111 EAAE-IAAE Seminar ‘Small Farms: decline or persistence’
University of Kent, Canterbury, UK
26th-27th June 2009
The Economics of Land Consolidation in Family Farms of Moldova*
Dragoş Cimpoieş,1 Zvi Lerman,2 Anatol Racul1
1
Department of Management, The State Agricultural University of Moldova, Chişinău 2049,
Republic of Moldova. Email: dcimpoies@uasm.md
2
Department of Agricultural Economics and Management, The Hebrew University, Rehovot
76100, Israel. Email: lerman@agri.huji.ac.il
Copyright 2009 by Dragoş Cimpoieş, Zvi Lerman and Anatol Racul. All rights reserved.
Readers may make verbatim copies of this document for non-commercial purposes by any
means, provided that this copyright notice appears on all such copies.
Abstract
The paper investigates the current situation with fragmentation of family farms in Moldova
and its effects on family well-being and farm productivity. A key hypothesis is that
consolidation of agricultural land in Moldova has beneficial effects in terms of productivity
and is desirable in the long run.
We examine the case for market-driven land consolidation using data from several recent
surveys in Moldova. We show that, in the individual sector, larger farms consume less of their
output and attain higher levels of commercialization. Larger individual farms thus have higher
revenues from commercial sales and generate higher family incomes. Farm augmentation
accordingly makes a positive contribution to the well-being of the rural population. The extent
of parcel consolidation is directly correlated with the relative efficiency of farms:
consolidated family farms are more efficient than those with fragmented holdings. Hence,
land consolidation leads to better economic performance of family farms.
Keywords
Land consolidation, land fragmentation, land market, family farms, rural incomes, Moldova
*
This work was financially supported by the state project on land consolidation 069/p, financed by the Academy
of Sciences of Moldova.
1
BACKGROUND
Despite an early start, the process of land reform in Moldova was not visible until 1996.
Authorities had no sufficient political will for restructuring of old legal entities and
privatization of their land to rural residents; the reform efforts stalled due to the unwillingness
of the managers of former collective farms to cooperate with the government. Therefore,
during the initial period land reform in Moldova saw only minimum changes and agriculture
largely retained the Soviet heritage. Nevertheless, most of the rural residents received during
this period paper certificates attesting to ownership of a certain land share, but in an
unspecified location.
In 1996, the constitutional court removed some legislative constraints on land reform,
providing an impetus for fundamental changes in the organization of the agricultural sector. A
significant shift started to be felt a year later, when the National Land Program (NLP) was
launched. In March 1998, the NLP was unrolled on a national scale triggering the
privatization of all existing collective farms and sweeping conversion of the paper certificates
to physical plots. Agricultural land in state ownership dropped from 100% in 1990 to less than
25% in 2005. As of the end of 2005, over 670,000 holders of land shares, or about two-thirds
of all beneficiaries, had withdrawn nearly 900,000 hectares of agricultural land from largescale collectives for individual use (Lerman, Cimpoies, 2006).
Each landowner who exercised his rights under the NLP received on average 1.3-1.4 hectares
of agricultural land. Combined with the original household plot of 0.3-0.4 hectares, the NLP
distribution produced small holdings of less than 2 hectares. The small farm sizes produced in
the process of land reform are one dimension of land fragmentation in Moldova.
Size fragmentation was exacerbated by the equity-driven design of land privatization in
Moldova. To ensure that all peasants had equal access to land of different types, each land
share was divided into three separate parts: a share of arable land, a share of orchards, and a
share of vineyards. In practice, many landowners received more than three parcels against
their land shares. In a 2003 survey of peasant farms, 55% reported 3-6 parcels and 19%
reported more than 6 parcels (Muravschi, Bucatca, 2005). The inherently small holdings were
thus further fragmented into still smaller parcels in scattered locations. The splitting of small
land holdings into multiple parcels is the second dimension of land fragmentation in Moldova.
Less than half the landowners who received physical plots through the NLP decided to farm
their land independently (DSS, 2004a), creating the new category of independent peasant
farmers that did not exist prior to reform. Others leased their land to so-called “leaders” or
“managers”, who founded new corporate farms by consolidating the dispersed small plots of
passive landowners. At present, these “leaders” manage about 1,500 farms – limited liability
companies, joint stock companies and agricultural production cooperatives – with an average
size of 500-800 hectares depending on organizational form.
The distribution of land to the rural population led to dramatic changes in the structure of land
use by farms of various organizational forms. Particularly notable is the shrinking share of
former state and collective farms and a corresponding increase in land used by the individual
sector. Thus, in 1990, less than 10% of the total of agricultural land was operated by the
individual sector. Since then, the picture has significantly changed: the two sectors of
corporate and individual farms each control about 50% of agricultural land. The traditional
collective farms practically disappeared during the last decade, as many of them were
privatized or liquidated and others registered in new legal forms.
2
While corporate farms average 500-800 hectares, the individual farms (household plots and
peasant farms) are much smaller. Thus, the average peasant farm has 1.8 hectares and only
277 peasant farms (out of over 350,000 in total) are larger than 50 hectares (DSS, 2004b).
Half the agricultural land in Moldova is in units smaller than 10 hectares (WORLD BANK,
2005). This category comprises over 1 million household plots and small peasant farms with
average holdings of 0.8 hectares. The small average size and the huge number of small
farming units in a population of less than 4 million clearly demonstrate the extent of
fragmentation produced by land reform in Moldova.
The creation of so-called “peasant farms” was one of the main objectives of land reform, and
this objective has been fully achieved. However, the small size of the peasant farms, whose
holdings are furthermore split into several disjointed parcels, raises considerable concerns
about their long-term viability and has led to an intense public debate regarding the impacts of
fragmentation.
In this paper we examine how the two dimensions of fragmentation – small farm sizes and
large number of parcels per farm – affect farm productivity and family incomes. We also
review the development of land markets in Moldova, as buy-and-sell transactions and land
leasing provide obvious mechanisms for market-driven consolidation of fragmented holdings.
The analysis relies on several farm and household surveys conducted between 2003 and 2008.
These surveys are shown at the beginning of the list of references. The latest in the series of
surveys (referred to as the 2008 ASM survey in what follows) was conducted in July 2008
covering about 600 households and peasant farms from four villages spread across the
country and about 80 corporate farms from 30 districts. Financing was provided by the
Academy of Sciences of Moldova under the state project “Developing of economic
mechanisms of land consolidation”
The paper is organized as follows: we start by presenting the survey evidence regarding the
positive impact of consolidation on farm efficiency and rural well-being. We then proceed to
describe the development of land market transactions based on survey data. A separate section
describes the formal land consolidation effort in Moldova and presents some preliminary
results of the 2008 land consolidation pilot project. Some concluding remarks are given at the
end.
2
FARM TYPES AND FARM SIZES IN MOLDOVA
There is a voluminous literature dealing with the effect of farm sizes on efficiency and
productivity in market economies and in transition countries. At the outset of transition some
argued for the necessity of preserving large farm structures and preventing farm
fragmentation on the basis that smaller farms were less efficient (Kanchev, Doichinova,
2000). In contrast, others argued that large farms in former socialist countries in Europe
suffered from diseconomies of size and land reform strategies had to include proposals for
reducing the mean farm size (Koester, Striewe, 1999). So far, the results are indecisive: there
is no evidence that large farms are more productive than small farms and we can only say that
small farms at not less productive than large farms.
Land reform contributed to significant structural changes in Moldovan agriculture. A recent
survey conducted in 2008 (2008 ASM survey) accordingly covered the three main farm types
that characterize the agriculture in Moldova today: household plots, peasant farms, and
corporate farms. The household plot is usually situated close to the house, but not always.
When the plot is situated outside the village, it is practically impossible to distinguish it from
3
the land of a peasant farm. The privatized land outside the village is considered a peasant farm
(regardless of whether it is officially registered or not)1. Many people have chosen to lease out
their land allotments outside the village to corporate farms or peasant farms, and to continue
cultivating only their household plot. These specific aspects have been taken into
consideration in our sample design.
Table 1:
Size distribution characteristics for farms of different types, in ha*
Min-max range
Mean size
Median size
Interquartile range
Lower 10%
Upper 10%
Number of parcels
Households
(n=135)
0,10-0,75
0,37
0,30
0,30-0,51
0,10
0,68
3
Peasant farms
(n=477)
0,76-18,40
2,61
2,16
1,58-3,02
1,23
3,98
6
Corporate farms
(n=76)
3,2-4224
851
529
240-1071
100
2400
* Farm size expressed by land in actual use.
Source: 2008 ASM Survey.
Figure 1:
Median size and interquartile range for farms of different types
Source: 2008 ASM Survey.
The three farm types surveyed span a wide range of farm sizes (Table 1), and we use our
survey data to examine how farm sizes affect farm efficiency.2 Household holds and peasant
farms combined constitute the so-called individual sector, as opposed to corporate farms.
There are distinctive differences between the individual and the corporate sectors (Table 1),
while the two components of the individual sector – household plots and peasant farms – are
much closer to one another by size. Still, there is no overlap between the interquartile ranges
of these types of farms (Figure 1), which means that all three types of farms are significantly
different by size. Thus, corporate farms are much larger than peasant farms, while the latter
1
Official sources give conflicting information on the number of peasant farms and the area of agricultural land
they control, their total number varying between 283 000 and 558 000, depending on the source of reference.
2
Following Lund (1983), we use the land holdings as a measure of farm size.
4
are larger than household plots. Also, peasant farms being larger are more fragmented: 6
parcels compared to only 3 on average for households.
3
EFFICIENCY AND LAND CONSOLIDATION
Evidence of higher efficiency and productivity of larger, consolidated holdings would be a
strong argument in favour of mass re-parcelling of fragmented family farms in Moldova.
Previous studies (Lerman, Cimpoies, 2006; Lerman, Sutton, 2008) have revealed an
interconnection between efficiency and farm size, demonstrating that small family farms are
more efficient than large corporate farms. The 2008 ASM survey investigated mainly the
effect that fragmentation of holdings into multiple parcels has on farm performance.
Figure 2:
Technical efficiency versus fragmentation of peasant farms
0,8
Technical efficiency
0,7
0,6
0,5
0,4
0,3
0,2
0,1
0
1
2
4
8
16
32
Number of parcels
Source: 2008 ASM Survey.
The advisability of reducing the number of parcels in a farm of a given size through land
consolidation emerges from the negative correlation between the number of parcels and
technical efficiency across farms as calculated by the stochastic frontier algorithms (SFA).
Our survey reveals a clear negative relationship between productivity and the number of
parcels held by the operator. Figure 2 shows that the productivity (technical efficiency)
decrease as fragmentation (i.e., the number of parcels in a farm) increases. The negative
relationship between productivity and fragmentation in Figure 2 is statistically significant by
all standard measures. This new result reinforces earlier findings, which showed that two
partial productivity measures – farm income per hectare and farm income per worker –
decreased with fragmentation as measured by the number of parcels per farm (Lerman,
Cimpoies, 2006).
4
FARM INCOMES AND LAND CONSOLIDATION
One of the major arguments in favour of land consolidation is based on the hypothesis that
farmers with consolidated holdings have higher incomes and their family well-being is
considerably higher than for farms with fragmented holdings.
5
Table 2:
Linear regression analysis of farm revenue versus farm size and number
of parcels*
Independent variables
Estimated coefficients
t value
Land used, ha
10.81
1.977
Costs, lei
0.432
6.39
Number of parcels
-6.93
-0.654
Employees, workers
1.376
5.20
Age of head of family
0.121
3.52
Intercept
-5.405
-2.72
R-square
0.788
Number of observations
193
*
Dependent variable: farm revenues from sales
Source: 2008 ASM Survey.
Linear regression analysis shows that farm revenue from product sales increases with farm
size (land used) and decreases with the number of parcels operated by the farmer (Table 2).
The important result here is that number of parcels has a negative effect on farm income when
we control for other variables (the negative regression coefficient is significant at p < 0.05).
Hence, consolidation, in the sense of reducing the number of parcels, makes economic sense
for peasant farms and households in Moldova. Other statistically significant factors affecting
farm income are farm costs and the number of workers employed: larger revenues are
generated by larger farms, which, in addition to more land, involve higher total costs and
more workers.3
5
RURAL FAMILY WELL-BEING AND LAND CONSOLIDATION
Consolidation affects not only farm productivity, but also the standard of living of rural
families. One of the major arguments for re-parceling is the hypothesis that land consolidation
increases farm income by raising the degree of commercialization, i.e., the share of output
sold.
Family farms in Moldova are generally viewed as subsistence operations. Indeed, fully 80%
of farms in the survey are smaller than 3 ha, reporting sales of less than 10% of their output
(Figure 3). The share of output sold clearly increases with farm size. Thus, the
commercialization rate of farms smaller than 1 ha is almost zero and these very small farms
can be regarded as pure subsistence operations. On the other hand, farms larger than 5 ha can
be regarded as practicing commercial farming: they sell more than 30 percent of their output.
This is consistent with the results observed in other transition countries (Lerman, Sedik,
2007). The level of commercialization increases with farm size: while small farms use all they
produce for family consumption, the output of larger farms exceeds the family needs, creating
a marketable surplus.
Moreover, our survey revealed that the second dimension of land fragmentation, namely the
number of parcels held by an operator, also affects the level of commercialization (Figure 4).
As the number of parcels per ha, i.e. the level of fragmentation increases, the
commercialization rate decreases. Family farmers operating one consolidated plot sell about
30 percent of their output, whereas those with highly fragmented holdings sell less than 5
3
A similar study in Ukraine (Lerman, Sedik, 2007) noted a decrease of income with the age of the family head.
In Moldova, on the other hand, the age of the head of family had a positive effect on farm revenues.
6
percent of the output. Thus, farmers with consolidated holdings have a higher marketable
surplus, which is conducive to creating a higher farm income and thus increasing their
families standard of living. Also, consolidated farms are much larger than fragmented farms.
Consolidated farms have 3,6 ha on average, compared to 1 ha and less for highly fragmented
farms (6 parcels and more). These results suggests that relatively large consolidated holdings
stimulate commercial farming, while small fragmented plots lead to subsistence operation,
with farm output used entirely for family consumption.
Farm size vs. commercialization
160
45
140
40
35
120
30
100
25
80
20
60
% sold
Farms, units
Figure 3:
15
40
10
20
5
0
0
0-1
1-2
2-3
3-4
4-5
5-10
Over 10
Farm size, ha
Farms in the sample, units
Percent sold
Source: 2008 ASM Survey.
Fragmentation vs. commercialization
30
4,0
Farm size, ha
3,5
25
3,0
20
2,5
15
2,0
1,5
% sold
Figure 4:
10
1,0
5
0,5
0,0
0
1
2
3
4
5
6-10
Over 10
Level of fragmentation, parcels per 1 ha
Farm size
Percent sold
Source: 2008 ASM Survey.
Larger farm sizes generally lead to a higher standard of living of rural families. A comfortable
standard of living is associated with a much larger farm size than lower standards of living.
Peasant farmers reporting a comfortable standard of living in the 2005 World Bank survey
(Lerman, Cimpoies, 2006) have 11 hectares on average, compared with less than 5 hectares
7
for farmers whose families are in lower standard of living categories – poverty, when family
income is not sufficient to buy food, and subsistence, when family income is sufficient to buy
food and daily necessities (the difference between farm sizes is statistically significant at p <
0.01). The standard of living of peasant farmers is thus an increasing function of farm size, as
is commonly observed in farm surveys in other transition countries.
Figure 5: Probability of achieving a given standard of living as a function of farm size
for peasant farmers
1
probability
0.8
0.6
Poverty
Subsistence
Comfortable
0.4
0.2
0
0
10
20
30
40
50
land use, ha
Note: Definition of standard of living levels: “poverty” – family income not sufficient to buy food;
“subsistence” – family income just sufficient to buy food and daily necessities;
“comfortable” – family income sufficient to buy food, daily necessities, and durables.
Source: 2005 World Bank survey (Lerman, Cimpoies, 2006).
The relationship between the standard of living and farm size is illustrated in Figure 5. Here
the probability of being in the highest standard of living (gray curve) increases with farm size,
while the probability of being on the lowest “poverty” level, when family income is not
sufficient to buy food (thick black curve), sharply decreases with farm size.4 These results
provide the ultimate support for land consolidation policies and hence the need to encourage
land market development.
6
LAND MARKETS AND LAND CONSOLIDATION
In Moldova land reform based on equity principles transformed all rural residents into small
landowners as almost one million hectares of agricultural land was distributed to over 600,000
people. Among this multitude of smallholders, many remain inactive for various reasons (age,
health, non-farming jobs, etc.). Mass distribution of small plots to individuals requires
development of land market mechanisms to enable land to flow from less efficient to more
efficient users, allowing farmers to adjust the size of their holdings. Land market is the only
effective way to satisfy the new demand for land on the part of those who want to enlarge
their farms.
4
The probabilities of achieving a given standard of living were obtained in a multinomial logistic regression
with the three-level standard of living as the discrete dependent variable and farm size as the continuous
covariate.
8
One of the main objectives of land market development is the creation of viable family farms
by transferring land from less efficient landowners to the most efficient farm operators or
managers. The main mechanisms of land use transfer based on market principles are buying
and selling of land and land leasing.
6.1
Buying and selling of agricultural land in Moldova
The moratorium on buying and selling of land introduced in December 19915 and the
imposition of high transfer taxes for land transactions were initially major obstacles to the
development of a viable land market in Moldova. In July 1997 new procedures for sale and
purchase of land6 removed the basic restrictions to the development of functioning land
markets and 1997 can be regarded as the year of birth of the land market in Moldova.
Table 3:
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
1999-2008
Source:
Buy-and-sell transactions with agricultural land
Number of
Transacted area,
Average
transactions
ha
transaction, ha
1933
232
0,12
9753
1268
0,13
24625
2336
0,09
27759
2682
0,10
49165
3595
0,07
44134
3201
0,07
47382
3250
0,07
51483
3773
0,07
65000
4697
0,07
72000
12911
0,17
393234
37945
0,10
Average price
per ha, MDL
3364
3100
2928
3781
3733
8001
9040
11000
12104
10301
Botnarenco, 2009
Both the number of transactions and the transacted area grew rapidly (Table 3). About 40 000
ha of agricultural land changed ownership in 400 000 transactions between 1999 and 2008.
Despite the impressive growth, this constitutes only 2 percent of the agricultural land in
Moldova (2 million ha).
According to two surveys conducted in 2004 and 2006 (Cimpoies, Schulze, 2006; Cimpoies,
2007), the development of buy-and-sell transactions dramatically changed during a very short
period of time. Farm managers began to understand the importance of having land in private
ownership. Only a few years earlier most corporate farms had very little privately owned land,
but now the picture is changing. Between 2003 and 2006, farm managers bought on average
more than 100 ha per corporate farm and in 2008 fully 40% of corporate farms participated in
land market transactions as land buyers (Table 4). The share of own land in total land used by
corporate farms increased substantially. As recently as 2003, 98% of cultivated land in
corporate farms was leased, not owned (Gudym et al., 2003). In 2006, own land reached about
17% of total land used in corporate farms (Cimpoies, 2007), and in 2008 the share of own
5
Land Code: Law No. 828-XII from 25.12.1991.
6 Law on Normative Price of Land and Procedure for Sale and Purchase of Land: Law No. 1308 – XIII from
25.07.1997.
9
land in corporate farms increased to 36% (Table 4). Buy-and-sell transactions are also
becoming more acceptable among individual farmers. In 2008, about 10% of peasant farmers
reported that they had bought land, while 15% reported selling land (Table 4). These are
respectable market participation rates, although they are far below the participation rates for
corporate farms.
Table 4:
Buying and selling of land in individual and corporate farms
Bought land
Did not buy land
Sold land
All sample
Households
Peasant farms
Corporate farms
Households
Peasant farms
Corporate farms
Households
Peasant farms
Corporate farms
Households
Peasant farms
Corporate farms
Percent of
respondents
1,5
10,1
40,0
98,5
89,9
60,0
3,7
15,0
5,2
100
100
100
Farm size, ha
1,8
3,2
923,0
2,1
2,6
837,7
2,0
2,3
1199,8
2,1
2,9
868,5
% of owned
land
100,0
97,6
39,4
100,0
98,9
34,1
100,0
100,0
50,8
100,0
98,7
36,1
Source: 2008 ASM Survey.
The average size of a corporate farm that bought land is about 10% larger than the average
size of a corporate farm that did not buy land (Table 4). Similar trends are observed for
peasant farms and household plots, which were 10%-20% larger than family farms that did
not buy land. This might indicate that the development of land markets through buy-and-sell
transactions has a positive effect on farm sizes and contributes to farm enlargement and hence
to land consolidation.
Based on national data, the average land sale transaction remained fairly constant at around
0,10 ha between 1999 and 2007 (Table 3). Then in 2008 it increased sharply to 0.17 ha per
transaction. The increase in average transaction size may reflect certain parcel consolidation
trends due to the launching of the National Land Consolidation Program at the end of 2007
(see below).
Despite these generally positive developments, the role of buy-and-sell transactions in land
consolidation so far seems to be marginal compared to the role of the widespread leasing
arrangements.
6.2
Development of agricultural land leasing in Moldova
The results of several recent surveys in Moldova (Gudym et al., 2003; World Bank, 2005)
indicate that about half the small landowners created in the process of land reform do not farm
their land and lease it to other operators.7 The lessees are mainly corporate farms, which
7
Land lease relations are governed by the Law on Agricultural Land Leasing passed in 2003. It tries to strike a
balance between the interests of the operator and the socio-economic guarantees required by the landowner. The
law clearly describes the formal part of the lease process and includes a detailed description of the lease
10
largely rely on leased land: 72% of land used by corporate farms is leased (Table 5). Peasant
farmers also act as lessees, but to a much smaller extent than corporate farms: they generally
cultivate owned land with some leased land mobilized to increase their original endowment.
As we see in Table 5, peasant farms leasing in land are substantially larger than farms that
rely on own land only.
Table 5:
Leasing out
Leasing in
Use own land
only
Participation in land leasing
% of respondents
Farm size, ha
% own land
% of respondents
Farm size, ha
% own land
% of respondents
Farm size, ha
% own land
Households
92
2,1
100
0
0,0
100
8
2,5
100
Peasant farms
16
3,2
99,3
5
4,7
69,7
78
2,7
100
Corporate farms
4
1117
100
71
826
28,2
17
1159
100
Source: 2008 ASM Survey.
Household plots, contrary to corporate and peasant farms, do not lease in land. Table 5
demonstrates a sharp dichotomy between household plots as supply side players and
commercial producers (peasant farms and corporate farms) as agents of the demand side in
land markets. Households actually use less than 20% of their holdings (0.4 ha out of 2.5 ha in
total). The rest is leased out. Analysis of leasing participation rates in Table 5 shows that 92%
of households lease out land and none leases in land. At the other extreme, 71% of corporate
farms lease in land and virtually none leases out. Peasant farms occupy an intermediate
position: they act as both lessees and lessors, yet their supply side role clearly predominates:
only 5% of peasant farms lease in land while 16% lease out.
Table 6:
Grouping of household plots by land leasing strategies
Number of respondents
Percent of respondents
Own land, ha
Used land, ha
Wish to enlarge, ha
Number of family members
Age of head of family
Age of spouse
Farm all owned
land
391
63
2,6
2,5
3,3
3
53
50
Lease out
Lease in
202
33
2,7
1,1
3,3
2
57
51
24
4
3,2
4,1
6,6
4
49
41
Source: 2008 ASM Survey.
agreement. In general, the spirit of the new law is restrictive. In particular, term limits are stipulated. The lease
payment is set at not less than 2% of the administratively prescribed normative price of land, without linkage to
the actual market price, which is generally much lower. However, such limitations are not effective, because the
lease payments are typically negotiated as a share of the harvest and their equivalent value is higher than the
stipulated minimum percentage.
11
Additional evidence that leasing in is used as a mechanism for augmentation of farm size is
provided by household plots. The few families that lease in land operate larger household
plots than families farming exclusively their own land and those only leasing out land (Table
6). Moreover, families that lease in land are larger than families using only their own land and
those leasing out a portion of their land: 4 members compared to 3 and 2 respectively. Thus,
families with insufficient labor prefer to lease out their land, while families with more
members available for farm work prefer to extend their own area by leasing in land from
others. Moreover, families leasing in land are younger than families in the other two groups,
which again positively affects labor availability.
6.3
Reasons for land leasing
Why do farmers and farm managers lease in land? Farm managers realize that land
consolidation allows them to use land more efficiently (Cimpoieş, Schulze, 2006). In a 2003
survey of 104 corporate farms in Moldova (Cimpoies, Schulze, 2006) more than 40% of farm
managers expressed the view that it was more profitable and more efficient to cultivate a
larger plot. Nearly 30% indicated that they preferred to lease plots adjacent to the existing
farm. In the 2008 ASM survey, the profitability of cultivation of larger plots was no longer as
important for enlargement of holdings as in 2003: less than 12% of corporate farm managers
mentioned it as an important consideration, down from more than 40% in 2003. On the other
hand, for individual farms the profitability of cultivating a larger plot is still a major reason
for enlargement (Table 7). No change was registered in the second factor: as five years
previously, enlargement of holdings by leasing in parcels from close neighbors remains
important for about 25%-30% of respondents.
Proximity to the existing farm and the conviction that it is more profitable to cultivate a larger
farm explain the strategy of leasing in additional land, mainly from households, but also from
peasant farms.
Table 7:
Reasons to lease in land for individual and corporate farms
Plot adjacent to the existing farm
Land of high quality
Access to irrigation
Good placement of plot
More profitable to cultivate more land
Enough cheap workforce
Other reasons
Individual farms
25,0
7,5
10,0
15,0
27,5
10,0
5,0
Corporate farms
30,5
17,9
11,6
9,5
11,6
14,7
4,2
Source: 2008 ASM Survey.
What reasons do the individual farms, mainly households, give for leasing out land? The main
reason is insufficiency of resources for active farming. In a 2003 survey (Gudym et al., 2003),
65% of lessors identified lack of machinery and purchased inputs as the main cause for
leasing out land. Age was also one of the important reasons for leasing out land – this was
indicated by every fourth landowner. In the 2005 World Bank survey, 40% of lessors put the
blame on insufficient labor, while difficulties with access to purchased inputs and credit (or
money in general) ranked next. In aggregate, reasons associated with the normal functioning
of markets are cited by 78% of the households in the 2005 survey as responsible for their
decision to lease out land (Lerman, Cimpoies, 2006).
12
It may be argued that these individuals would tend to farm the land on their own if the
missing or distorted markets were corrected. This conjecture is supported by the observation
that respondents who attribute leasing to market imperfections express a desire to increase
their plot size by a substantially greater factor than respondents who lease out because of
physical deficiencies of their land (Lerman, Cimpoies, 2006).
Health and age are important factors in the decision to lease out for pensioners and elderly
people. In one survey conducted in 2003 (Gudym et al., 2003), 80% of the pensioners and
70% of landowners older than 60 cited health and age as main reasons for leasing out their
land. In another 2003 survey (Muravschi, Bucatca, 2005), the highest percentage of
landowners who intended to lease out their land (36%) were 60 or older.
Table 8 summarizes the answers of the heads of individual farms in the 2008 ASM survey
regarding the reasons for leaving some parcels of their land uncultivated. We have included in
this sample farmers and household plot operators who lease out land, as well as those who
cultivate only a part of their holdings, without leasing out the rest.
Table 8:
Reasons for not cultivating the entire available land in individual farms
Insufficient labor
percent of respondents
Lack of machinery
Inputs not available
Land of poor quality
Other reasons
Total
Source:
100
2008 ASM Survey.
Lack of fuel, fertilizers, and other purchased inputs, as well as poor land quality are not
reported as serious obstacles by the respondents. Lack of working capital and low profitability
are considered as very serious constraints among those who do not cultivate all their land. The
most important single reason is insufficient labor, cited by about 30% of the respondents. This
is consistent with the observation that smaller families lease out land, while larger families
lease in (Table 6).
Although lack of machinery is cited by 12% of respondents, it is not as vital as, for example,
in Ukraine, where this constraint is reported by 26% (Lerman et al., 2007). This difference in
the perception of machinery constraints is presumably attributable to the small size of peasant
farms in Moldova (2,7 ha compared with 146 ha in Ukraine), which can be worked manually
by the family members. Larger farms in Moldova have the option of renting machinery from
machinery stations or from collective farms.
Lease payments in Moldova exist in three forms: cash, in-kind, and mixed payments. Payment
in-kind is the most prevalent form, used by over 80% of the respondents (Gudym et al., 2003).
13
It is followed by mixed payments (about 10%). The low acceptance of cash lease payment
(less than 5%) can be explained by two reasons. First, monetary relations are in general
poorly developed in the agrarian sector in Moldova. Second, families leasing out land prefer
to receive payment in kind because the goods can be directly consumed by the family
(Cimpoies, Baltag, 2004).
The lease payments for different farm types are shown in Table 9. The median varies between
800 and 1000 MDL per hectare,8 while the mean is 1100-1300 MDL per hectare per year,
being more sensitive to outliers than the median. Corporate farms do not exercise their power
in local land markets and do not push the lease payments to a much lower level. According to
the 2008 ASM survey, the payments by corporate farms do not differ substantially from those
reported in the individual sector.9
Table 9:
Lease payment for farms of different types
% leasing
Average leased, ha
Payment, lei/ha
mean in kind
mean in cash
mean total
Median
Households
(lease out)
44
1,83
Peasant farms
(lease in)
9
2,92
Corporate farms
(lease in)
66
669
943
1449
1137
1000
745
1431
1276
839
1040
783
1105
803
Source: 2008 ASM Survey.
Another attribute of lease agreements is the lease term (Table 10). Long-term lease relations
build the trust between the owner and the lessee, motivating the latter to invest in more
effective utilization of the land. Our results indicate that long-term leasing is not widespread
in Moldova. Corporate farms are the only category of farms that sign long term lease
agreements: about 5% of the farm managers concluded agreements for 10-30 years. As a rule,
these long-term lessees also develop a processing activity. For example, wineries prefer to
conclude lease agreements for a term of 30 years in order to plant new vineyards, which
require significant investment. Therefore, they need stability in the system of lease relations.
Table 10:
Lease term for farms of different types
1-3
4-5
6-10
> 10 years
Households
14
6
80
0
Peasant farms
90
0
10
0
Corporate farms
80
5
10
5
Source: 2008 ASM Survey.
8
1 Euro = 16,5 MDL (the average official rate for 2007)
Lease payments play only a marginal role in family income. Remittances from family members working abroad
are much more important than lease payments as a source of income for most rural families.
9
14
Short term lease agreements for a term of 1-3 years prevail in peasant and corporate farms:
about 80%-90% of respondents. Household plots prefer to lease out their land for a medium
term: 80% of respondents lease out their land for a term of 6-10 years.
7
FORMAL LAND CONSOLIDATION EFFORTS IN MOLDOVAN AGRICULTURE
The various approaches to land consolidation are based on common principles. First, land
consolidation schemes should not deprive people of their right to land and should not create
landless people. The process should be participatory, democratic, and based on market
principles. Second, policy makers should remember that not all fragmentation is a problem.
Land consolidation programs should address only those cases were land fragmentation is a
real problem and not attempt to impose a solution were it is not needed. Finally, we have to
accept that it will not be possible to eliminate land fragmentation entirely.
The State Planning Institute for Land Management has been the traditional vehicle for land
consolidation in Moldova. Nine consolidation projects, mainly in the south of the country,
were carried out in recent years, but lack of funding limited the Institute’s consolidation
activities. The projects typically focused on a mechanism whereby an investor buys or leases
land from smallholders.
Valuable experience with the implementation and design of land consolidation had been
accumulated since May 2003 in the framework of the USAID-funded Land Privatization
Support Project (LPSP), which ended in 2005. In most LPSP projects the instrument of
consolidation is selling land to an investor, not leasing. An LPSP consolidation project was
typically initiated by a buyer (a winery or an agricultural enterprise), who over a period of
time had tried to purchase contiguous land plots for large-scale agricultural production. It was
the responsibility of the buyer to negotiate the agreements with the small individual owners.
The project served as an intermediary between landowners and buyers and supported the
mayor’s office in the village in the use of a simplified land transaction method developed
under the LPSP in compliance with the procedures of the 2002 Amendment to the Land Code.
When small owners with land plots in the interest area preferred not to sell their land, they
were normally offered voluntary exchange of their land for other plots in order to make the
original land available for the project initiator. The focus of the LPSP consolidation projects
was the main buyer or investor, and the result was development of large-scale farms, often
owned by wineries or agricultural enterprises from outside of the village.
Given the accumulated experience, the Government of Moldova has decided to implement a
National Program of Land Consolidation (NPLC) with financial support from the World
Bank, based on concepts proposed by a team from the Danish Ministry of Agriculture
(Haldrup, Hartvigsen, 2005). In contrast to previous land consolidation activities, the new
program focused primarily on small and medium-sized family farms (3-30 ha) and not on
large corporate structures. The operational emphasis was on landowner preferences and on
identifying land exchanges in which people were willing and able to engage. The success of
the procedure depended entirely on the willingness and readiness of landowners to exchange
their land plots. Unfortunately, in a 2003 survey over 80% of respondents indicated that they
would not agree to exchange their existing land plot for a new one in the process of land
consolidation (Muravschi, Bucatca, 2005).
The entire process was based on voluntary participation and the participants retained the
freedom of choice throughout: they could decide to leave the project at any stage before the
final transaction agreement was signed. The consolidation solution was not known at the
15
outset and it only emerged at the very end as a result of multilateral negotiations. There was
no need to secure guidance or approval by the authorities, and the voluntary participatory
nature of the process reduced the likelihood of costly and time-consuming appeals.
The NPLC was launched in August 2007 in six pilot villages, thus enabling the procedures to
be ironed out before national rollout. The length of the project was 18 months and it ended in
February 2009. During the 18-month period, the project tested the demand for voluntary land
consolidation from small landholders and verified the available sporadic evidence that
indicated popular support for small-scale consolidation.
Table 11:
Land consolidation pilot project: preliminary results
Villages
Busauca
Sadova
3088
5922
6006
708
1319
60
Average parcel size, ha
Average number of
parcels per landowner
Number of land
parcels
Number of
landowners
Estimated number of
participating
landowners in % of all
landowners
Percent of parcels
offered for sale
Percent of parcels
offered for exchange
Percent of owners
willing to lease out land
Public agricultural land
available as a reserve
for land consolidation,
ha
Sources:
Bolduresti Calmatui
Opaci
Baimaclia
1757
5626
4204
1786
634
1762
1048
19
62
47
23
33
0,50
0,21
0,29
0,40
0,60
0,73
4,72
4,49
3,36
3,69
3,19
5,08
25,6
13,6
28,1
12,9
14,7
19,7
1,6
7,3
3,1
11,0
1,2
1,8
9
0
46
90
26
25
15
45
46
1,4
19
7
Implementation of land re-parcelling pilots in six villages: Mid-term report, May 2008.
Implementation of land re-parcelling pilots in six villages: Progress report II, September 2008.
The land consolidation pilot project has generally produced positive results, but its final
achievements are much more modest than originally expected. Big questions arise with the
procedure of parcels exchange, which is one of the main instruments of re-parcelling. As we
see from Table 11, an insignificant number of parcels have been offered for exchange. Also,
the small area of the public reserve land in local primaria (mayoralities) makes the task of
land consolidation extremely difficult.
One of the possible barriers to project success is a low demand for land or absence of active
buyers in many rural locations. Absentee ownership or non-participation may also require
16
development of new imaginative tools. How to proceed with land consolidation if there are
parcels belonging to absentee owners in the middle of the field or if a small number of
landowners refuse to participate and instead try to sell their land to outsiders at speculative
prices?
Two possible solutions to these difficulties – both requiring new legislation – are being
currently debated in Moldova. According to one proposal, landowners who do not farm their
land for a certain length of time (e.g., three years) will be obliged to sell their holdings to the
local authorities at the average market price. The authorities will then re-sell the land to active
farmers at the same average price, thus taking part in the consolidation process in the role of a
local land bank. According to another proposal, if a small minority of landowners (e.g., 10%)
block the local consolidation program by their refusal to participate (i.e., voluntarily sell or
exchange their land parcels), they will be obliged by law to exchange their plots for
equivalent land from the village reserve (if other options to use reserve land directly for
consolidation have failed).
The project ended its activities in January 2009. In response to a request from the Government
of Moldova, larger scale re-parcelling activities will be implemented by the World Bank in 40
new villages during the period from February 2009 through June 2010.
Although formal re-parceling programs can be very effective, they should supplement marketdriven consolidation and stimulate land market development through buying and leasing of
land by private entrepreneurs, not replace it.
8
CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS
Land consolidation through land market development has a positive effect on farm efficiency.
A clear negative relationship was observed between productivity and the number of parcels
held by the farmer. An additional argument in favour of land consolidation is that farm
revenue from product sales increases with farm size and decreases with the number of parcels
operated.
Consolidation affects not only farm productivity, but also the standard of living of rural
families, by raising the degree of commercialization and thus contributing to higher family
income. Larger individual farms attain a higher level of commercial sales, because they
consume a substantially smaller proportion of their output than the very small farms. Also, as
the number of parcels per ha increases, the commercialization rate decreases.
Farms leasing in land, as well as those that bought land are larger than farms that rely on their
own land only. The prevalence of short-term lease agreements is an obstacle to land
consolidation as it discourages investment by lessees in land improvement and infrastructure.
Agricultural policy therefore should encourage longer term leasing. It should also strive to
reduce transaction costs for buying and selling of land, which are at present excessive and
constitute an obstacle to the development of buy-and-sell transactions for land consolidation
(Lerman, Cimpoies, 2006).
The common approach to land consolidation in Moldova is individual or market-driven
consolidation, which relies on land market transactions – mainly leasing at the present stage.
Market-driven consolidation of agricultural land does not require new legislation, as the
existing land laws are sufficient for this purpose. Consolidation based on formal governmentsponsored projects will require certain amendments to the Land Code.
17
Consolidation of small fragmented parcels into contiguous holdings is preferred by both
farmers and landowners. However, land consolidation should be carried out on a voluntary
basis in accordance with market principles. Land consolidation projects should supplement
market-driven consolidation, not replace it.
REFERENCES
Household and Farm Surveys:
2005 World Bank survey: see World Bank (2005).
2003 PFAP survey: see Muravschi, Bucatca (2005).
2003 CISR survey: see Gudym et al. (2003).
2003 IAMO survey: see Cimpoieş, Schulze (2006).
2006 UASM Survey of farm managers: see Cimpoies (2007).
2008 ASM Survey (unpublished).
Other sources
Botnarenco, I. (2009). Consolidarea terenurilor agricole în Moldova: teorie, metode, practică.
Chişinău, Moldova: Pontos.
Cimpoieş, D. (2007). Economic impacts of land market development: evidence from
Moldova. Studies on the Agricultural and Food Sector in Central and Eastern Europe 39.
Leibniz Institute of Agricultural Development in Central and Eastern Europe (IAMO).
Halle (Saale): IAMO.
Cimpoieş, D., Schulze, E. (2006). Economic and Financial State of Farm Enterprises in
Moldova, IAMO Discussion Paper No. 91, IAMO – Leibniz Institute of Agricultural
Development in Central and Eastern Europe, Halle (Saale), Germany.
Cimpoieş, D., Baltag, G. (2004). Lease as a form of land consolidation in Moldavian
Agriculture. Studies on the Agricultural and Food Sector in Central and Eastern Europe
25. Institute of Agricultural Development in Central and Eastern Europe (IAMO). Halle
(Saale): IAMO.
DSS (2004a). Agricultural Activity of Households and Farms in the Republic of Moldova in
2003 (Results of the Statistical Survey). Department of Statistics and Sociology, Chisinau,
Moldova.
DSS (2004b). Agriculture in Moldova 2004, Department of Statistics and Sociology,
Chisinau, Moldova.
Gudym, A., Turkan, V., Jigau, I. (2003). Lease of Agricultural Lands 2003, CISR – Center for
Strategic Studies and Reforms, Chisinau. Moldova.
Hartvigsen, M. (2008). Implementation of land re-parceling pilots in six villages (Moldova
land re-parceling pilot project). Mid-term report. May, 2008. MAIA. Chisinau. Moldova.
Hartvigsen, M. (2008). Implementation of land re-parceling pilots in six villages (Moldova
land re-parceling pilot project). Process report II. September, 2008. MAIA. Chisinau.
Moldova.
18
Kanchev, I., Doichinova, Iu. (2000). Agrarian structures in Bulgaria – problems and
development. In: Tillack, P., Pirscher, F. (eds.), Competitiveness of Agricultural
Enterprises and Farm Activities in Transition Countries. Kiel: Wissenschaftsverlag
Vauk, 240-250.
Koester, U., Striewe, L. (1999). Huge potential, huge losses – the search for ways out of the
dilemma of Ukrainian agriculture. In: Siedenberg, A., Hoffman, L. (eds.), Ukraine at the
Crossroads: Economic Reforms in International Perspective. New York: Physica-Verlag,
257-270.
Lerman, Z., Cimpoieş, D. (2006). Land consolidation as a factor for rural development in
Moldova, Europe-Asia Studies 58, No. 3: 439-455.
Lerman, Z., Sedik, D., Pugachov, N., and Goncharuk, A. (2007). Rethinking Agricultural
Reform in Ukraine. Halle (Saale), Germany: IAMO.
Lerman, Z., Sedik, D. (2007). The role of land markets in improving rural incomes.
Discussion Paper No. 15.07, the Center of Agricultural Economic Research, the Hebrew
University of Jerusalem.
Lerman, Z., Sutton, W. (2008). Productivity and efficiency of small and large farms in
transition: Evidence from Moldova, Post-Soviet Affairs, 24: No. 2: 97-120.
Lund, P. (1983). The use of alternative measures of farm size in analysis of size and
efficiency relationship. Journal of Agricultural Economics 2: 187-189.
Muravschi, A., Bucatca, A. (2005). Agricultural Policy in Farmers’ Opinion. PFAP - Private
Farmers Assistance Program, East-West Management Institute and USAID, Chisinau,
Moldova.
World Bank (2005). Moldova Agricultural Policy Notes: Agricultural Land, Draft analytical
report, World Bank, Washington, DC (unpublished).
19