The Shipping Policy of the European Union1
H.E. Haralambides
Center for Maritime Economics and Logistics (MEL)
Erasmus University Rotterdam
INTRODUCTION
Over the last decennia, shipping has gradually been included as an important asset in the economic
policy and law making of the European Union and of Member States. This was overdue since
transport, and particularly shipping, is a key factor in economic life and a fundamental element in
international trade relations. It would be worth mentioning here that the EU is the biggest trading
area in the world accounting for more than 20% of world trade. Ninety per cent of the
Community’s external trade, and about 30% of the intra-community one, is carried by sea. Finally,
40% of Europe’s external trade is carried by vessels of European ownership and/or control. The
European shipping industry has invested 80 billion US dollars in mobile assets, while, in 1994, the
industry’s turnover was estimated at 50 billion US dollars.
Notwithstanding this, European shipping faces two main threats to its future survival: protectionist
policies by third countries and high costs of operation that have resulted in reduced market shares
and accelerated flagging-out. Thus, from 9,742 ships of 110 million GRT in 1985 (27.7% of world
tonnage), the EU-flag fleet (including Norway) numbered, in 1996, only 6,902 ships of 82 million
GT (17.6% of world tonnage). According to studies carried out for the European Commission, the
operational costs of a Community registered vessel could be reduced by 3.5 to 22% in the case of a
containership and by 15 to 44% for a bulk carrier, by flagging out. These developments can also be
ascertained by looking at the relevant maritime employment statistics of Figure 2: The number of
EU seafarers under national flag has declined from its 1983 level of 235,146 to 138,341 in 1995.2
In the same period, the number of non-EU seafarers employed on board European flag vessels has
increased from 31,867 to 53,388.3 It is estimated that 51% of this reduction in EU seafaring
employment is the result of flagging-out. An additional 27% can be attributed to the loss of market
share in general, and the remainder to reduced manning levels and increased productivity.
The grim prospects of European shipping in its present operating environment, and the European
citizens’ increased awareness of the importance of being able to rely on a safe, modern and
1
Despite the ambitiousness of its title, this paper does not address a number of important issues, such as liner
shipping consortia, shipbuilding and port policies and other areas in which the EU has produced substantial
work. The paper is written in the context of the author’s involvement in the deliberations of EU
Commissioner Neil Kinnock’s Core Group on Maritime Transport that culminated in the Commission
Communication Towards a New Maritime Strategy, COM(96) 81 final 13-3-96. Sincere thanks are
expressed to Wolfgang Elsner, Head of the Maritime Transport Policy Unit of the European Commission for
his constructive comments. Views expressed herewith by no means commit the European Commission and
are those of the author only.
2
Including Norway
3
European Community Shipowners’ Associations, Annual Report 1995-1996
1
efficient ocean transport system (including its economic and military security implications) to
serve their trading requirements are constantly feeding the debate as to the need for concerted
action at European level.
However, care should be taken with the often used argument that Europe needs a shipping industry
to serve its trading requirements. To third countries, this argument can be perceived as
protectionist, given that Europe’s trading requirements ought to be served by the most efficient
means of transport and this does not necessarily have to be of European ownership. European
shippers would also be inclined to use the same argument, as they have no commitment, obligation
or incentive to use European ships, unless the latter are efficiently serving their particular trading
requirements.
Industrial policy and international trade considerations should thus constitute the basic platform
from which a consistent shipping policy is designed and promoted. In such a context,
“consistency” means that the envisaged policy -having taken into account the intrinsic
characteristics of the shipping industry- should be able to provide plausible answers to questions
regarding oligopolistic markets, limit pricing, collusion, predation, determination of market shares,
barriers to entry, dominant firms, market power and concentration, mergers, co-operative R&D,
vertical/horizontal integration, market performance and similar issues that permeate discussions on
industrial policy.
Finally, any envisaged independent shipping policy should not fail to take into account the fact
that the European shipping industry is relatively too small, compared to other industrial sectors, to
be able to claim for itself radical policy measures or reforms that might set a precedent
endangering the conventional wisdom of Europe’s industrial policy.
POSITIVE MEASURES
The term “positive measures” is often meant to encompass all concerted action within an
assistance programme, at governmental or European level, predominantly focused on the fiscal
treatment and employment issues of shipping, aimed at equalising operating conditions of
European shipping to those prevailing in competing third countries. As such, “positive measures”
constitute an inward-looking policy vis a vis the Community’s outward-looking efforts for further
liberalisation of trade in shipping services on a global basis.
In an era of squeezed government spending and of “reinventing government”, a first test of the
plausibility of any “positive measure” would be its “self-sustainability”, i.e., whether or not the tax
revenues collected on the economic activities stimulated by support to the industry outweigh the
direct and indirect outlays incurred by the government to establish, operate and manage the
support programme.
Furthermore, the costs of any contemplated “positive measures” should be weighed against the
benefits such measures are expected to have on the future growth of merchant shipping, the
repatriation of flagged-out vessels and in turn on employment, household earnings from
employment (and their knock-on effects), tax and foreign exchange revenues.
In addition, the links between shipping and its related activities, such as shipbuilding, shipbroking,
insurance, banking, etc., should be established in a structural way that would allow the calculation
of the impact of the positive measures on employment, income, tax revenues and foreign exchange
from these shipping-related economic activities.
Finally, the evaluation of any “positive measures” should be contemplated on an opportunity cost
2
basis, i.e., what would be the net benefit to society if the resources made available for the
implementation of the “positive measures” were instead channelled to other sectors of the
economy, according to national priorities.
One of the major problems accounting for European shipping’s often proclaimed limited
competitiveness is to be found in its wage differentials with third countries. In the United States,
operating cost differentials have been tackled with by a combination of two measures: i) a cargo
preference scheme for government-impelled cargoes carried by US-flag ships and constituting a
set-aside cargo basis aimed at ensuring a minimum ship space utilisation, and ii) an Operating
Differential Subsidy Scheme (ODS) aimed at equalising certain ship operating costs (mainly
manning) to those pertaining in third countries, and in this way levelling the international playing
field. Within this framework, US-flag shipowners pay virtually no corporate taxes (as their gross
income before the ODS is negative over a number of years), and seafarers pay an average of 12 per
cent income tax.
In a recent effort to measure the impact of federal support for the private merchant marine in the
United States4, it was found that for each job in the maritime sector an additional 5.4 jobs were
created in the economy, mainly in maritime related industries, and for each dollar of household
income generated by the merchant marine 4.6 dollars of additional income was created in the
economy.
The same study concluded that in the absence of the above assistance programme to the industry,
the US-flag shipping would have disappeared (registered possibly under foreign flags), foreign
crews would have substituted US seafarers, US shipping revenues would have declined, and
foreign operators would have substituted foreign produced goods and services for some of the US
produced goods and services that were consumed by the US-flag merchant marine.
The Union is well aware of the cost disparities between member States’ shipowners and those of
third countries, and the resulting loss in competitiveness. In an attempt to readdress this problem,
the Commission is currently revising its 1989 state aid guidelines5 on shipping which may also
include a revision of the cost-gap method and a new approach towards an aid practice benefiting
Community shipowners, however the latter may be defined.
STATE AIDS TO SHIPPING
In general, state aids tend to discriminate against the most efficient producers and thus threaten
European integration. A good example of this was the steel industry of the early 1980s. The
Davignon plan (providing for production quotas and minimum prices) discriminated against the
more efficient German producers who would only consent to a restriction in cheap third country
steel imports under the condition that their European partners would phase out their subsidies.
State aids to industry are thus in principle prohibited by the Treaty (article 92(1)) with the
exemptions provided for in 92(2) and 92(3) which give the Commission the power to declare
certain categories of aid as compatible with the common market. In general, this is the case when
aid is intended to facilitate the development of certain economic activities (or regions), while it
does not adversely affect trading conditions to an extent contrary to the common interest. In an
attempt to define “common interest” in the case of shipping, the Commission considers that a
4
see Nathan Associates Inc. (1995) Economic Analysis of Federal Support for the Private Merchant Marine.
Submitted to the American Maritime Congress, January 1995.
5
SEC(89) 921 final
3
strong Community fleet is essential both for economic and strategic reasons.6 As the leading world
trading entity, the Community should not be excessively dependent on third country fleets for its
imports and exports, thus losing control and influence on the price and quality of transport to and
from its territory.
State Aid granted to shipping companies can take the form of:
◊
◊
◊
◊
◊
◊
direct subsidies for vessel operation;
total or partial cover of financial losses;
loan guarantees for the purchase of capital goods;
tax relief on earnings arising from maritime activities and on seafarer’s income;
reduced rates of contribution for the social protection of seamen;
capital contributions on terms which would be unacceptable for a private investor operating in
normal market economy conditions.
For example in November 1996, and in accordance with its strategy to encourage EU ships fly
European flags -and thus preserve competitiveness and safeguard maritime employment and knowhow-, the Commission approved as compatible with the Treaty German aid schemes for ship
operating companies, aimed at equalising manning cost differences between German-flag ships
and those plying under flags of convenience. The subsidy amounts roughly to DM 200,000 per
ship and a small part of it is earmarked for the training of seafarers.
However, the Commission is not particularly fond of state aid programmes and at any rate their
desirability and compatibility with EU law will always be scrutinised depending on the situation of
the Community fleet and in view of the fact that measures taken by individual Member States, in
order to improve the situation of their fleet, may produce adverse effects on competition between
Member States’ fleets. It should also be kept in mind that state aids to shipping are relatively easy
for Member States with small merchant marines and substantial budgetary resources, but rather
awkward in Member States with a large fleet and seagoing labour, but inadequate economic means
that have to be allocated in a number of other pressing national development requirements.
Notwithstanding this, and given the positive opinion of both the European Parliament and the
Economic and Social Committee, state aid measures can be approved by the Commission, but they
have to be introduced within a general framework aimed at minimising the distortive effects of
such an intervention. In addition, this type of assistance to shipping should be clearly distinguished
from that to shipbuilding, and must be transparent, well documented, adequately justified, but also
temporary and if possible on a declining scale. Finally, state aid to shipping must not specifically
contribute to increasing or maintaining capacity in sectors with manifest overcapacity.
The issue of “transparency” of state aid measures is of great importance in the law-making of the
EU. For example, in September 1996, the Irish Presidency introduced a discussion paper on “State
Aid Control”. The paper suggests more transparency, improvement of the legal rules and a general
promotion of a reduction in the levels of state aid. The issue of transparency has recently been
amply exemplified in the Commission investigation of the Bremer Vulkan case where shipbuilding
aid, intended for the restructuring of the eastern German yards MTW-Schiffswerft and Volkswerft,
was diverted to subsidiaries of the BV Group, including DSR-Senator Lines.
It is perhaps worth mentioning at this point the work that has been carried out over the past few
years by OECD. The aim of the Organisation’s Maritime Transport Committee is to increase the
6
it is interesting to remember, however, that during the times of the disappearance of the European textile
industry, manufacturers also invoked “strategic” arguments, as they were producing uniforms for the army!
4
transparency of measures affording financial/fiscal state aid to shipping, in an effort to eventually
reduce/eliminate the trade-distorting and discriminating effects of such practices.
In the context of OECD’s June 1992 Agreement on “Treatment of Financial and Fiscal Support
Measures for International Shipping Provided by Member Countries”, the Organisation has
compiled a comprehensive inventory of support measures existing in Member Countries. The
“problem areas” are identified through a “complaints procedure” by which Member Countries are
encouraged to report practices of other Member Countries perceived to be discriminatory and
distorting competition. One of the benefits of such an approach is the increased transparency
achieved by obliging the allegedly offending Member Country to justify the reasoning behind the
introduction of the support measure.
FLAGGING-OUT
Over the past 15 years, the merchant tonnage registered in open registry countries has increased
substantially, currently representing more than 40% of world tonnage. In the same period, OECD
registered tonnage has declined from 50% of world tonnage in the beginning of the 1980s to 30%
ten years letter. These developments can also be observed in Figure 1. Given the relative stability
of market shares in other national groups, it can be deduced from this figure that most of the gains
in open registry tonnage are mainly the result of OECD flagging-out.
Flagging-out is an operational decision of certain shipowners aimed at streamlining operating costs
and other conditions to those prevailing in competing third countries. As such, flagging-out cannot
be condemned ipso facto, particularly if the countries offering open registry facilities comply
adequately with international regulations concerning safety and the protection of the marine
environment. In this sense, a Dutch-owned ship registered in the Dutch Antilles and employing
Filipino crew is not much different than Philips manufacturing in Singapore, assembling in
Malaysia and distributing to the international market from Ireland. Both companies aim to take
advantage of the opportunities afforded by the ever-present globalisation of all forms of economic
activity, combining in an optimal way factors of production to achieve a competitive advantage.
It is evident, however, that flagging-out affects adversely the EU economies by reducing
employment, fiscal revenues, know-how and the knock-on effects on shipping-related activities.
This is the more so in cases where the flagging-out of ships is accompanied by the relocation of
management activities.
Although the Commission has, on occasion, been quite justifiably reluctant to draw the link
between flag and quality of shipping services, from the relevant statistics it appears that the
heaviest casualty record is to be found among open registries. According to LMIS7 statistics on
world-wide casualty analysis for 1993, the 15 flags with the largest number of casualties worldwide accounted for 61% of the total. Among those, the Panamanian flag had 158 casualties (11%
of total), followed by the Liberian one with 6% of all casualties.
Metaxas8 was among the first to note that although low short-term freight rates -as a result of
FOCs facilitating the registration of inexpensive tonnage under their flag- are definitely to the
benefit of the shipper9, long-run social costs are rising and this is a worrying phenomenon.
7
Lloyd’s Maritime Information Services
B.N. Metaxas (1986) Flags of Convenience, Gower, p.52 ff.
9
not necessarily the final consumer
8
5
However, the poor casualty record of these registries ought to be explained not so much by the
existence of a high percentage of substandard tonnage among their fleets, but by the many times
equally poor management performance of the beneficial owners and their staff and crews.
The point that is made here is that safety and environmental awareness cannot be imposed on
people by regulations only -which tend to be circumvented- but they are rather developed through
a long process involving education and more importantly the existence of an operating business
environment that unquestionably attributes higher societal values to a cleaner and safer
environment. In this light, the reflagging of ships and management back to European registers,
apart from the narrow economic benefits this would entail, would have some wider social benefits
too.
Figure 1: Tonnage Shares of National Groups
Others
FOCs
OECD
Developing Market Economy
countries
China
1993
Developing Asian Economies
Central and Eastern Europe
1981
Open Registry Countries
OECD Countries
0%
20%
40%
60%
80%
100%
Source: OECD Maritime Transport 1993
The Commission together with a number of OECD and many other developing countries have
been viewing the phenomenon of open/dual registries with considerable scepticism if not with
disdain. In addition to some well founded concerns regarding the laxity of the
safety/environmental/operational and other rules and regulations pertaining under such regimes,
considerable discussion has also been focused on the assertion that flagging-out distorts
competition between EU shipowners and, on the other side, frustrates the plans of developing
countries to promote their own shipping industries.
However, seen from a different perspective, flagging-out aims at restoring a level playing field by
equalising the operating conditions of EU shipowners with those prevailing in competing third
countries. On the other hand, the fact that despite the sometimes substantial economic benefits of
flagging-out a number of European shipowners have opted to remain under their national registers
means that, at least for them, the economic/non-economic benefits of doing so outweigh those of
flagging-out, at least in certain specific areas of shipping. In this light, the argument of “distortions
to competition” cannot hold much water, particularly when it is acknowledged that the
6
establishment of a level playing field internationally with third country competitors is by far more
important.
The main objective of Europe’s shipping policy, with regard to flagging-out, should be to entice
European shipowners to fly the flag of a Member State, to the extent possible, or at least to
conduct their management activities from within a Member State. The latter option might be even
more important as it has been shown that the greatest part of the value-added generated by
shipping and related functions originates from shore-based activities.
The policy direction in this regard is rather straightforward: Member States, in co-operation with
the Commission, should evaluate the long-term economic and social costs of flagging-out
(including its effect on freight rates, consumer welfare, safety and the environment) and weigh
them against the cost of the minimum meaningful positive measures necessary to entice European
shipowners back to their national registers. If the former costs exceed the latter, Member States
and the Commission should strive to design the minimum necessary package of positive measures
(preferably on the basis of existing experience in some Member States) aimed at equalising
operating conditions.
In this framework, important questions deserving a quantifiable answer might include: i) to what
extent flagging-out reduces employment in sea/shore activities? ii) to what extend flagging-out
reduces the consumption of European intermediate goods and services necessary for the
production of shipping services?
MARITIME EMPLOYMENT AND TRAINING
Figure 2 amply demonstrates the rapidly declining employment figures in the European shipping
industry during the past few years. The subsequent effects of this trend on the preservation of the
necessary maritime know-how, the safe operation of ships and R&D have given considerable
cause for concern among market participants, governments and the Commission.10 This situation
has often called for “positive measures” in order to reverse this trend.
10
see also BIMCO/ISF: 1995 Manpower Update, The World-wide Demand for and Supply of Seafarers.
7
Figure 2: Seafarers on Board EU Flag Vessels
UK
Sweden
Spain
Portugal
Netherlands
1983
1992
1995
Italy
Ireland
Greece
Germany
France
Finland
Denmark
Belgium
0
5000
10000
15000
20000
25000
30000
35000
40000
Source: European Community Shipowners’ Associations. Annual Report 1995-1996
It has often been argued that, from a cost-benefit analysis point of view, the creation of
employment is not a social benefit per se, but only the goods and services that this employment
produces (and society is willing to pay for), plus the value that society attributes to the
preservation of the necessary know-how. Notwithstanding this, however, it could be equally well
argued that, with more than 20 million people unemployed in Europe, enhancing the possibilities
of creating additional sectoral employment must have a value to society in its own right,
particularly if one takes into account the social costs concurrent with unemployment, too well
known to be mentioned here.
Despite its positive and measurable impacts, the creation of employment cannot be a strong
argument for maintaining and promoting international ocean transport. This is due not only to the,
nowadays, relative unattractiveness of the seafaring profession (often leading to considerable
wastage rates and thus reduced willingness of shipowners to train cadets on board), but mainly due
to the fact that shipping is a capital-intensive industry whose Labour/Capital ratio compares rather
unfavourably to that of other industries. This disadvantage is compounded by the increase in size
and automation of modern ships that significantly reduce labour requirements.
For example, in 1960, the Labour/Capital ratio of the Greek bulk shipping industry was 2.8 men
per 1000 GRT while presently this ratio does not exceed the value of one. In liner shipping, this
effect is even more pronounced: In 1968, a first generation container vessel of 740 TEUs was
employing ten licensed officers and 24 ratings while in 1992, a fourth generation container vessel
of 4400 TEUs was employing only seven multipurpose officers and seven qualified ratings.
However, there are good reasons to believe that most EU Member States attribute a high societal
value to the preservation of Europe’s maritime know-how. In a recent study undertaken by the
University of Wales -on behalf of the UK Department of Transport, the Chamber of Shipping and
8
the Marine Society- it was found that, in the UK alone, there are approximately 17,000 shorebased jobs which employers would prefer to fill with ex-seafarers. For 70% of these, seafaring
experience was considered essential.11 Apart from the shipping companies themselves, shore-based
activities requiring seafaring experience include shipbuilding, chartering and shipbroking, banking
and finance, marine insurance, ports, dredging companies, shipping agencies, equipment suppliers,
P&I Clubs, Classification Societies, etc.
In this context, the importance of a much wider vocational education for seafarers, preparing them
for the shore activities that they in all likelihood will be involved in after their usually short seagoing career, could not be overemphasised. As mentioned above, shore-based activities are to a
significant extent undertaken by ex-seafarers and, therefore, a shortage of the latter can have
detrimental effects on safety, the efficient management of shipping companies and the preservation
of the necessary shipping know-how.
This type of education could be jointly funded by shipowners, government and possibly by
Community resources12, and, apart from being self-fulfilling for the seafarer, it should contribute
in making the seafaring career more attractive. Furthermore, the level of education and training
facilities should be upgraded and education/research programmes co-ordinated among Member
States. This would make the transferability of sea-going labour between Member States easier and
it would tend to even out disparities in remuneration and thus in the cost structures of European
shipowners. The curriculum should comprise subjects such as maritime economics, law, logistics
and multimodal transport arrangements, port operations and economics, and in general subjects
pertinent to the efficient management of a modern shipping company.
The Commission has recently initiated a research programme under the name METHAR, aiming,
among others, to the harmonisation of maritime education and training systems in Europe and to
the adaptation of educational programmes to the needs of the industry. The results of this study are
intended to be used as guidelines for the possible development of positive measures with regard to
seafaring training.
SHORT SEA SHIPPING
The continuation and further enhancement of European shipping know-how and related “hard” and
“soft” infrastructure can be achieved by the effective promotion of short sea shipping and the
meaningful inclusion of this transport mode in trans-european transport networks. Such a policy
has been advocated both in the White Book on transport, the Fifth Action Programme and the
Green Paper on environment, mainly as a result of the unsustainable situation with regard to road
transport.
So far, modal split in Europe has been heavily biased towards road transport and this trend seems
to be increasing even for longer distances where rail transport should have a better role to play.
Figure 3 presents the transhipment modal split at the port of Rotterdam where, as can be seen, road
transport represents 53.4 % of total transhipment flows. Similar experiences are witnessed in other
west European ports. For the Union in general, the share of road freight transport in total inland
5
see Gardner, B.M. and S.J. Pettit (1996) A Study of the UK Economy’s Requirements for People with
Experience of Working at Sea. University of Wales, Cardiff. A similar project is currently going on at the
Dutch Ministry of Transport -Directorate General for Shipping and Maritime Affairs- with an aim to identify
future demand-supply imbalances and the requirements on Holland’s maritime education system; generally
acknowledged as one of the most advanced in the world.
12
such as the European Social Fund and the LEONARDO Programme
9
transport has increased from 50% in 1975 to 70% in 1995. The European Commission estimates
that, with the completion of the internal market and the enlargement of the Union, traffic volumes
will probably double by the year 2020.
Figure 3: Modal Split in the Port of Rotterdam
IWT
10.9%
Rail
11.1%
Trucking
53.4%
SSS
24.6%
Source: Erasmus University Rotterdam
The heavy demand on road use, compounded by the underpriced, fixed-cost-based, supply of road
infrastructure, and the increasing unwillingness of many governments to invest in new road
capacity (0.8% of Community GDP in 1995, compared to 1.5% twenty years ago) create a number
of significant problems, particularly with regard to congestion, safety and environment. Some
illustrative figures, often quoted by the EC, could further highlight this point. Thus:
•
•
•
•
•
The death toll in road transport amounts to 55,000 people per year (1.5 million injured);
Every day, 4,000 km of Community motorway are totally congested;
Yearly congestion costs amount to 120 billion ECU, or 2% of Community GDP;
The external costs of accidents, air13 and noise pollution have escalated to 130 billion
ECU/year;
In total, transport externalities represent roughly 4% of Community GDP.
Externalities such as these, however, are rarely internalised in the pricing of road infrastructure,
the more so when the latter has lost most of its “public interest” character and is increasingly
becoming a private consumption good. Thus, the anticipated emphasis towards a “variable cost”
approach in the pricing of road use (user pays principle) by many European governments14, is
expected to make competition among transport systems fairer and more efficient. This situation
could then indeed enhance the competitive advantage of short sea shipping.
Short sea shipping is considered to be:
•
•
•
13
14
the most economic mode in terms of consumption of energy per ton/km;
the most appropriate mode to serve the peripheral areas of Europe, particularly in the north and
south, but also in areas such as Ireland, the Baltic and the Black seas. Moreover, Europe
possesses about 35,000 kilometres of coast line with an abundance of over 600 ports situated
near to industrial centres;
the mode with the least requirements for infrastructure investment;
Excluding global warming
already emphasized in the Commission’s green paper “Towards a Fair and Efficient Pricing in Transport”
10
•
•
•
the environmental friendly mode par excellence;
the type of shipping most likely to stimulate the European shipbuilding industry;
the type of shipping with the most favourable labour/capital ratio and thus impact on
employment (both at sea and on shore). In other words, the employment created by one dwt
investment in short sea shipping is significantly higher than that of ocean shipping.
Having said that, however, there are a number of outstanding issues that tend to reduce the
economic attractiveness of this mode of transport and on which the Commission should further
focus its action. Namely,
•
•
•
•
•
As a result of the very nature of its operations (short distances), the proportion of terminal
costs (mainly the cost of ship’s time at port) in the total cost of operation in short sea shipping
is relatively high. It has been estimated that short sea ships spend more than half of their time
at ports;
The above shortcoming is compounded by the lack of required infrastructure, in some Member
States, for efficient and expedient interconnections with the hinterland, bureaucratic
administrative procedures at ports, and restrictive labour practices;
By the very nature of its operations, short sea shipping is less adaptable to door-to-door
requirements and new logistical developments;
Cargo-handling, warehousing and other port charges are priced comparatively highly,
particularly in some south European ports;
The inadequate information/advertising and lack of reliable statistics do not help shippers
evaluate the alternatives that this mode of transport offers them.
SAFETY AND ENVIRONMENT
The most appropriate way to improve safety at sea and the protection of the marine environment is
through action on an international basis, given that the “playing field” of shipping is international
par excellence. Regional measures can only distort the overall picture of international safety at sea
and in some cases they may result in retaliatory measures with self-evident negative commercial
consequences. This is the more so when regional/unilateral measures to safety and pollution can be
seen by third countries as hidden barriers to entry rather than what they actually are. Something
like this entails the danger of breaching GATT principles of non-discrimination, Market Access
and National Treatment and it can induce retaliatory action that can compromise progress towards
further liberalisation in goods and services, some of which perhaps more important than shipping.
In recent years, the work of the EU in the area of maritime safety and the protection of the marine
environment has been significant. A major objective of this work has been the convergent
implementation and uniform enforcement of international rules and regulations15, and might
include in exceptional cases carefully selected non-binding regulations of IMO which will be made
compulsory through EC legislation. Although such action will remain the exception rather than the
rule, the Commission firmly believes that these binding requirements should be enforced on all
ships indiscriminately when trading to and from EU ports, and that third country ships should not
receive a more favourable treatment than the EU-flagged ones.16
15
see for example the Commission Communication on A Common Policy on Safe Seas, COM(93)66 final,
24.02.93.
16
see COM(96) 81 final, op. cit. p.2.
11
However controversial, this matter is of great concern to many. At a national -or sometimes even
regional- level, the enforcement of laws and regulations is relatively effective: if the factory
chimney pollutes, the police arrives and penalties can be quite hefty. At an international level,
however, regulations are cumbersome to design, easy to circumvent and extremely difficult to
police. To quote William O’Neil, Secretary General of IMO,
…over the last three and a half decades, IMO has adopted several
shelves full of rules and regulations. They have certainly helped to
improve the situation, but regulations are only effective if they are put
in practice and are enforced. There is no doubt that many IMO
Conventions and other standards are not implemented as rigorously as
they should be. Before adopting still more regulations we should
therefore concentrate on assuring that the ones that already exist are
in fact applied to all ships throughout the world…17
Furthermore, if international regulations are not enforced uniformly, they can result in distortions
to competition. Suffice it to say, as an example, that, according to recent OECD estimates18,
differences in repair and maintenance only can give a sub-standard ship operator a comparative
advantage of 1 million US dollars per year per ship.
In addition, the external (social) costs of ship operations can neither be contained within the
narrow geographical confines of a single country, nor are they always reflected in the price of the
transport service. In fact, a lot of coastal States and their taxpayers face a bill -for such costs as
port state control; VTS systems; waste disposal facilities; search and rescue; cleaning polluted
beaches, birds and other animals, etc.- that in all fairness ought to be paid by those parties that
directly benefit from ocean transportation.19
It thus becomes strongly felt by an increasing number of policy-makers that safety and
environmental policies and standards are, in many areas of shipping, inextricably linked to issues
of industrial competitiveness and they should be seen as such.20 This assertion may pose a new
challenge on IMO -the only competent international body to set standards on safety and pollution
prevention- to increase its involvement in the commercial aspects of shipping. This can and ought
to be done by IMO through the carrying out of a thorough Cost-Benefit analysis of the economic
effects on the industry (including those on freight rates and shipping capacity), each and every
time a new regulation or standard is contemplated.
Notwithstanding the above, the EU is well aware of the fact that caution should be shown with the
insistence on higher standards, as they can be seen as protectionism inflicting unfair economic
disadvantages on poor countries.21 In this respect, it is also argued by many, including of course
IMO, that one cannot really expect the governments of many developing countries, which often
lack resources and expertise, to implement measures with the same speed and assurance as larger
17
Keynote speech delivered at the MAREFORUM 96 Conference, October 1996.
see Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development (1996) Competitive Advantages Obtained
by Some Shipowners as a Result of Non-Observance of Applicable International Rules and Standards.
OCDE/GD(96)4, Paris, 1996.
19
see keynote speech of A. Jorritsma, Dutch Minister of Transport, Public Works and Water Management,
delivered at the MAREFORUM 96 Conference.
20
That was the central message that I tried to get across at the MAREFORUM 96 Conference on Market
Mechanisms for Safer Shipping and Cleaner Oceans that took place in October 1996 at Erasmus University,
under the auspices of the Dutch Ministry of Transport and the European Commission. Given their relevance
to the present paper, the Resolutions of this Conference are appended at the end.
21
see keynote speech of EU Transport Commissioner Neil Kinnock, delivered at MAREFORUM 96.
18
12
nations with centuries of tradition and expertise behind them.22
“Speed” and “assurance” conceded, however, the EU is of the strong conviction that the effect of
casual or negligent practices by flag-states can be horrific for crews and vessels and they are
potentially devastating for the environment, for other shipping and for the well-being of people
across the world. In this respect, weaknesses of administration are not an acceptable excuse23 and
the right to operate a ship register carries a full responsibility to do it properly.24
Port State Control (PSC) is the last resort of many coastal States to monitor the implementation of
safety rules and other working and living standards on board ships and thus safeguard the quality
of shipping to and from their ports. The EU is committed to strengthening the effectiveness of
PSC25, currently considered by many as an inadequate deterrent (to the extent that it has sometimes
been described as “an opportunity for a free inspection”).
On the other hand, it has also been argued that a tighter PSC system in Europe might create a twotier situation, whereby sub-standard ships will avoid European ports and instead trade in other
areas, as long as charterers will still be willing to charter their tonnage and insurers to underwrite
it. This is indeed a likely scenario that does not solve the problem of sub-standard shipping, but
only achieves a not-in-my-backyard situation in Europe. The EU is aware of this and it intends to
address the issue by intensifying the operational links -for example through the inter-operability of
PSC EDI systems- with other third countries, particularly with Australia, Canada and the United
States.
In addition, the solution could well be that black-listed ships are well and widely publicised,
leading to higher marine and cargo insurance premia, difficulties in financing and unwillingness of
charterers to employ such tonnage. One could even imagine a situation where charterers, insurers
and financiers are also black-listed when knowingly or negligently deal with sub-standard tonnage.
However difficult, such an approach to PSC is feasible and desirable. It requires resources and a
harmonised approach to ship inspections across Europe, by a body of dedicated inspectors,
specifically and uniformly re-trained for that purpose, eventually serving on a rotating basis in EU
countries other than their own. Ideally, such training should take place at a supra-national
European training school, funded by Community resources and PSC revenues from fines.
Perhaps it is worth mentioning in the present context the already well-publicised fact that more
than 80% of all marine accidents is the result of human error.26 People, the “software” of the
industry, are receiving a renewed interest in the regulatory work of IMO, with the full support of
the EU. This is done through two very important instruments, namely the International
Shipmanagement Code (ISM) and the amendment of the International Convention on Standards of
Training, Certification and Watch-keeping for seafarers (STCW).
While the ISM Code aims at developing and sustaining a new safety culture in the corporate
thinking of shipping companies, the STCW amendments are intended to improve the quality of
personnel at sea. Both instruments represent a very positive step for IMO who, for the first time,
has been given the authority to monitor whether or not a number of important obligations imposed
22
O’Neil, op. cit.
particularly in view of the Union’s commitment to provide technical assistance to developing countries to
enable them upgrade their maritime administration.
24
Kinnock, op. cit.
25
see also Council Directive 95/21/EC, 19.06.95 (Port State Control).
26
care should be shown, however, with such unqualified statements; where does human error stop? Is it not,
for example, structural failure also the result of human error in ship construction/design?
23
13
by the two instruments on shipping companies, governments and training institutions have been
complied with.
EXTERNAL RELATIONS
In its external shipping relations, the Union’s prime objective is to promote shipping policies that
safeguard and promote open trade and free competition on a fair, non-discriminatory, and
commercial basis in international shipping, regardless of flag of registration. This objective is
pursued in conjunction with the Union’s firm insistence on compliance with international rules and
standards regarding safety, environment and living and working conditions on board ships.
The Community’s approach to the operating environment of international shipping can be
adequately reflected through its 1986 Regulations which are considered as the pillars of EU
shipping policy. Namely,
•
•
•
•
Regulation 4055/86, applying the principle of freedom to provide services for maritime
transport;
Regulation 4056/86, concerned with the application of EU competition rules to maritime
transport;
Regulation 4057/86, addressing unfair pricing practices in maritime transport, and
Regulation 4058/86, regarding co-ordinated action to safeguard free access to cargoes in
seaborne trade.
Regulation 4057/86 in particular, affords the Community its basic “anti-dumping” legislation in
maritime transport and it lays down the procedures to be followed in order to respond to unfair
practices by third country shipowners engaged in international cargo liner shipping. The
Regulation has so far been used only once against the Hyundai Merchant Marine27, but due to the
subsequent transferring of Korean interests to a French company, duties were levied only for a
limited time. Accordingly, some European shipowners have advocated towards the necessity of
making this Regulation more watertight, given that, in its present form, it may afford protection to
countries the Community has no interest in protecting. Nowadays, however, the danger of
individual dumping is significantly reduced as a result of the “multi-trade” character of liner
shipping services and the consequent formation of global alliances in most of the east-west trades.
Notwithstanding this, the Commission has, in a number of occasions, used the Regulation as a
“deterrent” against “potential” dumping.
Regulation 4055/86 is concerned with free access to cargoes and freedom to provide services. This
is an internal market opening regulation whose underlying principle is that countries should not
reserve national trade for their own transport companies. This practice was exercised by some
countries mainly as a means to protect their shipping industries from international competition
allowing them in this way to grow and acquire an increased market share in international ocean
transportation.
In October 1994, the Commission issued its third report on the implementation of Regulation
4055/86, reflecting the situation as of June 1994. The Commission presented all the outstanding
problems concerning unilateral restrictions still in force in Member States (France and until
recently Portugal) and a limited number of bilateral cargo-sharing agreements some Member States
(Germany, Belgium, Luxembourg, Spain, Italy, Portugal) still had with third countries, particularly
with regard to the application of the UN Code of Conduct for Liner Conferences. The Commission
27
see Hyundai Merchant Marine, Council Regulation (EEC) No. 15/89, O.J. No., L4, 6 January 1989.
14
has opened infringement procedures for many outstanding cases where the situation warranted it.
Cargo reservation should be distinguished according to the different shipping sectors it is
exercised. In bulk shipping it mainly takes the form of unilateral or bilateral arrangements and it is
occasionally justified on the grounds of the strategic importance of the transported commodities. In
liner shipping, cargo reservation is enforced predominantly through the cargo-sharing
arrangements of the UN Code of Conduct for Liner Conferences.
In both cases (bulk and liner) such arrangements, apart from distorting competition with a marked
effect on freight rates, are not in conformity with the fundamental principles of Most Favoured
Nation (MFN) and Market Access (MA) of the GATT/GATS system of trade negotiations.
However, the very same system of trade liberalisation can provide a number of opportunities to
developing countries, which are mainly those adopting such protectionist policies, to be exempted
from the liberal MFN and MA provisions of the GATT on reasons of “national objectives”,
balance of payments problems, infant industry protection arguments and similar concerns.
These prospects confront European shipping with the potential danger of making concessions to
liberalise their already liberal shipping regime that are not only unreciprocated but could result in
even greater protectionism than the one existing today. Having said that, however, the word
“liberal” needs further qualification for the sake of fairness: distortions to competition can result
not only from government measures, but also from the anti-competitive collusive agreements of
private enterprises. Governments may abandon certain trade restrictions and, then, turn a blind eye
to such restrictive business practices. If the parties to such agreements control an important
segment of the market, the result of such practices is the same as that of government measures
meant to protect national industries against foreign competition28.
The prohibition and gradual elimination of such restrictive practices -public or private- should be
one of the main targets of Community shipping policy. Business practices like these reduce
consumer welfare by maintaining freight rates above what would have prevailed under free
competition, distort competition, contribute towards perpetuating operational inefficiency, hinder
growth and economic integration and are thus in conflict the very same principles of the
underlying philosophy of the Treaty.
With few notable exceptions, restrictions to market access through policies of cargo reservation
should not be seen in isolation, but as policies befitting the general economic philosophy of the
country which applies them. Protectionist policies of this type are usually associated with countries
at a low level of economic development and a strong and sometimes dominant public sector. Cargo
reservation policies are expected to diminish, not so much because of international political
pressure or fear of reprisals, but because and when countries exercising such policies feel that the
time is ripe and that liberal shipping policies would benefit their economies and are in conformity
with their new economic philosophy. This prediction is vindicated by the thrust that many
developing countries have thrown towards achieving greater and faster progress within the GATT
system of multilateral trade talks.
On the basis of the above considerations, it is believed here that the Commission, notwithstanding
its commitment to effectively enforce the first phase policy of the four 1986 Regulations, should
strengthen its efforts towards making greater progress in the liberalisation of shipping services
world-wide, and in this way capitalise on third countries’ commitment towards free trade in
general.
28
COM(96) 81 final op. cit. p.21.
15
In the context of GATS29, Europe’s shipping policy should be safeguarded by agreement on
standstill and roll-back provisions and by striving to ensure the application of the Most Favoured
Nation (MFN) principle to the fullest extent, however difficult the latter might prove to be. In
addition, the Community should see to it that an adequate number of countries are thus committed
(critical mass) and that the above principles apply equally to all shipping related activities, i.e.
shipping, port and auxiliary services.
CONCLUSIONS
Despite its generally acknowledged importance in the economic life of the EU, European shipping
is at crossroads: flagging-out is increasing alarmingly, market share is declining and the maritimerelated employment figures give cause for concern. It seems that European shipping is taking its
place in the long queue of industries facing the dire effects of globalisation, thus constantly
feeding the debate as to the need for concerted action at European level. A short SWOT30analytical presentation of the outlook of European shipping would look like this:
STRENGTHS:
Advanced technology, training and the existence of a centuries-old
maritime know-how
WEAKNESSES:
High operating costs
OPPORTUNITIES:
Further liberalisation of international trade in shipping services
THREATS:
Protectionist policies of third countries and regionalisation of trade
The EU shipping policy is developed along the three axes of positive measures, external relations
and safety. With regard to positive measures, the Union is, inter alia, currently revising its stateaid guidelines in the firm belief that European shipping serves the “common interest” and it may,
therefore, under certain conditions, be exempted from the prohibitions of article 92(1) of the
Treaty, concerning state aids to industry. It is thus felt that a strong Community fleet is essential,
both for economic and strategic reasons, and, as the leading world trading entity, the Community
should not be excessively dependent on third country fleets. It is expected that the forthcoming
state-aid guidelines of the Commission will adequately stress its conviction that the whatever
assistance to the industry is afforded by Member States, should be transparent, well documented,
adequately justified, but also temporary and, if possible, on a declining scale. Furthermore, it
should not specifically contribute to increasing or maintaining capacity in sectors with manifest
overcapacity.
In its external shipping relations, the Union’s prime objective is to promote shipping policies that
safeguard and promote open trade and free competition on a fair, non-discriminatory, and
commercial basis in international shipping, regardless of flag of registration. This objective is
pursued in conjunction with the Union’s firm insistence on compliance with international rules and
standards regarding safety, environment and living and working conditions on board ships.
Despite the limited, so far, progress on the multilateral liberalisation of shipping services, the
Union firmly believes that further progress on this front is imperative. A policy thrust towards
further liberalisation enjoys the merit of “neutrality”, de-emphasises the arguments on the
29
The GATS talks on shipping did not succeed and were effectively postponed to the year 2000.
Strength-Weakness-Opportunity-Threat
30
16
importance of shipping (that could be put forward equally well by any country developed ones
included), enhances the cross-trading possibilities of the European fleet and places the emphasis on
the importance of trade liberalisation; a principle that is increasingly becoming a sine qua non to
most countries that have to operate in today’s global economy.
The prohibition and gradual elimination of restrictive practices should be one of the main targets
of Community shipping policy. Such practices can result not only from government measures, but
also from the anti-competitive collusive agreements of private enterprises. Public or private,
restrictive practices tend to reduce consumer welfare, lead to high freight rates, distort competition,
perpetuate operational inefficiency and hinder growth and economic integration.
The EU policies on maritime safety and the protection of the marine environment are very
comprehensive. They mainly stem from two convictions: a) that the quality of shipping to and
from European ports should reflect the European citizens’ increased environmental and safety
awareness and quality of life in general, and b) that substandard shipping is a distinctive threat to
the competitiveness of the European shipping sector.
Attributing high importance to the convergent implementation and uniform enforcement of
international rules and regulations, and concerned with the non-binding character of many IMO
regulations, the Union might wish to consider making some of the latter compulsory through EC
legislation and apply them indiscriminately to all ships visiting its ports. This, together with the
Union’s commitment to provide technical assistance to third countries -thus helping them upgrade
their maritime administration-, its support to IMO’s Flag State Implementation sub-committee, and
its conscientious efforts to improve the effectiveness of Port State Control internationally can go a
long way towards eliminating sub-standard shipping not only in Europe but across the world.
After a rather long gestation period, the last ten years or so have seen an impressive body of work
in the shipping law-making of the EU. The principal philosophies behind the Union’s shipping
policy have found significant consensus. Firm commitment is now needed to move ahead, together
with the necessary “fine-tuning” requiring sincere dialogue with all parties concerned.
But, evidently, this is not the end. Significant challenges still lay ahead. I feel, for example, that
capital concentration in liner shipping is an issue that eventually will have to be re-addressed. The
impetus to do so will come from the development of regional ports in the Mediterranean, Asia and
Latin America; the increasing volumes of regional trade; the un-sustainability of road transport in
Europe; the possibilities offered by short sea shipping and the deregulation of European railways.
These developments may eventually lead to a re-evaluation of the rationale behind the hub-andspoke system in ocean transportation and thus the structure of the liner shipping industry. But, of
course, these are “food for thought” and maybe the challenges for the 21st century.-
APPENDIX
MAREFORUM 96: Market Mechanisms for Safer Shipping and Cleaner Oceans, Erasmus
University Rotterdam, 10-12 October 1996. The Conference took place under the auspices of the
European Commission. It attracted leading shipping personalities from industry and government,
including EU Transport Commissioner Neil Kinnock an the Secretary General of IMO, W.A.
O’Neil. Given their relevance to the present paper, the Conference Resolutions are annexed here.
17
Resolutions
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
Safety and environmental policies and regulations are inextricably linked to issues of industrial
competitiveness and they should be seen as such. An economic framework should be
established integrating safety and environment, whereby the industry is led towards selfregulation.
Care should be taken so that the insistence on higher standards of, for instance, training and
employment, is not seen as protectionism (fortress Europe), inflicting unfair economic
disadvantages on poor countries. These countries often lack resources and expertise to
implement measures with the same speed and assurance as larger nations, having centuries of
tradition and expertise behind them.
Casual or negligent practices by flag states cannot be tolerated and weaknesses of
administration are not an acceptable excuse. The right to operate a register carries a full
responsibility to do it properly. There should be no concession to those who gain from the
right and show contempt for the responsibility. In this respect the role of IMO’s FSI subCommittee is of paramount importance.
The problem of “safer shipping and cleaner oceans” is in essence an economic one and has to
do with the availability of economic advantages of non-compliance. Coordinated action is thus
needed.
Prices charged to transport users should reflect the real costs generated by transport, which are
currently born by others or by society as a whole.
The operational business environment, business ethics and codes of practice have a decisive
impact on the safety performance of a company and the ships it operates. The selection of the
flag is decisive for the ships’ cost levels and may influence its safety performance.
IMO is the sole competent international body to set standards on marine safety and pollution
prevention and control. However, the ever-growing body of IMO’s legislative work has to be
rationalised and self-reevaluated. Before adopting still more regulations IMO should therefore
concentrate on assuring that the ones that already exist are in fact applied to all ships
throughout the world.
Human error is an extremely complex subject and it cannot be eliminated by introducing a few
training courses. In many cases, it will require a complete change in corporate thinking, the
introduction of totally new attitudes, the adoption of a genuinely safety culture. This effort will
also have to be sustained indefinitely and, to be effective, it will have to involve the industry
as a whole.
IMO’s ISM code is an issue as central to shipping company management as is the making of
profit. Companies not being able to comply will have serious problems and only themselves to
blame. Both ISM and the STCW revision will impose a number of important obligations on
shipping companies, governments and training institutions. Through the STCW amendments,
IMO has for the first time been given authority to monitor whether or not they have been
complied with.
Universal application of legislative instruments, port state control and flag state control should
be emphasised. Focus should be placed on sub-standard shipping and thus right targeting is
important. Proper maintenance and the overall condition of the ship should be the main
criterion, not age.
Safety and environmental protection in the transport chain is not a matter only for the
shipowner; all other parties involved, such as classification societies, P&I clubs, banks and
insurance companies should also play a role and assume their responsibilities within what
could be called the maritime environment and safety cluster.
The industry should conscientiously try to raise the public image of shipping which is unduly
18
•
•
•
•
•
bad.
The shipowner is the only responsible party for the safety of his ship. Bankers, insurers and
P&I Clubs do have an influence but they are restricted in their possibilities by commercial
interests due to their supplier/customer relations. Excess supply in the insurance and P&I
markets can be a problem with regard to ship safety. Competition weakens the position of the
insurer. Focus should also be placed on ancillary services, such as stevedoring, tug assistance,
bunkering, etc., i.e. what could be called the port cluster.
Classification societies do have a very important function. They should conduct closer and
better inspections to older ships. However, too many inspections are currently being
undertaken on behalf of various actors in the market. This is caused by a lack of trust in
classification societies. As a result, there is a significant lack of information and transparency,
which would, among others, help shippers to be more selective in the tonnage they charter. In
addition, the flow of information is very important for the proper functioning of the market.
Information systems could contribute to an environment where safety is enhanced. Effective
information systems can help in targeting sub-standard ships at an earlier stage.
Regulation increases the costs of the quality shipowner but not those of the sub-standard one.
Stable relations between quality conscious shippers and shipowners could be developed to
stimulate safer shipping.
MAREFORUM 96 was an excellent initiative to start the debate; the momentum has now to be
maintained.
19