willinger
D.R. n° 64
“Le rôle de l’environnement réglementaire, légal et institutionnel dans la défaillance des
banques : Le cas des pays émergents”, Christophe Godlewski, janvier 2004
D.R. n° 65
“Etude de la cohérence des ratings de banques avec la probabilité de défaillance
bancaire dans les pays émergents”, Christophe Godlewski, Mars 2004
D.R. n° 66
“Le comportement des étudiants sur le marché du téléphone mobile : Inertie, captivité
ou fidélité ?”, Corentine Le Roy, Mai 2004
D.R. n° 67
“Insurance and Financial Hedging of Oil Pollution Risks”, André Schmitt / Sandrine
Spaeter, September, 2004
D.R. n° 68
“On the Backwardness in Macroeconomic Performance of European Socialist
Economies”, Laurent Weill, September, 2004
D.R. n° 69
“Majority voting with stochastic preferences : The whims of a committee are smaller
than the whims of its members”, Pierre-Guillaume Méon, September, 2004
D.R. n° 70
“Modélisation de la prévision de défaillance de la banque : Une application aux banques
des pays émergents”, Christophe J. Godlewski, octobre 2004
D.R. n° 71
“Can bankruptcy law discriminate between heterogeneous firms when information is
incomplete ? The case of legal sanctions”, Régis Blazy, october 2004
D.R. n° 72
“La performance économique et financière des jeunes entreprises”,
Régis Blazy/Bertrand Chopard, octobre 2004
D.R. n° 73
“Ex Post Efficiency of bankruptcy procedures : A general normative framework”,
Régis Blazy / Bertrand Chopard, novembre 2004
D.R. n° 74
“Full cost pricing and organizational structure”, Jacques Thépot, décembre 2004
D.R. n° 75
“Prices as strategic substitutes in the Hotelling duopoly”, Jacques Thépot,
décembre 2004
D.R. n° 76
“Réflexions sur l’extension récente de la statistique de prix et de production à la santé et
à l’enseignement”, Damien Broussolle, mars 2005
D. R. n° 77
“Gestion du risque de crédit dans la banque : Information hard, information soft et
manipulation ”, Brigitte Godbillon-Camus / Christophe J. Godlewski
D.R. n° 78
“Which Optimal Design For LLDAs”, Marie Pfiffelmann
D.R. n° 79
“Jensen and Meckling 30 years after : A game theoretic view”, Jacques Thépot
D.R. n° 80
“Organisation artistique et dépendance à l’égard des ressources”, Odile Paulus,
novembre 2006
D.R. n° 81
“Does collateral help mitigate adverse selection ? A cross-country analysis”,
Laurent Weill –Christophe J. Godlewski, novembre 2006
D.R. n° 82
“Why do banks ask for collateral and which ones ?”, Régis Blazy - Laurent Weill,
décembre 2006
D.R. n° 83
“The peace of work agreement : The emergence and enforcement of a swiss labour
market institution”, D. Broussolle, janvier 2006.
D.R. n° 84
“The new approach to international trade in services in view of services specificities :
Economic and regulation issues”, D. Broussolle, septembre 2006.
D.R. n° 85
“Does the consciousness of the disposition effect increase the equity premium” ?,
P. Roger, juin 2007
D.R. n° 86
“Les déterminants de la décision de syndication bancaire en France”, Ch. J. Godlewski
D.R. n° 87
“Syndicated loans in emerging markets”, Ch. J. Godlewski / L. Weill, mars
2007
D.R. n° 88
“Hawks and loves in segmented markets : A formal approach to competitive
aggressiveness”, Claude d’Aspremont / R. Dos Santos Ferreira / J. Thépot,
mai 2007
D.R. n° 89
“On the optimality of the full cost pricing”, J. Thépot, février 2007
D.R. n° 90
“SME’s main bank choice and organizational structure : Evidence from
France”, H. El Hajj Chehade / L. Vigneron, octobre 2007
D.R n° 91
“How to solve St Petersburg Paradox in Rank-Dependent Models” ?,
M. Pfiffelmann, octobre 2007
D.R. n° 92
“Full market opening in the postal services facing the social and territorial
cohesion goal in France”, D. Broussolle, novembre 2007
D.R. n° 2008-01 A behavioural Approach to financial puzzles, M.H. Broihanne, M. Merli,
P. Roger, janvier 2008
D.R. n° 2008-02 What drives the arrangement timetable of bank loan syndication ?, Ch. J.
Godlewski, février 2008
D.R. n° 2008-03 Financial intermediation and macroeconomic efficiency, Y. Kuhry, L. Weill,
février 2008
D.R. n° 2008-04 The effects of concentration on competition and efficiency : Some evidence
from the french audit market, G. Broye, L. Weill, février 2008
D.R. n° 2008-05 Does financial intermediation matter for macroeconomic efficiency?, P.G.
Méon, L. Weill, février 2008
D.R. n° 2008-06
Is corruption an efficient grease ?, P.G. Méon, L. Weill, février 2008
D.R. n° 2008-07
Convergence in banking efficiency across european countries, L. Weill,
Février 2008.